Market-Oriented Initiatives in Health Care: What Have We Learned? Academy Health June 3, 2007 Professor James C. Robinson University of California, Berkeley OVERVIEW Goals: equity, efficiency, innovation Tradeoffs among goals Performance: biotechnology Performance: insurance Conclusions Principles of Evaluating Market (and non-market) Initiatives Apples to apples Compare real market initiatives to real governmental initiatives – Not real markets and idealized governmental initiatives – Not real governmental and idealized market initiatives A favorite tactic on the political left A favorite tactic on the political right Market failure and government failure More Principles Be clear on the goals or standards against which performance is being evaluated – Markets tend to be good at some tasks, governmental initiatives tend to be good at others Cherry-picking goals can pre-determine the comparison Pick the most important set of goals Consider synergies and tradeoff among goals – Success on one goal may facilitate or undermine success against others Three Goals of Health Care Initiatives Equity: Access to services/products is based on health status, values, and preferences, not income or wealth or employment or race or religion Efficiency: Services are produced at lowest possible cost, highest possible quality, lowest administrative burden, most appropriate mix Innovation: Continual development of better drugs, devices, procedures, forms of organization Synergies among Goals Equitable access promotes efficiency – Efficiency promotes innovation – Lowers administrative costs of enrollment churning, uncompensated care, unfunded mandate Effective purchasing of today’s services gives signals to entrepreneurs and investors on where to focus Innovation promotes equity – New technologies become cheaper with experience, diffuse to even most disadvantaged populations Tradeoffs among Goals Equity can stifle efficiency – One-size-fits-all forms of payment and regulation distort incentives, foster moral hazard, fraud, bureaucracy Efficiency can stifle innovation – Low prices, ease of entry (e.g., bio-similars) undermine incentives for risk-taking, investment in fixed assets Dynamic (Schumpetrian) competition v. static competition Innovation can impede equity – New clinical opportunities can increase disparities Sectors for Evaluation: Biotechnology Dynamic technology, with promise of significant benefits to sickest patients, potential for radical transformation of care for all patients – High scientific and commercial uncertainty (long lead time till revenue), major capital needs – Genomics, personalized medicine, stem cell therapy Sector as a whole is yet to be profitable Attractive economic spinoffs: jobs, training, etc. Sectors for Evaluation: Insurance Insurance as income re-distribution – – Pooling of (known) unequal risks Motivate the chronically well to support the chronically ill Insurance as purchasing – – – Methods of payment give incentives to providers Other incentives for providers: quality improvement, review of appropriate use patterns Design of cost-sharing give incentives to patients Biotechnology: Equity Biotech products are directed at severe needs – High prices and cost-sharing are financial barrier – Not population health but focus on the neediest But charitable donations help most patients in need The US purchasers (CMS, private insurers, employers, individuals) are financing R&D for the entire world, including other rich nations Biotechnology: Efficiency Very high “value-based” pricing – Most biotech firms still not profitable; external access to capital (VC and pharma licensing) remains crucial Most clinical gains to date have been incremental Debate over physician “buy and bill” incentives Overall, however, biotech has best scientific basis in medicine; expensive but worth it Biotechnology: Innovation The US biotech industry is the envy of the world – Major new products target major unmet needs – Cancer, auto-immune diseases, rare genetic conditions Mutual benefits for basic and applied science – New products, firms, capital investment, jobs Technology transfer: US universities are the world’s envy Genomics, diagnostics, stem cell are revolutionary Biotechnology: Positives Biotech is classic Schumpetrian industry – – High initial investments, high risk, with major potential rewards (more clinical than financial, it appears) To date, no lack of investment and entrepreneurship – – Bio-generics and pressure for lower prices may reduce risktaking. Short-term concern over early-stage investments? Rapid vertical integration between pharma and biotech Extensive global competition for biotech investments Biotechnology: Challenges Biotechnology is not “disruptive technology” – – It is high cost, not low cost and low functionality It clearly raises the cost of care – Cost-effectiveness ratio is not very favorable Often by converting fatal diseases into chronic illness Longevity gains often measured in weeks or months Continued access to private