Benefits of the Ballot Box for Species Conservation Kailin Kroetz

advertisement
Benefits of the Ballot Box for
Species Conservation
1
2
3
Kailin Kroetz1, James N. Sanchirico2, Paul R. Armsworth3, H. Spencer Banzhaf4
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
1
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Davis, One Shields
Avenue, Davis, CA 95616 ; email: kkroetz@ucdavis.edu
2
Department of Environmental Science and Policy, University of California, Davis, One Shields Avenue,
Davis, CA 95616 and University Fellow, Resources for the Future; email: jsanchirico@ucdavis.edu;
phone: (530) 754-9883
3
Department of Ecology & Evolutionary Biology, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996; email:
p.armsworth@utk.edu
4
Department of Economics, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, 14
Marietta Street, NW, Atlanta, GA 30303, and Research Associate at the NBER, and a Senior Research
Fellow at the Property and Environment Research Center (PERC); email: hsbanzhaf@gsu.edu
15
16
Running title: Ballot Box Conservation
17
18
Keywords: Biodiversity, conservation, conservation movement, endangered species, integer
programming, open space, referenda, reserve site selection
19
20
Type of article: Essay
21
Manuscript length: Abstract (143 words), Body (5,000), References (43), Figures (4), Tables (1)
22
Corresponding author:
23
24
25
26
27
28
James N. Sanchirico
Department of Environmental Science and Policy
University of California, Davis
One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA 95616
Telephone: (530) 754-9883 Email: jsanchirico@ucdavis.edu
29
30
31
32
Author Contributions: K.K, J.N.S., P.R.A., and H.S.B. designed research, analyzed results,
and wrote the paper.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
1
33
34
Benefits of the Ballot Box for
Species Conservation
35
36
Kailin Kroetz, James N. Sanchirico, Paul R. Armsworth, H. Spencer Banzhaf
37
38
39
Abstract
40
Recent estimates reaffirm that conservation funds are insufficient to meet biodiversity
41
conservation goals. Organizations focused on biodiversity conservation therefore need to
42
capitalize on investments that societies make in environmental protection that provide ancillary
43
benefits to biodiversity. Here, we undertake the first assessment of the potential ancillary
44
benefits from the ballot box in the United States, where citizens vote on referenda to conserve
45
lands for reasons that may not include biodiversity directly but that indirectly might enhance
46
biodiversity conservation. Our results suggest that referenda occur in counties with significantly
47
greater biodiversity than counties chosen at random. We also demonstrate that large potential
48
gains for conservation are possible if the past and likely future outcomes of these ballot box
49
measures are directly incorporated into national-scale conservation planning efforts. The possible
50
synergies between ballot box measures and other biodiversity conservation efforts offer an
51
under-utilized resource for supporting conservation.
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
2
59
60
Introduction
61
Global conservation funding needs to at least double to meet the 2020 biodiversity commitments
62
of the Convention on Biological Diversity (McCarthy et al. 2012). The shortfall of funding
63
heightens the importance of finding additional funding sources to support conservation. It also
64
means that what resources are available need to be deployed efficiently and has led to calls for
65
improving the coordination and planning of conservation organizations in a bid to capture
66
potential efficiency gains (Mace et al. 2000; Kark et al. 2009). The idealized coordinated efforts
67
that some authors have called for would prioritize sites that protect biodiversity at low cost
68
(Margules & Pressey 2000; Naidoo et al. 2006; Wilson et al. 2009), engage in planning that
69
operates at a number of scales (Erasmus et al. 1999; Meretsky et al. 2012), and have access to
70
resources for conservation that are fungible over these scales (Balmford et al. 2003).
71
72
Although the conservation biology literature includes pleas for more systematic planning
73
(Margules & Pressey 2000; Wilson et al. 2009), these efforts often are not well-coordinated
74
(Bode et al. 2011) or when coordinated, there is a mismatch between ecosystem and planning
75
scale (Meretsky et al. 2012). Indeed, much of the support for conservation is locally sourced
76
(Armsworth et al. 2012) and is intended to meet locally derived priorities (e.g. to provide open
77
space, recreation opportunities and other ecosystem services). For example, in the United States
78
there are over 1,600 active nonprofit land trust organizations that have varying objectives
79
including open space preservation, but whose activities may provide ancillary benefits for
80
biodiversity conservation (see e.g. Chang (2011)). As these groups have their own locally-
81
derived objectives aside from biodiversity, their conservation activities might not be judged as
82
efficient in terms of biodiversity conservation per dollar spent. Nevertheless, their efforts are
83
likely beneficial to biodiversity. Understanding the magnitude of these potential gains and how
84
best to capitalize on them in biodiversity planning is an important question for the conservation
85
community.
