UnitedNationsConferenceonTradeandDevelopment COMPENDIUMON DEBTSUSTAINABILITY ANDDEVELOPMENT UnitedNations NewYorkandGeneva,2009 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Note SymbolsofUnitedNationsdocumentsarecomposedof capitalletterscombinedwithfigures.Mentionofsucha symbol indicates a reference to a United Nations document. Thedesignationsemployedandthepresentationofthe materialinthispublicationdonotimplytheexpression ofanyopinionwhatsoeveronthepartoftheSecretariat oftheUnitedNationsconcerningthelegalstatusofany country, territory, city or area, or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. Material in this publication may be freely quoted; acknowledgement, however, is requested (including reference to the document number). It would be appreciated if a copy of the publication containing the quotation were sent to the Publications Assistant, Division on Globalization and Development Strategies, UNCTAD,PalaisdesNations,CHͲ1211Geneva10. UNITEDNATIONSPUBLICATION UNCTAD/GDS/DDF/2008/1 Copyright©UnitedNations,2009 Allrightsreserved ii CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CONTENTS COMPENDIUMONDEBTSUSTAINABILITYANDDEVELOPMENT ..................................................... i CONTENTS ................................................................................................................................. iii CHAPTERI.OVERVIEW:DEBTSUSTAINABILITYINTHEORYANDPRACTICE..................................... 1 A. B. C. D. E. F. G. Introduction ................................................................................................................................... 1 DefinitionandDimensionsofDebtSustainability ......................................................................... 3 CountryStudies.............................................................................................................................. 5 InstitutionalFrameworkforDebtManagement............................................................................ 7 CreditRatingAgencies ................................................................................................................... 8 GlobalRulesforInternationalFinanceandTrade ......................................................................... 9 ConclusionsandFutureTasks ...................................................................................................... 11 CHAPTERII.DEBTSUSTAINABILITYASSESSMENT:THEIMFAPPROACHANDALTERNATIVES......... 17 A. B. C. D. Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 17 WhatisDebtSustainability? ........................................................................................................ 18 ApproachestoAssessingDebtSustainability:ACriticalReview ................................................. 23 ReviewandConclusions............................................................................................................... 36 CHAPTERIII.THEMECHANICSOFDEBTSUSTAINABILITYANALYSIS.............................................. 45 A. B. C. D. E. Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 45 DebtIndicatorsandEarlyWarningofCrisis................................................................................. 46 ThePresentValueofFutureIncome ........................................................................................... 48 TheFinancingGap........................................................................................................................ 50 DevelopmentPolicyͲBasedApproachtoDebtSustainability ...................................................... 58 CHAPTERIV.ANANALYTICALFRAMEWORKFORDEBTSUSTAINABILITYANDDEVELOPMENT ...... 63 A. B. C. D. E. F. Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 63 Debtandthe“FinanceGap”Model............................................................................................. 66 SustainableDebtLevels ............................................................................................................... 71 FiscalConsequencesofExternalDebt ......................................................................................... 77 DebtVulnerabilityandExternalShocks ....................................................................................... 78 Conclusions:PrinciplesforDebtManagementinDevelopmentStrategies ................................ 81 CHAPTERV.THEDEBTEXPERIENCESOFUGANDA,KENYAANDBOLIVIA...................................... 89 A. B. C. D. E. F. Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 89 Uganda ......................................................................................................................................... 90 Kenya’sDebtExperience.............................................................................................................. 96 Bolivia’sDebtExperience........................................................................................................... 101 DebtExperiencesCompared...................................................................................................... 108 ConcludingRemarks................................................................................................................... 110 CHAPTERVI.CASESTUDIES:ARGENTINAANDTHEREPUBLICOFKOREA.................................... 115 A. B. C. D. Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 115 LessonsfromtheArgentineCrisisandDefault.......................................................................... 116 ExternalDebtManagementoftheRepublicofKoreaduringtheCrisesof1979Ͳ1980 and1997Ͳ1998 ........................................................................................................................... 123 ConcludingRemarks................................................................................................................... 130 iii CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERVII.APPROPRIATEINSTITUTIONALSETTINGSFORPUBLICDEBTMANAGEMENT.......... 143 A. B. C. Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 143 TheContextofPublicDebtManagement.................................................................................. 144 TheRoleandOrganizationofaDMO ........................................................................................ 148 CHAPTERVIII.CREDITRATINGAGENCIESANDTHEIRPOTENTIALIMPACTON DEVELOPINGCOUNTRIES........................................................................................................ 165 A. B. C. D. E. F. Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 165 CreditRatingAgenciesintheInternationalFinancialSystem ................................................... 166 CRAs’ProceduresandMethods................................................................................................. 168 ImpactofRatings ....................................................................................................................... 172 PublicPolicyConcerns ............................................................................................................... 176 Conclusions ................................................................................................................................ 180 CHAPTERIX.PURSUINGSUSTAINABLEDEVELOPMENTSTRATEGIES: THECASEOFTHEBALANCEOFPAYMENTRULESINWTO.......................................................... 191 A. B. C. D. E. F. Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 191 ExchangeControlsandConvertibility ........................................................................................ 194 TradeRestrictionsforBalanceͲofͲPaymentsPurposes............................................................. 199 TradeFinancingandEquity........................................................................................................ 202 TheGeneralAgreementonTradeandServices(GATS),BalanceofPayments,andDebt Sustainability .............................................................................................................................. 204 Conclusions ................................................................................................................................ 209 CHAPTERX.RISKASSOCIATEDWITHTRENDSINTHETREATMENTOFSOVEREIGNDEBT INBILATERALTRADEANDINVESTMENTTREATIES .................................................................... 211 A. B. C. D. E. Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 211 SovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties ...................................................... 211 ImplicationsforSovereignDebtProblemsofIncludingNationalTreatmentandMFN TreatmentinFTAs ...................................................................................................................... 213 InvestorͲStateLawsuitsandSovereignDebt ............................................................................. 216 ConcludingRemarks................................................................................................................... 217 iv CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERI OVERVIEW:DEBTSUSTAINABILITY INTHEORYANDPRACTICE AndrewCornford (FinancialMarketsCenter) A. Introduction Debt sustainability, which concerns the feasibility for a country of meeting its debtͲrelated financial obligations during a period beginning with the present, has proved an elusive concept. This is not surprisinginviewofitsdependenceonanintrinsicallyuncertainfuture.Interestintheconditionsfordebt sustainabilitybuildsonanearliertraditionofworkondebtmanagementwherethefocuswasoncountry riskandonthelikelihoodandconsequencesofdebtdefault. Theshiftinfocusfromcountryrisktodebtsustainabilityreflectsthesearchofnationalandinternational policymakers for rules for external debt management which have a good theoretical justification and a reasonable track record of application. The problems of debt management have traditionally also been closelyrelatedtoconsiderationofseveralotherissuesinvolvingexternaldebt.Therecentshiftinfocusis much less evident in the way in which these issues are approached. This is true, for example, of considerationofexternaldebtpolicyasanimportantelementofglobalregimesforinternationalfinance and trade. In spite of the lack of a direct link to debt sustainability some features of these regimes are takenupinthepapersinthiscollectionowingtotheirimportancetotheframeworkofinternationalrules withinwhichexternaldebtmanagementiscarriedout. Traditionalcountryriskanalysishadtwodimensions,politicalriskandtransferrisk.1Thefirstreferstothe determinantsofthepoliticalwillandthesecondtotheeconomiccapacitytomeetobligationsondebts incurredthroughsovereignborrowingaswellasthroughthecrossͲborderliabilitiesofprivateinstitutions operatingwithinthecountry’sfrontiers.Thetwodimensionsarenotcompletelydistinctsinceeconomic capacity depends partly on a country’s willingness to take the policy measures required to meet debt 1 GoodoverviewsofthetraditionalanalysisofcountryriskareFriedman(1983)andKrayenbuehl(1988) 1 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice obligations, and this willingness in turn reflects a balancing of political costs and benefits. Nevertheless analysisunderthetwoheadingscoverslargelydifferentsubjects. Thesubjects taken upunderpoliticalriskcomprise acountry’sconstitutional andpolitical environment, thequalityofGovernmentandthelevelofcorruption,inequalitiesofincomesandwealth,literacyrates, demographic structures, and ethnic and religious differences. Transfer risk concerns subjects not necessarily less complex but mostly more easily quantifiable. Some of these factors can be classified as having a substantially domestic origin such as fiscal and monetary policy, the exchangeͲrate regime, access to natural resources, the use of funds acquired through foreign borrowing, the tax system, and exchange controls for current and capital transactions. Other factors are external. These include trade barriers to a country’s exports, commodity prices, interest rates and other conditions in international financialmarkets,shippingcosts,theavailabilityofconcessionalfinancing,andnaturaldisasters. Transfer risk varies with the availability and terms of external financing and with changes in the other determinantsofaccesstoforeignexchange.Intheassessmentoftransferriskamajorroleisplayedby quantitativeindicatorssuchasthefollowing: x The debt service ratio: interest and principal with a maturity of at least one year divided by receiptsofforeignrevenueduringaperiodT; x Thedebt/GNPratio:externalpublicandprivatedebt(normallyexcludingthatwithamaturityof lessthanoneyear)dividedbyGNP; x Theinterestserviceratio:interestpayments(normallyexcludingthoseondebtwithamaturityof lessthanoneyear)dividedbyexportsofgoodsandservicesduringaperiodT,which,ifsubtracted from the debt service ratio, indicates the percentage of foreign exchange receipts required to serviceprincipal; x Thereserves/importsratio:officiallypublishedreservesdividedbyimportsduringaperiodT; x Theliquiditygapratio:anumeratorconsistingofdebtwithamaturityofuptooneyearminusthe balance on current account divided by the sum of export receipts and unilateral transfers. The ratioindicatestheliquiditygapwhichneedstobecoveredbyshortͲtermborrowing; x CurrentͲaccountbalance/GNP; x The compressibility ratio: nonͲessential imports as a percentage of total imports, an indicator whichinprincipaldependsonclassifyingpartof importsas basic needs (energy,food,essential inputs and investment goods) on the basis of knowledge of the economy’s requirements but whichinpracticeisoftenbasedonaruleofthumbsuchas25percentofimports. Until the late 1970s analysts tended to focus primarily on mediumͲterm indicators of transfer risk. However, owing to countries’ greater use of international financial markets to meet their external financingneedsandexperienceofthedebtcrisisofthe1980s,theyincreasinglydevotedgreaterattention toindicatorsbearingonliquidity(forexample,thereserves/importsratio,theliquiditygapratio,andthe compressibilityratio). However, actual experience of countries’ debt problems has indicated limits to the usefulness of the commonly used indicators. These limits are partly due to lack of information concerning aspects of countries’positionswithanimportantbearingontheircapacitytomeettheirexternalobligations.During theAsiancrisisof1997Ͳ1998,forexample,statisticsforofficialreservesdidnotinclude theauthorities’ commitments in the forward exchange markets or to private sector financial institutions which in both cases reduced the foreign exchange available to meet external debt service. Moreover, the traditional indicatorsofcountryriskaredesignedfortheassessmentofriskandaremuchlesswellsuitedtobetools fordebtmanagement. 2 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment To meet the needs of the latter attempts began to be made to give a more precise meaning to the conceptofdebtsustainability.Theseweredesignedtoprovideaconceptcapableofcontributingtopolicy undereachofthethreemajorheadingsofdebtmanagement,namelyavoidanceoffinancialcrises,debt management once a debt crisis appears imminent or is under way, and postͲdefault policy and rescheduling.Atthesametime,partlyinresponsetothegrowingcomplexityofmanycountries’external commitmentsandtothegreateravailabilityofinstrumentsformanagingthem,attentionhasincreasingly beendevotedtocountries’overallexternalbalancesheets,andtotheproblemsandopportunitieswhich theypresentforpolicymakers. Work on sustainability accompanied parallel attempts to investigate the theoretical underpinnings of conditionsfortheenforcementofcrossͲborderdebtcontracts,andhaslikewisebeenmarkedbyinterest indevelopingamorerigorousconceptualframeworktoreplaceitsmoreadhocpredecessor.2However, thepapersinthiscollectionpointtotheprobablyinsolubledifficultiesconfrontingtheattempttodevelop aconceptofdebtsustainabilitycapableofservingasaphilosopher’sstoneforpolicymakers. B. DefinitionandDimensionsofDebtSustainability InChapterII,Wyploszprovidesanextensivereviewofthekeyconceptsinvolvedindifferentdefinitionsof debtsustainability.Theseareasfollows: x Thresholdlevelofdebt/GDPratio; x Solvency, i.e. the condition that future surpluses on current account are sufficient to cover interestobligationsandrepaymentsofprincipal; x Debt serviceability, i.e. solvency plus the additional condition of no illiquidity, which denotes inabilitytoservicedebtsatparticularmomentsintime; x Solvency plus avoidance of the need for a major correction in the form of large cuts in public expenditureorlargeincreasesintaxationrequiredfordebtservice; x Networth,i.e.theconditionthatthepresentvalueofcurrentͲaccountsurpluseslesscurrentdebt isnotdecreasingovertime; x Debtstationarity,i.e.theconditionthatthedebt/GDPratiodoesnotincreasewithoutbounds. Wyploszpointsoutthatowingtothedependenceofeachoftheseconceptsonaninherentlyuncertain future they cannot be used to construct universally applicable rules for debt sustainability, an attempt which he characterizes as “mission impossible”. Thus rules using the concepts as a base for policy prescriptions will necessarily be arbitrary and imprecise. Wyplosz elaborates the implications of this impossibilitythroughanexaminationofproceduresforDebtSustainabilityAssessment(DSA)designedby the IMF and the World Bank’s International Development Association (IDA) to formalize the notion of prudentdebtstrategiesreceptiveoacountry’sdevelopmentneeds. The startingͲpoint for the IMF’s DSA is a baseline fiveͲyear forecast combined with stress testing for adverse shocks. To allow for the dependence of the probability of debt distress on countryͲspecific economic and political conditions this technical exercise is combined with a Country Policy and InstitutionalAssessment(CPIA)developedbytheWorldBank.TheCPIAgeneratesanindexofgovernance quality based on 20 component indicators, and countries are classified into three groups according to theirCPIAindex,thosewithindexesofhigherqualitybeingpermittedhigherdebt/GDPthresholds. 2 For a concise account of the development of the new conceptual framework for the analysis of crossͲborder debt see SturzeneggerandZettelmeyer(2006:chapter2). 3 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice AsWyplosznotes,thisprocedureincludesanumberofarbitrarychoicesregardingscenariosanddoesnot allowformutuallyreinforcingeffectsduetocorrelationsamongshocksorforalternativepolicyresponses to shocks. Moreover, it is not designed to take account of the potential of borrowing for actually accelerating economic growth, except indirectly to the extent that a good CPIA index is likely to be associatedwithanincreaseinthispotential.Thus,perhapsunsurprisingly,theIMF’sDSAhasbeenatthe centreofdiscussionsondebtpolicybetweentheFundandnationalGovernments. In view of the intractable nature of DSA, Wyplosz proposes limiting the exercise to less ambitious objectives.Forthispurposeheprefersafocusontheevolutionofdebtlevelsandontherequirementsof avoiding debt distress (concerns which were at the centre of the traditional approach to country risk describedinsectionI,thoughthisisnotmentionedbyWyplosz).Inthecaseofcountrieswithaccessto internationalfinancialmarketsimportantindicatorsforDSAaretherisk premiums in thetermsoftheir borrowing. Moreover Wyplosz stresses that any procedure for DSA be open, and that it should include experts other than those of the multilateral financial institutions themselves. DSA should also accommodatethefactthatdebtaccumulation canbealegitimatepartofdevelopment policy.Wyplosz acknowledges that his proposal can only lead to avoidance of debt distress under plausible, normal conditions.Thepossibilityofdebtdistressinresponsetoexceptionaleventsissimplytobeacceptedasa factoflife,andonewhoseconsequencesaretobedealtwithasandwhenitoccurs. WyploszisnotsuggestingthattheelementsoftheIMFapproachtoDSAhavenovalue.Buttheyshould bepartof theframeworkforpolicydiscussionand notamechanicalguide topolicyconclusions,asthe IMFitselfincreasinglyrecognizes. TheanalyticsoftheIMFapproachandofotherschematicapproachestodebtsustainabilityaremorefully developed in Chapter III and IV by TranͲNguyen and Tola (henceforth TranͲNguyen) and Fitzgerald (Fitzgerald). TranͲNguyen’s results include “templates” for debt sustainability based on alternative national accounting identities as points of departure as well as conclusions concerning the longͲrun stability – and thus feasibility – of time paths for debt. The paper also develops simple frameworks for analyzing the relation between debt and growth. In a similar spirit Fitzgerald also explores the use of nationalaccountingidentitiestoderivesimple“golden”rulesfordebtsustainabilityaswellasconstraints onfiscalpolicywhichtakeaccountofaccesstoexternalfinancing. Fitzgerald provides a critical review of “financing gap” models which were long widely used as an analytical framework for discussion of debt sustainability. These models place economic growth at the centre of the exercise. The objective of the planning authority is to maximize GDP growth subject to constraints imposed by domestic savings, import capacity, and the fiscal ceiling determined by tax revenueandaccesstosovereignborrowing. Theshortcomingsofthesemodelsaretheirdependenceonstableandexogenouslygivenrelationships. An alternative approach explored by Fitzgerald, which draws on assumptions now common in macroeconomics,involvestakinginvestmenttobedeterminedbyintertemporalmaximizationsubjectto relationshipsbetweenGDP,thecapitalstockdividedbetweenthatwhichisdomesticallyandthatwhichis externallyfinanced,depreciation,thecostofnewinvestment,nationalincomedefinedasthedifference betweenoutputandinterestcosts,andexternalconstraintsaccordingtowhichimportsaredetermined bynationalincomeandexportsbytheproductivityoftheexportsector.Thisapproachcangeneratean expression for the optimal debt level as a function of the allocation of financing to different major categoriesofinvestment. TranͲNguyen reviews recent literature on earlyͲwarning indicators of currency and debt crises. This literatureisanaturaldevelopmentoftheearlierapproachtocountryriskdiscussedabove.However,toa greaterextentthanearlierwork,themorerecentliteraturemakesuseofeconometricanalysis.Moreover 4 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment italsoincludesnewindicatorssuggestedbyrecentexperienceoffinancialcrisessuchasindicatorsofthe fragilityofthefinancialsector. AmajorconclusionofTranͲNguyenisthattheapproachessurveyedsufferfromtheshortcomingthatthe concept of debt sustainability is not integrated into a framework which also includes a country’s developmentstrategyandtheimpliedgrowthtrajectory.AlthoughTranͲNguyen’ssuggestionsastosuch integration are limited to simple debt and growth analytics, the subject would be natural candidate for inclusion in the more open, less ruleͲbound procedures to analysis of debt sustainability proposed by Wyplosz. C. CountryStudies Ofthefivecasestudiesincludedinthiscollectionofpapersthree,Uganda,KenyaandBolivia,wereoflowͲ incomecountrieswhoseexternaldebtwaslargelytheresultofpublicbilateralandmultilateralfinancing, whiletheremainingtwo,ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea,werecountrieswhosedebtcrisesreflected abreakdownintheiraccesstointernationalfinancialmarkets. 1. LowͲIncomeCountries The experiences of Uganda, Kenya and Bolivia share key common features in the form of failure to generatesustainablegrowthandpovertyreductionandcontinuingvulnerabilitytotheimpactofhigher interest rates and of lower prices on their commodity exports. All three countries undertook reform programs consisting of tighter macroeconomic policy and price liberalization. But the programs did not addressmajorweaknesses.Forexample,theydidnotincludeabroadeningofthetaxbase,andthetariff reductions adopted actually harmed progress towards this objective. The Governments of Uganda and Kenya are still heavily dependent on foreign aid for the financing of their expenditures. Moreover substantialproportionsofeconomicactivityandexportsinallthreecountriesremainconcentratedina limitednumberofunprocessedprimarycommodities. Therewerealsoimportantdifferencesbetweenthethreecountries’experiences. UgandaandBolivia,which(unlikeKenya)arebothHIPCcountries,illustratebothgeneralweaknessesof thisinitiativeandflawsmorespecificallyapplicabletothesituationsofthetwocountries.Thefirstsetof weaknesses included inadequate analytical bases, which reflected dependence on unrealistic country scenarios and failure to take proper account of vulnerability to exogenous shocks. The second included toonarrowadefinitionofdebtsustainability,failuretoallowforthewayinwhichpostͲHIPCborrowing couldspeedilyreversegainsinacountry’sdebtposition,andtheinappropriatenessofloansasopposedto grantsforthefinancingofprogramsofpovertyalleviation. DuringtheperiodcoveredbythecasestudiesUgandaandBoliviaachievedanadequatetechnicalcapacity fordebtmanagement.Kenyaontheotherhandstilllacksanadequatesystemforthispurpose. 2. LowͲIncomeCountries The main focus of the studies of the Republic of Korea and Argentina are their recent currencyͲcumͲ banking crises, for the former in 1997Ͳ1998 and for the latter in 2000Ͳ2001. For the Republic of Korea, thereisalsoareviewofanearlierdebtcrisisin1979Ͳ1980whichtheGovernmentsucceededinridingout withoutrecoursetothedeflationarymeasuresusuallycharacteristicofpolicyresponsesinsuchcases. 5 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice Therecentcrisesforbothcountriesweredominatedbydevelopmentsaffectingthecapitalaccountafter periods in which the liberalization of capital transactions led to greater integration into international financialmarkets.Inbothcasestherewerelargefluctuationsofcapitalflows–largeinflowspriortothe crises followed by large outflows. In both cases the IMF’s policy prescriptions were ill suited to dealing withthecrises. TheoriginoftheRepublicofKoreacrisiswasanunfavorableshiftinitsexportmarketsbeginningin1995. Thisledtoinventoryaccumulationandlossesamongstthecountry’slargeindustrialgroupsthatinturn provokedareassessmentofthesegroups’prospectsamongsttheforeigninvestorsandlendersonwhich thegroupswereincreasinglycomingtodepend.Asaresultofbankruptciesaccompaniedbyrevelations concerningpoorcorporategovernanceandcorruption,during1997foreigners’flightfromthecountry’s stock market accelerated and its banks faced increasing difficulties in rolling over shortͲterm interbank loans.TheinitialfinancingpackageagreedlateintheyearbetweentheGovernmentandtheIMF,which includedawiderangeofconditionsincludingmacroeconomicstringencyandliberalizationoffinancialand labormarkets,failedtostemthecrisisasinterestratesreached40percentandthecurrencycontinuedto depreciate. A second package was accompanied by an agreement with creditor banks to loan extension and to a lengthening of maturities in return for government guarantees on private debt. This sufficed to turn aroundmarketsentiment,andasharprecoveryineconomicgrowthfollowedin1999.Thisexperienceof theRepublicofKoreahasledcommentatorstoquerytheappropriatenessofthedeflationaryfiscaland monetary conditions of the first package as a response to what was principally a capitalͲaccount crisis ratheronecharacterizedbymacroeconomicimbalances. The paper on Argentina locates the source of its crisis in the exchangeͲrate regime and the impact on externalͲdebt dynamics of interest rates required to manage the country’s capital account. This interpretation is at variance with the view of the country’s Governments during the preͲdefault period whereby problems were seen to be due to fiscal mismanagement, which called for a policy response consistingofaseriesofpackagesoffiscaltightening. AsArgentina’scrisisgotunderway,thereweremarkeddisagreementsbetweenthenewGovernmentand theIMFastoappropriatepolicymeasures.TheIMF’srecommendationsincludedallowingtheexchange ratetofloatfreelyandanapproachtothebankingcrisiswhichwouldhaveentailedbankliquidations.The Government’spolicies,whichaccompaniedthebeginningofaneconomicrecoveryfromthefirsthalfof 2002,includedexchangecontrolsandrestrictionsoncapitaloutflowsaspartofapolicyofmanagingthe exchange rate, export taxes designed to capture for the Government some of the profits due to devaluation, and a flexible monetary policy aimed at assisting the recovery of the banking sector. The Government also resisted pressure from foreign Governments and the IMF to improve the terms of its offerondebtrestructuringtoitsexternalcreditors. Owing to the lack of the required data it is not possible to conduct a controlled experiment to test the validityofthenowincreasinglywidelyheldbeliefastoinappropriatenessofstandardfeaturesofpolicy programsassociatedwithIMFpolicypackages.However,theRepublicofKorea’sdebtcrisisof1979Ͳ1980 doesprovideacasestudyofthesuccessfulapplicationofadifferentpolicyapproach. Thecrisisbeganin1979afteryearsofrapidgrowthpoweredbyaninvestmentboom.Majorfeaturesof thecrisiswereasharpincreaseinthecurrentͲaccountdeficit,asevererecession,andariseininflationof consumerpricestoanannualrateofalmost30percent.InsuchcircumstancesthestandardIMFpolicy prescription would probably have involved macroeconomic stabilization through fiscal and monetary tightening and allowing the exchange rate to float. The view of the Republic of Korea Government, however,wasthatacceleratinginflationwasthesourceofdeterioratingincomedistribution,laborunrest, anddecliningexportcompetitiveness.ThepoliciesadoptedincludedaoneͲoffdevaluationfollowedbya 6 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment managed float under which the Won was tied to a basket of major international currencies, macroeconomic policies giving priority to stopping the economic downturn, and continued recourse to externalfinancingofadecliningcurrentͲaccountdeficitdespiteanalreadyhighlevelofexternaldebt. The economic recovery which followed is likely to have reflected the effects of an improvement in the external economic environment as well the policies pursued. Commentators also attribute a significant role to capital controls which prevented capital flight. Conditions associated with different countries’ currencyͲcumͲdebtcrisesareofcourseneverthesame.Nonetheless,theRepublicofKoreaexperienceof the early 1980s deserves a place in the template of the menu of policy measures for debt crisis management. D. InstitutionalFrameworkforDebtManagement Whatever the approach adopted by a developing country to debt sustainability, properly developed institutionsfordebtmanagementarerequired.ThetasksoftheseinstitutionsassetoutinChapterVIIby JaimeDelgadilloCortez(Delgadillo)includethefollowing: x x x x x x x x Theproductionofreliabledebtdata; Developmentofthedomesticfinancialmarket; Ensuringadequatefinancingfordevelopmentalandsocialneeds; EnsuringcompliancewithdebtͲserviceobligations; Controllingcontingentliabilities; Meetingtherequirementsofnegotiationswithcreditors; Performingcost/riskanalysis; Designingstrategiesfordebtsustainability. For this purpose design of the institutional framework for debt management has to focus on the following: x x x x x Governance; Clarityoftherolesofthedifferentinstitutionsdealingwithdebtmanagement; Specificationoftheobjectives; Coordinationofpublicdebtmanagementwithotherpublicpolicies; The organizational structure of the principal body responsible for debt management, the Debt ManagementOffice(DMO); Transparencyandaccountability. x Delgadillo discusses and exemplifies different options under these two headings for this institutional framework. ThenetworkofrelationsdescribedbyDelgadilloofwhichtheDMOisthecentreincludetheministryof finance, the central bank, the national/planning or development office, creditors, international organizations (which may themselves be among the country’s creditors), the public and private entities whichareasourceofguaranteesandinsurancefortradefinance,etc.,andmajorparticipantsindomestic financialmarkets. Theinstitutionalframeworkfordebtmanagementcanbeexpectedtoevolveinresponsetothechanging profileofacountry’sexternalliabilitiesanditsleveloffinancialdevelopmentaswellastotheincreasingly comprehensive approach to management of a country’s external assets and liabilities which is now receiving greater attention (see below). Inter alia, this approach may entail closer working relations between the DMO as described by Delgadillo and those responsible for the regulation of financial 7 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice institutions and thus for oversight of the currency and maturity risks associated with these institutions’ balancesheets. E. CreditRatingAgencies The ratings industry has its origins in firms which were established in midͲnineteenthͲcentury United States to provide merchants with information on the creditworthiness of their customers. Ratings originallyreferredtothecapacityofanobligortomeetpaymentsdueonaparticularfinancialobligation after taking into consideration the creditworthiness of guarantors, insurers, and other forms of credit enhancement.Butratingsmaynowrefertoissuers,includingcountries,aswellasissues. Assessment of developing countries’ creditworthiness long relied on financial institutions’ own systems for this purpose, guidance from their regulators, services providing information on country risks, and rankingsofcountrycreditriskprovidedbypublicationssuchasinstitutionalInvestorandEuromoney.The growthintheimportanceofcreditratingagenciesinrecentyearsreflectstherequirementsofthegrowth of international capital markets which has led to increasingly widespread need for creditworthiness assessments: borrowers are seeking ready recognition from investors; investors require an accessible vehicle for assessing the quality of securities; and banks find ratings a useful marketing tool for selling papertocustomers(Fight,2004:46). SincethemidͲ1990stheperformanceoftheagencieshasbeencriticizedonseveralgrounds,asdiscussed inChapterVIIIbyElkhoury:theirslownesstoreacttochangesincreditworthinessandthentheirtendency onoccasiontooverͲreact;theiruseofuntransparentratingmethods;theirprivilegedregulatoryposition; theirlackofaccountability;andthevulnerabilityoftheiroperationstoconflictsofinterest. x Criticsviewedtheagencies’responsetotheAsianfinancialcrisisof1997Ͳ1998ascharacteristicof theirtendencytoslownesstoreactfollowedbyoverͲreaction. x Althoughtheagenciesmakeknownthefactorstakenintoaccountasinputstotheirratings,their assignmentofweightstothesefactorsisopaque. x Theagencies’privilegedregulatorypositionisduetoinstitutionalinvestors’needforaratingof investmentgradebyanofficiallyrecognizedagencyforthesecuritiesinwhichtheyarepermitted to invest as well as to other regulatory exemptions accorded to such securities. In the United States such recognition is reserved for Nationally Recognized Statistical Rating Organizations (NRSROs), a designation conferred on only a limited number of agencies including the major three,Moody’s,Standard&Poor’sandFitch. x Theagenciesarenotaccountablefortheirmistakesortheirabuseofpower. x Conflicts of interest may arise owing to the agencies’ involvement in the structuring of instrumentstheyrate,theirprovisionofconsultancyservicestoissuers,thepotentialforpressure to purchase agencies’ consultancy services in return for an improved rating, and the use of aggressivesalestacticstoinduceanissuerto“solicit”andthuspayforaratingwhichithadnot initiallyrequested(an“unsolicited”rating). Elkhoury reviews some recent official initiatives to deal with these criticisms. These include the Credit RatingAgencyReformActpassedbytheUnitedStatesCongressinSeptember2006,whichtightensthe procedural requirements for NRSRO registration and certification, and strengthens the authority of the Securities Exchange Commission over NRSROs; and a Code of Conduct issued in December 2004 by the International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO), whose objectives include ensuring the integrityoftheratingprocessandachievinggreatertransparencyregardingratingsmethodology. 8 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment However, these steps are unlikely to satisfy the credit agencies’ growing band of critics. The agencies’ operationshavereturnedtothespotlightinconnectionwithratingsaccordedtotranchesofsecuritized assetsduringthecreditcrisiswhichbeganinthesummerof2007.Againspecialattentionisfocusedon the opacity of the methods underlying their ratings, their lack of accountability, and the potential for conflictsofinterestarisingfromtheirroleasprovidersof“exanteopinions”and“structuringadvice”as wellasratingsinthecaseofstructuredfinancing.3 The consequences may be more stringent rules for agency certification, minimum standards for the trainingandqualificationsofagencies’analysts,andincreasedtransparencyregardingtheiroperations.If one looks further into the future, a large increase and the number of credit rating agencies worldwide seems quite likely. Inter alia, such an increase would be a natural consequence of the role accorded to credit rating agencies in determining weights for credit risk in the determination of banks’ minimum regulatorycapitalunderBasel2,whichmorethan100countriesarenowplanningtointroduce. F. GlobalRulesforInternationalFinanceandTrade Discussion of global rules in connection with external debt typically focuses mainly on arrangements capable of making debt cries less likely and of facilitating their management and resolution. Subjects include bankruptcy mechanisms for sovereign, and sometimes also private, crossͲborder debt, improvementsintermsandfundingforIMFcrisislending,andpreͲcrisisinterventioninthemarketsfor internationaldebt.4Buttheframeworkwithinwhichcountriesmanagetheirexternaldebtisalsoaffected by developments elsewhere affecting rules for trade and trade finance, balanceͲofͲpayments measures andforeigninvestment. The importance of the latter set of rules was recognized in the Declaration on the Contribution of the WorldTradeOrganizationtoAchievingGreaterCoherenceinGlobalEconomicPolicyMakingadoptedat the time of the establishment of the WTO. This Declaration acknowledged the links between economic policies as follows: “Successful cooperation in each area of economic policy contributes to progress in other areas. Greater exchange rate stability…should contribute towards the expansion of trade, sustainablegrowthanddevelopment,andthecorrectionofexternalimbalances.Thereisalsoaneedfor anadequateandtimelyflowofconcessionalandnonͲconcessionalfinancialandrealinvestmentresources todevelopingcountriesandforfurthereffortstoaddressdebtproblems,tohelpensureeconomicgrowth anddevelopment.”Suchcoherenceinglobalpolicymakingrequiresthat“theinternationalinstitutionsin eachoftheseareasfollowconsistentandmutuallysupportivepolicies”. Twopapersinthiscollectiontakeupsomespecificinternationalrulesaffectingnationalpoliciesinareas characterized by interfaces between trade, investment and external financing. Chapter IX by Howse discusses the applicability of WTO rules to exchange restrictions and to measures directed at exports, importsandthebalanceofpaymentsfromthepointofviewoftheircompatibilitywithnotionsoffairness and equity. In Chapter X, Caliari examines the risks to national autonomy regarding debt policy which couldresultfromprovisionsconcerninginvestmentinrecenttradeandinvestmenttreaties. 1. TradeandBalanceͲofPaymentsMeasuresunderWTORules Howse takes as his startingͲpoint the commitment of United Nations Member States in the Millennium Declaration to “an open, equitable, ruleͲbased, predictable and nonͲdiscriminatory multilateral trading and financial system”. Whilst acknowledging that the concept of equity in international trade and in 3 Differencesbetweencreditratingagencies’rolewithrespecttostructuredfinance,ontheonehand,andbondissues,onthe other,aredescribedinCommitteeontheGlobalFinancialSystem(2005). 4 ForasurveyofsuchproposalsseeSturzeneggerandZettelmeyer(2006:chapter12). 9 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice financialrulesandinstitutionslacksagenerallyaccepteddefinition,Howseshowsthatinternationalrules (including those of the WTO and the IMF Articles of Agreement) incorporate fairness, a concept closely related to equity. Moreover one important ingredient of equity in international instruments concerning trade,financeanddevelopmentisthenotionthatrulesshouldbeadjustedtothedevelopmentneedsof countries’differentsituations.Anotheringredientisthatofpeople’srightto“voiceandparticipation”,i.e. their right not to have a vision of development forced on them or decided by others. The Millennium Declarationalsocontainsadistributionalcomponentsincetheconceptofglobalsolidarityrequiresthat “globalchallengesmustbemanagedinawaythatdistributesthecostsandburdensfairlyinaccordance withbasicprinciplesofequityandsocialjustice”. Concerning exchange restrictions Howse notes the generally accepted view of the intent of GATT/WTO provisionsforgoodstradethat,regardlessoftheeffectoftherestrictionsontradetransactions,theydo notimposedisciplinesgoingbeyondthoseoftheIMF.However,suchrulingsarepermissibleforexchange restrictionsnotendorsedbytheIMF,ascopewhichHowsebelieveshasbeenusedbytheGATTandthe WTOasthebasisforexcessivelynarrowinterpretationofcountries’rightofrecoursetotrademeasures. More generally Howse questions the apparent presumption of GATT/WTO case law that exchange restrictionsnotendorsedbytheIMFentailviolationofGATT/WTOrules. The GATT/WTO provisions for goods trade leave no scope for rulings on exchange controls applying to capital as opposed to current transactions. However, the corresponding provisions for balanceͲofͲ payments restrictions in the case of services trade under the General Agreement on Trade in Service (GATS) could lead to challenges to capital controls on the ground that they are inconsistent with a country’s specific commitments interpreted in combination with general GATS obligations. Howse believesthatguidelinesshouldbedrawnupforsuchcasesbyinstitutionswithamandatetotakeaccount ofequityinthetradeandfinancialsystems. HowsealsodiscussestwootherrecentWTOrulingssuggestingashifttomorerestrictiveinterpretationof provisions with a bearing on the compatibility of WTO rules with the principles of equity, voice and participation. The first ruling involved a case in which the United States challenged India’s continuing use of trade restrictionsforbalanceͲofͲpaymentsreasonsinpursuitofdevelopmentpoliciesunderGATTArticleXVIII. HeretheWTOAppellateBodyruledthatremovalbyIndiaofitsbalanceͲofͲpaymentsrestrictionswould not require a change in its development policies since the objectives of these policies could equally be achievedbymacroeconomicmeasures.HowsetakestheviewthatthisrulingisnotinaccordwiththeselfͲ declaratorycharacterofGATTArticleXVIII. InthesecondrulingtheAppellateBodydecidedagainstBrazil’suseofofficialsupportforthefinancingof aircraft exports on the basis of arguments which included use of the benchmarks of the OECD Export Credit Arrangement. As Howse points out, this Arrangement is an agreement reached through negotiations involving the organization’s restricted membership which takes no account of structural differencesbetweenthefinancialmarketsofdevelopinganddevelopedcountries. 2. DebtandBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties Caliaridrawsattentiontotherisksforpolicytowardsexternaldebtwhichareinvolvedintheextensionof the definition of investment to include debt instruments observed in some recent bilateral trade and investmentagreements(suchastheUnitedStatesͲChileFreeTradeAgreementandtheCentralAmerica Free Trade Agreement). These risks result from the association of investment in such treaties with the obligationsofNationalandMostͲFavouredͲNation(MFN)Treatment.NationalTreatmentguaranteesnonͲ discriminatory treatment of domestic and foreign firms. Under MFN Treatment each party to the 10 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment agreement binds itself to extend to the all others the same concessions as those accorded to the most favoredparty. Extended to sovereign debt, National and MFN Treatment could restrict a Government’s flexibility regarding postͲcrisis measures such as those involving the distribution of losses between domestic and foreigncreditorsandsupporttodomesticasopposedtoforeignbanksaspartoftherestructuringofthe financial sector. They could also reduce the leverage of the debtor country during negotiations on the restructuring of its external debt. In extreme cases they might even make it difficult to prioritize the servicingofdomesticdebtincurredtomeettheGovernment’swages,salariesandpensionsobligations. MoreoverapplicationofMFNTreatmenttoexternaldebtmighthavetheanomalousandalmostcertainly unacceptable effect of according seniority in meeting debt obligations to the parties covered by the agreementascomparedthosetopartiesnotsocovered. The risks described cover in the first instance only countries covered by treaties whose definition of investmentincludesdebt.However,precedentsbasedonbilateraltradeandinvestmenttreatiesarealso often included among demands submitted by participants and as part of proposed frameworks agreementsduringmuchbroadernegotiationsontradeandfinance. G. ConclusionsandFutureTasks Theprincipalfocusofthepapersinthiscompendiumistheneedforaconceptofdebtsustainabilitymore systematic than the piecemeal indicators of country risk previously used for external debt assessment. Problemsrelatedtodebtsustainabilityareexaminedthroughtheprismofaseriesofcountrystudies.The papers also discuss the institutional framework at national level for debt assessment and management andtheroleofcreditratingagenciesaswellasimportantfeaturesofglobalrulesbearingondeveloping countries’autonomyregardingpoliciesfortheexternalsector.Theconcludingremarkswhichfolloware limitedtoselectedfeaturesoftheconceptualframeworkforassessingdebtsustainabilityandofpolicies designed to contribute to the achievement of such sustainability. They include suggestions as to some possibledirectionsforfuturework. 1. MacroeconomicPolicy Likeothercasestudiesofexternaldebtmanagement,thoseinthiscollectionhighlighttheimportanceof appropriate macroeconomic policy to successful debt management. The contents of such policy necessarily vary among countries owing to differences in both economic conditions and Governments’ objectives. Thus the experiences of Argentina and the Republic of Korea reviewed in the case studies illustratethatsuccessfulmacroeconomicpoliciesinacontextofdebtcrisisdonotfollowageneralmodel but rather consist of measures geared to countryͲspecific circumstances and based on countryͲspecific balancingofthebenefitsandcostsofalternativeoptions. The case studies also draw attention to the special vulnerability of lowͲincome countries to external shocks.Thisisduetotheirlessdiversifiedstructuresofproduction,inparticulartheconcentrationoftheir exportsinalimitednumberofprimarycommodities.Theproblemscaused bysuch concentrationare a staple feature of the literature of development economics. The studies in this collection emphasize the threatposedbythisvulnerabilitytotheachievementofdebtsustainability. Onelessondrawnistheneedforthepoliciestowardsexternaldebtwhichaccommodatetheinvestment requiredfordiversifyingacountry’sproductivebase.Thislessonconcernsnotonlythedebtmanagement ofborrowingcountriesbutalsothetermsandconditionsoffinancingagreedwithofficialcreditors.Future 11 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice work on policies in this area might also include different techniques available for hedging commodity exportreceiptsandareexaminationofpricestabilizationatthenationallevelthroughmarketingboards. Inthiscontextitmayalsobeworthrevisitingissuesclassifiedbyanearlierliteratureundertheheadingof centralbankingprinciplesforanexporteconomy.Thisliterature,towhichamajorcontributorwasRaul Prebisch,firstSecretaryͲGeneralofUNCTAD,onthebasisofhisexperienceasmanageroftheArgentine Central Bank from 1935 to 1943, concerned the implications for appropriate monetary, and more generally macroeconomic, policy of frequently observed differences between the external and internal balanceofcommodityͲdependentcountries,ontheonehand,andofindustrialcountries,ontheother.5 Intheformergroupofcountriesamacroeconomicupswingtendedtobeassociatedwithamorepositive balanceoftradeandexternalpayments,andthusariseinreservesofforeignexchange;andconversely recession or depression tended to accompany a negative external balance and a contraction of foreign reserves.Bycontrasttheexternalbalanceofindustrialcountriestendedtodeteriorateduringeconomic upswingsandtoimproveduringdownswings.The monetarypolicyproposedforcommodityͲdependent countries in response to their circumstances involved restriction during the upswing with the aim of accumulatingreserves,whichwouldpermitamoreexpansionarypolicyandthefinancingofcontracyclical measuressuchas public worksduringthedownswing. Theunderlyingideas ofthisliteraturecouldwell have continuing relevance for the macroeconomic framework for policy towards external debt in commodityͲdependentcountries. 2. TowardsaMoreInclusiveApproachtoDebtSustainability Thiscollectionofpapershasachievedgreaterconceptualclarityconcerningdebtsustainabilitybutcannot provide definitive, comprehensive guidelines for assessment and policymaking. The papers point to the need for more flexible approaches to the subject which also take account of essential connections betweenthemanagementofexternaldebtanddevelopmentstrategy.Conclusionswhichcanbedrawn fromthecollectionincludethefollowing. x x x Assessment of debt sustainability will continue to require quantitative indicators as well as analysisofqualitativefactorstraditionallyincludedintheassessmentofcountryrisk. Amoreinclusiveviewofdebtsustainabilitywillsuggestnewindicatorsofcountryriskanddebt sustainabilityinadditiontothetraditionalonessurveyed. Assessment and policymaking should include discussion between the different parties – debtor countries, creditors and international organizations Ͳ to resolve legitimate differences between viewsastowhatconstitutesustainabledebtlevelsforacountry. Adevelopmentalperspectiveshouldbeanintegralpartoftheapproachtodebtsustainability.Thisimplies thatconsiderationofdebtsustainabilityshouldnotbeabstractedfromtherequirementsofdevelopment strategy. Such an approach to debt sustainability requires the involvement not only of those with responsibility for external financing and debt management but also of other policymakers who are responsiblefordecisionsregardingdevelopmentstrategy. These conclusions as to an appropriate framework for assessment of debt sustainability would be consistent with treatment of the subject as part of a comprehensive approach to monitoring and managementofacountry’sexternalassetsandliabilitiesoutlinedbelow. 5 TheargumentisexplainedinmoredetailinWallich(1950:chapterXV). 12 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 3. NationalBalanceSheetsandExternalDebt Atthecentreoftheconceptualapproachestodebtsustainabilityreviewedinthiscollectionofpapersare current and future receipts and outflows which determine the funds available for debt service. Such a focuson“earningpower”(touseterminologycommonamongaccountantsandfinancialanalysts)could beusefullysupplementedbyinformationcontainedinthebalancesheetsofacountry’sGovernmentand firms,especiallytheirexternalliabilities.Aprofileofnationalexternalliabilitiesservesastheanalogueat thisleveltoacorporation’scapitalstructurewhichprovidesnotonlyaguidetotheinstitution’sfunding butalsoenablesittoindexandcontroldifferentfinancialrisks.6 A focus on external liabilities and assets would be a natural extension to debt sustainability of recommendationsintheReportoftheWorkingGrouponCapitalFlowsoftheFinancialStabilityForumof April 2000 (Financial Stability Forum, 2000). These recommendations responded to terms of reference which included evaluation of prudential policies, regulations and risk management that might help to reducesystemicrisksassociatedwiththebuildͲupofexternalindebtedness. TheReportwasoneofmanyinternationalinitiativesundertakenintheaftermathofthefinancialcrisesof the 1990s which involved mainly emergingͲmarket (i.e. middleͲincome) developing and transition economies.Nevertheless,manyoftherecommendationsconcerningdatacollectionandanalysisandthe managementofrisks couldapplyequallytolowͲincomedeveloping countries.Therecommendations of theReportaredirectedatthepublicsector,thebankingsector,andthenonͲbankfinancialandcorporate sectors. For lowͲincome countries the recommendations of greatest immediate interest are those directed at the public sector (though the other recommendations can be expected to assume greater importance with the development of their institutional infrastructure). This is partly due to the greater relative importance of sovereign borrowing in such countries’ external liabilities. But it also reflects the likelihoodoflessdevelopedaccessinlowͲincomecountriestoinformationconcerningassetsandliabilities ofentitiesintheprivatesector. The Report argues that detailed profiles of external balance sheets can make a major contribution to monitoringandmanagingacountry’sexposuretodifferentfinancialrisks.Sectoraldataarenotonlypart ofthisprofile(thoughapart,asjustexplained,whoseimportancevariesfordifferentsectorsaccordingto a country’s level of development) but help to identify linkages capable of facilitating transfers of risk exposurebetweendifferentsectors. Forthepublicsectortherecommendationsaredesignedtotranscendthenarrowerfocusofpublicdebt management still found in many countries. The aim of the profile of assets and liabilities should be to enabletheformulationofastrategy balancing expectedcosts andriskscontainedin thepublicsector’s external assets and liabilities. This process can benefit from the development of new vulnerability indicators(forwhich,thoughtheReportdoesnotdiscussthis,accountingindicatorsusedaspartofthe analysisofthefinancialstatementsoffirmscanoftenprovideusefulmodels). Theimportanceofextendingtheprofilesofexternalassetsandliabilitiestothebankingsectorreflectsits strategiceconomicroleandthedangerthatintheeventofafinancialcrisisitsproblemsarecapableof inflictingeconomyͲwidedamage.Thedevelopmentofprofilesforthissectorwilloftenbenefitfromthe factthatevenindevelopingcountriesfinancialreportingbybankstoregulatorsandshareholdersisofa relatively high quality, though progress may still be required regarding the information necessary for assessment of liquidity and foreignͲcurrency risk – two risks which assume special significance in crises. Extension of the profiles of external assets and liabilities to the nonͲbank financial sector results in coverage of institutions often more loosely supervised than banks or not supervised at all which were nonethelessamajorsourceofvulnerabilityinsomecountriesintheAsianfinancialcrisis. 6 ForanilluminatingdiscussionoftherolecapitalstructureforbothcountriesandcorporationsseePettis(2001:chapter6). 13 Overview:DebtSustainabilityinTheoryandPractice No more than the other techniques discussed in this collection of papers can national balance sheets provide all the information required for the analysis of debt sustainability and the prevention and containment of debt crises. They can, however, provide a framework for the further development of conceptsclarifyingdebtsustainabilityaswellasforthemanagementoftherisksassociatedwithexternal debt. 14 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References CommitteeontheGlobal FinancialSystem (2005).The Roleof RatingsinStructuredFinance:Issuesand Implications.Basel,BankforInternationalSettlements,January. FightA(2004).UnderstandingInternationalBankRisk.Chichester,JohnWiley. FinancialStabilityForum(2000).ReportoftheWorkingGrouponCapitalFlows,April. Friedman IS (1983). The World Debt Dilemma: Measuring Country Risk. Washington, DC, Council for InternationalBankingStudies,andPhiladelphia,RobertMorrisAssociates. Krayenbuehl TE (1988). Country Risk Assessment and Monitoring, 2nd edition. Cambridge, WoodheadͲ Faulkner. PettisM(2001).TheVolatilityMachineEmergingEconomiesandtheThreatofFinancialCollapse.Oxford, OxfordUniversityPress. SturzeneggerFandZettelmeyerJ(2006).DebtDefaultsandLessonsfromaDecadeofCrises.Cambridge, MassachusettsandLondon,TheMITPress. Wallich HC (1950). Monetary Problems of an Export Economy the Cuban Experience 1914Ͳ1947. Cambridge,Massachusetts,HarvardUniversityPress. 15 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERII DEBTSUSTAINABILITYASSESSMENT: THEIMFAPPROACHANDALTERNATIVES CharlesWyplosz (GraduateInstituteofInternationalandDevelopmentStudiesandCEPR)7 A. Introduction Debtsustainabilityisavexingissue.Itsimportanceisimmediatelyobviousbuttheconceptescapesany easy definition. This situation is not unheard of in economics; price stability and full employment are examples of other crucially important policy objectives that cannot be simply defined. Yet, while price stability or full employment can both be measured with a reasonable degree of precision, debt sustainabilitycannotevenbemeasureddirectly. Every country, therefore, must grapple as best it can with the issue of debt sustainability. Private borrowersareinthesamesituationasGovernments–forpublicdebts–andstates–forexternaldebts– withonebigdifference:aprivatedefaultispromptlysanctionedaccordingtopreciselegislationunderthe controlofcourts,whilepublicandexternaldebtdefaultsarefollowedbylitigationandnegotiationswithin fuzzy legal rules and uncertain enforcement mechanisms. Uncertainty about the consequence of public and external debt defaults is a source of perverse incentives to default (formally called moral hazard) reflectingunwillingnessasopposedtoinabilitytopay.8 Officiallenderscannotavoiddealingwiththedebtsustainabilityissue.Themultilateralorganizationsand theParisClubhavelongdealtwiththeissueonacasebycasebasis.Theirstatedruleofprocedurewasto encourageborrowingcountriestoadoptprudentstrategies,whilebeingreceptivetotheirdevelopment needs. “Prudent” and “receptive” are subjective attributes, however, which inevitably lead to 7 I am indebted to AnhͲNga TranͲNguyen for suggesting the topic and providing me with much knowledge about debt sustainability analysis. Many useful comments were provided at the UNCTAD Expert Meeting Debt Sustainability and DevelopmentStrategiesonOctober26Ͳ28,2005.Alltheviewsexpressedherearemine,asaretheerrors. 8 ThisdistinctionisintroducedinBulowandRogoff(1989). 17 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives controversies. It is natural to try and escape such controversies by designing systematic and therefore universallyapplicableprocedures.Indeed,theWorldBank’sInternationalDevelopmentAssociation(IDA) andtheIMFhaverecentlystartedtoformalizetheirdebtsustainabilityassessment(DSA)procedures.IDA lending is now informed by a battery of criteria developed within the Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA) approach, while the IMF and the World Bank have put in place a standardized DSA proceduredesignedtoberoutinelyusedaspartofitssurveillanceandlendingoperations. This paper examines the DSA procedure. The next section explains why it is mission impossible. Noting thatsustainabilityisaforwardͲlookingconcept,itarguesthatanypracticaldefinitionisarbitrary,andthat any sustainability indicator will be both arbitrary and too imprecise to serve as a tool for policy prescription. Section C then examines the IMF’s procedure, intended to deal with this impossibility principle by being both simple and transparent. Because of the “mission impossible” nature of the exercise,however,theprocedureseemstobeevolvingtowardsmorecomplexity.Indeedsimplicitymay comeattheexpenseofprecision,whichcallsforincreasingcomplexity.Inaddition,giventheIMF’sown definition of sustainability, the procedure requires adopting, formally or informally, the CPIA approach developedbytheIDA,asourceofopacity.ThesectionalsoreviewsotherDSAapproaches,somewhich emphasizesimplicityatthecostofprecision,whileothersgofurtherinthedirectionofcomplexityatthe costoftransparency.Arguingthatsimplicityandtransparencyindeedareessentialtomaketheprocedure acceptable, Section D develops a series of principles that lead to a simpler, less ambitious and less systematicprocedurethatseekstoreplacearbitraryjudgmentswithaframeworkfordialoguebetween theofficiallendersandtherecipientcountries. B. WhatisDebtSustainability? 1. Definitions Debt sustainability is accepted that aims at answering a deceptively simple question: when does a country’sdebtbecomesobigthatitwillnotbefullyserviced?Thequestioncanbeappliedtotheexternal debtortothepublicdebt.Theanalyticsareidenticalonceitisnotedthattheexternaldebtislinkedto theevolutionoftheprimarycurrentaccountbalanceinthesamewayasthepublicdebtislinkedtothe primarybudgetbalance.Thisdistinctionwillbeblurredinthepresentsectionbyreferringto“debt”and “primarybalance”,withoutspecifyingwhetheritappliestopublicorexternaldebtsandbalances. The IMF’s own definition of sustainability is: a debt “is sustainable if it satisfies the solvency condition withoutamajorcorrection[…]giventhecostsoffinancing”(IMF,2002,p.5).Solvency,inturn,needsto be defined. Debt solvency is achieved when future primary surpluses are large enough to pay back the debt, principal and interest. More technically, solvency requires that the current debt plus the present discounted value of all expenditures does not exceed the present discounted value of all revenues (or, equivalently, that the current debt not exceed the present discounted value of future revenues net of nonͲinterestexpenditures). The solvency definition is clear cut and has long been formalized, but raises many implementation difficulties.Thesustainabilitydefinition,asstated,isvague. SolvencyIssues Solvency,andsustainabilityasaconceptthatbuildsuponsolvency,isentirelyforwardͲlooking.Itisfuture balancesthatmatter,notthepastandnotjustthecurrentdebtlevel.Hugedebtscanbepaidback,and smalldebtsmaynotbesustainable.Theoutcomedependsonwhattheprimarybalancewilllooklikein thefuture,including theverydistantfuture.Infact,mostGovernmentsareindebtedforeverandmany externaldebtsremainhighfordecades.Forinstance,FigureII.1.showstheevolutionoftheBritishpublic 18 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment debt,measuredinpercentofGDP.Duringthelast300years,itneverdroppedbelow20percent,reaching 270percentontwooccasionsandaveraging117percent.Thisdebtwasalwayssustainedinthesense thattheBritishGovernmentneverdefaulted.Wereturntothisexamplebelow.Fornowwejustnotethat dealing with the issue of debt solvency – and therefore sustainability – requires passing judgment on eventsthathavenothappenedyet,thatmaycoveraverylonghorizon,measuredindecades,andthat arelargelyunpredictable. FigureII.1.TheBritishPublicDebt–1700Ͳ2004 (PercentofGDP) British public debt 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1700 1738 1776 1814 1852 Source:BurdaandWyplosz(2005). 1890 1928 1966 2004 Thenextdifficultyisthatthedebtmustbescaledsomehowtocountrysize.Themostpopularapproachis torelatethedebttotheGDP,asinFigureII.1.,butthechoiceisnotstraightforward.Itdependswhatis the source of revenues. Public debts are serviced out of government revenues, so what matters is the taxingabilityoftheGovernment,nowandinthefuture. Ifthedebtisexternalorpublicbutpartlyowedtotherestoftheworldand/orinforeigncurrency,itwill beservicedbytheamountofrevenuesinforeigncurrencythattheGovernmentcancollect.Thereislittle relationshipbetweenGDPandtheadequacyofcollectiblerevenues.Soanotherscalingfactorisrequired and it is customary to use exports. But this assumes that a constant fraction of exports can be used to service the debt. The scaling factor – GDP, exports or any other measure – must be forecast over the relevanthorizonsothatitisnotjustthedebtitselfthatmustbeguessed.Therecanbenopretenseof precision. Afurtherdifficultyisthatdebtsarerolledover.EvenlongͲtermbondsarenotlongͲtermenoughtocover quasiͲpermanent debts.9As the debt is refinanced, borrowing costs change and must therefore be guessedaswell.Thisrequiresmakingassumptionsonthefuturecourseofdomesticinterestratesforthe part of the debt that is issued in domestic currency, and assumptions regarding future foreign interest ratesandcountryriskpremiaforthatpartissuedinforeigncurrency.Interestratescanchangebecauseof externalconditions–includingsometimescontagionfromfarͲawayevents–whichaffectinunpredictable waysthesolvencycondition. 9 Thisisnotentirelycorrecthistorically.TheBritishgovernmenthasissuedperpetuitiescalledconsols,bondslackingamaturity. Oncealargeproportionofthepublicdebt,consolsarenowanoddityunlikelytobefeasiblefordevelopingcountries. 19 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives Inextreme,butnotrare,situations,itmayprovetemporarilyimpossibletorefinancethematuringdebt, muchlesstoissuenewdebt.Thisdoesnotnecessarilymeanthatthedebtisunsustainable;itisacaseof illiquidity. Illiquidity may none the less force a debt default, even though the debt is sustainable, as previouslydefined. DefinitionofSustainability TwoqualificationsoftheIMFdefinitionimplythatsustainabilityisamoredemandingrequirementthan solvency.Thefirstqualificationistoruleouta“majorcorrection”intheprimarybalance.Thisprobably referstosevereexpenditurecutsorlargerevenueincreasesachievedthroughtaxationorpricingofgoods andservicessuppliedbythepublicsector.Thedefinitionthereforecoversliquidityconstraints–adryingͲ upoffinancing,eitherdomesticorexternal–thatrequiredrasticadjustments.Thesecondqualification refers to the “cost of financing”. Financing costs are bound to change over time and are therefore unpredictable. In particular, they may increase as the debt rises, creating a vicious circle of the type discussedfurtherbelow.Asaconsequence,adebtmaybesustainabletodayandunsustainabletomorrow, or conversely. Thus the definition can be unstable. Finally, note that “major” is a matter of judgment, whichmeansthattheIMFdefinitionisuncomfortablyvague. TheIMF’sdefinitionisatvariancewiththesustainabilityconceptproposedbyArrowetal.(2004)inavery different context (the environment). Applied to the debt issue, their definition could be interpreted as suggestingthatsustainabilityrequiresthatthenetworthofanentity(theGovernmentorthecountry), defined as the present discounted value of net revenues less the current debt, be on a nonͲdecreasing trend. This definition differs from the IMF’s in two important ways. First, it does not require solvency. Solvency is achieved only if net worth is nonͲnegative. The alternative sustainability definition does not ruleoutthat,initially,networthbenegativeaslongasitisrisingandeventuallybecomesnonͲnegative, thus meeting the solvency condition.10Second, and importantly for what follows, it does not imply any specificthresholdforthedebt. Makingdefinitionsoperational Thus there are many competing definitions of external or public debt sustainability. The Box below summarizesandinterpretsthesevariousconcepts.OnetheoreticallyͲpureconceptissolvency.Theother theoreticallyͲclearconcept,proposedbyArrowetal.(2004),isthatthenetworth(ofthecountryforthe externaldebtortheGovernmentforpublicdebt)beincreasing,oratanyratenonͲdecreasing.Thesecond conceptislessstrictthanthefirstonesincesolvencyrequiresthatnetworthbealwayspositive.These conceptscannotbeimplementedassuchbecausetheyrequireknowledgeofthefutureevolutionofthe debt. IMF (2002) adds to solvency the requirement that solvency be always maintained without any major adjustment. Both because it relies on solvency and because it rests on an unspecified limit to “major adjustment”,thisdefinitioncannotbeimplementedassuch.Asexplainedbelow,thedefinitionismade operationalbyrequiringthatthedebtdoesnotexceedathreshold,tobefurtherdiscussed.Itshouldbe noted that, if the threshold is conservatively set, the resulting definition is more demanding than the previousone(ifthethresholdisnotbinding,thedefinitionisempty). TheArrowetal.(2004)conceptcanbemadeoperationalbyignoringtheunobservablepresentvalueof primarybalancesandrequiringthatthedebtͲtoͲGDPratiobestationary.Sincestationarityisdifficultto assess in practice, the definition can be implemented by requiring that the debt ratio be on a declining trend,whichdoesnotruleoutoccasionalbuttemporaryincreases. 10 ThispointisformallystatedintheAppendix. 20 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment BoxII.1.TheoreticalandOperationalDefinitionsofDebtSustainability LetbtbethedebtͲtoͲGDPratioattimet.Simplifyingsomewhat,thevariousdefinitionsinthetextcanbe summarizedasfollows. bt d b ,where b isathresholddiscussedinsection3.1below. x DSAdefinition: x Solvency:thepresentvalueofbtbecomesnegligibleforlonghorizons(limbt/(1+r)t=0astїь), whereristherealinterestrate.Anequivalentdefinitionisthatthepresentvalueofprimary balancesшbt.(Seetheappendixforaformalization.) x Debtserviceability:solvencyplusnoilliquidity.Illiquidityariseswhenthedebtcannotbeservicedat aparticularpointintime. x IMF(2002)definition:solvencyplusnoneedformajorcorrection. x Arrowetal.(2004):networth,i.e.thepresentvalueofprimarybalanceslesscurrentdebt,isnot decreasingovertime. x Debtstationarity:btdoesnotgrowwithoutbounds.Analternativeisthatbtbe(weakly) declining. 2. AnImpossibilityPrincipleandItsImplications Because debt sustainability is a forwardͲlooking concept, it cannot be assessed with certainty. In this rigoroussensedebtsustainabilityassessment (DSA) isimpossible.Atbest,followingproceduressuchas thosepresentedinSection3below,educatedguessesmaybepossiblebutitisimportanttorecognizeat theoutsetthatthesearejustguesses,nomatterhowsophisticatedtheymaybe.Theimplicationsofthis impossibilityprinciplearefarͲreaching. Giventhelargenumberofguessesthatarerequiredtoreachanyconclusion,thebestthatcanbehoped for are statements of the type: “there is a probability of x per cent that the debt is sustainable at a particularhorizon”.Twoaspectsofthisstatementneedtobehighlightedatthisstage.First,DSAcanonly provideprobabilities.Insomeextremecases,thesemaybe0or100percent,11butgenerallytheywillbe somewhere between these values but not easily defined. Put differently, DSA is rarely blackͲandͲwhite andthereforeanimpreciseguidetopolicy. Second, the probability that a debt is sustainable in the IMF sense is bound to change over time. For example,ahighlyindebtedGovernmentthatrunsasizeableprimarysurpluswillseeitsprobabilityofdebt sustainability rise over time. This is in accord with definition of Arrow et al (2004). Conversely a Governmentthatstartswithalowdebtbutsystematicallyrunslargeprimarydeficitswillhaveadeclining probabilityofdebtsustainability. These two possibilities imply that any statement on sustainability is valid only for a particular horizon. What should that horizon be? In theory, it should be infinite but, in practice, it is determined by the availabilityofreliableforecasts:ifforecastsofprimarybalances,interestrates,GDP,etc.areextendedto 10 years, the DSA will provide an answer at the 10 year horizon, i.e. a much shorter horizon than the 11 ThecollapseoftheLTCMhedgefundisausefullesson.InSectionC,wewillpointoutthesimilaritybetweenDSAandportfolio assessment,andwillindeeddiscussvalueatrisk,asophisticatedtechniquedirectlyborrowedfromfundmanagement.Resorting tothemostadvancedtechniquesavailable,LTCMmanagers–whichincludedNobelPrizeͲwinnerRobertMerton–hadconcluded thattheirinvestmentwasnear100percentsure.Asitturnedout,anextremelyrareconjunctionofeventsoccurredandLTCM, arguablythemostprestigiousfund,wentbankrupt. 21 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives infiniteonelogicallyrequired.However,sinceeven10Ͳyearforecastsaretotallyunreliable,thehorizonis boundinpracticetobemuchshorter.Butthisunderminestheconceptualbasisofthisapproach. As discussed below, a common way of circumventing the horizon problem is to assume “everything constant”andextendpasttrendstoaninfinitehorizon.Thisisconvenientbuthasunlikelyconsequences, i.e.theprobabilityoftheassumedpathiscloseto0percent.Suchexercisesdescribepathsthatcannotbe takenatfacevalue,inparticularforthepurposesofpolicieswithseriousconsequencesforthelivelihoods ofmanypeople. Another aspect of the impossibility principle is that sustainability as defined by the IMF requires a judgmentof whendebtistoolarge.FigureII.1remindsusthat debt canbe verybigand yetsustained. Recent work has pointed out that “big” is a relative concept.12It is generally considered that the developingcountriescannotsustainlargedebts.FigureII.2.showsthat,indeed,thepeakinthemidͲ1990s foremergingmarketswasfollowedbyawaveofcrises.Willtherecentriseforthesecountries,nowabove the previous peak, usher a new wave of crises? No one knows. Yet, framing the debt sustainability definitionastheIMFdoesmakesunavoidabletheadditionofanewconcept,namelyadebtceiling.There isnoprecisewayofdefiningthisceiling.Itmustbebasedonthemaximumamountofresourcesrequired toservicethedebt,andthusonassumptionsabouteconomiccostsandpoliticalacceptability.Thiswayof puttingthequestionleadstoanotherimpossibility,thatofassessingadebtceiling. Finally,risinginterestratesincreasethedebtburdenandreducetheprobabilityofdebtsustainability.A disturbing aspect of this linkage is that interest rates on public debts, whether in domestic or foreign currency,includeariskpremium.Theriskitselfisrelatedtotheprobabilityofdefault,i.e.tosustainability. TheresultisthepossibilityofaviciouscirclethatgoesfromthefearofdebtnonͲsustainabilitytohigher interestratesandthustoahigherprobabilityofnonͲsustainability.13InotherwordsthemerefearofnonͲ sustainabilitymakesitmorelikely.DebtdistresscanthusbeselfͲfulfilling.Thismaymeanthatimproperor incorrectlyinterpretedDSAcanhaveadeleteriouseffectondebtsustainability. FigureII.2.PublicDebtsinIndustrialandEmergingMarketCountries–1992Ͳ2002 Source:IMF(2003a). 