capital is not certain – Especially for early stage firms, frontier technologies Biotechnology: Summing Up Equity: 8/10. Targets the sickest patients with greatest unmet needs; charitable programs blunt cost-sharing requirements Efficiency: 6/10. High prices, weak costeffectiveness, modest breakthroughs in short run Innovation: 10/10. Envy of the world; no centralized system can come close (e.g.,Germany) Insurance: Income Redistribution and Purchasing of Health Care Services Two functions of insurance must be evaluated – – Redistribution: motivating the healthy to pay for the sick and the rich to pay for the poor Purchasing: creating appropriate incentives for providers and consumers through network (provider payment) and benefit (cost sharing) designs Insurance as Redistribution: Equity The US insurance sector fails 46 million at any one time, many more at some time (churning) Under-insurance (excessive cost sharing) for low income and chronically ill patients Tax exclusion of health benefits favors high income taxpayers and those with gilt benefit designs Medicare taxes fall on all workers, including uninsured, and favor all elderly, including wealthy Minneapolis and Portland subsidize Miami and Manhattan Insurance as Redistribution: Efficiency The mix of public/private insurance imposes high administrative costs – – Enrollment, disenrollment, marketing Confusion and chaos (e.g., Part D) Tradeoff betw. admin costs and fraud in Medicare Private insurance reduces incentive distortions of income taxes (on job creation, labor force participation), compared to Europe Insurance as Income Redistribution: Innovation Health Savings Accounts – – Incentives for saving are important, but skewed distribution of need attenuates social benefits “Consumer” benefit designs “protect the healthy from ill” The erosion of entitlement thinking – Health care is not free. It is a scarce social resource that should be cherished and used when most needed. Personal responsibility should play a part. Insurance as Income Redistribution: Positives The US seems really and truly not to want NHI – – – Blue Cross was created as alternative to NHI Employment-based coverage as alternative to tax-based Consumer-driven coverage as alternative to employment-based and tax-based coverage The mixed system performs not too poorly, given this (controversial) philosophical stance Insurance as Income Redistribution: Challenges The US insurance system challenges most people’s concept of fairness It undermines whatever social solidarity we have The administrative costs are horrific It gives the whole US market-oriented economic philosophy a black eye in global discussions Insurance as Purchasing of Health Services: Equity Efforts by insurers to get lowest prices undermine provider ability to offer charity care But insurer as purchaser is agent of enrollee in obtaining wholesale pricing – Retail prices would be even more unfair for those most in need and least able to bargain The uninsured pay the highest prices, if they pay Insurance as Purchasing of Health Services: Efficiency US pays highest prices for health services – Continual conflict between insurers and providers – Providers hate HMOs, Medicare FFS, Medicaid Multi-payer system reduces risk to providers – MD and RN earnings; drugs and devices This reduces imperative for lobbying Cost sharing facilitates generic substitution etc. Insurance as Purchasing of Health Services: Innovation The multi-payer system facilitates experimentation – – – Methods of provider payment (DRG, capitation, EOC) Disease management for chronic conditions Methods of provider organization – Medical groups, vertical integration, specialty facilities Transparency and performance monitoring Report cards, pay-for-performance Insurance as Purchasing of Health Services: Positives Multi-payer systems foster experimentation and diversity in organization and delivery of care The US system fosters more transparency, performance measurement than many It is less subject to capture by providers It offers less pork to politicians Insurance as Purchasing of Health Services: Challenges Multi-payer systems lack cost control power – This may be a good thing (for innovative sectors) Conflict and confusion at the plan/provider interface Exhaustion and low expectations – Dynamic versus static efficiency Case rates? Specialty organization? DM and QI? Consolidation among insurers and providers Insurance as Redistribution and Purchasing: Summing Up Tradeoffs between the two functions of insurance? – – Single-payer governmental systems are more effective at pooling risk, forcing healthy to pay for sick Multi-payer (mixed public/private) systems allow more experimentation in care delivery/organization Universal coverage within a multi-payer system? Biotechnology and Insurance: Summing Up Equity – – Efficiency – – Biotechnology: 8/10 Insurance (distribution): 4/10 Biotechnology: 6/10 Insurance (purchasing): 6/10 Innovation: – – Biotechnology: 10/10 Insurance (purchasing): 6/10