86
87
Much of the support for local land trusts derives from the direct democracy process, where
88
citizens vote on ballot initiatives to conserve lands for a myriad of reasons (e.g., public access to
89
open-space, conservation, groundwater protection, and recreation). According to the Land Trust
3
90
Alliance (LTA), there have been approximately 2,400 land-vote referenda since 1988 occurring
91
in over 46 states and setting aside more than $58 billion in conservation funds (Trust for Public
92
Land 2012). Although larger conservation organizations (e.g., LTA, The Nature Conservancy)
93
do provide support to help formulate initiatives and bring them to the ballot (Kline 2006;
94
Kotchen & Powers 2006; Sundberg 2006; Nelson et al. 2007; Banzhaf et al. 2010), ultimately
95
the success of the referendum depends on the preferences of the jurisdictional (e.g., municipality,
96
county) residents towards land conservation as expressed through their votes (see, e.g., Deacon
97
& Shapiro (1975)).
98
99
To date, there is no systematic assessment of the potential ancillary benefits of the ballot box
100
initiatives on biodiversity protection. Even though the local services citizens derive from land
101
conservation are likely not the same as the value of a site assigned by a planner with the
102
objective of maximizing biodiversity, the potential biodiversity benefits can be nonetheless large
103
in aggregate because ballot initiatives are prevalent and the sums of money are substantial (e.g.,
104
according to Jordan et al. (2007), the average yearly expenditure on these initiatives is
105
approximately on par with the U.S. average annual expenditure of the U.S. Conservation Reserve
106
Program).
107
108
Furthermore, the potential for efficiency gains by incorporating these ballot measures into
109
national-scale planning is an open question. For example, Abbitt, Scott, and Wilcove (2000)
110
identified U.S. county-level hotspots of vulnerability across the United States as a type of area
111
for central planning efforts to target. These hotspots where based on projected increases in
112
populations and development and occur in areas near urban centers. These areas, however,
113
might also be the places more likely to hold ballot measures for land conservation (see e.g. Press
114
(2002)).
115
116
We contribute to the literature by developing insights into the complementarity of these two
117
processes: top-down national-scale biodiversity planning and bottom-up citizen voting.
118
Specifically, our paper connects the political-economy research analyzing the occurrence and
119
success of the land-vote referenda (e.g., Kline (2006), Kotchen & Powers (2006), Nelson et al.
120
(2007) and Banzhaf et al. (2010)) and the conservation biology literature on the optimal
4
121
conservation site selection that assumes a nationally-planned and well-coordinated set of
122
activities. In particular, we compare the outcome of the direct democracy process with a
123
hypothetical top-down planner to address the following questions: how well has direct
124
democracy done at directing funding towards places that the top-down planner would have
125
identified and how well is direct democracy likely to do by this standard in the future? We also
126
illustrate the potential for efficiency gains by incorporating the spatial patterns of direct
127
democracy directly into conservation planning.
128
129
130
Materials and Methods
131
132
We divide up our analysis into three parts. First, we undertake a retrospective analysis and
133
examine the overlap of the location of past successful ballot measures with areas of high species
134
concentration. We also compare the successful ballot measures with both a random selection
135
process and one that corresponds to the recommendation of a hypothetical top-down biodiversity
136
planner allocating a fixed conservation budget across the United States. The planner is
137
represented by the solution of a reserve site selection algorithm (RSS). In the second part, we do
138
a prospective analysis using a multivariate regression model to predict the likelihood of
139
jurisdictions holding and passing land vote referenda. We compare the set of predicted counties
140
to data on the presence of endangered species and to the sites selected by the top-down planner.
141
Finally, we do an illustrative experiment where we include the past results of referenda directly
142
into the reserve site RSS algorithm to investigate the potential efficiency gains from
143
incorporating direct democracy outcomes in conservation planning.