12 13 Forarecentassessment,includingmanyreferences,seeCordellaetal.(2005). ThisprocessisstudiedinBlanchard(2005). 22 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 3. DebtsandInflation Inflationisa further complication thatisoftenignoredinDSA. Evenforexternaldebt,inflationmatters becauseinterestandexchangeratesdonotalwaysreflectactualinflation.Forexample,iftheexchange ratedepreciatesfasterthanprices,foreigncurrencydebtbecomesmoreexpensiveindomesticcurrency. Thesamehappenswhentheinterestrateondomesticcurrencydebtincreasesbymorethantheinflation rate. Debt service becomes heavier. Conversely, when interest and exchange rates fail to fully reflect expectedinflationandthedebtisnotindexedandisdenominatedindomesticcurrency,risinginflation temporarilyreducesthecostofborrowing.14 DSA should recognize these various possibilities but does not incorporate standard procedures for this purpose.Onereasonistechnicaldifficulties.Notonlywoulditbenecessarytoforecastinflationbutalso expectedinflationandnonͲneutralities,i.e.theextenttowhichtheexchangerateandtheinterestrate failtoreflectexpectedinflation.Whileitispossibletoforecastinflationoverarelativelyshorthorizon,say two to three years, forecasts beyond that horizon depend on policy actions that are yet to be taken. It may also be that international institutions, that typically do not condone inflation, are unwilling to speculateonwhatitcouldbeandhowitcouldbeusedtoalleviatethedebtburden.15 4. LinkwithEarlyWarningIndicators A large literature has been devoted to early warning indicators which try to identify irregularities that eventuallyresultinafinancialand/orcurrencycrisis.LikeDSA,earlywarningindicatorsmustbeforward looking. Crises, and therefore early warning indicators, are beyond the scope of the present paper. The onlydirectlyrelatedquestioniswhetherahighdebtlevelisacauseoffinancialcrises,amongthemany potentialones.AccordingtotheextensivesurveyinHemmingetal.(2003),theanswerismaybe.Formal statistical analyses provide conflicting results on this point. A problem is that they use current fiscal indicators, the budget balance or the debt level, as potential pointers of impending crisis. So far, DSA indicatorshavenotbeenused,tothebestofmyknowledge,inearlywarningindicatorestimates.Todoso wouldprovideagoodgaugeoftheirempiricalrelevance. C. ApproachestoAssessingDebtSustainability:ACriticalReview TheimpossibilityprincipledevelopedinSectionB.2representsaformidablehurdle.AllapproachestoDSA havetorelyonassumptionsaboutthefutureevolutionofbudgetbalances,GDP,interestrates,etc.The usefulnessoftheconclusionsisdirectlyrelatedtothevalidityoftheseassumptions,whichbydefinition areneithersafenortestable.Thissectionstartswithacriticaldescriptionoftheapproachchosenbythe IMF.Itthenpresentsandevaluatessomealternativeapproaches. 1. TheIMFStandardizedApproach The IMF has decided to systematically attach a standardized DSA to program design and to Article IV consultations.TheseDSAsexamineboththepublicandexternaldebts.Thestatedintentionistoprovidea simple, fully transparent and standardized tool that can be readily applied to all countries.16The World 14 Buiter(1985)hasshownthatthegreatreductionoftheBritishpublicdebtover1946Ͳ1970hasmostlybeenachievedthrough the inflation tax. A full account of this process includes regulated interest rates, i.e. some degree of financial repression. In countrieswithfullcapitalmobility,thiswillnotbepossible.Awiderdiscussionoftheroleoffinancialrepressionisbeyondthe scopeofthispaper.AwellͲknowndefenseofsomedegreeoffinancialrepressionisRodrik(1998). 15 AbiadandOstry(2005)provideevidencethatinflationraisestheprimarybudgetsurplus. 16 Infacttherearetwodifferentbutrelatedprocedures,onedesignedforcountrieswithmarketaccessandanotheronedesigned forlowͲincomecountrieswhichrelymostlyonpublicfinancing.Themaindifferencesarethefollowing.1)Inthecaseofcountries 23 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives Bankhasadoptedasimilarprocedure. Unfortunately,theimpossibility principleisin contradictionwith these intentions. Simplicity is achieved at the cost of improbable assumptions; these assumptions are transparent,buttheyarelessinnocuousthantheyaremadetoappearbecausetheunderlyingcomplexity isconcealed. Focusing here on the external debt part of the exercise, the IMF approach includes the following four steps:17 (i) AfiveͲyearcentralforecast,orbaseline,ofthevariablesthataffecttheevolutionoftheexternal debt:theprimarycurrentaccount,GDP,interestandexchangerates,andinflation. (ii) Theresultingevolutionofthedebt,asashareofGDP,overthenextfiveyears.Thisevolutionis uncontroversialasitfollowsfromthefollowingaccountingidentity: bt bt 1 (r g )bt 1 primary balancet WherebisthedebtͲtoͲGDPratio,ristherealinterestrateandgistheGDPgrowthrate. (iii) Several stress tests that look at the effect on debt of adverse shocks affecting the variables forecastedinstep((i).Theshocksareasfollows:first,eachofthreevariables(theinterestrate, realGDPgrowthandtheprimarycurrentaccount)ischangedonebyoneͲhalfstandarddeviation overthesamefiveͲyearhorizon;thenallthevariablesaresimultaneouslyshockedbyonequarter standard deviation each over five years; finally the exchange rate is assumed to be depreciated onceby30percentatthebeginningofthesimulationperiod. (iv) TheDSAconcludeswithajudgmentonwhetherthedebtlevelsimpliedbyanyorallofthestress testsaretoohighforthedebttobeconsideredsustainable. The result is a figure like Figure II.3., which is based on the November 2005 review of the standͲby agreementwithColombia,seeIMF(2005b).18Thefiguredisplaysvarioussimulatedpathsoftheexternal debtoverthefiveͲyearperiod2006Ͳ10:thebaselineobtainedinstep((ii))andtheeffectsofthreeofthe shocksdescribedinstep((iii)).Theseshocksare:aoneͲhalfstandarddeviationcurrentͲaccountshockand the combined shock, both assumed to last the whole simulation period 2006Ͳ2010; and a 30ͲperͲcent exchangedepreciationoccurringin2006. withmarketaccess,theanalysisconcernsboththeexternaldebtandthepublicdebtand,inthecaseoftheexternaldebt,itdeals with its level while, in the case of lowͲincome countries, it concerns only the external debt, which is measured in net present discountedvalueterms.2)ForlowͲincomecountries,theDSAusesanexplicitproceduretoestablishdebtthresholds,whilethe thresholdisleftopentodiscussioninthecaseofthemarketaccesscountries.IMF(2003b)proposestousethesamestandard proceduretobothgroupsofcountries.Thepresentanalysisignoresthesedifferences. 17 ThisdescriptionfollowstherecentchangesasdescribedinIMF(2005a). 18 Thisseemstobethefirst,andsofaronly,countryreviewthatappliesthechangesasdescribedinIMF(2005a). 24 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment FigureII.3.ExampleofDSA:SimulatedPathsoftheDebtͲtoͲGDPRatio 45 40 35 30 25 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Baseline Current account shock Combined shock 30% depreciation Source:IMF(2005b). Whatcanthisinformationbeusedfor?Obviously,thebaselineisnocauseforconcern.Thestresstests, ontheotherhand,arelessbenign.TheoneͲtimedepreciationraisesthedebtͲtoͲGDPratiobyabout30 percent,presumablybecausetheexternaldebtisinforeigncurrency.Thisisnotathreattosustainability, however,becausethedebtstartsdeclininginthethirdyear,mostlikelybecausedomesticpricescatchup withtherateofdepreciation.Moreworrisomearetheeffectsofaworseningofthecurrentaccountand ofthecombinedshocksinceinbothcasesthedebtkeepsonrising. The unavoidable question is whether these simulations are sufficient to warrant a policy reaction. Undoubtedly,werethedebtratiotokeepongrowing,thedebtmusteventuallybecomeunsustainable, butwhen?Inaddition,sincetheshocksareexpectedtolastforfiveyears,thedebtshouldpresumably declinebeyondthehorizon.Inordertobeabletodrawanyconclusionfromthisexercise,therefore,one must be able to conclude that the debt level reached at some point in Figure II.3. is too high to be sustainable. This, in turn, requires establishing a debt threshold level beyond which danger is looming. Danger means debt distress, i.e. financing difficulties or, worse, partial or total default. In view of empirical results that show that the risk of debt distress rises with the size of debt, it seems logical to establishadebt thresholdbeyondwhich therisks canbedeemedunacceptable.Thisistherationale of step((iv)). Should there be a single threshold for all countries? Here again, empirical research shows that the probability of debt distress depends not just on the debt level itself, but also on a variety of factors, includingtheprevailingmacroeconomicsituationand,importantly,thequalityofeconomicandpolitical institutions. A unique common threshold, therefore, is bound either to be too restrictive or too lax, dependinguponthecountrycharacteristics.ThisiswhytheIMFhasbeguntouseaspartofstep((iv))an additionalprocedurecalledCountryPolicyandInstitutionalAssessment(CPIA).DevelopedbytheWorld Bank,CPIAproducesanindexofgovernancequalityforeachcountryproducedbytheWorldBank.19 This index, which ranges from 1 (lowest quality) to 6 (highest quality), is based on 20 indicators. It is updatedannually,followingaformal andelaborateprocessthatinvolves theBank’s countryteams and centraldepartments.Foundtoperformwellinstatisticaltests,theindexisusedtoclassifycountriesinto 19 ThisproceduresofaronlyappliestothelowͲincomecountries,presumablybecauseitisinuseatIDA.TheFundisconsidering applyingittocountrieswithmarketaccess. 25 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives threegroups:countrieswithalowCPIAindexareascribedadebtthresholdof30percentofGDP,raised to45percentfortheintermediategroupofcountries,andto60percentforthecountriesinthehighest CPIA index group. These thresholds are chosen such that the probability of debt distress is 25per cent whentheyarereached.Followinganexpertreview,theWorldBankreducedthenumberofcriteriafrom 20to16andhavemadeindividualratingspubliclyavailableforIDAcountriesin2005. 2. DiscussionoftheIMFApproach Steps ((i))and((ii))aremechanicalimplicationsof theIMF’sforecasts.If theforecastsareaccurate, the implieddebtlevelisareasonablysafeprevision.TheFundreportsonitsownstudiesthatshowthatthe forecaststendtoerrontheoptimisticside,withequallyoptimisticdebtpredictions(IMF,2005c). ProbabilityofWorstCaseScenarios Thispossibilityofforecastingerrorexplainswhy,“inordertoimposediscipline”onthediscussion,step ((iii))looksatsomeworstͲcasescenarios.Since“worst”canbevirtuallyanything,theprocedureattempts tobereasonableandtransparent.Tothateffect,theshocksarepreciselycalibrated.Buthowlikelyare0.5 standarddeviationshocks?TheIMFarguesthattheprobabilityofthedebtexceedingtheworstcaseon thefifthyearisbetween15and30percent,“whichseemsareasonablebalancebetweencapturingthe mediumͲtermriskstodebtdynamicswithoutbeingsoextremeastobeirrelevantforpolicydiscussions” (IMF,2005a;p.3).Theemphasisisrightlyputonpolicyimplicationsbuttheargumentraisesthegeneral questionofwhatcanbelearntfromstresstests. ThereisnothingwrongwithstressͲtesting.Indeed,itisacommonapproachtoportfoliomanagementand widely used in the financial industry, as explained in Section C.3. Yet, the implications profoundly differ betweeneconomicpolicyandportfoliomanagement.Inthefinanceindustry,whenstresstestsreporta dangerzone,evenahighlyunlikelyone,portfoliomanagersmaydecidetochangetheassetcomposition oftheirportfolios.Theadjustmentdoesnotcomeforfreesinceitimplieslowerexpectedreturns,butthis istheusualpricetobepaidforlowerrisk.Itsacceptabilitydependsoninvestorpreference:ifinvestors areunhappywiththeirportfoliomanagers,theycanchangethem. Inthe caseofDSA,when stresstestssignalariskysituation, the requiredadjustmentis toimprove the primary current account. Inevitably, this calls for contractionary macroeconomic policies designed to compress demand. The costs take the form of falling incomes and rising unemployment. The costs are bornebythepopulation.AdmittedlycitizenscanvotetheirGovernmentsoutofoffice–whentheregime is democratic – but only ex post. A Government’s decision to react to events that may occur with a probabilityof15Ͳ30percentisconsiderablymoresensitivethanthatofportfoliomanagers. CharacterizationoftheWorstCaseScenarios Thestresstestsinvolvechangesinonevariableatatimeexceptinthecasewhereallofthemarevaried togetherina“bad”directionforfiveyears.Howlikelyaresuchchanges?Itisunclearhowthe15Ͳ30per cent estimate is constructed. Why does it assume that each shock is expected to be maintained over consecutive 5 years? Does it take into account the fact that some of these shocks may be correlated? Lettingtheshockslastthewholefiveyearsassumesa100percentautoͲcorrelation.TheoneͲatͲaͲtime shockassumesazerocorrelation,whilethethreeͲvariableshockassumesacorrelationof100percent. TheinformationprovidedinIMF(2005a)doesnotshedlightonthisimportantquestion,suggestingthat correlationsareignored. What can be done about these problems? Here, as with the threshold question, the proper technical responseistojackupthelevelofcomplexity,atthecostofreducingtheintendedtransparency.Faced with the criticism that changes in just one of the variables that drive the debt process have historically 26 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment typically affected the others as well, the normal tendency is to acknowledge the point and take up the challenge. This means using econometric techniques to estimate how, in the past, these variables have beenrespondingtoeachother’sshocks.20 Theprocedureiswellestablishedbuthasmanydrawbacks.Tostartwith,theestimateswouldhavetobe conducted country by country, an enormous task that would face serious data availability and comparability problems. Next, the quality of the estimates is likely to be poor in many cases,21thus injectingafurtherdoseofuncertaintyregardingthemeaningofthedebtthresholdandthusundermining its usefulness. In addition, the procedure would turn a simple and transparent procedure into a highly technicalandcompletelyopaqueexercise,withlittleassurancethatthetestsareplausible. The challenge is formidable, possibly insurmountable.22It would be a mistake to go in the direction of addedcomplexity,usingtheabundantparaphernaliaofeconometricinstruments.Resortingtosimplebut less extreme stress tests (shocks with reasonable overall probability) would be an alternative, but the resultscouldwellbetoomundanetobeworthconsidering.Thelackofasatisfactorysolutionisnothing morethananimplicationoftheimpossibilityprinciplepresentedinSectionII.C. BorrowingandGrowth MissingfromtheDSAframeworkisthepossiblegrowthͲenhancingeffectofexternalborrowing.Intheory, acountrywithlowlevelsofhumanandphysicalcapitalstandstobenefitfromexternalborrowing.Ifthe borrowingiswiselyinvested,thereturnsshouldmorethancoverthecosts.Thebenefitscomeintermsof acceleratedgrowthandcatchingͲup.23 Thislinkageisexplicitlyignoredinthestresstests.Thismaylooksurprisinggiventhatmultilaterallending isultimatelyjustifiedbyitsgrowthͲenhancingeffect.Onepossibleexplanationisthatthehorizonistoo short for the growth effects to materialize. The proper response to this argument is to lengthen the horizon, not to ignore the link. If debt distress occurs along the way, the expected growth bonus from externalborrowingwouldbedissipatedbutthisdoesnotjustifyignoringthelink. Anotherpossibleexplanationisthatborrowedresourcesdonotsystematicallydeliveranygrowthbonus. There is much evidence that the quality of policies and of political governance matter crucially in this respect(Cordellaetal.(2005).ThisaspectispartlytakenintoaccountbyCPIAasthequalityofpolicies andinstitutionsareusedtodeterminedebtthresholds. Giventheoverwhelmingimportanceofgrowthamorecomprehensiveframeworkisneeded.Bylimiting theroleofpolicyandinstitutionqualitytothedeterminationdebtthresholds,DSAputsalltheemphasis ontherisksofoverborrowing.Ignoringtheconditionsunderwhichexternalborrowingcanharmorboost growthamountstoposingthequestioninadequately.Ifexternalborrowingisgrowthenhancing,therisk of over borrowing is small, possibly nonͲexistent. If, instead, external borrowing does not exert any favorable growth effect and possibly stunts growth, the relevance of DSA is moot. Countries in this 20 Some papers have started to explore this issue, see Garcia and Rigobon (2004), Abiad and Ostry (2005) and Celasun et al. (2005). 21 The degree of precision of such estimates is generally quite limited but in most developing countries data availability and qualityproblemsarelikelytobemoreserious. 22 IMF(2003b)suggestsusingthetechniquetoderivefancharts,i.e.chartsthatdepicttheevolutionofthedebtfollowingashock byindicatingthemostlikelypathalongwitharangeofpossibilities.FanchartshavebeenpopularizedbytheBankofEnglandas partofitsinflationtargetingstrategy.ThisishowtheBankpresentsitsinflationforecasts.Importantly,however,thefancharts aredesignedbytheBankofEngland’sMonetaryPolicyCommittee.Theyarenottheresultofacomplexeconometricprocedure but a snapshot representation of what policymakers believe. Fan charts are a great communication tool, which reflect the considerationsthatgointopolicydecisionsbutnotoutsideexperts’estimationsofwhatislikelytohappen. 23 IntermsoftheformulapresentedinFootnote29,thegapbetweentheinterestcostandthegrowthratedeclines,andthedebt accumulationbecomeslessdestabilizing,orthegapbecomesnegativeandthedebtisspontaneouslyonadecliningtrend. 27 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives situation should only borrow in distress situations and promptly pay back the debt before the burden becomescrippling. PolicyResponses Thestress testsalsoassumethat the Government doesnotreacttotheshocks.Thisisincontradiction with much evidence that shows that the primary budget reacts to a rising public debt, which should presumablyalsohaveadampeningimpactontheexternaldebt.24ThustheworstͲcasescenariosmustbe seenasapredictionthatassumesthatGovernmentsdonotdowhatinfacttheyusuallydo.Thisfurther reducestheplausibilityofthetests. CountryPolicyandInstitutionalAssessment(CPIA) TheinclusioninIMFdefinitionofdebtsustainabilitytheconditionthatdebtlevelsnotbe“toolarge”leads totheneedtoestablishthresholds.Theobservationthatreasonablethresholdsarelikelytovaryfromone country to another then requires an explanation of why some countries are more likely to suffer from debt distress than others. This explanation involves a large number of economic and political considerationsandrequiresvaluejudgments,averyuncomfortableundertaking. TheIMFͲIDAsolutionhasbeentolookforstatisticallinksbetweenvariouscausesofdebtdistressandthe debtlevel.ThetwoacknowledgedbackgroundstudiesareKraayandNehru(2003)attheWorldBankand anunpublishedIMFpaper.Inlinewiththeliteratureontheroleofgovernance,25theresultingCPIAindex, whichisreasonablypreciselyestimated,isfoundtoexertasignificanteffectontheprobabilityofexternal debtdistress.OnthisbasisitwouldbepossibletoassertthatanimprovementintheCPIAindexreduces the probability of distress and even to compute by how much. This is not how CPIA is used in DSA, however. Theprocedureinsteadusestheestimationtoansweradifferentquestion:whatdebtlevelimpliesa25Ͳ perͲcentprobabilityofdebtdistress?TheanswercannotbebasedonthepartialeffectoftheCPIAindex only but also involves estimates of the effect of other economic variables. If the resulting overall estimationdoesagoodjobofexplainingdebtdistressepisodes,itwouldbeagoodcandidatetoestablish athresholdforeachcountry.Unfortunately,whiletheeffectofeachofthethreevariablesselectedͲdebt, CPIAindexandrealGDPgrowthͲispreciselyestimated,togethertheyexplainonly23.4percentofthe probability of debt distress. In a study that seeks to explain 163 episodes of debt distress all over the world,thisisagoodperformanceͲamongthebestintheliteratureͲandunlikelytobemuchimproved upon.Yet,thefactthattheanalysisexplainssolittleofthephenomenonofdebtdistressimpliesthatthe answerishighlyimprecise.SubsequenttestsprovidedbyKraayandNehru(2003)candidlyconfirmthis. A further problem is that the CPIA index is not applied country by country. Instead, the countries are classifiedinthreegroupsdependingontheirownCPIAindex.Theeffectofgovernanceisappliedgroupby group,whichimpliesthattheeffectiseitherexaggeratedorunderestimatedforthecountrieswhoseCPIA indicesdonotlieinthemiddleoftherange.Thisdistortionriseswiththedistancefromgroupmeans. This procedure is surprising. On the basis of the estimation, it is possible to compute individual debt thresholds. Why is it not done? One reason is simplicity. Three thresholds are easier to deal with than countryͲspecificthresholds.Butthisisaweakjustificationforintroducingseriousdistortionswhichimply thatthethresholdcannotbetakenseriously.AnotherreasonisthepoliticalsensitivityoftheCPIAindex forindividualcountries.Thisisunderstandable,buttheresultisthattheDSAthresholdsaretoocoarseto leadtofirmpolicyconclusions. 24 25 AgoodsurveycanbefoundChapter3ofIMF(2003a). AgoodreferenceisManasseetal.(2003). 28 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment SustainabilityMeasure It can be argued that the debt level, suitably scaled, is arguably the correct measure for sustainability analysis.26Whentrackingitsevolutionovertime,however,aproblemarises.Whenevertheinterestrate exceeds the economy’s growth rate, the debt accumulation process is intrinsically unstable. This is preciselywhysustainabilityisanimportantissue.27Twodifficultiesfollow.First,relativelysmallchangesin therealinterestrateandintrendgrowthcantiltthedebtpathfromstabilitytoinstability.Second,when therealinterestandgrowthratesareclose,smallshockscanhavedramaticallypowerfuleffectsonthe debtpath. ThestrengthofthiseffectcanbeseeninFigureII.4.ThefiguredisplaysthebaselinedebttoGDPratioand theeffectoftheDSAstandardcombinedstressͲtest,bothalreadyshowninFigureII.3.Thethirdcaseadds tothecombinedtesttheeffectofanexternalinterestrateset3percenthigherthanassumedbytheIMF. Thusincreasingtheinterestrateproducesasizeableeffect.Comparingthecombinedshockeffectswith thelowerandhigherinterestrates,weseethatnotonlyisthedebtrisingfasterbut,moreimportantly, thatthedebtratioisnotstabilized,possiblysuggestingnonͲsustainabilityunderanydefinition. ThisexampleillustratesthepointthatdebtaccumulationeffectscanbeeyeͲcatchingand,inthisinstance, mayraiseconsiderablealarmsincethedebtͲaccumulationprocessisunstable.Inreality,primarybalances willbeadjustedastheresultofpolicymovesandofequilibratingreactionswithintheeconomywiththe resultthatdebtinstabilityisusuallytakencareof.Ofcoursetherehavebeenepisodesofexplodingdebts, largely because small slippages can have dramatic effects as the result of the unstable nature of the process.ThisiswhyputativedebtpathsofthesortproducedbytheIMFaspartofitsDSAprocedurecan besomisleading.28 26 Asnotedinfootnote16,forlowͲincomecountriesthisprocedureusesthenetpresentvalueofthedebt.While,inprinciple,this isasuperiormeasure,itscomputationraisesanumberofdelicatequestions,whicharenotconsideredhere.Whenwereferto debtlevels,wedonotdistinguishbetweenthedebtanditsnetpresentvalue. 27 Whentheinterestrateislowerthanthegrowthrate,thedebttoGDPratioisstableandsustainabilityisassured.InthelongͲ run,thisisanunrealisticcasebecausegrowthinexcessoftherealinterestrateisacatchͲupphenomenon(acountrythatdisplays asteadyͲstaterealinterestratelowerthanthegrowthrateisonthe‘wrong’sideofthegoldenruleinthesensethatitsavesand invests‘toomuch’,suboptimallyrepressingconsumption).Butintheshortrunthisconditionallowscountriestorundownthe debttoGDPratio.Theinterestratemaybelowerthanthegrowthrateduringaperiodoffastgrowth(asinChinaorIrelandover thelastdecade)orduringaperiodofacceleratinginflation(asduringsomeperiodsfortheUKshowninFigureII.1). 28 ArelatedconcernappliestotheDSAforlowͲincomecountries.Thechosenmeasure,thenetpresentvalue(NPV)ofthedebt,is very sensitive to interest changes. This measure is compared to the NPV of the debt ceiling. Should the ceiling itself also be adjusted?TheIMFdoesnotdothis,arguingthatthereareoffsettingeffectsintermsofexpectedproductivityadjustments.Thisis likelytobetrue,eventhoughthetimingandsignoftheseeffectsisnotknown.Butitisalsotruethatthesameeffectswillaffect thepathofthedebtinthesameway.Itisinconsistenttoadjustonemeasureandnottheother. 29 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives FigureII.4.EffectontheDebttoGDPRatioofaHigherInterestRateontheCombinedShock 40 35 30 25 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Baseline Combined Shock Combined Shock with higher interest rate Source:Author’scalculationbasedonIMF(2005b). Implementation TheIMFhasexaminedtheshortexperiencewiththeimplementationofDSA.ItemergesthattheDSAhas notbeenassuccessfulasitspromotersintended:“withsomeexceptions,sustainabilityassessmentshave generallynotbeenatthecenterofpolicydiscussionsbetweenstaffandnationalauthorities.Thismaybe becausethesensitivitytestsareconsideredtooextremetoberealisticor,evenifrealistic,tooextremeto warrant a policy response. Conversely, there remain concerns that the assumed shocks are too benign. Finally, from a presentational standpoint, debt sustainability assessments would have greater impact if theywereintegratedinthebodyofthestaffreportinsteadofbeingrelegatedtoanannex.”(p.15) ThissituationreflectsreservationsaboutDSAascurrentlypracticed,whichleadstoreluctancetoraisethe topic with national authorities. The intended transparency of the shocks used for the stress testing is marred by their low probability of occurrence. Another factor is the “black box” nature of the exercise, especiallytheassumptionsabouttheeconomy’sresponsetotheshocks.(Infact,itisassumedthatthere isnoresponse,whichisunrealisticasnotedabove.)Moreimportantly,Staffmaybeembarrassedbythe question: “so what?”. This question immediately brings to the fore the need to decide whether a temporarybulgeinthedebtisthreatening.TheanswerismeanttobeprovidedbytheCPIA.TheCPIA, however, is another “black box” with a large degree of uncertainty. This uncertainty reduces the usefulness of the CPIA thresholds as a reliable guide for policy. Being unable to answer the “so what?” question,IMFStaffdownplaytheDSAexercise. 3. OtherApproaches Until recently, due to the impossibility principle, there have been few other attempts to design implementableapproachestoDebtSustainability.Theearlyonesacknowledgedtheconcept’ssensitivity tounavoidableassumptionsbystressingsimplicityandtransparency.Simplicityisjustifiedbytheneedto make heroic assumptions which imply that the conclusions will always be fragile. Transparency is necessary to allow users to understand what lies behind the result. More recently, DSA has moved towards more elaborate procedures, driven by the hope that empirical regularities can generate more reasonableassumptionsandfacilitateassessmentoftheirplausibility.Acommentaryonotherapproaches totheproblemsraisedabovefollows. 30 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TheDebtͲStabilizingPrimaryBalance The classic approach to sustainability asks what is the primary balance required to stabilize the debt (Blanchardetal.,1991;Buiter,1985).Theobjectivecanbetostabilizethedebteitheratitscurrentlevel or at any other level deemed more desirable. This approach is simple, transparent and easily implementablebecauseitrequiresfewassumptions.Initssimplestform,itlooksatthecurrentdebtto GDP ratio and computes the primary balance which would permanently keep this ratio unchanged. It requirestwoassumptions:whatwillbetheevolutionoftherealinterestrateandwhatisthepotential growthrate?Typically,pasttrendsareassumedtoremainstableovertheindefinitefuturebutshockscan befactoredin,justasintheIMF’sDSA. UltimatelyIMFdebtͲpathprojectionsandthecomputationofdebtͲstabilizingprimaryaccountsarebased on the same reasoning and assumptions. Both rest on the debt accumulation identity bt bt 1 (r g )bt 1 primary balancet .Yet, there is an important difference. DebtͲpath projections either indicate that the debt is stable or declining, in which case there should not be any sustainability issue, or that it is rising, indicating eventual unsustainability. The debtͲstabilizing primary account approach stops there. The IMF’s DSA goes one step further by exploring adverse shocks. When these shocksimplyarisingdebt,newquestionsarise.Sincetheshocksare,byconstruction,temporary,arising debtpathdoesnotmeanunsustainabilityunlessthedebtbecomestoolarge.Thisthenraisesahostof newissues,whichhavealreadybeendiscussedinSectionB.1.ThevirtueofthedebtͲstabilizingprimary accountapproachistoavoidtheseissuesor,moreprecisely,topreventthemfrombecomingprominent. Ofcourse,thequestionofwhatisanappropriatedebtlevelcannotbealtogetheravoided.Lookingatthe primary account that stabilizes the current debt assumes that the current debt is appropriate. But alternativetargetsforthedebtlevelcaneasilybelookedat.Thequestionisvexingbecausethetheory doesnotprovideananswer.TheWorldBank’sCPIAisoneattempttoprovideapracticalanswerbutis subjecttotheproblemsdescribedinsectionC.2. HowcouldthealternativeconceptofthedebtͲstabilizingprimaryaccountbeappliedtotheexampleofa majorshockliketheexchangeͲratedepreciationpresentedinFigureII.3.?Inthebaselinecaseunderthe IMFDSAthedebt/GDPratioisassumedtodecline.ThusadebtͲstabilizingprimarybalancewouldconsist of a deficit.29This would provide an answer to the question of what is the balance on current account needed to keep the debt level unchanged as a percentage of GDP, ignoring capital inflows? The alternativeapproachcouldalsobeusedtoanswerthequestionofwhatwouldbethebalanceoncurrent account required to bring the debt level down to a particular level by, say 2010, if the debt level is perceivedtobetoohigh?Thiswouldbeastraightforwardcalculation. As noted, the concept of the debtͲstabilizing primary account is formally identical to the IMF DSA, but interpretationisdifferent,asillustratedinFigureII.5.Herethedebtisassumedinthebaselinescenarioto decline, and the figures show the effects of the combined shock. The corresponding paths for external debtandtheprimaryaccountaredenotedas“original”.Theprimaryaccountremainsinsmalldeficitas the debt must be reduced. If it is assumed that the authorities can control the primary account, the questionishowtheywouldpursuethepolicygoalofstabilizingthedebt. OnepossibilitywouldbetofixthedebtatitspreͲshocklevelof2005.Thisrequiresalargeprimarysurplus, onethatcompletelyoffsetstheeffectoftheshock.Thissurplusisshownas“Stabilized1”intheleftpanel ofFigureII.5.Therightpanelshowsthatthispolicyrequiresahugeimprovementintheprimaryaccount in response to the sudden increase in the domestic currency value of the external debt due to the depreciation.Thepolicyresponseisrelaxedwhenthepriceincreasescatchupwiththedepreciationso thatthedebtisstabilizedindomesticaswellasforeigncurrency. 29 Theformula,itwillberecalled,isprimarybalance=(interestrate–growthrate)xdebt. 31 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives Anotherpossibilityistoletthedebtriseinitiallybuttoaimatreturningittoits2005levelbytheendof theplanningperiod,here2010.Theleastdisruptivewayofdoingthisistoachieveaprimarysurplusthat remainsconstantovertheplanningtheperiod.ThisisshowninFigureII.5.as“Stabilized2”.Theprimary balancenowincreasesmoderately,eventhoughtheshockisunusuallyviolent.Thedownsideisabulgein thedebtleveluntil2006. FigureII.5.DebtStabilizingPrimaryBalance Debt(percentofGDP) Primarybalance(percentofGDP) 45 14 Original Stabilized 1 Original Stabilized 2 Stabilized 1 Stabilized 2 12 10 40 8 6 4 35 2 0 30 -2 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Source:Author’scalculationbasedonIMF(2005b). 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Looking at the debtͲstabilizing primary balance, not just at the effect on the debt path, provides a different perspective on stress testing. First, it deͲdramatizes the shock effects. It shows that sustained but moderate primary balance corrections can eventually ensure sustainability – here defined as debt stabilization –in thefaceofevenunusualshocks. BothexperimentsshowninFigure II.5.quicklyreturn thedebttoitspreͲshocklevel,immediatelyinthe“Stabilized1”caseandafterfiveyearsinthe“Stabilized 2” case. Given the low probability of the shock, it would make sense to allow the slower return. Lengthening the horizon would clearly allow for smaller primaryͲ account corrections. It should also be notedthatadverseshocksarelikelytobecompensatedsoonerorlaterbyfavorableshocks. Second, this approach also deͲdramatizes the inherent instability of the debt accumulation process illustratedinFigureII.4.Timepermitting,evenverylargedebtshockscanbedealtwiththroughmoderate primaryͲaccount corrections. The reason is that a moderate sustained primaryͲaccount correction eventuallyproducesasalargecumulativeeffectastheshockitself. Third, this approach brings to the fore important policy implications. Obviously, “Stabilized 2” is more palatable,economicallyandpoliticallysinceitavoidsamassivespendingcontractionboundtoresultina severe recession. It is a good general principle that temporary shocks should be met with smoothing policies,i.e.policiesthatspreadovertimetheadjustmentcosts.30Merelylookingattheoriginaldebtpath intheleftͲhandsidepanelinFigureII.5.mayconveyasenseofurgencythatisnotnecessarilywarranted. Ofcourse,the“Stabilized2”pathassumesthattheexternaldebtbulgecanbefinanced,whichmaynotbe the case for a number of countries. But the answer is that the IMF was created precisely to provide emergencyfinancinginthefaceofatemporaryshock. 30 Permanentshocks,ontheotherhand,needtobemetbyapermanentoffsettingpolicyassoonaspossible.Thisdoesnotrule outagradualimplementationiftherequiredpolicyinvolvesadjustmentcosts,whicharebestspreadovertime. 32 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Fourth,theissueofaccesstotemporaryexternalfinancingdrawsattentiontotheallͲimportantcredibility issue.Thedownsideofthe“Stabilized2”responseisthatthedebtincreasewillbetemporaryonlyifthe authoritiescancommittoasustainedprimaryaccountsurplus.Absentcredibility,theadjustmentmustbe frontͲloaded,asinthe“Stabilized1”case. CredibilityisalsopartoftheIMFDSAsinceitliesattheheartoftheprocedureofthresholddetermination carriedoutunderCPIA.Yet,FigureII.5pointstoashortcomingofthisapproachwhichfailstodistinguish betweencaseswhereanincreaseinthedebtlevelismerelythetemporaryconsequenceofatemporary shock, on the one hand, and those where it results from endemic policy indiscipline.31This is why it is essentialthatIMFlendingbeaccompaniedbycredibilityͲenhancingconditionality. Thisexampleillustratesthepointmadeabove:theIMFDSAprocedureimaginesshockswhichmayresult insizeabledebtbuildͲupsbecausetheauthoritiesareassumed nottoreact. Weseethat,ifgiventime, relatively moderate primary account improvements can stabilize the debt (this is “Stabilized 2”). There shouldbenoimplicationthattheshockmustbedealtwithimmediatelyaswith“Stabilized1”. ValueͲatͲriskstresstests Financial institutions have developed procedures to explore the risks associated with portfolios in the formofthevalueͲatͲrisk(VAR)approach.Forfinancialfirms,theobjectiveistheavoidanceofinsolvency. Attheheartofthisapproacharetwomainideas:thathistoryallowstheevaluationoftheprobabilityof variouseventsorcombinationsofevents,andthatreactionsshouldtakeintoaccountboththepossible severityofeacheventanditslikelihood. The techniques used to measure the plausibility of various risks can also be applied to the debt sustainability question. The IMF’s approach takes a partial step in this direction when it sets levels for some variables in stress testing on the basis of their previous behavior. But, as noted above, it ignores howthesevariablesreacttoeachother.Inprinciple,onecouldgomuchfurtherinthisdirectionbutonly atthecostofaddingconsiderablecomplexityandopacity. TheissuehasbeenstudiedbyGarciaandRigobon(2005)andCelasunatal.(2005),sothatitispossibleto giveasenseofwhatshouldandcanbedone.Ratherthanspecifyingshocksonthebasisofthehistorical evolutionofindividualvariables,properlyconstructedstresstestsshouldtakeintoaccountthehistorical interdependenceamongthesevariables.Forexample,inthecasesdisplayedinFigureII.3.thecombined shockinvolvesasimultaneousdeteriorationinthecurrentaccount,theinterestrateandGDPgrowth.This combination may be more or less likely than each of its components. For instance, if GDP growth systematically worsens when the interest rate increases, the combination is as likely as each of its components.Allowingforsuchcorrelationsenablesbetterappraisaloftheprobabilityoftheshocksthat areconsidered. This is the first step of the VAR approach which assumes that historical correlations are likely to be relevantinthefuture–areasonablebutnotnecessarilycorrectassumption.Thenextstepthenistotake intoaccountallthepossiblecombinationsofshocksbasedonestimatedcorrelations.Theprocedurecan beautomatedtorandomlygenerateaverylargenumberofshocksbothsmallandbig,inisolationandin combination.Eachshockisassociatedwithaprobabilityofoccurrence.32Thelaststepistoassociatewith eachshockthecorrespondingevolutionofthedebt,muchasintheIMF’sDSA,exceptthateachdebtpath nowcomeswithaspecifiedprobabilityofoccurrence. 31 ThesamefailuremayhelptoexplainwhytheestimatesofKraayandNehru(2003)explainonlyasmallpartofepisodesofdebt distress. 32 Technically,thisiscalledMonteͲCarlosimulations. 33 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives Onecanthenaskthefollowingquestion:at,forexample,thethreeͲyearhorizonwhatistheprobability thatthedebtbebetweenahighandalowlevel?Thedifferentcombinationsofhighandlowlevels,with associated probabilities can then be presented in a “fan chart” like the one shown in Figure II.6. In this figuredifferentlyshadedrangesidentifyalternativeprobabilitiesforpublicdebtofSouthAfricaoverthe 2005Ͳ2009horizon.33Thedarkestrangecorrespondstoanestimatedprobabilityof80percent,witheach lighterrangereducingthelikelihoodby20percent.Thefigureshowsthat,thefurtheroutwelook,the greatertheuncertainty. This presentation resembles the debt paths shown in Figure II.3. but with important differences. In contrast to Figure II.3., the shocks are not identified. This is a step forward since the shocks under considerationinFigureII.3.arearbitraryandthereforeunlikelytobewellsuitedtoanyparticularcountry. The large number of randomly generated shocks underlying the VAR exercise of Figure II.6. avoid this criticism.StandardizationoftheIMFDSAistheconsequenceofsimplicity,butitscostisarbitrarinessand therefore limited credibility. Moreover the VAR approach enables one to judge at a glance how likely someofthedramaticscenariosare. FigureII.6.ValueͲatͲRiskAnalysis:TheFanChartforSouthAfrica’sPublicDebt (ExternaldebtasaproportionofGDP) Source:IMF(2005d). HowevertherearecostsassociatedwiththeVARprocedure.Tostartwith,itiscomplex.Fewdeveloping countries are equipped to carry out such estimations and it would stretch even the staff of any multinationalinstitutiontodealwithalargenumberofcountries.Inordertoprovidereasonablyreliable estimates, the procedure requires good data, possibly going far back in the past, and few developing countrieshavesuchdata. Complexfanchartexercisesmayalsoprovideanillusoryimpressionthatuncertaintyiswellunderstood. Whilefanchartsdoprovideusefulinformation,theirprecisionisunknown.Itdependsonthequalityof thedata,ontheperformanceoftheunderlyingeconometricanalysis,andontherelevanceofhistoryfor the future. Importantly, perhaps, its “black box” nature goes against the goal of transparency and may deterpolicyaction.Thustheunavoidablecomplexityandopaquenessmaynotbeworththeeffort.34 33 Thechartdisplaysthepublic,nottheexternaldebt. It may be ironic that the most advanced countries, which can and often carry out similar exercises, pay limited attention to thematdecisionͲmakingtime,whileIMF(2003b)andIMFandIDA(2004)callforprioritizingDSAimplicationsinthecaseofthe lessadvancedcountries. 34 34 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment ReactionFunctions AkeymessagefromFigureII.5.isthatpoliciesdomatter.Adequatepolicyreactionscandealwithshocks, andthesereactionsneednotbedrastic,giventimeandcommitment.Thisobservationleadstotheidea thatdebtsustainabilitycanbeachievedthroughtheadequacyofpolicyreactionstoshocks. Viewed this way, debt sustainability can be assessed by observing how a country’s authorities behave. Thisleadstotheestimationofpolicyreactionfunctions.Intheareaofmonetarypolicy,suchfunctionsare knownasTaylorreactionfunctionsandhavebecomeroutine.Theapproachhasstartedtobeappliedto publicdebt,butapparentlynotyettoexternaldebt. Thekeyquestionhereiswhethertheprimarysurplusissystematicallyraisedwhenthedebtlevelrises.It ispossibletoestimatethestrengthofthisreactionandtodetermineathresholdbeyondwhichthedebt accumulation process is stable, and which thus provides an alternative definition of sustainability. IMF (2003a)presentsanoverviewoftheemergingresultsonpublicdebtreactionfunctions.Whilethisworkis stillpreliminary,itseemsthatmanycountriesdopassthesustainabilitytest.Thisisgenerallythecasefor theadvancedeconomies.Fortheemergingmarketcountriesthereactionisadequateatmoderatedebt levelsbutprobablynotforhighlyͲindebtedcountries.35 Theadvantageofthisapproachisthatitdoesnotrequireassumptionsaboutlikelyshocksandestimation oftheirrespectiveprobabilities.Nordoesitrequirepassingjudgmentonwhatisanacceptabledebtlevel, thusavoidingthecontentiousCPIAprocess.Thelimitoftheapproachis,onceagain,aconsequenceofthe impossibility principle. Debt sustainability is a forwardͲlooking concept: future Governments are not boundbypastgovernmentbehavior.Evidenceofpastsustainability,orthelackthereof,isnotguarantee thatfutureGovernmentswillcontinuetoreactinthesameway.Allthatcanbeconcludediswhetherpast practicesaredeliveringdebtsustainabilityornot. Itmightbearguedthatsimplylookingattheexistingdebtlevel,orthehistoryofpastdefaults,provides the same answer in a much simpler way. But this is not correct. The debt may be high currently either becauseofundisciplinedpastpoliciesorbecauseofadverseshocks.Inordertoassesswhetherhighdebt is the result of bad luck or of bad policies we need to disentangle these two assumptions. This is what reactionfunctionsaredesignedtodo.Forinstance,ifthereactionfunctionindicatesthattheauthorities havesystematicallyreactedinastabilizingwaytodebtbuildups,wecanconcludethatahighdebtisdue tobadluck.Inasmuchasbadluckdoesnotstrikeagainandagain,insuchinstancesadebtcanbeassessed ashighandyetsustainable.ThisisthekeylessonfromFigureII.1.,confirmedbyFigureII.5. One benefit of this approach is that it focuses attention on the issue of policyͲmaking institutions. The best guarantee that the authorities will always react to shocks in a debtͲstabilizing way is that their decisions are embedded in a framework that constrains them to do so. Put differently, sustainability requiresthatthedebtlevelbesystematicallytreatedasapolicyobjective.Thiscanbedoneinmanyways. Onesolutionistheadoptionofrules.Thishasbeenthecaseintheareaofmonetarypolicywithrulesfor moneygrowthorwiththeadoptionofexchangeͲrateanchors.Fiscalruleshavebeenproposedtoensure publicͲdebtsustainability;theStabilityandGrowthPactoftheEconomicandMonetaryUnioninEuropeis oneexample.AhugeandinconclusiveliteraturehasexploredthetradeͲoffbetweenrulesanddiscretion. More recently there has been attention to intermediate solutions in the form of institutions that are boundbystrictobjectivesbutarealsogivensomeleewaytoexercisediscretion.Muchprogresshasbeen achieved in the area of monetary policy with the adoption of inflation targeting and independent monetarypolicycommittees.Similarconsiderationscouldbeappliedtofiscalpolicy(Wyplosz(2005b)). 35 SeealsoWyplosz(2005a)foracomparisonofBrazilandtheOECDcountries. 35 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives D. ReviewandConclusions Alongwithpricestability,lowunemploymentandbalancedgrowth,sustainabilityofexternalandpublic debt is an essential attribute of good macroeconomic policies.36Along with these other attributes, its precise definition is elusive and its assessment challenging. This section takes stock of the previous analysis,developsanumberofprinciples,andadvancessomesuggestions. 1. Assessment TheoverviewoftheIMF’sDSAandalternativeapproachesyieldsanumberofconclusions. x Thevariousapproachestodebtsustainabilitydifferfromoneanotherintwomainrespects:the definitionofsustainabilityandthewaytheyattempttodealwiththeimpossibilityprinciple. x Strict definitions of sustainability start from the solvency condition. These are, sometimes strengthened,forexample,wheretheIMFaddsanoͲmajorͲadjustmentcondition,andsometimes relaxed, for example, in the approach of Arrow et al. (2004) to the eventual achievement of solvency.Weakerdefinitionsfocusonthestationarityofthedebtlevel,usuallyscaledbyGDPor exports. x Implementation of these definitions requires making guesses about the future evolution of key variables. This gives rise to the impossibility principle: because the future is unknown, any debt sustainabilityassessmentisonlyvalidwithintheboundsoftheunderlyingguesses. x Thereisnowaytoescapeimpossibilityprinciple.Anyapproachisbasedeitheronananalysisof the past, whose relevance is unknown, or on simulations of what the future might be, which is unknownbydefinition.Someapproaches–e.g.VARstresstests–combinebothprocedures. x TheIMFapproachcombinessimpleandtransparentprocedures(computingdebtpathsbasedon scenarios) with more elaborate procedures (CPIA) for determining country debt ceilings. The formerarenecessarilyarbitrary.Thelatterattempttoextractinformationfromthepastthrough “blackbox”procedures. x The impossibility principle does not necessarily provide support for the view that added complexityallowsformorepreciseassessmentsofsustainability.VARstresstesting,forinstance, isstateͲofͲtheͲartbut,asfaraspolicyͲmakingisconcerned,thebenefitsareillusory.37 x Debt sustainability is intimately related to credibility. Credible authorities may adopt a weaker definition of debt sustainability, eschewing the serious economic and political costs inherent in strict definitions. Credibility, in turn, emphasizes the role in debt sustainability of policyͲmaking institutions. x PolicyconclusionsdrawnfromDSAexercisesmustbeconsideredwithcare.Sacrificinggrowth–in theshortandeveninthelongrun–toimpreciselyknownrisksconcerningdebtsustainabilitycan be very costly. Trading off growth and debt sustainability will always remain more art than science. 2. Principles Likeanyguidetopolicymaking,DSAmustbebothsimpleandtransparent.Simplicityisneededtomakeit possible for every country – especially the less developed countries where growth crucially depends on 36 DebtsustainabilitymaybeseenasapreͲconditionforalltheotherattributes.Itiscertainlynotasufficientcondition.Whether itisanecessaryconditionremainsopentodebate. 37 ThispointismadebyGoldfajninhisexcellentdiscussionofGarciaandRigobon(2005). 36 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment externalborrowing–tobeabletoproduceitsownanalysis.Transparencyisimportantbecausetherange ofpossiblecausesofdebtdistressisinfinite.Vagueandlowprobabilitythreatsshouldnotinformpolicy choices. ThispaperarguesthatDSAoughttorelyonanumberofprinciples. AccepttheImpossibilityPrinciple Exceptforobviousbutextremecases,itwill neverbe possible to assert that a debt is unsustainable as definedbytheIMF.Itsowndefinitionrequirescheckingforsolvency,whichisimpossible.Italsorequires passing judgment of what is a major adjustment, which involves assessing the willingness and political abilityoftheGovernmenttocarryoutunpopularpolicies.Thisturncallsforanevaluationoftheimpactof these policies and of the likely reaction of various segments of society, which depends on the political regimeand,indemocraticcountries,ontheelectoralcalendar.Finally,exceptforconcessionalloans,DSA is directly influenced by market sentiment, which can be a source of unpredictable vicious or virtuous cycles. ThereisNoTradeͲOffbetweenImpossibilityandSimplicity Theimpossibilityprinciplerestsontheuncertaintyinherentinpredictingthefuture.Whileeliminatingthis uncertainty is plainly not an option, a natural temptation is to reduce uncertainty by adopting sophisticatedtechniquesofassessment.Mostusersareunlikelytograsphowthesetechniquesfunction. Complexity means opacity. It is an illusion to think that some degree of opacity is worthwhile because eventhemostsophisticatedinstrumentsdonotavoidtheimpossibilityprinciple.Moreoveropacitymay also result in the mistaken use of the instruments. By contrast simplicity, which lays bare our lack of knowledgeofthefuture,isavirtueinitself. AdoptaWorkableDefinitionofDebtSustainability Thedifferentdefinitionsandapproachesrevealthatdebtsustainabilityisandwillremainavagueconcept. Inadditionthereisahugegapbetweentheoryandimplementation.Fromanoperationalviewpoint,two mainapproachesarepossible:thefirstonerestsondebtthresholdsandthesecondontheevolutionof debtlevels.Giventheimpossibilityprinciple,ifDSAistoestablishuncontroversialdebtthresholds,atleast for the time being it should rest on a variant of the second approach which specifies that debt is sustainableifitisonanonͲincreasingtrend. EvenBetter,ReplaceDebtSustainabilitywithDebtDistressAvoidance However,thatadebtlevelbetrendͲdecreasingisneithernecessarynorsufficienttoavoiddebtdistress. Numerous debt crises have occurred while the debtͲGDP ratio was declining. On the other hand many countries with long rising debt levels have not run into trouble. In the end, the main reason for paying attention to the evolution of debts is concern with the possibility of debt distress which, unlike sustainability,isaclearconcept. RecognizethatDebtsAreNotNecessarilyBad Many countries and virtually all Governments are quasiͲpermanently indebted, for both good and bad reasons.Theviewthatdebtsshouldalwaysbereducedassumesthatalldebtsarebad,whichcannotbe generally true. Separating good from bad debts is a hopeless undertaking, but it is important to move awayfromthepresumptionthatdebtaccumulationistobeavoidedunderallcircumstances.38 38 It is puzzling that the IFIs, which routinely emphasize debt reduction, exist mainly to grant loans and are actually the main creditorstomanydevelopingcountries. 37 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives OpenUptheProcessofDeterminingWhetherDebtsAreExcessive Howshouldoneassesswhetheradebtisexcessive?Whenthedebtistraded,theriskpremiumprovidesa reasonableguide.ItalsoprovidestherightincentiveforGovernmentstolowertheirdebtlevels.Butwhen thecountrydoesnothavemarketaccess,thereisnosuchgauge.Yet,thelendersarenaturallyentitledto have a view. Given that any assessment is bound to be controversial, as the shortcomings of the CPIA exercisewellillustrate,themultilateralfinancialinstitutionsshouldhaveaproceduretoassessexcessive indebtednessthatisopenandinvolvesexpertsotherthantheirownstaffs.39 TimeisoftheEssence Whencurrentdebtlevelsareconsideredexcessive,avoidanceofdebtdistresscallsforadecliningtrend. Howsteepshouldtherateofdeclinebe?Obviously,bringingthedebtdowntoasafelevelbeforedebt distressoccursishighlydesirable,butitmaybecostlyintermsofgrowthandemployment.Thereisthusa tradeͲoffbetweenafastdebtrollͲbackandtheassociatedcosts.ThistradeͲoffmustbecarefullyassessed, takingdueaccountofeachcountry’sspecificities. AcceptRisk Unless current debt levels are considered excessive, keeping them stable is likely to avoid debt distress under most plausible conditions. To be sure, there will always be exceptional events that will result in debtdistress.Likealldisastrousevents,thisriskmustbeacceptedasafactoflife.Acompleteguarantee thatdebtdistresswillneveroccurisillusory,andahighlevelofprotectionisboundtobeverycostly. 3. Suggestions UsebothApproaches DSA rests on the debt accumulation process, which is nothing more than an accounting identity: bt bt 1 (r g )bt 1 primary balancet . At the operational level, one approach is to make assumptions about the evolution of the primary balance, interest rate r and growth rate g in order to projectthedebtpath.ThisistheIMF’sDSAapproach.Theotherapproachistoaskwhatshouldhappento the primary balance to achieve a desirable debt path, given assumptions about the evolution of the interestraterandgrowthrateg.ThisisthedebtͲstabilizingprimaryaccountapproach.Whichapproachis moreappropriate? WhiletheIMFalsocomputesdebtͲstabilizingprimaryaccounts,itspolicyanalysisandgraphicalapparatus emphasizesdebtpath projections.The presentpaperhasargued thatthe policyinterpretationofdebtͲ path projections, already subject to the impossibility principle, inevitably leads to a search for debt thresholds,anothermissionimpossible. Thissuggeststhatitis preferabletorelyonthe debtͲstabilizing primaryaccountapproach. Butinfactthereisnoreasontochooseoneovertheother.BothcanbeusedasFigureII.5.shows.Allthat isneededistheclassicdistinctionbetweentargetsandinstruments.Thedebtpathisatarget.Theprimary account is the instrument (assuming that the authorities can control it). The policy implications then follownaturally:DSAbecomesaprocedurethatexplorestheeffectonthedebtpathofvarioussettingsof the primaryͲaccount instrument. What should this combined approach include and what assumptions shouldbemade? 39 ThisisinlinewiththerecommendationsoftheexternalpanelthatreviewedtheWorldBank’sCPIA,seeWorldBank(2004). 38 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment ParameterSettings Abaselineprojection,suchascarriedoutbytheIMF,showshowthedebtaccumulationunfoldsonthe basisofthecurrentlyforeseenprimarybalance,exchange,interestandgrowthrates.Inassociationwith thisprojectionitisstraightforwardtocomputetheprimarybalancethatwouldstabilizethedebtunder current conditions, as well as the primary balance required to lower the debtͲtoͲGDP ratio when the currentlevelisperceivedexcessive. The baseline is not a forecast, only a statement of where current conditions lead. Currently the IMF provides two baselines: one that is based on Staff forecasts and one that is based on historical trends. Neither is adequate. Staff forecasts introduce a degree of arbitrariness. Indeed, IMF (2003b) reports a tendency for these forecasts to err on the side of optimism. Producing a baseline on the basis of these forecasts has the merit of consistency, but this comes at the cost of a selfͲinflicted lack of realism. In addition, the baseline should extend over a horizon which goes beyond the ability to make credible forecasts. Historicaltrendshave theadvantageovercurrentvaluesofprovidingsomestability,but thisstabilityis illusory.TrendprojectionisadequateforGDPgrowth,whichtendstofluctuatearoundareasonablystable level,withgoodyearsmakingupforbadyears.Butthisistheonlyhistoricaltrendthatshouldbeused. Theothervariables,theexchangeandinterestratesandtheprimarybalancearepotentiallyvolatileand, partlyatleast,controlledbytheauthorities.Exploringthedebtimplicationsofthecurrentsettingsismore informativethanrelyingonhistoricalaveragesthatareoftenoutdated. Thehorizonshouldbelong,saytenyears.AsarguedinSectionC.3,debtcorrectionsarebestcarriedout slowly, with small changes in the primary account maintained over a long period. Debt corrections are inherentlycostly–andmorecostly,thesharpertheyare.Thesamecorrectioncanbeachievedatamuch lowercostifitistheresultofchangessustainedovermanyyears. PolicyImplications Projected over a long horizon, the charts displayed in Figure II.5. provide an adequate framework for policy discussions. The impossibility principle means that DSA should not lead to automatic policy conclusions, a fact well recognized in IMF (2003b). For this reason, the more transparent are the parametersettings,thesmalleristheriskoftheirbeinggivenanoverlyprominentrole. Thebaselinedebtprojectionimmediatelyindicateswherethedebtisheading.Theprimaryaccountwhich isdebtͲstabilizing–ordebtͲreducingwhenthedebtisdeemedexcessiveandalowerlongͲruntargetcan beagreedupon–providesareasonableevaluationofwhatisrequiredtoachievedebtsustainability. Itisthenpossible,indeeddesirable,toask“whatif?”questions.Inpolicydiscussions,manyquestionscan beaskedandeasilyanswered. Itisstraightforward toproduce chartssimilar toFigureII.5. showing the mechanical effects on debt and the stabilizing primary account of changes in interest or growth rates, whether they are permanent or temporary. But it is important to keep in mind that such an exercise is purelymechanical,becauseitignoresthelinkagesamongthevariablesthatdrivedebtaccumulation.For example,changesintheprimarycurrentaccountmayrequireactingontheexchangerate,whichinturn willnotonlyaffectthedebtͲGDPratiointermsoflocalcurrencybutmayalsoleadtodifferentinterestͲ ratelevels. ThishassomeresemblancetotheIMFapproachtoDSAbutdiffersfromitintwoimportantways:1)there isnopretenseofprovidingforecastsandofassessingtheirlikelihood;and2)theresultsareanswersto questions asked by policymakers and not simply readyͲmade suggestions that the debt might be in a dangerzone. 39 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives InstitutionsMatter Credibility is an essential component of DSA, yet it is largely hidden. Credibility affects exchange and interest rates, and can trigger virtuous or vicious circles. The CPIA is one way of recognizing the importance of credibility but suffers from its assumption that institutions are given. Policymaking is not justaboutsettingmacroeconomicvariables.ItshouldalsogiveaprominentroletoshapingpolicyͲmaking institutions. A number of countries have taken steps to improve their policyͲmaking institutions in the area of fiscal policy,withmuchsuccess.BrazilandChile,forinstance,haveadoptedformalproceduresthatbindpolicy actionswithinaframeworkthatputsdebtsustainabilityattheforefront.MostEastAsiancountrieshave informallydonethesame,relyingonnormsinsteadoflegalarrangements.MechanicalDSAimplicitly(and, as just noted, CPIA explicitly) takes institutions as given. It would seem important to downplay the mechanical part of DSA and, in contrast, to emphasize forcefully the contributions that adequate institutionscanmaketoavoidingdebtdistress. 40 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References Abiad A and Ostry JD (2005). Primary Surpluses and Sustainable Debt Levels in Emerging Market Countries.IMFPolicyDicusssionPaperPDP/05/6. ArrowKetal.(2004).AreWeConsumingTooMuch?JournalofEconomicPerspectives,18(3):147–172. Blanchard OJ (2005). Fiscal Dominance and Inflation Targeting: Lessons from Brazil. In: F. Giavazzi, I. GoldfajnandS.Herrera(2005)InflationTargeting,DebtandtheBrazilianExperience.MITPress: 49–80. Blanchard OJ et al. (1990). The Sustainability of Fiscal Policy: New Answers to an Old Question. OECD EconomicStudies15:7–36. Borensztein E et al. (2004). Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis Prevention. Occasional Paper, 237, InternationalMonetaryFund. BuiterW(1985).AGuidetoPublicDebtsandDeficits.EconomicPolicy,1:13–62. Bulow J and Rogoff K (1989). A Constant Recontracting Model of Sovereign Debt. Journal of Political Economy,97(1):155–78. BurdaandWyplosz(2005).Macroeconomics,AEuropeanText.FourthEditions,OxfordUniversityPress. Celasun O, Debrun X and Ostry JD (2005). Primary Surplus Behavior and Risks to Fiscal Sustainability in EmergingMarketCountries:A“FanͲChart”Approach.IMFPolicyDiscussionPapers,PDP/05/6. Chang R and Velasco A (1999). Liquidity Crises in Emerging Markets: Theory and Policy. In: B. Bernanke andJ.Rotemberg,eds.NBERMacroeconomicsAnnual,theMITPress. Cordella T, Ricci LA and RuizͲArranz M (2005). Debt Overhang or Debt Irrelevance? Revisiting the DebtͲ GrowthLink.IMFWorkingPaper05/223. Garcia M and Rigobon R (2005). A Risk Management Approach to Emerging Market’s Sovereign Debt Sustainability with an Application to Brazilian Data. In: F. Giavazzi, I. Goldfajn and S. Herrera (2005).InflationTargeting,DebtandtheBrazilianExperience,MITPress:163–188. HemmingR,KellMandSchimmelpfenningA(2003).FiscalVulnerabilityandFinancialCrisesinEmerging MarketEconomies.OccasionalPaper218,InternationalMonetaryFund. Hostland D and Karam P (2005). Assessing Debt Sustainability in Emerging Market Economies Using StochasticSimulationMethods.IMFWorkingPapersWP/05/226. IMF(2002).AssessingSustainability.PolicyDevelopmentandReviewDepartment,SM/02/166.Available at:www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sus/2002/eng/052802.htm. IMF(2003a).PublicDebtsinEmergingMarkets:IsItTooHigh?WorldEconomicOutlook,September:113– 152. IMF (2003b). Sustainability Assessments—Review of Application and Methodological Refinements. Availableat:www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sustain/2003/061003.pdf. IMF and IDA (2004). Debt Sustainability in LowͲIncome Countries: Further Considerations on an Operational Framework and Policy Implications. Available at: www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sustain/2004/091004.pdf. IMF(2005a).InformationNoteonModificationstotheFund’sDebtSustainabilityAssessmentFramework forMarketAccessCountries.Availableat:www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/070105.htm. 41 DebtSustainabilityAssessment:theIMFApproachandAlternatives IMF(2005b).Colombia:FirstReviewUndertheStandͲByArrangement.CountryReport,05/392.Available at:www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2005/cr05392.pdf. IMF(2005c).AreFundStaffProjectionsofDebtMoreOptimisticUnderProgramContexts?Availableat: www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/110905.pdf. IMF(2005d).SouthAfrica:SelectedIssues.CountryReport,05/345. Jeanne O and Zettelmeyer J (2001). International Bailouts, Moral Hazard and Conditionality. Economic Policy,33:407–32. Kraay A and Nehru V (2003). When Is External Debt Sustainable? Available at: www.imf.org/external/ np/res/seminars/2003/lic/pdf/kn.pdf. Manasse P, Roubini N and Schimmelpfenning A (2003) Predicting Sovereign Debt Crises. Working Paper 03/221,InternationalMonetaryFund. MissaleA(2000).PublicDebtManagement.OxfordUniversityPress. RodrikD(1998).WhoNeedsCapitalͲAccountConvertibility?In:S.Fischerandothers(1998).Shouldthe IMF Pursue CapitalͲAccount Convertibility? Essays in International Finance, 207, International FinanceSection,DepartmentofEconomics,PrincetonUniversity,May. World Bank (2004). Country Policy and Institutional Assessments: An External Panel Review Panel Recommendations and Management FollowͲup. Available at: www.siteresources.worldbank.org/ IDA/Resources/CPIAExpPanRepSecM2004Ͳ0304.pdf. WyploszC(2005a).InstitutionsforDebtStabilityinBrazil.In:F.Giavazzi,I.GoldfajnandS.Herrera(2005). InflationTargeting,DebtandtheBrazilianExperience.MITPress:193–222. WyploszC(2005b).FiscalPolicy:InstitutionsVersusRules.NationalInstituteEconomicReview,191:70– 84. 42 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Annex:AnAlternativeDebtSustainabilityCondition Section B.1. suggests an alternative definition of debt sustainability. This appendix briefly characterizes thelinkofthisdefinitionwiththesolvencycondition. LetBtbethedebtoutstandingatbeginningofperiodt,Rt,t+ithediscountfactorbetweenperiodstand t+i,andSttheprimarybudgetbalance.Thedebtaccumulationprocessimplies: n Bt ¦ Rt ,t i St i Rt ,t n Bt n i 0 Solvencyisdefinedbytheusualtransversalitycondition: lim Rt ,t n Bt n d 0 nof whichcanberewrittenas: f Bt d ¦ Rt ,t i S t i i 0 Thenetworthoftheentity(Government,country)is: f Vt ¦R t ,t i S t i Bt andthereforesolvencysimplyrequiresVtш0. i 0 Thealternativesustainabilitycondition(basedonArrowetal.(2004))isthatVtbetrendͲincreasing,i.e.: Vt+n–Vtш0formostn. Thus,itmaybethatinitiallyVtч0butthesustainabilityconditionimpliesthatthereexistsahorizonN suchthat,foralln>N,Vt+nш0. 43 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERIII THEMECHANICSOF DEBTSUSTAINABILITYANALYSIS AnhͲNgaTranͲNguyenandAlbiTola (UNCTAD) A. Introduction Debtsustainabilityhasbecomeakeyissueinthediscussionondebtindifferentfora.Theconceptofdebt sustainabilityisdifficulttodefineinpracticeanddependsonanswerstoanumberofquestions.Whenisa certainlevelofdebttoohighandunsustainable?Howimportantisdebtsustainabilityfordevelopment? Shoulditbeamajorobjectiveandshouldeconomicpoliciesbeadjustedaccordingly?Alternativelyshould developmentbeanobjectivewhichcanoverridedebtsustainability?Ifso,whatdoesthismeaninterms of policies? Or on the contrary should there be acknowledgement that debt sustainability and developmentaretoointerconnectedforsuchaseparationofobjectivestobefeasible? Answers to these questions are not straightforward. The literature on debt sustainability offers a wide rangeofanalysesoftheissuefromdifferentperspectives.Thebasicelementsofthedifferentapproaches are highlighted in this paper, with particular reference to their practicality and relevance. Four main approachesarecovered: x x x x Presentvalueanalysis; Financinggapsanalysis; Theindicatorsofdebtcrisis;and AdevelopmentpolicyͲbasedframework. The analytical underpinnings of these approaches are linked, but the focus on particular aspects of the debt problems is typically different. The last approach attempts to address various concerns within a comprehensivemacroeconomicandpolicyͲbasedmodel. 45 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis B. DebtIndicatorsandEarlyWarningofCrisis In the aftermath of recent debt crises economists have attempted to identify early warning indicators whichwouldsignalinadvancetheprobabilitythatacurrencyordebtcrisiswilloccur.Suchindicatorsare intendedtofacilitatecorrectivemeasures.Onesuchindicatorisanunsustainablecurrentaccountdeficit associatedwithlowGDPgrowth.Thattypicallycharacterizeddebtcrisesinthe1980s. Accordingtothemodelsofdebtdynamicsdiscussedbelow,acountry’sdebtaccumulationissustainable as long as the growth of GDP is greater than the real interest rate. However, access to credit can be abruptlystoppedifcreditorsbecomeworriedaboutincreasingdebt.Inaddition,highgrowthratesofGDP accompaniedbycapitalinflows,cancausetherealexchangeratetoappreciate.Thiscanleadtolossof competitivenessandfurtherdeteriorationofthecurrentaccount. Anotherimportantindicatorofdebtsustainabilityisthesizeofexports,whichenhancethedebtor’sability to generate the foreignͲcurrency revenues needed to service debt. However, a large export sector can makeacountryvulnerabletotermsͲofͲtradeandforeigndemandshocks.Forexample,asitisshownby Corsettietal.(1998),theexportsofSouthEastAsiancountriesweresubjecttonegativetermsͲofͲtrade shocksin1996priortothefinancialcrisisof1997followingthefallinthepricesofsemiconductorsand other exports, the increasing competition of cheaper goods from China, and decreasing demand from Japanduetolongstagnationofitseconomy. Radelet and Sachs (1998) point out that so long as investments financed by external borrowing are channeled to productive activities, they can contribute to growth. However, overͲreliance on external financingcanbethesourceofmacroeconomicinstabilityifitinducesanappreciationoftherealexchange rate.PriortotheAsianfinancialcrisisasignificantpartofcapitalinflowswasdirectedtosectorsproducing nonͲtradedgoodsandtorealestate,neitherofwhichgenerateforeignexchangerevenue. RadeletandSachs(1998)alsoidentifytheincreasingfragilityoffinancialsectorasasignofanupcoming debtcrisis.AscredittotheprivatesectorgrewrapidlypriortotheAsianfinancialcrisis,banksincreased theirrecoursetoshortͲtermforeignborrowing.Bankswerethusexposedintwoways:(1)toexchangeͲ rate risk since they were borrowing in foreign currency for onͲlending in domestic currency; and (2) to maturitymismatchessincetheyborrowedshortandlentlong. Traditionalindicatorssuchasaslowingofexportgrowth,adeterioratingcurrentͲaccount deficitandan overvaluedexchangeratearenotnecessarilyareliablesourceofwarnings.Somerecentresearchonearly warningsystems(EWS),describedinBergetal(2004),hasbeenmodelͲbased.Theaimofthisresearch,of which examples are Kaminsky, Lizondo and Rienhart (KLR) (1998) and work of the IMF Developing CountriesStudiesDivision(DCSD),hasbeentodevelop“theexchangemarketpressureindex”.Ifthevalue ofthisindexexceedsitsmeanbymorethanthreestandarddeviations,thenthecurrencyisexposedtoa serious risk of devaluation. Although the models developed for this purpose use different econometric techniques,theyaredesignedtoestimatetheprobabilityofan“event”onthebasisofvariousindicators. The indicators of the DCSD model include realͲexchange devaluation, changes in foreign reserves, the ratioofshortͲtermdebttoforeignexchangereserves.TheKLRmodelusesalsoincludesindicatorssuchas thedomesticcreditgrowth,changeinmoneymultiplier,andtheratioofforeignͲexchangereservestoM2. TheIMFalsoexaminedtheratiooftheshortͲtermdebttoreservesasawarningindicatorbutfoundthatit performedbetterasanindicatorofliquiditythanofexternalsolvencyproblems.Forexample,priortoits debt crisis of January 2002 Argentina had a better indicator for this ratio than Turkey in 1999Ͳ2000. However, its ratio of debtͲservice to current receipts was twice as large as that of Turkey and more successfullyanticipateditssubsequentsolvencyproblems. 46 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TheIMFhasdrawnattentiontothepossibilityofincludingmodelsofcountryriskmodelsandsovereignͲ risk indices in the EWS, pointing to an econometric model of Eichengreen and Moody (2000) in this context. This model is used to estimate the determinants of emergingͲmarket debt spreads and to forecast currency problems on this basis. Inter alia the authors found that the debtͲserviceͲtoͲexports ratiowashighlycorrelatedwiththelevelofspreads. OtherstudiesofEWSmodels(reviewedinBergetal.,2004)pointtoamixedperformanceinpredicting crises. While they tend to perform better than nonͲmodelͲbased indicators such as sovereign spreads, sovereign ratings or market surveys, they have often signaled false alarms. On the other hand, these modelshavecoveredalargenumberofmacroeconomicandfinancialvariablesformanycountriesandfor long periods. They have highlighted invaluable information about the relative vulnerability of different countries(BergandPatillo,2000). Aliquidityproblemarisesbecauseofabunchingataparticulartimeofdebtobligationswhichcannotbe fullyservicedonthebasisofexistingrevenues.However,thedebtcanberepaidifrecoursetoexternal fundingisavailableonatemporarybasisorifthedebtisrestructuredsothatdebtobligationsarebetter matchedtothedebtor’srevenues.Insolvency,ontheotherhand,denotestheinabilityofthedebtorto pay in full his debt obligations owing to more structural problems which cannot be solved simply by a rearrangementofpaymentsdue. In theory a country is solvent even if it runs a huge current account deficit as long as it is capable of producingcurrentaccountsurplusesinthefutureand,asdescribedbelow,GDPincreasesatarateabove the rate of interest. In practice this condition has been shown to be unrealistic. According to Roubini (2001)themainproblemwithsuchdebtdynamicslieswiththefactthataGovernmentcannotcredibly committoruntherequiredfiscalandbalanceͲofͲpaymentssurplusesinthefuture.Thisauthorprefersthe simpleratioofforeigndebttoGDPratioasanindicatorofbothsolvencyandsustainability.Ifthisratiois increasing,thenalargertradesurpluswillberequiredtoachievesolvencyandthismustbeincreasedstill furtheriftherealinterestrateisbiggerthanGDPgrowth. Other studies have attempted to determine empirically the thresholds beyond which a “debt crisis” (or solvency problems) will develop. The debt crisis is defined as an event in which there are arrears of principal or interest on external obligations, or in which the country reschedules or restructures its external debt. These studies (IMF, 2002a) have found that a debt crisis occurs typically at debt to GDP ratios below 50Ͳ60 per cent. The “transfer problem” implies that a country must also generate foreignͲ exchange receipts through an export surplus sufficiently large to service its debt. This implies that the exportsͲtoͲGDP ratio (or another indicator for the same purpose such as the debtͲ serviceͲtoͲexports ratio)isrelevant.ThesurveyofIMF(2002a)showedthatfordebtcrisesatexportͲtoͲGDPratiosbelow20 percentthreeͲquartersoccurredatdebtͲtoͲGDPratiosoflessthan60percentofGDP,whileforcrisesat exportͲGDPratiosofbetween20and40percentthecorrespondingdebtͲtoͲGDPratiowasbetween60 and80percent. Themainindicatorsusedtomeasureliquidityaretheratioofforeignexchangereservestoimports,the ratio of foreign exchange reserves to shortͲterm debt, the share of shortͲterm debt in total debt, and interestpaymentstoforeignexchangereserves.Althoughacountrycanbesolvent,itrisksadebtdefault orcrisisifitdoesnothaveenoughliquiditytoserviceitsshortͲtermdebt,perhapsowingtoabunchingof loansmaturingataparticulartime.ThismighthappenduringafinancialpanicwhereshortͲtermcreditors decide not to renew their loans or ask for a repayment. Thus debtor countries should monitor their maturity structure to make sure that they have enough shortͲterm assets to cover their shortͲterm liabilities. Assessingthesolvencyandtheliquidityofacountryisadynamicprocesswhichshouldtakeaccountof differentshocksthatmightreduceitscapacitytoserviceitsdebt.Theseshockscouldbedropsinexport 47 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis earnings,unfavorablemovementsinthetermsoftrade,orincreasesinoilprices.Roubini(2001)draws theattentiontowhathecalls“selfͲfulfillingsolvencytraps”.Thisiswhereahighexternalorpublicdebt– but not necessarily at a level entailing insolvency Ͳ will be considered by the markets as a situation sufficientlyriskyforthespreadsoninterestratestoincrease.Asaresult,thedebtorcountrywillpaymore interestandwillaccumulatedebtmorerapidly.Thisisanothercasewherealiquiditycrisismayturnintoa solvencycrisis. Liquidityandsolvencyconceptsareusuallyinterlinkedinpracticesothatitisverydifficulttodistinguish between the two. It is generally difficult to determine whether incapacity to pay is temporary or permanent.Moreoverproblemsofilliquiditycanturnintoinsolvencyiftheyarenottackledintime. C. ThePresentValueofFutureIncome How should debt sustainability be defined? Since debt is generally incurred to finance investment, one approachinvolvesananalogywiththemicroͲlevelanalysisofinvestmentprojects.Heredebtsustainability isdeterminedbytheconditionthatthepresentvalueofthefutureincomestream(netofexpenditure) derivedfrominvestmentprojectsshouldbeatleastequaltothenominalvalueofdebtusedtofinance them.Therearetwowaystoobtainthepresentvalueoffutureincomestreams.Thepresentvaluecanbe computed by discounting the streams of income by the interest rate of the debt. Another way is to compute the expected internal rate of return, defined as the rate of discount applied to future income whichwouldmakestheexpectedpresentvalueofincomeequaltothenominalvalueofdebt.Inthiscase debtsustainabilityisassurediftheexpectedinternalrateofreturnisatleastequaltotheinterestrateof thedebt. Application of the present value approach to debt sustainability to the debt of a country nonetheless involvesaddressingmanychallengesatonce: x Theinvestmentprojectsfinancedbydebtarethesumofprivateandpublicprojectswithdifferent ratesofreturn.Thelattermayincludeprojectsaddressingsocialratherthaneconomicneeds. x The income generated by investment can be denominated in foreign currency (in the case of exports)orinlocalcurrency. x External debt sometimes is used to smooth out cyclical changes in consumption (which do not generateanyincome), debtbeingincurredduring timesofdepressedgrowth andrepaidduring highͲgrowthperiods. x Debt can carry concessional or market interest rates and have different maturities and grace periods,whichmakethechoiceoftheappropriatediscountrateacomplicatedissue. Notwithstanding these difficulties, the present value approach has been widely applied to developing countries’ debt. The IMF implicitly uses this concept of the present value in their approach to debt sustainability (see IMF, 2002a). It defines debt sustainability as “a situation in which a borrower is expectedtobeabletocontinueservicingitsdebtswithoutanunrealisticallylargefuturecorrectiontothe balanceofincomeandexpenditure”.40Underlyingthisdefinitionofsustainabilityareconceptsofsolvency andliquidity,whicharedefinedonthebasisofthepresentvalueapproach. 