144
145
Our analysis uses a number of different data sources to capture the two processes. The three
146
main data sets include; county-level USDA agricultural land values as a proxy for the cost of
147
conservation land in a county; county-level data on the presence of endangered species; and
148
county referenda ballot and outcome data between 1988-2006 come from the Trust for Public
149
Land’s “Landvote database”. To focus on referenda that have potential ancillary benefits for
5
150
conservation, we exclude measures that list only recreational and historical purposes (removes
151
~10% of the total referenda from 1988-2006).
152
To derive species presence/absence information, we utilize NatureServe’s GIS files and
153
calculate, for each U.S. county, a list of the species that are present and the rating the species
154
receives from NatureServe. NatureServe rates species on a G1 to G5 scale, where G1 is
155
critically imperiled and G5 is secure. We focus on species classified as G1 (critically imperiled)
156
and G2 (imperiled). We also use the same data on Federal endangered species that have been
157
used in other site selection algorithms (see e.g. Ando et al. (1998)). NatureServe’s G1 and G2
158
designations include 3,949 species, which is much more inclusive than the Federal endangered
159
species list which only includes 874 species. The correlation between the number of
160
NatureServe G1G2 species in a county and the number of ES is .74, suggesting there are
161
differences in the spatial distribution of biodiversity represented by the two datasets (Stein et al.
162
2000).
163
164
Retrospective Analysis
165
In the retrospective analysis, we examine two questions:
166

167
168
169
Do successful ballot referenda occur in counties with more or fewer G1G2 species and
ES than the G1G2 species and ES in randomly sampled counties?

Are successful ballot referenda more likely to have occurred in counties targeted by RSS
algorithms?
170
171
To answer the first question, we compare ballot box outcomes to a random sample of counties.
172
First we compare the number of species in ballot box counties to the number of species covered
173
when randomly selecting 146 counties (equal to the number of counties with prior successful
174
referenda; see Figure SI-14 and SI-15 for G1G2 species and ES). Then we compare the number
175
of species in ballot box counties to the number of species covered by randomly selecting
176
counties having the same overall area as those with successful ballot measures (see Figure SI-16
177
and SI-17 for G1G2 species and ES).
178
6
179
To answer the second question, we examine how outcomes of successful ballot box measures
180
compare to the set of sites selected by a top-down biodiversity planner. In this case our
181
benchmark is the outcomes of an RSS algorithm. While there are many possible variants of RSS
182
formulations to consider (see, e.g. Sarkar et al. (2006) and our review in the SI), we choose for
183
illustration purposes the simple yet seminal framework of Ando et al. (1998). Following Ando
184
et al. (1998), we use two common site selection approaches to summarize the results of top-down
185
conservation planning. Specifically, we solve the set covering problem (SCP) (Underhill 1994)
186
and the maximum coverage problem (MCP) (Camm et al. 1996; Church et al. 1996) (see SI for
187
mathematical formulation) from operations research. We explore several budgets in our
188
analysis. Our base budget amount is consistent with that used in Ando et al. (1998), except that
189
we account for the differences in farmland values (1992 in Ando et al. and 2002 here) by
190
inflating the budget to reflect an 8% increase per year over the 10-year period.
191
192
Prospective Analysis
193
A key component of the prospective analysis is the development of a predicted probability of a
194
successful referendum for each county in the U.S. that reflects the likelihood of the local citizens
195
putting a measure on the ballot and passing it. We use these predicted probabilities to examine
196
the overlap between predicted sites of successful referenda and species presence/absence and the
197
RSS benchmark. Specifically, we address the following two questions:
198

199
200
201
How do the predictions of our model of successful ballot box referenda compare to
counties with G1G2 species or ES?

How do the predictions of our model of successful ballot box referenda compare to
counties targeted by RSS?
202
203
To predict the probability of a successful referendum, we build off of the econometric analysis of
204
Banzhaf, Oates, and Sanchirico (2010) and utilize the same set of covariates. They estimated a
205
polychotomous sample selection model using Landvote data from 1988-2006. Their set of
206
covariates included U.S. Census data, USDA Economic Research Service land use data, U.S.
207
county election data, and data on state characteristics that may influence the occurrence of
208
referenda.
7
209
210
Based on their results, we make a number of simplifying assumptions. First, we use a probit
211
model for estimating the probability of holding a successful referendum. Banzhaf, Oates, and
212
Sanchirico (2010) used a multinomial logit model due to their interest in developing predictions
213
specific to funding mechanism (e.g. bond, tax) for the referendum. The funding mechanism,
214
however, is not of prime interest for our analysis. Second, we do not control for the potential
215
selection issue (that is, we only observe counties that have held referenda), because they found
216
along with Kotchen and Powers (2006) and Nelson, Uwasa, and Polasky (2007) that a two-step
217
Heckman (1979) correction for sample selection is not necessary.
218
219
The probit model is 𝑃𝑟(𝑆𝑢𝑐𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑓𝑢𝑙 𝑅𝑒𝑓 = 1|𝑋𝑖 ) = 𝛷(𝛽𝑋𝑖 ), where Successful Ref is the
220
dummy variable for whether or not the county has held at least one successful referendum from
221
1998-2006, X is a matrix of explanatory variables, Φ is the cumulative normal distribution, and β
222
is a vector of coefficients on the explanatory variables. The set of explanatory variables include
223
those in Table 1 and public finance (e.g., type of measure, tax or bond), political-economy (e.g.,
224
% voting for Bush in 2000, voter turnout in the election, home rule index, etc.), along with other
225
controls (e.g., latitude and longitude, land area (sq. miles), % change in farmland, % of land in
226
farming, % living in urbanized area, etc.). Estimation results are available in the SI. Using the
227
estimated coefficients, we predict the probability of a successful referendum.
228
229
Efficiency gains experiment
230
231
In addition to illustrating the overlap between areas of conservation interest and those places that
232
have passed or are likely to pass ballot measures, we construct a thought experiment to
233
illuminate the potential gains from directly incorporating the outcomes of ballot measures into
234
conservation planning.
235
236
237
238
In particular, we ask the following question:

How much would including counties with successful ballot referenda in RSS algorithms
improve the efficiency of conservation expenditures?
239
8
240
The answer to this question depends in part on the nature of the conservation organization that is
241
engaging in national-scale planning. We consider the case where the organization views any land
242
preserved through referenda as exogenous to their efforts and as a potential substitute for their
243
own land acquisitions (we discuss other possible scenarios in the Discussion section).
244
Substitution is equivalent to assuming that the organization will count species as covered if
245
counties with successful referenda coincide with species ranges. For such an organization, we
246
illustrate the potential gain they could realize by adapting their prioritization of land purchases to
247
account for the ballot box measures.
248
249
We measure the gains by examining the change in number of species conserved and budget
250
invested when (1) RSS is conducted independently of land vote and (2) RSS takes into account
251
locations of past successful referenda and assuming species in these counties are covered at zero
252
cost. The latter assumption implies that the hypothetical conservation planner can focus their
253
limited budget only on the remaining, unprotected species.
254
255
A possible extension could consider an organization that does not want to work directly within
256
the land vote process but wants to invest resources in co-locating conserved and referendum
257
sites. In this case, the spatial configuration of sites is important for measuring the potential gains,
258
as groups can benefit from investing and/or partnering with other groups that are also conducting
259
local conservation efforts, possibly supported by funding made available through the ballot box.
260
261
262
Results
263
Retrospective Analysis
264
Analyzing the Land Vote data for U.S. counties from 1988-2006, we find that counties with at
265
least one successful referendum tend to have a higher median household income, a higher
266
median home value, and a higher population density than counties with none (see Table 1).
267
These successful referenda counties, therefore, have similar characteristics to those used by
268
Abbitt et al. (2000) to create their vulnerability index, suggesting there may be some overlap
269
with counties important for biodiversity investments.
270
9
271
To test this possibility, we compare the distribution of successful referenda counties with the
272
G1G2 species and ES presence/absence data. Just over 20% of species classified as G1G2 occur
273
in the set of 146 counties that had successful referenda from 1988-2006 (see Figure SI-1 for a
274
map of all counties with at least one successful referendum from 1988-2006). Approximately
275
35% of ES are present in counties that had successful referenda. These counties tend to be in the
276
Northeast, Florida, and the West.