40 Sustainability, according to the IMF, rules out: (1) debt restructuring; (2) Ponzi games where the borrower indefinitely accumulates debt faster than its capacity to service debt is growing); (3) moral hazard whereby the borrower lives beyond its meansbyaccumulatingdebtintheknowledgethatamajordebtservicereductionwilleventuallybeneeded. 48 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Solvencyissecuredwhenthepresentvalueofadebtor’scurrentandfutureprimaryexpenditure(E)isno greaterthanthepresentvalueofitscurrentandfuturepathofincome(Y),netofanyinitialindebtedness (D): f ¦ i 0 f Et i d ¦( i (1 r t j ) j 1 i 0 Yt i (1 rt ) Dt 1 ) i (1 r t j ) j 1 . A liquidity crisis occurs when a debtor’s liquid assets and available financing are insufficient to meet or rollͲover its maturing liabilities, regardless of whether the solvency condition is met. Sustainability is reachedwhenadebtor’sliabilitypositionsatisfiesthepresentvaluebudgetconstraintwithouttheneed foramajorcorrectioninthebalanceofincomeandexpenditure,givenitscostsoffinancing. Thepracticalityofsuchanotionofsolvencyisquestionable.First,thetimehorizonisinfinitelylong,which makes planning or time framing of Government’s budget impossible. Furthermore, the appropriate discountratemuststillbechosen.Differentchoiceswillresultindifferentestimatesofpresentvalue. The present value approach is also applied to the analysis of the primary balance of the Government budget or the balance of payments on current account excluding payments. Based on the national accounting identities, the balance, Pt, that is the difference between revenue and expenditure or the currentͲaccountbalance,inbothcasesexcludinginterestpayments,isequaltothechangeindebtDtplus interestpayments: Dt (1 r ) Dt 1 Pt 1 Assumingaconstantinterestrate,recursiveapplicationofthisformulagives: i Dt ¦ j 1 D Pt j (1 r ) j 1 t i 1 i 1 (1 r ) Asitendstoinfinity,thetermontherightͲhandsidetendstozero.Thismeansthatthepresentvalueof debt in the indefinite future converges to zero and reflects the unwillingness of lenders to allow the debtor perpetually to pay its interest obligations by borrowing more. Hence, for i sufficiently f Dt large, ensue. ¦ j 0 Pt j (1 r ) j 1 ,whichimpliesthatalldebtmusteventuallybepaidbackforsustainabilityto Thisobservationleadstotheinterestingconclusionthattheabilitytogenerateasurplusisaprecondition forlongͲtermdebtsustainability.Inthecaseofthefiscalbalancethisisaprimarysurplus.Inthecaseof thebalanceofpaymentsoncurrentaccountthedebtorcountrymusteventuallyexportandearnenough foreignexchangethroughatradesurplustorepaydebt(thesocalledtransferproblem). AdifferentversionofthepresentvalueapproachistheIMFNetPresentValueofDebt.InthecaseoflowͲ income countries thatreceiveloansonconcessionalterms, creditorsapplythe conceptof “Netpresent Value”41(NPV)ofloanstocalculatethe“realburden”ofdebt,usingaformulaforwhichthedebtservice onconcessionalloansisdiscountedatthemarketrateofinterestinordertoreflectthe“trueopportunity 41 Theterm«NetPresentValue»(NPV)isusedhereinawaythatdivergesfromstandardcorporatefinancejargonforwhichNPV isthedifferencebetweenthepresentvaluesoftheincomeandcostofaninvestmentproject.Infact,amorecorrecttermhere wouldbethe“presentvalue”(PV). 49 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis cost” of the loans. This NPV concept was first applied in the context of Paris Club rescheduling on concessionaltermsandtheninthecontextoftheInitiativefortheHeavilyIndebtedPoorCountries(HIPC). The IMF applies it to the lowͲincome countries in its debt sustainability analysis framework (IMF, 2003, May). TherationalebehindtheuseofthisversionofNPVisthatdiscountingthestreamoffuturedebtͲservice payments by an appropriate market interest rate provides an aggregate measure of the effective debtͲ serviceburdenimpliedbyagivendebtstock.However,asseenatthebeginningofthissection,inorderto gaugewhetherthedebtorcanserviceitsdebt,thedebtor’sfuturestreamofincomehastobediscounted either at the rate of interest on the loan which has been contracted or at the rate of return on the investmentproject. ThisNPVapproachdoesnot,therefore,reflectthedebtor’scapacitytopay.Ifatall,thiscapacityistaken intoaccountwhenconcessionaltermsaregrantedtolowͲincomecountries.TheversionofNPVisrathera conceptofinteresttocreditors,usedtomeasurethegrantelementofaid.Itcanalsobeusefulasameans to determine comparable opportunity costs for donors for burden sharing purposes in debtͲrelief operations. D. TheFinancingGap Thefinancinggapanalyticalapproachesarebasedonthethreenationalaccountidentitiesrelatedtothe balanceofpayments,domesticinvestmentandsavings,andgovernmentbudget,whichlinkexternaldebt withdifferentfinancinggaps:thecurrentaccountdeficit,ortheshortageofdomesticsavingscompared todomesticinvestments,orthegovernmentbudgetdeficit(partofwhichcannotbefinancedbydomestic publicdebt). Assuch,thefinancinggapsarejustaccountingidentities.Economistshaveexpandedtheseidentitiesand added behavioral equations in order to project financing gaps or to analyse the dynamic stability conditions of external debt. The use of gap models to project financing gaps and aid requirements has been widely accepted by international financial institutions. However this approach has been much criticized, notably because of exͲpost inaccuracies of these projections and because of the instability of the key variable, the incremental capitalͲoutput ratio (ICOR),42used to determine the growth path of income. Despite these shortcomings, financing gaps as determined by accounting identities remain useful indicators for policymakers in the short run for the analysis of the origins of external debt and of the burdenofdebtservicingongovernmentbudget. 1. DebtandNationalAccountingIdentities Threenationalaccountingidentitiesrelatedtothebalanceofpayments,domesticinvestmentandsavings, andthegovernmentbudgetshowthelinksofexternaldebttodifferentfinancinggaps. (1)ThebalanceͲofͲpaymentsidentityisstatedasfollows: Et ( DtE DtE1 ) Et Pt* M t Pt X t Et > i * DtE1 FDI t ( Rt Rt 1 ) @ 42 SeeEasterly(1997). 50 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment where DtE istheexternaldebtstockindomesticcurrency, Et thenominalexchangerate(domesticper unit of foreign currency), Pt * foreign prices, M t import volume, Pt domestic prices, X t export volume, it* theforeigninterestrate, FDI t thenetflowofforeigndirectinvestment(includinglongtermportfolio R equityinvestment),and t thestockofforeignexchangereserves. This identity shows that new debtͲcreating capital inflows fill that part of the currentͲ account deficit ( Et Pt * M t Pt X t Et i * DtE1 )notfinancedbyFDIandthechangeinreserves. (2)TheinvestmentͲsavingsidentityisderivedfromthenationalincomeidentity: Yt * Ct S t C t I t ( Pt X t Et Pt M t ) Where C t isconsumption, S t issavings,and I t isinvestment. sothat St I t Pt X t Et Pt* M t CombiningthebalanceͲofͲpaymentsandinvestmentͲsavingsidentitiesgivesanotherequationforexternal debt: E (D E D E ) (I S ) E > i* D E FDI 'R @ t t t 1 t t t t t 1 t t ThisidentityshowsthatnewdebtͲcreatingcapitalinflowsfillthegapbetweendomesticinvestmentplus InterestspaymentsanddomesticsavingswhichnotfinancedbyFDIandthechangeinreserves. ' DG t ' D tD E t ' DG tE it D tD1 E t i t* DG tE1 Pt (3)TheGovernmentbudgetidentityisstatedas: DD where t is Government’s domestic debt, Gt 1 is government consumption expenditure and Pt is the primarysurplus. Pt Tt ETt (Gt IGt DTt ) T ET G Where t isgovernmentrevenue, t externaltransferstoGovernment, t government consumption, IGt governmentcapitalformation,and DTt domestictransfersandsubsidies. This identity above shows that new debtͲcreating capital inflows fill the gap between the total budget deficitandtheamountofthedeficitthatcanbefinancedbyissuingdomesticdebt. 2. TheStabilityofExternalDebtDynamics TheroleofforeigncapitalinthedevelopmentprocesshasfirstbeenanalysedinthecontextofthetwoͲ gap models, whereby debt or capital inflow helps in filling the resource gap resulting from of shortage foreignexchangeearnings(derivedfromidentity(1))orofsavings(derivedfromidentity(2)).Asdebtis assumedtocontributetogrowth,overtimetheresourcegapisgraduallynarrowedandtowardstheend ofthecycle,thedebtorcountrywillhaveenoughsurplusesinresourcestorepayitsdebt. 51 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis This virtuous cycle of debt is characterized by a stable dynamic path of debt accumulation, which decreases over time. Assuming unchanged exchange rate and expressing the variables in the same currency(withE=1),thedynamicinteractionsbetweendebtononehandandincomegrowthandexport growthontheotherhand,woulddeterminetheconditionsunderwhichthedebtaccumulationprocess canbecontrolled.Thebasicmodelshownbelowillustratessuchdebtdynamics.43 Thefirstequationdescribesdebtaccumulation(D)tofinancetheresourcegap,whichisdefinedhereas thedifferencebetweenimportsandexports(MͲX)andtheinterestpaymentsonearlierdebt(iD). dD (1) dt M X iD Theincreaseinoutputissimplytheproductofinvestment(I)andtheinverseoftheincrementalcapitalͲ outputratio(1/k): dY (2) dt 1 I k Thesavingsgap(thedifferencebetweeninvestmentIanddomesticsavingsS)andtheforeignexchange gap(thedifferencebetweenimportsMandexportsX)areequalexpost: I S MX dD iD dt (3) Other specifications can be added to this basic model. For example, imports can be broken down into importsofcapitalgoodsandimportsofconsumptiongoods.Exportscanbespecifiedtogrowexogenously ortodependontheinvestmentrate. Considerthesavingsgapfirst. Thesavingsfunctionsimplystatesthatsavingsaretheproductofthemarginalpropensitytosave(s)and domesticproduct: (4) S=sY Usingthesavingsgap(IͲS)andrearrangingtheterms,debtaccumulation(expressedasaratioofdebtto output)canbesetinfunctionoftheoutputgrowthrate(g),investment(gk)andsavings(s)rates: d (D / Y ) dt (5) D (i g ) ( gk s ) Y Equation5statesthatthechangeintheratioofdebttodomesticproductdependsonthecurrentlevelof this ratio, as well as the difference between the interest rate and the growth rate, and the difference betweentheinvestmentrateandsavingsrate.Thesolutiontothisdifferentialequationwilldeterminethe conditionofstabilityofthedebtaccumulationprocess: (6) D Y gk s § D0 gk s · (i g ) t ¸e ¨ g i ¨© Y0 g i ¸¹ whereD0/Y0isthevalueofD/Yattimet=0. 43 Notethatthemodelisinrealterms,i.eallvariablesaredividedbytheGDPdeflator. 52 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Fromequation6itcanbeseenthatthedynamicpathwillbestableandconvergetoequilibriumonlyif the rate of GDP growth is higher than the interest rate. If the interest rate is higher than the rate of growth,debtwillgrowataneverͲincreasingrateandwillreachanexplodinglevel. Withg>i,theasymptoticvalueofthedebtͲincomeratiois: LimD/Yї[(gk–s)/(g–i)] tїь The maximum amount of D/Y (or the maximum level of sustainable debtͲtoͲGDP) is determined by the differencebetweenthemarginalinvestmentrate(gk)andsavingsrate(s). Alternatively, using the trade gap (M Ͳ X) and rearranging the terms, debt accumulation can be set in functionoftheinterestrate(i)andtherateofgrowthofexports(x). d (D / X ) dt (7) D MX (i x) X X whereD/XisthedebtͲtoͲexportratio. Equation7statesthatthechangeintheratioofdebttoexportisthesumofthecurrentlevelofthisratio multipliedbythedifferencebetweentheinterestrateandtherateofgrowthofexports,andthecurrent trade gap divided by the current level of exports. The solution to this differential equation gives the followingtimepathofthedebtͲexportratio: (8) D X 1 §M X ¨ xi© X 1 §M X · ª D0 ¸« ¨ ¹ ¬X0 x i © X ·º ( i x ) t ¸» e ¹¼ whereD0/X0=debtͲexportratioattimet=o. Here,thestabilityconditionisthattheinterestrateshouldbelowerthantherateofgrowthofexports(i< x).ThetrajectoryofD/Xcanbeexponentiallyascendingordescending,dependingonwhetherxisgreater orsmallerthani. Withi<x,D/Xwillconvergetoanequilibriumwiththefollowinglimit: LimD/Xї[1/(xͲi)][(M–X)/X] tїь AsthesizeofthedebtͲtoͲexportratiodependsonthetradegap,thislimittosustainabilitycanbevery highifthetradegapisverylarge. Finally, taking into consideration the fiscal gap, as derived from the Government budget identity (and assumingthattheGovernmentincursonlyexternaldebtanddoesnothavedomesticallycontracteddebt), applyingthesameprocedureasaboveyieldsthefollowingequation: d (D / Y ) dt (9) D PB (i g ) Y Y 53 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis PBistheprimarydeficitoftheGovernmentbudgetandgistherateofgrowthoftheeconomy.Thistime thestabilityconditionisthatgexceedsi. The debt dynamics depicted above imply that as long as GDP grows faster than real interest rate, a countryissolventeveniftheratioofforeigndebttoGDPkeepsgrowing.Thesameappliesforfiscaldebt. Likewise, as long as export grows faster than real interest rate, a country is solvent even if the ratio of foreigndebttoexportsisincreasing. In practice, these concepts have shown to be not very realistic. In particular, even though the stability conditionscanbesatisfied,theasymptoticvaluesofdebt,aswellasthetradegapandfiscaldeficitwhich determinethesevalues,canbeveryhigh.Nothinginthemodelsignalsthecapacityofdebtorstorepay thefullamountofthisdebt.Unlesslendersarewillingtolendoveraprolongedperiodwhileknowingthat debtisnotgoingtoberepaid,debtorsneedtorunfiscalsurplusortradesurplusinordertoreducetheir debt. 3. TheIMFandWorldBankDSAFramework ThethreefinancingͲgapidentitiesarealsousedasthebasisoftheframeworkemployedbytheIMFand theWorldBankfordebtsustainabilityassessment(DSA).Theframeworkconsistsoftwotemplates,one relatedtotheexternaldebtsustainabilityandtheothertothefiscalsustainabilityofthepublicsector. The external debt sustainability template analyses the debt incurred externally by domestic residents (boththepublicandtheprivatesector).UsingthebalanceͲofͲpaymentsidentityasthepointofdeparture and rearranging the terms derived from the algebraic transformations of this identity, the following equationcanbeusedtodecomposechangesinexternaldebt: d t 1 d t 1 (r g U (1 g ) HD (1 r ))d t tbt 1 (1 g U gU ) where d isthedebtͲtoͲGDPratio, D istheshareofdomesticͲcurrencydebtintotalexternaldebt, H is the change in the exchange rate expressed in US$ per local currency unit, tb is the currentͲaccount balance excluding interest payments in per cent of GDP, U is the change in the domestic GDP deflator expressedinUS$, g istherealGDPgrowthrate,and r istheinterestrate. Thisequationallowsthefollowingdecompositionoftheseparatechannelsaffectingtheevolutionofthe debtͲGDPratio: x thenonͲinterestcurrentaccountdeficit,tb; x r dt therealinterestͲrate, (1 g U gU ; g dt therealgrowthrate, (1 g U gU ) ; x U (1 g ) HD (1 r ) dt . priceandexchangeͲratechanges, (1 g U gU ) x Thethreelasteffectscanbecharacterizedasthecontributionsofendogenousdebtdynamics. 54 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment The fiscal sustainability template analyses the behavior of the debtͲtoͲGDP ratio with all variables expressed in domestic currency. Using the Government budget identity as the point of departure and rearrangingthetermsderivedfromalgebraictransformationsofthisidentity,thefollowingequationcan beusedtodecomposechangesinpublicdebt: dt 1 dt 1 (rˆ S (1 g ) g HD (1 rˆ))dt pbt 1 (1 g S gS ) where d is the debtͲtoͲGDP ratio, pb is the primary balance, r̂ is a weighted average of domestic and foreign interest rates, D the share of foreignͲcurrency denominated public debt, S the change in the domesticGDPdeflator,andgtherealGDPgrowthrate.Changesintheexchangerate(localcurrencyper U.S.dollar)aredenotedby H ,with H ! 0 indicatingadepreciationofthelocalcurrency. ThisequationallowsthefollowingdecompositionofthechannelsaffectingtheevolutionofthedebtͲGDP ratio: x theprimarydeficit pb , x r S (1 g ) dt g g ( 1 S S ) ; therealinterestrate, g dt g g ( 1 S S ) ; therealgrowthrate, HD (1 r ) dt g g ( 1 S S . exchangeͲratedepreciation, x x Again,thethreelasteffectscanbecharacterizedasthecontributionsofendogenousdebtdynamics. Byidentifyingdifferentfactorscontributingtothegrowthofthedebtratios,thetemplatesindicatethe channelsthroughwhichdebtcanbereduced,ifthelevelistoohigh.Notethatinthetemplatesthereal GDP growth rate and export growth rate are exogenously given so that there is only a oneͲway relationshipfromGDPandexportgrowthtodebtaccumulation.Theshortcoming,therefore,isthelackof areverserelationshipfromGDPanddebtgrowthtogrowthofexports,whichlimitsuseofthetemplates forexaminingcertainscenariosfordebt,GDPandexportgrowth. Furthermore,theIMFandWorldBankDSAframeworkleavesopenthequestionoftheappropriatelevel of debt around which debt should be stabilized. An example of ad hoc character of the application of IMF/WorldBankDSAframeworkindeterminingasustainablelevelofdebtisthesettingoftheindicative thresholdsfortheratiosofNPVofdebttoGDP,toexportsandtogovernmentrevenueatdifferentlevels forlowͲincomecountriesaccordingtothepolicyperformanceofborrowingcountriesasmeasuredbythe CountryPolicyandInstitutionalAssessment(CPIA)Index.Thefollowingtableillustratesthesethresholds. 55 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis TableIII.1.IndicativeExternalDebtBurdenIndicators1/ NPVofdebtinpercentof: Exports GDP Revenue3/ Debtserviceinpercentof: Exports Revenue3/ QualityofPoliciesandInstitutions2/ Poor Medium 100 30 200 15 25 150 40 250 20 30 Strong 200 50 300 25 35 1/SeeIDAandIMF“OperationalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityAssessmentsinLowͲIncomeCountriesͲFurther Considerations”,2005. 2/Country’swithaCPIAbeloworequalto3.25aredefinedtohaveapoorqualityofpoliciesandinstitutions,while aCPIAabove3.75indicatesagoodquality. 3/Revenueisdefinedexclusiveofgrants. There are several problems with using the CPIA as the sole criterion for determining debt thresholds. Historical series for the CPIA index are not publicly disclosed (only data for IDA countries starting from 2005 are disclosed). As a consequence, all analyses that link debt sustainability to the CPIA have been conductedbyWorldBank/IMFstaffandnoexternalresearcherhasbeenallowedtotesttherobustnessof thelinksbetweenthesetwovariables.ItisalsoquestionablewhetherthequantitativeimpactoftheCPIA ontheprobabilityofdebtdistressislargeenoughtoformulatedebtthresholdsonlybasedontheCPIA. Moreover,itisnotclearwhethertheCPIAisindeedameasureofpoliciesorjustaleadingindicatorofa debtcrisis. 4. Debt,TradeandGrowth Interlinkagesbetweentrade,growthanddebtcanbeshownmoredirectlybyrearrangingthebalanceof payments identity of section B.1 in accordance with the algebraic transformations in section I of the Appendix.Thesegivethefollowingequation: d t d t 1 m x (i f p f )d t 1 (ctot g )d t 1 wheredistheratioofexternaldebttoGDP,mtheratioofimportstoGDP,xtheratioofexportstoGDP, iftheforeigninterestrate,pftherateofchangeofforeignpriceindex,phthedomesticpriceindex,ctot(= e + pf – ph) the rate of change of the terms of trade (e being the rate of change of the exchange rate expressedasdomesticperunitofforeigncurrency),variablesbeingexpressedindomesticcurrency. IgnoringtheeffectofrealforeigninterestrateandincludingatermrepresentingtheeffectofFDI(fdi,the ratioofnetflowsofFDItoGDP),thisequationhasbeentestedempiricallythroughapanelregressionof data for seven countries (Argentina, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Kenya, the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, and Uganda)overtheperiod1981Ͳ2004.Theresultsareasfollows(tͲstatisticsinparentheses): dt–dtͲ1=0.27Ͳ0.36(xt–mt)Ͳ0.37fdiͲ0.14gͲ0.18ctot (6.07)(5.54)(2.30)(1.68)(0.66) R2=0.1858 56 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment ThevariablesontherightͲhandsideoftheequationexplain18Ͳ19percentofthevariationsindebtratios. Thecoefficientsaresignificantatthe5Ͳor10ͲperͲcentlevelexceptforthatofthetermsͲofͲtradechange. Allthecoefficientshavetheexpectedsigns.Understandably,thetradebalanceplaysahighlysignificant roleindebtaccumulation:atradedeficitaddstodebt,whileatradesurplusreducesit.FDIandgrowth reducedebtaccumulation. 5. ContributionofDebttoGDPGrowth Theprecedingsuggeststhatgrowthreducestheexpansionofthedebtratio.Butwhatisthecontribution of debt to growth? In order to assess this relationship, the balanceͲofͲpayments identity is rearranged again to show the relationship between growth as a dependent variable and other variables including debtflows(seeappendixforthealgebraictransformations).Thisrelationshipisreflectedinthefollowing equation(derivedinsectionIIoftheAppendix).44 * * e e w w dY (1 OK \ )(dP/ P dE/ E dP / P ) (1 O)(d('D ) / 'D ) OH dY / Y Y S where O istheinitialratioofexportstoimports,ʗthepriceelasticityofimports,ʋtheincomeelasticity ofimports,ɻthepriceelasticityofexports,ɸtheincomeelasticityofexports,ȴDethenetexternaldebt flows, P the export price index, P* the import price index, E the exchange rate (domestic per unit of foreigncurrency),andYwworldincome. Panelregression,coveringthesamecountriesandthesameperiodasintheanalysisabove,wasusedto estimatealternativerelationships((i)and(ii))basedonthisequation. (i)g=0.04Ͳ0.109ȴd+0.049ctot+0.054ȴx (10.75)(5.25)(2.00)(1.91) R2=0.25 where g is real GDP growth, ȴd the change in the ratio of external debt stock to GDP, ctot the rate of changeofthetermsoftrade(UNCTADindexoftermsoftrade),andȴxthegrowthrateofconstantUS$ exports Allcoefficientsaresignificant.Thesignofthecoefficientofdebtisnegative,signifyingthatanincreasein thedebttoGDPratioreducesgrowth. (ii)g=0.338+0.127ȴf+0.094ctot+0.045ȴx (8.05)(2.22)(3.23)(1.46) R2=0.11 inwhichthedebtstockisreplacedbyavariable(ȴf)measuringtheratioofnetexternalresourceflowto GDP:ѐf=ft ͲftͲ1andf=nd+fdi +oda,ndbeing theratioof net transfersondebt (debtflowsnet of amortizationminusinterestpayments)toGDP,fditheratioofnetflowsofFDItoGDP,andodatheratio ofgrantstoGDP. 44 Thirwall and Hussain (1986) derived a similar equation, expressing growth in terms of the volume effect of relative price changes,thetermsoftrade,andthegrowthoftheworldeconomyandcapitalflows. 57 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis The variables on the rightͲhand side of (ii) explain only 11 per cent of GDP growth However, the coefficients except that of export growth are statistically significant. This time external debt is not specifiedintheequationassuchbutisincludedasoneofthecomponentsofthevariablerepresenting netexternalresourceflowswhichhaveastatisticallysignificantpositiveimpactongrowth. E. DevelopmentPolicyͲBasedApproachtoDebtSustainability TheabovediscussionshowsthatthereisadiversityofapproachestoDSA.Eachapproachhasaparticular focus and serves a different purpose, whether it be debt management, crisis prevention, or debt relief. Technical indicators should be supplemented by policy considerations and other kinds of analysis if countriesaretomanagetheirexternaldebtinasustainableway. Bearing in mind all external and domestic factors contributing to debt sustainability, under a developmentͲpolicy approach, debt sustainability is not viewed only from the narrow perspective of reducinganunsustainablelevelofdebtbutisalsointegratedintotheoveralldevelopmentstrategyofa country.Underthisapproach,debtshouldbemanagedinsuchawayastomaximizeitscontributionto sustainabledevelopment. Suchanapproachincorporatestheviewthatexternalindebtednesscannotbesustainableinthelongrun ifthedevelopmentstrategyadopteddoesnotleadtoanincreaseinforeignexchangeearningstorepay thedebtonlyaftertheotherdomesticresourcerequirementsofthedevelopmentstrategyhavebeenmet. Thusthepointofdepartureofasustainabledebtstrategyisaclearvisionofthecountry’sdevelopment trajectory. Debt should be integrated into this development trajectory by encouraging efficient use of externaldebtwhichbalancesitscostsandbenefitsinthecontextofthetrajectory. Thepanoplyofpoliciesintegratingdebtintoacountry’sdevelopmentstrategywouldaimataddressing differentsituations: x x x policiestoenhanceanefficientuseofdebtinlinewithdevelopmentobjectives; policiestoadjusttoshocksinordertoavoiddebtcrises; policiestodealwithdebtcrisesandtorestoregrowth. Integrationofdebtanddevelopmentstrategydoesnotexcludepoliciestoreduceexcessivelevelsofdebt but emphasizes the context of a growthͲoriented approach to debt sustainability. Furthermore such integration is based on acknowledgement that in an interdependent world prevention of a debt crisis often also requires actions at the international level, based on international cooperation to ensure adequatetransferofresourcesfordevelopmentaswellastradingopportunitiesfordebtorcountries. The establishment of an effective institutional framework up for debt management is essential for the implementation of a sustainable debt strategy. Within this framework specific roles and responsibilities shouldbeassignedtotheministryoffinance,thecentralbankandthedebtmanagementagency,i.e.the differentgovernmententities,andtheframeworkitselfshouldbeadaptedtotheadministrativecapacity ofeachdebtorcountry. Development is not a smooth process, and no country can be sheltered from the threat of a debt or financialcrisis.Countriescanmoreeffectivelyadjusttodebtandcurrencycrisesiftheymanagetoforesee theeventslikelytotriggerthem.Takingearlyadjustmentmeasures,wherepossible,couldinsomecases help to mitigate the gravity of the crisis and shorten its duration. The indicators reviewed in this paper should help in this respect. They should also help countries to assess the costs and benefits of debt renegotiations. 58 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References BergAandPattilloC(2000).TheChallengesofPredictionEconomicCrises.IMFEconomicIssues.22,July. BergA,BorenszteinEandPattilloC(2004).AssessingEarlyWarningSystems:HowHaveTheyWorkedin Practice?IMFWorkingPaper(WP/04/52),March. Corsetti G, Pesenti P and Roubini N (1998). What Caused the Asian Currency and Financial Crisis. NBER WorkingPapers,6833,December. EichengreenBandModyA(2000).WouldCollectiveActionClausesRaiseBorrowingCosts?NBERWorking Papers,7458,January. IMF(2002a).AssessingSustainability.PreparedbythePolicyDevelopmentandReviewDepartment,May. IMF(2002b).EarlyWarningSystemModels:TheNextStepForward.In:GlobalFinancialStabilityReport. Washington,DC,InternationalMonetaryFund,March. IMF(2003).DebtSustainabilityinLowͲIncomeCountries:TowardsaForwardͲLookingStrategy.Prepared bythePolicyDevelopmentandReviewDepartment,May. InternationalDevelopmentAssociationandInternationalMonetaryFund(2005).OperationalFramework forDebtSustainabilityAssessmentsinLowͲIncomeCountries:FurtherConsideration(IDA/R2005Ͳ 0056). KaminskyG,LizondoSandRienhartC(1998).LeadingindicatorsofCurrencyCrises.IMFStaffPapers,47, 0:62–98. RadeletSandSachsJ(1998).TheOnsetoftheEastAsianFinancialCrisis.Mimeo,February. Roubini N (2001). Debt Sustainability: How to Assess Whether a Country is Insolvent. New York, Stern SchoolofBusiness,NewYorkUniversity,20December. ThirwallAPandNureldinͲHussainM(1982).Thebalanceofpaymentsconstraint,capitalflowsandgrowth ratedifferencesbetweendevelopingcountries.OxfordEconomicPapers,November. 59 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis ANNEX 1. Debt,TradeandGrowth FromtheBalanceofPaymentsidentity: 1) Ph X EPf M i f ED EF 0 X arerealexports(orvolumeofexports) M arerealimports(orvolumeofimports) Ph isdomesticpriceindex Pf isforeignpriceindex D isexternaldebtexpressedinforeigncurrency F areexternalflows,includingnewdebtandnetFDI,expressedinforeigncurrency E isnominalexchangerate(domesticcurrencyperunitofforeigncurrency) if istheforeigninterestrate Weassumethattherearenochangesininternationalreserves. DividingallvariablesbynominalGDP, x m if 2) ED EF PhY PhY m where x = PhX PhY , F relatedsothat d Define PhY ,weget: 0 EPf Ph * M Y and for simplicity it is assumed that all external flows are debt dD dt ED f PhY and EF PhY Differentiatetheexpressionfor d : ( EdD DdE ) Ph Y ED ( dPh Y Ph dY ) dd dt ( Ph Y ) 2 EdD DdE ED(dPhY Ph dY ) PhY ( PhY ) 2 EdD DdE EDdPh 1 EDdY 1 PhY Ph PhY Y PhY EdD DdE EDp h EDg PhY PhY PhY 60 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment ED>dD / D dE / E p h g @ PhY Wecanrewritetheaboveexpressionas: dd dt d (e p h g ) ED F PhY D = d (e p h g ) f e rateofchangeofexchangerate p h rateofchangeofdomesticprices grealGDPgrowthrate(dY/Y) Finally,wereplace f withtheaboveexpressioninequation2: x m i f d (e p h g ) d dd dt or dd 3) dt 0 m x (i f e p h g ) d Further,wecanrewriteequation3as: dd dt where or pf m x i f d (e p f p h g p f ) d representstherateofchangeofforeignprices dd dt m x (i f p f ) d (ctot g ) d where ctot (= ph Ͳ pf Ͳ e) is the rate of change of thetermsoftrade. 2. ContributionofDebtandCapitalFlowstoGrowth First,thebalanceofpaymentsidentity: (D e D e ) E P * M P X i * Dte1 'FDI t ( Rt Rt 1 ) t 1 t t t t t 4) t Deisexpressedindomesticcurrency. De Forsimplicity,wewillassumethatallcapitalinflowsaredebtͲrelatedandsoincludedinto t ,thatthese inflowsareestimatedonanetbasis(i.e.afterallowingfori*DtͲ1),andthattheforeignexchangereserves areunchanged( 'Rt 'Dte Pt * X t 0 ).Then: Et * Pt* * M t 61 TheMechanicsofDebtSustainabilityAnalysis Takinglogsonbothsides: ln('Dte Pt * X t ) Differentiating: d ('Dte P * X ) 'Dte P * X ln( Pt* * Et * M t ) * dP dE dM * E M P 'D e P * X E * P* * M t t t t t t wecanrewritethisexpressionas: Since d ( P * X ) dP * X P * dX and {P*X/P**E*M}{dP/P+dX/X}+{ѐDet/P**E*M}{d(ѐDet)/ѐDet}=dP*/P*+dE/E+dM/M 'Dte P* X * * Replacing P * E * M by O and P * E * M by 1 O weget. § d ('D e ) · ¸ O §¨ dP dX ·¸ (1 O )¨ ¨ 'D e ¸ X ¹ © P ¹ © 5) dE dP * dM * E M P where O representstheinitialratioofexportstoimports. Substitutingtheexpressionforrealimports, dM / M \ (dP * / P * dE / E dP / P) SdY R / Y R andrealexports, dX / X K (dP / P dE / E dP * / P * ) H dY w / Y w , whereɻisthepriceelasticityofexports,ʗthepriceelasticityofimports,ʋtheelasticityofdemandfor imports,ɸtheelasticityofdemandforexports,YrtheGDPofthedebtorcountry,andYwforeignincome, andsolvingfordYr/Yr,weget: (1 OK \ )(dP/ P dE/ E dP* / P* ) (1 O)(d('De ) / 'De ) OH dYw / Y w S 6)dYr/Yr= OntheRHSofthisexpression,weseethatthebalanceͲofͲpaymentͲconstrainedgrowthrateofrealGDP dependson: * * therateofchangeoftermsoftrade (dP / P dE / E dP / P ) ; the combined effect of price elasticity of imports and export and relative price changes/changes in the * * termsoftrade (K \ )(dP / P dE / E dP / P ) ; the combined effect of rate of change of debtͲrelated foreign capital inflows and the trade deficit as a e e proportionofimports,(1Ͳʄ) d ('D ) / 'D ; thecombinedeffectofgrowthrateoftheratioofexportstoimports,theelasticityofdemandforexports, andforeignincome,ʄɸYw. 62 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERIV ANANALYTICALFRAMEWORKFORDEBT SUSTAINABILITYANDDEVELOPMENT ValpyFitzGerald (UniversityofOxford) A. Introduction 1. ExternalDebtandDevelopment This paper is intended to contribute to the further development of debt sustainability analysis for developing countries, within a framework that does not take the narrow view of debt sustainability as beingreachedsolelybyreducingexcessivecurrentlevelsofdebt.Ratheritviewsdebtsustainability,asan integralpartofasuccessfuldevelopmentstrategy,closelylinkedtoexportgrowth. There are at least three good reasons for developing country Governments to borrow abroad: (i) the economicreturnonpublicinvestmentindevelopingcountriesissuperiortothecostofborrowedcapital so that growth can be accelerated by prudent use of debt without excessively reducing current consumptionlevels;(ii)domesticfirms(particularlysmallandmediumenterprises)cannoteasilyborrow abroadandtermsarebetterforsovereignborrowerssothatitisefficientfortheGovernmenttousedebt foronͲlendingtoproductivesectors,particularlyexports;and(iii)theexternalitiesfrompublicinvestment ininfrastructure,health,education,etc.arelargeandpositivebutcannotgenerallybecapturedinreturns toforeigndirectinvestors. ForeignprivateinvestorscanbenefitfrominvestingindevelopingͲcountrysovereigndebtastheratesof return are higher than those obtainable on OECD government bonds, while the risk due to possible defaultcanbemitigatedbyappropriatediversificationofportfolios.However,financefromthissourceis available only for “emerging markets” – that is middleͲincome countries and a few large lowͲincome countries.MostlowͲincomecountries,ontheotherhand,donothaveaccesstoexternalprivatecapital except for foreign direct investment in natural resource sectors owing to problems associated with contractenforcement,informationasymmetry,andeconomic externalities.Inconsequencebilateralaid 63 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment donors and multilateral development banks act as financial intermediaries to provide loans on suitable termsonthebasisoftheirownabilitytoraisefundsinglobalcapitalmarkets. External debt has to be repaid in foreign exchange, so that trade plays a critical role. The relationship between external borrowing and trade is the key to a successful external debt strategy, as external indebtedness cannot be sustainable in the long run if the development strategy does not lead to an increaseinforeignexchangeearningsaboveimportrequirementssufficienttorepaythedebt.Thepoint ofdepartureofasustainabledebtstrategyis,therefore,aclearvisionbytheGovernmentofthecountry’s developmenttrajectoryanditsrelationtoitstradepotential. 2. TheCurrentEmpiricalContextforExternalDebtAnalysis It is essential to take into account the situation of different types of debtor countries (middleͲincome countries, lowͲincome countries, HIPCs, etc.) both because lenders are diverse (with distinct objectives andleverages)andbecausecountries’economicstructuresandvulnerabilitytoexogenousshocksdiffer. InthissubͲsectionwetakeabrieflookataggregatedataorganizedbyregionalgroups,incomelevels,and debt difficulties. This disguises many problems at the country level but gives a good idea of the overall issues. AsTableIV.1.indicates,thedebtburdeninrelationtoexportsisthreetimeshigherinlowͲincomethanin middleͲincomecountries.HowevermiddleͲincomecountriesowethreeͲquartersofalldevelopingͲcountry debt.Thusthe“debtproblem”isanissueofintegrationintotheworldeconomyifconsideredfromthe point of view of a middleͲincome country, but an issue of economic development if viewed from the perspectiveofalowͲincomecountry. TableIV.1.ExternalDebtandExportsbyIncomeLevel,2003 Exports (US$bn) ExternalDebt Debt/Exports (US$bn) (Percent) 176 523 297 MiddleͲincomecountries 1813 1815 100 Totaldevelopingcountries 1999 2339 117 LowͲincomecountries Source:WorldBank(2005b). Thetotalvalueofexternaldebtanddebtservicevarieswidelybyregionandbydebtorstatus,atTable IV.2.indicates.By2003netexternalborrowingwasquitelowcomparedtooutstandingdebtinallthree regionsidentifiedhere,45butonlyinDevelopingAsiaarereservessufficientlylarge(particularlysincethe midͲ1990sfinancialcrises)tocoverexternaldebtliabilities.InLatinAmerica(andbyextensionin“UDC” countries with recent debt difficulties) reserves barely cover debt service, leading to serious liquidity difficulties.InAfrica(andbyextensiontheHIPCgroup)reservesareatleastfourtimesdebtservicebut this has no practical significance because the debt is not traded. It is worth noting that if the overseas assets of the private sector were recorded and entered here, the net asset position of developing countries would be positive – and in this sense there is no “developing country debt issue” as such but ratheraserioussovereigndebtproblem. 45 TheCISandEasternEuropewereinfactthemainnetborrowersin2003. 64 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableIV.2.ExternalDebtofDevelopingCountriesbyRegionandDebtorStatus,2003(US$bn) Total Externaldebt OfficialReserves Debtservice Netexternalborrowing Exceptionalfinancing 2724.3 1412.6 437.8 91.5 32.4 of which Developing Asia 695.7 670.1 105.5 18.7 6.2 Latin America and Caribbean 759.0 196.2 174.3 0.6 14.4 Africa UDC HIPC 278.0 90.9 25.2 3.8 6.7 804.2 168.7 112.3 3.8 13.0 145.8 19.7 3.6 2.0 5.1 Source:IMF(May2005). Notes:“UDC”areUnsustainableDebtCountries(author’sdefinition)witharrearsand/orreschedulingduring1997Ͳ2001; HIPCare“highlyindebtedpoorcountries”underconsiderationbytheWorldBankandIMFfordebtcancellation; “debt service” is actual payments of interest on total debt plus amortization payments on longͲterm debt, incorporating exceptional financing; “exceptional financing” is arrears on debt service, rescheduling of debt serviceanddebtforgiveness. Theexternaldebtstructurevariesintwodimensions–maturityandcreditor.AstableIV.3.shows,most debtis“longͲterm”(thatiswithamaturityofoneyearormore)andhasanaveragematurityoftheorder oftenyears.AfricaandtheHIPCcountriesrelymostlyonofficialcreditors,whileAsiaandLatinAmerica rely more on private lenders. Within this latter category bonds predominate over bank credit, although thedifferenceisnotgreatinpracticefromthepointofviewoftheborrower. TableIV.3.StructureofExternalDebt,byMaturityandCreditor,2003(US$bn) ShortͲterm LongͲterm Totaldebt Officialcreditors Privatecreditors: bankcredit bonds Total 377.9 2344.9 2724.3 1021.9 722.1 960.0 of Developing which Asia 106.3 589.4 695.7 292.6 161.9 241.3 LatinAmerica andCaribbean 89.7 669.3 759.0 204.5 185.8 368.7 Africa UDC HIPC 19.4 34.8 3.3 258.6 769.4 142.5 278.0 804.2 145.8 213.1 491.3 132.0 42.5 183.2 10.8 22.4 129.7 3.0 Source:IMF(May2005). Notes:ForUDCseenotestotableIV.2. In relation to exports it is clear from Table IV.4. that the major “debt overhang” difficulties are encounteredinLatinAmericaandAfrica,wheremostoftheUDCandHIPCaretobefound.Inrelationto debtserviceLatinAmerica(andbyextensiontheUDCs)hasthemostseriousproblem.Africancountries (andthustheHIPC) benefitfromsofter,aidͲrelateddebtterms –and,indeed,donotfullyservice their debt.ThedifferencesininterestratespaidreflectthedifferencesbetweenmiddleͲincomecountrieswith accesstoprivatelendingandlowͲincomecountrieswhichrelyonofficiallenders,ontheonehand,and thehigherdefaultriskinLatinAmericacomparedtoAsia,ontheother. 65 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableIV.4.IndicatorsofDebtinRelationtoTrade,2003 of which: Total Percentofexports ExternalDebt InterestPayments Amortization Percentofdebt Interest Amortization 111.3 4.3 13.6 3.9 12.2 Latin America and Caribbean Developing Asia 73.2 2.6 8.5 3.6 11.6 199.3 10.8 34.9 5.4 17.5 Africa UDC HIPC 144.6 4.1 9.0 2.8 6.2 208.9 6.8 22.3 3.3 10.7 321.1 3.6 6.6 1.1 2.1 Source:IMF(May2005). 3. CoverageofthePaper This paper focuses on external debt. It does not examine domestic debt, even though with currency convertibilitypublicdebtdenominatedindomesticcurrencycanrepresentacontingentclaimonforeign exchangereserves–albeitatanundefinedexchangerate.Nordoesthispaperaddressdebtcrisesassuch and the subsequent renegotiations and restructurings. None the less, many of the analytical results for prudentdebtmanagementdiscussedbelowarerelevanttodebtsustainabilityatthedomesticaswellas theexternallevelbecauselattersustainabilitycannotbesensiblyplannedforeitherexceptinthecontext ofasustainabledebttrajectory. The structure of the paper is as follows. Section B provides the appropriate national accounting framework for debt analysis, and then sets out the traditional “gap models” (savings, trade and fiscal) along with a summary of the modern critique of this approach. Section C outlines the modern intertemporalapproachtodebtanalysis,derivestheoptimaldebtlevelinrelationtooutputandexports foranopen developingeconomy,andproposestwo“goldenrules”forexternaldebtmanagement. The macroeconomic consequences of external debt are addressed in Section D, which starts with the key impact on real exchange rates and follows this with the framework for analysing the effects on fiscal balancesandincomedistribution.SectionEexplainshowcreditrationinginglobalcapitalmarketsmeans thatdebtlevelsarenotdeterminedbyborrowers,andgoesontoanalysetheimpactofinterestͲrateand trade shocks under these circumstances. Finally, Section F derives policy conclusions for both domestic Governmentsandtheinternationalcommunity. B. Debtandthe“FinanceGap”Model 1. NationalAccountingsandDebt Debtaccountingisquitecomplexbecausedebtflows–inflowsoffreshdebtcapitalandoutflowsofdebt service–enterintotheprocessofsavingsandinvestment,thebalanceofpayments(onbothcurrentand capital account) and the fiscal framework. In the savings and investment balance, net debt flows constitute“externalsaving”.Inthecurrentaccountofthebalanceofpaymentsinterestpaymentsondebt areanoutflowoffactorincome.Inthecapitalaccountnetdebtflowscreatechangesinthenetexternal assetposition.Inthefiscalaccountsgrossdebtinflowsareanexternalresource,whileamortizationand 66 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment interest payments are major expenditure items. Furthermore net debt flows in a particular year, in combinationwithinheriteddebt,determinedebtfornextyear,thusintroducingadynamicelementinto debtaccounting. Theseaccountingidentitiestellusnothingaboutthebehaviorofthevariouscomponents:inotherwords theyarenotamodel.However,theydoclarifythecomplexrelationshipbetweendebtandthedomestic economy,andalsounderlinethefactthatthecomponentsmustbereconciledͲinotherwords,“addup”. Weusethefollowingnomenclature: Yaggregateoutput(i.e.GDP) Caggregateconsumption Xexportsofgoodsandservices M importsofgoodsandservices Sdomesticsaving I investment(grossfixedcapitalformation) i interestrateonexternaldebt ɷamortizationrateonexternaldebt Dexternaldebt Ggovernmentexpenditure Tgovernmentrevenue Rofficialforeignexchangereserves WestartwiththeaggregatedemandͲsupplybalance Y M { C I X [B.1] which,whenthesavingsͲinvestmentidentityisinserted,yieldsthe“accumulationbalance” [B.2] Thebalanceofpaymentsoncurrentaccountincludesnotonlyexportsandimportsofgoodsandservices, but also factor income (income from capital and workers’ remittances). To simplify the exposition we include here only the interest payments on (public) external debt at this stage. Note that, if these are includedin[B.2],thenthedefinitionofsavings(S)isnationalsavingsandthatofoutput(Y)isGNP. Thecurrentaccount(CAB)andthecapitalaccount(KAB)areoppositeandequal.Thus CAB { X M iD [B.3] andthecapitalaccountis KAB { 'D 'R [B.4] sothat CAB KAB { 0 [B.5] 67 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Note that private capital flows (and the corresponding factor payments) can be inserted into this accounting framework very simply. Foreign private assets (A) include portfolio holdings overseas (sometimes misleadingly called “capital flight”) and FDI abroad by domestic companies. Foreign private liabilities(L)includebothforeignborrowingbydomesticfirmsandinwardFDI.Thefullcapitalaccountcan thusbewritten46 KAB { 'D 'L {'R 'A} [B.4a] However,intherestofthispaperweshallassumethattheGovernmentistheonlyexternaldebtor–not leastbecausethe“externaldebt”statisticsreflectpublicsectorandpubliclyguaranteedexternaldebt. Inthisframeworkweassumethatthefiscalbalanceisclosedonlybyforeignborrowing–thusexcluding monetaryissue(“seignorage”)anddomesticborrowingfromconsideration: T 'D { G iD [B.6] Last,butfarfromleast,wehavethelawofmotionfortheexternaldebtitself(D)intermsofitsprevious periodvalue(DͲ1),andnewborrowing(ȴD)andthedepreciationrate(ɷ)inthefollowingtwoalternative forms: D { D1 GD1 'D 'D { D D1 GD1 [B.7] 2. “FinancingGap”ModelsofDebtandGrowth In the context of work on development strategies from the 1960s through the 1980s “financing gap” modelsprovidedthebasicanalyticalframeworkforbothlendersandborrowers.47Inthesemodels,48the objectiveoftheplanneristomaximizetherateofoutputgrowth(y)subjecttotheconstraintsimposedby domestic savings (i.e. the capacity to invest), the external sector (i.e. the capacity to import) or fiscal balances(i.e.thecapacitytospend). The savings constraint exists because available funds are determined by the domestic economy’s propensitytosave(s)andtheinflowofexternalfinance(F),whichinturndeterminesthemaximumlevel ofinvestment(I)thatcanbeundertakenandthustherateofgrowth(y). The external constraint exists because the level of imports (M) cannot exceed the foreign exchange available from exports (X) and capital inflows (F). Exports are assumed fixed in the short term, due to capacityconstraintsand/orlimitedexternalmarkets.Theavailabilityofimportsdeterminesthemaximum levelofoutput(Y)foragivenimportpropensity(m). The fiscal constraint exists because growth depends on public investment (either because it constitutes the bulk of investment, as in poor countries, or because it is essential in order to promote private investment,asinmiddleͲincomecountries).Publicinvestmentisassumedtobeaconstantproportion(p) oftotalinvestment.Publicinvestment,andthusgrowth,isconstrainedbybudgetarybalance(Z). 46 AcompletecurrentͲaccountidentitywouldincludeprivateinflowsandoutflowsoffactorincome Avramovicandothers(1964)isagoodsurveyofthetraditionalmethodologyforanalysingtherelationshipbetweendebtand growth. 48 Thereisalargeliteratureonthesemodels,whichoriginateswiththeHarrodͲDomargrowthmodelofthesavingsconstraint, andcontinueswithChenery&Strout(1955),whomodeledtheexternalconstraint.Thismodelwasthenextendedtoincludealso thefiscalconstraint.Goodformalexpositionsofallthree‘gapmodels’aregivenbyBacha(1990)andTaylor(1994). 47 68 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Inconsequenceoftheseassumptionsexternalfinance(F)actsasasourceof“externalsaving”,tofillthe gapbetweendomesticsavingsandtotalinvestment,actingasaformof“importsupport”andasasource offiscalrevenue.ThroughthesechannelsFaffectsboththelevelofinvestmentandtherateofgrowthof GDP.Thismodelstillinformsmostoftheempiricalpolicydebateaboutaid,debtandforeigninvestment. Theplanningproblemisthustomaximizeywhere Yt = k Kt K t = K t -1 + I t S t = s Y t (t g )Yt M t = m1 Y t + m2 I t Dt Dt 1 (i G ) Dt 1 Ft Zt ( g t )Yt pI t [B.9] [B.8] subjecttothethreeconstraints I t d St + F t M t d X t + Ft Z t d Ft (wheretistaxrevenueandggovernmentexpenditureasaproportionGDP). Theoutcomedependsonwhichofthethreeconstraintsactuallybindsatanyonepointintime,whichis anempiricalissue. ThesavingsͲconstrainedmaximumgrowthrate( y s* y s* )canbederivedas: Fº ª k « s (t g ) » Y ¼ [B.10] ¬ The main concern of aidͲrelated policy modeling in most developing countries is the externallyͲ constrainedmaximumrateofgrowth( y e* = y e* ),whichcanbederivedas: k ªX F º m1 » « Y ¼ [B.11] m2 ¬ Finally,thefiscallyconstrainedrateofgrowth( y *f = y *f )canbederivedas k ªF º (t g ) » « p ¬Y ¼ [B.12] Allthreegrowthratesareofcourseincreaseinresponsetonetdebtinflows(i.e. wy / wF ! 0 ),butwith differentderivatives.Whichbindsdependsonthecharacteroftheeconomy.Generallyitisreasonableto assumethatinthepooresteconomiesthesavingsconstraintisbinding,andthatexternalandfinallyfiscal 69 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment become binding as economic development advances. The effect of net debt flows is likely to be progressivelygreaterineachofthesethreestagesbecausegenerally p m2 1 wy *f wF ! wy e* wy s* ! wF wF [B.13] 3. TheLimitationsof“FinancingGap”Models The “financing gap” model continues to form the basis for the trade, aid and growth linkages in the mediumͲtermmacroeconomicprogrammingmodelusedbytheWorldBank:theRevisedMacroeconomic StandardModel(RMSM).49Italsoinformstheshorttermmonetaryprogrammingframeworkusedbythe IMF.50Thesetwomodelsstillformtheessentialanalyticalunderpinningforthemissionreportsofthetwo BrettonWoodsinstitutionsonstabilizationandadjustmentprograms.51TheUNDPmakesestimatesofthe externalfinancingrequirementsofpoorcountriesonasimilarbasiswhenpreparingformeetingsofdonor consortia. However,thelastdecadehaswitnessedgrowingawarenessofthelimitationsofthesemodels,whichno longercorrespondeithertomodernmacroeconomictheoryortomacroeconomicpolicypracticeinopen economies. Indeed from a neoclassical viewpoint this analytical tradition is regarded as invalidating the proposals from the Bank and the Fund on additional lending and debt forgiveness.52However, their persistenceisdoubtlessdueinlargeparttotheiranalyticalsimplicityandthefactthattheparameterscan beestimatedeasilyandquicklyfromavailablemacroeconomicdataindevelopingcountries. Withoutgoingsofarastoreject“financinggap”models,itispossibletoidentifyfourareasofweakness whichneedtoberemediedinordertoproduceasounderconceptualframeworkandanalyticalmodelfor quantifyingdebtsustainability.Theseare: x First,thecoefficientsinthebehavioralequations(particularlytheconstraints)areassumedtobe stable and exogenous, rather than endogenously determined. In the case of savings, empirical evidence and Keynesian theory suggest that domestic saving (and thus consumption) in fact adjuststotheleveloffixedinvestmentandforeigninflowsofcapital.53Again,thefiscalbalance canalwaysbeadjustedbyvaryinggovernmentexpenditure. x Second,intheexternalbalanceoftrade,exportsareassumedtobegivenandimportstodepend onlyonthelevelofeconomicactivity.Thisignorestheeffectoftherealexchangerateonboth import and export volumes, and thus the possibility of adjusting to foreign exchange shortages without having to reduce growth.54It also underplays the role of exchange rates in determining thefiscalbalance. x Third,“financinggap”modelsassumethatextraexternalfinancealwayscontributestogrowth,by simply and directly adding to savings, import capacity or fiscal resources and thus allowing investment–andthusgrowth–torise.However,itisestablishedthatexternalresourcesoftenin 49 SeetheAddison(1989)andhttp://www.worldbank.org/data/rmsm/index.htmforanupdatedversionofthispaperplusother RMSMdocuments. 50 See IMF (1987), which in turn derives from Polack (1957). See also Baquir and others (2003) for the growth linkages in IMF models. 51 See Aghenor and Montiel (2003) for a recent survey, and Khan and others (1990) for a formal statement of the relationship betweenthetwomodels. 52 SeeEasterly(1999). 53 SeeFitzGerald(2003a). 54 SeeDornbusch&Helmers(1988). 70 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment practiceleadtoincreasedconsumption.55Moreovertheinvestmentundertakenmaynotleadto increasedexportsandthusdebtͲrepaymentcapacity. x Fourth,andmostseriouslyfromananalyticalviewpoint,the“financinggap”modeldoesnotallow for intertemporal optimization by economic agents: that is, the fact that households, firms and Governmentstakeinvestment,savingandborrowingdecisionslookingforwardovermanyyears. Theassumptionofintertemporaloptimizationisthebasisofmodernmacroeconomicsingeneral and for small open economies in particular; and allows resource allocation behavior to be endogenized.56 C. SustainableDebtLevels 1. TheOptimalDebtLevel,ExportCapacityandIntertemporalMaximization The contemporary approach to debt sustainability starts from the same foundation as the modern macroeconomictheoryofopeneconomies,whereapparentbalanceofpaymentsdisequilibriaintheshort run can be seen as part of an intertemporal equilibrium based upon expectations by economic actors about the future. The small open economy is composed of overlapping generations of households optimizingconsumptionandsavingovertimeandoffirmsmakinginvestmentdecisionsbasedonprofit maximization.57Currentaccountsurpluses(ordeficits)generatenetasset(orliability)positionswiththe restoftheworld,whichinturnaffectthefuturebehavioroffirmsandhouseholds. Ifthereisfreeaccesstointernationalfinancialmarketsatagiveninterestrate(i)andnoissuessuchas debtdefault,thenthecountryobeystheFisherianmaximandseparatesthedecisiontoinvestfromthe decisiontoconsume.58Focusinghereonthedecisiontoinvest,firmschoosetheirinvestmentstrategyso as to maximize the wealth of their shareholders when measured at world interest rates. The intertemporalequilibriumstrategy59amountstoselectinganinvestmentrate(k*)thatisasolutionto f max ³ exp( it )(Qt J t )dt k Qt K t 0 Q( K t ) I t GK t k { I t / Qt [C.1] whereQisthelevelofnetoutput,Jthecostofinstallingnewcapital,Kthecapitalstockandɷtherateof depreciation. In order to find a tractable solution to this general problem, we have to specify the relevant functional forms.Westartoffbydefiningnationalincome(W)asoutputminusdebtinterestcosts,wheredebtalso playsaroleincapitalformation,suchthat 55 AtleastsinceGriffin(1970). SeeObstfeld&Rogoff(1995)andSen(1994). 57 Thisisnowastandardformulation:seeforinstanceObstfeld&Rogoff(1995). 58 Thesavingsratedependsonthesocialratediscountfactorandtheintertemporalelasticityofsubstitutionofconsumption,on theonehand,andthe(world)interestrate,ontheother.SeeSen(1994). 59 SeeCohen(1994)forthederivation. 56 71 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment W Y iD W ' ( D) ! 0 W ' ' ( D ) 0 [C.2] inorderthatamaximumshouldexist.60Thisformulationisalsoconvenientbecausethetwoconstraints reflectdecliningabsorptioncapacityanddebtoverhangeffectsrespectively.Undertheseconditions,the optimaldebtlevelwillbedefinedbytheconditionformaximizingWwithrespecttoD: wW wD wY wi (i D ) wD wD 0 [C.3] Inotherwords,debtshouldbecontracteduptothepointwherethemarginaladditiontooutputequals themarginaladditiontointerestcosts.Ceterisparibus,thehighertheinterestrate,thelowertheresulting optimaldebtlevel;andthelargerthepositiveimpactofthatdebtonoutput,thehighertheoptimaldebt level. Tofindtheoptimaldebtlevel,westartwithastandard61endogenousͲgrowthproductionfunctionofthe form Y aK [C.4] Leavingasidethelasttermin[C.3]andthusassumingthattheinterestrateisunaffectedbythedebtlevel, wehavethefollowingmaximizationcondition: wW wD wK wD wY i wD i a wY wK i wK wD 0 [C.5] Thekeyissueisthusshowntobetheeffectofdebtoninvestment.Weshallexaminetheparticularcase where the domestically funded capital (K1) is already installed, there is no previous debt, and the authoritiescontemplatemovinginoneperiodtotheoptimaldebtlevel,byprovidingextracapitalstock (K2)fundedbyexternaldebt K K1 K 2 [C.6] Externaldebt(D)isthencontracted.Afixedproportion(ʄ)ofthisisusedtofundtheinstallationofnew productivecapital(directlyasinruralinfrastructure,orindirectlyasloanstoexporters),whiletherestis allocatedtootheractivitiessuchassocialinvestments(healthetc),coverageofcurrentͲaccountdeficits, ornonͲeconomicinfrastructure.Thecostofthisproductivepublicinvestment(J)isaquadraticfunctionof theinvestmentrate:62 60 Otherwisetheoptimaldebtlevelwouldbeinfinite,ofcourse. SeeRebelo(1991)forthebasisofthe‘AK’modelusedhere,andAghion&Howitt(1999)foracomprehensivesurveyofmodern endogenousgrowththeory. 62 SeeHeijdraandvanderPloeg(2002:40)andalsoCohen(1994:490). 61 72 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment D J O § I K2 · ¸ K 2 ¨¨1 2 K1 ¸¹ © [C.7] WithI>I J Sowecannowspecifytheobjectivefunction[C.2]as W a ( K1 K 2 ) § I K2 · ¸ K 2 ¨¨1 O © 2 K1 ¸¹ [C.8] i anddifferentiatingwithrespecttoK2yieldstheoptimalsolutionintermsoftheratio(ɶ)betweendebtͲ fundedcapitaland“domesticallyfunded”capital: wW wK 2 Kˆ 2 K1 a K · i § ¨¨1 I 2 ¸¸ K1 ¹ O© 1 § aO · 1¸ ¨ I© i ¹ 0 J [C.9] Notethattheoptimalcapitalstructurecoefficient(ɶ)canbenegative–whichwouldimplyaccumulation offoreignassetsinsteadofborrowingabroad. WefindtheoptimaldebtͲtoͲoutputratio(ɽ),bysubstituting[C.9]into[C.7]and[C.4]: Dˆ Yˆ T Kˆ 2 § Kˆ · J ¨1 I 2 ¸ K1 1 JI ¨ ¸ K1 ¹ O © O a ( K1 Kˆ 2 ) aK1 (1 J ) Dˆ Yˆ J (1 JI ) aO (1 J ) [C.10] Clearlyɽisincreasinginɶ,andthusby[C.9]theoptimaldebtͲoutputratiowillbeloweredbyanincrease intheinterestrate(i)(asweshouldexpect),butwillbeloweredbyanincreaseintheproportionofdebt fundsallocatedtoproductiveinvestment(ʄ)orintheoverallproductivityofcapital(a).Thisresultcanbe generalizedtoasteadyͲstategrowthsituationbecauseinsuchasituationY/Kisconstant(andthusboth components of capital grow at the output growth rate), and thus D/Y must be constant. If the optimal debtlevel(ɽ)ishigher,thendebtcanbesafelyraised. Overall capital productivity requires some further comment in the context of this study. We assume a simplifiedformoftheexternallyconstrainedeconomydiscussedintheprevioussectionsuchthat: M mY MdX X DEK [C.11] 73 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment whereexportsareafunctionoftheproportion(ɴ)ofthecapitalstocklocatedintheexportsectorwith knownproductivity(ɲ).Ifitisassumedthatthesecondconstraintof[C.11],i.e.thatM=X,substitutionof thefirstexpressionof[C.11]into[C.4]andtheresultintothethirdexpressionof[C.11]gives a Kˆ 2 K1 DE m 1 § DE O · 1¸ ¨ I© m i ¹ J [C.9a] Inotherwords,theoptimaldebtlevelriseswiththeproportionɴofdebtͲfundedcapitalstockallocatedto theexportsector.However,itfallswithanincreaseininterestratesortheimportcoefficient.Toputthis anotherway:longͲrundebtsolvency–andthustheavoidanceofdebtcrisesarisingfromtradeorcapital marketshocks–requirestheallocationofahigherproportionofthefundsraisednotonlytoproductive investmentbutalsotoinvestmentintheexportsector. Finally,wecanalsodefinetheoptimaldebtserviceratio(ʘ)fromthisresult,where Z (i G ) Dˆ Xˆ [C.12] bysubstituting[C.10]and[C.11]into[C.12]toyield: Z (i G ) Dˆ Yˆ Yˆ Xˆ (i G )T a DE [C.13] The optimal debt service ratio (ʘ) will decrease with a higher interest rate (i) because its negative influenceontheoptimaldebtͲoutputratio(ɽ)outweighsthatoftheexplicititermin[C.13]. 2. The“GoldenRules”forDebtSustainability The “law of motion” for external debt from the previous section (equation [B.7]) can be expressed in termsoftheprimary63currentaccountbalance(P)ontheassumptionthatthisdebtistheonlyformof externalfinance: Dt (1 i ) Dt 1 Pt 1 [C.14] whichthroughrepeatedsubstitutionyields Dt (1 i ) t t 1 Pt ¦ (1 i) t t 0 +D0 [C.15]. Whenngoestoinfinity,thepresentvalueofdebt(i.e.thelefthandsideoftheequation)goestozeroand weretrievetheintertemporalbalanceofpaymentsconstraint 63 Thatis,excludinginterestpayments. 74 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment f D0 Pt ¦ (1 i ) t t 0 [C.16] Inotherwords,alldebtmusteventuallybepaidback. However, in practice, developing country financial authorities and debt managers have to work on a shortertimescaleandwithouttheluxuryofsearchingforoptimalsolutions.Theceilingon“prudent”debt is conventionally expressed as a share of output or as a ratio of debt service to exports, the former reflectinglongerͲtermsolvencyconsiderationsandthelattershorterͲtermliquidityones. Oncetheprudentialceiling(d)onthedebtoutputratiohasbeenreached,debtmanagementstrategyis logicallynottoexceedit.Thusthe“goldenrule”isthat Dt Dt 1 d Yt Yt 1 d [C.17] Foragivenrateofoutputgrowth(y)andexpressingtheprimarydeficitasaratio(p)ofoutputwehave (1 i ) Dt 1 Pt (1 y )Yt 1 dt Dt Yt dt 1 i dp 1 y (1 i ) Dt 1 Pt (1 y )Yt 1 Yt [C.18] sothatthe“goldenrule”forthedebtͲoutputratiois § 1 i · p t d ¨¨ 1¸¸ | (i y )d ©1 y ¹ [C.19] In other words, a primary deficit (p<0) can only be safely incurred if the growth rate is higher than the interestrate(y>i). Ifweexpresstheruleintermsofthecurrentaccountbalanceproper,asaproportion(c)ofoutputthen thegoldenrulebecomes c p id c t yd [C.20] In other words, the maximum current account deficit as a proportion of GDP is the rate of growth multipliedbytheprudentdebtͲGDPratio. We can now turn to the second “golden rule” related to the ratio of debt service to exports. The derivationisverysimilartothatforthefirstrule,butexpressedintermsofthesecondceiling(ʍ): Oncetheprudentialceiling(d)ondebtinrelationtooutputratiohasbeenreached,thenextrequirement of debtͲmanagement strategy is that service payments on the resulting Dt in relation to exports should notexceedʍ.Thusthe“goldenrule”isthat 75 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment (i G ) Dt (i G ) Dt 1 d Xt X t 1 V [C.21] Foragivenrateofexportgrowth(x)andexpressingtheprimarydeficitasaratio(p’)ofexportswehave (i G ) Dt Xt Vt (i G ){(1 i ) Dt 1 Pt } (1 x) X t 1 1 i (i G ) Dt 1 (i G ) Pt 1 x X t 1 Xt 1 i V (i G ) p 1 x Vt sothatthe“goldenrule”forthedebtserviceratiois pc t [C.22] V § 1 i · ix V 1¸ | ¨ i G ©1 x ¹ i G [C.23] Inotherwords,andmoregenerallythataprimarydeficit(p’<0)canonlybesafelyincurrediftheexport growthrateishigherthantheinterestrate(x>i).IfweexpressthesecondruleintermsofthecurrentͲ accountbalanceproper,asaproportion(c’)ofexports cc p c iV x V cc t i G [C.24] 3. ConvergenceandExpectations PolicymakerswithresponsibilityfordebtattempttoadoptatleastamediumͲtermview,andwhentheir debtlevelsareabovetheprudentlimits,thena“convergence”strategymustbeadoptedinordertoreach theselimitswithinareasonablenumberofyears.Supposethatwewishtoreachtotheprudentiallimit(d) of the debtͲGDP level over a number of years from the present level (d’) by reducing the debt by a proportionueachyearovernyears,then u § dc d · ¨ ¸ © dc ¹ 1/ n [C.25]. ThefirstgoldenruleisthenreͲexpressedas: ~ p t (i u y ) d ~ c t (u y )d [C.26] Whethernewdebtissustainabledepends,therefore,onexpectationsaboutthefuturegrowthofoutput andofthedeterminantsofthebalanceoftradeandofthecurrentaccount,namelyexportgrowthand future interest rates and terms of trade. As we have seen, the debt level itself will affect growth in an optimalsolutionsothattheusetowhichthedebtistobeput,andthusfutureproductivity,arealsopart of the solution. Debtors and creditors should have agreed on these forecasts before signing a debt 76 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment contract.Forinstance,ifweexpecttherateofchangeofthetermsoftrade(h)tohaveaprojectedvalue inthefuture,thenthisisdistinguishedfromexportvolumegrowth( x )sothat[C.24]isrewrittenas cc t hx V i G [C.24a] For a debt contract to be agreed upon by debtor and creditor, both must agree on projections of key parameters; or if they disagree, at least the overall outcome must be anticipated as profitable to both sides..Butasexemplifiedbythedebtcrisesoftheearly1980sandofthemiddle1990sandbythepresent plightoftheHIPCs,eventsdonotalwaysturnoutasexpected.Expectationsonbothsidesarethuscrucial tothelending/borrowingdecision–therecanbeno“overͲborrowing”without“overͲlending”. D. FiscalConsequencesofExternalDebt Analytical frameworks such as those developed in sections B and C can be used explore the effects of policy towards external debt. One important issue under this heading is the relation between debt and fiscalpolicy.Heretheanalysisstartsfromanadjustedversionofequation(B.6)inwhichtaxrevenueand foreignfinancingconstrainfeasiblelevelsofgovernmentexpenditureandservicespayments(interestand amortization)onexternaldebtasfollows: G (i G ) D d T F c [D.9] Thusanincreasedgrossdebtflow(Fʚ)allowsafiscalexpansion(i.e.Gtorise).However,accumulateddebt itselfgenerateslargebudgetaryitemswhichinsomecasesbecomethelargestsingleitemofgovernment expenditure,crowdingoutotherexpenditurecategories.64 Thisconstraintcanbeelaboratedandsimplifiedtotakeaccountofadditionalassumptions: x x x x x SinceexternaldebtisdenominatedinforeigncurrencyandtherestoftheGovernment’sbudget indomesticcurrency,thedebttermismultipliedbytherealexchangerate(e=(Epf/)/pd); Debtamortizationflowsarenettedout:, A strict budgetary rule is observed that only allows a maximum fiscal deficit (q) in domestic currencytobefinancedfromseignorageand/ordomesticborrowing; TheprudentdebtͲoutputratio(d)ismaintained; Taxrevenueisagivenshare(t)ofnationalincome (D.9)isthenrewrittenas: G ieD d (t q )Y de'Y [D.10] Diving through by Y and rearranging, we then obtain the constraint on the share (g) of government expenditureinnationalincomeintermsofthefamiliardebtparameters(d,i)andtherateofgrowth(y)of output: g d (W q ) e( y i )d [D.11] Absent a serious tax reform (ȴʏ) or a more relaxed monetary stance (ȴq), the governmentͲexpenditure share (g) in national income is highly dependent on the debt parameters, on the one hand, and the 64 Foralldevelopingcountriesin2003,theaverageratioofexternaldebtservicetoGDPwas6percent.Theaverageratiooftax revenuetoGDP(t)was15percentandofpublichealthexpendituretoGDPwas3percent(WorldBank,2005a). 77 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment growth rate (y) and the real exchange rate (e), on the other, Ͳ both of which variables are themselves stronglyaffectedbythedebtstrategy.Inparticular,anincreaseineconsequentupondevaluationwhen therateofoutputgrowthislow(i.e.y<i)–acommonoccurrenceduringdebtcrisesͲwillhaveastrongly negativeimpactonthefiscalconstraintandthusongovernmentexpenditure. This subordination of government expenditure as illustrated by the fiscal constraint [D.11] to debt managementhasatleastthreemajorconsequences: (a) It is difficult to give priority to increasing social provision in general (and poverty reduction in particular)byexpandingrealhealthandeducationexpenditurefasterthanpopulationgrowth; (b) ItisnotpossibletoengageinanactivecounterͲcyclicalfiscalpolicyinordertoreducetheimpact of exogenous shocks on investment and growth, for example, by expanding infrastructure expendituretomaintaincapacityutilization; (c) LongͲtermplanningofpublicexpenditureisrenderedmeaningless,withnegativeeffectsforthe efficiencyofpublicservices,infrastructureprovisionandtheutilizationofscarceadministrative skills. E. DebtVulnerabilityandExternalShocks 1. DeterminantsofDebtFlows Sofarwehavebeenworkingontheassumptionthatdevelopingcountriescanchoosethelevel(D)ofdebt thattheycontractatagiveninterestrate(i).Thisistheconventionalassumptionineconomicanalysisas well as in policy debates when reference is made to “overͲborrowing”. In fact, however, lenders determinethevolumeofchangesindebtandtheinterestrateisnotgiven.Internationaldebtflowsare subjecttoaformofcreditrationing. Official lending (that is by bilateral donors or multilateral organizations) is always determined by the lenderonitsowncriteria,althoughtheseshouldinprinciplesupportsustainabledevelopmentandthus coincidewiththoseoftheborrower.However,theborrowerdoesnotdecidethedebtlevel.Ratherthe overallvolumeofofficiallendingisdeterminedbytheinstitutionalstrategyofthelender.Withinthetotal regional and country allocations lending depends upon both the technical appreciation of development prospectsͲandthusthesustainabilityofdebtͲ;ontheonehand,andthegeopoliticalpressuresofdonor Governments,ontheother. Givenaceilingofofficiallendingfromdonorsinanyoneperiod,developingͲcountryGovernmentstendto contractdebtuptothislimit.Itisinthissensethat“creditrationing”existsforthiscategoryoflending.It is extremely rare for developing countries – particularly small lowͲincome countries without access to privatecapitalmarkets–toturndownofficiallendingproposals.Theinterestrateandmaturityofofficial debtisalsosetbythelender,usuallyonasubsidizedbasis.Eligibilityisdecidedbythedonor. IninternationaldebtmarketsforbothbondsandbankloanstothegreatmajorityofdevelopingͲcountry Governments (“sovereigns”) another form of credit rationing obtains. This reflects the influence of uncertainty in the loan market creates which causes adverse selection, as the two sides have different perceptions ofriskandlenders cannotdistinguish between borrowersastotheirabilitytorepayinthe future.ItalsoreflectsthelowertoleranceofriskonthepartofOECDinvestorsinforeignthanintheirown markets,asituationwhichleadstoaninefficientallocationoftheirportfoliosknownas“homebias”.65 65 SeeFitzGerald&Babilis(2005). 78 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Consider the initially upwardͲsloping supply schedule of bank loans or bond purchases in Figure IV.1. below.Thisshowsthereturnspread,r(theexcessoftheriskyovertherisklessrate,thelatterbeingthe rateofinterestongovernmentbonds,alongtheordinateandthevolumeoflendingalongtheabscissa. The competitive international banking market is made up of many nonͲcollusive bank lenders and borrowers. Banks are priceͲtakers in deposit markets but set lending rates (i.e. spreads) to maximize expectedreturns.Higherlendingrateshaveanadverseselectioneffectsonborrowersbyincreasingthe perceivedrisksoflending.Theseinturnthusincreaseactualdefaultriskowingtotheincreasedburdenof interestpaymentsandtheenhancedincentivetodefaultduetoriseswithdebtandinterestrates.Beyond a certain point the debt supply schedule will be backwardͲsloping. Banks’ unwillingness to differentiate betweendifferentriskreflectstheirimperfectinformationonfundamentals(e.g.defaultrisk)aswellas theirfearofcovariantriskbetweenborrowers(contagion). Thedemandschedule(Dd)infigureIV.1.fordebtisthebackwardͲslopingcurveforthesupplyofcapital. Competitivelendersmaximizetheirdebtholdingsatthepoint(Dd,r*):atthisprice(i.e.returnspread) the potential supply of capital or demand for debt assets from developing countries (Ds) is in excess of demand for capital or the supply of assets (Dd)– in other words, the willingness to borrow exceeds the willingnesstolend. D Dd ( r*) Ds ( r*) [E.1] The market interest rate in foreign currency (if) to emerging market borrowers is determined by two elements, the riskless world rate (iw) and the risk premium (r). The risk premium is the product of the perceived66probability of default (ʋ) and an appropriate of investors’ degree of risk aversion (A).67 PerceiveddefaultriskdependsuponindicatorsdiscussedinsectionC.BsuchasthedebtͲGDPratio(d)and thedebtserviceratio(ʍ).68 FigureIV.1.CreditRationinginGlobalDebtMarkets 66 Theperceptionisthatoflenderstypicallyinfluencedbycreditratingsagencies. Thus the risk premium is only equal to the underlying default risk if the financial market is strictly riskͲneutral and there is perfectinformation;sothatyieldspreadsshouldnotgenerallybeinterpretedasmeasuresof‘countryrisk’–seeCunninghamand others(2001). 68 Aswellascruderliquiditymeasuressuchasthe‘quickratio’mentionedinSectionF.1. 67 79 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Thuswehave: if iw r SA S S (d , V ) [E.2] r Clearly an increase in d or default risk (which is why the loan supply curve eventually becomesbackwardͲsloping)andthusnotonlyraisesinterestcostsbutalsoreducesloanavailability.Note that the risk premium (r) depends on forecasts of debt default probability, and thus on expectations of exportandoutputgrowth,ontheonehand,andontherisktoleranceofinvestors,ontheother. 