277
278
To provide context for these percentages, we compare ballot box outcomes to a random sample
279
of counties. We test whether the number of G1G2 species and ES in ballot box counties is
280
greater than the number of G1G2 species and ES covered when randomly selecting 146 counties
281
(equal to the number of counties with prior successful referenda). We find that counties with
282
successful referenda cover more species than would be expected by a random sample: the p-
283
values associated with the hypothesis test for G1G2 species and ES are .00018 and .00308,
284
respectively. We also find that the number of G1G2 species and ES in ballot box counties is
285
greater than the number covered by randomly selecting counties having the same overall area as
286
those with successful ballot measures (the p-values associated with the hypothesis tests for G1G2
287
species and ES are .00072 and .0031, respectively).
288
289
Next we ask: How do the outcomes of successful ballot box measures compare to the set of sites
290
selected by a top-down biodiversity planner? For each comparison of the RSS to referenda
291
outcomes, we consider the overlap in terms of the counties and the species covered. We present
292
results here for our base budget, which is consistent with that used in Ando et al. (1998). In
293
terms of the counties, when the objective is to maximize G1G2 species covered, 170 counties are
294
selected via RSS, of which only 10 counties (~7%) are also in the set of counties with prior
295
successful referenda (Figure 1). These RSS-selected counties are more concentrated in the west,
296
are not as concentrated in the northeast, and have a denser distribution in Appalachia than the
297
counties with prior successful referenda.
298
299
In terms of species covered, we find that 2,719 G1G2 species (~69%) are covered by RSS
300
selected counties compared to 846 G1G2 species in counties with past successful referenda
301
(~21%). Not surprisingly, the average number of G1G2 species and ES is higher in counties
10
302
selected via RSS and the farmland and housing prices are lower (see Table 1). The RSS is by
303
design selecting counties with greater diversity at lower cost.
304
305
Prospective Analysis
306
While the focus of the retrospective analysis is on how well direct democracy has done at
307
passing land set-aside referenda in important locations for preserving species, the prospective
308
analysis asks how well it likely will do by comparing local citizen preferences for land
309
conservation measures with G1G2 species and ES data. To develop the predicted probabilities
310
associated with any county holding and passing a land vote referenda, we estimate a multivariate
311
cross-sectional regression (probit) model for 1998-2006 – the period over which we have a full
312
suite of covariates. We find a pseudo-R2 of .4735 (column 1 in Table SI-1), which is an
313
acceptable fit for a cross-sectional analysis.
314
315
We also run two sets of robustness checks. First, we do an out of sample test (see Methods)
316
where we compare the predicted probabilities for the 13 counties that hold successful referenda
317
from 2007-2011 to those for counties that never have a successful referendum from 1988-2011.
318
We find the average predicted probability for the counties with successful referenda from 2007-
319
2011 is 24.92% compared to an average of 2.31% for the counties that never have a successful
320
referenda. Second, we omit the referenda that occurred in a given year and repeat the
321
estimation. We do this omitting each year one at a time for 1998-2006. The average predicted
322
probabilities for the counties that previously were designated as having had a successful
323
referendum before we dropped the year’s data are, on average, higher (24.1% average predicted
324
probability of holding a successful referendum for counties with prior successful referenda
325
versus 2.4% for counties without prior successful referenda).
326
327
In terms of statistically significant covariates, we find that voter turnout in the election, the %
328
voting for Bush in the 2000 presidential elections (proxy for Republican voters), and % without a
329
high school degree in the county are statistically significant at the 1% level and negatively
330
correlated with the probability of holding a successful referenda. Median income (1% level),
331
home rule index (1% level), and % living in an urbanized area (10% level) are all positively
332
correlated.
11
333
334
To examine the potential contribution to biodiversity conservation from counties that are more
335
likely to hold successful ballot measures in the future, we examine species coverage over varying
336
thresholds of probabilities for both the comparison to G1G2 species and ES and the RSS
337
benchmark. That is, we assume that all counties with a predicted probability greater than the
338
threshold eventually will pass referenda that protect lands (and cover the species) in the county.
339
In this analysis we only generate predictions for counties that have not had prior successful
340
referenda.
341
342
We first examine the number of species that are present in counties with varying predicted
343
probabilities of having successful referenda (see Figure 2 for the G1G2 results and Figure SI – 7
344
for the ES results, which are similar). While most of the predicted probabilities are clustered
345
near zero, there are, however, 16 counties with a predicted probability of having a successful
346
referendum greater than 50%. Approximately 3% of G1G2 species and 8% of ES are covered by
347
this set of counties. If we assume all species in counties that had successful referenda in the past
348
are also conserved, then 23% of G1G2 species would be expected to be conserved overall.