2. CapitalͲMarketShocks Oneshockisanincreaseinratesofinterestinacountrywithamajorfinancialmarket.Thisshockaffects interestratespaidbydevelopingcountrysovereignborrowers(if)intwowaysasEquation[V.2]indicates: firstly,bysimplyraising)theriskfreerate(iw),and,secondly,byraisingtheriskpremium(r)owingtothe increaseinthedebtͲserviceratio(ʍ). However, another more commonly observed market shock results from shifts in the demand for emergingͲmarketdebtduetochangeswithindevelopedcountrymarkets–suchaschangesinregulations, fluctuationsinriskaversionamongstlendersandinvestors,orcontagionfromotherdebtors.Theselead to“horizontal”downwardshiftsintheassetdemandcurveinFigureIV.1. The macroeconomic and distributional consequences for emerging markets can be disproportionately large.69This results from a fundamental asymmetry in international capital markets: while capital flows arerelativelysmallinrelationtothehomeeconomiesoflendersandinvestors,theyaremuchlargerin relation to host markets. The effect of the shocks is exacerbated by hysteresis: 70 owing to the irreversibilityofinvestmentandwageͲpricestickiness,adownswingdoesnotleadtheeconomybackto whereitwasbeforetheupswing.FluctuationsintherealexchangerateassociatedwithshortͲtermcapital flowsalsoleadfirmstomisallocateinvestmentbetweenthetradedandnonͲtradedsectors,withnegative consequencesforgrowth.71 Another potentially serious negative effect of debt shocks on growth is not felt directly through the balanceofpaymentsbutratherthroughtheeffectoninvestoruncertaintyaboutfuturemacroeconomic conditions72andpolicychanges73whenthedebtlevelexceedstheprudentiallimit,apositioncommonly knownas“debtoverhang”.Butthisriskcanbereducedbygovernmentaction.EveniftheGovernment cannotcrediblypreͲcommittorepaydebt,investingingrowthbeforeborrowingcanmakeforeignlenders aswellasdomesticinvestorsmoreoptimisticaboutgrowthprospects. 3. GlobalTradeShocks Globaltradeshockscantakevariousformswhichinclude: 69 See FitzGerald (2001). Interestingly, this was the position taken by the IMF in the 1998 World Economic Outlook (‘Financial Crises:CharacteristicsandIndicatorsofVulnerability’).However,by2005theWorldEconomicOutlookhadbecomemuchmore sanguine,attributingmostofemergingͲmarketvolatilitytodomesticfundamentals. 70 A model of this process is set out in Chapter 6 of FitzGerald (2003). On the macroeconomic theory of hysterisis and pathͲ dependencyseeHeijdra&vanderPloeg(2002),Chapter2.2andAppendixA.6.4. 71 SeeFitzGerald&Perosino(1999). 72 SeeFitzGerald,Jansen&Vos(1994). 73 SeeRodrick(1991). 80 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment x x x Suddenmovementsinexportprices,particularlyforprimarycommodities,duetodemandshifts indevelopedcountriesorsupplychangesbyotherproducers; Unexpectedshiftsinimportprices,particularlythoseforessentialcommoditiessuchasoil;and Thelossofaccessforexporterstoparticulardevelopedcountrymarketsduetochangesintrade barriersordomestic(e.g.health)regulations. TheseshocksobviouslyhaveaneffectonthedebtserviceͲexportratiobychangingthedenominator:for example,asuddenfallinprimarycommoditypriceswillraisethisratio,eventhoughdebtserviceitselfhas not changed, and can render a previously sustainable debt unsustainable. SecondͲorder effects depend uponwhatpolicyresponsetheauthoritiestake.Insummarytheyhavefouroptions: x Incurringmoredebtinordertosustainimportlevelsandmaintainthelevelofeconomicactivity. Thisislikelytoappreciatetherealexchangerate(oratleastpreventitfromdepreciating)andto preventanincreaseinexports.TheresultisafurtherriseinthedebtͲserviceratiothroughlower exportsinadditiontothehigherdebt. x MaintainingthedebtlevelandallowingthecurrencytodepreciateinordertoimprovethecurrentͲ accountbalanceandstimulateexports.InthiscaseexportsdonotfallandthedebtͲserviceratio does not increase. However, owing to the increased burden of servicing the external debt in domesticcurrencythefiscalbalanceisworsenedwithconsequentcutsinsocialexpenditurecuts. Moreovertheincomedistributionworsenswithdecliningrealwagesandinflation. x Maintaining the debt level and stabilizing the real exchange rate. This is likely to be associated with cutting the level of economic activity in order to depress imports, prevent inflation and balancethecurrentaccount. x Any one of the above policies combined with a reallocation of debt funds to exports with good marketssoastomaintainexportgrowthandthusreducethedebtͲserviceratio. Which policy option is adopted determines the impact of a trade shock on debt sustainability. The domestic policy choice between exchangeͲ rate shifts and demand management depends on local economic structures and political processes, as well as pressures from creditors or international institutions. The “golden rule” in this context is well known: “treat negative shocks as permanent and positiveshocksastemporary”.Itisclearlybettertoreducedebtinresponsetoimprovedtradeconditions thantoincreaseitwhentheydeteriorate.Nonetheless,developingͲcountryGovernmentsfrequentlydo theexactopposite:increasingdebtduringdownswingsandnotreducingitagaininupswings.Moreover the tendency to apply public external debt to nonͲtraded sectors (which is often encouraged by the internationalinstitutions)reducestheabilitytocopewithtradeshocks. F. Conclusions:PrinciplesforDebtManagementinDevelopmentStrategies 1. TheParametersofDebtPolicy ThemainindicatorsunderlyingprudentdebtmanagementareshowninTableIV.5.Itisclearthatthose economies with unsustainable debt (i.e. the UDCs which were in arrears and/or undertook debt reschedulingduringthe1997Ͳ2001period)stillhaveveryhighdebtͲGDPratiosclosetotheconventional upperboundof60percent.Thisceilingisderivedfromexperienceofcountrieswhichgetintomajordebt 81 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment difficultiesandisinfactconsiderablylowerthanthatsetbytheWorldBank74inthecontextoftheHIPC initiative. ThoseUDCswhichdependonprivatecreditorsaremainlyinLatinAmerica:theirdebtͲserviceratiosand interest payments as a proportion of debt are higher and the average maturity shorter than for other countriesintheregion.TheLatinAmericanUDCsaretypicallysufferingfromaliquidityproblem,reflected in the fact that the ratio of reserves to shortͲterm obligations (or “quick ratio” as it is known by debt traders)islessthanunity,makingthemsusceptibletospeculativeattack.TheAfricanHIPCsincontrast, appear to be insolvent rather than illiquid: their inability to repay principle results in very long implicit maturities(i.e.yearsrequiredtopayoffdebtatpresentratesofamortization).Inmarkedcontrast,Asia appearstobebothsolventandliquid. TableIV.5.IndicatorsofDebtVulnerability,2003 Total ExternalDebt(percentofGDP) 38.1 DebtService(percentofexports) 17.9 InterestPayments(percent 3.9 ofdebt) Implicitmaturity(years) 8.2 LiquidityRatio 1.73 of Developing which: Asia 25.4 11.1 3.6 8.6 3.16 LatinAmerica Africa UDC HIPC andCaribbean 43.9 49.9 63.2 86.9 45.8 13.1 29.2 10.2 5.4 2.8 3.3 1.1 5.7 0.74 16.1 9.4 2.04 1.14 48.7 2.86 Source:Author’scalculationsbasedonIMF(May2005). Notes: “UDC” are Unsustainable Debt Countries’ with arrears and/or rescheduling during 1997Ͳ2001; HIPC are “highly indebtedpoorcountries”underconsiderationbytheWorldBankandIMFfordebtcancellation;interestpayments divided by debt outstanding should be compared with longͲterm average interest rates in advanced economies averaging 5 percent in this period; “implicit maturity” is outstanding debt divided by amortization payments; “liquidity ratio” is the ratio of reserves to payments in the form of interest and principle on shortͲ term debt principleplusservicepaymentsonlongͲtermdebt. Nonetheless,asTableIV.6.shows,sustainabilityas measuredbyallindicatorsandforalldebtorclasses clearlyimprovedbetween1996and2003.Thisappearstobeduetoexportgrowthandcontrolofimports (whichallowedcurrentͲaccountbalancestomoveintosurplusinmanycountries,especiallyinAsiaand LatinAmerica)ratherthantosignificantreductionsindebtlevels.Indeed,allregionsappeartoberunning current account deficits that are less or surpluses which are larger than indicated by the prudent rules showninthetable. Theseindicatorspointtotheeffectsofcreditrationingonthepartofcreditorsandstabilizationeffortson thepartofdebtors.Theysuggestthatthereisroomtoinitiateanewcycleofincreaseddebtlevelssolong asitisaccompaniedbyprudentmacroeconomicpolicy. 74 See World Bank (2004). ‘Moderately indebted’ countries are those with a ratio of the present value of contracted debt payments (PV) to GNP of over 132 percent and of PV to exports of goods and services (XGS) of over 48 percent, while ‘highly indebted’countrieshavePV/GNPofover220percentandPV/XGSofover80percent.Noexplanationisgivenforhowtheseexact figures are derived. These ratios are also difficult to compare with the IMF data used in this paper because the ratio of PV to nominaldebtdependsonthetermsofthedebtitself. 82 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableIV.6.ChangesinDebtSustainability1996Ͳ2003 ExternalDebt(percentofGDP) 1996 2003 GDPgrowth(percent) 1996Ͳ2003 CurrentͲaccount balance (per centofGCESR(2005para.117).DP) 1996 2003 “prudentvalue”(ʍ) DebtService(percentofexports) 1996 2003 Exportgrowth 1996Ͳ2005 CurrentͲaccount balance (per centofexports) 1996 2003 “prudentvalue”(ʍ) Total of which: Developing Asia 37.8 38.1 5.1 31.2 25.4 6.6 Latin America and Caribbean 35.0 43.9 2.6 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ1.9 21.5 17.9 10.8 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ2.1 Africa UDC HIPC 69.0 49.9 3.9 51.0 63.2 3.5 126.9 86.9 4.8 Ͳ1.9 3.1 Ͳ1.9 Ͳ2.2 0.3 Ͳ1.0 Ͳ1.1 Ͳ0.1 Ͳ2.3 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ2.0 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ5.1 13.9 11.1 12.0 46.7 45.8 7.0 20.3 13.1 8.1 29.2 29.2 8.1 22.6 10.2 7.1 Ͳ7.3 8.9 Ͳ1.5 Ͳ14.7 1.4 Ͳ3.2 Ͳ3.6 Ͳ0.29 Ͳ1.4 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ2.4 Ͳ Ͳ Ͳ1.24 Source:author’scalculationsfromIMF(May2005). Note:fordefinitions,seeSectionIIIabove..Thedebt/GDPanddebtͲservice/exportlevelsusedinthecalculationofprudential CABand“goldenrule”arethesimpleaveragesof1996and2003. 2. PolicyImplicationsforDevelopingCountries Debt levels must clearly be kept within prudent limits and Governments should make credible commitments to keep within these constraints, employing appropriate legislation if necessary. Such a policyisessentialtoreduceuncertaintyfordomesticfirmswhicharethemainvehiclesfortheinvestment on which growth depends. A debt overhang and the prospect of deflationary stabilization policies and debtrestructuring(orevenmoratoria)implyfuturelossesofsales,profitsandassetvalues. Debt should be contracted on the longest terms possible. The cost of servicing should be kept at a minimum subject to appropriate control over the vulnerability to future capitalͲmarket or worldͲtrade shocks.Suchcontrolmayimplythathigherinterestratesareareasonablepricetopayforloansoflonger maturityifvulnerabilitycanbereducedthereby.75 The use of funds generated by external debt should be geared to ensuring repayment capacity. This meansthatasubstantialproportionofthesefundsshouldbeallocatedtothesupportofexportgrowth. ThisdoesnotimplythattheGovernmentshouldbedirectlyengagedinexportproductionbutratherthat 75 Missale(1999)demonstrateshowthisprinciplehasbeenappliedinOECDcountries. 83 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment funds should be used to support appropriate infrastructure provision, the supply of longͲterm credit to exporters,andtrainingfortheworkforce. The support of export growth also involves maintaining a competitive real exchange rate, which has implications bothfor nominalexchangeratemanagementand forwagebargainingpolicy.ThepoliticalͲ economy constraints on excessive reduction of real wages are best countered by appropriate commitments to output and employment growth. Low real interest rates and an expansionary credit policyareneededtosupporttheinvestmentratelikelytoberequiredforthetargetrateofgrowth.Thisin turn means that the domestic financial system should to some extent be shielded from international capitalmarkets. The recent popularity of inflation targeting as the core of stabilization policy in emergingͲmarket economiesdoesnothelpreducedebtvulnerabilitybecauseithastheeffectofincreasingvulnerabilityto cyclicalcapitalflows.Openingofthecapitalaccountandafloatingexchangeratehasbeenaccompanied by reliance on a single monetary policy instrument (the interest rate) and rigid fiscal rules in emergingͲ marketeconomiesinpursuitofpricestability.Thisprecludesnotonlycountercyclicalmonetaryandfiscal policybutalsotheuseoftheexchangeratetomaintainexportcompetitivenesswhichisakeyelementof prudent debt management. There is a strong argument for emergingͲmarket Governments to adopt a counterͲcyclical monetary stance in response to capital flows. This would need to be supported by real exchangeͲratetargeting,bankcreditregulationandamoreactivefiscalstance.76 IfsuchapolicyistobesuccessfulinmiddleͲincomecountrieswithsubstantialshortͲtermprivatecapital flows, there is thus a strong case for intervention through various controls to reduce the volatility of capital flows.77These controls now usually take the form of taxes, regulatory measures (such as setting specialreserveordepositlevelsforinflows),andtargetedmoneyͲmarketoperations,whilequantitative controlshavebecomelesscommon. 3. PolicyImplicationsfortheInternationalCommunity Thereareanumberofotherpolicyareasthatcanonlybeaddressedbytheinternationalcommunity. Substantial debt reduction has not yet been forthcoming, even for HIPC countries, due to difficulties in budgetaryallocationsforthecorrespondingassetwriteͲdowns.Thisisaninternalaccountingmatterfor OECDcountriesandrequiresurgentsolution.Furtherdebtrestructuringcanreducetheliquidityproblem ofdebtͲservicepressureonthecurrentaccount.However,itdoesnotreducetheinvestmentdisincentives fromdebtoverhangandmayevenmakethemworsebyincreasinguncertainty.78 Giventhatexportgrowthisakeycomponentofprudentdebtmanagement,accesstoOECDmarketsfor developing country exporters is crucial to their ability to contract debt prudently, while accelerating economicgrowthandpovertyreduction.Thesameistrueofmeasurestoreducespeculativefluctuations inprimarycommodityprices.Ideally,thesewouldbecombinedwithlinkageofdebtrepaymentstoexport levels–atleastinthecaseofpaymentstoofficialcreditors.79 Since capital shocks to developing countries usually originate within OECD financial markets, policy towardsthemshouldbebasedonrecognitionoftheirexternalcharacter.Onesteptoreducetheimpact of these exogenous shocks would be for the IMF to provide temporary finance on a larger scale, more quicklyandwithlessconditionalityinordertofacilitatesmoothdebtmanagement.Inthelongerrun,itis 76 SeeFitzGerald(2005b). SeeFitzGerald(2005a). 78 Thiseffectfaroutweighsanypotentialmoralhazardimplicitin‘frontloading’debtforgiveness. 79 In practice markets are very unlikely to accept sovereign bonds with yields linked to commodity exports. However, certain primarycommoditiescanbeusedascollateralforborrowing. 77 84 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment essentialtodeepenthemarketfordevelopingͲcountrydebtinOECDcountriesby:lengtheningthetenor of instruments, taking measures to increase their liquidity, and encouraging their inclusion in the investmentsofpensionandinsurancefunds.80 80 Suchmeasureswouldalsoreducetheriskinessofsovereigndebt. 85 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References AghionPandHowittP(1998).EndogenousGrowthTheoryCambridge.MA,MITPress. Addison D (1989). The World Bank Revised Minimum Standard Model: Concepts and Issues. Working PaperSeries231.WashingtonDC,WorldBank.Anupdated(1999)versionofthispaperplusother RMSMdocumentsareavailableat:www.worldbank.org/data/rmsm/index.htm. Agenor PR and Montiel PJ (1999). Development Macroeconomics. 2nd edn Princeton, NJ, Princeton UniversityPress. AvramovicDetal.(1964).EconomicGrowthandExternalDebt.Baltimore,MD,JohnsHopkinsUniversity Press. Bacha EL (1990). A ThreeͲGap Model of Foreign Transfers and the GDP Growth Rate in Developing Countries.JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,32. BaqirR,RamcharanRandSahayR(2003).IMFProgramDesignandGrowth:WhatistheLink?Research WorkshoponMacroeconomicChallengesinLowIncomeCountries,Washington,DC,International MonetaryFund. BuiterWH(1990).PrinciplesofBudgetaryandFinancialPolicy.NewYork,HarvesterWheatsheaf. Chenery HB and Strout AM (1955). Foreign Assistance and Economic Development. American Economic Review,65. Cohen D (1994). Growth and External Debt. In Van der Ploeg F ed. Handbook of International Macroeconomics,Oxford,Blackwell Cunningham A, Dixon L, Hayes S (2001). Analysing Yield Spreads on Emerging Market Sovereign Bonds. BankofEnglandFinancialStabilityReview,175,December. Dornbusch RandHelmersF(1988).TheOpenEconomy:ToolsforPolicymakersinDevelopingCountries. NewYork,OUP. EasterlyW(1999).TheGhostoftheFinancingGap:TheGrowthModelUsedintheInternationalFinancial Institutions.JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,60. FitzGerald V, Jansen K and Vos R (1994). External Constraints on Private Investment Decisions in Developing Countries. In: Gunning JW, Kox H, Tims W and de Wit Y eds. Trade, Aid and DevelopmentBasingstoke.Macmillan. FitzGeraldV(2001).ShortͲTermCapitalFlows,theRealEconomyandIncomeDistributioninDeveloping Countries. In: GriffithͲJones S, Montes M and Nasution A eds. ShortͲterm Capital Flows and EconomicCrises.Oxford,OxfordUniversityPressforUNU/WIDER. FitzGeraldV(2003a).GlobalMarketsandtheDevelopingEconomy.Basingstoke,Palgrave. FitzGerald V (2003b). The Instability of International Demand for Emerging Market Assets. In: FfrenchͲ DavisRandGriffithͲJonesSeds.FromCapitalSurgestoDrought:SeekingStabilityforDeveloping Economies.Basingstoke,PalgraveforUNU/WIDER. FitzGerald V (2005a). Policy Issues in Market Based and NonͲMarket Based Measures to Control the Volatility of Portfolio Investment. In: Green CJ, Kirkpatrick C and Murinde V eds. Finance and Development:SurveysofTheory,EvidenceandPolicy.Aldershot,EdwardElgar. FitzGeraldV(2005b).MonetaryModelsandInflationTargetinginEmergingMarketEconomies.In:Arestis P, McCombie J and Baddeley M (2005). The New Monetary Policy. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton,MA,EdwardElgar. 86 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment FitzGerald V (forthcoming). International Risk Tolerance, Capital Market Failure and Capital Flows to Emerging Markets. In: A. Shorrocks ed. Thinking Ahead: the Future of Development Economics. Basingstoke,PalgraveforUNU/WIDER. FitzGeraldVandBabilisS(2005).RiskAppetite,HomeBiasandtheUnstableDemandforEmergingMarket Assets.InternationalReviewofAppliedEconomics,19(4). FitzGeraldVandPerosinoG(1999).TradeLiberalization,EmploymentandWages:ACriticalapproach.In: BarbaͲNavarretti G, Faini R and Zanalada G eds. Labour Markets, Poverty and Development, Oxford,Clarendon. Griffin KB (1970). Foreign Capital, Domestic Savings, and Economic Development. Oxford Bulletin of EconomicsandStatistics,32(2). Heijdra BJ and van der Ploeg F (2002). The Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics. Oxford, Oxford UniversityPress. IMF (1987). Theoretical Aspects of the Design of FundͲSupported Adjustment Programs. IMF Occasional Paper55.WashingtonDC;InternationalMonetaryFund. IMF(2003).PublicDebtinEmergingMarkets–IsittooHigh?WorldEconomicOutlook2003,ChapterIII. IMF,WorldEconomicOutlook. KhanMS,MontielPJandHaqueNU(1990).AdjustmentwithGrowth:RelatingtheAnalyticalApproaches oftheWorldBankandtheIMF.JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,32. McCombie J and Thirlwall AP (1994). Economic Growth and the Balance of Payments Constraint. Basingstoke,Macmillan. MissaleA(1999).PublicDebtManagement.Oxford,OxfordUniversityPress. ObstfeldMandRogoffK(1995).TheIntertemporalApproachtotheCurrentAccount.In:GrossmanGM andRogoffKeds.HandbookofInternationalEconomics,3.Oxford,Blackwell. PolakJJ(1957).MonetaryAnalysisofIncomeFormationandPaymentsProblems.IMFStaffPapers,6(1). RebelloS(1991).LongRunAnalysisandLongRunGrowth.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,94. Rodrik D (1991). Policy Uncertainty and Private Investment in Developing Countries. Journal of DevelopmentEconomics,36. RomerPM(1986).IncreasingReturnsandLongRunGrowth.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,94. SachsJD(1989).DevelopingCountryDebtandtheWorldEconomy.Chicago,IL,UniversityofChicagoPress forNBER. Sen P (1994). Savings, Investment, and the Current Account. In: van der Ploeg F ed. The Handbook of InternationalMacroeconomics.Oxford,Blackwell. TaylorL(1994).GapModels.JournalofDevelopmentEconomics,45. Taylor L (ed.) (1993). The Rocky Road to Reform: Adjustment, Income Distribution, and Growth in the DevelopingWorld.Boston,MA,MITPressforUNU/WIDER. TranͲNguyen AN (2004). Debt ServicingͲCapacity of Developing Countries: Conceptual Approaches and MeasurementProblems.Geneva,UNCTAD(processed). UNCTAD(2005).WorldInvestmentReport2005.Geneva,UNCTAD. WorldBank(2004).GlobalDevelopmentFinance2004.Washington,DC,WorldBank. 87 AnAnalyticalFrameworkforDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment WorldBank(2005a).WorldDevelopmentIndicators. WorldBank(2005b).WorldDevelopmentReport. 88 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERV THEDEBTEXPERIENCESOF UGANDA,KENYAANDBOLIVIA DamoniKitabire,PeterMichaelOumo,FrancisM.Mwegaand PaulBeckerman81 A. Introduction This chapter reviews the debt experiences of three of the world’s poorest economies, namely Uganda, KenyaandBolivia.Thechapterhighlightstheconditionsanddebtproblemsthatunderpinnedthefailure ofsuccessivedebtinitiativestorendertheirdebtpositionsustainable. Amajorcontributoryfactortothisfailureisthatthethreecountries’exportsremainconcentratedona handful of commodities, all of which suffered significant deteriorations in the terms of trade since the 1980s. Moreover, the three countries also experienced severe climatic shocks, such as severe droughts (Kenya)andElNino(Bolivia).Tothesefactorsmustbeaddedpoliticalturmoil,instabilityandwars. Uganda and Bolivia have records of having been exemplary pupils of Washington Consensus policies. Kenya followed similarly orthodox approaches to macroͲeconomic management, albeit against a background of turbulent relations with creditors. All three countries went through a succession of programs. The reform efforts revived growth at the outset but sustained per capita gains failed to materialize. ThecountryreviewsinsectionsII,III,andIVhighlighttheroleoffactorsaffectingsustainabilitythatshould havebeenincorporatedinpastdebtreliefanalyseswithspecialemphasisonexportdiversification,fiscal 81 Section B is based on a paper by Damoni Kitabire and Peter Michael Oumo (Ministry of Finance, Planning and Economic Development of Uganda) (Kitabire and Oumo (2005)), Section C is based on a paper by Francis M. Mwega (Department of Economics, University of Nairobi) (Mwega (2005)), Section D isbased on a paper by PaulBeckerman (Independent Consultant) (Beckerman(2006)). 89 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia positions, and new financing. The three experiences are then compared and contrasted in Section E. SectionFsummarizestheprincipalfindings. B. Uganda 1. Introduction Despite three decades of attempts to reduce the external debt burden, debt sustainability still eludes Uganda.Thecountry’sprincipaldebtproblemhasbeenitsheavydebtserviceburden.Despiteremarkable GDPgrowthsincethe1990sandimprovementsinexportearnings,theeconomyremainsdependenton rainͲfedagricultureandvulnerabletoshocksdeliveredbyworldcommoditymarkets.Thecountryisalso stillheavilydependentondonoraidwhichcurrentlyfinancesabout40percentofthebudget. Since the 1991 debt crisis, Uganda has developed a fairly coherent debt strategy. However, its debt burden remained high until the HIPC Initiative put Uganda on a sustainable debt path momentarily. UnfortunatelytheHIPCInitiativedidnotleadtoapermanentexitfromdebtproblems.Thecountryhas borrowedheavilypostͲHIPCtoachievetheMDGsanditsdebtindicatorsareunsustainableagain. 2. EconomicPerformanceandPolicies Uganda entered the 1980s with a degree of political stability that allowed GDP growth to recover to a positive 1.7 per cent in 1980Ͳ1983. Thereafter, industrial production declined due to foreign exchange shortageandthepoorstateofinfrastructure,whileagriculturalproductionalsolagged.In1983/84fiscal there was fiscal slippage on an IMF stabilization program which was cancelled in late 1984. Political instabilityandaprotractedguerrillawarledtoanewGovernmenttakingpowerinJanuary1986. InMay1987,thenewGovernmentembarkedonanEconomicRecoveryProgrammewiththesupportof IMF,WorldBankandothers.Thiswasfollowedin1989byaStructuralAdjustmentProgramme(SAP).Its focus was on limiting the involvement of the state in economic activities, the liberalization of trade, financialͲsectorandmarketingactivities,theprivatizationanddivestitureofpublicenterprises,andmore generally the promotion of privateͲsector participation in production. The program resulted in an acceleration of GDP growth to an average rate of 6.9 per cent per annum between 1991/92 and 1999/2000(seeFigureV.1.). By 2000, the structure of the Ugandan economy had changed dramatically. In 1982/83, agriculture accountedfor53.6percentofGDP,butitssharedeclinedto36.3percentin2004/05.Atthesametime, thesharesofindustryandservicessteadilyincreased,thatofservicesrisingfrom35.2percent1982/83to 36.6percentin1990/91andbecomingthelargestin2001/02.However,Ugandaremainsvulnerableto weatherchangesasthecountry’sagriculturalsystemreliesheavilyonrainͲfedsmallholderagriculture. 90 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment FigureV.1.Uganda’sGDPGrowth1982/83–2004/05 (Percent) 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 3 /8 -5% 82 19 /03 /99 /01 /05 /97 /93 /95 /87 /89 /91 /85 00 02 98 04 94 96 88 90 92 84 86 20 19 20 20 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 -10% Agriculture Industry Services GDP at Market Prices Source:UgandabureauofStatistics. Largelydependentonprimarycommodities,Uganda’sexportgrowthhasbeenerratic.Followingreform efforts,growthreboundedintheearly1990s.Thiswasreinforcedbythecoffeepriceboomof1993/94Ͳ 1996/97. Following efforts to diversify away from coffee, the share of coffee in Uganda’s exports has declined from 70 per cent in the 1990s to about 20 per cent since 2000/01. Fish has become Uganda’s leadingexport,followedbycotton,tea,tobacco,andflowers. As shown in Figure V.2., Uganda’s terms of trade (TOT) have been erratic but with an overall secular decliningtrend,largelydeterminedbytheinternationalpriceofcoffee.TheTOThaverecentlyimproved andchangeshavebeenpositivesince2002/03.Deterioratingtermsoftradehaveadirectimpactondebt sustainability.Coffeeexportpricesin2003/04were49percentlowerthanenvisagedatthetimeofHIPC IIcompletion.64percentofthedeteriorationintheratiooftheNPVofdebttoexportsbetween2002 and2004wasduetofallingcoffeeexportprices. FigureV.2.ChangesinUganda’sTermsofTrade1989/90–2004/05 (Percent) 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 19 89 /9 19 0 90 /9 19 1 91 /9 19 2 92 /9 19 3 93 /9 19 4 94 /9 19 5 95 /9 19 6 96 /9 19 7 97 /9 19 8 98 /9 19 9 99 /0 20 0 00 /0 20 1 01 /0 20 2 02 /0 20 3 03 /0 20 4 04 /0 5 0% -20% -40% Source:BankofUganda. 91 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia Under the Economic Recovery program initiated in 1987, reforms in trade policy gradually eased quantitative restrictions and were geared towards export promotion. Trade licensing schemes were abandonedandcoffeemarketingwasliberalizedinthelate1980s.In1992,thetaxoncoffeeexportswas abolished.Itwasbrieflyreintroducedin1994tolimittheappreciationoftheexchangerateasaresultof thecoffeeboom,andabolishedagainin1996.Importdutieswererationalizedin1992toarangeof10Ͳ60 percent,andwerefurtherreducedtoarangeof10Ͳ50percentin1994. Initially, the exchangeͲrate policy involved repeated devaluations and rationing of the available foreign exchange under various schemes. A foreignͲcurrency retention scheme was introduced in 1988 and extended in 1989. In 1990, the exchange market was liberalized with the legalization of the parallel (kibanda) market. In 1992, an exchange rate auction market was created. The foreign exchange market was fully liberalized and the exchange rate was floated in 1993. In 1997, the capital account was liberalized. Topromoteforeigninvestment,UgandaenactedanInvestmentCodein1991.ThisreversedlongͲstanding antipathy towards foreign investment and introduced standard provisions regarding investment incentives, profit repatriation and protection against expropriation. FDI rose from US$43.2 million in 1992/93toUS$670millionasofend2004/05. Successive reforms have enabled Uganda to manage its fiscal balances more prudently but have not reduced the country’s dependency on donor aid for financing its budget. In the 1990s, over half of Uganda’sbudgetwasfundedbydonoraidandthisratiowasstill40percentin2005/06.Upto1996over half of the aid received was in the form of loans, though grants became more important subsequently (AtingiͲEgo2005). DealingwiththeDutchDiseaseeffectsoftheseflowshasbeenthesourceofasignificantriseindomestic debtservicing.DutchDiseaseeffectsputappreciationpressuresontheexchangerate,withinterestrate rises owing to the attempt to contain the inflationary effects of the inflows on liquidity. According to AtingiͲEgo (2005), since 1998 Dutch Disease effects in Uganda have adversely affected investment and imports. 3. ExternalDebt Uganda’s debt problems date back to the 1980s. Debt continued to accumulate (despite the Government’s increasing inability to service it) due to continuing foreign exchange shortages. By 1986, Uganda’s debt stock had grown to US$1.4 billion, up from US$680 million in 1980. Between 1986 and 1990,becauseofthereconstructionandrecoveryprogramandofalackofaneffectivedebtmanagement strategy, both the debt stock and debt service went out of control. Large sums were borrowed on unfavorabletermsandarrearsaccumulated,theburdenbeingexacerbatedbydelinquentprivateͲsector loansguaranteedbytheGovernment. By the late 1980s, Uganda faced a debt crisis. In 1990, the Government ran out of foreign exchange following a sharp decline in terms of trade due largely to a decline in the price of coffee. Debt service obligations amounted to over 60 percent of export earnings. Drastic action was therefore necessary to reversethecollapseinthebalanceofpayments,promptingthedevelopmentofUganda’sfirstintegrated debtmanagementstrategyin1991. AsshownintableV.1.,mostofUganda’sdebt(63percentin1991to88percentasof2004)isowedto multilateral institutions and is therefore longͲterm. Owed mainly to IDA and ADF the debt is also on concessionalterms,i.e.has10yearsofgrace,andarepaymentperiodof30yearsforIDAandof40years forADF.ThedebttoGDPratiohasdeclineddrasticallyfromapeakof98percentin1992andhasrecently stabilized in a range of 60 Ͳ70 per cent. The ratio of debt service to exports has also undergone sharp 92 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment fluctuationsbutsincetheendofthe1990shasstabilizedataround20percentlargelyduetoHIPCdebt reliefinitiativeandthepromotionofnonͲtraditionalexports. TableV.1.Uganda’sDebtStructureandIndicators1980–2004 US$ Million Total Debt Stock o/w arrears Multilateral Bilateral o/w Paris Club Non Paris Club Other Mulitilateral (% Debt Stock) Bilateral (% Debt Stock) Other (% Debt Stock) Debt Service Debt/GDP Debt Service/Exports Debt /Exports Ratio 1980 689.0 101.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1986 1,422.0 92.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1987 1,945.0 99.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1988 1,923.0 136.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1989 2,177.0 190.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1990 2,583.0 298.0 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 1991 2,591.6 370.9 1,643.6 811.8 285.5 526.3 136.2 1992 2,647.4 583.1 1,755.9 651.4 273.2 378.2 240.1 1993 2,637.1 301.8 1,815.9 697.3 281.7 415.6 123.9 1994 2,999.4 251.0 2,156.1 730.4 332.0 398.4 112.9 1995 3,386.9 233.4 2,487.9 787.9 380.1 407.9 111.1 1996 3,515.8 250.3 2,655.1 755.1 350.6 404.5 105.6 1997 3,660.2 316.6 2,763.0 796.0 339.1 456.9 101.2 1998 3,631.6 275.5 2,826.8 748.6 325.0 423.6 56.2 1999 3,499.6 241.5 2,782.6 649.9 288.2 361.7 67.1 2000 3,579.9 232.0 2,936.3 593.2 260.6 332.6 50.5 2001 3,397.5 286.8 2,893.3 476.1 131.5 344.7 28.1 2002 3,825.2 301.7 3,318.1 488.5 111.4 370.1 18.5 2003 4,296.3 318.7 3,720.4 555.5 122.8 432.7 20.4 2004 4,310.0 342.9 3,782.8 510.3 66.1 444.2 16.9 n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a n.a 63.4% 31.3% 5.3% 66.3% 24.6% 9.1% 68.9% 26.4% 4.7% 71.9% 24.4% 3.8% 73.5% 23.3% 3.3% 75.5% 21.5% 3.0% 75.5% 21.7% 2.8% 77.8% 20.6% 1.5% 79.5% 18.6% 1.9% 82.0% 16.6% 1.4% 85.2% 14.0% 0.8% 86.7% 12.8% 0.5% 86.6% 12.9% 0.5% 87.8% 11.8% 0.4% 57.0 54.6% 17.2% 208.2% 172.0 32.7% 43.2% 357.3% 160.0 66.4% 43.8% 532.9% 202.0 54.2% 62.3% 593.5% 186.0 147.0 148.0 131.0 140.6 167.8 59.5% 86.0% 83.4% 98.2% 87.4% 81.3% 61.2% 59.8% 66.1% 65.2% 83.2% 66.1% 716.1% 1050.0% 1157.0% 1317.1% 1560.4% 1180.9% 150.7 64.3% 22.6% 507.8% 142.2 64.0% 19.7% 486.3% 155.9 64.0% 18.9% 443.8% 154.6 59.5% 24.4% 573.1% 162.9 62.0% 22.4% 481.8% 133.4 65.9% 20.1% 540.0% 146.1 65.0% 21.6% 501.9% 133.6 71.3% 19.1% 545.7% 172.0 74.4% 22.2% 555.1% 179.7 68.8% 19.4% 464.4% Source:MinistryofFinance,Planning&EconomicDevelopmentandBankofUganda. Firstattemptsatdevelopingadebtmanagementsystemcamein1983withtheformationoftheExternal Debt Management Office (EDMO) within the Bank of Uganda (BoU). In 1986, two other offices; the Aid CoordinationUnit(ACU)intheMinistryofFinancePlanningandEconomicDevelopment(MFPED),andthe TreasuryOfficeofAccounts (TOA)were mandated tomanageand disburse external debttogetherwith the EDMO. The ACU, now called Aid Liaison Department (ALD), was responsible for seeking and negotiatingnewloansinlinewithGovernment’sfinancingrequirements. The key features of Uganda’s debt adopted in the 1995 strategy include seeking grant funding before contracting any loan and ensuring that all loans are strictly on IDAͲcomparable terms. Loans must be approved by the beneficiary sector and the development committee before being contracted, and they mustbeinlinewithsectoralandpovertyreductiontargets.LoansarethenscrutinizedbytheMinistryin chargeandcheckedagainstbudgetarytargets,afterwhichcabinetandparliamentaryapprovalaresought. TechnicalcapacityfordebtmanagementinUgandaiswelldeveloped.Particularlysince1995,Ugandahas madesustained,tangibleprogressincapacitybuildinginallaspectsofdebtmanagement.Moreover,BoU has now a good debt recording capacity and a complete upͲtoͲdate computerized database which uses UNCTAD’sDebtMonitoringandFinancialAnalysisSystem(DMFAS). 4. DomesticPublicDebt In Uganda the issuance of Government debt has not only had the normal function of meeting revenue shortfalls, but also that of financing the sterilization of foreign aid inflows. As sterilization efforts intensifiedattheendofthe1990s,Treasurybillsalesrosefrom23percentto32percentofcommercial bankholdingsbetween1998and2004despitethefactthatdomesticdebtwastypicallyintherangeof1Ͳ 2percentofGDP(seeTableV.2.).Interestpaymentsondomesticdebt,however,doubledin1995Ͳ2000 owingtothepolicyofhighinterestratesassociatedwiththeattempttomanagetheconsequencesofhigh aidinflows.ByaddingtopressuresonthefiscalbalancetheseinterestpaymentscontributedtopostͲHIPC difficulties. 93 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia TableV.2.DomesticDebtinUgandaandKenya,1980Ͳ2000 (Percent) Domesticdebt (inpercentofGDP) Totaldebt (inpercentofGDP) Domestic/Totaldebt Domesticinterest payments/totaldebt Source: Christensen(2004) 1980Ͳ89 1990Ͳ94 1995Ͳ00 1980Ͳ89 1990Ͳ94 1995Ͳ00 1980Ͳ89 1990Ͳ94 1995Ͳ00 1990Ͳ94 1995Ͳ00 Kenya Uganda Average HIPC 21 23 22 81 100 74 25 23 29 71.7 74.5 2 1 2 2 74 59 100 1 4 14.4 29.4 11 12 15 62 102 118 25 19 22 49.7 51.9 9 6 8 69 138 169 22 6 6 42.3 42.5 Decision NonͲHIPC Point2/ 3/ 10 14 18 7 8 23 73 53 143 59 164 59 25 30 35 7 7 40 43.6 60.8 43.2 65.3 Notes: 1/BothdomesticdebtsincludeTreasuryBillsandGovernmentStocks,withKenyaalsoissuingbonds 2/IncludesUganda 3/IncludesKenya 5. TheDebtStrategyfrom1991to1995 In early 1991, the Government of Uganda embarked on a comprehensive debt strategy, including a full debt audit. The 1991 Debt Strategy focused on overcoming the immediate debt payment crisis and developing mechanisms to ensure that it did not reͲoccur. The first objective of this strategy was to provideasolutiontothecashflowproblemthroughdebtrestructuring.Thisnecessitatedclearingarrears andreducingdebtservicetolevelsconsistentwithUganda’sabilitytopay.Thesecondobjectivewasto improve debt management structures. This resulted in the strengthening of debt management by requiringministriestoworkwiththeAidCoordinationUnit(ACU)intheMinistryofFinance.Inaddition, strictlimitsonborrowingwereputinplace,witharequirementtoexhaustallsourcesofgrantfinancing beforeconsideringnewloans,whichhadtocomefromhighlyconcessionalsources. By1991,UgandahadalreadyundertakenfourrestructuringoperationswithintheframeworkoftheParis Clubin1981,1982,1987,and1989.Unfortunately,theserestructuringoperationswerenotsufficientto easethedebtoverhangfortworeasons.First,in theParisClubs1to3,negotiationscoveredonlydebt fallingdueduringashortconsolidationperiod(12Ͳ18months).Second,untilParis8,onlypreͲcutoffdebt (accountingfor4percentofthetotaldebtstock)waseligiblefordebtrelief.Moreover,thedeminimis clauseexcludedloansoflessthanSDR500,000fromrescheduling. The 1991 strategy also addressed the country’s commercial debt. Although this debt accounted for just over9percentoftotaldebtstockin1992,mostofitwasinarrears.UgandaembarkeduponadebtbuyͲ backstrategy,financedbytheWorldBank.Theofferpricewasfixedat12centsperdollarinDecember 1992,andtheclosingdatewasinFebruary1993.Overall,thebuybackwasverysuccessful. The1991debtstrategywassuccessfulinmanyways.Itestablishedclearproceduresfornegotiatingnew loans and strengthened debt management. It helped to increase the proportion of payments made on time.Itledtolargereductionsincommercialdebtanddebtservice.Consequently,thedebttoGDPratio fellfrom83percentin1991to64percentin1995.Thestockofarrearsfellfrom15percentin1991to7 percentin1993,whilemultilateraldebtincreasedfrom61percentto75percentoftotalexternaldebt 94 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment overthesameperiod.However,thisputthecountryinadifficultpositionbecausemultilateraldebtcould notberestructured. Therewerethreemainweaknessesinthe1991debtstrategy.Firstwastheinsufficientreductioninlong term multilateral debt. Secondly, the country continued to require large amounts of new financing to supportthereformprogramwiththedangerofincreaseddebtservicingobligationsifthenewfinancing wasnotconcessionalenough.Thirdly,therewerestillsomeproblemswithdebtmanagementstructures. A comprehensive review of the debt strategy was carried out in 1995 with help from the Swedish Government.Thenewstrategywhichemergedfocusedonfourobjectives: Reductionofthemultilateraldebtserviceburdenthroughbilateralgrants; Increasingtheconcessionalityofnewborrowingandthequalityofloanfinancedinvestment; Improvingdebtandreservemanagement; Improvingcoordinationwithdonors,andlobbyingforlongtermmultilateraldebtreduction.In fact, in November 1995, a Multilateral Debt Fund (MDF) was established, with contributions usedtoservicedebt.Thestrategyalsointroducedtherequirementofparliamentaryapprovalof newloans. (a) (b) (c) (d) 6. TheHIPCDebtReliefInitiative InApril1998,UgandabecamethefirstcountrytobenefitfromHIPCDebtReliefInitiative.PriortoHIPC debtrelief,thenominalvalueofUganda’sexternaldebtstockwasUS$3.5billion,andtheNPVofdebtto exportsratiowas294percent.UnderHIPCI,UgandareceiveddebtreliefofUS$347millioninNPVterms. Ofthisamount,79percentwasduetomultilateralcreditorssothatforthefirsttime,debtreliefhada largemultilateralcomponent.Uganda’sNPVofdebttoexportsratiowassupposedtofall196percent,i.e. belowthethresholdratioof202percent. However, Uganda’s debt swiftly returned to unsustainable levels, mainly on account of the El Nino weatherphenomenon,whichseverelyaffectedexportperformancein1999.Hence,inMay2000,Uganda received further relief under Enhanced HIPC. Prior to this, in June 1999, Uganda’s external debt stock reachedUS$3.6billion.TotalreliefunderHIPCIIwasexpectedtoamounttoanadditionalUS$656million, withmultilateralcreditorscontributing83percent.ThetotalreliefundertheHIPCasawholewasUS$1 billioninNPVterms,orunderonethirdofthepreͲHIPCnominaldebtstock. 7. PostͲHIPCDevelopments Since HIPC II completion, Uganda’s external debt sustainability as measured by NPV of debt to exports ratio has deteriorated. Uganda’s NPV of debt to exports ratio had reached 280 per cent according to a June2004analysis. Anumberoffactorshavecontributedtothedeteriorationindebtindicators. x First,istheimpactoffallingcoffeepricesonexportearnings,whichwere57percentand36per centlowerin2002/03and2004/05thaninitiallyenvisaged. x Secondly,risinginterestratesreducedtheconcessionalityofthecountry’sdebt. x Thirdly,attheEnhancedHIPCdecisionpoint,estimatesfornewfinancinginthemacroeconomic framework and balance of payments projections were not fully incorporated in the Debt SustainabilityAnalysis. x Fourth,theinitiativewasweakenedbytherefusalofsomecreditorstoparticipate. 95 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia x Fifth, and most importantly, Uganda has borrowed more than US$1.6 billion since HIPC II completion, 85 per cent of which is owed to IDA and ADF, primarily to finance the Poverty EradicationActionPlan(PEAP),Uganda’soverͲarchingpolicyframeworktoeradicatepoverty.This heavyrelianceonborrowedfundsreflectslimitedimprovementsindomesticrevenues,whichhas leftthecountryhighlydependantonexternalassistance. Inthe2004budgetspeechitwasannouncedthatceilingswouldbeputonannualtoachieveagradual declineintheNPVofdebttoexportsratiotosustainablelevels. Its tumultuous history aside, Uganda’s experience serves to underscore that without a comprehensive debtstrategyitisimpossibletousedebtfordevelopment.Inaddition,thefailuretodiversifytheexport basehasleftthecountryatthemercyofprimarycommodityprices Uganda needs to consolidate the gains of the debt strategy it has pursued since 1991. The institutional arrangementsforexternalborrowingshouldclearlyoutlinetheroles,responsibilities,andobligationsof all stakeholders. Uganda is currently attempting to ensure that borrowing is strictly for enhancing productivity and competitiveness. Moreover the quality of infrastructure built with past borrowing has fallen into a dilapidated state even before the loans are repaid so that there is a serious risk of accumulatingfurtherdebtforitsrepair. C. Kenya’sDebtExperience 1. Introduction Kenya did not experience one big default. Rather, it has had serious recurrent debt servicing problems, withadebtcrisispeakingin1991.Theseproblemsoccurredagainstabackgroundofnegativeexogenous financial and trade shocks arising from the vulnerability of the Kenyan economy and the prices of key primarycommoditiestoweatherconditions. 2. TheEconomicEnvironment (a)OverallEconomicPerformance The 1980Ͳ84 period was characterized by various adverse external and internal shocks (including two severedroughts),globalrecessionandreducedcapitalinflowsfollowingthe1982debtcrisis.Itwasalso characterized by inability to satisfy the IMF credit ceilings and Government borrowing conditionalities, leadingtothecancellationofanumberofprograms.In1985Ͳ90,economicgrowthwasrelativelyrapid, partly due to an increase in coffee and tea prices and a decline in petroleum prices. The Government adoptedaproͲcyclicalpolicyandincreasedpublicexpenditure(bothcapitalandcurrent)morethanthe increaseinrevenue. Inthefirsthalfof1990s,theeconomyreceivedmoreshocks:adroughtin1991/1992,oilpriceincreases due to the Gulf War, an aid embargo in 1991Ͳ93, and ethnic clashes in 1992. These shocks were accompaniedbyanincreaseinthebudgetdeficit,risinginflation,andlargeexchangeratedepreciations, astheforeignexchangemarketwasliberalized.Inthesecondhalfofthe1990s,economicgrowthdeclined furthertoanaverageof1.9percent,assimilarinstabilitiescontinued. As shown in table V.3., the performance of Kenya’s export sector has been lacklustre and exports have grownlessthanGDPsinceindependence.TheshareofexportsinGDPdecreasedfrom21.8percentin 1980 to 12.5 per cent in 2004. Tea, horticulture and coffee are by far the most important exports, 96 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment accounting for 54 per cent in 2000Ͳ2004. Kenya’s terms of trade have also declined substantially. Dependenceonprimarycommodityhasalsomeantthatthetermsoftradeareveryvolatile. TableV.3.Kenya:ofExports,TermsofTrade(TOT)andForeignDirectInvestment(FDI) Year Exports (K£million) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Average 487.64 513.86 545.74 633.08 754.81 785.10 957.97 753.41 917.74 999.83 1232.38 1533.83 1708.08 3625.21 4170.72 4656.18 5696.30 5722.95 5722.25 5770.3 5988.2 6071.7 6569.7 6835.45 7953.05 GDP Exports Exports (K£million) (inpercentof (US$million) GDP) 2235.37 21.8 1318.0 2597.23 19.8 1388.8 2944.62 18.5 992.2 3316.63 19.1 994.8 3851.78 19.6 1041.2 4374.62 17.9 957.4 5083.98 18.8 1182.6 13.3 913.2 5648.23 6480.62 14.2 986.8 7451.34 13.4 925.8 8377.78 14.7 1022.8 9540.33 16.1 1091.6 11402.53 15.0 943.6 14185.41 25.6 1063.2 16903.24 24.7 1162.0 19205.79 24.2 1674.8 21865.55 26.1 2071.2 31161.76 18.4 1944.9 34701.44 16.5 1738.3 37173.95 15.5 1528.9 39817.15 15.0 1529.2 48391.90 12.5 1560.1 51938.20 12.6 1715.2 57089.00 12.0 1781.4 63685.80 12.5 2056.5 Growthof exports (percent) 5.37 Ͳ28.56 Ͳ4.78 10.20 Ͳ8.05 23.52 Ͳ22.78 8.06 Ͳ6.18 10.47 6.73 Ͳ13.55 12.67 75.13 Ͳ10.05 23.67 Ͳ6.10 Ͳ10.63 Ͳ12.05 0.02 2.02 9.94 3.86 15.44 0.10 TOT 1982=100 FDI/GNI (percent) 123 108 100 94 110 92 103 85 88 79 69 82 79 90 101 95 93 102 100 86 84 79 78 81 77.4 1.1 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.8 0.7 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.4 0.4 0.4 1.3 0.5 0.4 Source:EconomicSurvey,VariousIssues. CollierandGunning (1999)attributemuchofKenya’sweak growth performance to geographyandrisk. MuchofthecountryisalsosemiͲaridsothatagriculturalproductionintrinsicallyrisky.Kenya’sgeography also means that transport costs are high, quite aside from deficiencies in infrastructure. But they also argue that trade shocks caused an economic decline because of overͲregulation and the Government’s lossofcontroloverpublicexpenditure.Azam(1997)shows thatinsufficient privateinvestmentandthe failure to increase human capital accumulation contributed to the slowing of growth in the 1980s and 1990s. (b)LiberalizationStrategies Inthe1980s,Kenyahada“managedͲfloat”exchangerateregime.Theperiodwitnessedacuteshortages of imported inputs due to nonͲavailability of foreign exchange. This resulted not only in frequent interruptionsinproductionbutalsoinchronicunderͲutilizationofinstalledcapacity.Kenyatookaseries of measures that gradually removed foreign exchange controls and liberalized the exchange rate, including a large devaluation of the shilling. In 1992Ͳ1993 the official exchange rate and the interͲbank foreignexchangerateweremerged,controlsoncurrentandcapitalaccounttransactionswereremoved. Furtherliberalizationfollowedin1995. 97 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia Similarly in the 1980s and 1990s Kenya implemented trade reforms, which eliminated most nonͲtariff barriers and lowered tariffs, substantially opening the economy. The maximum tariff rate was reduced from 170 per cent to 70 per cent over 1987Ͳ1993. Recently, under obligations of the East African Communitycustomsunion,tariffbandswerereducedtothreewithamaximumexternaltariffof25per centsinceJanuary2005. Kenyaliberalizeditscapitalaccountoverthesameperiod.Reformsalsoincludedtheeasingofrestrainton foreign ownership and the establishment in 1990 of the Capital Markets Authority (CMA). The Nairobi StockExchangemarketopenedtoforeigninvestorsinJanuary1995.Toinsureagainstthepotentialriskof liquidity crises delivered by exogenous shocks or speculative activities, Kenya has followed other developingcountriesinaccumulatingforeignreserves. Kenya also embarked on financial sector reforms. Positive real interest rates, the target of the market reforms,aimedatenhancingefficiency.InstitutionalreformsfocusedonstrengtheningtheCentralBank, particularlyinitssupervisoryandregulatoryroles.Inmonetarypolicytherewasashifttomoreindirect instrumentslikeopenͲmarketoperations.Therewasafinancialcrisisin1998whichledtotheliquidation ofseveralbanks.Muchofthefinancialdeepeningwhichhasresultedisduetotheconversionofdeposits ofnonͲbankingfinancialinstitutionstocommercialbanksdeposits. The Central Bank has maintained a high interestͲrate regime to stabilize the exchange rate and has pursuedagenerallytightmonetarypolicyinthefaceofinflationarypressures.Oneoftheconsequences hasbeenwidespreaddistressedborrowingsothatbanks’portfolioshaveincludedmanynonͲperforming loans.Thedeclineincredithasbeenassociatedwithdeclininginvestment. Kenya’sfiscalpolicyislinkedtoitsexternalindebtedness.Kenyaisheavilydependentonaidinflowsforits governmentfinances,withaidaccountingfor45percentofthebudgetatthepeakin1991(O’Brienand Ryan,1999).Throughoutthe1990s,foreignaidaveragedabout9percentofGDP,accountingforabout 20 per cent of the annual government budget and financing slightly over 80 per cent of development expenditures(Njeru2004). 3. ExternalDebt Kenyaisasamoderatelyindebtedcountry.Thecountry’sexternaldebtincreasedfromUS$4.2billionin themidͲ1980stoapeakofUS$7.5billionin1991,decliningtoUS$6billionin2002.AsaproportionofGNI itincreasedfrom70.8percentofGNIin1985toapeakof156percentin1993butthendeclinedto49.2 percentin2002.(SeeTableV.4.)Externaldebtserviceincreasedtoapeakof39percentofexportsin 1988butthendeclinedto13percentin2002. Almost all of Kenya’s external debt is either public or publicly guaranteed and owed primarily to Governments and multilateral organizations. For the period 1985Ͳ2002, private nonͲguaranteed debt generallyaccountedforlessthat15percentofthetotal.ShortͲtermdebtaccountedforbetween54and 69percentofoutstandingstocks.Theaveragegraceperiodisabout6.9years,theaveragegrantelement about50.9percent,andtheaveragematurityperiodabout26.5years.Bilateralaidhasbeenmainlyin theformofgrants(72percentofthetotal),whereasmultilateralaidhasmainlybeenintheformofloans (86percent),mostlyfromtheWorldBankgroup. While Kenya’s external debt to GNI ratios are currently less unfavorable than at the beginning of the 1990sandareevensustainableaccordingtoHIPCcriteria(IMF2003),thestockofexternaldebtandits servicing nevertheless poses a major problem for two reasons. First, debt servicing is still a large proportion of export earnings and government expenditures. Second, a large external debt creates uncertaintiesforinvestmentsandunderminesthecredibilityofdomesticpolicies(Elbadawietal.,1997). Pattilloetal.(2002),usingapaneldatasetof93developingcountriesover1969Ͳ98,findthattheaverage 98 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment impactofexternaldebtongrowthbecomesnegativeforadebttoGDPratioof35Ͳ40percent.Kenya’s externaldebtsignificantlyexceedsthisthreshold. TableV.4.DebtIndicatorsofKenya Year 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Totaldebt External ExternalDebt Principal service stocks debt arrears (US$million) (aspercent (aspercentof (US$ Exportsof ofGNIa) million) goodsand services) 4180.6 70.8 38.7 4.1 4602.8 65.9 35.6 6.2 5782.9 75.4 39.8 12.6 5808.9 71.2 39.0 25.5 5889.6 73.7 36.6 49.4 7057.6 87.2 35.4 71.8 7457.8 98.3 32.6 155 6902.6 90.7 31.1 263.3 7115.4 156.0 27.1 409.8 32.9 9.2 7128.9 105.5 7313.4 84.2 30.4 6.1 6811.4 75.4 27.8 14.8 6455.6 62.2 22.1 56.6 6808.1 60.9 23.2 105.7 6450.2 64.5 25.7 177.9 6159.2 61.1 18.7 133.6 5561.6 49.9 15.8 149.9 6031.2 49.2 13.6 236.5 Domestic Foreign Interest Budget Debt financing arrears deficit (US$ ((asper (aspercent (aspercent million) centofGDP ofGDPb) ofbudget b ) deficitb) 10.9 17.3 28.3 40.3 64.6 94.7 140.9 188.8 241.7 81.2 31.4 9.9 27.5 58.2 68.8 42.1 34.4 56.8 3.7 4.8 7.5 3.7 3.8 4.3 5.0 1.3 4.5 5.8 1.3 1.2 2.2 0.8 0.7 0.9 1.6 12 16 27.8 27.1 26 24.6 26.9 25.9 33.5 27.2 24.9 21.5 22.4 21.1 20 19.7 18.1 42.7 40.6 21.9 17.9 21.3 54.3 40.4 44 42.6 6.2 175.1 12.7 48.8 Ͳ135.8 168.5 268.7 84.9 aSource:WorldBank,GlobalDevelopmentFinance,2004. bSource:KenyaEconomicSurvey,VariousIssues. Kenya has yet to develop a coherent strategy for managing aid flows. Aid design, process and implementation have been ad hoc through issues of circulars from the Ministry of Finance (MOF). The defaultpolicyistoaccommodateasmuchforeignaidasismadeavailable.TheexternalLoansandCredits Act specifies limits on borrowing to a principal amount outstanding to no more than 650 million Kenya poundsattheprevailingexchangerate,or“suchhighersumastheNationalAssemblymaybyresolution approve”.Thelatterisaloopholeroutinelyusedbyministersinparliament.Themanagementofforeign aid and external debt are the responsibility of several government ministries and agencies. The main governmentsdepartmentsdealingwithdonorsandloans(theExternalResourcesDepartment(ERD)and Loans Division and the External Debt Management (DMD)) are highly constrained in human resource capacityintermsofnumbersandskills.Thecountryalsolacksdebtmanagementobjectives. 4. PublicDomesticDebt Tofinanceitsbudgetdeficits,Kenyahasborrowedondomesticmarketsaswellasabroad.AsTableV.4. shows, Kenya’s domestic debt accounted for 25 per cent of GDP for much of the 1990s, and foreign financinginsomeyearscoveredahighproportionofthebudgetdeficit.Attheirpeakin1993/94interest payments on domestic debt amounted to 47.6 per cent of government revenues and 24.8 per cent of governmentexpenditurerespectively.Thesepercentagesexceedwidelyusedbenchmarksforsustainable rates of interest on domestic debt. Sterilization of the inflows associated with the foreign financing of 99 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia budget deficits contributed to tight credit markets and recession, thereby undermining growth and contributingtodebtproblems. 5. TheEvolutionofKenya’sExternalDebt Kenya’s first debt problems followed the drought and trade shocks of the early 1980s, with external debt/GNIratioexceeding70percentby1985.Afterabriefimprovement,followingmoreexternaltrade shocks and the ethnic clashes of 1992, debt levels rose again, and Kenya accumulated arrears on both interestandprinciple.ArrearspeakedinmidͲ1993afterthecuttingofaidandofrelationswithdonors.By 1994KenyahadrescheduleddebtsworthUS$500millionitowedtotheParisClub(WorldBank2003).In 1998itbegannegotiationstorescheduledebtowedtoprivatelendersattheLondonClub.82 Debt indicators improved as a result of the 1994 debt rescheduling. When HIPC was launched in 1996, KenyawasdeclaredcapableofachievingsustainabilitywithanNPVofdebttoexportsoflessthan150per cent(148percent).However,furthertrade,climateandpoliticalshocks(surroundingthe1997elections and another suspension of foreign aid) worsened the situation again in the late 1990s (see Table V.4.). Following the approval of an IMF program in 2000, Kenya rescheduled with the Paris Club under “Houston”termswithan agreementcovering US$300millionofarrears.However,arrearscontinued to accumulate and, following a third IMF program in 2003, a new Paris Club deal was secured in January 2004 covering US$353 million of arrears. External debt stocks were not significantly reduced by the agreementsof2000and2004.Indeed,thestockincreasedfromUS$5.5billionin1999toUS$5.7in2004. Inrecentyears,therehasbeensomeimprovementineconomicperformance.Afiscalstrategyhasbeen establishedtocontrolexpenditureoverthemediumtermandtherehasbeenareversalofthedeclining trendindomesticrevenuesaswellasasmallrepaymentofpublicdebtin2004/05.However,Kenyahas been demanding moredebtrelieffollowingthe MDRIinitiative,particularly sinceitsserviceburdenhas beenexceedingMDGspendingforyears. As with Uganda, Kenya’s debt accumulation has been closely related to its fiscal needs. Kenya’s case shows that in the absence of a debt strategy, external debt is unlikely to serve a development agenda. Kenya’s development and public investment expenditure suffered from both fluctuations in external financingandtheburdenofdebtservice Kenya’s debt woes are also related to its continued dependency on agriculture and on primary commodities.SevereclimaticandtermsͲofͲtradeshockshaveunderminedgrowthanddeepenedpoverty. Despite diversification in the production and export base the economy remains vulnerable to adverse exogenousshocks. Kenya has failed to develop significant debtͲ management capacity or clear aid strategies. Arrears have tended to accumulate even when external debt stocks were not growing. Owing to poor relations with donorsthecountryhasalsomissedoutonmajordebtreductioninitiatives.Mostdebtrestructuringshave concentratedonliquidityproblems,i.e.arrears.Weaknessindebtmanagementandaidstrategyarelikely toresultinacontinuationofthecountry’shistoricalpatternofdebtproblems. 82 TheformeragreementledtothecancellationofUS$21millionofarrearsandmaturities,whilethelatterdealeventuallyledto thereschedulingUS$45millionofdebt. 100 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment D. Bolivia’sDebtExperience 1. Introduction Bolivia is topologically rugged country with arid agricultural conditions and low population density. The naturalͲ resourcesͲbased economy has generated only limited employment, and exports earnings have contributedlittletorelievingpoverty.BoliviawasoneofthefirstbeneficiariesofHIPCInitiativesbecause itstrackrecordasaliberalizingreformer.However,sincethelate1990sBolivia’sperͲcapitarealGDPhas stoppedgrowing.Politicaloppositiontoreformhasintensified.ThedebtstockreturnedtopreͲHIPClevels. Bolivia’sexperienceraisesquestionsconcerningcurrentdebtreliefarrangements. 2. OverallEconomicPerformance In the early 1980s, like many other Latin American economies, Bolivia’s economy slid into recession associatedwithsurgingworldinterestratesandthe1982debtcrisis(seeFigureV.3.).Between1981and 1988perͲcapitarealGDPdeclinedby15percent.Overthesubsequent10yearsperͲcapitarealGDPgrew atanannualaveragerateof2percent.In1998Ͳ2003itstagnated. In the 1990s economic growth was revived by rising investment associated with the “capitalization” process (see below) and with the export of natural gas. FDI inflows became more important than debt from the midͲ1990s, and remittances were also an important source of external financing. Inflows of financing from private foreign creditors have been adversely affected by past experience of losses. However,recentlymultilaterallendersliketheAndeanDevelopmentCorporation(CAF)andtheIDAhave beenasignificantsourceofcredit. As an exporter of naturalͲresource products Bolivia has been vulnerable to adverse price shocks and termsͲofͲtrade movements. The prices of its key exports collapsed spectacularly in the early 1980s. Commodity prices did not recover significantly in the 1990s. Figure V.4. shows the decline in Bolivia’s termsoftradesince1991.Exportpriceslostaquarteroftheirvaluebetween1991and2000,whileimport pricesdriftedupwardswithworldinflation.Decliningtermsoftradeunderminedebtexportratios. Additionally Bolivia was affected by a series of shocks as of 1997: El Niño; the East Asian crisis in September1997;theRussiancrisisofAugust1998;andtheBrazilianandArgentinecrisesof1999Ͳ2001. More generally countryͲspecific factors have hindered growth though to an extent difficult to measure. Thesefactorsincludeharshtopographyandclimate,ethnicandlinguisticdiversity,regionaldivisions,and ahistoryofpoliticalinstability. 101 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia FigureV.3.Bolivia:PerͲcapitarealGDP,PrivateConsumption,andPublicExternalDebt, 1970Ͳ2004 $1,800 $1,600 $1,400 $1,200 $1,000 $800 $600 $400 $200 $0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Per-capita real GDP Per-capita real non-government consumption Per-capita real public external debt (incl. debt to IMF and interest arrears) Source:InternationalFinancialStatistics(InternationalMonetaryFund). FigureV.4.Bolivia:TermsofTrade,1991Ͳ2004 (June;1991=100) 140.0 120.0 Import prices --> 100.0 Export prices --> 80.0 Terms of trade --> 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 Terms of trade (1991 = 100) 1997 1998 1999 2000 Export prices (1991 = 100) 2001 2002 2003 2004 Import prices (1991 = 100) Source:CentralBankofBolivia(website). 3. Bolivia’sLiberalizationandStructuralͲReformPolicies Since 1985 successive Bolivian Governments have carried out some of Latin America’s most ambitious liberalizationandreformprograms.Thereformprocessbeganwiththe1985stabilizationprogram,which 102 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment vanquished hyperinflation. The Bolivian Government introduced a “New Economic Policy” of: fiscal discipline;priceandinterestͲrateliberalization;liftingofcontrolsoncrossͲborderfinancialflows;aunified marketͲbased exchange rate; and trade liberalization. Price liberalization, which had ended the control and subsidies of prices, was none the less replaced by price capping in 2000 after export prices rose sharply. ExchangeͲrate management has been at the centre of Bolivia’s stabilization efforts since 1985. The authoritiesallowedthepesotofloatandendedmultipleexchangeͲratepractices.InJanuary1987,anew currency, the “boliviano”, was introduced, at a rate of one peso per million. In early 1988 the new currencystabilizedatabout2.3bolivianosperdollar.TheCentralBankhasmanagedtheexchangerateas acrawlingpeg,movingitinlinewiththedifferencebetweenBolivia’sandworldinflationrates.Thispolicy hasledtothemaintenanceofrelativelyhighforeignexchangereserves(seeFigureV.5.). Persisting dollarization has complicated exchangeͲrate policy. Despite compulsory conversion of dollar bank deposits into Bolivian pesos in the early 1980s, there has remained a large amount of informal dollarization, which has contributed to inflationary pressure. Since 1985 dollarͲdenominated accounts haveaccountedfor85Ͳ90percentofdepositsandloans.Bolivia’scocatradehasalsocontinuedtobringa largeinflowofdollars,contributingtodollarization. Tight monetary control has been fundamental to the maintenance of price and exchangeͲrate stability. Between1987and2004,theaverageannualrateofincreaseinconsumerpriceswasonly8.7percent;and the average annual rate of increase in the price of the U.S.dollar in bolivanos was 8.2percent. On the whole,Bolivia’sexchangeͲratepolicyhascontinuedtosupportstabilizationsince1985. FigureV.5.Bolivia:YearͲendForeignͲExchangeReserves,1980Ͳ2003 Months Per cent of GDP 7.0 16.0 6.0 14.0 12.0 5.0 10.0 4.0 8.0 3.0 6.0 2.0 4.0 1.0 2.0 0.0 0.0 1980 1985 1990 1995 Months of imports of goods and non-factor services 2000 Per cent of GDP Source:CentralBankofBolivia The midͲ1990s witnessed a “second generation” of reforms, which centered on three elements: restructuring and capitalization of key sectors; pensions’ reform; and significant decentralization. The “capitalization” program of 1995Ͳ1996 was an alternative to politically unfeasible privatization. The Governmentauctionedtherightto50ͲperͲcenttemporaryownershipstakeandmanagementcontrolin selected enterprises accompanied by a commitment to carry out specified capital expenditures. The program was successful in the sense that the enterprises which were capitalized exceeded agreed 103 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia investment targets, and services improved (IMF2005). A closely associated reform was the 1996 HydrocarbonsLawdesignedtoenhanceforeigninvestment,particularlyinthedevelopmentofnewfields. The reform did succeed in attracting substantial investments, and led to discovery and exploitation of large gas reserves. However, government revenue from the sector was disappointing, and deepening foreignparticipationhasbeensourceofpopularresentment. In 1997 the Government undertook reform of the troubled pensions system along the lines of Chile’s pension reform, i.e. shifted to a contribution system. As for decentralization, representative governing bodiesweresetupfordepartmentsandprovinces.Theseinstitutionsweregivensignificantfiscalroles, including shares of government revenue. However, the transfer of revenue and responsibilities proved politicallycontentious,andcontributedtoBolivia’sfiscaldifficulties. Throughoutthesechanges,theGovernmentlackedfirmpoliticalsupport.Ambitiousasthereformswere, theydidlittleforordinaryBolivians.Inresponse,manyBolivianstriedtoescapepovertyby“rentͲseeking” strategies involving publicͲsector employment, smuggling activities, or participation in the illicit cocaͲ derivatives trade. Thus the political process became closely linked to persistent pressures for public employmentandsubsidization;smugglingbecameubiquitous;andsuppressionofthecocatradehasbeen impossible. Since securing public positions has become a basic function of political parties, it is hardly surprisingthattheadministrationhasbeenpronetoinefficiency,overstaffingandcorruption. Thereformsofthe1990shavebeguntounderminefiscalbalancesdespitetheexistenceofpolicyrules such as forbidding the printing of money and mechanisms to control government expenditure and to ensureagoodflowofforeigntraderevenues.Taxrevenuehasstabilizedsince1998atabout12Ͳ13per cent of GDP with customs revenues steady at about 1per cent of GDP. Hydrocarbons reform had an unexpectedly large upͲfront fiscal cost, especially when royalties were cut in 1997. Earnings from hydrocarbonshadbeenaround10percentofGDPbutby2004theyhadslidto6.4percent.Receiptsfrom fuel excises initially rose after 1997 but stagnated in 2000 when fuel prices were frozen. On the expendituresidepersonnelcostsare10percentofGDP.Thecostsofdecentralizationandofthepension reformturnedoutwellabovewhatwasanticipated.Lastly,domesticinterestpaymentshavebeenrising inlinewithdomesticborrowing. 4. Bolivia’sExternalDebt:StructureandMainFeatures Externaldebtgrewindollartermsfromthe1970suntilHIPCdebtreliefin2001.Inthe1970sthebulkof thedebtwasbilateraldebtowedtocommercialsourcesandborrowedmostlyfordevelopmentpurposes, notablyinfrastructure(communications,roads,airports).Between1980and1987thegrowthofBolivia’s totalexternaldebtaccelerated,increasingfromUS$2.7billiontoUS$5.8billionͲfromjustunder60tojust over 140per cent of GDP. The prime reason for this surge was increases in world interest rates. In addition, international recession drove down Bolivian export prices. As a result Bolivia could no longer meetitsdebtͲserviceobligationstocommercialbanks,andwentintoarrearsanddefault. Between 1989 and 1992, Bolivia’s overall external debt stock stabilized at about US$4billion, rising to US$5billionafter1996.Meanwhile,highereconomicgrowthduringthemidͲ1990sreducedthedebtͲGDP ratio somewhat. In 1998 and 2001 Bolivia received about US$1billion in HIPC debt relief, reducing the debtͲGDPratio.However,thisreductionprovedtransitoryandwithintwoyearsslowgrowthandheavy borrowing from multilateral sources raised the debtͲGDP ratio to where it had been before HIPC debt reduction. Since the second half of the 1980s Bolivia has cut its dependence on commercial bank finance. Multilateralagenciesincreasedtheirlendinginthelate1980stoassiststabilization,andinthe1990sto support liberalization and structural reform. Thus, of the endͲ2004 total external debt of US$4.6billion 104 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment US$4.3billionwasowedtomultilateralentitieswiththeIDAaccountingforUS$1.7billion(seeFiguresV.6. andV.7.). FigureV.6.Bolivia:YearͲEndPublicandPubliclyͲGuaranteedExternalDebt,1970Ͳ2004 (US$billion) 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 Multilateral Bilateral Private sources: Source:GlobalDevelopmentFinance(WorldBank). Debtserviceremainedwithinarangeof4to5percentuntiltheendofthe1990s.Itthensurgedbrieflyin 2000and2001duetorelativelyhighrepaymentflows.Bolivia’sexternaldebtͲserviceͲtoͲexportsratiowas generallybeenabove20percentuntilitfellbelow20percentafterHIPCdebtreduction.Bolivia’sinterest burdenwaskeptdownbytheconcessionalnatureofmuchofitsdebtsincethesecondhalfofthe1980s. FigureV.7.Bolivia:YearͲEndPublicandPubliclyͲGuaranteedExternalDebt,1970Ͳ2004 (PercentofGDP) 200.0 180.0 160.0 140.0 120.0 100.0 80.0 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 Multilateral Bilateral Private sources: Source:GlobalDevelopmentFinance(WorldBank). 105 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia Bolivia debt management has improved significantly since the early 1980s. At that time, Bolivia had no administrative system of debt management and governance as such, though the Government formed committeestodealwithcommercialbanks.In1985debtwasconsolidatedinthenationalTreasury,anda ministerialͲlevelcommitteewasformedtoworkoutastrategy.In1987commercialbanksdecidedtooffer reliefthroughdebtbuybacksbuttheoperationswerecarriedoutadhocbyexpertswithoutthehelpof sophisticateddebtͲmanagementsystems. Under the basic institutional arrangement eventually adopted the Government assigned the bulk of managing and monitoring of external debt to the Central Bank because of its institutional depth and analyticalcapacities.Sincethe1980sBolivia’stechnicaldebtͲmanagementcapacityhasimprovedsteadily andBolivia’sdebtpoliciesarenowhighlytransparent.TheConstitutionrequiresparliamenttoapproveall newborrowing. 5. DomesticPublicDebt Alongside of its external borrowing to finance government expenditures Bolivia has also borrowed domestically particularly after the 1985 reforms. Thus domestic public debt rose steadily from 1991 to overUS$1bnin2000,thendoublingtojustunderUS$2billionby2004,i.e.from13to21percentofGDP. The issuance of domestic obligations can help Governments to deepen their financial sector and widen theirrevenuebase.ButaswithotherHIPCs,Boliviahadtopayhighinterestratesonitsdomesticdebt, whichisnotcontractedonconcessionalterms.Interestpaymentsoninternaldebtrodefrom0.4to1.8 per cent of GDP between 1998 and 2004, while interest payments on external debt remained stable aroundonepercentofGDP.Domesticdebtreached21percentofGDPin2004,andtotalpublicdebt95 per cent of GDP. Initial fiscal sustainability targets under HIPC programs overlooked this source of indebtednessandtheresultingpressureonfiscalbalances. 106 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableV.5.Bolivia:DomesticPublicDebt1991Ͳ2004 Year DomesticDebt (US$million) 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 385.6 396.2 296.8 97.5 217.0 438.8 508.4 827.9 983.6 1100.1 1508.6 1504.3 1724.4 1992.9 Source:Cowanetal2006. TotalPublicdebt (US$million) 4258.4 4429.8 4300.1 4576.5 4999.6 5080.8 5040.0 5487.3 5557.4 5560.1 5920.6 5804.7 6768.7 6944.0 Domesticdebt (aspercentof GDP) 7.2 7.0 5.2 1.6 3.2 6.0 6.4 9.8 11.9 13.2 18.7 18.3 20.1 21.3 TotalPublic debt(aspercent ofGDP) 86.9 85.5 80.2 78.3 77.8 74.8 70.1 74.5 79.3 79.7 92.2 89.1 98.8 95.5 6. PastandPresentExternalDebtPracticesandStrategy Sincetheearly1980sthreebroadphasesofBolivia’sdebtstrategycanbedistinguished.Thefirstbegan withtheonsetofthedebtcrisisin1982.AtthattimeBoliviareliedheavilyonexternaldebttocoverits fiscaldeficit,andwhendebtflowswerecutoff,theGovernmentshiftedtomonetaryfinancing,generating hyperinflation.In1984Boliviadeclaredamoratoriumondebtservice.ThemarketvalueofBolivia’sdebt to commercial banks plunged to 10Ͳ15per cent of its face value by the midͲ1980s. The second phase lasted from the August1985 stabilization program until 2000 and consisted largely of reducing debt throughvariousinitiativesandincreasingrecoursetoconcessionalflows.Since2001newmultilateraldebt inflowshaveoffsetHIPCdebtreduction,politicalturmoilhasintensified,andGDPgrowthhasstagnated. OncethestabilizationprogrambeganinAugust1985,theauthoritiesrestoredrelationswiththeIMFand other creditors. The 1986 IMF program opened the way to new financing. Bolivia took a pioneering approachtoitscommercialͲbankdebt(aboutUS$650millionin1986).Usingfundsprovidedbydonors,it retired the bulk of its debt by purchasing it at deeply discounted values.83Bolivia’s debt to commercial bankswasmostlyeliminatedbytheearly1990s. Thereafter, Bolivia sought relief on its bilateral debt through the Paris Club. It went through six reschedulingsbetween1986and1995.Between1986and2003,BoliviahadthreeIMFprogramsinvolving SDR515million, including one of the first Poverty Reduction and Growth (PRG) Facilitiesin 1998. In April2003, Bolivia secured an IMF agreement for SDR 129 million amidst economic and political crises. Fearing that the collapse of the agreement would aggravate Bolivia’s problems, the IMF waived some conditions,andBoliviadrewSDR102millionbyMarch2005(IMF2005). In September1998, multilateral and bilateral creditors provided Bolivia debt relief amounting to US$449million in netͲpresentͲvalue (NPV) terms, at the “completion point” of its HIPC process. Of this total,bilateralcreditorsandtheIADBeachaccountedforabout35percent,theWorldBankforabout12 per cent, CAF for 9 per cent, and the IMF for about 6percent. The conditions Bolivia satisfied for 83 TheBolivianbuybackoperationof1987,whereUS$253millionwererepurchasedatabout11centsperdollar,wasoneofthe firstlargeͲscalebuybackcarriedoutwiththespecificpurposeofreducingacountry’sexternaldebtsincethe1930s. 107 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia completion were its history of IMFͲ led programs. The estimated equivalent stock reduction was US$760million(7.8percentof1998GDP)(IMF&IDA1998). In May2001, Bolivia became the second country to reach its completion point under “enhanced” HIPC. This time, official creditors provided debt relief of US$834million in NPV terms. Conditions satisfied for completionincludedasuccessfulreviewofperformanceunderthe1998PRGFacility,theformulationofa PovertyReductionStrategy,andcontinuedimplementationofsocialͲsectorprograms. Subsequently, however, Bolivia’s economic performance has deteriorated. A widening public deficit meant that Bolivia had to secure increased financing. Over 2001Ͳ2003, the Government used external sourcestocoverabout60percentofitsfinancingrequirements.Ofthetotalaboutonehalfcamefrom theIADBandtheWorldBankatconcessionalratesandtheremainderfromtheCAFatnonͲconcessional rates. The premise of Bolivia’s debt strategy was that stabilization, liberalization, structuralͲreform and debtͲ reduction would create a dynamic economy and high real GDP growth. But the results have been disappointing.TheIMF2005staff’sreportnotesthatBolivia’spostͲ1998slowdownmaybeunderstoodas theconsequenceof“aprotractedsequenceofexternalanddomesticshocks…”(IMF2005,p.12).Reforms had not achieved their goals, and the political and social roots of Bolivia’s problems were deeper than recognized. ForthemajorityofBolivians,theoverridingobjectiveofstructuraleconomic policyought tohavebeen theidentificationofways tobringabout theirparticipationintheeconomy. However,liberalizedprices discouraged enterprise in areas capable of generating employment, and reforms led to cuts in public sector employment. Through their political protests Bolivians are now demanding that the Government make these problems its highest priority. Negotiated debt relief is of little consequence in this context, since as in much of the rest of Latin America, repayments are viewed as illegitimate since debt was accumulatedinthefirstplacewithoutpopularconsent. It is not clear how much Bolivia benefited from the HIPC initiative. By the time Bolivia negotiated HIPC relief it had already reduced burdensome commercial and bilateral debts. When debt reduction is not accompaniedbymeasuressuccessfulinreducingbothinternalandexternalborrowingrequirements,debt indicators are likely to grow again. The IMF failed to grasp the deeper problems behind Bolivia’s debt accumulation, hiding instead behind customary calls to deepen reforms along lines already tried unsuccessfully. E. DebtExperiencesCompared Despite nearly three decades of adjustment, stabilization, extensive reforms and liberalization, Uganda, KenyaandBoliviahavenotescapedtheirpredicamentashighlyindebtedpooreconomies.Comparisonof thethreeeconomiespointstothreecommonremainingfeatures: x x x Failuretoreducepovertysignificantly; Failuretogeneratesustainedgrowth;and Failure to reduce their vulnerability to external shocks and the continued concentration on vulnerablesourcesofincome. TheassumptionofIMFandWorldBankprogramshadbeenthatreformandliberalizationwoulddeliver growth by instituting prudent macroeconomic management and eliminating price distortions. In many cases, the policy measures not only caused momentary pain but also had longerͲterm adverse effects. Higher interest rates did not automatically result in financial deepening, but did increase defaults of 108 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment privateenterprisesandthefiscalcostsofdomesticborrowing(orboth).ExchangeͲratedevaluationfailed to make primary commodity exports more competitive, and trade liberalization undermined the government revenue base. Cuts in government spending undermined public investment, thereby weakeningprivateinvestmentandhumancapitalformation. InallthreecasesthereformsadoptedwerenotsufficienttoovercomemanydeepͲrootedproblemsand structuralweaknesses.Fiscaldisciplinehasbeenbeneficial,butitdoesnotexpandataxandrevenuebase curtailedbymeasuressuchastariffremovals.Hence,40Ͳ50percentofgovernmentactivitiesinUganda and Kenya continue to be financed by foreign aid. Likewise, orthodox reforms have not reduced high productionandtransportationcostsinherenttothethreecountries’difficultgeographyandtopography. Neither the reforms nor the debt initiatives have adequately recognized or produced solutions to the extreme vulnerability of the three countries to strong external shocks. All three countries have a heavy concentration of economic activity and exports in a few primary and unprocessed commodities, whose prices have been highly volatile and subject to sharp declines. The effects of this concentration are exacerbatedbythedependenceoflargepartsofthepopulationonrainͲfedagriculture. Itisagainstthiscontextthatthethreedebtorshavehadtomanagetheirexternaldebtburdens.Whilethe countries were catapulted into debt traps at different times and with different intensities, debt sustainabilitycontinuestoeludeall three.Althoughinheriteddebtstockshavebeenreducedand there have been shifts to concessional financing and grants, the three debtors continue to experience the pressuresofhighdebtburdens. Recent debt crises in all three cases have originated in the government sector, i.e. the inability of the Government to service foreign loans. However, the defaults and arrears were caused less by the ballooningofdebtstocksthanbysuddenandunexpectedsharpshortfallsinrevenuesduetoexogenous shocks,namelyrisinginterestratesorcollapsingexportearningswhichleddebtratiostosoar. AllthreeGovernmentshaveincreasinglyresortedtodomesticborrowing,albeittodifferentdegrees,to financegovernmentbudgets.Domesticdebtsanddebtburdenshaveonlyrecentlybeenincludedindebt sustainability analyses (World Economic and Social Survey 2005). Domestic debt tends to be more expensive than external finance, so that its costs worsen fiscal difficulties or widen fiscal deficits. This underminesthebeneficialeffectsofoperationsreducingexternaldebt,andisoneofthereasonsforthe failureofHIPCinitiatives.InUgandaandKenyadomesticdebthasalsobeenissuedtosterilizeofficialaid inflows.InUgandasuchsterilizationhashadtheconsequencethattherewouldbenoimprovementinits debtserviceafterHIPCIIafterallowanceforthecostoftheTreasuryBillsissuetosterilizeaidflows. Atthetimeoftheirfirstcrisesnoneofthethreecountrieshadinplaceameaningfuldebtstrategyoreven good management systems to monitor or analyse debt. This has changed substantially in the case of UgandaandBolivia,whichbothnowhaveadequatetechnicalcapacitytomanagetheirdebt.OnlyKenya stilllacksanadequatedebtmanagementsystem. Since the 1990s, debt strategies have been determined by official creditors. Rescue from defaults and fresh finance depended on the IMF and multilaterals, which initiated the countries’ adjustment and reformprogramsaspreͲconditionsfordebtrestructuringswiththeLondonandParisClubs.Thedetailsof theagreementsreachedexplainwhytherewasaneedforcontinuousandrepeatedreschedulingefforts. These resulted from early cutͲoff points, the exclusion of too many types of debts and creditors, debt reliefinadequatetoeaserepaymentdifficulties. ThelaunchoftheHIPCinitiativewasarecognitionofthefollowing: x x Debtproblemsparticularlyforpoorercountriesreflectinsolvencyratherthanilliquidity; PartialandprotractedreͲschedulinghasnotprovidedapermanentexitfromrestructuring;and 109 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia x Reachingsustainabledebtpathsrequiresdebtreduction. The fact that HIPC had to be enhanced almost as soon as it was born highlighted its similarity to the reluctant and partial approach to debt problems that characterized previous initiatives. It also reflected weak analytical bases, which, for example, overlooked fiscal criteria for sustainability. More seriously, debt sustainability analyses were not based on realistic and comprehensive scenarios, and underestimated thevulnerabilitytoand theextent ofexogenousshocks (see forexample Nissankeand Ferranini (2006). Even the most compliant countries included in the initiative had been consistently thrownoffcoursebysuchshocks,includingduringandafterHIPC. ThepostͲHIPCproblemsofUgandaandBoliviarevealotherflaws: x x x x Thelimitsofanarrowfocuswhichdefinestheattainmentofdebtsustainabilityintermsofdebt ratiosbelowthresholdsatonepointintime; FailuretotakeintoaccountthattheriseinpostͲHIPCborrowingcouldquicklyreversegains(the resultinUganda’scaseofafailuretoplacealimitonthestockofnewborrowing); Theproblemofusingloansinsteadofgrantstofinancepovertyalleviationprograms; Themoregeneraldifficultyforpoorereconomiesofachievingthereformsoffiscalpolicywhich makepossibleobservanceofdomesticdebtthresholds. In 2007 Bolivia had unsustainable debt based on fiscal criteria and Uganda’s debt sustainability has deteriorated since HIPC II completion. Kenya’s debt indicators remain unsatisfactory and its second PovertyandGrowthFacilityisunderreview. F. ConcludingRemarks All three countries covered by this study have extensively liberalized their trade and foreignͲexchange regimes and their financial sectors. Part of this liberalization was undertaken at the countries’ own initiative.Butwithrespecttomanyofthemeasuresthecountrieshadlittlechoice,sincereceivingdebt relief and aid from multilaterals depended on implementation of conditions in agreed programs. These conditionslimitedthespaceofpolicymakersandfailedtodelivereitherbroadͲbasedorsustainedgrowth. These experiences show that the programs on which debt relief was conditional were based on an inadequateapproach.Byfailingtodelivergrowthortostabilizerevenuesandexportearnings,theyalso failed to provide a sufficient improvement in the ability to repay or service debt. Debt initiatives were blinkeredandpartialintheircoverage,draggingeachcountryintoanunendingseriesofnegotiationsand reschedulings. Onelessonoftheseexperiencesistheneedforamuchdeeperandmorecomprehensiveunderstanding of debt sustainability and of solvency which goes beyond thresholds and liquidity ratios, however rigorously derived. Another lesson is that it is impossible to use debt to spur economic growth and development without a coherent debt management strategy. A third lesson is that new external borrowing by poorer countries will contribute to growth only if directed at expenditures that enhance productivityandcompetitiveness. 110 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References AfricanDevelopmentBankandOECD(2005/2006).AfricanEconomicOutlook,2005/06,Kenya.Available at:www.oecd.org/dataoecd/34/31/36740590.pdf. AjayiSI(1991).MacroeconomicApproachtoExternalDebt:TheCaseofNigeria.AERCResearchPaper,8, December. AllenMandNankaniG(2004).DebtSustainabilityinLowͲIncomeCountries–ProposalforanOperational Framework and Policy Implications. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund and InternationalDevelopmentAssociation,February. AndersenLE and Osvaldo N (2000). TheHIPCInitiativeinBolivia.LaPaz, UniversidadCatólicaBoliviana, November. Available at: www.bcb.gov.bo/deudaexterna/documentos/general/the_hipc_ initative_in_bolivia.pdf. AtingiͲEgo M (2005). Budget Support, Aid Dependency, and Dutch Disease: the Case of Uganda. Cape Town,ConferenceonPractioners’ForumonBudgetSupport,May2005. Aiyar S, Berg A and Hussain M (2005). The Macroeconomic Challenge of More Aid. Finance and Development, 42 (3), September. Available at: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2005/09/ aiyar.htm. AzamJP(1997).PublicDebtandtheExchangeRateintheCFAFrancZone.JournalofAfricanEconomies,6 (1),March. BeckermanP(2006).Bolivia’sEconomicPerformanceandExternaldebtSincethe1980s.UNCTADproject onCapacityBuildingforDebtSustainabilityinDevelopingCountries.Geneva(January). BeckermanPandSolimanoAeds.(2002).Ecuador’sCrisisandDollarization,Washington.DC,WorldBank. Bleaney et al. (1995). Revenues Instability with Particular Reference to SubͲSaharan Africa. Journal of DevelopmentStudies,31(6),August. BurnsideCandDollarD(2000).AidPoliciesandGrowth.AmericanEconomicReview,90:847–868. CollierPandGunningJ(1999).ExplainingAfrica’sEconomicPerformance.JournalofEconomicLiterature, March. Collier P and Reinikka R (2001). Post Reconstruction and Liberalization: An Overview. In: Collier and Reinikkaeds.Uganda’sRecovery.TheRoleofFarms,FirmsandGovernment.Washington,DC,The WorldBank. CowanK,LevyͲYeyatiE,PanizzaUandSturzeneggerF(2006).SovereignDebtintheAmericas:NewData andStylizedFacts.ResearchDepartmentWorkingPaper,577.InterͲAmericanDevelopmentBank, October. Christensen J (2004). Domestic Debt Markets in SubͲSaharan Africa. IMF Working Paper, 04 (46), Washington, DC. Available at: http://www.internationalmonetaryfund.com/external/pubs/ft/wp /2004/wp0446.pdf. EasterlyW(2001).TheElusiveQuestforEconomicGrowth.Cambridge,Massachussets,MITPress. EasterlyWandSchmidtͲHebbelK(1993).FiscalDeficitsandMacroeconomicPerformanceinDeveloping Countries.TheWorldBankResearchObserver,8(2). ElbadawiI,NduluBandNdung’uN(1997).DebtOverhangandEconomicinSubͲSaharanAfrica.In:Iqbal andKanbur.ExternalFinancingforLowIncomeCountries.WashingtonDC,InternationalMonetary Fund. 111 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia Geithner T (2003). Sustainability Assessments Ͳ Review of Application and Methodological Refinements. IMFPolicyDevelopmentandReviewDepartment,Washington,DC,June. Geithner T (2002). Assessing Sustainability. Washington, DC, IMF Policy Development and Review Department,May. Government of Uganda (1998). Vision 2025: A Strategic Framework for National Development. BackgroundPapers,2,Kampala. GreeneJandVillanuevaD(1990).PrivateInvestmentinDevelopingCountries:AnEmpiricalAnalysis.IMF StaffWorkingPaper(WP/90/40).Washington,DC. Henstridge M and Kasekende L (2001). Exchange Reforms, Stabilisation and Fiscal Management. In: Reinikka and Collier P eds. Uganda’s Recovery. The Role of Farms, Firms and Government. The WorldBank.Washington,DC. IMF(2003).Kenya:DebtSustainabilityAnalysis.IMFCountryReport,03(400).Washington,DC. IMF (2004). SubͲSaharan Africa Regional Economic Outlook. Washington, DC. Available at: www.internationalmonetaryfund.com/external/pubs/ft/afr/reo/2004/eng/02/pdf/reo1004.pdf. IMF (2005). Bolivia: Ex Post Assessment of Longer Term Program Engagement. Washington, DC, IMF Country Report, 05 (139),April. IMFandInternationalDevelopment Association (1997).Bolivia: FinalDocumentontheInitiativeforthe HeavilyIndebtedPoorCountries(HIPC).27August. IMF and International Development Association (1998). Bolivia: Initiative for the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries(HIPC).September. IMF and International Development Association (2000). Bolivia: Decision Point Document for the EnhancedHeavilyIndebtedPoorCountriesHIPC)Initiative.January. IMFandInternationalDevelopmentAssociation(2001).TheChallengeofMaintainingLongͲTermExternal DebtSustainability.Washington,DC,April. IMF and International Development Association (2001). Bolivia: Completion Point Document for the EnhancedHeavilyIndebtedPoorCountries(HIPC)Initiative.Washington,DC,May. Independent Evaluation Group (2006). Debt Relief for the Poorest: An Evaluation of the HIPC Initiative, WorldBank.Washington,DC.Availableat:www.worldbank.org/ieg. Johnson A (2001). Key Issues for Analysing Domestic Debt Sustainability. Publication, 5. Debt Relief International. Kenya (2003). Economic Recovery Strategy for Wealth and Employment Creation 2003–2007. Nairobi, GovernmentPrinter. KitabireDandOumoPM(2005).Countrystudy:Uganda.UNCTADprojectonCapacityBuildingforDebt SustainabilityinDevelopingCountries.Geneva(December). M’Amanja D and Morrissey O (2005). Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth in Kenya. Working Paper, CP05/06. Centre for Research in Economic Development and International Trade, University of Nottingham. MatyamaF(2001).TheNationalDebtandtheHIPCDebtReliefInitiative–Uganda’sExperience.Kampala, PaperPresentedattheILIWorkshoponDebtManagementandNationalBudgeting,September. MbireBandAtingiM(1997).GrowthandForeignDebt:theUgandaExperience.AERCResearchPaper,66. 112 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment MoralesJA(1988).InflationStabilizationinBolivia.In:BrunoM,diTellaG,DornbuschR,andFischerSeds. InflationStabilization:TheExperienceofIsrael,Argentina,Brazil,BoliviaandMexico.Cambridge, Massachusetts,MITPress:307Ͳ347. MussaM(2000).MeetingtheChallengesofGlobalisation.Nairobi,PaperpreparedforthePlenarySession oftheAERCBiͲAnnualResearchWorkshop,May. MuwangaͲZake ESK (2000). External Debt Management and Policy. Kampala, Paper Presented to the MasterofArtsEconomicPolicyManagementClassatMakerereUniversity,July. MuwangaͲZakeESKandStephenN(2001).TheHIPCDebtReliefInitiative–Uganda’sExperience.Helsinki, PaperPresentedattheUnitedNations(UNI/WIDER)ConferenceonDebtRelief,August. MwegaFM(2005).ExternalDebtManagementinKenya.UNCTADprojectonCapacityBuildingforDebt SustainabilityinDevelopingCountries.Geneva(July). MwegaFM,MwangiNandOleweͲOchiloF(1994).MacroeconomicConstraintsandMediumͲTermGrowth inKenya:AThreeͲGapAnalysis.AERCResearchPaper,23. Mwega FM and Ndung’u NS (1996). Macroeconomic Policies and Exchange Rate Management Kenya. Report of an AERC/ICEG Collaborative Project on Macroeconomic Policies and Exchange Rate ManagementinAfricanCountries. MwegaFMandNdung’uNS(2004).ExplainingAfrica’sGrowthPerformance:ACaseStudyofKenya.Paper preparedforanAERCCollaborativeResearchProject. NjeruJ(2004).TheImpactofForeignAidonPublicExpenditure:TheCaseofKenya.AERCResearchPaper, 135,March. Nissanke M and Ferrarini B (2006). Assessing the Aid Allocation and Debt Sustainability Framework: Working Towards Incentive Compatible Aid Contracts. Helsinki, Wider Development Conference onAid:Principles,PoliciesandPerformance,June. O’BrienFSandRyanTCI(1999).AidandReforminAfrica:KenyaCaseStudy.Mimeo,WorldBank. Oumo PM (2005). Debt Management Process: Uganda’s Experience, Current Situation & Future Plans. Tokyo,aPaperpresentedattheExternalDebtManagementWorkshop,January. PattilloCA,PoirsonHandRicciL(2002).ExternalDebtandGrowth.IMFWorkingPaper02(69). PsacharopoulosGetal.(1992).PovertyandIncomeDistributioninLatinAmerica:TheStoryofthe1980s. Report,27,Washington,DC,LatinAmericaandCaribbeanTechnicalDepartment,WorldBank. PratiAandTresselT(2006).WhatistheMostEffectiveMonetaryPolicyforAidͲReceivingCountries?IMF, EconomicandSocialAffairs,DESAWorkingPaper,12(ST/ESA/2006/DWP/12).February. Rajan R (2004). Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis Prevention. IMF Occasional Paper, 237, Washington, DC. TheRepublicofUganda(2004).PovertyEradicationActionPlan2004/05–2007/08.Kampala,Ministryof Finance. The Republic of Uganda (2002). Uganda PostͲHIPC Debt Strategy and New Financing Workshop Report. Kampala,November. The Republic of Uganda (2004). Uganda National Debt Strategy and New Financing Workshop. Draft Report,Kampala,July. RoeARandGriggsJ(1990).InternalDebtManagementinAfrica.AERCSpecialPaper,4. RongeE(2001).ExportBoomRegimesandtheDebtAccumulationProcess:TheKenyanExperience. Helsinki,WiderDevelopmentConferenceonDebtRelief,17–18August. 113 TheDebtExperiencesofUganda,KenyaandBolivia Rudaheranwa N (1999). Transport Cost and Export Trade of Developing Countries: A Case Study of Uganda.PhDThesis,UniversityofNottingham. SachsJ(1986).TheBolivianHyperinflationandStabilization.Cambridge,Massachusetts,NationalBureau ofEconomicResearchWorkingPaper,2073,November. Serven L (1997). Irreversibility, Uncertainty and Private Investment: Analytical Issues and some Lessons fromAfrica.JournalofAfricanEconomies,Supplementtovol.6(3). StiglitzJ(2002).GlobalizationanditsDiscontents.England,PenguinBooks. UNCTAD(2000).CapitalFlowsandGrowthinAfrica.Geneva. Unidad de Análisis de Política Economica, Ministerio de Finanzas, Bolivia(2000).Bolivia: Economic Performance and Social Issues: From the 80s Up to Date. March. Available at: www.nssd.net /pdf/boecon1.pdf. United Nations (2005). World Economic and Social Survey. New York. Available at: www.un.org/esa/ policy/wess/wess2005files/wess2005web.pdf. United Nations (2007). World Economic Situation and Prospects. New York. Available at: www.un.org/esa/policy/wess/wesp2007files/wesp2007.pdf. vanTrotsenburgAandMacArthurA(1997).TheHIPCInitiative:DeliveringDebtRelieftoPoorCountries. Washington,DC,InternationalMonetaryFundandWorldBank,February. World Bank (1992). Kenya Financial Sector Adjustment Project. Project Completion Report. Washington, DC,December. WorldBank(2003).Kenya:PolicyAgendatoRestoreGrowth.Washington,DC. WereM(2001).TheImpactofExternalDebtonEconomicGrowthandPrivateInvestmentsinKenya:An EmpiricalAssessment.Helsinki,WiderDevelopmentConferenceonDebtRelief17–18August. 114 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERVI CASESTUDIES:ARGENTINAAND THEREPUBLICOFKOREA MarioDamill,RobertoFrenkel,MartínͲRapettiandYungChulPark84 A. Introduction This paper examines recent crises that shook the economies of Argentina and the Republic of Korea as well as the international financial system. Both were capitalͲaccount crises in apparently successful middleͲincomedevelopingeconomies.Whilebothcountrieshadexperienceddebtcrisesbeginninginthe late 1970s, Argentina’s default of 2000Ͳ2001 and the Republic of Korea meltͲdown of 1998 were exceptional in their severity. International rescue packages led by the IMF were organized in both instancesandwereasourceofpoliticalcontroversy. TheArgentinecrisisanddefault,thelargestinrecentyears,isstillsubjecttodisagreementastoitscauses. SectionIIascribescentralimportancetoawrongdiagnosisofthecrisisbytheIMF,whichconcentratedon addressing a fiscal disequilibrium during a liquidity crunch. The country’s political leadership shared the IMF’s belief, as is evident from the various fiscal adjustment programs undertaken. Several factors Ͳ externalaswellasinternalͲdidpushpublicdebttowardsunsustainablelevels,particularlyinthecontext of a recession. However, structural features of the economy such as the convertibility regime and the dollarization of the banking system were of critical importance to the default, which led to a historical fallingͲoutbetweenArgentinaandtheIMFandanacrimoniousdebtrestructuring. 84 Section B is based on a paper by Mario Damill, Roberto Frenkel and Martín Rapetti (Researchers at CEDES, Buenos Aires) (Damill, Frenkel and Rapetti (2005)), Section C is based on the paper by Yung Chul Park (Graduated School of International Studies,SeoulNationalUniversity)(Park(2005)). 115 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea TheexperienceoftheRepublicofKoreadescribedinSectionIIIalsosuggeststhatIMFpolicyprescriptions worsened the crisis by helping to push the economy into default. Section III also highlights the role of banking crises, collapsing financial markets, and irresponsible foreign borrowing by chaebols. Yet, as in Argentina,theimmediatetriggersofthecrisiswereadverseexternalshocks,namelytheweakeningofthe Yenandregionalcontagion.SectionIVcomparesmajorfeaturesofthetwocrises. B. LessonsfromtheArgentineCrisisandDefault 1. Introduction This section challenges the leading explanations of the latest Argentinean debt crisis, whereby uncontrolledpublicspendingisperceivedasthemaincauseofdebtaccumulation,crisisanddefault. Firstly, it is shown that the effects of rises in interest rates rises were the main driver of public debt dynamicsattheendofthe1990s.Evenifallowanceismadefortheeffectofuncertaintiesaboutpublic debt sustainability on investors’ assessment of the country’s position, the main source of the deteriorationwasnotfiscalpolicybutfinancialfragilityandcontagion. Secondly, the role of macroeconomic policies – particularly exchange rate policy Ͳ in generating an unsustainabledebtpathisemphasized.InthisregardtheArgentinecaseisanextremeexampleofbadly managed financial integration leading to high interest rates, low growth, and vulnerability to financial contagionandvolatilityofcapitalflows(Frenkel,2003b). Thirdly,thepaperchallengesacommonlyheldopinionthatthedefaultdecisionwasmainlyresponsible for the deep crisis in Argentina. It shows on the contrary that the abrupt contraction in activity and employment occurred before the default as the Government tried to keep debt service on track. The defaultprovedtobeoneoftriggersthatsubsequentlyallowedrecovery. Fourthly, the section examines how debt restructuring took place in the context of a confrontational relationshipbetweentheIMFandArgentina.Themostunusual–indeedunprecedentedͲfeatureofthis processwasthattheIMFdidnotparticipateinthedesignoftherestructuring. 2. MacroeconomicPerformanceinthe1990s Between 1977 and 1982 Argentina went through a phase of financial opening and accelerated indebtednessthatendedinmassivecapitalflight,exchangeͲratecrisis,anddefault.Thiswasfollowedbya longperiodofinternationalcreditrationingbetween1982and1990.The1991Ͳ2001periodalsoendedin crisisanddefault.Adistinguishingfeatureofthesetwoperiodsistheroleplayedbytheprivatesectorin thegenerationofexternalfinancialobligations.Despitethestrongriseintotalexternaldebtinthe1990s theshareofpublicexternalintotaldebtdeclinedbyover20percentagepointswhichsuggeststhatfiscal disequilibriumwasnotthemaincauseofthecrises.85 Argentinaenteredbothphasesofacceleratedindebtednessinthecontextofstabilizationprogramsbased on a fixed nominal exchange rate. These programs set in motion proͲcyclical macroeconomic processes which left the economy vulnerable to negative external financial shocks. (Frenkel, 1983; Taylor, 1998; Frenkel,2003a). In1981thestabilizationpolicybasedontheexchangeͲrateanchorwasabandoned.Anewphasefollowed, characterized by massive devaluations of the peso. These devaluations were accompanied by higher 85 SelectedindicatorsforArgentina’seconomyduring1977Ͳ2006aregivenintable1. 116 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment internationalinterestratesandaneventualpeakoftheratioofforeigndebttoGDPofnearly60percent in 1982. The public sector’s share in external debt also rose in this period because the Government assumed a considerable proportion of the private foreign debt. During the second phase of the 1990s totalexternaldebtincreasedbutmostofthatrisewasgeneratedbytheprivatesector. Thefiscalbalancewentthroughthreeperiodsinthe1990s.(seetableVI.2.)During1991Ͳ94theaverage deficit,whichinthe1980swasabout7percentofGDP,decreasedtolessthan1percentofGDP.This wasmainlyduetoanimprovementintheoverallpublicsectorbalance.Nonetheless,publicdebtrosein the early 1990s because the Government assumed debts that were not registered in the fiscal balance, especiallydebtsofpublicͲsectorpurveyorsandofthesocialsecuritysystem. In1994newnegativepressuresemergedonpublicfinancesduetothreefactors.Firstly,asocialsecurity reform that created the Private Pension Funds led to a significant fall in contributions. Secondly, the regionalboomwasfollowedbytheconsequencesoftheTequilaeffectin1995,whichwasmanifestedina sharp rise in the countryͲrisk premium of Argentina’s interest rates (see table VI.3.). Thirdly, the Governmentattemptedtocountertheseconsequencesbyloweringthetaxburdenontradables.Between 1995and1997thepublicdebt/GDPratioroseslightlybeforestabilizing. The Russian and Brazilian crises in 1998 resulted in a new jump in the countryͲrisk premium. This was accompanied by a recession and increased financial vulnerability of debtors. A sharp rise in interest payments had already begun in 1996. By 2000 these payments amounted to nearly 19 per cent of governmentrevenues.Recessionandhigherinterestrateslargelyexplaintheexplosivepathstakenbythe publicdebtanddeficit,whichhadtheconsequencethatthepublicdebt/GDPratioincreasedbyalmost20 percentagepointsbetween1997and2001. 3. MacroeconomicPerformanceBeforeandAftertheDefault Themacroeconomicstoryofthelate1990scanbedescribedasaswingfromeuphoriatodepression.The negative turnaround in the external environment experienced in 1997Ͳ1998 left the economy with a significantandgrowingcurrentͲaccountdeficit,anappreciatedrealexchangerate,andavisiblelackof policyinstrumentstodealwiththeproblem.Hence,restrictivefiscalpolicieshadtobearthemainburden of attempts at adjustment. The expectation was that fiscal discipline would trigger greater confidence, leading to a recovery in domestic expenditure which would push the economy out of recession. De la Rua’sadministrationacceptedthisargument,andtheIMFgaveitssealofapproval. However, the result was failure. Fiscal policy alone was impotent to counter large macroeconomic imbalances,whichweremostlyrootedintheexternalsectoroftheeconomy.Theeconomysufferedthe longestrecessionsincetheFirstWorldWar. Capital inflows contracted sharply in response to the contagion caused by the Mexican crisis at the beginningof1995(seetableVI.4.).ForeignͲexchangereservesalsofell.However,therecessionwasshortͲ livedthankstotheeffectsoftheIMFͲledpackageoffinancialsupport.AfterabriefrecoverythecountryͲ risk premium began to increase again after the devaluation in Thailand in 1997. As noted above, a sustainedcontractionstartedaftertheRussiandefaultin1998. Duringtheearly1990stherewerelargeprivatecapitalinflows,followedbyacontractionin1995.Capital inflowstothepublicsectorweremorestable,beingsustainedintherecessionof1995andduringthat which began in 1998. Private capital inflows recovered in 1996 but were accompanied by outflows ofa similarmagnitude.From1998onwardsthenetinflowturnedintoalargenetoutflow. 117 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea Theincreaseintheforeignpublicdebtoftheentireperiodfrom1991onwardsexceededUS$35billion. ThisamountisquiteclosetotheincreaseintheforeignfinancialobligationsofthenonͲfinancialprivate sectorwhich,however,weremorethanoffsetbytheriseofthesector’sexternalassets. In December 1999, a new Government took office. As previously mentioned, this Government believed thatthemaincauseoftheeconomicdepressionwasfiscalmismanagement.Successivepackagesoftight fiscalmeasureswereapplied.EffortstopreventdefaultincludedaFiscalResponsibilityLawin1999that setamandatorydecliningtrendforthepublicdeficitdesignedtobringittozeroinafewyears.BymidͲ 2001themeasuresbecamedesperateandincludedanunprecedented13ͲperͲcentacrossͲtheͲboardcut in public wages and pension benefits. Coming after years of severe recession, these cuts did not contributetosocialpeace. Theexpected“confidenceshock”nevermaterialized.Indeed,theroundsofcontractionaryfiscalpolicies onlyreinforcedthedeflationarytrend.During2000and2001theGovernmentattemptedtocomplement fiscal measures with some financial initiatives. It also implemented important debt swaps aiming at convincingthepublicthattherewasnoriskofdefault.Bytheendof2000,apackageoflocalandexternal support of about US$40 billion was announced (the “blindaje” or financial shield). The IMF led the operationwithaUS$13.7billionextensionofthestandͲbycreditinforcesinceMarch2000.However,two monthslater,acrisisinTurkeyledtoasharpriseinthecountryͲriskpremium. Asareactionavoluntarydebtswap(the“megacanje”)ofbondsofUS$30billionwaslaunchedinJune. However, because the newly issued bonds carried interest rates of about 15 per cent, they fuelled the perception that debt had become unsustainable. Another voluntary swap directed at domestic bondholdersinvolvingUS$42billionofpublicbonds,waslaunchedinNovember2001.Allthesemeasured failed to halt the withdrawal of bank deposits and the fall of international reserves which began in October2000. From the beginning of December 2001 the Government established tough restrictions on capital movements and on cash withdrawals from banks. It was hoped these measures would hold back the demandforforeigncurrency,preservethestockofreserves,andmakeitpossibletoavoiddevaluation.In fact,theyusheredintheendoftheregime.TheDecembermeasuresthrewthecountryintosocialand politicalunrest.Inthefirstdaysof2002,thecurrencyͲboardregimewasofficiallyabandoned,andwithit theoneͲtoͲoneparityofthepesototheUS$. AfterthreeyearsofrecessioneconomicactivitysufferedaparticularlyabruptfallasofmidͲ2001.Social indicators such us the unemployment rates and poverty indexes, which had worsened in the 1990s, deteriorated further, adding to social tensions and to the political crisis (Damill, Frenkel and Maurizio, 2003). Thecatastrophicfallinoutputandemploymentcontinuedforawhileaftertheendoftheconvertibility regime. However, contrary to mainstream beliefs and quite extraordinarily, a recovery started only one quarterafterthedevaluationanddefault.Itwastriggeredbythesuddenchangeinrelativepricesinfavor ofsectorsproducingtradables. The turnaround was associated with a set of policies aimed at recovering basic macroeconomic equilibrium.Thepoliciesincludedthefollowing: (a) The imposition of restrictions on capital outflows and exchange controls, including under the lattertherequirementthatexporterssellapartofforeigncurrencyearnings; (b) The establishment of taxes on exports, which allowed the authorities to capture some of the benefitsofthedevaluationforexporters’incomes; (c) Aflexiblemonetarypolicyaimedtoassisttherecoveryofbanks; 118 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment (d) AnexchangeͲratepolicyaimedatavoidingtheappreciationofthepeso. The IMF had insisted on the immediate free flotation of the peso. For a short period the Government adoptedthisregime.Oncetheexchangeratewasfreetofloat,theexchangeratemovedabruptlytolevels of close to 4 pesos per US$. The reintroduction of exchange controls was designed to contain further movement. Soon afterwards the demand for pesos started to recover with US$ in excess supply. This resultingstabilizationhelpedtohalttheriseindomesticprices,asdidthefreezingofpublicutilityrates. GDP recovery of the first half of 2002 had a short first phase in which aggregate demand barely rose. Whatstoppedtherecessionwasarecoveryindomesticproductionwhichwasnowmeetinganincreased proportion of domestic demand as imports contracted sharply. Investment rose by nearly 40 per cent between2002and2004,beingfollowedcloselybyprivateconsumption. Economicrecoverytookplaceinacontextofseverecreditrationing.Investmentwasfinancedbyretained profits.A“wealtheffect”fromtheexternalassetsholdingsoftheprivatesector,alsohelped.Theseassets – now estimated at over US$100 billionͲ rose in value as result of exchange rate depreciation, and in relationtothepricesofdomesticassetssuchasrealestate. Improvementinthecurrentaccountstartedin1998.Theabruptcontractionofimportsaftertheendof convertibilityhelpedtotransformadeficitofalmostUS$3billionin1998intoasurplusofUS$17billionin 2002. On the fiscal front between 2001 and 2004 there was an improvement in the overall balance of the ConsolidatedPublicSectorfromadeficitof5.6percentofGDPin2001toasurplusof3.5percentin2004 (see table VI.5.). This reflected improvements in the three major components, the primary balance, interestpayments,andtheaggregatebalanceoftheprovinces. The most important factor in the improvement of the primary balance was an improvement in tax revenues due mainly to those on exports and income. In table VI.7. interest payments are shown as decliningby2.5percentofGDP.However,thisdoesnotindicatetheeffectofthesuspensionofpayments onexternalpublicdebt,whichatthe2004exchangeratewouldhaveamountedtoabout10percentof GDP: 4. DefaultonExternalDebtandtheRestructuringProposals Thesuspensionofservicepaymentsonpartofpublicdebtwasdeclaredon24December2001.Outofa total of US$144.5 billion US$61.8 billion in public bonds and some US$8 billion in other liabilities were affected.Thedevaluationofthepesohadamajorimpactontheeconomy’scontractualobligations,given thepervasivedollarizationofcontracts.Afewdaysafterthedevaluation,aspartofpoliciestoattenuate theshock,theauthoritiesissuednewdebt. Themainsourceofthenewindebtednesscamefrominterventionsinthefinancialsystem,andledtoa US$14.4billionriseinpublicdebt.InFebruary2002theGovernmentdecidedtoundertakeacompulsory conversion of foreignͲcurrency bank deposits at a rate of 1.4 pesos per dollar.86The withdrawal of depositswasrestrictedto1,500pesosperpersonperweek.Bankcreditsinforeigncurrencyweresubject to conversion at a rate of one peso per dollar. This “asymmetric pesoification” of credits and deposits causedasignificantlossinbanks’networththatwascompensatedbytheGovernment.Newdebtissued forthispurposeamountedUS$5.9billion. 86 Whenthemeasurewassanctioned,thedollarwasataround2.15pesos.Fourmonthslater,thedollarexchangeratereached4 pesos,decliningsmoothlythereafter.FromMarch2003,theparitystabilizedatbetween2.8Ͳ3pesosperdollar. 119 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea The pesoification of private deposits and the forced resetting of their maturities triggered legal claims. Many of the courts’ rulings were favorable to these claims. In response the Government of President Duhalde launched three offers for the voluntary swap of deposits for new public bonds, which were widely accepted by savers. This measure alleviated the financial system’s liquidity problems, but at the expenseofincreasingpublicdebtbyafurtherUS$6.1billion. Another source of increases in public debt was the transfer of the bank liabilities of provincial GovernmentstothecentralGovernment,whichamountedtoUS$9.7billion.ThecentralGovernmentalso assumed the loss due to the assumption of obligations on provincial Governments’ bonds that had performedascurrencybetween2001and2003.87Bothtransactionswereguaranteedbyaproportionof thefutureflowofnationaltaxresources.Lastly,in2002Ͳ2003,publicdebtalsorosebyUS$2billiondueto obligationstoemployees,pensionersandpurveyors.ThisfollowedaSupremeCourtrulingstatingthatthe 13ͲperͲcentcutofpublicwagesandpensionsinJuly2001wasunconstitutional. In February 2002, the Government decided to convert into pesos all debts issued in foreign currency undertheArgentineanlegislation.ThemeasurewouldaffectUS$57.5billionofmostly“guaranteedloans” issuedaftertheNovember2001swap.88Itwasalsodecidedtoapplyfixedinterestratesof2Ͳ5.5percent tothe“new”debt.Thepesoificationofthe“guaranteedloans”reducedthe dollarvalueofthe debtby aboutUS$22.1billion.However,duetotheindexationofthisdebt,bytheendof2003,thevalueofthese obligationshadrisenbysomeUS$7.3billion. Insummary,variousmeasuresrelatedtomanagingtheconvertibilitycollapseandthedefaultledpublic debtstockstoincreasebyUS$28.2billionbetweenDecember2001andDecember2003. Inthesecondhalfof2003,thefirstofficialstepstowardsrestructuringthedefaulteddebtweretaken.In September, after an agreement with the IMF, the Government announced the main guidelines of a restructuring proposal at the annual meeting of the IMF and the World Bank in Dubai. The “Dubai proposal”established thattheofferwould be directed toholdersofbondsissued untilDecember2001 withauniformtreatment,therestofthedebtbeingserviced.8990 TheGovernmentacknowledgedadefaulteddebtstockofaboutUS$87billionexcludingunpaidinterest.A 75ͲperͲcent haircut was imposed on this amount with new bonds to be issued up to a maximum of US$21.8 billion. The issue of three new bonds (Par, QuasiͲPar and Discount) was announced for this purpose.Thefirsttwowouldreceivemoderatehaircuts,butthatontheDiscountbondwouldbehigher. TheproposalwasconsistentwiththeprimarysurplustargetthathadbeenrecentlyagreedwiththeIMF (2.4percentofGDPforthecentralGovernmentand3percentfortheconsolidatedpublicsector). Argentina’screditorsexpressedstrongdisapproval,arguingthatthecountrywasinapositiontomakea betterofferbycommittingitselftoahigherfiscaleffort.TheIMFexertedpressureontheGovernmentfor signs of “goodͲfaith”. Similar pronouncements were made in June 2004 by GͲ7 finance ministers. In response the Government announced a new proposal in Buenos Aires, aimed at getting closer to the creditors’ positions. The eligible debt was the same as that defined in Dubai.91But in exchange for defaulted debt new bonds would be issued up to a total of US$38.5 billion, depending on the level of 87 Asofmid2001,someprovincialgovernmentsissuedbondsthatperformedasmoney.WhentherescueprocessstartedinMay 2003,thestockof‘quasiͲmonedas’wasat7.5billionpesos(2percentofGDP). 88 Themeasureaffectedpublicbonds,bilateralloans,debtwithcommercialbanksandotherobligations,whichalladdedtoabout US$15billion. 89 Thissetofobligationswastermed‘eligibledebt’.Itconsistedof158instruments,issuedin7differentcurrenciesandunder8 jurisdictions. 90 Someobligations(bilateraldebt,debtwithcommercialbanksandothercreditors)remainedwithoutdefinition.InDecember 2003,thesedebtsamountedtoUS$7.5billion. 91 TheBuenosAiresofferspecifiedsomedetailsomittedinDubai.Itwasclarifiedthatthe‘eligibleamount’comprisedthestockof bondsatDecember31,2001,plusaccruedinterestsuptothatdate. 120 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment acceptance.92Later,itwasmadeclearthattheswapwouldcomprisebothcapitalandinterestarrearsand theamountofthenewbondswasincreasedtoamaximumofUS$38.5Ͳ41.8billion.Thethreedifferent bondsweremaintainedinthenewproposal. TheBuenosAiresproposalimpliedahigherfuturefiscaleffort.TheGovernmentwasineffectcommitted toaprimarysurplustargetof2.7percentofGDPduringthefirstfiveyears,thistargeteasingtoaround 2.3percentofGDPasof2014.Undertheassumptionof3.3percentannualaveragegrowth,projections indicated that the fiscal effort would finance most interest payments. However, even if the multilateral organizations agreed to refinance debt due to them, the Government would still have to obtain annual fundingofabout2percentofGDPfortenyearsaftertheswap. EvidencethatArgentinawouldfaceaheavydebtburdenaftertheswapdidnoteasecreditors’demands. ImmediatelyaftertheannouncementinJunebondholders’organizationsrejectedtheproposal.Financial analysesshowed thatasubstantialhaircutofabout73Ͳ80percentwasimplied.Thesize ofthehaircut depended crucially on the discount rate used in the calculation. That used was the yield of assets of emergingͲmarketcountriesratedasofsimilarrisk,i.e.12Ͳ14percent. By late 2004 developments on international capital markets unexpectedly started to play in favor of Argentina.GreaterworldliquiditystimulatedtheappetiteforriskandforemergingͲmarketsdebt,andled to a reduction of developing countries’ risk premium.93In this new context estimates of the haircut impliedbyArgentina’sproposalwerereducedandtheswaplookedmoreattractive.Thepresentvalueof offeredbondscalculatedatthenewdiscountratewas30Ͳ35centsonthedollar.Thiswassimilartothe marketpriceofthedefaultedbonds. The improvement in the financial environment paved the way for the Government finally to launch the swapwithoutintroducinganychangetotheJune2004proposal.94TheswapstartedonJanuary14,2005. On May 3, 2005, the Government announced that acceptance had reached 76.15 per cent. This meant thatUS$62.3billionoftheoldbondswouldbeexchangedforaboutUS$35.3billionofnewinstruments and GDP growthͲlinked coupons. The operation reduced public external debt by US$67.3 billion,95and attenuatedthepublicfinances’exposuretoforeignexchangerisk,sincearound44per centof thenew bondsweredenominatedinlocalcurrency. 5. Argentina,theIMFandtheInternationalFinancialSystem At first glance it may seem striking that the crisis and the massive default took place in a country considered an example of the success of Washington Consensus policies. From the IMF’s perspective Argentina’s currency board had been a prime example of a feasible corner solution for exchangeͲrate policyinanemergingmarket(Fischer,2001).Yetatthesametimeitwaswidelybelievedthatthedebt andtheconvertibilityregimewerenotsustainable,astheprogramdidnotinvolveanysubstantialchanges tomacroeconomicpolicy. Argentina’s program aimed at reͲestablishing confidence through commitments to fiscal austerity. However, the recession and the liquidity crunch meant that it was implausible that the issuing of fiscal 92 In the lower acceptance scenario the recognition of interest arrears would include the period until December 31, 2003 for aboutUS$18.1billion,whereasinthehigheracceptancescenarioitwouldincludeinterestsarrearstillJune30,2004,forUS$1.4 billion. 93 The JP Morgan EMBI+ index decreased to an average of 375 basis points in the last quarter of 2004, whereas the Brazilian countryriskͲpremiumfellto417basispoints. 94 Torelieveitselffromcreditors’pressures,thegovernmentgaveuptherighttochangetheguidelinesbysendingabilltothe Congresspreventingtheadministrationfromdoingso.Congressquicklyapproved. 95 According to minister Lavagna, at the end of 2004, the haircut would reduce debt stocks from US$191.2 billion to US$123.9 billion.Thepublicdebt/GDPratiowouldhavefallenfrom113to72percent. 121 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea signalswouldbesufficienttostopthecrisis.Bythetimeofthereductionsingovernmentexpenditurein midͲ2001, there were good reasons to think that multilateral resources would end up financing private capitalflightwithoutpreventingadefault. After the changes at the head of the IMF in 2001, the Fund’s relationship with Argentina became increasinglystrained.IMFrecommendationsplayedanegativeroleinstabilizationandrecovery.Aprime examplewasexchangeͲratepolicy.InFebruary2002theIMFdemandedtheimmediateflotationofthe exchange rate, threatening not to reestablish negotiations in its absence. The implementation of this measure predictably led to an abrupt rise in the price of the dollar and an acceleration of inflation. Similarly, there was a clash over the management of the crisis in the banking sector. The Lavagna Government wanted gradual action and voluntary options, while the IMF promoted heroic “solutions” suchasbankliquidations. TheseexamplesshowthattheFundoperatedonthebasisofthediagnosisthat(1)theexchangemarket couldnotbestabilized,(2)ahyperinflationaryprocesswasunavoidable,and(3)reestablishmentofsome degreeoffinancialintermediationindomesticcurrencysoonwouldbeimpossible.Theimplementationof themeasurespromoted bythe IMF wouldhavetransformeditsdiagnosisintoaselfͲfulfilling prophecy. The IMF maintained its policy line until May 2003 when the Deputy Manager Director recognized the deficiencyoftheFund’sdiagnosis. The 2002 and 2003 agreements were signed in the context of a highly confrontational relationship between Argentina and the IMF. In September 2003, a threeͲyear agreement to refinance debts to the IMFwasagreed.Thetermsofconditionalitywereonlyestablishedforthefirstyear,astheGovernment refusedtocommittohighertargetsforsubsequentones.Targetsincludednewregulationsofprivatized public utilities, measures to strengthen financial system, and a new law about the distribution of fiscal revenues between the national and provincial Governments. The conditionality also included a clause underwhichthecountrywastodisplay“goodfaith”inthetreatmentofexternalcreditors.Theambiguity ofthetermlefttotheIMFagreatmarginofdiscretioninitsevaluation. AyearlaterArgentinahadcomfortablyfulfilledthequantitativetargetsbutnotthequalitativeones.The most significant one under the latter heading was probably the finalization of the renegotiation of contractsandtheestablishmentofanewregulatoryframeworkforprivatizedpublicutilities.Whilethe IMF was conducting its evaluation, Argentina was presenting the debt restructuring proposal and organizing the swap. The relationship between Argentina and the Fund reached an impasse. The IMF couldhaveterminatedtheagreementonthebasisofthefailuretofulfillqualitativetargets.Thatwould have signified a serious negative shock for a country in the middle of the debt restructuring process. It couldalsohaveledtofinancialdifficultiesfortheIMFsinceArgentinawasalargeborrower. Theimpassewasovercomebythesuspensionoftheprogramuntilthebeginningof2005atArgentina’s request.Thereafter,ArgentinarepaidtotheIMFallprincipalandinterestthatcouldnotbepostponed.In theperiod2002Ͳ2004itmadenetprincipalpaymentsofmorethanUS$2.1billion,andinterestpayments of US$1.9 billion. As these figures compared with net receipts of US$23 billion in 1994Ͳ2001, the ArgentineanMinisteroftheEconomydescribedtheIMFasmovingfrombeinga“lastͲresortlender”toa “privilegeddebtpaymentscollector”. A crucial element in the process was the Government’s view that international financial crises and defaults are the result of excessive debts attributable to the irresponsible behavior of borrowers and lenders. This irresponsible behavior is encouraged by the implicit guarantee given by the IMF’s rescue packages. Hence, there should be less intervention by the IMF both under normal conditions and in default situations. Argentina’s Government requested nonͲintervention of the IMF, arguing further that the restructuring proposal did not involve additional multilateral funding. The high haircut was seen as 122 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment proportionaltotheirresponsibilityshownbythemarket.Indeed,Argentina’sstrategyillustratedboththe flawsoftheinternationalfinancialsystemandtheviabilityofalternativewaystosolveproblems. By2006ArgentinahadrestartednegotiationswiththeIMFfromapositionstrengthenedbythehighlevel ofacceptanceoftheswap.Thenegotiationsgavegreaterlegitimacytotheoperation.Toorigidposition by the IMF risked being politically uncomfortable for some GͲ7 Governments, and would have contradictedtheacceptanceofthehaircutbyprivatecreditors. Moreover, with the high acceptance of the swap, the IMF faced a fait accompli in that the outcome indicatedanassumptionbythemarketthatArgentina’smultilateraldebtwouldberefinanced.Stillmore uncomfortably for the IMF the Fund had not participated in the design of the proposal. This clearly clashedwithIMF’sinstitutionallogicinthattherefinancingofacountry’sdebtwassupposedtorequire itsapprovalofnewloans.Therefore,byacceptingArgentina’sdemandstheIMFappearedtobeaccepting achangeinitsrole. Thesetensionswereexacerbatedbythespecialcircumstancesthattheinstitutionwasgoingthrough.The IMF had actively participated in the restructurings of sovereign debts with the private sector since the 1980s.TherecentSDRMinitiativewasintendedtobeanextensionofthattradition,andwasanattempt todefine,formalizeandstrengthentheIMF’sroleincasesofsovereigndebtdefault.AfterWallStreetand theUnitedStatesrejectedtheSDRMinitiative,thisroleoftheIMFremainsilldefined.Thisisnotthefirst time that the Governments of developed countries –particularly the United StatesͲ have redefined the functionsoftheIMFduringtheprocessofdealingwithimmediateandspecificproblems.Forexample,the 1995 Mexican crisis led to IMF rescue packages for capitalͲ as opposed to currentͲaccount crises. Argentina’s case may eventually contribute to a redefinition of the functions of the IMF in the internationalfinancialsystem. C. ExternalDebtManagementoftheRepublicofKoreaduringtheCrisesof1979Ͳ 1980and1997Ͳ1998 1. Introduction During the past four decades, the Republic of Korea has experienced a number of periods of financial stress.Themostseriouswasthe1997Ͳ98crisisthatbroughtthecountrytothebrinkofdefault.Theother periodsofstress,includingthecrisisof1979Ͳ80,werelessdamaging(Park,1986;Cooperetal.,1994).In many respects the causes were similar: they included investment booms in the periods leading to the crises,largeandgrowingcurrentͲaccountdeficits,andappreciationsoftherealexchangerate.However, the 1997Ͳ98 financial meltͲdown was a capitalͲaccount crisis, of which the Republic of Korea had no previousexperience.96 TheRepublicofKoreaengineeredaquickrecoveryfrombothcrises.Intermsofeconomicfundamentals there was no reason to believe the Republic of Korea was any more vulnerable to a crisis during the second half of the 1990s than it had been two decades earlier. Nevertheless, the cost of resolving the secondcrisiswasfargreater,andthetwocrisesfolloweddifferentadjustmenttrajectories. SectionBdiscussesthebuildͲupandresolutionofthe1979Ͳ80debtcrisis.ThisisfollowedinSectionsC and D by an examination of macroeconomic developments prior to and in the aftermath of the second crisis.SectionEexploresthelessonsandSectionFcontainsasummaryofthemainpoints. 96 SelectedeconomicindicatorsforRepublicofKoreafor1975Ͳ1985and1995Ͳ2004aregivenintables6and7. 123 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea 2. The1979Ͳ1980DebtCrisis The Republic of Korea economy slowed in 1979 after three years of strong growth, while the current accountslidintodeeperimbalance,risingtoadeficitof6.6percentofGDPin1979andof8.3percentin 1980fromoneof2percentin1978.In1980outputcontractedby1.5percentandtheconsumerprice index (CPI) soared to 29 percent. The economy was thus experiencing stagflation with a large currentͲ accountimbalance.AtthesametimetotalexternaldebtasaproportionofGDPswelledto42.6percent. In these circumstances a traditional IMFͲsupported prescription would have included a strong dose of stabilizationmeasurestogetherwithacurrencydevaluation.ButRepublicofKoreapolicymakersoptedfor adifferentgrowthͲfirstpolicy.TothesurpriseoftheIMFandtheinternationalfinancialcommunity,the economyreboundedin1981,growing6.2percent. At the centre of Republic of Korea economic policy in the midͲ1970s was the plan for the heavy and chemicalindustries.Thispolicyentailedtaxincentives,lowͲcostbankcredit,andothersubsidiesmostlyto large firms belonging to the Republic of Korea’s industrial groups or chaebols. The result was an investmentboomleadingtoariseintheratioofgrossinvestmenttoGDPfrom28.7percentin1977to36 percentin1979.Atthesametimetheeconomyoverheated,withannualincreasesinrealwagesin1976Ͳ 78averagingover18percent.Asteephikeinagriculturalpricescausedbyapoorharvestin1978further aggravatedinflationarypressures. Despite this, the Republic of Korea Government was determined to maintain a dollarͲpegged exchange rate.Thisledtoanappreciationoftherealexchangerate,whichinturnunderminedexportearnings.At thesametime,theRepublicofKoreasufferedadverseexternalshocks.Itwashitbythesecondoilcrisisin 1979,sufferinga15ͲperͲcentdeteriorationinitstermsoftradein1979Ͳ1980. Furthermore, the Republic of Korea was thrown into political turmoil by the assassination of President Park in 1979. The new military Government of May 1980 was hardly in a position to adopt a strong stabilization program. Political uncertainties worsened Republic of Korea economic prospects. Not surprisingly, businesses adjusted by cutting investment, fixed investment falling by 11 per cent in 1980. Theeconomysankintoadeeprecessionin1980,whichwasaggravatedbyacrisisintheinformalcredit market. However, surprisingly the currentͲaccount deficit did not shrink as expected. This was because consumption remained strong: consumers considered the fall in output transitory and cut their savings rather than their consumption. As a result the share of saving in GDP dropped more than that of investment. Lackingsupportforastabilizationprogram,thecaretakerGovernmentfocuseditspolicyresponsetothe deteriorating current account on the exchange rate. The won was devalued visͲàͲvis the US$ by 27 percentin1980,andthereaftertheRepublicofKoreamovedtoamanagedfloattiedtoabasketofmajor international currencies. On the macroeconomic front the Government gave priority to stopping the economicdownturn. Hereitscommitmentwastobroadlyconceivedstabilizationtogetherwithfinancialreformandcorporate restructuring. In its view inflation was at the root of the deterioration in income distribution, of labor unrest, and of the weakening of the country’s export competitiveness. A growthͲfirst strategy would succeedonlyifthedeficitonthecurrentaccountwasbroughtundercontrolandfinancedexternally.The prospectforsuchapolicywasuncertainastheRepublicofKoreahadoneoflargestexternaldebtsamong developingcountries.Nevertheless,debtservicelevelsremainedwithinasustainablerange.Thegamble paid off. The Government maintained an expansionary policy until 1983 when it began restraining domesticdemand.By1981inflationwasalreadysubsidingandtheeconomyrecoveredfullyonlyayear aftertherecessionof1980. 124 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment What were the factors responsible for the dramatic turnaround? Haggard and Collins (1994) single out threedevelopments: x An improvement in the external environment due to (1) falling prices of oil and raw materials leading to a better terms of trade and lower inflation, (2) declining international interest rates, and(3)anappreciationoftheyenagainsttheUS$; x Decliningrealwagesinboth1980and1981,partlyduetomoreflexiblelabormarkets; x The depreciation of the real exchange rate, which improved the Republic of Korea’s export competitiveness. However,otherimportantfactorsalsohelpedpulltheRepublicofKoreaeconomyoutofcrisis.Onewas theclosedcapitalaccount.ThisallowedflexibilityaswellaseffectivenessformonetarypolicyinafixedͲ exchange rate regime. Despite the economic crisis and political turmoil, the Republic of Korea did not experienceanycapitalflightoranywithdrawalofforeignloans.TheothercrucialfactorwastheRepublic ofKorea’sabilitytofinanceitscurrentͲaccountdeficitexternally.Thecountrywasneverdeniedaccessto internationalfinancialmarkets,althoughitsborrowingcostswentup. By 1983, stability returned alongside of the resurgence in growth. By now both domestic demand and exportearningswerestrong.Inthesecircumstancesacontinuationofloosemonetaryandfiscalpolicies couldhaverekindledinflation.Furthermore,totalexternaldebtremainedatover47percentofGDP.To reduce the debt burden the current account had to move in the direction of surplus. This explains the Government’sshifttoastabilizationpolicywhichwassustaineduntil1988. 3. The1997Ͳ1998Crisis (a)InvestmentBoomFueledbyForeignBorrowing TheRepublicofKoreaeconomyreboundedstronglyfromaslowͲdownin1992and1993.Thisgrowthwas ledbyexportsandinvestment(39percentofGDPin1996).Inthatyear,thedeficitoncurrentaccount was a little over 4 per cent of GDP and apparently manageable yet a major financial crisis followed in 1997Ͳ1998. Expansion of investment on this scale in an economy with still small financial markets led to higher external borrowing. Two major developments can help to explain this debtͲfinanced investment surge. Thefirstwasthestrengtheningoftheyenfromthesecondhalfof1992tothefirsthalfto1995.Thisrise endedinthespringof1995whentheyenhitthelevelof79.5yentothedollar.Theyen’sappreciation broughtaboutasharpincreaseinRepublicofKoreaexportearningsbecausemanyofitsindustrieswere indirectcompetitionwiththoseofJapan. The second development was increased financial openness, which increased the availability of lowͲcost foreign credit. In the period 1996Ͳ1998 external debt rose from 28 to 47 percent of GDP. Much of the inflows during 1995Ͳ1997 consisted of shortͲterm borrowings by domestic financial institutions, which usedtheproceedstofinanceinvestmentsbychaebols.Theconsequencesincludedseriouscurrencyand maturitymismatchesinthebalancesheetsoffinancialinstitutions(Park,1998,andParkandSong,2002). Atthesametime,RepublicofKoreaindustrialgroupswereincreasingtheirinvestmentsabroad.Muchof this investment was financed with foreign credits. This helps to explain a rise in the foreign debts of domesticfirmsfromUS$35.6billionin1996to US$43.2billion ayearlater. Theliabilitiesoftheforeign subsidiariesand branches ofRepublicofKoreafirmswereestimatedto have exceeded US$51billionat theendofJune1997. 125 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea (b)TheBurstingoftheInvestmentBubbles Attheendof1995,theJapaneseyenbegantodepreciate.Atthesametimethetermsoftrademoved against the Republic of Korea, and continued to deteriorate for the next two years. This termsͲofͲtrade shock, which reflected falling demand for the Republic of Korea’s major exports, worsened the current accountandsetinmotionaweakeningoftheeconomy.Therealexchangeratecontinuedtoappreciate throughout 1996. However, policymakers did not react owing to their preoccupation with industrial restructuring and the belief that a strong won would help facilitate the shifting of resources from light manufacturingtomoreskillͲandknowledgeͲintensiveindustries. Despiteaslowdownoftheeconomyasofthesecondhalfof1996largeindustrialgroupsdidnotadjust theirproductionandinvestment.Astheirinventoriespiledup,sodidtheirlosses.However,commercial banks became less accommodating. As a result chaebols tuned to highͲcost, shortͲterm loans from any foreignfinancialinstitutionswillingtolendtothem. WhyweretheRepublicofKorea’sindustrialgroupssoinflexibleinadjusting?Theanswerlayinsomeof theircharacteristics.Oneofthesewastheirpredatorybehaviorofcompetingformarketsharemorethan for profit, a feature nurtured by an industrial policy geared to obtaining economies of scale in major export industries. Thus, when profits fell, they tried to protect their share by investing more, and by diversifyingatthefirstopportunityintonewindustries. Furthermore,rigidandbureaucraticmanagementsystemswithdecisionͲmakingconcentratedatthetop made it difficult for chaebols to adjust quickly to changing market conditions. Reluctance to reduce investmentledtohighlyleverage.Asurveyconductedin1997showsthattheaveragedebtͲequityratioof the30largestchaebolswasabove380percentin1996,fourtimesashighasthatofTaiwanProvinceof China (Korea Institute of Economics and Technology, 1997). The high leverage and the balance sheet mismatches of the corporate sector proved to be the Republic of Korea economy’s most damaging structuralweaknessesduringthecrisis. By1994thenewGovernmentwascommittedtomarketopeningasaresultofitsWTOagreement.This agreementreducedtheroomforindustrialpolicy,whilereductionincontroloverfinancialactivitytook away much of the rest of the Government’s ability to coordinate investments. Moreover reform of corporategovernanceorfinancialregulationfailedtokeeppacewithmarketopening. (c)TheFinancialMarketCollapseof1997 Theexternallyfinancedinvestmentboomcouldonlylastsolong.Oncetheinvestmentbubbleburst,the number of corporate bankruptcies also soared as did the volume of nonͲperforming loans at financial institutions.BetweenDecember1996andJune1997,nonͲperformingloansasaproportionoftotalloans doubled(Park1998).Thefirstmajorcorporatecasualtyinthesecondhalfof1996wasHanbo,the14th largestchaebol. TheinvestigationintotheHanbocollapserevealedthatmanyloanstothisgrouphadbeenmadeunder politicalpressure.Theextentofunholytiesbetweenpoliticiansandindustryandthescaleofcorruption shocked both the Republic of Korea people and foreign investors. Moreover, the pervasiveness of corruptionunderminedtheconfidenceofforeigninvestorsintheGovernmentandtheeconomy,thereby helpingtobringaboutthecrisis. MorehighͲprofilebankruptciesfollowed.TheKiagroupwasputintoliquidationinOctober1997,andwas followedbyfivemorechaebols.Bytheendof1997,theRepublicofKoreahadalameͲduckGovernment whichwasunabletorestorestabilitytotheRepublicofKoreafinancialmarkets.Foreigninvestorsknew this,andbeganwithdrawingfundsfromtheRepublicofKoreastockmarketduringtheautumn. 126 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment ReflectingtheineffectivenessoftheGovernment,exchangeͲratepolicyinthelastthreemonthsbefore the crisis drifted into inconsistency and unpredictability. The won had been under strong pressure of depreciation since early 1997. Throughout the year, the Government stated that it would defend the exchangerate.Whenthewon/US$exchangerateapproachedthepsychologicallyimportantlevelof1000, theGovernmentintervenedheavilyinthemarket,onlysuddenlytowithdrawafewdayslater. Between June and November 1997, the Bank of Korea’s reserve holdings fell by US$10 billion. The Government further strained investors’ credulity by failing to divulge the true level of foreign exchange reserves.ItassertedthattheBankofKoreastillheldaboutUS$30billioninreserves,whentheactuallevel ofusablereserveshadalreadydroppedbelowUS$22billioninMarch.BytheendofNovemberthefigure hadfallentoUS$7billiondollars. The dire financial situation was further compounded by changes in sovereign credit ratings. Between JanuaryandNovember1997,Moody’sadjustedtheratingdownwardtwice,andS&Pthreetimes.Bythe sametokenthepremiumonRepublicofKoreasecuritiesrose.Foreignbanksbegantorefusetorollover shortͲtermloanstotheRepublicofKorea.Theactionsofthecreditratingsagenciesgeneratedavicious cycleofdecliningratingsandmarketsentiment. 4. ManagementofandRecoveryfromthe1997Ͳ98Crisis BytheendofOctober1997thefinancialsituationwasoutofcontrol.Foreigninvestorsmovedoutofthe stockmarketindroves,andRepublicofKoreabankswereincreasinglyunabletorollovertheirshortͲterm foreignloans.Toavoiddefault,theywereforcedtoturntotheBankofKoreaforliquidityortoresortto foreignovernightloans. No action was taken until the announcement on 19 November of a reform package, which included measures for the disposal of nonͲperforming loans and a widening of the band for exchangeͲrate movements. In the prevailing panic, the market hardly noticed. Three days later, unable to control the situation,theGovernmentpubliclyapproachedtheIMFforassistance.NegotiationsbetweentheRepublic ofKoreaGovernmentandtheIMFwerecompletedinarecordtimeof10days.TheIMFagreedtoprovide atotalofUS$21billiontobedisbursedoverathreeͲyearperiod.Italsosecuredfinancialcommitments totalingUS$36billionfromtheWorldBank,theAsianDevelopmentBank,theUnitedStates,Japan,and othersasasecondlineofdefense. IMF conditionality required tight monetary policy, a fiscal surplus, sweeping financialͲsector reform includingfurtherliberalization,greaterflexibilityinthelabormarket,andrestructuringthechaebols.By the end of December, a 25ͲperͲcent interest rate ceiling and most capital controls were abolished. The limit on aggregate stock ownership by foreigners was raised to 55 percent, and the shortͲterm money market was also to be deregulated. However, the swift conclusion of negotiations did little to change market sentiment which was also affected by the political uncertainties concerning the outcome of the presidential elections due in December 18. The won/dollar exchange rate continued to depreciate; interestratessoared;andstockpriceswentintoanoseͲdive. The squeeze on the money supply together with banks’ efforts to meet the 8Ͳ percent Basel capital adequacyratiobyApril1998reducedtheavailabilityofbankcredit.InDecemberthepercentagerateof loan defaults jumped to 1.49 from 0.14 a year earlier, while business failures were five times higher. ExternallenderssawthattheIMFfinancingwhichhadbeenagreedwasshortoftheamountofforeign debt repayment due. There were also concerns that tight monetary and fiscal policies would depress economicactivitysomuchthattheRepublicofKorea’sabilitytoserviceitsdebtwouldbeundermined. Interestratesshotuptothedizzyingheightof40percent,andthewon/depreciatedtoalevelof1,995per dollar. 127 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea Thefinancialsituationwasclearlyunsustainable,andrumorsbegantocirculatethattheRepublicofKorea mighthavetodeclareadebtmoratorium.OnChristmasEve,theIMFandtheGͲ7countriescameupwith anotheremergencyfinancingprogramofUS$10billion,drawingonthesecondlineofdefense.Thenew package succeeded in turning around market sentiment as it demonstrated the resolve to rescue the RepublicofKoreafromfinancialcollapse.Foreignlenderswantedtobeassuredofpaymentsofprinciple and interest. They asked for and received government guarantees on private debt on the basis of the argument that this would facilitate debt restructuring and new credit extension. By January 1998, international creditor banks agreed to convert most of the shortͲterm debt of Republic of Korea banks (US$24 billion) into longͲterm loans, with government guarantees that mature over one to three years, andinterestratesof2.25Ͳ2.75pointsaboveLibor. In1998thegrowthrateofGDPplungedtoͲ6.9percentfrom+4.7percentayearbefore.Pricesleaped by7.5percent,thewondepreciatedby27percentvisͲàͲvisthedollar,andtheunemploymentreached8 per cent, the highest since the 1960s. Surprisingly, the crisis was short lived. The rebound was no less drastic than preceding fall. The Republic of Korea economy grew by 9.5 per cent in 1999, and recovery continuedthereafter. TheinitialGDPcontractionin1998waslargelycausedbythecollapseofinvestment.TheconsumptionͲ GDPratioremainedfairlystable,whiletheinvestmentͲGDPratiodroppedsharplyto25percent.In1998, therewasahugecurrentͲaccountsurplusofalmost12percentofGDP.Thiswasbecauseimportdemand declinedby22percentin1998,whileexportsfellbyunder3percent,movementswhichreflectedthe influenceofboththerecessionandthedepreciationofthewon. An empirical examination by Park and Lee (2002) of worldwide patterns of adjustment in 160 currency crisis episodes from 1970 to 1995 shows a widespread tendency for countries to undergo a VͲtype recovery of real GDP growth similar to that experienced by the Republic of Korea after the 1997Ͳ1998 crisis.Thestudyalsoshowsthatalargerealdepreciation,expansionarymonetaryandfiscalpolicy,andan improvement in the global economic environment are usually responsible for the upturns. All of these developmentswerepresentduringthesecondRepublicofKoreacrisis.WhatdistinguishestheRepublicof Koreaexperiencefromothersarethedegreeoftheinitialcontractionandsubsequentrecovery.Thiswas duetothefollowingfactors: x ExchangeRateDepreciationandOpenness:inviewoftheRepublicofKorea’srelativelyhighlevel ofopennessandrelativelylargetradesector,adepreciationoftherealexchangeratewasgoing tohaveanespeciallylargeimpact. x Favorable External Environment: the Republic of Korea economy was the beneficiary of an improvement in the external trading environment. The global economy was strong in 1999. Moreover,theRepublicofKoreaexportsalsobenefitedfromhigherpricesofsemiconductors,and fromanappreciationoftheyenwhichimproveditsindustries’competitiveness. x MacroeconomicPolicyAdjustments:realizingthedepthoftheslowdown,theIMFagreedtorelax monetary and fiscal policies as early as April 1998. The ensuing expansion of money supply preventedafurthercontractionofdomesticdemand. The positive role of expansionary macroeconomic policies in the postͲcrisis recovery has raised the questionofwhethertheinitialtighteningwastooharsh,maintainedfortoolong,andasaconsequence deepened the crisis. In order to deal with the crisis, the IMF chose a traditional policy prescription designedformanagingacurrentͲaccountcrisis,whichcomprisedtightmonetarypolicyandfiscalausterity. However, the Republic of Korea crisis involved principally the capital account. In these circumstances increasedinterestratesresultedinwidespreadbankruptcieswhichdidlittletorestorefinancialstability andtheconfidenceofforeignlendersandinvestors. 128 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TheIMFandsupportersofthecontractionarymonetarypolicyarguethatintheabsenceofsuchapolicy capitaloutflowsandthebankrunwouldhavecontinued.ThosewhodisputetheIMFviewsuchasRadelet andSachs(1998)andFeldstein(1998),ontheotherhand,maintainthattheRepublicofKoreaproblem wasoneofliquidity.Therefore,thetraditionalIMFstrategywaslikelytohavedonemoreharmthangood asitdrovemanyhighlyleveragedbutviablefirmsoutofbusiness,therebydeepeningeconomicrecession. 5. LessonsoftheTwoCrises Bothdebtcriseswereinpartprecipitatedbyinvestmentboomsfinancedbyforeignborrowing.Theratios ofexternaldebttoGDPweresimilar,andtheRepublicofKoreaexaggeratedthecrisesbyadheringfortoo longtorigidexchangeͲrateregimes.Inbothcases,TheRepublicofKoreaeconomyreboundedswiftlyin bothcases,butthescarsofthe1997Ͳ98crisisweremoreextensiveanddeeper. Themostsignificantdifferencebetweenthetwocrisesinvolvedthepolicyresponses.Inthe1979Ͳ80crisis the Republic of Korea policymakers took advantage of the country’s continuing access to international financialmarketstofinancethedeficitoncurrentaccountinthebeliefthateconomicfundamentalswere strongandthattheeconomywasafflictedbyatransitoryimbalance.InthesecondcrisistheGovernment hadtoseekIMFfinancingthatsubjectedtheeconomytoawiderangingarrayofpolicychanges.Itpaida highpriceintermsoflostoutputandofthecostofresolvingbankruptfinancialinstitutionsandbailingout insolvent corporations,whichamounted16 percentof GDPin1998.Ithad nochanceofreplicatingthe strategyofrelianceonexternalborrowingfollowedafterthe1979Ͳ1980owingtoitsincreasedfinancial opennessandthemorelimitedpossibilityofrecoursetocapitalcontrols. GreaterfinancialopennesswastheresultofthepolicyofeconomicliberalizationpursuedsincethemidͲ 1980s,whichhadalsoresultedinamoreopentraderegime.TheGovernmenthadopenedthefinancial sectorandderegulatedcapitalͲaccounttransactionaheadofthebidtojointheOECDintheearly1990s. By the time of the 1997Ͳ98 crisis broke out the Government had been reforming institutions and restructuringitsfinancial,corporate,andpublicsectorsformorethanadecade. A financially open economy with a relatively inflexible exchange rate lacks an effective buffer against external financial shocks. Moreover orderly financial opening requires an efficient financial regulatory system to monitor risks. The reform of the regulatory system lagged in the Republic of Korea at a time whenfinancialinstitutionsweretakingonnewrisks,especiallyintheiroperationsabroad. AccordingtoEichengreen,WyploszandRose(1996)therearethreetypesofdistortionthatcangiverise toafinancialcrisis.Thefirstisasymmetricinformationwhereborrowersorissuersofdebtorequitytake advantageofsuperiorinformationascomparedwiththatoflendersandinvestorsabouttherisksoftheir business.Asymmetricinformation,isassociatedwiththedangerofherdbehavioronthepartofforeign investors and financial institutions. Second is moral hazard in both domestic and international financial markets. This denotes the danger that those who expect protection against loss through bailͲouts by publicauthoritieswilltakegreaterrisksthantheywouldotherwise.Thethirdisanydistortionthatcould leadtotheinstabilityintheexchangerateassociatedwithmultipleequilibriainforeignexchangemarkets. AllofthesedistortionswerepresentintheRepublicofKoreaintherunͲuptothe1997Ͳ98crisis. Before and during the early years of market liberalization foreign lenders and investors did not care to learnaboutthestructuralweaknessesofRepublicofKoreabanksandcorporategovernancebecauseof governmentguarantees.OnlywiththegrowingexposureoftheKoreaneconomytointernationalfinancial marketsdidtheirawarenessincreaseofbalanceͲsheetmismatchesatbanksandchaebols.Bythetimethe Thai crisis spread to other parts of East Asia in September 1997, the Republic of Korea began losing reserves. Lacking confidence concerning the adequacy of Republic of Korea reserves, lenders and investorsbegantoreducetheirexposuretothecountry,refusingeventorenewshortͲtermloans.Both 129 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea borrowersandlendersweretoblameforbringingonthecrisisͲborrowersowingtotheirdisregardfor prudenceandriskmanagementandlendersowingtotheirshortͲtermismandherdmentality. InternationalfinancialmarketsandRepublicofKoreapolicymakersshareresponsibilityforfailingtocarry outreformswhichwouldhavereducedmoralhazard.Commercialandmerchantbankhadlongoperated with implicit government guarantees. Together with inadequate supervision these guarantees provided incentivestobankstoborrowlargeramountsoffundsabroad,andtoinvestinriskierprojectsthanthey wouldotherwise. Moral hazard also appears to have affected the lending behavior of foreign financial institutions. These expected to receive national treatment. Assuming that they too would benefit from government guarantees, foreign banks did not conduct careful credit analyses of Republic of Korea borrowers. Moreover, when the crisis broke out, few foreign banks attempted to reschedule loans to troubled Republic of Korea banks in sharp contrast to their behavior towards delinquent borrowers in their domesticmarkets. Finally, creditors believed that, as a group, they could pressurize the Republic of Korea Government if there was a crisis. In the event this assumption was to prove justified since their pressure played an importantroleinthedecisionoftheRepublicofKoreaGovernmenttoseekIMFfinancing.Thebankswere aware that a debt moratorium was not a realistic option owing to the large number of lenders and borrowers involved. Banks’ recourse to this pressure also reflected their knowledge that IMF programs favorcreditorsoverdebtors(Soros1998). Thecrisisof1997Ͳ98wasacapitalͲaccountcrisisinwhichtheinitialcurrentaccountͲimbalancedidnot playaprimaryrole.Massivecapitaloutflowsprovokedaliquidityandcreditcrisis.Intheseconditionsthe traditionalIMFstabilizationprogramdidnotwork,andaninfusionoffreshcapitalwasrequiredtostop thebleedingoftheeconomy. It is natural to ask whether the Government could have followed the same policy as that pursued in response to the crisis of 1979Ͳ1980, i.e. combining a growthͲoriented macroeconomic policy with continuedrelianceonexternalborrowing.Itishardtobelievethatfinancialmarketstodaywouldsupport anythingbutamacroeconomicstabilizationprogram,evenifthereweregoodgroundsforthinkingthat thecrisiswouldbetransitory.InsuchanenvironmenttheaccumulationoflargereservesthroughcurrentͲ account surpluses by major emergingͲmarket countries as insurance against the imposition of inappropriatestabilizationprogramsbecomesfullyunderstandable. D. ConcludingRemarks ThesecondcrisesofboththeRepublicofKoreaandArgentinawerecapitalͲaccountcrisesthattookplace in economies that had liberalized capital transactions and that were thus integrated into international financialmarkets.CapitalinflowswhichfuelledthegrowthprecedingthecrisesandwhichintheRepublic ofKoreacasebecameaninvestmentboomweretransformedintooutflowswhichledtomeltͲdowns.In bothcasesIMFpolicyprescriptionsworsenedthecrises. During much of the 1990s Argentina experienced strong growth. However, as early as 1995 adverse developmentsintheexternalenvironmentbegantotriggereconomicdifficultiesandthecountrysuffered aminiͲcrisistogetherwithasharpdeteriorationinitsfiscalbalancefollowingtheMexicancrisisof1995. Afterarecoveryin1996Ͳ1997Argentina’sriskpremiumbegantoriseagainandforeignborrowingbecame more costly. External debt was increasing, while the ability to pay was being undermined. A series of rescue packages failed to restore confidence, and were unable to stop eventual bank runs and the bleedingofforeignexchangereserves.Thedollarizationofbankcreditsandofthecontractualstructureof 130 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment theeconomymadethecollapsemoresevere.PublicͲsectordebtroseafterthedefaultowingtomeasures takenbytheGovernmentaspartofitsinterventioninthefinancialsystem. The Republic of Korea crisis also came after a period of high growth, and was triggered by the depreciationoftheyenandadverseshockstoitsexports.Thesechangestriggeredgreaterattentionon the part of foreign lenders to the scale of foreign borrowing by chaebols and to deteriorations in their balance sheets. The rises in bankruptcies and nonͲperforming loans that followed heralded a financial market crisis with foreign borrowers refusing to rollͲover major bank loans. Given the context of the earliercrisisinThailandthewoncameundermassiveattackasbankrunsandcapitaloutflowscontinued. ThesedevelopmentsunderlinedtheimportanceofbetterfinancialregulationandcorporategovernanceͲ andnotjustgoodmacroͲeconomicmanagementͲasessentialelementsofsuccessfuldebtmanagement. In both countries the meltͲdowns led to sharp falls in GDP growth. Resolution of the debt problems followed different courses. In the Republic of Korea case, bank lending to private borrowers was more important and resolution involved the conversion of shortͲterm bank loans into longerͲterm loans with government guarantees. In Argentina debt securities were more important and restructuring involved theirconversionintoalternativesecuritieswithlowercouponsorvaluesandlongermaturities. InbothcasestheIMFprogramsincludedillͲconceivedpolicymeasuresduetomistakesindiagnosis,which worsenedtheimpactofthecrises.InArgentina,theausteritymeasuresdeepenedtherecession,thereby undermining payment capacity and accelerating default. In the Republic of Korea, earlier relaxation of monetaryandfiscalpolicycouldhavemeantthatbankruptciesandlostoutputwouldhavereachedless than16percentofGDP. In both cases, the recovery was aided by favorable external developments such as the improvement in appetiteamongstlendersandinvestorsfordevelopingcountryrisk,easingofinterestratesandimproved export markets. In Argentina default also provided a respite to the fiscal balance and the domestic economy. Inbothcases,devaluationcompressedimportsaswellashelpingexports(whoseincreasewasparticularly notable for the Republic of Korea). The turnarounds were surprisingly quick: the worst of the crisis in Argentina was in December 2001, and signs of recovery were evident in the first half of 2002; and the Republic of Korea crisis collapse of 1998 was followed by a spectacular recovery as early as 1999. This followsapatternidentifiedbyLevyͲYeyatiandPanizza(2006)accordingtowhich,bythetimeadefault occurs,thelossesintermsofoutputandgrowthhavealreadytakenplacesothatitsoccurrencecoincides withthebeginningofeconomicrecovery.Animplicationofthispatternisthat,oncefirmexpectationsof defaulttakeholdandthemeltͲdownstarts,measurestopostponethedefaultmaywellbemorecostly thanthedefaultitself. Beyondacertainpoint,neithercountrycouldhavedoneanythingtostopexternaldebtfromfollowingan exploding path. Herd behavior delivered the final blows, As Park (2005) notes, international financial markets are not a good source of shortͲterm liquidity for emerging economies, when they are experiencing financial instability. The lesson drawn by several emergingͲmarket countries has been to accumulate reserves as a form of insurance. If these economies felt assured of adequate liquidity assistance from international financial institutions or regional financial cooperative arrangements, they wouldbelessinclinedtofollowthispolicy. IMFpolicyfailuresandtheperceptionthatitsidedwithcreditorsinthesetwocriseshavecontributedto underminingofitsauthorityamongstdevelopingcountries.Argentina’sdebtrestructuringproposalsand independent recovery program have set a precedent for crisis resolution not mediated by the IMF. However, the faith of the United States and private creditors in individual debt workͲouts under rules subjecttoonlyminormodificationsincomparisonwiththepresentregimeisunlikelytoconstituteafullyͲ 131 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea fledged, unquestioned alternative. Moreover impetus from these quarters in favor of further capitalͲ accountliberalizationhasnowbeenlost. 132 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References CetrángoloOetal.(2000).LasostenibilidaddelapolíticafiscalenAméricaLatina.Elcasoargentino.In: Talvi E and Végh C eds. ¿Cómo armar el rompecabezas fiscal? Nuevos indicadores de sostenibilidad.IDB,Washington,DC. Cetrángolo O and Jiménez JP (2003). Política fiscal en Argentina durante el régimen de convertibilidad. SerieGestiónPública,108.SantiagodeChile,CEPAL. Cooper RN (1994). Korea’s Balance of International Payments. In: Haggard S, Cooper R, Collins S, Kim C andRoST. Damill M (2000). El balance de pagos y la deuda externa pública bajo la convertibilidad. Boletín InformativoTechint,303.BuenosAires. Damill M and Frenkel R (2006). Argentina: Macroeconomic Performance and Crisis. In: FfrenchͲDavis R, NayyarD,andStiglitzJEcomps.StabilizationPoliciesforGrowthandDevelopment,CapitalMarket LiberalizationProgram,InitiativeforPolicyDialogue.NewYork,November. Damill M, Frenkel R and Juvenal L (2003). Las cuentas públicas y la crisis de la Convertibilidad en Argentina.DesarrolloEconómicoͲRevistadeCienciasSociales,170.BuenosAires. Damill M, Frenkel R and Maurizio R (2003). Políticas macroeconómicas y vulnerabilidad social. La Argentinaenlosañosnoventa.SerieFinanciamientodelDesarrollo,135.SantiagodeChile,CEPAL. DamillM,FrenkelRandMaurizioR(2002).Argentina:Adecadeofcurrencyboard.Ananalysisofgrowth, employmentandincomedistribution.EmploymentPaper,2002/42.Geneva,InternationalLabour Office. Damill M, Frenkel R and Rapetti M (2005). Lesson from the Argentine case of debt accumulation and default. UNCTAD project on Capacity Building for Debt Sustainability in Developing Countries. Geneva(July). Eichengreen B, Wyplosz C and Rose A (1996). Contagious Currency Crises. National Bureau of Economic ResearchWorkingPaper5681,ScandinavianJournalofEconomics,98. FeldsteinM(1998).RefocusingtheIMF.ForeignAffairs,77:20Ͳ33. FischerS(2001).Exchangeratesregimes:isthebipolarviewcorrect?DistinguishedLectureonEconomics inGovernment.NewOrleans,AmericanEconomicAssociation,January6. Frenkel R (1983). Mercado financiero, Expectativas Cambiarias y Movimientos de Capital. El Trimestre Económico,L(4)200.México. FrenkelR(2003a).GlobalizationandFinancialCrisesinLatinAmerica.CEPALReview,80.SantiagodeChile. Frenkel R (2003b). From the Boom in Capital Inflows to Financial Traps. Barcelona, Initiative for Policy Dialogue(IPD),CapitalMarketLiberalizationTaskForce.2–3June. Haggard S et al., eds. (1994). Macroeconomic Policy and Adjustment in Korea, 1970–1990. Harvard InstituteforInternationalDevelopment,KoreaDevelopmentInstitute. Haggard S (1994). From the Heavy Industry Plan to Stabilization: Macroeconomic Policy, 1976–1980. In: HaggardS,CooperR,CollinsS,KimCandRoST. HaggardSandCollinsS(1994).ThepoliticalEconomyofAdjustmentinthe1980s.In:HaggardS,CooperR, CollinsS,KimCandRoST. Hausman R and Velasco A (2002). Hard Money’s Soft Underbelly: Understanding the Argentine Crisis. Harvard,BrookingTradeForum. 133 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea Availableat:www.ksghome.harvard.edu/~rhausma/paper/btf02_hard_money.pdf. IMFIEO(2004).ReportontheevaluationoftheroleoftheIMFinArgentina,1991–2001.Washington,DC, IndependentEvaluationOffice,InternationalMonetaryFund. IMF(2001).Argentina:CountryReport2001,01/90.Washington,DC. IMF(2004).Argentina:SecondReviewUnderStandͲByArrangement.IMFCountryReport,04(195),July. IMF (2005). Public Information Notice (PIN), 05 (83). Washington, DC, June. Available at: www.imf.org/external.np/sec/pn/2005/pn0583.htm. KoreaInstituteofEconomicsandTechnology(1997).EconomicReview,29,December. LevyͲYeyati E and Panizza U (2006). The elusive costs of sovereign defaults. Working Paper, 581. InterͲ American Development Bank, November. Available at: www.iadb.org/res/pub_desc.cfm?pub_id =WPͲ581. MussaM(2002).ArgentinaandTheFund:FromTriumphtoTragedy.WorkingPapers.Washington,DC., InstituteforInternationalEconomics. OECD,ExternalDebtStatisticsSeries2(1995–1998).Electronicdatabase. OECD,ExternalDebtStatisticsSeries3(1998–2002).Electronicdatabase. Park YC (1986). Foreign Debt, Balance of Payment, and Growth Prospects: The Case of the Republic of Korea,1965–88.WorldDevelopment,14:1019–1058. Park YC (1998) Financial Crisis and Macroeconomic Adjustments in Korea, 1997–98. In: Financial LiberalizationandOpeninginEastAsia:IssuesandPolicyChallenges.KoreaInstituteofFinance. Park YC and Song CY (2001). Financial Contagion in the East Asia Crisis –with Special Reference to the RepublicofKorea.InternationalFinancialContagion,KluwerAcademicPublishers,May. ParkYCandLeeJW(2002).FinancialCrisisandRecovery:PatternsofAdjustmentinEastAsia,1996–99. ADBInstituteResearchPaper,45,October. Park YC (2005). Economic Liberalization and Integration in East Asia: a Post Crisis Paradigm. Oxford UniversityPress,December. Park YC (2005). A tale of two crises: Korea’s experience with external debt management 1979Ͳ80 and 1997Ͳ98. UNCTAD project on Capacity Building for Debt Sustainability in Developing Countries. Geneva(September). Simpson L (2006). The role of IMF in debt restructuring: Lending into arrears, moral hazard, and sustainabilityconcerns.G24DiscussionPaperSeries,40.UNCTAD,May. RadeletSandRadeletJ(1998).OnsetoftheEastAsianFinancialCrisis.PresentedatNBERCurrencyCrisis ConferenceandtoUSAgencyforInternationalDevelopment.January. SorosG(1998).TheCrisisofGlobalCapitalism:OpenSocietyEndangered.NewYork,PublicAffairs. WorldBank(2006).GlobalDevelopmentFinance,electronicdatabase. 134 135 (Percent) RealGDPannualgrowth InflationCPIchange NominalExchangeRate(PesoperUS$) TermsofTrade(goods) TermsofTrade(goodsandservices) (inUSDmillionsunlessotherwisestated) Totalexports,fob Totalimports,fob CurrentAccountBalance Currentaccount(aspercentageofGDP) GrossReserves Publicpubliclyguaranteeddebt(aspercentageofGDP) Privatenonguaranteeddebt(aspercentageofGDP) Publicfinances (PercentofGDP) Central Government, total revenue and grants Central Government, total expenditure and net lending Central Government balance Outputandtrade 5651 Ͳ3799 1126 2.0 3331.7 8.9 5.7 6.4 176.0 191.2 1977 6401 Ͳ3488 1856 3.2 5161.6 11.5 5.3 Ͳ3.2 175.5 95.2 1978 7810 Ͳ6028 Ͳ513 Ͳ0.8 9589.6 12.6 8.0 7.0 159.5 65.5 1979 13.3 16.7 Ͳ3.4 8021 Ͳ9394 Ͳ4774 Ͳ6.3 6914.6 13.5 8.7 1.5 100.8 39.5 1980 12.6 21.3 Ͳ8.7 9143 Ͳ8431 Ͳ4712 Ͳ6.0 3446.5 13.5 15.6 Ͳ5.4 104.5 139.6 18.5 Ͳ18.3 1981 10.5 19.2 Ͳ8.7 7623 Ͳ4859 Ͳ2353 Ͳ2.9 2675.2 19.8 14.0 Ͳ3.2 164.8 488.8 Ͳ17.0 Ͳ8.9 1982 TableVI.1.Argentina:SelectedEconomicIndicators,1977Ͳ2006 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 11.9 18.4 Ͳ6.5 7835 Ͳ4119 Ͳ2436 Ͳ2.8 1332.6 29.3 12.0 4.1 343.8 306.2 Ͳ3.5 6.1 1983 12.2 18.2 Ͳ6.0 8100 Ͳ4118 Ͳ2495 Ͳ2.7 1392.6 29.0 11.2 2.0 626.7 542.4 7.0 Ͳ0.2 1984 15.8 19.7 Ͳ3.9 8396 Ͳ3518 Ͳ952 Ͳ1.1 3441.1 42.3 5.2 Ͳ7.0 672.2 789.6 Ͳ13.9 12.4 1985 16.5 18.3 Ͳ1.8 6852 Ͳ4406 Ͳ2859 Ͳ2.7 2905.2 38.7 4.1 7.1 90.1 56.7 Ͳ14.8 Ͳ3.0 1986 136 Central Government, total revenue and grants Central Government, total expenditure and net lending Central Government balance (Percentunlessotherwisestated) RealGDPannualgrowth InflationCPIchange Nominalexchangerate(PesoperUS$) TermsofTrade(goods) TermsofTrade(goodsandservices) (inUS$millionsunlessotherwisestated) Totalexports,fob Totalimports,fob CurrentAccountBalance Currentaccount(inpercentofGDP) GrossReserves Publicpubliclyguaranteeddebt(aspercentageof GDP) Privatenonguaranteeddebt(aspercentageofGDP) Publicfinances (PercentofGDP) Outputandtrade 15.6 19.6 Ͳ4.1 13.5 18.0 Ͳ4.4 37.5 1.4 45.2 1.7 Ͳ2.0 343.0 308.2 6.9 Ͳ8.7 9134 Ͳ4892 Ͳ1572 Ͳ1.2 3569.4 1988 6360 Ͳ5343 Ͳ4235 Ͳ3.9 1834.1 2.5 131.3 127.4 Ͳ14.2 Ͳ10.0 1987 14.1 26.2 Ͳ12.1 67.6 2.3 9573 Ͳ3864 Ͳ1305 Ͳ1.7 1664.4 Ͳ7.0 3079.8 4736.7 1.4 Ͳ7.9 1989 14.3 16.0 Ͳ1.7 33.2 1.3 12354 Ͳ3726 4552 3.2 4803.1 Ͳ1.3 2314.0 1051.8 Ͳ12.2 Ͳ8.0 1990 TableVI.1.(continued) 16.7 18.0 Ͳ1.2 25.1 0.9 11978 Ͳ7559 Ͳ647 Ͳ0.3 6211.1 10.5 171.7 95.6 Ͳ2.0 44.9 1991 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea 17.1 17.4 Ͳ0.2 18.9 18.0 0.9 19.4 2.7 20.8 1.0 6.3 10.6 0.8 Ͳ1.4 3.0 13268.9 Ͳ15632.5 Ͳ8205.89 Ͳ3.5 14001.4 1993 12398.9 Ͳ13794.8 Ͳ5547.75 Ͳ2.4 10200.2 10.3 24.9 3.9 Ͳ4.5 1.3 1992 18.9 19.4 Ͳ0.5 19.5 5.1 16023.3 Ͳ20162.2 Ͳ10979.5 Ͳ4.3 14550.4 5.8 4.2 0.0 17.1 1.2 1994 18.6 19.6 Ͳ0.9 21.3 6.2 21161.7 Ͳ18804.3 Ͳ5117.96 Ͳ2.0 14515.4 Ͳ2.8 3.4 0.1 Ͳ0.2 Ͳ5.8 1995 17.6 20.1 Ͳ2.5 22.9 7.0 24042.7 Ͳ22283.2 Ͳ6769.98 Ͳ2.5 18324.1 5.5 0.2 0.0 7.7 9.2 1996 137 19.0 20.3 Ͳ1.3 18.5 20.1 Ͳ1.6 9.3 8.0 25.8 22.8 3.9 0.9 0.0 Ͳ6.0 Ͳ4.8 26433.7 Ͳ29530.9 Ͳ14482 Ͳ4.8 24769.9 1998 26430.8 Ͳ28553.5 Ͳ12138.1 Ͳ4.1 22336.8 8.1 0.5 0.0 Ͳ2.0 0.0 1997 21.9 Ͳ2.5 19.4 9.6 28.6 23308.6 Ͳ24103.2 Ͳ11942.8 Ͳ4.2 26268.3 Ͳ3.4 Ͳ1.2 0.0 Ͳ6.1 Ͳ4.4 1999 22.0 Ͳ2.4 19.5 9.1 29.8 26341 Ͳ23889.1 Ͳ8980.62 Ͳ3.2 25147.7 Ͳ0.8 Ͳ0.9 0.0 10.1 9.9 2000 22.6 Ͳ3.7 18.8 11.8 32.0 26542.7 Ͳ19157.8 Ͳ3780.42 Ͳ1.4 14553.4 Ͳ4.4 Ͳ1.1 0.0 Ͳ0.5 Ͳ0.7 2001 33.4 Ͳ15.2 18.2 27.9 88.3 25650.6 Ͳ8473.1 8719.69 8.5 10489.8 Ͳ10.9 25.9 206.5 Ͳ0.4 Ͳ0.6 2002 25.8 Ͳ5.2 20.7 21.9 74.5 29938.8 Ͳ13134.2 8092.6 6.2 14153.9 8.8 13.4 Ͳ5.3 9.8 8.6 2003 27.8 Ͳ4.3 23.4 15.5 65.6 34575.7 Ͳ21311.1 3218.98 2.1 18980.6 9.0 4.4 0.8 0.4 1.8 2004 26.2 Ͳ2.5 23.7 14.4 33.1 40386.8 Ͳ27300.1 5690.52 3.1 27266.9 9.2 9.6 Ͳ0.7 Ͳ3.0 Ͳ2.1 2005 25.9 Ͳ1.7 24.2 10.4 29.9 46456.4 Ͳ32584.8 7998.22 3.7 30996.2 8.0 10.9 5.2 6.5 5.7 2006 Source:UNNationalAccountStatistics;IMFBalanceofPaymentsStatistics,InternationalFinancialStatisticsandWorldEconomicOutlookdatabases;WorldBankGlobalDevelopmentFinance database. (Percentunlessotherwisestated) RealGDPannualgrowth InflationCPIchange Nominalexchangerate(PesoperUS$) TermsofTrade(goods) TermsofTrade(goodsandservices) (inUS$millionsunlessotherwisestated) Totalexports,fob Totalimports,fob CurrentAccountBalance Currentaccount(inpercentofGDP) GrossReserves Publicpubliclyguaranteeddebt(as percentageofGDP) Privatenonguaranteeddebt(as percentageofGDP) Publicfinances (PercentofGDP) Central Government, total revenue and grants Central Government, total expenditure and net lending Central Government balance Outputandtrade TableVI.1.(continued) CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea TableVI.2.Consolidatedfiscalbalance(NationalAdministrationandProvinces) (asapercentageofGDP,annualaverage) National Adm inistration Prim ary Surplus Total Period Prim ary Interest without Social Balance Surplus paym ents Security (2) (1) Av erage 1981-90 nd -4.4 1.9 -6.2 Av erage 1991-94 2.1 1.3 1.2 0.1 Av erage 1995-97 1.7 -0.3 1.7 -2.0 Av erage 1998-01 3.1 0.5 3.1 -2.7 Av erage 1991-01 2.3 0.6 2.0 Consolidated Public Sector Balance (3) -1.5 -7.0 -0.6 -2.6 -4.1 -2.4 Source:Authors´calculationsbasedonMinistryofEconomy,CetrángoloandJiménez(2003)andGaggero(2003). (1)Primarybalanceexcludingreceiptsandexpendituresofnationalsecuritysystem. (3)=(2)+ProvincesandBuenosAiresCitybalances. TableVI.3.Totalpublicinterestpayments,TaxcollectionͲGDPratioandsovereignrisk premium (inpercent) Year 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Tax Average Interest Sovereing collection as interest rate payments / risk premium percentage on public tax collection (annual of GDP debt ratio average) (1) (2) (3) 18.8 20.8 21.3 21.1 20.9 19.6 21.0 21.4 21.4 21.9 21.0 19.2 23.1 s.d 6.6 5.0 5.5 6.1 5.8 6.7 7.6 8.3 8.9 9.4 5.2 1.9 5.5 8.3 6.0 6.9 9.2 9.7 10.9 12.2 15.9 18.5 23.4 13.3 9.6 9.6 6.9 4.9 5.9 12.4 6.5 3.3 5.8 7.2 11.5 14.8 -.-.- Source:Authors´calculationsbasedonMinistryofEconomy. (1)IncludesSecuritySystemreceipts. (2)CalculatedasaratiobetweeninterestpaymentinperiodtanddebtattheendoftͲ1. (3)Taxreceiptsincludethosefromsocialsecuritysystem. 138 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableVI.4.Changeinforeigndebtandforeignassetsbysectorandperiod (US$million) Changes in Net external External debt of External assets of debt of private Public Financial Private Financial Private Sector sector (2)-(3) Total Sector (1) Sector Sector (2) Sector (3) Period 1991:4 to 1994:4 8,529 5,726 10,321 24,575 1,728 566 9,755 1994:4 to 1995:4 5,924 2,952 4,361 13,238 821 11,174 -6,813 1995:4 to 1998:2 9,222 11,579 15,607 36,407 15,307 15,050 557 1998:2 to 2000:4 8,523 -555 3,139 11,107 -4,274 11,876 -8,737 2000:4 to 2001:4 2,975 -8,053 -688 -5,766 -10,665 12,865 -13,553 Total 35,173 11,649 32,740 79,561 2,917 51,531 -18,791 Source:Authors´estimationsonthebasisofdatafromtheMinistryofEconomy. (1)IncludingtheCentralBank. TableVI.5.Fiscaladjustment:ResultsoftheConsolidatedPublicSector(CPS) (aspercentofGDP) Concept 2001 National Public Sector Tax receipts Taxes on exports Financial tax (*) VAT Income tax Other taxes (**) Other receipts Total receipts Total expenditures Primary expenditures Interest services Primary result Total result of the NPS Provinces (***) Total result of the CPS 13.8 0.0 1.1 3.1 2.5 7.2 4.9 18.8 22.0 18.2 3.8 0.5 -3.2 -2.4 -5.6 2004 18.7 2.3 1.5 3.4 3.4 8.1 4.8 23.5 20.9 19.6 1.3 3.9 2.6 0.9 3.5 Variation (2004-2001) 4.9 2.3 0.4 0.4 0.9 0.9 -0.1 4.7 -1.1 1.4 -2.5 3.3 5.9 3.3 9.2 Source:Authors´calculationsbasedonMinistryofEconomy. (*)Taxonbankdebitsandcredits. (**)Includestaxessharedwithprovinces,whichareincludedas. expendituresinPrimaryexpendituresastransferstoprovinces. (***)IncludingtheCityofBuenosAires. 139 140 87.0 TermsofTrade(1985=100) 93.4 39.5 28.2 12.7 1.6 Realeffectiveexchangerate(1993=100) TotalexternaldebtaspercentageofGDP ShortͲtermDebtaspercentageofexternaldebt DebtServiceRatio(longtermdebtonly) ForeignExchangeReserves(US$billion) 404.5 13.9 Realexportgrowth NominalExchangeRate(Won/USD) Ͳ8.8 CurrentAccountaspercentageofGDP (percentunlessotherwisestated) ExternalSectorIndicators 1975 3.0 10.4 28.6 35.5 108.6 484 99.3 51.8 Ͳ1.1 1976 19.8 17.6 Realwagesannualgrowth InflationCPIchange 28.7 10.2 26.7 15.3 28.7 25.3 28.4 InvestmentaspercentageofGDP 25.0 30.2 19.8 20.7 8.9 Investment 10 1977 SavingaspercentageofGDP 10.6 1976 5.9 1975 RealGDPannualgrowth (Percent) MacroeconomicIndicators 4.9 11.3 4.3 26.2 28.1 107.6 484 111.3 26.5 Ͳ2.0 1978 8.5 36.1 18.3 30.0 10.0 6.8 1979 29.4 33.2 113.1 484 106.2 30.2 0.0 1977 18.2 33.1 14.7 30.3 34.4 9.3 1978 5.7 13.7 27.1 32.1 120.1 484 108.9 18.4 Ͳ6.6 6.6 14.0 34.6 42.6 107.6 484 94.4 16.3 Ͳ8.3 1980 92.5 21.4 Ͳ6.4 1981 6.9 14.7 31.5 45.4 108.4 7.0 16.1 33.4 48.7 106.3 681 96.5 2.8 Ͳ3.3 1982 7.9 28.7 7.2 26.3 11.1 7.3 1982 607.4 Ͳ0.5 Ͳ4.0 1979 29.6 21.4 31.8 28.7 25.4 Ͳ3.1 Ͳ10.7 25.0 6.2 1981 Ͳ1.5 1980 TableVI.6.RepublicofKorea:SelectedEconomicIndicators,1975Ͳ1985 CaseStudies:ArgentinaandtheRepublicofKorea 6.9 16.3 30.0 47.8 101.9 731 97.4 11.9 Ͳ1.8 1983 7.2 29.0 3.5 29.5 17.4 10.8 1983 7.6 16.3 36.5 46.2 99.3 776 99.5 19.6 Ͳ1.4 1984 6.4 30.3 2.2 31.8 10.9 8.1 1984 7.7 21.3 22.9 48.4 93.4 806 100.0 3.6 Ͳ0.8 1985 6.6 30.0 2.4 32.2 5.3 6.8 1985 141 37.7 InvestmentaspercentageofGDP Source:BankofKorea. 20.4 52.0 24.2 33.2 36.6 47.3 32.7 48.2 33.7 73.7 1,401 74.1 28.2 34.4 84.3 1,189 114.1 8.6 Ͳ2.8 116.7 5.5 1999 2.2 5.6 31.0 33.9 12.2 8.5 2000 11.7 1998 0.8 11.2 29.1 ForeignExchangeReserves(US$billion) 45.8 ShortͲtermDebtaspercentageofexternaldebt 28.2 100.5 950 122.2 5.0 Ͳ1.6 1997 7.5 Ͳ9.3 25.0 35.8 23.2 TotalexternaldebtaspercentageofGDP 108.1 804 125.4 3.7 Ͳ4.1 1996 4.4 2.5 36.0 37.9 Ͳ22.9 Ͳ2.3 35.8 9.5 Ͳ6.9 4.7 8.3 1999 1998 1997 DebtServiceRatio(longtermdebtonly) 105.0 771 138.5 Realeffectiveexchangerate(1993=100) NominalExchangeRate TermsofTrade(2000=100) 30.3 Realexportgrowth 1995 Ͳ1.7 5.0 6.7 38.9 35.7 8.4 7.0 1996 CurrentAccountaspercentageofGDP (percentunlessotherwisestated) ExternalSectorIndicators Realwagesannualgrowth 4.4 6.4 36.5 SavingaspercentageofGDP Inflation 13.1 9.2 1995 Investment RealGDPannualgrowth (Percent) MacroeconomicIndicators 96.2 33.7 29 90.7 1,130 100.0 19.9 2.4 2000 4.1 1.5 29.3 31.9 Ͳ0.2 3.8 2001 102.8 32.2 27.1 85.1 1,291 95.5 Ͳ12.7 1.7 121.4 34.8 26.1 89.7 1,252 95.0 8.0 1.0 2002 2.7 8.6 29.1 31.4 6.6 3.1 2002 2001 TableVI.7.RepublicofKorea:SelectedEconomicIndicators,1995Ͳ2004 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 155.4 33.9 26.6 92.1 1,192 89.0 19.3 2.0 2003 3.6 5.7 30.0 33.0 4.0 4.6 2003 199.1 33.8 26.1 94.6 1,146 85.3 31.0 4.1 2004 3.6 2.8 30.2 35.0 1.9 2004 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERVII APPROPRIATEINSTITUTIONALSETTINGS FORPUBLICDEBTMANAGEMENT JaimeDelgadilloCortez (WorldBank97) A. Introduction Weak institutions dealing with public debt management in transition and emerging economies as well as external shocks can be major sources of debt distress. While shocks cannot be totally controlled,theinstitutionalsettingfordebtmanagementcanbestrengthened.Thusvulnerabilityto debtproblemscanbereducedorbettermanagedwhensolidinstitutionsareinplace. Publicdebtmanagementcanbedefinedastheprocessofestablishingandexecutingastrategyfor managingtheGovernment’sdebtportfolioinordertomeetgovernmentfundingrequirements,to achieveobjectiveswithregardtocostsandrisks,andtomeetotherobjectivesrelatedtodebtsuch as promoting investment for economic growth and developing the domestic financial market for governmentsecurities.Effectivedebtmanagementcanalsohelptoensurethatboththeleveland growthofdebtarefiscallysustainable.98 In emerging and transition economies the main emphasis in debt management is put on the following: x x x x Theproductionofreliabledebtdata; Marketdevelopment; Ensuringadequatefinancingfordevelopmentalandsocialneeds; EnsuringcompliancewithdebtͲserviceobligations; 97 98 TheauthorwasaSeniorEconomicAffairsOfficerofUNCTADwhenhewrotethischapter. SeeWorldBankandIMF(2002),andDMFAS,EffectiveDebtManagementaRevision,forthcoming. 143 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement x x x x Controllingcontingentliabilities; Negotiatingagreementswithcreditors; Performingcost/riskanalysis; Designingstrategiestoattainasustainabledebtposition. An appropriate institutional framework for debt management can contribute to achieving the objectivesofeffectivedebtmanagement.Institutionalarrangementsshouldfocusonthefollowing: x x x x x x Governance; Clarityoftherolesoftheinstitutionsdealingwithdebtmanagement; Specificationoftheobjectivesforpublicdebtmanagement; Coordinationofpublicdebtmanagementwithotherpublicpolicies; TheorganizationalstructureofDMOs; Transparencyandaccountability. This paper is divided in two parts. Section II provides an overview of the context of public debt managementanddescribesthechallengeswhichDMOsandotherareasofpublicdebtmanagement must meet as part of the broad framework of macroeconomic policies. Section III examines the different issues related to the institutional framework of debt management including governance, mandates, accountability and transparency, the separation of executive and operational debt management,andtheneedforanexecutivedebtmanagementcommittee.Theprincipalfocusisthe role,organizationandfunctionsofDMOsinlowandmiddleͲincomecountriesfromtheperspective ofdevelopmentneeds. B. TheContextofPublicDebtManagement 1. TheChallengesandConstraintsFacingInstitutionsDealingwithDebtManagement ProͲactive debt management is essential in today’s market conditions. DMOs must face the challengeofmorecomplexportfoliosofpublicandprivatedebt,theglobalizationofcapitalmarkets, andthevolatilityofcapitalflows.Furthermore,manyemergingmarketeconomiesobtainsubstantial financingintheformofequityflows. External factors such as volatility in the price of export products and exchangeͲ and interestͲ rate fluctuations, and contagion effects are beyond the DMO’s control. However, in normal circumstances,DMOscanplayacrucialroleincrisispreventionandresolution. Inadequate legal arrangements, unclear definition of functions and responsibilities, inappropriate organizational structures, inadequate staff and insufficient training, and the failure to define strategicobjectivesandresponsibilitiesarealltoocommonfeaturesofDMOs.Theseweaknessesare manifest in the absence of strong middle offices which should be equipped to conduct analytical work required for defining a debt strategy. Unclear debt management objectives and benchmarks andtheinabilitytoconductDebtSustainabilityAnalysis(DSA)arealsofrequentproblemsofDMOs. Other deficiencies involve the implementation of strategies and the lack of coordination with monetaryandfiscalpolicies. FactorswhicharenotunderthecontrolofDMOsbutwhichnonethelesscanimpedetheirefficient performance include structural deficiencies in money markets and in the primary and secondary markets for financial instruments as well as inadequate management of quasiͲfiscal deficits and 144 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment internationalreserves.MoreoversomeDMOslack theresourcesormandate(orboth) to transmit clearmessagestootherlevelsoftheGovernment. Thisdocumentdoesnotaddressalloftheseissues.Itfocusesonwaysinwhichtheconstraintsand challenges facing DMOs can be addressed by strengthening the ability of DMOs to manage their debt portfolios and by strengthening other institutional and legal arrangements for debt management. Figure VII.1. illustrates the core activities typically performed by DMOs in lowͲ and middleͲincome countries. In the former, debt management is concerned principally with captive markets for domestic debt and concessional financing or grants. Government financing depends heavily on shortͲterminstrumentswithhighinterestrates.DMOsthusattempttodiversifythedebtportfolio by developing primary and secondary financial markets and by eventually accessing international capitalmarkets. In the case of middleͲincome countries, debt management has a wider role in involving the managementofthecostsandrisksofamorediversifiedportfolioincludingrecoursetotransactions inderivatives,providingarangeoffinancialservicestotheGovernment,andeventuallyparticipating inaintegratedfinancialriskmanagementwithotherpartsoftheGovernment.99 FigureVII.1. Debt Management ExpandedRole IntegratedCost/RiskManagement ofLiabilities; SupplyofFinancial ServicestoGovernment; ManagementofFinancialAssets; TransactionsinDerivativeMarkets; OperationalRiskManagement. Debt Management BasicRole AccessInternationalCapital MarketstoDiversifyDebt Portfolio; DevelopDomesticPrimary& SecondaryMarkets; IssueShortͲTermGovernment Securities;TapCaptiveSourcesof DomesticDebt; ManageODAandIDAGrants. MiddleͲIncome Countries LowͲIncome Countries 99 See,forexample,TheChangingRoleofthePublicDebtManager,presentationmadebyPhillipAnderson,WorldBank,in UNCTAD(2005). 145 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement 2. PublicDebtManagementasanIntegralPartoftheFrameworkofMacroeconomic Policies Figure VII.2. below indicates the relationship between public debt, external debt and the real domesticsectorsoftheeconomy.Publicinvestmentprogramsarefinancedwithinternalorexternal resourcesintheformofloansorgrants. Debt flows are recorded in the Balance of Payments. DSA relates public debt information to the balanceofpaymentsdataandmacroeconomicvariablesincludinggrowthobjectivesandeconomic and social programs. Information regarding debt stocks and flows (including debt service and disbursements), interest rates, exchange rates, capitalͲaccount movements, etc. is combined to determinethesizeofthefinancinggap.Thisneedstobefilledwithacombinationofexternaland domesticfinancingand,ifnecessary,withdebtrestructuringordebtrelief. Given the importance of domestic debt and the necessity of incorporating it into the overall managementofgovernmentliabilities,theconceptofTotalPublicDebtisusedinthispaper,which thusincludesbothexternalanddomesticdebt. FigureVII.2. Flow chart for public debt management in developing economies within macroeconomic framework EXTERNAL SECTOR Imports - Exports B.O.P. Fin an Gr ow cing th pr oj Ob jec ects tiv es s ipt n ts e m t m ay res e p s te e ur vic in sb er l & Di t s ipa b c De Prin t en re ce PUBLIC DEBT EXTERNAL Internal Financing Requirements Tax and revenues Local currency Local counterpart funds Public investment programs REAL SECTOR G.D.P. External Financing requirements Loans and grants BUDGET DOMESTIC DEBT PUBLIC FINANCIAL SECTOR Sincepublic debt is often the largest liability in the national balance sheets of low and middleͲ income countries, its management cannot be seen as isolated from the overall macroeconomic managementofacountry.Publicdebthasmajorlinkageswithmacroeconomicandfinancialstability. 146 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment The objectives of fiscal, monetary and public debt policies should be coordinated to achieve and maintaindebtsustainabilityandfiscaldiscipline. Moreover, an effective system of overall financial management is essential not only for macroeconomic management butalsoforprovidingreliablefinancialinformationtopreventfraud andwaste. Publicdebtmanagementaspartofsuchasystemcansignificantlycontributetotheattainmentof its objectives. Relevant information on debt management strategies, DSA, and public debt stocks andflowsareessentialingredientsofsoundpublicfinances.Thisisparticularlytrueinthecontextof budgetingandexpendituremanagement.Inthisarea,Governmentswanttoimproveplanningand budgetformulation;setrealisticandachievablespendingceilings;improvespending prioritization; monitorcommitmentsanddisbursements;andensureaccurateandtimelyinformationflowsamong governmentinstitutions. As is noted in the World Bank’s Public Expenditure Management Handbook, theory and practice showthatreformofacountry’sinstitutionsoffinancialmanagementͲbothformalandinformal– can have a decisive influence on budgetary outcomes at three levels. At the first level, the introduction of institutional reforms in public financial management can improve aggregate fiscal discipline and planning as well as the traditional control functions of public expenditure through budgetparameters.Atthesecondlevel,thesereformscanimprovetheplanningfunctionofpublic expendituremanagementthroughimprovementsinthecapacitytoallocateresourcesinaccordance withstrategicprioritiesandbaselinedataonpriorexpendituresandrevenuepatterns.Atthethird level, the reforms contribute to political decisionͲmaking concerning the allocation of scarce resourcestoselectedpriorities. Figure VII.3. illustrates the flows of information between a consolidated DMO and its main stakeholders: the Ministry of Finance, the Central Bank, the National Planning Agency, and its externalcreditorsincludingInternationalOrganizations.Incomingandoutgoinginformationtoand from the DMO contribute to a close and coordinated relationship regarding debt management amongkeyinstitutions.Thisfacilitatestheimplementationofdebtmanagementoperationssuchas debtservicepayments,andenablestheDMOtoassisttheGovernmentinconductingaDSA. 147 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement FigureVII.3.IntegratedDebtManagementInformationFlows CONGRESS Budget Debt Service Projections Debt Service Central Bank Fiscal Targets BOP Information Private Debt National Planning / Development Office Ministry of Finance : Debt Stocks & Flows Debt Exchange Rates Interest Rates - Budget Public Investment Social & Economic Projects Grants Disbursement Projections Marcoeconomic Objectives DMO International Organizations Creditors Stocks & Flows Internal/External Financing Requirements Records on Balances Public/Private Entities (guarantees) - Treasury - Accounting Information on guarantees C. TheRoleandOrganizationofaDMO 1. GovernanceIssues:LegalFramework,MandatesandJurisdiction,andAccountability andTransparency The legal framework for a DMO should identify the authority that borrows and issues new debt, invests,andundertakestransactionsontheGovernment’sbehalf.Theorganizationalframeworkfor debt management should be well specified, and should ensure that mandates and roles are well articulated. In accordance with IMFͲWorld Bank guidelines, the legal framework should cover the appropriatedelegationofauthoritytodebtmanagers. An Act of Parliament usually stipulates that the Minister of Finance may delegate to the DMO specificpowers,dutiesandfunctionsthatpertaintothemanagementofpublicdebt.Thishelpsthe DMOtoconcludetransactionsinatimelymanner,totakeadvantageofmarketopportunities,and toensurethatprojectsarefundedinthefiscalyearinwhichtheywerebudgetedfor.Thesebenefits also apply to concessional funding inasmuch as loan negotiations may be concluded but projects maynotbeimplementedontimeduetodecisionͲmakingdelayscausedbyinadequatedelegation. ThedegreeofdelegationmaydependonthenumberoffinancialtransactionstheDMOundertakes in a year. Finance Ministers face difficult decisions in determining how much decisionͲmaking authorityshouldbevestedinothers,whatspecificborrowingandinvestmentpowerstodelegate, and whom to delegate this power to. Given the importance of these issues, Governments tend to move cautiously. Debt management objectives should be clearly defined and published. These objectives should encompass all types of government obligations, including domestic and external debt and contingent liabilities. The policies regarding risk and cost should also be disclosed. The responsibilities and roles attached to each institution involved in debt management should be clearly spelled out, since otherwise lack of coordination can lead to uncertainties and higher 148 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment transaction and borrowing costs. Consolidation of the authority for debt management in a single wellͲstructuredDMOcanenormouslycontributetotransparencyandaccountability. Legislation on fiscal responsibility can bring the debt management objectives in line with fiscal targets. This is particularly important when local Governments have a certain degree of independencetoincurdebts,bothforeignanddomestic,especiallyinfederalcountries. Delegationimpliesaccountability.Therefore,itishighlydesirablethattheActofParliamentspecifies thattheMinisterofFinancepreparesanannualorsemiͲannualreportwithParliamentonactivities related to public debt management, and on plans regarding public debt management in the next fiscalyear.Thishelpspromotetransparencyandaccountability,andencouragesadomesticdebate on these issues. Investors and international financial institutions would also be able to acquire a better knowledge of the Government’s future funding plans and of its developmental priorities. (MajorfeaturesofthelegalframeworkforDMOsandofitsresponsibilitiesaresummarizedinBoxes 1and2.) BOXVII.1.DMOs’MainFunctionsandResponsibilities x Toimplementthedebtstrategy,debtmanagementpolicies,procedures,benchmarksandguidelines prescribedintheregulationsdesignedattheappropriatelevelofGovernment; x ToissuedebtortocontractdebtonbehalfoftheMinisterofFinance,toparticipateinDSAtogether withotherareasoftheGovernment,toalerttheauthoritiesconcerningsituationsofunsustainable debt,andtorecommendtimelyadjustmentswhenneeded; x Tomaintainatimelyandreliabledatabaseonpublicdebtandtoconductregulardatavalidation; x Tominimizecostsandrisksassociatedwithpublicborrowingandpubliclyissuedguarantees; x To order debt service payments to the financial agent of the central Government through the Treasuryand/ortheBudgetDepartment,fortheloansandbondissuesofthecentralGovernment. x Togenerateandprovidereliableandtimelyinformationonpublicdebtpoliciesanddatatoavariety ofusersandtothepubliconaperiodicbasis; x Toprovidegovernmentguaranteesafterriskevaluation.TheCongressonannualbasisthroughthe budget law normally authorizes guarantee coverage. The DMO should monitor all forms of contingentliabilities; x Tomonitortheloansandbondsissuesofpublicentitiesandenterprises; x To monitor debt incurred at the subͲnational level, including the loans and bonds issues of local Governmentsandentitiescontrolledbythem; x Tomonitorgrants,privateexternaldebtandonͲlendingtobothpublicandprivateentities; x To ensure that the provisions of international agreements with creditors (Paris Club, London Club, otherbilateralcreditors,multilateralcreditors,etc.)arecompliedwith. 149 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement Sound practice under the heading of accountability requires regular auditing of the financial transactions undertaken bythe debtmanagerstoassesstheircompliancewithgenerallyaccepted accountingpracticesandwiththeGovernment’sportfoliomanagementpolicies.Thisauditingwould reviewtherisksintheportfolioandcompliancewiththeriskmanagementframework.Itcouldalso facilitate the establishment of multiͲyear targets for debt. The results of the audits would be disclosedinthereportstotheMinisterofFinanceandParliament. BOXVII.2.LegalandRegulatoryProcessesforDebtIssuancebyaDMO A DMO needs to be able to operate in accordance with rules which ensure that debt issuance is consistent with specified borrowing limits, and which do nothing to undermine the confidence of lendersandinvestorsconcerningtheobligationtoserviceandrepaygovernmentdebt.Thedelegation ofauthorityshouldbeclear,asshouldbeaccountabilityandreportingobligations.ManyGovernments have in place legislation of this kind. Usually the legislation authorizes the Minister of Finance to conductallborrowingandrelatedfinancialtransactionsonbehalfoftheGovernmentandestablishesa maximum amount of new funding and guarantees that can be extended over a specified period (generally one year). This avoids the need for specific authorizations from Parliament for individual transactions, which might increase the role of political factors in the decision making and delay the executionoftransactions. 2. Policies,ProceduresandOperations Risks of losses from inadequate operational controls should be managed according to sound business practices, including wellͲarticulated responsibilities for staff, clear monitoring and control policies,andadequatereportingarrangements. x x x x x x Debt management activities should be supported by an accurate and comprehensive managementinformationsystemwithpropersafeguards. StaffinvolvedindebtmanagementshouldbesubjecttoacodeͲofͲconductandconflictͲofͲ interestguidelinesregardingthemanagementoftheirpersonalfinancialaffairs. A framework should be developed to enable debt managers to identify and manage the tradeͲoffs between expected costs and risks in the Government’s debt portfolio. Portfolio benchmarksshouldreflectthelevelofriskthatisacceptabletotheDMO. Aspartofriskassessment,debtmanagersshouldregularlyconductstresstestsofthedebt portfolioonthebasisofeconomicandfinancialshockstowhichtheGovernment–andthe countrymoregenerally–arepotentiallyexposed. In order to help/guide decisions and reduce Government’s risk, debt managers should considerthefinancialandotherriskcharacteristicsoftheGovernment’scashflows. Theresponsibilityforidentifyinganddevelopingplanstomanageoperationalrisksalsolies with the DMO which should have a plan to minimize damages caused by such risks. (For moredetailonoperationalrisksseeAnnex1.) 150 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment BOXVII.3.TypesofRisk MarketRisk.Theriskassociatedwithchangesinmarketindicators,suchasinterestrates,exchangerates,commodity prices.ForbothdomesticandforeigncurrencydebtchangesininterestratesaffectdebtͲservicingcostsonnewissues and on floating rate debt at the rateͲreset dates. The market risk of debt denominated in or indexed to foreign currencies is due to the vulnerability of debtͲservicing costs as measured in domestic currency to exchange rate movements.Bondswithembeddedputoptions(i.e.rightsforinvestorstosellthebondstotheissuerataspecified priceduringacertainperiod)canexacerbatemarketandrolloverrisks. RolloverRisk.Theriskthatdebtwillhavetoberolledoveratahighcostor,inextremecases,cannotberolledoverat all.Totheextentthatrolloverriskislimitedtotheriskthatdebtmighthavetoberolledoverathigherinterestratesit maybeclassifiedasatypeofmarketrisk.However,becauserolloverriskcanleadto,orexacerbate,adebtcrisis,itis oftentreatedseparately.Managingthisriskisparticularlyimportantforemergingmarketcountries. LiquidityRisk.Therearetwotypesofliquidityrisk.Oneconcernstherisksofsituationsinwhichaborrowerdoesnot have access to liquid assets when they are needed. The otherrefers to the risk of penalty rates of interest or other costswhenaborrowerwantstoexitapositionthroughthesaleofassetsforwhichthemarketisilliquid.Thisriskis particularlyrelevanttothemanagementofliquidassetsandliabilitiesandtotheuseofderivativescontracts. CreditRisk.TheriskofnonͲperformancebyaborrowersorbyoneofthecounterpartiestootherfinancialcontracts. ThisriskarisesinvariouscontextssuchastheacceptanceofbidsinauctionsofsecuritiesissuedbytheGovernment andinrelationtocontingentliabilitiesandderivativecontracts. SettlementRisk.Thepotentiallossthatacounterpartycouldsufferasaresultofthepossibilitythatitdoesnotreceive funds or other assets, for reasons other than default, from another counterparty in accordance with an agreed timetable. Operational Risk.Thisincludesarangeofdifferenttypesofrisksduetoinvolvementinvariouskindsofbusiness.It includesrisksduetotransactionerrorsinthevariousstagesofexecutingandrecordingtransactions,toinadequacies orfailuresininternalcontrols,systemsandservices,andtotheeffectsofnaturaldisasters.Itmaybedefinedtoinclude reputationalriskandlegalrisk. DMOs can implement a “Code of Conduct for Staff and Management” that rests on a tripod of professionalismandintegrity;honesty,faithfulness,efficiency,staffcourtesyinofficialconduct;and dignifiedconductinprivatelife. x Professionalism and integrity requires staff to openly demonstrate professionalism and integrityinexecutingthepoliciesandprogramsoftheDMO; x Honesty,faithfulness,efficiency,andcourtesyinofficialconductrequiresstafftokeepfaith to their official responsibilities by not allowing personal considerations or activities to interfere with official duties, maintaining constancy and sincerity of purpose, being resultͲ oriented,andrespectingthepeopleitdealswith; x Dignifiedconductinprivateliferequiresstafftoexerciserestraintintheirprivatelivesandin theconductofprivateactivitiesthatcouldhavebearingsontheirofficialengagements. Annualworkplansshouldbetightlyintegratedwithdebtstrategywork.Thereisastrategyhierarchy extendingfromoverallstrategicdebtmanagementobjectivestoannualdebtmanagementreviews andplansconsistentwiththeoverallobjectivesandtooperationalplansforindividualworkareasto giveeffecttotheannualstrategy. 151 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement 3. TheSeparationofExecutiveandOperationalDebtManagement TheExecutiveDebtManagementfunctions(thatisthepolicy,regulatoryandresourcingfunctions100) are the responsibility of the Minister of Finance and other high government officials, such as the Heads of the DMO, National Planning, and Budget and Treasury Offices. These functions may be subjecttooveralldirectionandcoordinationthroughahighlevelbodywhichcouldbedenominated astheExecutiveDebtManagementCommittee(EDMC). Theroleofthe EDMCistoapprovedebt management guidelinesand theprinciplestoimplement them. It meets at intervals to analyse the DMO’s performance and evaluate compliance with establishedregulationsandtargets.TheGovernoroftheCentralBankcanbepartofthisCommittee tohelptoensurecoordinationbetweenmonetarypolicy,debtmanagementandfiscalpolicy.DayͲ toͲday operations are delegated by the EDMC to the DMO and then reported to and coordinated withtheMinisterofFinance. An organizational structure for effective debt management is shown schematically in figure VII.5., andtheproposedcompositionoftheEDMCinfigureVII.6.ItsdifferentfunctionsarespecifiedinBox VII.4. FigureVII.5.EffectivePublicDebtManagement ExecutiveDebtManagementCommittee (HeadedbyMinisterofFinance) ExecutiveDebtManagement OperationalDebtManagement DebtManagementOffice Front Office MiddleOffice BackOffice The DMO must have a clear mediumͲterm strategy, performance indicators, and strict monitoring andcontrolfunctions.Thesefunctionsshouldnotberelatedonlytodebtissuanceanddebtservice. Theyshouldalsoencompasseffectivemanagementoftherisksassociatedwiththedebtstructure andensuringcompatibilitywiththefiscaltargets,whilereducinggovernmentfinance’svulnerability toshocks. Based on previous work on effective debt management developed by DMFAS/UNCTAD and other international organizations such as the World Bank and the IMF and best practices in debt management implemented in several countries, the recommended Executive Debt Management (EDM)functionscanbesummarizedasfollows: 100 SeeDMFAS/UNCTAD(1993). 152 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment (a) EDMfunctionsforexternaldebtincludetheestablishmentofdebtsustainabilitystandards; determination of borrowing needs and limits, and desired terms and borrowing sources; formulation of guidelines for debt operations such as debt conversions, buyͲbacks, onͲ lending,etc;apolicyframeworkforgovernmentguaranteesandcontingentliabilities;and arrangementsandregulationsforborrowing,disbursements,anddebtservice. (b) EDMfunctionsfordomesticdebtconcerntheformulationofdebtmanagementobjectives and strategy; establishing borrowing ceilings according to budgetary and fiscal goals; development of a benchmark debt structure; determination of the volume and types of instrumentstobeusedandtheirmaturity,timing,frequency,andsellingtechniques;and developmentofcommunicationlinkageswithstakeholders. (c) Operational Debt Management is the responsibility of the DMO itself. Basic functions underthisheadingincluderecording,operating,monitoring,controlling,coordinatingand negotiating public debt. These functions are best performed within the framework of a Back,Middle,andFrontOfficetypeoforganization.Separationoffunctionsinthiscontext helps promote the independence of those designing strategies and monitoring them (Middle Office) from those registering debt and performing operations (Back Office) and fromthosecarryingoutnegotiationsanddebttransactions(FrontOffice). FigureVII.6.PossibleCompositionoftheExecutiveDebtManagementCommittee Head of Treasury Head of Budget Head of DMO Secretary Minister of Finance Chairman Economic Adviser to the President Governor of Central Bank Head of Planning Office 153 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement Consolidationofthedebtmanagementfunctionsinasingleofficecanleadtoefficiencygains.Thisis crucially important to avoid fragmentation of the debt strategy. When conducting DSA and risk analysisitisimportanttohaveanintegratedviewofthetotaldebtportfolio. The terms of reference of the DMO should incorporate all functions related to the contracting of domesticandexternaldebt.Therefore,theorganizationalstructuremusthaveunitsresponsiblefor theregistrationandmanagementofbothtypesofliabilities.(FordetailsseeBoxVII.1). TheorganizationalstructureoftheDMOshouldbebasedonaFunctionsManualthatdeterminesits role, responsibilities and functions together with a staff table detailing job descriptions and responsibilities.ThefunctionsofeachelementoftheDMOstructureshouldbeclearlyspecifiedhere. There should be effective coordination and information sharing within the DMO embodied in an internalcommunicationsstrategy. TheDMOshouldhavethepersonnelrequiredforefficientresponsetoitsmandates,andapolicyof adequateremunerationtoattractandretainqualifiedstaff. BOXVII.4.FunctionsoftheExecutiveDebtManagementCommittee x ApprovethedebtmanagementstrategyoverthemediumͲterm; x Decideonsectorsthatwillhaveaccesstoexternalordomesticfinancingandonwhatterms; x Definethelevelandcharacteristicsofdomesticdebtissuesforfiscalpurposes; x Establishborrowingceilingsbydebtorandcreditorcategories; x Establishguidelinesforextendinggovernmentguarantees; x Definetherequiredmixofexternalanddomesticindebtednessandthedesiredamortizationprofiles; x DecideondebtrestructuringsproposedbytheDMOtoconformwiththedebtstrategy; x Providelaws,guidelinesandregulationsforeffectivedebtmanagement; x Define institutional framework for the DMO and other institutions involved in debt management operations,includingpropercoordinationofactivities; x Put in place the organizational framework for the DMO, including information flows, functions, and schedulesofduties; x Through the Budget Law, for each fiscal year, establish the debtͲservice targets and ceilings on indebtednessforforeignanddomesticdebt; x Establishbenchmarksforcertaindebtindicators,suchasdebtservicetoexports,stockofpublicdebtto GDP,debtservicetogovernmentrevenues,etc.; x Definepolicies,includingthosecoveringsalaries,careerperspectivesandallowances,forattractingand retainingDMOstaffwithrelevantqualifications; x PutinplacetrainingprogramsforDMOstaff; x Supportimprovements,maintenanceandextensionsofthedebtdatabase. 154 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 4. TheFront,Middle,andBackOfficesofaDMO (a)BackOffice The Back Office centralizes all aspects of the registration, monitoring and control of disbursements/subscriptions, of the execution and management of public debt service operations, andoftheproductionofstatisticalinformation.Thefunctionscomprisetheadministrationofthefull cycleofthelifeofacontract/instrumentfromthesignature/issuetoitsfullpayment. TheOfficeisresponsibleforthemanagementoftherecordsofdebtholdersandfortheregistration of government debt instruments. Forecasts of forthcoming debtͲservice payments for domestic as well as external debt need to be produced and sent to the financial agent of the Government for compliancewiththedebtͲserviceobligations. The Office performs the basic functions which permit all other operational functions to be carried out.Thedistributionoftaskstocomplywiththesefunctionscouldbedividedintothefollowing:(1) theAreaofRegistrationconcerningtheregistryofdebtinformationinthedatabase;(2)theAreaof AccountingOperations,whichismainlyconcernedwiththeissueofthePaymentOrders;and(3)the AreaoftheDatabaseAdministratorinchargeofthesystemandnetworkmaintenanceincludingthe requiredinformationtechnology.ThesefunctionsshouldberegulatedbyaProceduresManualthat setsnormsfortheflowofinformationintheoperativecycleandthatlinkstheoperationalactivities withthestructureandfunctionsoftheDMO. UnderAreaofRegistrationgrants,onͲlending,guaranteeddebtandcontingentliabilitiesshouldbe registeredandmonitoredclosely,asshouldprivatenonͲguaranteeddebtanddebtincurredatthe subͲnationallevel. TheBackOfficenormallyhastodealwithlargeͲscalerequirementsforinformationonpublicdebt. International organizations, different areas of the executive and legislative branches, researchers, and the media require reliable and continuously updated debt information. Transparency and efficiencyingeneratinginformationisthusakeytaskofthe“AreaofRegistration”.101 AnimportantactivityofthispartoftheBackOfficeistoconductdatavalidationatregularintervals inordertoensurethereliabilityofthedatabase.Normally,thisalsorequiresregularreconciliations of data with creditors. The dissemination of information on public debt should be closely coordinatedwiththeFrontandMiddleOffices. The preparation of payment orders to service public debt can be performed by the Area of AccountingOperations,withpaymentschedulesgeneratedbythefunctionalgroupsoftheAreaof Registration,althoughtheactualaccountingfordebtservicepaymentsisnotnecessarilydoneinside the DMO. With a reliable debt database and a debt system, the preparation of payment orders shouldberapidandefficient.Thepaymentorderscanbegeneratedandprinteddirectlyfromthe databasesystem,basedonthedebtsystem’sinformation.Theprocessofdebtservicepaymentsto creditorsisperformedafterthereconciliationofthecreditors’requestswiththeamountsscheduled inthedebtsystem’sdatabase.Thiscentralizationofpublicdebtregistrationandmonitoringandthe operative process for the issue of the payment orders represent important savings through the reductionofprocessingtimeandtheeliminationofpenaltiesforlatepayments. 101 FormoredetailsonthistopicseeInformationandTransparencyinDebtManagement,presentationbyUdaibirS.Das, IMF,inUNCTAD(2005). 155 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement TheAreaofAccountingOperationsoftheBackOfficeshouldalsoensurethatbudgetaryprovisions exist for (external and domestic) public debt service, including contingent liabilities, and that sufficientsumsareallocatedtoreserves. A wellͲorganized Back Office will have a structure for ensuring the efficient flow of information, adequate business processes, and the quality of information produced. Therefore, the structure shouldbeorganizedwithadistributionoffunctionsthatclearlydefinesandestablishesthesources offinancingandthecoͲordinationofthedifferententitiesinvolved. Under the Area of the Database Administrator the monitoring and control of publicͲdebt information should be based on a methodical centralization of public credit operations in the database of the DMO. The debt database should contain upͲtoͲdate information on the domestic and external debt registered in the system. The registration of operations of domestic or external financinginthedatabasesystemisinitiatedwiththeopeningofloanfilesclassifiedbythetypeand use of the financing, creditor, debtor, and executing agency. This registration will facilitate an adequatecontrolofthemanagementofdisbursementsandpaymentsmadeduringthefiscalyearas wellastheprojectionoffuturedebtservice.Thecontrolandmonitoringoftheregistrationofnew loansinthedatabaseshouldbecarriedoutbytheheadofeachfunctionalgroup.Thestatusofthe database and its evolution should be evaluated in regular meetings among the heads of the functionalgroupswhohavetheresponsibilityofexecutingtheworkprogram. The input of loan information to the database should be monitored and controlled periodically by the head of unit of the Back Office of the DMO. The technicians of the units should have the responsibilitytorunlistsofloanstoverifytheconsistencyoftheinformationandtocorrectthemif necessary. The Database Administrator should perform the validation of the consolidated debt information periodically. Errors and inconsistencies in the information can be detected through consolidatedreports,andtheheadofeachgroupshouldbenotifiedforcorrections.Thestatusof the database and its consistency should be analysed in periodic meetings with the heads of units whohavetheresponsibilityofexecutingtheagreedworkprogram. Confidence in the debt information processed and reported by the DMO has a direct relationship withthequalityofdatathatisenteredinthesystem.Inordertoensuretimelinessandhighquality, theprocessingandreportingofdebtinformationshouldberegulatedbyaresolutionorlegalnorm thatinstructsalltheentitiesofthepublicsectortorespondtodatarequirementsoftheDMO. ThecontrolandsupervisionfunctionsofaDMOrequirethatdebtinformationbecollectedwithout obstacles.ThiswillguaranteethattheauthoritieshaveaccesstoupͲtoͲdatedetailedandaggregated information. Therefore it is important that the DMO establishes direct contact with the executing agenciesorusersofresourcesandcreditors.Informationfromthesesourceswillbereconciledwith thatreceivedfromothersourcesincludingtheCentralBank. It is also important that the institution in charge of monitoring the public investment program providesallitsinformationtotheDMO.Thisinformationwillguaranteethattheprojectionsofdebt servicearecompatiblewith estimates ofdisbursementsforinvestmentprojects.Thiswill enhance thequalityoftheestimatesprovidedbytheDMOforthepreparationoftheGovernment’sbudget. (b)TheMiddleOffice The main function of the Middle Office is to conduct the analytical work required for assisting executivemanagementlevelsindesigningadebtstrategyandaframeworkforriskmonitoringand 156 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment control.Regulardebtportfolioreviewshouldbepartoftheactivitiesofthisofficeincoordination withothergovernmentoffices. Otherimportantrolesofthisofficearethegenerationofmanagerialreportsonpublicdebtforusers insidetheDMOandtheGovernment,andthepublicationandotherdisseminationofstatisticsand other information related to policies concerning external and domestic debt. The preparation of debt information and reports should be in accordance with standard requirements and specific requests. The Procedures Manual should specify the reports that are required by various governmententitiesandbyexternaluserssuchastheWorldBank,theIMF,regionaldevelopment banks,ParisClubcreditors,civilsocietyandotherprivateparties. The work program of the Middle Office should include the preparation of monthly and quarterly managerial reports for the Ministry of Finance. The reports would comprise the stock of debt outstandingandtransactionsthattookplaceduringspecificperiods.Thisworkprogramshouldalso besupportedbythepreparationanddistributionofaStatisticalBulletinofPublicDebt. The work program should also include estimates mainly used for analytical purposes such as projectionsofdisbursementsandpublicdebtservicewithvariousassumptionsconcerninginterest andexchangerates.Theusefulnessofsuchestimateswillbeenhancedbythedevelopmentofthe capacitytoincorporatedebtdataintotheframeworkofbalanceͲofͲpaymentsandmacroeconomic data analysis. Such an expanded framework will facilitate the design and implementation of debt strategies. ForthisworkitmaybeusefultoestablishanAnalyticalFunctionandaRiskAnalysisFunction. TheAnalyticalFunctionwillperformportfolioanalysisinamacroeconomicframeworkandanalysis of longͲterm debt sustainability on a regular basis. DSA needs to include fiscal sustainability and should also include scenario analysis of ways of meeting mediumͲ and longͲterm social and economicneeds.ThiscanbeaccomplishedbyusingdifferentDSAanalyticaltools,suchastheWorld Bank/IMFdebtdynamicstemplates,DebtͲProorDSM+.102 Performance of sensitivity analysis with different assumptions about exchange rates and interest rates allows the Middle Office to provide information about the impact of different debt service scenariosonfiscalandmonetaryvariables.Proposeddebtmanagementtargetsregardingcurrency composition and amortization profiles are also part of the Middle Office’s responsibilities. This function will provide a basis for the Minister or the EDMC to evaluate the macroeconomic debt strategy and amend it, if necessary. The Analytical Function would also allow the DMO to adopt strategieswithinthemandategiventoitandtoproposestrategychangestotheMinisterofFinance. TheRiskAnalysisFunctionwillberesponsiblefortheevaluationandestablishmentofcostandrisk limits for the debt portfolio. This can be accomplished by scenario analysis involving different assumptionsconcerningnotonlyexchangeandinterestratesbutalsoothermajormacroeconomic variablessuchasglobaleconomicgrowthaswellasgrowthandpricesinthecountry’smajorexport markets. 102 Information on these analytical tools can be obtained through the websites of Debt Relief International or the DMFAS/UNCTADProgramme. 157 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement (c)TheFrontOffice ThefunctionsoftheFrontOfficearemostlyrelatedtothegatheringoffinancialresourcestocover resourceutilizationandneedsrelatedtothepublicdebtordebt.Theythusincludealltheprocesses involvingthenegotiationandcontractofnewborrowing. ThefrontofficeperformsthefunctionsthatcouldbedescribedasthoseofanEDMCSecretariat,i.e. toensurethatthelaw,therulesandregulations,andtheguidelinesissuedbytheEDMCareapplied andfollowed.ForthispurposetheFrontOfficerequiresproperlegaladvice. Two major functions of the Front Office are the Implementation/Monitoring/Negotiating Function andtheGovernmentSecuritiesMarketFunction. The Implementation/Monitoring/Negotiating Function is responsible for the following up and implementationofthedecisionstakenattheexecutivelevelandforensuringthatimplementation bytheGovernmentisestablishedinaccordance.Inlowerincomecountriesthisfunctionisalsolikely tocoverattractingOfficialDevelopmentAssistance(ODA)andgrants. The Government Securities Market Function comprises numerous responsibilities regarding the development of markets for government debt, and carrying out issuance, redemption, and other tasksrelatedtomanagementoftheGovernment’sdebt. Theseincludethefollowing: x x x x x x The development of securities market regulation to support the issuance and trading of governmentsecurities; The development of market infrastructure to help increase market liquidity and reduce systemicrisk; Strengtheningthedemandforgovernmentsecuritiesbybuildingthepotentialinvestorbase; Improving the quality government securities in primary and secondary markets through extendingmaturitiesandconsolidatingthenumberofissues; MatchingtheGovernment’sfinancingneedswiththetermstructureofitsdebt;and Creatingefficientchannelsforthemarketinganddistributionofgovernmentsecurities. In its Government Securities Market Function the Front Office should aim as far as possible at the separationofinstrumentsusedfordebtmanagement,ontheonehand,andformonetarypolicy,on the other. When the market for government securities is limited to shortͲterm instruments, it conflictsbetweenthepursuitoftheobjectivesofmonetaryanddebtpoliciesaredifficulttoavoid. InmoresophisticatedDMOstheFrontOfficehasrolesinvolvingderivativestransactions,integrated riskmanagement,accessingtheinternationalcapitalmarkets,andprovidingvariousotherfinancial servicestotheGovernment. 5. InstitutionalLocationoftheDMO AunifiedDMOwithconsolidatedfunctionsregardingoperationaldebtmanagementappearstobe themostappropriatesettingforeffectivedebtmanagement.103Theexistenceofasingleinstitution in charge of implementing debt policies permits a greater attention and concentration to debt management issues and helps to ensure a clear separation between fiscal, monetary and debt managementpolicies. 103 SeealsoCurrie,Dethier,andTogo(2003). 158 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment RegardingthelocationoftheDMOwiththeGovernmentpresentpracticesvary. Separate DMOs are more frequent in developed economies with sophisticated financial markets. UnderthisarrangementDMOsimplementthedebtstrategiesdeterminedbytheMinisterofFinance as an agency of the Government. 104 To ensure Government monitoring and control of debt management, for example, through an EDMC, clear governance, legal and institutional arrangements are put in place and strategic objectives and benchmarks for debt management established. ThemainadvantagesofseparateDMOscanbesummarizedasfollows: (a) (b) (c) (d) Greaterefficiencyinmanagingdebt; Moreindependencefrompoliticalinfluence; Thepossibilityofattractingqualifiedstaffatbettersalaries;and Latitude for the application of privateͲsector management practices and debt techniques. AnexampleoftheorganizationalstructureofaseparateDMOisprovidedinBoxVII.5. DMOsinsidetheMinistryofFinance(MOF)aremorecommoninlessdevelopedeconomies,where morecoordinationisneededbetweendebtmanagementandotherpoliciesowingtothevitaland strategicroleoftheformer. Advantagesofthisarrangementarethefollowing: (a) Greater coordination of debt management with the core activities of the MOF, suchasfiscalandbudgetarypolicies; (b) MoreflexibilityinmanagingcontingentliabilitiesandonͲlending;and (c) Facilitationofhandlingissuesrelatedtothefiscalsustainabilityofdebt. Fiscaldiscipline,socialandeconomicgrowth,anddebtsustainabilityareinextricablyintertwinedin lessdevelopedeconomies.105 IneithercasetheMOFisultimatelyaccountableforincurringdebtonbehalfoftheGovernmentand delegatessomeofitsauthoritytotheDMOforthispurpose.Whenthedebtmanagementactivities are consolidated in a single office with an appropriate organizational structure and governance arrangements, there are no great dissimilarities between a separate DMO and a DMO inside the MOF. 104 105 RecentExperiencesintheOrganizationofDebtManagementOffices,presentationbyFredJenseninUNCTAD(2005). SeeBorresenandCosioͲPascal(2002). 159 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement BoxVII.5.TheSeparateDMOofNigeria ThereareafewdevelopingcountriessuchasNigeriawithseparateDMOs.Thefigurebelowshows thearrangementsoftheNigerianDMO. Supervisory Board (Executive Debt Management) Public debt committee headed by Minister of Finance (Executive Debt Management) DirectorGeneral (OPERATIONAL (Operational Debt Management) Front Office Middle Office Back Office 160 Internal Audit Corporate Affairs Department CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References AsieduE(2003).DebtReliefandInstitutionalReform:afocusonHeavilyIndebtedPoorCountries. TheQuarterlyReviewofEconomicsandFinance,Kansas,May. BankforInternationalSettlements(2003).SoundPracticesfortheManagementandSupervisionof OperationalRisk,Basel,February. Borresen P and CosioͲPascal E (2002). Role and Organization of a Debt Office. DMFAS Programme TechnicalPaperNº1(UNCTAD/GDS/DMFAS/2).NewYorkandGeneva,UnitedNations. Cohen D et al. (2004). Beyond the HIPC Initiative. France, Investment Development Consultancy, March. CommonwealthBusinessForum(2003).AchievingSustainableDevelopment:ChallengesforBusiness andGovernments.Abuja,December. Contaduria General de la Nacion (2005). The Integrated System of Financial Information. Buenos Aires,February. Currie E, Dethier JJ and Togo E (2003). Institutional Arrangements for Public Debt Management. WorldBankResearchPaper3021,Washington,DC. DeredzaC(2004).ConceptualisingaSovereignForeignBorrowingPolicyFramework.ForumMEFMI, Harare,March. DMFAS/UNCTAD(1989).EffectiveDebtManagement(UNCTAD/RDP/DFP/DMS/2).Geneva. DMFAS/UNCTAD(1993).EffectiveDebtManagement(UNCTAD/GID/DMS/15)Geneva. International Monetary Fund (IMF), Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the Commonwealth Secretariat (Comsec), Eurostat, the Organization for Economic CoͲoperation and Development (OECD), the Paris Club Secretariat, the United Nations Conference on Trade andDevelopment(UNCTAD)andtheWorldBank(2003).ExternalDebtStatistics:Guidefor CompilersandUsers.Washington,DC. IMF(2003).ManualonFiscalTransparency.Washington,DC. IMF and the Hong Kong Monetary Authority (2000). Sovereign Assets and Liabilities Management. Washington,DC,November. IMF(2004).SovereignDebtStructureforCrisisPrevention.Washington,DC,July. MagnussonT(2001).TheInstitutionalandLegalBaseforEffectiveDebtManagement.UNCTADThird InterͲRegionalDebtManagementConference,Geneva. MehranH,ed.(1985).ExternalDebtManagement.Washington,DC,InternationalMonetaryFund. MEFMI and World Bank (2001). Public Debt Management, Cash Management and Domestic Debt MarketDevelopment.TanzaniaWashington,June. Noel M (2000). Building SubͲnational Debt Markets in Developing and Transition Countries, a framework for Analysis, Policy Reform and Assistance Strategy. For the World Bank preparation of the Manual on Domestic Debt Markets Development Ͳ The Policy Issues. Washington,DC,January. UNCTAD (2005). Presentations on Debt Management. UNCTAD’s Fifth InterͲRegional Debt ManagementConference.Geneva,June. 161 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement UNCTAD (2004).EconomicDevelopmentinAfrica–DebtSustainability:OasisorMirage, NewYork andGeneva,August. UNCTAD(2003).ProceedingsoftheThirdInterͲRegionalDebtManagementConference,Geneva3–6 December2001.GenevaandNewYork,UnitedNations. UNDP (1997). A Report on the Joint UNCTADͲWorld Bank Programme of Debt Management, ManagementDevelopmentandGovernanceDivision.NewYork,DiscussionPaper,4,UNDP. WheelerG(2004).SoundPracticeinGovernmentDebtManagement.Washington,DC,WorldBank. WorldBankandIMF(2001).GuidelinesforPublicDebtManagement.Washington,March. WorldBankandIMF(2001a).DevelopingGovernmentBondMarkets:AHandbook.Washington. WorldBankandtheIMF(2002).GuidelinesforPublicDebtManagement:AccompanyingDocument. Washington,November. World Bank and the IMF (2003). Amendments to the Guidelines for Public Debt Management. Washington,November. World Bank and the IMF (2004). Debt Sustainability in LowͲIncome CountriesͲProposal for and OperationalFrameworkandPolicyImplications.Washington,February. 162 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Abbreviations ALM BIS BOP CB ComSec DMFAS DMOs DSA DSM+ EDM EDMC GDP GͲ8 GͲ77 IDA IFMS INTOSAI IT/IS IMF MDGs MEFMI MOF ODA OECD SAI UN UNCTAD AssetandLiabilityManagement BankforInternationalSettlements BalanceofPayments Centralbank CommonwealthSecretariat DebtManagementandFinancialAnalysisSystem DebtmanagementOffices DebtSustainabilityAnalysis DebtSustainabilityModelPlus ExecutiveDebtManagement ExecutiveDebtmanagementCommittee GrossDomesticProduct GroupofEight Groupof77 InternationalDevelopmentAgency IntegratedFinancialManagementSystems InternationalOrganizationofSupremeAuditInstitutions InformationTechnology/InformationSystems InternationalMonetaryFund MillenniumDevelopmentGoals Macroeconomic&FinancialManagementInstituteofEasternandSouthernAfrica MinistryofFinance OfficialDevelopmentAssistance OrganizationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment SupremeAuditInstitutions UnitedNations UnitedNationsConferenceonTradeandDevelopment 163 AppropriateInstitutionalSettingsforPublicDebtManagement Annex ManagingOperationalRisks Operations risks arise in the areas that provide support services to the management of public debt. Auditorswouldrecognizethefollowingoperationalriskswhentheyexaminetheorganizationalstructure ofpublicdebtmanagement. (a) Lack of separation of duties or functions. Public debt transactions must be independently processed,confirmed,valued,andreviewed,andmonitoredbyanindependentadministrative office. (b) Inadequate staff expertise.Supervisors must have the proper expertise to avoidbecoming a “rubberstamp”tothoseresponsiblefordebttransactions.Supportstaffisusuallythefirstline ofdefensetouncovererrorsandirregularitiesthatmayoccurinprocessingdebttransactions. (c) Productrisk.Newdebtinstrumentscanbetoocomplexorpoorlyunderstood.Thiscanleadto theinabilityofsupportstafftoprocess,value,andcontrolnewdebtinstruments. (d) System and technology risks. These risks exist when staff fails to stay up to date in its understanding of technological developments associated with new information systems or adopts computerized information systems without “reͲengineering” their debt management practices. (e) Proceduresrisks.Theserisksexistwhenthedebtmanagementfunctionsdonothavewritten procedures and the work flow is not structured in a predictable and wellͲ designed manner withproperaudittrails.Thesewrittenproceduresbecomemoreimportant,themorecomplex debtinstrumentsare. (f) Disaster recovery risks. These risks exist when the debt organization has not planned for alternativesites,computerresources,communications,resources,tradingfacilities,andother supportservicesinthecaseofadisaster.Thoseresponsiblefordebttransactionsmusthave alternativeremotetradingandtechnologysites. (g) Documentation risks. These risks exist when debt transactions do not have wellͲdesigned agreements that are legally authorized, properly executed and supported by appropriate confirmationinatimelymanner.Legaldepartmentsandsupportstaffmustmaintainmaster agreementsandsupportingconfirmations. (h) Valuationrisks.Theserisksexistwhenthesupportstaffcannotperform,atleastonaregular basis,anindependentvaluationofalldebtinstrumentsorifthevaluationofthesupportstaff differs from the valuation of the Supreme Audit Institutions (SAI) or an independent third party. Source:INTOSAIGuidanceforPlanningandConductinganAuditofPublicDebt. 164 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERVIII CREDITRATINGAGENCIESANDTHEIRPOTENTIAL IMPACTONDEVELOPINGCOUNTRIES MarwanElkhoury (IndependentConsultant) A. Introduction Credit rating agencies (subsequently denoted CRAs) specialize in analysing and evaluating the creditworthiness of corporate and sovereign issuers of debt securities. In the new financial architecture CRAs are expected to become more important in the management of both corporate and sovereign credit risk. Their role has recently received a boost from the revision by the Basel CommitteeonBankingSupervision(BCBS)ofcapitalstandardsforbanksculminatinginBaselII. ThelogicunderlyingtheexistenceofCRAsistosolvetheproblemoftheinformationalasymmetry between lenders and borrowers regarding the creditworthiness of the latter. Issuers with lower credit ratings pay higher interest rates embodying larger risk premiums than higherͲrated issuers. Moreover,ratingsdeterminetheeligibilityofdebtandotherfinancialinstrumentsfortheportfolios ofcertaininstitutionalinvestorsduetonationalregulationsthatrestrictinvestmentinspeculativeͲ gradebonds. The rating agencies fall into two categories, recognized and nonͲrecognized. The former are recognized by supervisors in each country for regulatory purposes. In the United States only five CRAs(ofwhichthebestknownareMoody’sandStandard&Poor’s)arerecognizedbytheSEC.The majority of CRAs such as the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU), Institutional Investor (II), and Euromoneyare“nonͲrecognized”. 165 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries ThereisawidedisparityamongCRAs.Theymaydifferinsizeandscope(geographicalandsectoral) of coverage. There are also wide differences in their methodologies and definitions of the default risk,whichrenderscomparisonbetweenthemdifficult. RegardingtheirrolevisͲàͲvisdevelopingcountries,thesovereignratingisparticularlyimportant.As defined by Nagy (1984), “Country risk is the exposure to a loss in crossͲborder lending, caused by events in a particular country which are Ͳ at least to some extent Ͳ under the control of the Government but definitely not under the control of a private enterprise or individual”. Under this definition all forms of crossͲborder lending in a country, ͲͲ whether to the Government, a bank, a privateenterpriseoranindividualͲͲareincluded.Countryriskisthereforeabroaderconceptthan sovereignrisk.ThelatterisrestrictedtotheriskoflendingtotheGovernmentofasovereignnation. However, sovereign and country risk are highly correlated as the Government is the major actor affectingboth.Moreover,thereonlyrareexceptionstotheprincipleofthesovereignceiling;i.e.the debtratingofacompanyorbankbasedinacountrycannotexceedthecountry’ssovereignrating. ThefailureofbigCRAstopredictthe1997Ͳ1998AsiancrisisandtherecentbankruptciesofEnron, WorldComandParmalathaveraisedquestionsconcerningtheratingprocessandtheaccountability ofCRAsandhaspromptedlegislatorstoscrutinizeratingagencies.Thisreportgivesanoverviewof thesovereigncreditratingindustry,analysesitsimpactondevelopingcountriesandassessessome oftheCRAs’shortcomingsinthecontextofconcernsthathaverecentlybeenraised. B. CreditRatingAgenciesintheInternationalFinancialSystem 1. AsymmetryofInformationandCRAsas“Opinion”Makers A credit rating compresses a large variety of information that needs to be known about the creditworthiness of the issuer of bonds and certain other financial instruments. The CRAs thus contribute to solving principalͲagent problems by helping lenders “pierce the fog of asymmetric information that surrounds lending relationships and help borrowers emerge from that same fog”(White(2001)). CRAs stress that their ratings constitute opinions. They are not a recommendation to buy, sell or holdasecurityanddonotaddressthesuitabilityofaninvestmentforaninvestor.Ratingshavean impactonissuersviavariousregulatoryschemesandby determiningtheconditionsandthecosts under which they access debt markets. Regulators have outsourced to CRAs much of the responsibility for assessing debt risk. For investors ratings are a screening tool that influences the compositionoftheirportfoliosaswellastheirinvestmentdecisions. 2. CreditRatingsandBaselII Regulatory changes in banks’ capital requirements under Basel II have resulted in a new role for creditratingagencies.Ratingscanbeusedtoassigntheriskweightsdeterminingminimumcapital chargesfordifferentcategoriesofborrower.UndertheStandardizedApproachtocreditriskBaselII establishes credit risk weights for each supervisory category which rely on “external credit assessments”(seeBoxVIII.1.).Moreover,creditratingsarealsousedforassessingrisksinsomeof theotherrulesofBaselII. TheimportanceofratingsͲbasedregulationsisparticularlyvisibleintheUnitedStates,whereitcan betracedbacktothe1930s.Theseregulationsnotonlyaffectbanksbutalsoinsurers,pensionfunds, 166 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment mutual funds and brokerͲdealers by restricting or prohibiting the purchase of bonds with “low” ratings, i.e. nonͲinvestment grade or speculativeͲgrade ratings.106While ratingsͲbased regulations arelesscommoninEurope,theyarepartofthenewCapitalRequirementsDirectivethattheEUwill implementthroughBaselII. BOXVIII.1.BaselII ThemajorobjectiveofBaselIIistorevisetherulesofthe1988BaselCapitalAccordinsuchawayasto alignbanks’regulatorycapitalmorecloselywiththeirrisks,takingaccountofprogressinthemeasurement andmanagementoftheserisksandtheopportunitieswhichtheseprovideforstrengthenedsupervision. Under Pillar 1 of Basel 2 regulatory capital requirements for credit risk are calculated according to two alternative approaches, the Standardized and the Internal RatingsͲBased. Under the Standardized Approach(SA)themeasurementofcreditriskisbasedonexternalcreditassessmentsprovidedbyexternal creditassessmentinstitutions(ECAIs)suchascreditratingagenciesorexportcreditagencies.Underthe internal ratingsͲbased approach (IRBA), subject to supervisory approval as to the satisfaction of certain conditions,banksusetheirownratingsystemstomeasuresomeorallofthedeterminantsofcreditrisk. Underthefoundationversion(FIRBA)bankscalculatetheprobabilityofdefault(PD)onthebasisoftheir ownratingsbutrelyontheirsupervisorsformeasuresoftheotherdeterminantsofcreditrisk.Underthe advancedversion(AIRBA)banksalsoestimatetheirownmeasuresofallthedeterminantsofcreditrisk, includinglossgivendefault(LGD)andexposureatdefault(EAD). Under the regulatory capital requirements for operational risk there are three options of progressively greater sophistication. Under the Basic Indicator Approach (BIA) the capital charge is a percentage of banks’grossincome.UndertheStandardizedApproach(SAOR)thecapitalchargeisthesumofspecified percentagesof banks’gross income from eightbusiness lines (or alternatively for two of thesebusiness lines,retailandcommercialbanking,ofdifferentpercentagesofloansandadvances).UndertheAdvanced Measurement Approach (AMA), subject to the satisfaction of more stringent supervisory criteria, banks estimatetherequiredcapitalwiththeirowninternalsystemsformeasuringoperationalrisk. Pillars 2 and 3 of Basel 2 are concerned with the supervisory review of capital adequacy and the achievementofmarketdisciplinethroughdisclosure. Various writers such as Reisen (2002) have expressed the view that the Basel II Accord may destabilizeprivatecapitalflowstodevelopingcountries.Thiswouldbetrueifthecloserlinksunder Basel II between the levels of banks’ regulatory capital and their assessment of credit risks accentuated proͲcyclical fluctuations in their lending. Moreover the same link may also result in higher interest rates than under the 1988 Accord for less creditworthy developingͲcountry borrowers. The ratings of CRAs may contribute to unfavorable effects under both headings. As discussed below, changes in these ratings sometimes follow closely cyclical changes in economic conditions.Moreoverowingtotheirlowcreditratingscertaindevelopingcountriesmaybeassigned higher weights for credit risk than under 1988 Capital Accord and thus be charged higher rates of interestontheirborrowing. 106 The major CRAs have their own ratings schemes which differ for different categories of debt – longͲand shortͲterm, bank and nonͲbank Ͳ and in the case of Fitch’s ratings for banks include the likelihood of external support, should this becomenecessarytoenablethemtocontinuemeetingtheirfinancialobligationsonatimelybasis.Thebestknownratings arethoseofStandardandPoor’sandMoody’sforlongͲtermdebt,whichvarybetweenAAAandBBBͲforinvestmentgrade forStandardandPoor’s(AaaͲBaa3forMoody’s)andbetweenBB+andCCforspeculativegradeforStandardandPoor’s (Ba1ͲCforMoody’s).Formoredetailsseetable1ofAnnex2. 167 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries C. CRAs’ProceduresandMethods 1. QuantitativeandQualitativeMethods The processes and methods used to establish credit ratings vary widely among CRAs. Traditionally CRAs have relied on a process based on a quantitative and qualitative assessment reviewed and finalized by a rating committee. More recently there has been increased reliance on quantitative statistical models based on publicly available data with the result that the assessment process is more mechanical and involves less reliance on confidential information. No single model outperformsalltheothers.Performanceisheavilyinfluencedbycircumstances. A sovereign rating is aimed at “measuring the risk that a Government may default on its own obligationsineitherlocalorforeigncurrency.Ittakesintoaccountboththeabilityandwillingnessof a Government to repay its debt in a timely manner” (Moody’s, Special Comment (2006)). The key measureincreditriskmodelsisthemeasureoftheprobabilityofdefault,PD,butexposureisalso determined by the expected timing of default and by the recovery rate, RE, after default has occurred. (a) S&P ratings seek to capture only the forwardͲlooking probability of the occurrence of default.Theyprovidenoassessmentoftheexpectedtimeofdefaultorofmodeofdefault resolutionandrecoveryvalues. (b) BycontrastMoody’sratingsfocusontheExpectedLoss,EL,whichisafunctionofbothPD andtheexpectedrecoveryrate,RE.ThusEL=PD.(1ͲRE). (c) Fitch’s ratings also focus on both PD and RE (Bhatia, 2002). They have a more explicitly hybridcharacterinthatanalystsarealsoremindedtobeforwardͲlookingandtobealertto possiblediscontinuitiesbetweenpasttrackrecordsandfuturetrends. The credit ratings of S&P and Moody’s are assigned by rating committees and not by individual analysts. There is a large dose of judgment in the committees’ final ratings CRAs provide little guidanceastohowtheyassignrelativeweightstoeachfactor,thoughtheydoprovideinformation on what variables they consider in determining sovereign ratings. Identifying the relationship betweentheCRAs’criteriaandactualratingsisdifficult,inpartbecausesomeofthecriteriaused areneitherquantitativenorquantifiablebutqualitative.Theanalyticalvariablesareinterrelatedand the weights are not fixed either across sovereigns or over time. Even for quantifiable factors, determiningrelativeweightsisdifficultbecausetheagenciesrelyonalargenumberofcriteriaand thereisnoformulaforcombiningthescorestodetermineratings. InassessingsovereignriskCRAshighlightseveralriskparametersofvaryingimportance:economic, political, fiscal and monetary flexibility and the debt burden (see Box VIII.2.). Economic risk addresses the ability to repay its obligations on time and is a function of both quantitative and qualitativefactors.Politicalriskaddressesthesovereign’swillingnesstorepaydebt.Willingnessto pay is a qualitative issue that distinguishes sovereigns from most other types of issuers. Partly becausecreditorshaveonlylimitedlegalredress,aGovernmentcan(andsometimesdoes)default selectively on its obligations, even when it possesses the financial capacity for debt service. In practice,politicalriskandeconomicriskarerelated.AGovernmentthatisunwillingtorepaydebtis usually pursuing economic policies that weaken its ability to do so. Willingness to pay, therefore, encompasses the range of economic and political factors influencing government policy (see Box VIII.2.). 168 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Broadly speaking, the economic variables aim at measuring three types of performance: (1) measuresofdomesticeconomicperformance,(2)measuresofacountry’sexternalpositionandits ability to service its external obligations and (3) the influence of external developments. Bhatia (2002) notes that CRAs’ analysis prior to the Asian financial crisis focused on traditional macroeconomic indicators with limited emphasis on contingent liability and international liquidity considerations.MoreoverprivateͲsectorweaknesseswerenotincludedintheanalysisofsovereign rating. Inpractice,asmallnumberofvariablesͲͲGDPpercapita,realGDPgrowthpercapita,theconsumer priceindex(CPI),theratioofgovernmentfiscalbalancetoGDP,andgovernmentdebttoGDPͲͲhave a large impact on credit ratings.(The relationship between these indicators and S&P’s ratings are illustrated in figures 1Ͳ5 of Annex 1.). By and large, higher GDP per capita lead to higher ratings; higher CPI to lower ratings, the lower the rating, the lower the government balance as a ratio to GDP;higherfiscaldeficitsandgovernmentdebtinrelationtoGDPalsolowerratings. 169 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries BoxVIII.2.S&PSovereignRatingsMethodologyProfile Politicalrisk x x x x x x Stabilityandlegitimacyofpoliticalinstitutions Popularparticipationinpoliticalprocesses Orderlinessofleadershipsuccessions Transparencyineconomicpolicydecisionsandobjectives Publicsecurity Geopoliticalrisk Incomeandeconomicstructure x x x x x x x Prosperity,diversityanddegreetowhicheconomyismarketͲoriented Incomedisparities Effectivenessoffinancialsectorinintermediatingfunsavailabilityofcredit CompetitivenessandprofitabilityofnonͲfinancialprivatesector Efficiencyofpublicsector ProtectionismandothernonͲmarketinfluences Laborflexibility Economicgrowthprospects x Sizeandcompositionofsavingsandinvestment x Rateandpatternofeconomicgrowth Fiscalflexibility x x x x x Generalgovernmentrevenue,expenditure,andsurplus/deficittrends RevenueͲraisingflexibilityandefficiency Expenditureeffectivenessandpressures Timeliness,coverageandtransparencyinreporting Pensionobligations Generalgovernmentburden x x x x Generalgovernmentgrossandnet(ofassets)debtasapercentofGDP Shareofrevenuedevotedtointerest Currencycompositionandmaturityprofile Depthandbreadthoflocalcapitalmarkets Offshoreandcontingentliabilities x x SizeandhealthofNFPEs Robustnessoffinancialsector Monetaryflexibility x x x x x Pricebehaviorineconomiccycles Moneyandcreditexpansion Compatibilityofexchangerateregimeandmonetarygoals Institutionalfactorssuchascentralbankindependence Rangeandefficiencyofmonetarygoals Externalliquidity x x x x Impactoffiscalandmonetarypoliciesonexternalaccounts Structureofthecurrentaccount Compositionofcapitalflows Reserveadequacy Externaldebtburden x x x x Grossandnetexternaldebt,includingdepositsandstructureddebt Maturityprofile,currencycomposition,andsensitivitytointerestratechanges Accesstoconcessionallending Debtserviceburden Source:S&P,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”,October2006. Notes:NFPEs:NonͲfinancialpublicsectorenterprises. 170 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment 2. EmpiricalAssessmentsofCreditRatingDeterminants Anumberofeconomistshaveestimatedeconometricallythedeterminantsofcreditratingsforboth matureandemergingmarkets(CantorandPacker(1995,1996),Haqueetal.,(1996,1997),Reisen andvonMaltzan(1999),JuttnerandMcCarthy(2000),andBhatia,(2002)).Inthesestudiesasmall numberofvariablesexplain90percentofthevariationintheratings: x x x x x x GDPpercapita; GDPgrowth; Inflation; TheratioofnonͲgoldforeignexchangereservestoimports; TheratioofthecurrentaccountbalancetoGDP; Defaulthistoryandthelevelofeconomicdevelopment. Indeed, a single variable, GDP per capita, explains about 80 percent of the variation in ratings (Borenszstein and Panizza (2006)). It is worth noting that the fiscal position, measured by the average annual central government budget deficit/surplus ratio to GDP, in the three years before the rating year and the external position measured by the average annual current account deficit/surplus in relation to GDP, in the three years before the rating year, were found to be statisticallyinsignificant. Whileincludingpoliticaleventscanimprovetheexplanatorypoweroftheregressions,theexclusion ofpoliticalvariablesdoesnotbiastheparameterestimates(Haqueetal.,1996;CantorandPacker, 1996). In addition, for developingͲcountry ratings, two other variables adversely affected ratings independentlyofdomesticeconomicfundamentals(Haqueetal.,1996,1997): x x Increasesininternationalinterestrates; Thestructureofitsexportsanditsconcentration. JüttnerandMcCarthy(2000)foundastructuralbreakinratingsassessmentin1997inthewakeof theSouthͲEastAsiancrisis.“[…]Econometricestimatesmayconveywrongormeaninglesssignalsto investorsduringaratingcrisis…thereisnosetmodelorframeworkforjudgmentwhicharecapable of explaining the variations in assignment of sovereign ratings over time” (Jüttner and McCarthy (2000)).Theauthorsaddinafootnotethatthismeansthatinaglobalfinancialcrisisratingsmodels might become completely obsolete since a stable relationship between rating and their determinantsmightbeimpossibletoidentify. In their analysis of the determinant of ratings during the Asian crisis, Jüttner and McCarthy found thatthefollowingvariables: x TheCPI; x Theratioofexternaldebttoexports; x Adummydefaulthistory,and; x Theinterestratedifferential; x Therealexchangerate. Neither the interest rate differential nor the real exchange rate were found to be significant determinantspriortotheAsiancrisisthusindicatingthatthesevariablesmayhavebeenoverlooked by the agencies before the crisis. Variables denoting financial strength were not found to be significant determinants of sovereign ratings even one year after the Asian crisis. However, these variables were subsequently included in ratings assessments by the major CRAS following their unsatisfactoryperformanceduringAsiancrisis. 171 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries 3. RatingDifferences,Notching,SolicitedandUnsolicitedRatings Although CRAs have different concepts and measurements of the probability of default, various studieswhichhavecomparedMoody’sandS&P’ratings,havefoundagreatsimilarityforinvestment graderatings(CantorandPacker,1996;AmmerandPacker,2000).InthecaseofspeculativeͲgrade issues,Moody’sandS&Passigndivergentratingsmuchmorefrequentlytosovereignbondsthanto corporate bonds. The literature also finds clear evidence of differences in rating scales once we movebeyondthetwolargestagencies.Forexample,ratingsforthesameissuertendtobelowerfor thetwolargestagenciesthanforotheragenciessuchasFitchorDuffandPhelps. Some of these differences can be explained by sample selection bias. The analysis of Cantor and Packer(1996)pointstoonlylimitedevidenceofsignificantselectionbiasandsignificantevidencefor differences in rating scales between larger and small CRAs. Regardless of ratings differences, the market appears to reward issuers with a lower interest costs when a third rating is assigned, especiallywhentheratingishigher(BCBS(2000)). Fitch and the EganͲJones Ratings Company have accused the two big CRAs of practicing the “notching”, a practice whereby S&P and Moody’s would initiate an automatic downward of structuredsecurities,ifthetwoagencieswerenothiredtoratethem(EganͲJonesRatingsCompany, 2002). Moody’s response to Fitch’s accusations is that unsolicited ratings usually result in a lower rating for debt securities because of either a lack of information or the use of different methodologiestodeterminetheprobabilityofdefault. Unsolicitedratingsraisepotentialconflictsofinterest.BothMoody’sandS&Pstatethattheyreserve therighttorateandmakepublicratingsforUnitedStatesSECͲregisteredcorporatebonds,whether or not requested by an issuer. If the issuer does not request the rating, the rating will simply be based on publicly available information. If the issuer requests the rating, then it provides informationtotheratingagencyandpaysthefees.Manynewentrantsinthecreditratingindustry issueunsolicitedratingstogaincredibilityinthemarket.SomeissuershaveaccusedCRAsofusing unsolicitedratingsandthethreatoflowerratingsinduceissuerstocooperateintheratingprocess andpaythefeesofsolicitedratings.107 Since2001,Moody’sclaimsthatithasnotdoneanyunsolicitedratinginEurope.S&Palsoclaimsnot to do any unsolicited rating outside the United States. As unsolicited ratings are based on public information and thus lack issuer input, the issue of unsolicited ratings could be addressed by requiring CRAs to disclose whether it has been solicited or not. Both Moody’s and S&P already specify in their ratings whether the rating has been solicited and give issuers the opportunity to participateatanystageoftheprocessiftheywish. D. ImpactofRatings 1. CostsandBenefitsofObtainingaRating As mentioned earlier, the primary purpose of obtaining a rating is to enhance access to private capital markets and lower debtͲissuance and interest costs. Theoretical work (Ramakrishnan and Thakor, 1984; Millon and Thakor, 1985) suggests that credit rating agencies, in their role as information gatherers and processors, can reduce a firm’s capital costs by certifying its value in a 107 SEC,‘Concept’Release.RatingAgenciesandtheUseofCreditRatingsundertheFederalSecuritiesLaws,Securitiesand ExchangeCommission.ReleaseNos.33Ͳ8236;34Ͳ47972;ICͲ26066. 172 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment market,thussolvingorreducingtheinformationalasymmetriesbetweenpurchasersandissuers.For sovereign borrowers, there is evidence of a clear correlation between bond spreads and rating grades,asshowninFigureVIII.1.,(BIS(2006)):thelowertherating,thehigherthespread. FigureVIII.1.BondSpreadsbyRatings Source:BISQuarterlyReview,March2006fromJPMorgan ChaseEMBIGlobalDiversified(EMBIGD). There are other indirect benefits from ratings for low income countries, namely to foster FDI, to promote more vibrant local capital markets, and increase publicͲsector financial transparency (StandardsandPoor’s(2004)).Asaresult,evensomesovereignsthatdonotintendtoissuecrossͲ borderdebtintheimmediatefutureseekcreditratingsfromCRAs. Foremergingmarkets,thereisanimportantexternalityofobtainingarating,thatofthe“sovereign ceiling”effect.Borenzsteinetal.(2006)findthat,althoughithasbeenrelaxedsince1997,theeffect ofthesovereignceilingremainsstatisticallyhighlysignificant,especiallyforbankcorporations,being moreimportantforbanksthatresideincountrieswithahighlevelsofsovereigndebtandsmaller forbankswithstrongforeignparents. 2. BoomsandBusts:FinancialCrisesinEmergingMarketsandtheProͲcyclicalityof Ratings The 1997Ͳ1998 Asian crisis highlighted CRAs’ potential for reinforcing boomsͲandͲbusts of capital flows. As ratings were lagging instead of leading market events and overͲreacted during both the preͲandpostͲcrisisperiods,theymayhavehelpedtoamplifythesecycles. Severalempiricalstudiesshowthatsovereignratingsaresticky,laggingmarketsentimentandoverͲ reactingwithalagtoeconomicconditionsandthebusinesscycle.Larrain,ReisenandvonMaltzan (1997)havefoundthatratingsarecorrelatedwithsovereignbondyieldspreads.Intheaftermathof the1994Ͳ1995Mexicancrisis,theauthorsfindatwoͲwaycausalitybetweensovereignratingsand market spreads. Not only do international capital markets react to changes in the ratings, but the ratingssystematicallyreact,withalag,tomarketconditionsasreflectedinthesovereignbondyield spreads.Thisstudyalsoindicatesahighlysignificantannouncementeffectwhenemergingmarkets sovereign bonds are put on review with negative outlook. Moreover, the study finds a significant 173 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries negative effect of rating announcements: following a rating downgrade investors readjust their portfolios.Positiveratingannouncements,bycontrast,donotseemtohaveasignificanteffecton bondspreads. Moody’s more recent (2003) report on proͲcyclicality claims that the relative stability of credit ratings compared to marketͲbased indicators suggests that ratings were more likely to dampen ratherthantoamplifythecreditcycle,andthatmostratingchangesreflectedlongͲlastingchanges in fundamental credit risk rather than temporary cyclical developments. The relationship between creditratingsandcyclicality–andthustheimpactofchangesintheCRAs’practicesinresponseto shortcomingsrevealedbythecrisesofthe1990sͲthusremainsanopenempiricalquestion. 3. AccuracyandPerformanceofRatings CRAs’failuretopredicttheMexicanandAsianfinancialcriseswasdue,amongotherthings,tothe fact that contingent liability and international liquidity considerations had not been taken into accountbyCRAs.. ConcerningtheAsiancrisis,Moody’sacknowledgedthatithadbeenconfrontedwithanewsetof circumstancesrequiringaparadigmshiftinthefollowingareas: x x x x x Greater analytic emphasis on the risks of shortͲterm debt for otherwise creditworthy countries; Greateremphasisontheidentityandcreditworthinessofacountry’sshortͲtermborrowers; Greaterappreciationoftherisksposedbyaweakbankingsystem;and GreaterattentiontotheidentityandlikelybehaviorofforeignshortͲtermcreditors; Increased sensitivity to the risk that a financial crisis in one country can lead to contagion effectsforothercountries. AbalancehastobefoundinthetradeͲoffbetweenaccuracyandstability.Ratingagenciesareaverse toreversingratingswithinashortperiodoftime.BothMoody’sandS&Pintendtheirratingstobe stable measures of relative credit risk. Moody’s claims that this corresponds to issuers’ as well as institutionalinvestors’wishesandthatits“desireforstableratingsreflectstheviewthatmorestable ratingsare“better”ratings. Bhatia (2002) has measured “failures” based on ratings stability. With exceptions for some of the lowestratingshedefinesa“failedrating”asonethatisloweredorraisedby“threeormorenotches within 12 months. The choice of three notches is related to the small probability of a three notch ratingchangeamongCRAs.ApplyingtheBhatiadefinitionofratingfailuretothelongͲtermforeign currency sovereign ratings of S&P and Moody’s in 1997Ͳ2002, shows that S&P and Moody’s both experienced failures during the Asian crisis; S&P also failed during the Russian and Argentinean crisis; and Moody’s failed during the Russian but not the Argentinean crisis (see table VIII.1.). Bhatia’sfailuredefinitionsuggeststhatratingfailureswerelessprevalentin1999Ͳ2002thanin1997Ͳ 1998. 174 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TableVIII.1.SovereignRatingsFailureStatistics,1997Ͳ20021/ Source:Bhatia,2002,Box5. In response to criticism concerning such failures, Moody’s has introduced “Watchlist” and S&P’s launched “Outlook” reports in order to alleviate the tension between accuracy and stability by providingtimelywarningsoflikelyratingchanges. Ratings performance can also be compared with market indicators. IMF (1999) conducted an analysisofyieldspreadsinrelationtotheAsiancrisisandfoundthatoneyearaheadofthecrisisin Thailand,Indonesiaand the Republic ofKorea,sovereignspreadswere quitelowͲof theorderof 100Ͳ150basispoints.InRussiaandBraziltheywerehigherͲabout300basispoints.Thus,inrelative terms the markets were in broad agreement with the CRAs with respect to these countries, indicating a higher risk of default for Russia and Brazil than for the Asian countries. Moreover, spreads did not widen much initially in response to the onset of the Asian crisis, a pattern conformingtothatoftheratings.Thustheperformanceoffinancialmarketsbroadlyparalleledthat ofthemajorCRAs. 4. ImpactofRatingsonPoliciesPursuedbyBorrowingCountries Forborrowingcountriesarating downgradehasnegativeeffectsontheiraccesstocredit andthe costoftheirborrowing(CantorandPacker,(1996)).Althoughpreciseinformationisnotavailableon the way in which macroeconomic policies are taken into consideration by CRAs in establishing sovereign ratings, it is reasonable to assume that orthodox policies focusing on the reduction of inflation and government budget deficits are favored. There is a risk, therefore, that in order to avoidratingdowngradesborrowingcountriesadoptpoliciesthataddresstheshortͲtermconcernsof 175 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries portfolioinvestorsevenwhentheyareinconflictwithlongͲtermdevelopmentneeds.However,this isanissuewhichhasnotbeenthesubjectofsystematicresearch. E. PublicPolicyConcerns 1. RecentRegulatoryInitiatives InviewofthecriticalroleplayedbyCRAsinthemodernfinancialarchitecture,policyͲmakershave recentlyfocusedonsomeshortͲcomingsarisingfromthefollowingconcerns: x x x x Barrierstoentryandlackofcompetition; Conflictsofinterest; Transparency; Accountability. These concerns have been raised by the International Organization of Securities Commission, (IOSCO), the United States Securities and Exchange Commission, (SEC), the European Commission Committee of European Securities Regulations, (CESR), and by the United States Congress and Senate. OnthebasisofSection702oftheSarbanesͲOxleyActof2002theUnitedStatesCongressmandated theSECtoissueaReportontheRoleandFunctionofCreditRatingAgenciesintheoperationofthe SecuritiesMarkets.Thiswastoaddressseveralissuespertainingtothecurrentroleandfunctioning of CRAs including the information flow in the creditͲrating process, barriers to entry artificially created by the Nationally Recognized Statistically Rating Organizations (NRSRO) designation in the UnitedStates,andconflictsofinterestorabusivepractices. AreviewoftheconceptofNRSROwasalreadyunderwayattheSEC.InJune2003,theSECissueda Concept Release seeking comments with respect to whether CRAs’ ratings should continue to be usedforregulatorypurposes,andifso,whethertheNRSROcertificationprocedurewasappropriate as well as more generally what should be the adequate level of regulatory oversight for CRAs. In April2005,theSECreleasedaProposedRuleaimingatinsuringahigherleveloftransparencywith respecttotheNRSROconcept. The technical committee of the IOSCO issued three reports in September 2003: (i) Report on the Activities of Credit Rating Agencies; (ii) Statement of Principles Regarding the Activities of Credit Rating Agencies; (iii) and Report on Analyst Conflicts of Interest. These reports highlighted the important role CRAs play in financial markets, and aimed at ensuring greater reliability for their ratings.InDecember2004,theIOSCOpublisheditsCodeofConductFundamentalsforCreditRating Agencies (the IOSCO Code) which aimed at developing “governance rules” for CRAs to ensure (i) quality and integrity of the rating process, (ii) independence of the process and avoidance of conflicts of interest and (iii) greater transparency in the methodology of ratings and adequate treatment of confidential information. However, the IOSCO Code did not address the issue of enforcementoftheCode,recommendingthatCRAsadopttheserulesvoluntarily. InresponsetoIOSCO’sCodeofProfessionalConduct,Moody’sandS&PpublishedtheirownCodeof Professional conduct in the second half of 2005, thus aligning their policies and procedures with IOSCO’s Code. In the spring of 2006, Moody’s and S&P published their first report on the implementationoftheCodeofconduct.Hereitwasstatedthat,evenbeforetheSECandIOSCOhad recommended new rules of conduct in 2003, the two agencies had already established internal 176 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment codes of conduct and procedures to prevent and manage potential conflict of interest and to safeguardtheindependenceandobjectivityoftheirratingprocesses. ConsiderationoftheissuesrelatedtoCRAsbytheUnitedStatesCongresseventuallyculminatedin the Credit Rating Agency Reform Act which was signed into law in early September 2006. This amended the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 to redefine an NRSRO as any CRA that has been in business for at least three consecutive years and is registered under the Act. It also prescribed procedural requirements for mandatory NRSRO registration and certification. It granted the SEC exclusiveenforcementauthorityoveranyNRSROandauthorizedtheSEC(i)totakeactionagainstan NRSRO that issued credit ratings in contravention of procedures, criteria and methodologies included in its registration application, and (ii) to censure, or limit, suspend or revoke the registrationofanNRSROforviolationsoftheAct. IntheEU,theEnronandParmalatcollapsesprompteddiscussionsonCRAreliability.Inresponsetoa call by Commission for advice the CESR released in March 2005 “CESR’s Technical Advice to the EuropeanCommissiononpossibleMeasuresConcerningCreditRatingAgencies”. 2. IssuesofConcern (a)Barrierstoentryandlackofcompetition IntheUnitedStatesthereareonly5CRAsdesignatedbytheSECasNRSROs:A.M.Best.,Dominion BondRatingService(DBRS),Fitch,Moody’sInvestorsService(Moody’s)andtheStandard&Poor’s (S&P)divisionofMcGrawHill.DBRSisCanadianͲbasedwitharegionalscopeandtheonlynonͲU.S. NRSRO designated agency. A.M.Best is a global agency which rates the debt only of insurance companies. Thus there are three global NRSROs providing a comprehensive service in the United States,ofwhichtwoagencies,Moody’sandS&P,controlover80percentofthemarket.Themean numberofCRAsrecognizedamongtheBCBS’membercountriesisaroundsixandtherearebetween 130Ͳ150creditratingagenciesintheworld.However,onlyasmallnumberofCRAsarerecognized internationallyandthenumberhasnotchangedmuchsincethe1970s(BCBS,2000). AccordingtotheUnitedStatesDepartmentofJustice,theNRSROdesignationhasactedasabarrier to entry in a catchͲ22 manner108. A new rating agency cannot obtain national recognition without NRSROstatusanditcannotobtainNRSROstatuswithoutnationalrecognition.Inthewordsofthe RapidRatingstestimonybeforetheCommitteeonFinancialServices(H.R.2990(2005b,p.8)),“the effect of this catchͲ22 has been to preserve a duopoly that has thwarted competition and innovation”. In an effort to increase competition and improve the quality of credit ratings Representative FitzpatrickintroducedH.R.2990,TheCreditRatingAgencyDuopolyReliefActof2005.Hebelieved thattheSECNRSROdesignationconstitutedan“insurmountableandartificialbarriertoentry…[…] Lack of competition in the industry has led to inflated prices, stifled innovation, lower quality of ratings,anduncheckedconflictsofinterestandanticompetitivepractices.”(H.R.2990(2005a),p.4Ͳ 5)).ThisbillwasthebasisoftheCreditRatingAgencyReformActof2006(H.R.2990(2005b)). Inits2005reporttotheEUCommissionmentionedabovetheCESRalsostatedthatnewCRAsfacea numberofbarrierstoentryandexistingCRAsfaceanumberofnaturalbarrierstoexpansion.Issuers usually only desire ratings from those CRAs that are respected by investors and which tend to be only those with a long performance record (CESR (2005), paras. 247Ͳ248). The CESR report 108 http://www.sec.gov/rules/concepts/s71203/rapid110603.htm#P69_8177#P69_8177. 177 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries concludedthat“theimpactofregulatoryrequirementsoncompetitionisnotclearandthereforeit cannot conclude that any regulatory requirements would either increase or decrease the entry barrierstotheratingindustry.ThusCESRdoesnotrecommendtheuseofregulatoryrequirements asameasuretoreduceorremoveentrybarrierstothemarketforcreditratings”(CESR(2005),para. 252).TheCESRrecommendeda“waitͲandͲsee”attitudeandimplementationofIOSCO’s“Code”. In a response to such initiatives Moody’s stated that it “has supported eliminating regulatory barrierstoentry”.But,withregardtocompetitionissues,Moody’sarguesthatthe“costlynatureof executive time” would not allow issuers to have many different ratings. Because of network externalities, only a small number of CRAs would be favored by investors, who would desire “consistencyandcomparabilityincreditopinions”.NewlyestablishedCRAswouldneedtimetogain credibilityinthemarket. S&Palsorecommendeditssupportto“amoreopenandtransparentprocesstodesignateNRSROs, reduce barriers to entry and ensure that the markets remain the ultimate judge of the rating process”(StandardsandPoor’s(2003)).However,S&PdidnotbelievethatthewholeNRSROprocess shouldbewithdrawn. (b)Potentialconflictsofinterest InitsSeptember2003“ReportofAnalystConflictsofInterest”,IOSCOhighlightedpotentialconflicts ofinterestfacingtheindustrythatcaninterferewiththeindependenceandobjectivityofitsanalysis. Conflictsofinterestmayarisewhenaratingagencyoffersconsultingorotheradvisoryservicesto issuersitratessinceissuerscouldbeundulypressuredtopurchaseadvisoryservicesinreturnforan improved rating. The report also drew attention to the issue of “notching” by CRAs, i.e. lowering ratings for issues which they had not rated, and that of “solicited” versus “unsolicited” ratings, whereaggressivetacticsmightbeusedtoinducepaymentsforaratinganissuerdidnotrequest. TheIOSCOCodeaddressesthefirstoftheseissueswiththefollowingrecommendation:“Thecredit ratingaCRAassignstoanissuerorsecurityshouldnotbeaffectedbytheexistenceoforpotential forabusinessrelationshipbetweentheCRA(oritsaffiliates)andtheissuer(oritsaffiliates)orany otherparty,orthenonͲexistenceofsucharelationship”(IOSCOCode(2004),Section2,para.2.2). This principle has been integrated into Moody’s and S&P own Codes of Professional Conduct (StandardsandPoor’s(2003)).” (c)Transparency ManymarketparticipantshaveexpressedconcernoverthelackoftransparencyoverCRAs’ratings methodologies, procedures, practices and processes. In this context the IOSCO Code stresses the following : “In order to promote transparency and improve the ability of market participants and regulators to judge whether a CRA has satisfactorily implemented the Code Fundamentals, CRAs shoulddisclosehoweachprovisionoftheCodeFundamentalsisaddressedintheCRA’sowncodeof conduct. CRAs should explain if and how their own codes of conduct deviate from the Code Fundamentals and how such deviations nonetheless achieve the objectives laid out in the Code FundamentalsandtheIOSCOCRAPrinciples.Thiswillpermitmarketparticipantsandregulatorsto draw their own conclusions about whether the CRA has implemented the Code Fundamentals to theirsatisfaction,andtoreactaccordingly”(IOSCOCode(2004),p.2). IOSCOrequirestheCRAs’methodologiestobecomepublictoenhancetransparencyinanindustry whichisveryopaqueinnature.CESRgoesfurtherandproposes,asanalternativetoselfͲregulation, “theneedtointroducesomespecificrulesonfairrepresentationwhichwouldestablishaminimum 178 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment levelofdisclosureonthoseelementsandassumptionswhichmakeclearformarketoperatorsand investors to understand how a specific rating was determined by a credit rating agency” (CESR (2005),para.117). Thenatureandextentofinformationmadeavailabletothepublicstillvariesfromagencytoagency. SincethepublicationoftheIOSCOCodeanditsintegrationintotheCRAs’ownCodeofConduct,the CRAshaveincreasedthenumberoflengthyresearchreportsandpublicationsontheirwebsitesand published some of the criteria used to assess credit risk in their bid to improve transparency. However, the view is still widespread that CRAs’ methodologies, the variables and weights which theyemploy,andthecriteriausedinthedeliberationsofratingscommitteesremainopaquetoboth investorsandborrowers.TheCESRsummedupthecontinuingproblemwhenitstatedthat:“Credit ratingagenciesshouldaimfortransparencyasthebestwayforwardtoenableinvestorsandissuers tounderstandthequalityandobjectivityofthecreditrating.Creditratingagenciesshouldtherefore implementmeasure2.7oftheIOSCOCode”. (d)Accountability Thereisnomechanismtoprotectinvestorsand/orborrowersfrommistakesmadebyCRAsorany abuse of power on their part. This is true even if reputational interests and competition provide incentives for generating quality financial information. In order to promote transparency and improvetheabilityofmarketparticipantsandregulatorstojudgewhetheraCRAhassatisfactorily implementedwhatitpledgesitisdoing,theIOSCOCoderecommendsonlythatCRAsgivefulleffect totheCodebypublishingtheirown,adheringtoitandjustifyingpubliclyanydeviationbetweenthis codeandtheiractivities. There remains the need for more formal regulation to address market failures in the form of imperfectcompetitionandprincipalͲagentproblemsinthecreditratingindustry.TheCESRtechnical reportclearlyputsitsfingerontheissueinvolved:“Thereasonforhavingaregulatorymechanism shouldratherbethatthereexistssomemarketfailurethathastobedealtwith.Inessenceallthe issuesdiscussedinthepreviouschapterarisebecausetheexistenceofconflictsofinterestsbetween the CRAs and the issuers and/or the users of ratings (the investors). These types of conflicts of interests between professional players on the financial markets are natural and exist in numerous areasofthemarkets.Theybecomeespeciallyapparentintheratingmarketbecauseofthelackof balanceofpowerbetweenthedifferentplayers.IssuersarerelativelyweakcomparedtotheCRAs becauseoftheirdependenceontheratingstheyget.Investorshavenothistoricallyinvestedlarge resources in improving rating agencies behavior, perhaps because there was insufficient transparencyontheway CRAsoperated tofacilitatethis.ThismeantthatCRAshistoricallyhave a verystrongposition.WhattheIOSCOCodeistryingtodoistorebalancetheinterestsbetweenthe differentplayers”(CESR(2005),para.260). Rousseau(2005)–notinreferencesͲsumsupconcernsovertheresulting“accountabilitygap”as follows:“ThisaccountabilitygapisworrisomeforCRAsaswellasmarketparticipants.Fortheformer, theaccountabilitygapmayaffecttheircredibilityinthemarketplace.Forthelatter,itisofparticular concern given the role that CRAs play in capital markets...There is a need for a […] mechanism to takeoverifreputationfails.” ForthefirsttimeinthehistoryofratingsintheUnitedStatestheCreditRatingAgencyReformActof 2006 has clearly designated the SEC to monitor CRAs’ compliance with new securities laws and regulations. The SEC will be able to act as deemed necessary and to study and report to congressional committees any problems faced in the future with anything relating to the credit ratingindustry. 179 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries F. Conclusions CRAsplayakeyroleinfinancialmarketsbyhelpingtoreducetheinformationalasymmetrybetween lenders and investors, on one side, and issuers on the other side, about the creditworthiness of companies (corporate risk) or countries (sovereign risk). CRAs’ role has expanded with financial globalization and has received an additional boost from Basel II which incorporates the ratings of CRAsintotherulesforsettingweightsforcreditrisk. Inmakingtheirratings,CRAsanalysepublicandnonͲpublicfinancialandaccountingdataaswellas information about economic and political factors that may affect the ability and willingness of a Governmentorfirmstomeettheirobligationsinatimelymanner.However,CRAslacktransparency anddonotprovideclearinformationabouttheirmethodologies. Ratingstendtobesticky,laggingmarkets,andthentooverͲreactwhentheydochange.ThisoverͲ reactionmayhaveaggravatedfinancialcrisesintherecentpast,contributingtofinancialinstability andcrossͲcountrycontagion.Moreovertheactionsofcountrieswhichstrivetomaintaintheirrating gradesthroughtightmacroeconomicpoliciesmaybecounterͲproductiveforlongͲterminvestment andgrowth. The recent bankruptcies of Enron, WorldCom, and Parmalat have prompted legislative scrutiny of theagencies.Criticismhasbeenespeciallydirectedtowardsthehighdegreeofconcentrationofthe industry,whichintheUnitedStateshasreflectedaregistrationandcertificationprocessintheform ofNRSROdesignation biasedagainstnewentrants. The effectofsuch concentration hasbeen the absenceofthedisciplineenforcedbycompetitionandalowlevelofinnovation. IntheUnitedStatespolicyactionhasincludedthe2006CreditRatingAgencyReformActwhichhas overhauled the regulatory framework by prescribing procedural requirements for NRSRO registrationandcertificationandbystrengtheningthepowersoftheSEC. At the international level the main initiative has been the publication by IOSCO of its Code of Conduct.ThisCodeaimsatdevelopinggovernancerulesforCRAstoensurethequalityandintegrity oftheratingprocess,theindependenceoftheprocessandtheavoidanceofconflictsofinterest,and greater transparency. In its 2005 Technical Advice to the European Commission on possible Measures Concerning Credit Rating Agencies the CESR recommended the implementation of the IOSCOCodeandadoptionofa“waitͲandͲsee”attitude. Definitiveassessmentoftheseinitiativeswouldstillbepremature.Theindustrywillreceiveafillip from implementation of Basel II. The major CRAs will undoubtedly seek a substantial share of the new business which will result. The promotion of competition may require policy action at the nationalleveltoencouragetheestablishmentofnewagenciesandtochannelbusinessgeneratedby newregulatoryrequirementsintheirdirection.Regulatoryactionatthenationallevelmayalsobe necessary to ensure that the agencies operate in accord with levels of accountability and transparencymatchingtherecommendationsoftheIOSCOCode. 180 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment References Ammer J and Packer F (2000). How Consistent are Credit Ratings? A Geographic and Sectoral Analysis of Default risk. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International FinanceDiscussionPaper,668,June. BaselCommitteeonBankingSupervision(BCBS)(2000).CreditRatingsandComplementarySources ofCreditQualityInformation.BaselCommitteeonBankingSupervisionWorkingPapers, 3, Basel,August. BankforInternationalSettlements(BIS)(2006).QuarterlyReview,June. BeersDandCavanaughM(2005).SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer.NewYork,Standard&Poor’s, RatingsDirect,September. BeersDandChambersJ(2004).SovereignDefaultsSettoFallAgainin2005.StandardandPoor’s, RatingsDirect,September. Beers D (2004). Credit FAQ: The Future of Sovereign Credit Ratings. London, Standard and Poor’s, March. BergAandPattilloC(1999).AreCurrencyCrisesPredictable?IMFStaffPapers,Vol.46,June. BhatiaAV(2002).SovereignCreditRatingsMethodology:anEvaluation.IMFWorkingPaper02/170, InternationalMonetaryFund. Blum J and Hellwig M (1995). The Macroeconomic Implications of Capital Adequacy Requirements forBanks.EuropeanEconomicReview,39(3). BorioCEV,FurfineCandLoweP(2001).ProcyclicalityoftheFinancialSystemandFinancialStability: IssuesandPolicyoptions.BISPapers,1,March. Borensztein E, Cowan K and Valenzuela P (2006). The “Sovereign Ceiling Lite” and Bank Credit Ratings in Emerging Markets Economies. Mimeo, Washington, DC, InterͲAmerican DevelopmentBank,SantiagodeChile,BancoCentraldeChile. BorenszteinEandPanizzaU(2006).TheCostofSovereignDefault.Workingpaper.WashingtonDC, InterͲAmericanDevelopmentBank. BrandLandBaharR(1999).RatingsPerformance1998.Standard&Poor’sCorporation. CantorRandPackerF(1996).Determinantsandimpactofsovereigncreditratings.EconomicPolicy Review,FederalReserveBankofNewYork,vol.2,October. CantorRandPackerF(1996).MultipleRatingsandCreditStandards:DifferencesfoOpinioninthe CreditRatingIndustry.StaffReports12,FederalReserveBankofNewYork. Cantor R and Packer F (1995). Sovereign Credit Ratings. Current Issues in Economic and Finance, FederalReserveBankofNewYork,Vol1(3),June. CantorRandPackerF(1994).TheCreditRatingsIndustry.QuarterlyReview,FederalReserveBankof NewYork,Summer/Fall. CESR(2005).CESR’sTechnicalAdvicetotheEuropeanCommissiononPossibleMeasuresConcerning CreditRatingAgencies.TheCommitteeofEuropeanSecuritiesRegulations(CESR/05Ͳ139b), March. Claessens S and Embrechts G (2002). Basel II, sovereign Ratings and Transfer Risk: External versus InternalRatings.UniversityofAmsterdamandRabobankInternational,theNetherlandsfor 181 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries presentation at the conference Basel II: an Economic Assessment. Basel, Bank for InternationalSettlements,May17Ͳ18. Cornford A (2005). Basel II: The Revised Framework of June 2004. UNCTAD Discussion Paper, 178, April. CornfordA(2001).TheBaselCommittee’sProposalsforRevisedCapitalStandards:Mark2andThe StateofPlay.UNCTADDiscussionPaper,156,September. Daly K and Fischer D (2006). Sovereign Ratings History Since 1975. Standard and Poor’s, RatingsDirect,April. EganͲJonesRatingsCompany(2002).StatementofEganͲJonesonCreditRatingAgenciestotheSEC. November10. Estrella A (2000). Credit Ratings and Complementary Sources of Credit Quality Information. Basel, BaselCommitteeonBankingSupervision,WorkingPapers,3,August. Ferri G (2003). More Analysis: Agencies Invest Enough in Less Developed Countries ? University of Bari. Ferri G, Liu LG and Majnoni G (2000). The Role of Rating Agency Assessments in Less Developed Countries: Impact of the Proposed Basel Guidelines. The World Bank, University of Bari. At:.www.siteresources.worldbank.org/INTABCDEWASHINGTON2000/Resources/ferrietal.pdf FerriG,LiuLGandStiglitzJ(1999).TheProcyclicalRoleofRatingAgencies:EvidencefromtheEast AsianCrisis.EconomicNotesbyBancaMontedeiPaschidisienataSpA,vol.28(3). FitchRatings(2006).FitchSovereignRatingTransitionandDefaultStudy.SpecialReport,23February. GoldsteinM,KaminskyGL,ReinhartCM(GKR)(2000).AssessingFinancialStability:anEarlyWarning SystemforEmergingMarkets.WashingtonDC,InstituteforInternationalEconomics. Haque NU, Mathieson D and Mark N (1998). The relative importance of Political and Economic VariablesinCreditworthinessRatings.IMFWorkingPaper(WP/98/46). HaqueNU,MathiesonDandMarkN(1997).RatingtheRatersofCountryCreditworthiness.Finance &Development,InternationalMonetaryFund,March. HaqueNUetal.(1996).TheEconomicContentofIndicatorsofDevelopingCountryCreditworthiness. IMFStaffPapers,vol.43(4),December. H.R.2990(2006).AnAct,ToImproveRatingsQualitybyFosteringCompetition,Transparency,and Accountability In The Credit Rating Agency Industry. U.S. House of Representatives, 109th Congress,2ndSession. H.R.2990(2005a).ReformingCreditRatingAgencies:TheSEC’SNeedforStatuoryAuthority.Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Capital Markets, insurance and Government Sponsored Enterprises of the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, 109th Congress,1stSession,SerialNo.109–66,12April. H.R.2990(2005b).TheCreditRatingAgencyDuopolyReliefAct.HearingBeforetheSubcommittee onCapitalMarkets,insuranceandGovernmentSponsoredEnterprisesoftheCommitteeon Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, 109th Congress, 1st Session, Serial No. 109Ͳ66,29November. IMF (1999). International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects and key Policy Issues, September1999.Availableat:www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/icm/1999/index.htm. 182 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment IOSCO (2003). IOSCO Statement Of Principles Regarding The Activities Of Credit Rating Agencies, Statement of the Technical Committee of IOSCO, Report on the Activities of Credit Rating Agencies,ReportoftheTechnicalCommitteeofIOSCO(IOSCOPD153),September. IOSCO (2003). Report on Analyst Conflict of Interest, Report of the Technical Committee of IOSCO (IOSCOPD152). IOSCO (2003). IOSCO Statement of Principles Regarding The Activities of Credit Rating Agencies, StatementoftheTechnicalCommitteeofIOSCO(IOSCOPD151). Japan Center for International Finance (1999). Characteristics and Appraisal of Major Rating CompaniesͲͲFocusingonRatingsinJapanandAsia.April. JuttnerandMcCarthy(2000).ModellingaRatingCrisis.Sydney,MacquarieUniversity,unpublished, 2Ͳ22. Kaminsky G and Schmukler SL (2002). Emerging Markets Instability: Do Sovereign Ratings Affect CountryRiskandStockReturns?WorldBankEconomicReview,OxfordUniversityPress,vol. 16(2),August. KaminskyGL,ReinhartCandVeghC(2004).WhenItRains,ItPours:ProͲcyclicalCapitalFlowsand MacroeconomicPolicies.NBERWorkingPaper,10780. Kaminsky GL and Reinhart C (1999). The Twin Crises: The causes of Banking and BalanceͲofͲ paymentsProblems.AmericanEconomicReview,89(3),June. Kaminsky GS, Lizondo and Reinhart CM (1998). Leading Indicators ofCurrency Crises. Staff Papers, InternationalMonetaryFund,Vol.45,March. Larrain GH, Reisen and von Maltzan J (1997). Emerging Market Risk and sovereign Credit Ratings. Paris,OECDDevelopmentCentreTechnicalPapers,124,April. Lehmann A (2004). Sovereign Credit Ratings and Private Capital Flows to LowͲIncome Countries. AfricanDevelopmentReview,16(2). Liu LG and Ferri G (2001). How do Global Credit Rating Agencies Rate Firms from Developing Countries?ADBInstituteResearchPaper,26. Millon MH and Thakor AV (1985). Moral Hazard and Information Sharing: A Model of Financial InformationGatheringAgencies.JournalofFinance,40. MartinMandRoseͲInnesC(2004).PrivateCapitalFlowstoLowͲIncomeCountries:Perceptionand Reality.CanadianDevelopmentReport,Chapter2. Moody’s(2001).RevisedCountryCeilingPolicy:RatingMethodology.June. Moody’s,SpecialComment(1998).WhitePaper:Moody’sRatingRecordintheEastAsianFinancial Crisis.Moody’sInvestorsService,May. Moody’s Special Comment (2003). Are Corporate Bond Ratings ProͲcyclical? Moody’s Investor’s Service,May. Moody’sSpecialComment(2006).AGuidetoMoody’sSovereignRatings.August,p.1. MoraN(2005).SovereignCreditRatings:GuiltybeyondReasonableDoubt?AmericanUniversityof Beirut. Nagy PJ (1984).Country Risk: How to Assess, Quantify, and Monitor it? Euromoney Publications, London. 183 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries PackerFandReynoldsE(1997).TheSamuraiBondMarket.CurrentIssuesinEconomicandFinance, June. PowellA(2004).BaselIIandDevelopingCountries:SailingThroughtheSeaofStandards.WorldBank PolicyResearchWorkingPaper,3387,September. Ramakrishnan RTS and Thakor AV (1984). Information Reliability and a Theory of Financial Intermediation.ReviewofEconomicStudies,51. ReinhartCM(2002).Default,CurrencyCrisesandSovereignCreditRatings(NBERWP8738). ReisenH(2002).RatingssincetheAsianCrisis.DiscussionPaper,2002(2),UnitedNationsUniversity. Reisen H and von Maltzan J (1999). Boom and Bust in Sovereign Ratings. OECD Technical Papers, 148.Availableat:www.oecd.org/pdf/M00006000/M00006204.pdf. Rousseau S (2005). Enhancing the Accountability of Credit Rating Agencies: The Case for A DisclosureͲBasedApproach.CMI,UniversityofMontreal,p.37. SachsJ,TornellAandVelascoA(1996).FinancialCrisisinEmergingMarkets:theLessonsfrom1995. BrookingsPapersonEconomicActivityno.1,Washington,BrookingsInstitution. Setty G and Dodd R (2003). Credit Rating Agencies: Their Impact on Capital Flows to Developing Countries.FinancialPolicyForum,SpecialPolicyReport,6. Smith Rand WalterI(2001).RatingAgencies:IsthereanAgencyIssue?SternSchoolofBusiness, NewYorkUniversity. Standards and Poor’s (2003). Standards and Poor’s Supports a New, More Transparent NRSRO DesignationProcess.PressRelease,July. Standards and Poor’s (2004). Credit FAQ: The Future of Sovereign Credit Ratings. David Beers, London. StandardandPoor’sandUNDP(2005).SovereignRatingsinAfrica.September. SyA(2004).Ratingtheratingagencies:anticipatingcurrencycrisesordebtcrises?In:CantorRed., RecentResearchonCreditRatings(specialissue),JournalofBankingandFinance,28(11). Varma P et al. (2003). Sovereign Bond Defaults, Rating Transitions, and Recoveries (1985–2002). Moody’sSpecialComment,February. WhiteLJ(2001).TheCreditRatingIndustry:AnIndustrialOrganizationAnalysis.Paperpresentedat the Conference on “The Role of Credit Reporting Systems in the International Economy”, WashingtonD.C.,TheWorldBank,1–2March. World Bank (2006). Global Development Finance: The Development Potential of Surging Capital Flows.TheWorldBank. 184 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment AnnexI.SovereignRatingsMethodologyProfile Figure1.GDPperCapita Source:S&P,Oct.2006,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”. Figure2.RealGDPGrowthperCapita Source:S&P,Oct.2006,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”. 185 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries Figure3.ConsumerPriceIndex(CPI) Source:S&P,Oct.2006,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”. Figure4.GeneralGovernmentBalanceasPercentageofGDP Source:S&P,Oct.2006,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”. 186 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Figure5.NetGeneralGovernmentDebtasPercentageofGDP Source:S&P,Sept.2005,“SovereignCreditRatings:APrimer”. 187 CreditRatingAgenciesandtheirPotentialImpactonDevelopingCountries AnnexII Table1.RatingSymbols RATING SYMBOLS FOR LONG-TERM AND SHORT-TERM DEBT Interpretation Moody's S&P Fitch Long-Term Short-Term Long-Term Short-Term Long-Term Short-Term INVESTMENT-GRADE RATINGS Highest Credit Quality Aaa AAA AAA High Credit Quality Strong Payment Capacity Adequate Payment Capacity Last Rating in Investment-Grade Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Prime-1 Prime-2 Prime-3 AA+ AA AA- A1+ AA+ AA AA- A+ A A- A1 A+ A A- BBB+ BBB BBB- A2 A3 BBB+ BBB BBB- F1 F2 F3 SPECULATIVE-GRADE RATINGS Speculative credit risk developing due to economic changes Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 Higly Speculative, credit risk present with limited margin of safety B1 B2 B3 High Default Risk, capacity depending on sustained, favorable conditions Caa1 Caa2 Caa3 BB+ BB BBNot Prime B+ B BCCC+ CCC CCCCC C, D Ca, C Default, although prospect of partial recovery B BB+ BB BB- B B+ B BC D CCC+ CCC CCCCC C, D C D Source:BasedonS&P,Moody’sandFitch. 188 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Table2.RatingAgenciesRecognizedinVariousCountries Source:BCBS(2000),Table2,p.46. Note:Table2showstheratingagenciesrecognizedbythebankingsupervisorsinBCBScountriesand selected nonͲmembers. The total number of agencies recognized in each country is shown in therightͲhandcolumn.Itisevidentthereisconsiderabledisparityinthenumberofrecognitions grantedbysupervisors.ThebigthreeCRAs,S&P,Moody’sandFitch,arerecognizedbyallBCBS membersandalmostallnonͲBCBScountriesshown. 189 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERIX PURSUINGSUSTAINABLEDEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES:THECASEOFTHEBALANCEOF PAYMENTRULESINWTO RobertHowse,AleneSmithandAllanF.Smith (UniversityofMichigan) A. Introduction 1. Equity InSectionIIIoftheMillenniumDeclarationentitled“DevelopmentandPovertyReduction,”United NationsMemberStatescommittedthemselvesto“tocreateanenvironmentͲatthenationaland global levels alike Ͳ which is conducive to development and to the elimination of poverty.” This depends on “good governance within each country”, “good governance at the international level, andontransparencyinthefinancial,monetaryandtradingsystems.”Hence,they“arecommittedto anopen,equitable,ruleͲbased,predictableandnonͲdiscriminatorymultilateraltradingandfinancial system.” The concept of equity in international trade and financial rules and institutions has not been explicitly defined and is the subject of debate and speculation among philosophers and political theorists. Economists are often skeptical of whether the trade and financial systems should be understood at all in terms of justice rather than as instruments of economic policy coordination. Nevertheless,itwillbeobservedthattheactualrulesoftendodepend,explicitlyorimplicitly,ona conceptoffairness.Forinstance,oneoftherulesthatwillbediscussedinthispaper,containedin ArticleIVoftheIMFArticlesofAgreementrequiredthatIMFMembersnot“manipulateexchange rates or the international monetary system in order to prevent effective balance of payments adjustmentortogainanunfaircompetitiveadvantageoverothermembers.” 191 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO The concept of equity is thus inescapable in the interpretation and application of the law of the internationaltradeandfinancialsystems.Thequestioniswhethertherearelegalandpolicysources thatallowustogiveadefinitemeaningtothisconceptasweapplyittoparticularrulesanddisputes inthetradeandfinancialsystems. One ingredient of equity that is widely reflected in international instruments concerning trade, financeanddevelopmentisthenotionthatrulesshouldbeadjustedtotheindividualsituationsof countrieswithrespecttotheirdevelopmentneeds.Thus,thereiswidespreadagreementthatformal legalequality,treatingeveryonethesameregardlessoftheirparticularsituation,isnotequitable.At thesametime,thereisdisagreementamongstatesonhowmuchdifferentialtreatmentisjustified inagivensituation. Thereisaninterestingparallelismbetweentheconceptionofequityastreating“unlikes”differently and the recognition in recent economic literature that—contrary to what was implied in the WashingtonConsensusformula—thereisnotasingleformulaorpathwaytodevelopmentthatwill workforallcountries.109 Anotherdimensionofequityreflectedininternationalhumanrightsinstrumentsisthatofvoiceand participation.Theseinstrumentssuggestthatpeopleshouldnothaveavisionofdevelopmentforced onthemordecidedbyothers.TheDeclarationontheRighttoDevelopment,forexample,stipulates thattheRighttoDevelopmentincludes“freeandmeaningfulparticipationindevelopment.” Closelyrelatedtothenotionofequityistheconceptofsocialandeconomicjusticeexpressedinthe United Nations Covenant on Social and Economic and Cultural Rights. Article 11 of the Covenant provides: “1. The States Parties to the present Covenant recognize the right of everyone to an adequatestandardoflivingforhimselfandhisfamily,includingadequatefood,clothingandhousing, and to the continuous improvement of living conditions. The States Parties will take appropriate steps to ensure the realization of this right, recognizing to this effect the essential importance of international coͲoperation based on free consent.” While not all states Ͳ most notably the United StatesͲhaveembracedtherightsintheCovenantastreatyorcustomaryinternationallaw,eventhe UnitedStateshasparticipatedintheDeclarationontheRighttoDevelopment,whichincorporates toalargeextentandaffirmstheserights.Aconcreteimplicationofthisnotionofequityisthatthe rules of the international trade and financial system should, at a minimum, not undermine, and ideally should facilitate, the ability of states to discharge their obligations under the Covenant to implementsocialandeconomicrights. Finally, equity has been considered by United Nation Member States to imply a fair global distribution of burdens and benefits from the operations of the international trade and financial system.Thisgoesbeyondanotionsimplythatthesystem(s)shouldenablestatestoachievesocial and economic justice within their borders to a conception of global solidarity. According to the MillenniumDeclaration,solidarityrequiresthat“globalchallengesmustbemanagedinawaythat distributes the costs and burdens fairly in accordance with basic principles of equity and social justice.”110 In its examination of WTO rules and jurisprudence as they relate to the balanceͲofͲpayments and other international financial issues this paper will draw on the dimensions of equity articulated above. 109 Rodrik D (2001). The Global Governance of Trade as if Development Really Mattered. United Nations Development Programme. 110 See also Beviglia Zampetti A (2005). Progressing Towards a Just Future Through the MDGs: What is the Role of an “Equitable”MultilateralTradingSystem?Draft:12.October. 192 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment TheWTOAgreementdefinesthegoalofthemultilateraltradingsystemintermsoftheprinciplethat “relationsinthefieldoftradeandeconomicendeavorshouldbeconductedwithaviewtoraising standardsofliving,ensuringfullemploymentandalargeandsteadilygrowingvolumeofrealincome and effective demand, and expanding the production of and trade in goods and services, while allowingfortheoptimaluseoftheworld’sresourcesinaccordancewiththeobjectiveofsustainable development...”Clearly,thegoalsofraisingstandardsoflivingandensuringfullemploymentare closely linked to the conception of social and economic justice in the UN Covenant on Social EconomicandCulturalRights. 2. Coherence Arguablycoherenceisalogicalimplicationoftherecognitionofequityasafundamentalelementof theinternationaltradeandfinancialsystems.Coherencerefers,firstly,to therulesand policiesof theinstitutionswhereequityisarticulatedanddefinednormativelyand,secondly,totherulesand policies of the international trading and financial systems themselves. Inequity may result from uncoordinatedrulesbetweenthetradingandthefinancialsystems. Forexample,theIMFmayrequireacountrytoimproveitsbalanceofpayments.However,therules of the trading system may not permit the use of certain instruments for doing so. There may be goodreasonswhytheseinstrumentsareconstrainedbytherulesoftheinternationaltradingsystem. However,intheabsenceofabroadandpalatablerangeofpolicyoptionsfortrade,thecountrymay pursue the goal specified by the IMF through recourse to policy instruments that threaten social equity,andresultinpovertyandunemployment. AnearlyexplicitattempttoaddresscoherenceattheWTOistheUruguayRoundDeclarationonthe ContributionoftheWorldTradeOrganizationtoGreaterCoherenceinGlobalEconomicPolicymaking. Paragraph2oftheDeclarationreads: “Trade liberalization forms an increasingly important component in the success of the adjustment programs that many countries are undertaking, often involving significant transitional social costs. In this connection, Ministersnote the role of the World Bank and the IMF in supporting adjustment to trade liberalization, including support to net foodͲimporting developingcountriesfacingshortͲtermcostsarisingfromagriculturaltradereforms.” ThemostimportantpartoftheDeclarationisarguablytobefoundinParagraph5: “The interlinkages between the different aspects of economic policy require that the international institutions with responsibilities in each of these areas follow consistent and mutually supportive policies. The World Trade Organization should therefore pursue and developcooperationwiththeinternationalorganizationsresponsibleformonetaryandfinancial matters, while respecting the mandate, the confidentiality requirements and the necessary autonomy in decisionͲmaking procedures of each institution, and avoiding the imposition on Governments of crossͲconditionality or additional conditions. Ministers further invite the DirectorͲGeneral of the WTO to review with the Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund and the President of the World Bank, the implications of the WTO’s responsibilitiesforitscooperationwiththeBrettonWoodsinstitutions,aswellastheformssuch cooperation might take, with a view to achieving greater coherence in global economic policymaking.” Paragraph 2 draws attention to the significant social costs of trade liberalization and economic reform. But the Declaration does not extend the idea of coherence to cooperation with those 193 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO internationalinstitutionswhosemandateisdevelopmentpolicysuchasUNCTADandUNDPnorto thoseconcernedwithsocialequityandjusticesuchastheUnitedNationshumanrightsinstitutions. Instead, the need for coherence is limited to those international institutions “responsible for monetaryandfinancialmatters”.However,accordingtoParagraph5theseinstitutionsaretoavoid “crossͲconditionality,” under which a Government is forced to pursue harmful or inconsistent policies to meet uncoordinated conditions or restrictions imposed by different international economicinstitutions. In 1996, the WTO entered into a cooperation agreement with the IMF, which provides for consultationsandtheexchangeofinformationbetweenthetwoorganizations.Paragraph10ofthe agreementprovides: “The Fund’s staff shall consult with the WTO Secretariat on issues of possible inconsistency between measures under discussion with a common member and that member’s obligations undertheWTOAgreement.TheWTOSecretariatshallconsultwiththeFund’sstaffonissuesof possible inconsistency between measures under discussion with a common member and that member’sobligationsundertheFund’sArticlesofAgreement.” ThisprovisionisimportantforcoherencesinceitappearstostrengthenandimplementParagraph5 of the Uruguay Round Declaration on Coherence by requiring consultations about possible inconsistency while measures are still “under discussion”. As discussed below, in at least one prominent WTO dispute it is clear that this consultation requirement had not been followed, a circumstance to which unfortunately the Appellate Body of the WTO did not attach much importance. TheWTODohaDeclarationprovidedfortheestablishmentofanewWorkingGrouponTrade,Debt andFinance: “36.Weagreetoanexamination,inaWorkingGroupundertheauspicesoftheGeneralCouncil, oftherelationshipbetweentrade,debtandfinance,andofanypossiblerecommendationson steps that might be taken within the mandate and competence of the WTO to enhance the capacityofthemultilateraltradingsystemtocontributetoadurablesolutiontotheproblemof external indebtedness of developing and leastͲdeveloped countries, and to strengthen the coherence of international trade and financial policies, with a view to safeguarding the multilateraltradingsystemfromtheeffectsoffinancialandmonetaryinstability.” TheWorkingGrouphasexaminedanumberoftheissuesdiscussedbelowbuthasbeenunableto makeanyconcreterecommendations.A2005report111summarizestheviewsofindividualMembers of the Working Group but concludes only with the recommendation that the Group continue its activitiesintothefuture. B. ExchangeControlsandConvertibility The GATT rules on exchange controls and convertibility reflect the international financial and monetary system designed at Bretton Woods at the end the World War II. The postͲwar Bretton Woods arrangements contemplated a system of fixed exchange rates tied to gold. When a temporary imbalance of payments occurred (i.e. where a country could not meet payments for imports with its receipts of foreign currency from export sales without selling gold for foreign 111 World Trade Organization (2005). Report of the Working Group on Trade, Debt and Finance to the General Council. (WT/WGTDF/4),October. 194 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment currency),thiswouldbefinancedbyborrowingfromtheInternationalMonetaryFund.Inthecaseof astructuralorpersistentimbalance,acountrywoulddevalueitscurrencyunderthesupervisionof theIMF,whichmightrecommenddomesticpolicyadjustmentstoensurethatfurtherdevaluations werenotrequiredsubsequentlyinordertomaintainthebalanceofpayments. TheBrettonWoodssystembrokedownin1971whentheUnitedStatesunilaterallyoptedoutofthe systemwhenitannouncedthesuspensionofconvertibilityofthedollarintogold.TheresultiswellͲ summarizedina2004UNCTADdocument: “Unfortunately, after the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system at the beginning of the 1970s, the world monetary system slipped back into the kind of “monetary chaos” that had characterizedthepreͲwarperiodanditsdismaleconomicandpoliticaloutcomes.Nevertheless, the liberalization of the trading system, even after the end of the BrettonWoods system, was pushed forward by policymakers as if a consistent approach on the monetary side, i.e. a coherentmonetaryorder,wouldhaveexisted.Onlyrecently,withtheAsiancrisisaswellaswith the Latin American currency turmoil, have the shortcomings of the “monetary chaos” and its repercussionsonthetradingsystembeenacknowledged,evenbymainstreameconomictheory andtheWTO.Butinstabilityisonlypartofthestory.....ifchangesintheinternationalvalueof moneyareinnowayrelatedtothefundamentalsofcountrieswithopenmarketsforgoodsand capital,traditionaltradetheoriesquicklylosetheirgrasponrealityandtradeliberalizationloses muchofitsallegedjustification.”112 In the case of developing countries progress towards convertibility and the removal of exchange controlswasamajorfeatureoftheeconomicorthodoxyinthe1980sand1990s.Suchreformswere thought to have the effect of encouraging foreign investment and creating domestic financial systems as well as access to the global financial networks that would underwrite growth and development. TheAsianandLatinAmericanfinancialcrisesofthe1990sledtorethinkingofthisorthodoxy.Well knowneconomistssuchasJagdishBhagwatiandJosephStiglitzmaintainedthattoorapidfinancial liberalization contributed to the crises, which led to widespread human misery in a number of countries,expressedtheirsupportforcapitalcontrolsasaninstrumentforstemmingapanicflight ofshortͲtermcapital.113114 TheGATTrulesconcerningexchangemeasuresandconvertibilityarecontainedinArticleXVofthe GeneralAgreement: x Article XV:4 states that “Contracting parties shall not, by exchange action, frustrate the intentoftheprovisionsofthisAgreement,norbytradeaction,theintentoftheprovisions oftheArticlesofAgreementoftheInternationalMonetaryFund.” x According to the Interpretative Note Ad Article XV: “The word “frustrate” is intended to indicate, for example, that infringements of the letter of any Article of this Agreement by exchangeactionshallnotberegardedasaviolationofthatArticleif,inpractice,thereisno appreciabledeparturefromtheintentoftheArticle.Thus,acontractingpartywhich,aspart of its exchange control operated in accordance with the Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund, required payment to be received for its exports in its own currencyorinthecurrencyofoneormoremembersoftheInternationalMonetaryFundwill 112 World Trade Organization (2004). Economic Policy Challenges in an Open Economy: Coherence between Trade and Finance. Communication of UNCTAD to the WTO Working Group on Trade, Debt and Finance (WT/WGTDF/W/27), November. 113 BhagwhatiJ(2004).InDefenseofGlobalization.Oxford,OxfordUniversityPress,199Ͳ200. 114 StiglitzJ(2002).GlobalizationandItsDiscontents.NewYork,W.W.Norton. 195 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO nottherebybedeemedtocontraveneArticleXIorArticleXIII[oftheGATTonquantitative restrictions]. Another example would be that of a contracting party which specifies on an importlicensethecountryfromwhichthegoodsmaybeimported,forthepurposenotof introducing any additional element of discrimination in its import licensing system but of enforcingpermissibleexchangecontrols.” x ArticleXV:9oftheGATTprovides:“NothinginthisAgreementshallpreclude:(a)theusebya contracting party of exchange controls or exchange restrictions in accordance with the Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund or with that contracting party’s specialexchangeagreementwiththeCONTRACTINGPARTIES,or(b)theusebyacontracting partyofrestrictionsorcontrolsonimportsorexportsthesoleeffectofwhich,additionalto theeffectspermittedunderArticlesXI,XII,XIIIandXIV,istomakeeffectivesuchexchange controlsorexchangerestrictions.” x AccordingtoArticleXVI:2oftheGATT,thereshallbedeferenceto“thedeterminationofthe Fundastowhetheractionbyacontractingpartyinexchangemattersinaccordancewiththe ArticlesofAgreementoftheInternationalMonetaryFund,...” Taken together, these provisions suggest that, where measures have been taken with respect to exchange controls or restrictions, even if such measures would otherwise be considered trade restrictionsbecauseoftheireffectonimportandexporttransactions,theintentoftheGATTisnot toimposedisciplinesbeyondthoserequiredbytheIMF. Itisinaccuratetoviewtheseprovisions,assomecommentatorshave,essentiallycedingjurisdiction to the IMF. According to this view, when an exchange measure is not consistent with the IMF Articles, the “safe haven” of Article XV disappears and the measure may well then fall afoul of a provisionoftheGATTsuchasArticleXI.Thus,whenacountrydisagreeswiththeFundonthebest course for solving a financial crisis, including one that does not worsen the plight of the least advantaged, the GATTpermitscountry tobe“punished”throughbeingfoundinviolation ofGATT rules.InsuchcasestheGATT/WTOwouldbecomearesidualenforcerfortheIMF. ArguablythiswasnottheintentoftheGATTframers.Firstofall,priortotheWTOtheGATTdispute settlementsystemcontainedmanydiplomaticsafetyvalves.Secondly,theoriginalIMFArticleswere premisedonaworldoflargelyfixedexchangeratesadjustedthroughIMFsupervision.However,in today’s world of speculationͲdriven currency markets and the widespread liberalization of capital controls(generallyendorsedbytheIMF)thereisnoagreedinternationalstandardagainstwhicha currencycanbeviewedasoverͲorunderͲvalued,thustriggeringareasonableobligationtoadjust economicfundamentalsthroughmeansthatdonotimposeunreasonablecostsonothercountries. Inthisworldrecoursetoexchangerestrictionsmaybeajustifiableoptionforacountryseekingto avoidacurrencycrisisortoprotectitselffromthecontagioneffectsofacrisiselsewhere.Thiscan beillustratedwiththecaseofMalaysia. In September 1998 Malaysia decided to defy the IMF’s advice and to impose selective capital controlsinordertohelptoresolveitsfinancialcrisisaswellastoenablethemaintenanceofafixed exchangerate.KaplanandRodrikconcludethat,incomparisonwithothercountriesthatfollowIMF prescriptions, and taking into account differences in those countries’ situations, “the Malaysian policywasmoresuccessfulinaccomplishinganimmediatereductionininterestrates,stabilizingthe currency, and stemming financial panic. This eased, for the short term at least, worries that the banking system would go under and that there would be a devaluation spiral. The turnaround in marketconfidencewascorrespondinglymorerapid.Inaddition,fiscalpolicywasonbalancemore 196 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment expansionary.Alltheseinturnspurredconsumptionandeconomicactivity.”115Fromtheperspective of equity, the observation of Kaplan and Rodrik that the Malaysian approach resulted in employment and incomes falling less in other Asian countries which followed IMF prescriptions is particularlyrelevant. Malaysia’s capital controls would not, on their face, have violated the original IMF Articles of Agreement, which the drafters of the GATT had in mind when they linked the safe haven for exchangemeasurestoIMFdisciplines.OnlycurrentͲaccountrestrictionsareclearviolationsofthese Articles,andIMFMemberStatesretaintherighttomaintaincontrolsoncapitalaccounttransactions. AsUpakbiexplains:“Whenreadtogether,...[ArticleVII:3(b)andArticleXIV:2oftheIMFArticlesof Agreement] suggest . . . [w]hereas, in respect of what is regarded as current international transactions (current account transactions), restrictions are ab initio disallowed (subject to limited exceptions);inrespectof the capitalaccount,thereverseisthecaseͲrestrictionsaremaintainable (again,subjecttolimitedexceptions).Giventhisdifferenceinthetreatmentofthetwoaccounts,a distinction between what falls within their respective ambits appears crucial. . . In part, [current transactions,accordingtoArticleXXXoftheIMFArticlesofAgreement]envisage“allpaymentsdue inconnectionwithforeigntrade.”116 AdifficultywiththeseprovisionsistheirassumptionofaclearͲcutdistinctionbetweencapitaland current account controls. They do not strictly speaking address current account, tradeͲrelated measures aimed at preventing circumvention of capital controls, such as artificial or overͲinvoiced tradetransactionswithinmultinationalenterprises. With respect to exchange rates, the IMF Articles of Agreement provide that an IMF Member shall not“manipulateexchangeratesortheinternationalmonetarysysteminordertopreventeffective balanceofpaymentsadjustmentortogainanunfaircompetitiveadvantageoverothermembers.” (IMF Agreement Article IV, Section 1(iii)). Currency manipulation as such is defined in the surveillanceprovisionsoftheIMFArticlesas“protractedlargeͲscaleinterventioninonedirectionin theexchangemarket.” However, the concept of an “unfair” competitive advantage is not defined. Recently the United StateshasputconsiderablepressureonChinatoeitherrevalueor“float”itscurrency,onthetheory that the exchange rate was “unfair” Ͳ rigged through official intervention to keep Chinese exports artificially cheap. The implication is that a “fair” exchange rate would that determined by the currency markets. However, in a world of floating exchange rates, where there is no objective standard,theconceptofa“correct”exchangerateisanillusiveone. However,inthiscasetheinternationalcommunitymayrequireabroaderbenchmarkwhichincludes a relevant conception of “equity.” Should China’s purchase of dollars with Renminbi be evaluated solely in the context of the objective of maintaining an exchange rate that constitutes an “unfair” competitive advantage? Arguably, under an approach to fairness influenced by conceptions of sustainabledevelopmentandtherighttodevelopment,oneessentialaspectofthequestionwould bewhetherChina’sexchangeͲratepolicyrepresentsalegitimateexerciseofitsrighttodevelopment, andthusthewayinwhichthepolicyfiguresinitsdevelopmentneedsandstrategies.Forexample, as Erik Denters argues, pegging the Renminbi to the dollar may well have encouraged foreign investment,acrucialpartofChina’sdevelopmentstrategy.117Atthesametime,onewouldhaveto 115 KaplanEandRodrikD(2001).DidtheMalaysianCapitalControlsWork?NBERWorkingPaper,8142:27. Ukpabi UC (2004). Juridical Substance or Myth over BalanceͲofͲPayments: Developing Countries and the Role of the InternationalMonetaryFundintheWorldTradeOrganization.MichiganJournalofInternationalLaw,26(2):710. 117 DentersE(2003).ManipulationofExchangeRatesinInternationalLaw:TheChineseYuan.ASILInsights,November. 116 197 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO ask how far China’s exchangeͲrate measures undermine the development policies of other WTO Members. In GATT/WTO practice and jurisprudence, the justifiability of measures under Article XV has been consideredonanumberofoccasionsinrelationtomanagementofthebalanceofpayments. x AccordingtotheGATTAnalyticalIndex,“DuringtheReviewSessionin1954Ͳ55,Italybrought a complaint concerning action by Turkey providing export bonuses for certain agricultural productsandlevyingspecialimporttaxesoncertaingoodsdeemedlessessentialinorderto providethenecessaryfundsforthebonuses.Italystatedthattheexportsubsidieshadnot beennotifiedasrequiredbyArticleXVI:1andthattheimporttaxeswereinconsistentwith ArticleII:1(b).Turkeystatedthataspartofareformofitsforeignexchangesystem,ithad establishedanEqualizationFundwhichwasfinancedbythesaleofimportpermits,andthat thissystemhadbeenapprovedbytheInternationalMonetaryFund.Arepresentativeofthe Fund confirmed that the practices under question were multiple currency practices under the Fund Articles of Agreement and that in a Decision concerning Turkey the Fund had stated that it did not object to the temporary continuance of these practices and would remaininconsultationwithTurkeyonthesepractices.”118 x In 1998 in the ArgentinaͲTextiles and Apparel case, Argentina argued that a 3 perͲcent ad valoremtaxthatitcollectedwasforpurposesoffundingthecollectionofaccuratestatistical dataonimportandexporttransactionsaspartofitsoverallunderstandingwiththeIMFon stabilization and adjustment.119In its ruling the panel held that there was no exception undertheGATTthatwould,forthesereasons,limitArgentina’sobligationsunderArticleVIII withregardtocustomsfees.Thepaneldidnotconsiderwhether,giventhatArgentinawas maintaining the tax in the context of its arrangements with the IMF, the tax could be deemedtobeanexchangemeasurewithinthemeaningofXV:9oftheGATT.Thefactthat thetaxappliedtoallimportsindicatesthatitwasnotintendedasaprotectionistmeasureto shelterArgentineindustriesfromcompetitionwhilelendingplausibilitytoitsconnectionto Argentina’s exchange arrangements. The Appellate Body upheld the panel’s approach. Argentina had argued that the Declaration on Coherence and the subsequent Agreement betweenthe1996IMFandtheWTO,referredtoabove,were“legislativedevelopments”in the WTO which had the effect of creating a metaͲnorm of avoidance of “crossͲ conditionalities,” such that its relations with the IMF would require a state to engage in conductthatwouldviolateWTOlaw.TheAppellateBodyfirstofallobservedthatArgentina hadnotshowntothepanel’ssatisfactionthatthetaxhadbeenrequestedofitbytheIMFor therewasaconflictoflegalobligation,i.e.thatArgentinahadalegallybindingagreement withtheIMFthatwouldbeviolatedifitdidnotimposethetax. ThefindingsoftheAppellateBodyintheArgentinaͲTextilesandApparelcasesuggestanarrowand formalistic view of the problem of coherence and conflicting conditionalities. In many cases the IMF’s requirements are of a general nature, and linked to the achievement of certain results. The IMFleavestheinstrumentalitiestothecountry’sGovernment.ThattheIMFhasnotrequested“x” policydoes notmeanthat“x”policydoesnotresultfromrequirementsimposedby theIMF—the policyinquestionmaybeoneoftheonlyfeasiblewaysofsatisfyingtheIMFdemandsatreasonable social cost. Moreover the notion of legal conflict suggested by the Appellate Body is equally problematic. It reduces the challenge of coherence to a notion of avoiding conflicting treaty requirements.However,internationallawisnottheonlyoreventheprimaryleverthattheIMFuses 118 WorldTradeOrganization(1995)GuidetoGATTLawandPractice.Geneva,1:439. World Trade Organization (1998). ArgentinaͲMeasures Affecting Imports of Footwear, Textiles, Apparel and Other Items,ReportoftheAppellateBody.(WT/DS56/AB/R),(adopted22April1998),paras.69Ͳ74. 119 198 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment to“enforce”conditionality;rather,theIMFwillsimplynotdisbursefurtherfundstoacountrythat does not meet its conditions, regardless of whether those conditions are formalized as legal requirementsorexpressedasistypicallythecasein“memoranda”or“lettersofintent”.120121 In its decision the Appellate Body placed considerable emphasis on the notion that neither the Declaration on Coherence nor the subsequent Cooperation Agreement between the WTO and the IMF added to or diminished the rights and obligations contained in the WTO Agreements. The Appellate Body noted that the effect of crossͲconditionalities or possible conflicts between measuresthatmightresultfromIMFprogramsandWTOobligationswasspecifiedas“consultation” betweentheFundandtheWTO.Yetwhenitconsideredwhetherthepanel’sfailuretoconsultwith theFundconstitutedaviolationofitsobligationtomakeanobjectiveassessmentofthematter,the Appellate Body ignored the consultation requirement as set out in the Paragraph 10 of the Agreement between the IMF and the WTO. The thrust of the Declaration on Coherence and the subsequent Agreement between the IMF and the WTO is that issues that arise from possible inconsistencies between measures taken in relation to Fund programs on the one hand and WTO obligationsontheotherought,atleastinthefirstinstance,tobeaddressedthroughconsultations andcooperationbetweentheWTOSecretariatandtheFund. Insummary, asinterpretedin thepracticeofWTO disputesettlementinthecases discussedhere and in others, the WTO rules on exchange actions are likely to be permissive regarding any macroeconomicpolicyinterventionthathastheexplicitblessingof,orisspecificallyrequiredbythe IMF. However, where a WTO Member takes an action that the Fund is not prepared to endorse explicitly, or that it has not required, and such an action falls generally with the kind of exchange measurescoveredbyArticleXV,thereissomethingclosetoapresumptionthattheWTOruleshave beenviolated.Yet,acompletereadingoftheagreementestablishingtheWTOandofIMFrulesand proceduressuggeststhattheydonotnecessarilyjustifythispresumption. C. TradeRestrictionsforBalanceͲofͲPaymentsPurposes122 ArticlesXIItoXIVoftheGATTelaborateacomplexcodedesignedtogovernanddisciplinetheuseof import restrictions for balanceͲofͲ payments purposes. Article XII:1 states the basic right of any Contracting Party to impose quantitative restrictions in derogation from Article XI “in order to safeguarditsexternalfinancial positionanditsbalanceofpayments”.ArticleXII:2establishesthat suchrestrictionsshallbelimitedtowhatis“necessary:(i)toforestalltheimminentthreatof,orto stop,aseriousdeclineinmonetaryreserves,or(ii)inthecaseofaContractingPartywithverylow monetaryreservestoachieveareasonablerateofincreaseinitsreserves”.Suchrestrictionsmustbe progressivelyrelaxedasthebalanceofpaymentsimproves. Furthermore, Contracting Parties “undertake, in carrying out their domestic policies, to pay due regardtotheneedformaintainingorrestoringequilibriumintheirbalanceofpaymentsonasound andlastingbasis”(ArticleXII:3).Atthesametime,noContractingPartyisobligatedtotakedomestic balanceͲofͲpaymentsmeasuresthatwouldthreatentheobjectiveoffullemployment).Aprocessof consultations is envisaged with the GATT Council concerning any new restrictions or increase in 120 See Eldar O (2005). Reform of IMF Conditionality; a Proposal for SelfͲImposed Conditionality. IILJ Working paper, 10. NewYorkUniversityLawSchool,CentreGlobalAdministrativeLawSeries. 121 Siegel DE (2002). Legal Aspects of the IMF/WTO Relationship: The Fund’s Articles of Agreement and the WTO Agreements.AmericanJournalofInternationalLaw,96:561Ͳ581. 122 The following draws from Michael J, Trebilcock and Howse R (2005). The Regulation of International Trade. Third Edition,Routledge,LondonandNewYork,ch.5“Trade,ExchangeRatesandtheBalanceofPayments.” 199 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO restrictions,withperiodicreviewofthenecessityofthetrademeasuresandtheirconsistencywith Articles XII–XIV. In addition, Article XII contains provisions on dispute settlement, including the authorizationofretaliationwhereaPartypersistsintraderestrictionsthathavebeenfoundbythe ContractingPartiestoviolatetheGATT. ArticlesXIIIandXIVcontain,respectively,therequirementthatmeasurestakenpursuanttoArticle XII:1 be implemented on a nonͲdiscriminatory basis and certain narrow exceptions to this nonͲ discrimination requirement, e.g. where discriminatory exchange controls have been authorized by theIMF(seethediscussionofsubstitutabilitybelow). In the case of developing countries, there is a much broader exemption from GATT disciplines for traderestrictionsundertakenforbalanceͲofͲpaymentsreasons.ArticleXVII:2(b)statestheprinciple that developing countries should have additional flexibility “to apply quantitative restrictions for balanceofpaymentspurposesinamannerwhichtakesfullaccountofthecontinuedhighlevelof demandforimportslikelytobegeneratedbytheirprogramsofeconomicdevelopment”. This suggests that even though a developing country could address its balance of payments difficultiesthroughexchangeͲrateadjustmentsortightermacroeconomicpolicies,itshouldnotbe expectedtodosoinviewoftheharmtodevelopmentthatmaycomefromtheresultantdeclinein needed imports. It is recognized that quantitative restrictions will allow a developing country to conserveitslimitedforeigncurrencyresourcesforpurchasesofimportsnecessaryfordevelopment –whereasadevaluationofitscurrencywouldresultinallimportsbecomingmoreexpensive.Inthis connectionitbearsemphasisthatbalanceͲofͲpaymentsrestrictionsingeneralmaybediscriminatory with respect to products although not with respect to countries. Indeed, it is explicitly stated that “the contracting party may determine (the) incidence (of restrictions) on imports of different productsorclassesofproductsinsuchawayastogiveprioritytotheimportationofthoseproducts whicharemoreessentialinthelightofitspolicyofeconomicdevelopment”(ArticleXVIIIB(10)). In 1979 the Contracting Parties, without formally amending the General Agreement, made the “Declaration on Trade Measures taken for BalanceͲofͲPayments Purposes”, which expanded the ambitofArticlesXII–XIVandXVIIIbeyondquantitativerestrictionstoinclude“allimportmeasures takenforbalanceofpaymentspurposes”. TheUnderstandingontheBalanceofPaymentsProvisionsoftheGeneralAgreementonTariffsand Trade 1994 (BOP Understanding), incorporated in the Uruguay Round Final Act, is aimed at improvingGATT/WTOdisciplineregardingtrademeasurestakenforbalanceͲofͲpaymentspurposes. Memberscommitthemselvestopublish,assoonaspossible,timeͲschedulesfortheremovalofsuch trade measures. Furthermore in perhaps the most important modification of the existing GATT regimeMemberscommitthemselvestogivepreferencetotrademeasuresofapriceͲbasednature, such as tariff surcharges, and to only resort to new quantitative restrictions where “because of a criticalbalanceͲofͲpaymentssituation,priceͲbasedmeasurescannotarrestasharpdeteriorationin theexternalpaymentsposition”(Articles2,3). PursuanttotheUnderstanding,on31January1995theWTOGeneralCouncilestablishedtheWTO Committee on BalanceͲofͲPayments Restrictions. From its inception through 2003, the Committee has conducted consultations with numerous Members concerning the existence and possible reductionandphaseͲoutoftheirbalanceͲofͲpaymentsrestrictions.Insomeinstances,withrespect for example to India and Tunisia, there was controversy within the Committee itself as to how rapidly the balanceͲofͲpayments situation of the country could reasonably permit the removal of measures. 200 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Dissatisfied with the lack of consensus on India’s use of balanceͲofͲpayments based trade restrictionstheUnitedStateschallengedIndia’scontinueduse oftraderestrictionsforbalanceͲofͲ paymentsreasonsindisputesettlement,claimingviolationsoftheGATTandtheBOPUnderstanding. A key issue here was the relationship between the mandate of the BOP Committee and the jurisdictionoftheWTOdisputesettlementorgans.Indiaarguedthat,giventheexplicitroleofthe Committee in the surveillance of the challenged measures, the dispute panel should defer to that process.ThepanelbelowfoundthatthecompetenceoftheBOPCommitteeandthatofthepanel werenotmutuallyexclusiveinthesematters.Indiaappealedthisfinding. The Appellate Body (AB) first observed that, according to Article 1.1 of the Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU), the dispute settlement procedures in the DSU apply generally to disputes broughtunderthedisputesettlementprovisionsofthecoveredagreements(inthiscaseArticleXXIII oftheGATT 1994). Moreoverone couldnotinferanylimitation ontherightsofaccesstodispute settlementundertheDSU,oronthecompetenceofpanelstointerpretandapplythebalanceͲofͲ payments provisions of the GATT, from the grant of competence to review Article XVIII:B justificationsforsuchrestrictionstotheCONTRACTINGPARTIES. India, however, had argued that GATT practice with respect to Article XXIII precluded access to dispute settlement regarding trade restrictions maintained for balanceͲofͲpayments purposes. The BOP Understanding limited the competence of the dispute settlement organs in balanceͲofͲ paymentsdisputesinfavorofthatoftheMembership,sittingastheBOPCommittee.Thedistinction thatIndiadrewwasbetweendisputesaboutthe“application”ofbalanceofpaymentsmeasuresand thosethatconcernedthesubstantivejustificationofthemeasures. TherewerealsodifferencesbetweenIndiaandtheABoverthescopeofdevelopmentpolicieswhich couldjustifyTraderestrictionsforbalanceͲofͲpaymentsreasons. India argued that under Article XVIII balanceͲofͲpayments restrictions are to be removed as the conditions to which they were addressed improve only so long as the removal was not likely to provoke the return of those conditions. Moreover under a further proviso of Article XVIII a developing country should not be required to remove balanceͲofͲpayments import restrictions, if doing so could require a change in that country’s development policies.123India’s reliance on this provisionrequiredtheABtodeterminewhatisadevelopmentpolicyandwhetherremovalbyIndia ofitsbalanceͲofͲpaymentsrestrictionswouldrequireachangeinthesepolicies. In its ruling the AB relied on a judgment of the IMF that India did not need to change its developmentpoliciesbecauseitcouldaddresstheconsequencesofremovingitsimportrestrictions through“macroeconomic”policies.However,thisrulingisquestionableonvariousgrounds. Had the AB considered development policy informed by a conception of equity that includes the notion that development policy is a matter in the first instance for participation of those who are affected,itwouldhaveanalyzedthelegalissuequitedifferently. x Firstly,theABwouldnothaveacceptedthatoneinstitution,particularlythetechnocratsin thatinstitution,have“ownership”ofthemeaningofa“development”policy. x Secondly,theABwouldnothaveembracedthestarkcontrastbetweendevelopmentpolicy andmacroeconomicpolicy.Thiscontrastimpliesthatdevelopmentpolicyisrestrictedtoa series of techniques that “experts” view as formulae for “development,” rather than 123 The following draws on Howse R (2004). Mainstreaming the Right to Development into International Trade Law and PolicyattheWorldTradeOrganization.(E/CN.4/Sub.2/2004/17),3Ͳ20.UnitedNations,Geneva. 201 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO including all those policies that people—in this case, those of India—view as affecting the fulfillmentoftheirapproachtodevelopment.Fromtheperspectiveofequity,asinformedby the social and economic rights recognized in the UN Covenant on Social, Economic and CulturalRights,macroeconomicpoliciesareclearly“developmentpolicies.” x Thirdly, on the question of whether India should be required to change its development policyinordertobeabletoremovethebalanceͲofͲpaymentsrestrictionswithoutareturn to crisis conditions, for the purposes of both equity and coherence the AB ought to have solicited the views of a broader range of institutions and social actors—at a minimum the internationalorganizationswithexpressmandatesregardingdevelopmentsuchasUNCTAD andtheUNDP. x Finally,theABmighthavetakenaccountoftheselfͲdeclaratorycharacterofArticleXVII.B, i.e.thatitempowersIndiatochartitsowncourseindevelopmentpolicy.Thisimpliesthat the provision is not intended to invite the dispute settlement organs to examine de novo India’sjudgmentthatremovaloftherestrictionswouldrequireachangeinitsdevelopment policy. D. TradeFinancingandEquity Increasing exports is recommended as part of policy packages for addressing indebtedness and balanceͲofͲpayments difficulties since, unlike macroeconomic deflation, it actually increases employment and reduces poverty. Trade financing is crucial to many export transactions. Yet the very economic conditions that export receipts are needed to address may make access to such financingdifficult,particularlyfordevelopingcountriesthathavesufferedfinancialcrises.Thisissue isbroachedinthe2005ReporttotheWTOGeneralCounciloftheWorkingGrouponTrade,Debt andFinance.124Ina1999WTOstudyFingerandShulnechtexplaintheimportanceofgovernmentͲ backed export credit agencies in trade financing as follows: “the commercial and political risk of international trade transactions is often much larger than for domestic transactions. . . . wellͲ functioningECAs[ExportCreditAgencies]areprobablyevenmoreimportantfordevelopingcountry exporters [than for industrial country exporters in developed countries]. [DevelopingͲ country exporters](andtheirbanks)areoftenrelativelysmalland,therefore,lessabletogeneratetheirown information on commercial and political risk abroad. They are also often likely to obtain less favorablefinancingtermsbecauseofmistrustbyimportersfromothercountries.”125 WTOrules,however,arenotconcernedwithfacilitatingdevelopingcountryexportsthroughexport financing, but rather with disciplining or curbing such financing to the extent it is viewed as an export subsidy. The relevant provisions are paragraphs (j) and (k) of Annex I (“Illustrative List of Export Subsidies”) to the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement). Paragraph (j) states that the following would be examples of prohibited export subsidies: “The provision by Governments (or special institutions controlled by Governments) of export credit guarantee or insurance programs, of insurance or guarantee programs against increasesinthecostofexportedproductsorofexchangeriskprograms,atpremiumrateswhichare inadequatetocoverthelongͲtermoperatingcostsandlossesoftheprograms.” 124 World Trade Organization (2005). Report of the Working Group on Trade, Debt and Finance to the General Council. (WT/WGTDF/4).10October. 125 Finger KM and Schulknecht L (1999). Trade, Finance and Financial Crises. World Trade Organization Special Studies. WorldTradeOrganization,Geneva.9Ͳ10. 202 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment Furtherexamplesaretobefoundinparagraph(k)ofAnnexI:“ThegrantbyGovernments(orspecial institutions controlled by and/or acting under the authority of Governments) of export credits at ratesbelowthosewhichtheyactuallyhavetopayforthefundssoemployed(orwouldhavetopay iftheyborrowedoninternationalcapitalmarketsinordertoobtainfundsofthesamematurityand othercredittermsanddenominatedinthesamecurrencyastheexportcredit),orthepaymentby themofallorpartofthecostsincurredbyexportersorfinancialinstitutionsinobtainingcredits,in sofarastheyareusedtosecureamaterialadvantageinthefieldofexportcreditterms”. This characterization is subject to following important exception in paragraph (k): “Provided, however, that if a Member is a party to an international undertaking on official export credits to which at least twelve original Members to this Agreement are parties as of 1 January 1979 (or a successor undertaking which has been adopted by those original Members), or if in practice a Memberappliestheinterestratesprovisionsoftherelevantundertaking,anexportcreditpractice whichisinconformitywiththoseprovisionsshallnotbeconsideredanexportsubsidyprohibitedby this Agreement.” The international undertaking referred to here is the OECD Export Credit Arrangement. By incorporating this Arrangement in paragraph (k) the WTO SCM Agreement essentiallydrawsalinebetweenprohibitedandpermissibleformsofexportfinancingbasedonan AgreementnegotiatedbyandfordevelopedcountriesinadevelopedͲcountryforum,theOECD. The benchmarks in paragraphs (j) and (k) for deciding whether or not a trade financing measure shouldbeclassifiedasanexportsubsidypresupposethematurecapitalmarketsandsophisticated riskͲspreading and allocationͲvehicles typical of fully developed economies. Whether they are also appropriatefordevelopingcountries,especiallyonesthathavehadaccesstoprivatecapitalseverely limited due to debt and/or other financial crises is questionable. The Center for International EnvironmentalLawnotesconcerningtheOECDArrangement:“TheArrangementcanbeunderstood asacartelͲlike,priceͲfixingmechanism,wherethelargestlendersofexportcreditsestablishlimits oncompetition…Itisanagreementbytherichestcountriesintheworld,andthereforeitsprovisions aretailoredfortheirneeds.”126 ImplicationsinpracticeoftheSCMAgreementcanbeillustratedbytheBrazilͲAircraftcase,where theissuewasthesaleforexportofcommuterjetssupportedbyexportcreditsbybothBraziland Brazil’scompetitorCanada. IntheBrazilͲAircraftcaseBrazilarguedthat“duetothehighlevelofriskperceivedbyinternational markets with respect to Brazilian borrowers, the cost to EMBRAER and to Brazilian financial institutionsofraisingfundstofinanceexportsofBrazilianregionalaircraftishigherthanthecostto Bombardier and Canadian financial institutions of raising funds to finance exports of Canadian regionalaircraft.BecausePROEXpaymentsmerelyoffsetinpartthathighercostoffunds,allowing export credit financing for Brazilian regional aircraft on terms that are closer to, but still less favorablethan,thoseavailableforcompetingCanadianregionalaircraft,thosepaymentsarenotin Brazil’sviewusedtosecureamaterialadvantageinthefieldofexportcreditterms.”Inotherwords, Brazilwasarguingthattheparticularfinancingbarriersfacedindevelopingcountriesshouldbeused to determine the benchmark against which an export credit is assessed to decide whether it is an unfairexportsubsidy.(Para7.21) The panel curtly and almost scornfully rejected Brazil’s approach. Most disturbingly, it suggested that Brazil’s argument that the baseline of the “marketplace” in paragraph (k) be adjusted to the circumstancesandneedsofdevelopingcountrieshadtoberejectedbecausetheparagraphwasnot 126 CenterofInternationalEnvironmentalLaw(2003).ExportCreditAgenciesandtheWorldTradeOrganization.DraftIssue Brief.November:4Ͳ5. 203 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO a provision concerning special and differential treatment (for developing countries) (Para. 7.32). Article 27 of the SCM Agreement does provide limited relaxation of WTO disciplines applying to export subsidies for developing countries. Nevertheless, the interpretative approach of the panel suggeststhat,evenwherespecialanddifferentialtreatmentexistsinaWTOAgreement,theother provisionsshouldbeinterpretedinamannerthatisblindastotheequitiesasbetweendeveloped anddevelopingcountrymembers. Article 27.1 of the SCM Agreement states a general principle much broader than the specific exceptions and limitations of Article 27.2Ͳ15: “Members recognize that subsidies may play an importantroleineconomicdevelopmentprogramsofdevelopingcountryMembers.”However,the panel tendentiously characterized Brazil’s approach to the meaning of “used to secure a material advantage” in para. (k) as a “general lowering” of SCM disciplines, which might be harmful to developingcountriesasawhole.ButonamorereasonableinterpretationBrazil’sargumentwasnot intendedtoleadtoanacrossͲtheͲboardloweringofdisciplines,butrathertotakeintoaccountthe differenceinfinancialmarketconditionsofaparticulardevelopingcountryinrelationtothoseofits developedͲcountrycompetitors.Itishardtoseehowsuchanapproachcouldbeharmfultoother developing countries, manyofwhichface muchmoreseriousstructuraldisadvantagesin termsof accesstofinancingthanBrazil. The Appellate Body compounded the indifference to developingͲcountry concerns and challenges shownbythepanel.Althoughparagraph(k)refersonlytotheOECDArrangementasa“safehaven” in terms of the disciplines of that paragraph, the Appellate Body used the benchmarks of the ArrangementastheappropriatemethodologyfordetermininginBrazil’scasewhethertheratesof interestonitsexportcreditsweresuchastoleadtotheconclusionthatthey“areusedtosecurea materialadvantage”. Intheaftermathofthisdecision,somedevelopingcountrieshavejustifiablyputparagraph(k)ofthe SCMAgreementontheagendaofthepresentDohaRoundofnegotiations.127 E. TheGeneralAgreementonTradeandServices(GATS),Balanceof Payments,andDebtSustainability The regulation of banks and other financial institutions is critical to management of debt and financial crises, especially from an equity perspective. The collapse of financial intermediaries can destroythesavingsandjobsofordinarycitizens.Thus,theWTOhasaspecialsetofrulesthatapply toliberalizationoffinancialserviceswithinthegeneralcontextofGATS. Before considering these special rules, it is important to understand the provisions of the general WTOframeworkforservicesliberalization,theGATS,whichmayapplytothemanagementofdebt and financial crises. The GATS applies to trade in services through four modes: (1) crossͲborder delivery; (2) presenceoftheconsumerinthe territoryofthevendor(e.g. tourism,education,and health care); (3) commercial presence of the vendor in the consumer state; and (4) crossͲborder movement of workers engaged in providing services. Certain obligations in the GATS apply to all services trade in these four modes. There are also general exceptions, including in relation to balanceͲofͲpayments measures (which are examined below). Many of the most important obligationsinGATS,suchastherulesapplyingtothegrantingofMarketAccesstoforeignsuppliers 127 CIEL,supra.n.20. 204 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment andaccordingthemtheNational(i.e.nonͲdiscriminatory)Treatmentobligationapplyonlywherea specifiedservicesectorislistedinaWTOMember’sscheduleofspecificcommitments. Article XI:1 of GATS creates a general rule that “a Member shall not apply restrictions on international transfers and payments” applicable to sectors where a Member has made specific commitmentsArticleXI:2states:“NothinginthisAgreementshallaffecttherightsandobligationsof the Members of the International Monetary Fund under the Articles of Agreement of the Fund, including the use of exchange actions which are in conformity with the Articles of Agreement, providedthataMembershallnotimposerestrictionsonanycapitaltransactionsinconsistentlywith its specific commitments regarding such transactions, except under Article XII [of GATS] or at the requestoftheFund.” ThelanguageofXI:2indicatesanextremelyimportantdifferencebetweenGATTandGATS.However narrowlyorrestrictivelyinterpreted,therelevantprovisionsoftheGATT,aswehaveseen,contain only disciplines on currentͲaccount measures. However, under the GATS a Member’s specific commitmentsmaypreventitfrominstitutingcapitalͲaccountcontrols.Tounderstandtheflexibility undertheGATSwithregardtocapitalcontrolsitisthereforenecessarytolookcarefullyatArticleXII, the balanceͲofͲpayments exception. This exception can only be utilized after satisfying a very complexandlongseriesofconditions.ThiscanbeillustratedfromthetextofArticleXIIisasfollows: ArticleXII:RestrictionstoSafeguardtheBalanceofPayments 1. In the event of serious balanceͲofͲpayments and external financial difficulties or threat thereof, a Member may adopt or maintain restrictions on trade in services on which it has undertakenspecificcommitments,includingonpaymentsortransfersfortransactionsrelatedto such commitments. It is recognized that particular pressures on the balance of payments of a Memberintheprocessofeconomicdevelopmentoreconomictransitionmaynecessitatetheuse ofrestrictionstoensure,interalia,themaintenanceofaleveloffinancialreservesadequatefor theimplementationofitsprogramofeconomicdevelopmentoreconomictransition. 2. Therestrictionsreferredtoinparagraph1: (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) shallnotdiscriminateamongMembers; shall be consistent with the Articles of Agreement of the International MonetaryFund; shallavoidunnecessarydamagetothecommercial,economicandfinancial interestsofanyotherMember; shallnotexceedthosenecessarytodealwiththecircumstancesdescribedin paragraph1; shallbetemporaryandbephasedoutprogressivelyasthesituationspecified inimproves. 3. In determining the incidence of such restrictions, Members may give priority to the supply of services which are more essential to their economic or development programs. However, such restrictions shall not be adopted or maintained for the purpose of protecting a particularservicesector. 4. Anyrestrictionsadoptedormaintainedunderparagraph1,oranychangestherein,shall bepromptlynotifiedtotheGeneralCouncil. 205 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO 5. (a) Members applying the provisions of this Article shall consult promptly with the CommitteeonBalanceͲofͲPaymentsRestrictionsonrestrictionsadoptedunderthisArticle. (b) TheMinisterialConferenceshallestablishprocedures128forperiodic consultations withtheobjectiveofenablingsuchrecommendationstobemadetotheMemberconcernedasit maydeemappropriate. (c) Such consultations shall assess the balanceͲofͲpayment situation of the Member concerned and the restrictions adopted or maintained under this Article, taking into account, interalia,suchfactorsas: i) the nature and extent of the balanceͲofͲpayments and the external financial; ii) difficulties; iii) the external economic and trading environment of the consulting Member; iv) alternativecorrectivemeasureswhichmaybeavailable. (d) Theconsultationsshalladdressthecomplianceofanyrestrictionswithparagraph2, inparticulartheprogressivephaseoutofrestrictionsinaccordancewithparagraph2(e). (e) In such consultations, all findings of statistical and other facts presented by the International Monetary Fund relating to foreign exchange, monetary reserves and balance of payments,shallbeacceptedandconclusionsshallbebasedontheassessmentbytheFundofthe balanceͲofpaymentsandtheexternalfinancialsituationoftheconsultingMember. 6. IfaMemberwhichisnotamemberoftheInternationalMonetaryFundwishestoapply the provisionsofthisArticle,the MinisterialConferenceshallestablishareviewprocedureand anyotherproceduresnecessary. AnumberoffeaturesofArticleXIIareworthyofspecialattention. x First of all, XII:1 gives developing or transitional economies a clear right to take measures thatprovidealeveloffinancialreserves“adequate”fortheMember’sprogramofeconomic transition or development. Thus, Article XII:1 affirms that development goals are the legitimatebasisforaWTOMemberdeterminingthekindsofbalanceofpaymentsmeasures itneeds. x Whereasthemeasuresmust“notexceedthosenecessary”todealwith“seriousbalanceͲofͲ payments and external financial difficulties or threat thereof,” Article XII:3 affirms that a Member “may give priority to the supply of services which are more essential to their economicordevelopmentprograms.” x Moregenerally,theconceptof“necessity”oughttobeinterpretedinthecontextofArticle XII as a whole, which gives considerable emphasis to an individual Member’s approach to development. Article XII can be read as not requiring a Member to use alternative policy measures, even if these are less restrictive of services trade, where such measures would underminetheconceptofequityimplicitorexplicitintheMember’sdevelopmentprogram. 128 Itisunderstoodthattheproceduresunderparagraph5shallbethesameastheGATT1994procedure. 206 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment UnliketheprovisionsoftheGATT,ArticleXIIoftheGATSspecifiesthatdeferencetotheIMFextends only to statistics and facts and conclusions drawn from such statistics and facts. Therefore, a judgmentabouttheconsistencyofmeasureswiththeIMFArticlesmaybemadeindependentlyat theWTO. ArticleXIIenvisagesconsultationsonbalanceͲofͲpaymentsmeasuresintheCommitteeonBalance of Payments Restrictions. However, according to the logic of the IndiaͲBalance of Payments case discussedabove,sincetheGATSprovidesnoexceptionfromdisputesettlementforArticlesXIand XIIoftheGATS,theexistenceoftheCommitteeonBalanceͲofͲPaymentswouldnotleadtoremoval orrestrictionofpanelandABjurisdiction. ItisimportanttoappreciatetheextenttowhichGATSspecificcommitmentsmayimplylimitstothe ability to impose capital account controls. Footnote 8 of Article XVI:1 reads: “If a Member undertakesamarketͲaccesscommitmentinrelationtothesupplyofaservicethrough[mode1]and if the crossͲborder movement of capital is an essential part of the service itself, that Member is thereby committed to allow such movement of capital. If a Member undertakes a marketͲaccess commitmentinrelationtothesupplyofaservicethrough[mode3],itistherebycommittedtoallow relatedtransfersofcapitalintoitsterritory.”Situationswhere“movementofcapitalisanessential part of the service itself” would apply most obviously to certain kinds of financial services (for example,mutualfunds),buttheotherkindofsituationmentionedinFootnote8ismuchbroader, applyingtoallcaseswheretheserviceisbeingsuppliedthroughacommercialpresenceintheWTO Member. Nevertheless, in such circumstances, the requirement of liberalization seems limited to inwardmovementofcapital. Some kinds of controls over (outbound) capital might be viewed as conditions on who can supply services(numberofservicesuppliers)inviolationofXVI:2(a),oras“limitationsonthetotalvalueof servicetransactionsorassets”inviolationofXVI:2(b)or“totalnumberofserviceoperationsorthe total quantity of service output” in violation of XVI:2(c). This possibility would follow from an extremelybroadinterpretationofXVI:2(a)and(c)bytheABintheUSͲGamblingcase.Essentially,the ABsuggestedthattoviolateeitherprovision,measuresneednottaketheexplicitformsdescribedin thoseprovisions,providedthattheyhavecomparableeffectsonrestrictingmarketaccessandare quantitative in nature (Report of the Appellate Body, paras. 232, 247). Since capital controls are clearly measures that are quantitative in nature, they may well have effects on the number of servicesuppliersorthetotalvalueofservicestransactionsorassetsunderArticleXVI. Commitments with respect to financial services are governed by the Annex on Financial Services. TheAnnexcontainsthefollowingprovision: DomesticRegulation (a) Notwithstanding any other provisions of the Agreement, a Member shall not be preventedfromtakingmeasuresforprudentialreasons,includingfortheprotectionof investors,depositors,policyholdersorpersonstowhomafiduciarydutyisowedbya financialservicesupplier,ortoensuretheintegrityandstabilityofthefinancialsystem. WheresuchmeasuresdonotconformwiththeprovisionsoftheAgreement,theyshall not be used as a means of avoiding the Member’s commitments or obligations under theAgreement. The first sentence of this provision appears to allow any measure “to ensure the integrity and stabilityofthefinancialsystem”withouttheneedtoshowthatthemeasureisnecessaryortheleast restrictive of trade in services. The second sentence, however, seems drafted in a manner to 207 PursuingSustainableDevelopmentStrategies:TheCaseoftheBalanceofPaymentRulesinWTO underminetheregulatoryflexibilitygrantedinthefirstsentence,inthatitqualifiestheuseofthe provision as an exception to GATS commitments and obligations. Thus, where a measure is not in conformitywithGATS,it“shallnotbeusedasameansofavoidingtheMember’scommitmentsor obligationsundertheAgreement.” Itisdifficulttodiscerntheexactimplicationofthisqualifyingorconditionallanguage.Onepossible reading would be that it imports an intent requirement into 2(a), namely the notion that the measuresmustbegenuinelyintendedto“ensuretheintegrityandstabilityofthefinancialsystem” ratherthantoprotectdomesticfinancialindustries.Suchanintentrequirementmightbedifficultto applyinthecaseofafinancialcrisis,whereensuringthesurvivalofdomesticfinancialinstitutions maywellbepartandparcelofensuringthe“integrityandstabilityofthefinancialsystem”itself. Finally,anycommitmentorobligationunderGATSissubjecttothegeneralexceptionsinArticleXIV ofGATS.Thus,whetherornotaMember’smeasuremeetsthecriteriasetforthinArticleXIIofthe GATS or the Annex on Financial services, the measure may still be justified if “necessary” for the protection of human life or health or of public moral or public order. According to footnote 5 of ArticleXII,Thepublicorderexceptionmaybeinvoked“onlywhereagenuineandsufficientlyserious threatisposedtooneofthefundamentalinterestsofsociety.”Inthiscontextitisnoteworthythat intheUnitedStatesͲGamblingcasetheABupheldthepanelapproachthatsuggestedtheremustbe somedeferencetoaWTOMember’sowndeterminationofthemeaningofpublicmoralsandpublic order(AppellateBodyReport,paras.296Ͳ297). AsageneralmatterotherpoliciessuchasexchangeͲratestabilization,depreciationorappreciation undertakeninresponsetoafinancialcrisismaybeunsustainableintheabsenceofcapitalcontrols. Experience with applicable parts of the GATS will thus eventually play a role in determining the rangeofmacroeconomicpolicyresponses. 208 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment F. Conclusions WTO rules on exchange actions and the balanceͲofͲpayments justifications for trade restrictions clearlyreflectaconceptionofequitythattakesintoaccounttheparticularneedsandsituationsof developing countries. In certain, carefully defined matters the WTO rules entail deference to judgmentsoftheIMF. However,inactualdisputesettlementelementsintherulesthatreflectequitytowardsdeveloping countrieshavebeenminimizedorignored.Moreover,thedisputesettlementorganshavegonewell beyondtheexplicitlimitsofdeferencetotheIMF,deferringsuchtotheIMFeveninsuchamatteras the meaning of a country’s “development policy” (the IndiaͲBalance of Payments case). Since developing countries have limited representation and voice in the IMF, from the perspective of equityasparticipationindecisionͲmakingconcerningdevelopmentthesetendenciesofthedispute settlementorgansseemdifficulttojustify. More generally, the concept of coherence reflected in relevant WTO instruments and activities directed towards balanceͲofͲpayments and exchange matters is too narrowly focused on relations between the IMF and the WTO, and does not include cooperation with other international institutionsconcernedwithequityindevelopment.Theconceptofcoherenceshouldberevisedto accommodate the relationship with equity implied in the Millennium Declaration and related instruments. Moreover even within the narrow conception of coherence embraced in the WTO, the agreed mechanism for avoiding crossͲconditionalities, namely obligatory consultations between the WTO SecretariatandtheIMFpriortoeithertakingdecisionsthatcouldresultincrossͲconditionalities,has not been closely followed. A review should be undertaken of the justification for not using this process and of the extent to which avoidance of crossͲconditionalities has been achieved in experiencesofar. InthecaseoftheGeneralAgreementonTradeinServices(GATS),thereisarealpossibilitythata WTO Member’s specific commitments combined with the general obligations of the GATS could meanthataMember’sadoptionofcapitalcontrolsconstitutesaGATSviolation,eventhoughsuch controls may be necessary to address a financial crisis in a manner consistent with social and economic justice. In view of the exceptions and limitations in the GATS that could none the less justifysuchmeasuresthereisacaseforthedrawingupofguidelinesinthisareawhichtakeaccount ofequityinthetradeandfinancialsystemintheinterpretationofsuchlimitsandexceptions.This task should be undertaken by international institutions with a mandate related to equity in development. As exemplified by the BrazilͲAircraft case, the rules on export subsidies in the SCM Agreement appear to limit the capacity of developing countries to provide support for export transactions through export credits. This reflects the use of market benchmarks devised for and by developed countries in the OECD Arrangement for the assessment of export credit arrangements. Considerationshouldbegiventoanalternativeapproachwhichwouldtakeintoaccountstructural differences between the financial markets of developed and developing countries as well as the specialchallengesregardingaccesstocapitalmarketsforexportfinancingfacingcountriesthathave facedfinancialordebtcrises. 209 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment CHAPTERX RISKASSOCIATEDWITHTRENDSINTHE TREATMENTOFSOVEREIGNDEBTINBILATERAL TRADEANDINVESTMENTTREATIES AldoCaliari (CenterofConcern) A. Introduction ThereisagrowingtrendinFreeTradeAgreementsfortheinclusionofprovisionsthatsubjectpolicy towardsthefinancialsectortolegaldisciplinesenshrinedintradeandinvestmentagreementsand totheassociateddisputeͲsettlementmechanisms.Thistrendplaceslimitsontheusebydeveloping countries of several tools designed to build and preserve stable and healthy financial sectors responsive to national development priorities and supportive of trade. The limits are capable of increasingdevelopingcountries’vulnerabilitytofinancialanddebtcrises. B. SovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties In bilateral Free Trade Agreements recently negotiated by the United States Government a controversialissuehasbeentheinsistenceoftheUnitedStatesonpursuinginclusionofclausesthat wouldapplytosovereigndebtissuedbythepartiesprinciplessuchasNationalTreatmentandMostͲ FavoredͲNation(MFN)TreatmentwhicharepartofbilateralinvestmenttreatiesandofGATT/WTO rulesfortradeingoodsandservices. A review of some recent treaties reveals at least two different approaches to the treatment of sovereigndebt. 211 RiskAssociatedwithTrendsintheTreatmentofSovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties 1. SovereignDebtExplicitlyExcludedfromApplicationofthePrinciples UnderNAFTA,investmentcoversasweepingarrayoftypesofownershipinterests,includingloans and securities. However, in conformity with Article 1416 in the section on Financial Services, “investment means “investment” as defined in Article 1139 (Investment Definitions), except that, withrespectto“loans”and“debtsecurities”referredtointhatArticle:(a)aloantoordebtsecurity issuedbyafinancialinstitutionisaninvestmentonlywhereitistreatedasregulatorycapitalbythe Partyinwhoseterritorythefinancialinstitutionislocated;and(b)aloangrantedbyordebtsecurity owned by a financial institution, other than a loan to or debt security of a financial institution referredtoinsubparagraph(a),isnotaninvestment;” Tothisisaddedthefollowing:“forgreatercertainty:(c)aloanto,ordebtsecurityissuedby,aParty orastateenterprisethereofisnotaninvestment”(author’sitalics). Therefore,underNAFTA,sovereigndebtsareexplicitlyexcludedfromthedefinitionofinvestment. 2. SovereignDebtExplicitlyIncludedwithintheScopeofApplicationofInvestment Principles In the 2003 United StatesͲChile Free Trade Agreement (FTA) specific principles on investment are explicitly applicable to sovereign debt. The United StatesͲChile FTA contains a broad definition of investmentbasedonthefollowingstandardadoptedbytheUnitedStatesinitsmostrecentBilateral InvestmentTreaty(BIT)Model.129 “Investmentmeanseveryassetthataninvestorownsorcontrols,directlyorindirectly,thathasthe characteristicsofaninvestment,includingsuchcharacteristicsasthecommitmentofcapitalorother resources,theexpectationofgainorprofit,ortheassumptionofrisk.Formsthataninvestmentmay takeinclude: x x x x x x x x Anenterprise; Shares,stock,andotherformsofequityparticipationinanenterprise; Bonds,debentures,loans,andotherdebtinstruments; Futures,options,andotherderivatives; Rights under contract, including turnkey, construction, management, production, concession,orrevenueͲsharingcontracts; Intellectualpropertyrights; Rights conferred pursuant to domestic law, such as concessions, licenses, authorizations, andpermits;and Other tangible or intangible, movable or immovable property, and related property rights, such as leases, mortgages, liens, and pledges; but investment does not mean an order or judgmententeredinajudicialoradministrativeaction…” Thisdefinitiongenerallyincludes“bonds,debentures,loansandotherdebtinstruments”.130Inwhat represents a significant departure from NAFTA, the treaty explicitly makes the agreement’s 129 ThisdefinitionhasbecomestandardblueprintfortheUSnegotiatingpositionintreaties.SeeUnitedStates2004Model BIT,Art.1 130 Usuallywithafootnotethatclarifies“Someformsofdebt,suchasbonds,debentures,andlongͲtermnotes,aremore likely to have the characteristics of an investment, while other forms of debt, such as claims to payment that are immediatelydueandresultfromthesaleofgoodsorservices,areleslikelytohavesuchcharacteristics.” 212 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment provisions applicable to sovereign debts issued by the Chilean Government.131The same rules are contained in the Central America Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA).132Thus, the United StatesͲChile FTAandCAFTAmakeNationalTreatmentandMFNTreatmentapplicabletosovereigndebtsissued bytheGovernmentsofthecountriesinvolved. 3. The“Elliptic”InclusionofDebtintheUnitedStatesͲUruguayFTA TheUnitedStatesͲUruguayFTA(signedin2004)raisesaninterestingquestionbecauseitsprovisions could lead to reͲinterpretation of previous treaties. The FTA contains the standard definition of investment as including “Bond, debentures, other debt instruments and loans” It also contains, in AnnexF,aclausewithlanguagesimilartothefirstpartoftheNAFTAarticleabove.133 Uptothispointofthetext,althoughthereisnoexplicitexclusionasintheNAFTAsupplementary clause, the agreement seems to imply that sovereign debt is excluded from the definition of investment. However,thisdoesnotappear tobe the case.Annex Gofthe UnitedStatesͲUruguayFTAheaded “SovereignDebt”,readsasfollows: “1.NoclaimthatarestructuringofadebtinstrumentissuedbyUruguaybreaches an obligation under Articles 5 through 10 may be submitted to, or if already submitted continue in, arbitration under Section B, if the restructuring is a negotiated restructuring at the time of submission, or becomes a negotiated restructuringaftersuchsubmission.” Thiswouldappeartomeanthatsovereigndebtis,indeed,includedinthescopeofthedefinitionof investmentforthepurposesoftheTreaty.Italsowouldopenthewayfortheinterpretationthat, absent an explicit exclusion, sovereign debt is considered to fit into the scope of the definition of investment.Thiscouldhavetheconsequenceofleadingtoanexpansionofthescopeoftheterm, “investment”, in treaties worded similarly to the United StatesͲUruguay FTA, such as the United StatesͲSingaporeFTA. C. ImplicationsforSovereignDebtProblemsofIncludingNationalTreatment andMFNTreatmentinFTAs WhatarethepossibleimplicationsofapplyingNationalTreatmentandMFNTreatmenttosovereign debt? 131 SeeAnnex10ͲB(Annextothechapterofthetreatythatdealswithinvestment):“ThereschedulingofthedebtsofChile, orofitsappropriateinstitutionsownedorcontrolledthroughownershipinterestsbyChile,owedtotheUnitedStatesand thereschedulingofitsdebtsowedtocreditorsingeneralarenotsubjecttoanyprovisionofSectionAotherthanArticles 10.2and10.3”Articles10.2and10.3intheTreatyrefertoNationalTreatmentandMostͲFavoredͲNationTreatment. 132 SeealsoUgarteche(2004,14Ͳ18and34Ͳ35). 133 Art.4reads: “(b)Investmentmeans“investment”asdefinedinArticle1,exceptthat,withrespectto“loans”and“debtinstruments” referredtointhatArticle:(i)aloantoordebtinstrumentissuedbyafinancialinstitutionisaninvestmentinafinancial institutiononlywhereitistreatedasregulatorycapitalbythePartyinwhoseterritorythefinancialinstitutionislocated; and(ii)aloangrantedbyordebtinstrumentownedbyafinancialinstitution,otherthanaloantoordebtinstrumentofa financialinstitutionreferredtoinsubparagraph(b)(i),isnotaninvestmentinafinancialinstitution”. 213 RiskAssociatedwithTrendsintheTreatmentofSovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties These principles were originally developed in different historical contexts. National Treatment featured from the first half of the twentieth century onwards in treaties of friendship, commerce andnavigation(FCNtreaties),i.e.bilateraltreatiescoveringmiscellaneoussubjectssuchasaccessto ports,tariffs,thepowersandresponsibilitiesofconsuls,andprotectionagainstappropriation.The lastoftheseheadingstypicallyincludedprovisionsconcerningnationaltreatment,i.e.guaranteesof nonͲdiscriminatory treatment of foreign firms. MFN clauses were included in reciprocal trade agreementsnegotiatedbetweentheUnitedStatesandvariouscountriesunderaprogramlegislated in 1934. Under the MFN clauses included in these agreements each of the parties bound itself to extendtotheothertariffconcessionsatleastasgreatasthoseextendedtothemostfavorednation with which it traded. Both National Treatment and MFN Treatment were included in the GATT as principlesapplyingtotradeingoods. The extension of National Treatment and MFN Treatment to other subjects is neither straightforward nor uncontroversial.134Indeed, their extension to sovereign debt raises issues that could be more harmful to developing countries than those considered under their traditional applicationtoforeigninvestment.Adiscussionofanumberoftheseissuesfollows: 1. DismantlingToolsNeededfortheRecoveryoftheLocalEconomyinPostͲCrisis Situations The application of National Treatment to sovereign debt would restrict the ability of the debtor Government to take certain policy measures aimed at the recovery of the local economy in the aftermath of financial crises. National Treatment in this context means that foreign creditors are offeredtreatmentindebtrestructuringsnolessfavorablethanthatofferedtodomesticcreditors.135 However,thereareseveralreasonswhyacountryrestructuringitssovereigndebtafterafinancial crisismightneedtoresorttoofferingpreferentialconditionstodomesticcreditors. x In a financial crisis, domestic creditors often suffer a double adjustment. First, they are typically forced to accept a “haircut” on their claims, which means that the value of their loansarereducedbyacertainpercentage.Secondly,theyoftensuffercostsrelatedtothe internaladjustment,suchashighinterestrates.Infact,theimpactofdebtrestructuringon domesticcapitalmarketsand,inturn,ontheresumptionofgrowthandrepaymentcapacity needs to be taken into account in assessing the consequences of debt crises (Machinea, 2004:188)..” x Dealing with domestic before foreign debt might also allow the Government to return rapidlytodomesticcapitalmarketsduringwhatislikelytobeasustainedinterruptioninits accesstointernationalcapitalmarkets(IMF,2002:13). x The debtor may also need to accord priority to domestic debt in order to protect the financialsystem.TheIMFhassaidthat“therestructuringofcertaintypesofdomesticdebt may have major implications for economic performance, as a result of its impact on the financialsystemandtheoperationofdomesticcapitalmarkets”(IMF,2002:13).Sovereign debt restructuring typically has a double impact on the financial system. On the one hand 134 SeeKhor(2002),whostates:“ItiscertainlynotclearthattheprinciplesoftheWTO(includingNationalTreatmentand MostͲFavoredͲNationtreatment)thatapplytotradeingoodsshouldapplytoinvestment,northat,ifapplied,theywould benefitdevelopingcountries.”SeealsoChangandGreen(2003),ActionAid(2003),OxfamInternational(2003). 135 ThisisimportantinthecontextofthedevelopingcountrysignatoriesofCAFTA,since,withtheexceptionofHonduras, animportantshareofpublicdebtinallthesecountriesisowedtodomesticcreditors.Insomeofthem,likeCostaRica, domesticdebtisactuallyhigherthanexternaldebt. 214 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment financialinstitutionsareweakenedbytheimpactontheircapitallevelsofthereductionin the value of bonds. On the other hand, debt restructuring is associated with a general increase in uncertainty, which can inflict widespread damage on the creditworthiness of firms (Machinea, 2004: 188Ͳ189). Thus, in such cases special treatment to domestic debt mayenablethedebtortoprotect“acoreofthebankingsystembyensuringtheavailability ofassetsrequiredforbankstomanagecapital,liquidityandexposuretomarketrisks”(IMF, 2002:13). x Asovereigndebtormayalsoneedtoaccordspecialtreatmenttodomesticdebtorsforthe samereasonsthatcanleadittoaccordspecialtreatmenttonationalsectorsandindustries aspartofanationaldevelopmentstrategyandtheachievementofdevelopmentgoals. x In the IMF’s view sheltering domestic investors from the full impact of debt restructuring maybenecessaryinorderto“garnersupportforanambitiousadjustmentprogram”(IMF, 2002:13). 2. PreventingtheStatefromPayingSalariesandPensionsinDebtCrises TheapplicationofNationalTreatmenttosovereigndebtmeansthattheGovernmentwillbeunable toprioritizedomesticdebtassociatedwithmeetingwages,salariesandpensionobligations.Inother words, the Government is bound to treat these debts in the same way as foreign debts held by transnationalbanksandinstitutionalinvestors.Ifitsresourcesareenoughtocoveronlyaportionof its debts, the state will not be able to choose to direct those funds to meeting these priorities, at leastnotaslongasitdoesnotdevoteequalamountforpaymentstoforeigncreditors. Unlikeanindebtedprivatecompany,anindebtedsovereignhashumanͲrightsobligationsandsocial responsibilitiestowardsitspeople.Thismeansthat,indealingwithsovereigndebt,thereareissues that cannot be addressed by strict analogies with bankruptcy principles applicable to the private sector.ThusproposalsofcivilsocietyforarulesͲbasedframeworkhavetypicallycalledforrecourse toanalogieswithframeworkswhichaccommodatetheoverallmissionthatthestateisexpectedto fulfill. Such frameworks include Chapter 9 of United States Bankruptcy Law applicable to municipalities. Even the IMF’s muchͲcriticized Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism proposal excluded“Wages,salariesandpensions”fromitsapplication(IMF,2003:24). 3. ReducingtheLeverageofDebtorsinaDebtRestructuring ByfirstgatheringthesupportofdomesticcreditorsaGovernmentcanacquiresubstantialcloutfor thenegotiationsoverdebtrestructuringwithothercreditors.Theofferofpreferentialconditionsto thesedomesticcreditorscanbecriticalinthiscontext.ThusiftheprincipleofNationalTreatmentis applied to sovereign debt, this avenue for the indebted country to strengthen its negotiating positioniseffectivelyforeclosed. TheofferofpreferentialconditionstodomesticcreditorswascrucialtoenhancingtheGovernment’s leverageinArgentina’snegotiationswithitscreditorsafteritsDecember2001default.InSeptember 2003theGovernmentreleaseditsinitialproposedconditionsfordebtrestructuring,whichincluded a 75ͲperͲcent haircut for bond holders. The Government contended that this was the size of the reduction that would enable it to recover sustainable economic growth, while ensuring that its promisesofpaymentwerekept.SomegroupsofbondͲholdersquicklyrejectedthisoffer,claiming thatitwaswoefullyinsufficientand,inthelightofthecountry’smostrecentgrowthfigures,below thecapacityofthecountrytorepay.ThecreditorsalsostronglylobbiedtheG7which,directlyand 215 RiskAssociatedwithTrendsintheTreatmentofSovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties through the IMF, put pressure on Argentina to improve its offer.136With pressure mounting from thesequarters,ArgentinaturnedtodomesticpensionfundswithanofferofinflationͲlinkedbonds thatrepresentedanimprovementovertheoffermadetotheotherbondholders.Bythusgranting these institutions preferential conditions, Argentina was able to reach agreement with creditors holdingmorethan17percentofitstotaldebt.Thiswasacriticalfirststepingarneringthesupport of a majority of creditors that eventually totaled 76 per cent. However, the offer of preferential treatmenttodomesticpensionfundswouldnothavebeencompatiblewiththeprincipleofNational Treatment. 4. CreationofaPrivilegefortheDebtOwned(orAcquired)byCreditorsfromthe Party ApplicationofNationalandMFNTreatmentonlytocreditorsofcountriesthatarepartiestobilateral investmenttreaties(whichhaveinrecentyearslargelyreplacedtheFCNtreatiesmentionedearlier) would have the discriminatory result of granting seniority to creditors from such countries over thosefromother countries.Thiswouldaffect therightsofbondͲholdersfromnonͲparty countries without their consent since they are, by definition, excluded from intervening in the negotiations under the bilateral agreement. For these bondͲholders such treatment might be equated to an involuntarydebtswapunderwhichtheyfindthemselvesholdingadowngradedinstrument. D. InvestorͲStateLawsuitsandSovereignDebt OneeffectofapplyingtheprinciplesofinvestmenttreatiestosovereigndebtisthatGovernments that violate investor protections can face expensive lawsuits. As under NAFTA and numerous bilateral investment treaties, CAFTA grants private foreign investors the right to bypass domestic courtsandsueGovernmentsininternationaltribunals(Peterson,2004:3). Such“investorͲstatelawsuits”arehighlycontroversialforanumberofreasons(Peterson,2004and 2004a). Many arbitration tribunals operate with a lack of transparency, having no obligation to disclose relevant documents or allow any form of public participation. The system for choosing arbitrators has also drawn criticism as the arbitrators can be drawn from the ranks of practicing investment lawyers and there is no obligation to appoint arbitors who will be independent in the senseofnothavingastakeinhowthetreatyisinterpreted. Moreover,arbitraltribunalsdonothavetopayregardtolegalprecedents(Peterson,2004:6).This feature, which creates a lot of uncertainty in the investment arena, could become particularly troublesomewhenappliedtosovereigndebtcrises.Indeed,themainrationaleformoresystematic arrangements for handling sovereign debt defaults has been the need to provide greater predictability for both debtors and creditors in the messy process of exiting sovereign debt crises. Clearly,theexistingsystemofarbitrationtribunalswoulddoapoorjobataddressingthoseconcerns andwouldinjectadditionaluncertaintyintoexistingarrangementsforthefollowingreasons: 136 InitsIMFagreementtheArgentinegovernmenthadpromisedto“negotiateingoodfaith”andwassingledoutinsome G7statementsasnotcomplyingwithsuchapledge.Privatecreditorsmaintainedthatnegotiationsingoodfaithrequired theagreementof80percentofcreditors,whilethegovernmentofArgentinaclaimedthatafigureabove65Ͳ70percent would suffice. It was incongruous that the IMF and G7 countries, which were themselves amongst the creditors, should haveunilaterallyattemptedtodefinetheconditionsofanacceptabledebtrestructuring. 216 CompendiumonDebtSustainabilityandDevelopment x The application of the principles of National Treatment and MFN to sovereign debt might givethesearbitraltribunalstheauthoritytodefinedifficultquestionsthatarguablybelong tothedomesticjurisdictionofstates. x The application of these principles might also open the way for the application of other more general principles that are becoming common in investment treaties, such as “minimumstandardoftreatment”or“fairtreatment.Asillustratedaboveinthediscussion ofArgentina’sdebtrenegotiation,thereisnorulesͲbasedframeworktodeterminewhatis an“acceptable”levelofrepaymentor“negotiationingoodfaith”,etc.indebtnegotiations andrestructurings.Noristhereanycertaintythatprinciplesorrulesoriginallyformulatedin thecontextofbankruptcylawwillbeappliedbyanarbitrationtribunal. x These general principles are contentious even in the context of investment treaties. That minimum or fair standards of treatment apply only to investors, while considerations involving workers and other human rights as well as the environment, which might counterbalancethem,arenotgivenequalweightisasourceofcontroversy. x CloselyrelatedtopointsraisedinsectionC.2isthepointthatapplicationofthesegeneral principlestosovereigndebtwouldnottakeaccountoftheresponsibilityoftheGovernment ofthedebtorcountrytoitspopulation. E. ConcludingRemarks The existing regime for dealing with sovereign debt crises lacks a rulesͲbased, multilateral framework.Thisleavesdebtorsvulnerabletopowerasymmetriesascomparedwithcreditors.These asymmetries would be reinforced by extension of the definition of the investment instruments coveredinbilateralinvestmenttreatiestoincludeallormostdebtinstruments,particularlythosefor sovereigndebt.Therehavealreadybeenmovestowardsamoreinclusivedefinitionofinvestmentin somerecenttreaties.Thishastheconsequencethatdebtinstrumentsaresubjecttoprinciplessuch as National Treatment and MFN Treatment which were originally developed to handle problems arisingunderbilateralinvestmenttreatiesandgoodstradeundertheGATT,andnotdebtcrises.A notableexceptiontotherecenttendencyforextendingsuchprinciplestodebtistheNAFTA,which explicitly excludes sovereign debt from the definition of investment. In view of the dangers to developing countries from the extension of principles designed for foreign investment and goods tradetodebtinstruments,theNAFTAapproachfurnishesasuperiormodelforthefuture. 217 RiskAssociatedwithTrendsintheTreatmentofSovereignDebtinBilateralTradeandInvestmentTreaties References ActionAid(2003).UnlimitedCompanies.TheDevelopmentalImpactsofanInvestmentAgreement attheWTO.UnitedKingdom,June. ChangHJandGreenD(2003).TheNorthernWTOAgendaonInvestment:DoasWeSay,NotasWe Did.Geneva,SouthCentreandCAFOD,June. Correa C (1999). Key Issues for Developing Countries in a Possible Multilateral Agreement on Investment.In:InternationalMonetaryandFinancialIssuesforthe1990s,5.NewYorkand Geneva,UnitedNations. IMF (2003). Proposed Features of a Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism. Washington DC, 12 February. IMF(2003a).IMFDiscussesPossibleFeaturesofaSovereignDebtRestructuringMechanism.Public InformationNotice,03(06).WashingtonDC,7January. IMF (2002). Sovereign Debt Restructuring MechanismͲFurther Considerations. Prepared by the InternationalCapitalMarkets.WashingtonDC,14August. IMF (2002a). The Design of the Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism. Washington DC, 27 November. IMF (2002b). IMF Board Discusses Possible Features of a New Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism.PublicInformationNotice,02(106).WashingtonDC,24September. Khor(2002).TheWTO,thePostͲDohaAgendaandtheFutureoftheTradeSystem:ADevelopment Perspective.ThirdWorldNetwork.Malaysia,May. Machinea JL (2004). Reestructuración de la deuda: nuevas propuestas para viejos problemas. In: Gobernabilidadeintegraciónfinanciera:ámbitoglobalyregional.SantiagodeChile,ECLAC. OxfamInternational(2003).TheEmperor’sNewClothes.BriefingPaper,46,April. Peterson LE (2004). Bilateral Investment Treaties and Development PolicyͲMaking. International InstituteforSustainableDevelopment,Winnipeg. Peterson LE (2004a). UK Bilateral Investment Treaty Programme and Sustainable Development. ImplicationsofBilateralNegotiationsonInvestmentRegulationataTimewhenMultilateral TalksareFaltering.London,TheRoyalInstituteofForeignAffairs,February. UgartecheO(2004).VeinteAñosDespués...LaDeudadelosPaísesAndinos.Lima,ProgramaLaboral deDesarrollo,September. 218