349
Under the same assumption 37% of ES would be expected to be conserved overall. The number
350
of species covered varies with the probability threshold, for example, there are 82 counties with
351
predicted probabilities of having a successful referendum greater than 20%. These 82 counties
352
cover 11% of G1G2 species and 29% of ES. These results suggest that past and predicted future
353
referenda conserve lands in counties that overlap with the presence of species of concern.
354
355
Finally, we compare the potential contribution of direct democracy toward biodiversity to our
356
biodiversity planner benchmark. We do this by comparing the predicted probability of having a
357
successful referendum with our RSS sets. The sets of sites selected via RSS are identical to the
358
sets described previously. We focus on the overlap between counties with past successful
359
referenda and various thresholds for the predicted referendum success, and sites selected via
360
RSS. Figure 3 shows the distribution of the predicted probability of success of referenda in
361
counties in the contiguous United States (darker colors indicate higher predicted probability)
362
overlaid with the results from the base case RSS (black-hashed counties).
363
12
364
We see evidence, for example in the Western United States, of overlap between counties with
365
high predicted probabilities and the RSS set. However, we also observe counties, for example,
366
inland counties in the Great Plains and Appalachia, which are selected via RSS but have a low
367
probability of successful referenda. We also find a number of places where the referenda occur in
368
counties neighboring those chosen by the biodiversity planner, implying that there might be
369
agglomeration benefits especially for species with ranges that cover multiple counties
370
(something we are not considering in this analysis; see e.g. Önal & Briers (2002)). These results
371
assume a budget for the RSS consistent with Ando et. al (1998), which is 14% of the total
372
necessary to conserve all G1G2 species; as we increase the budget the number of counties in the
373
RSS increases as does the overlap (see Figure SI-12).
374
375
Potential Efficiency Gains
376
377
Here we illustrate one possible way a national conservation organization might use ballot box
378
measures to utilize their budgets more efficiently. Specifically, we rerun for a range of budgets
379
the previous RSS (MCP) analysis assuming land in counties with prior successful referenda is
380
free (zero cost) to the central planner.
381
382
Figure 4 panel A illustrates the relationship between a national conservation group’s budget and
383
species (see Figure SI-9 for ES). The additional coverage, in terms of species, from taking into
384
account sites covered via prior successful referenda is substantial, especially at low budgets. For
385
example, if we focus on the base case budget, which is marked in the figure by the red dashed
386
line and based on updating budgeting assumptions used in Ando et al.’s (1998) top-down
387
planning study, we find that the base RSS budget could be reduced by 45% while still protecting
388
the same number of G1G2 species (horizontal green line in the Figure; 47% with ES). Looked at
389
another way, at the same budget level, the planner can protect 14% more G1G2 species (vertical
390
blue line; 12% more ES).
391
We also find that the location of conservation priorities change when accounting for the ancillary
392
benefits available from successful referenda in national scale conservation planning (see Fig. 4
393
panel B). For example, at the base budget, the national-scale planner omits 27 counties from the
13
394
optimal solution, 10 of which had past successful referenda but 17 of which did not. These 17
395
share species with counties protected by referenda and thus become a lower priority, as
396
evidenced for example, by the new RSS no longer selecting counties in peninsular Florida. With
397
the savings from not having to allocate funds to counties with past referenda, the planner adds 34
398
new counties to their optimal set. When comparing sets of species in the omitted and new
399
counties, we find that the planner substitutes toward counties that have a higher concentration of
400
species not in referenda sites.
401
402
403
Discussion
404
The purpose of this paper is to examine the potential for the direct democracy process to
405
contribute to biodiversity conservation in the United States. To our knowledge the ancillary
406
benefits of citizen-supported initiatives have yet to be considered in this light. The values local
407
residents derive from living near land set aside via referenda is analogous to the “human amenity
408
value” that Fuller et al. (2010) suggested could be incorporated into top-down planning objective
409
functions. Rather than requiring top-down planning to account for human amenity value though,
410
the referenda process in the United States allows local residents to express their support for
411
particular amenities and local biodiversity by voting in favor of conservation initiatives directly.
412
Therefore, unlike other processes outside the control of the top-down planner that may serve as a
413
source of inefficiency, such as political pressure (Pressey 1994; Margules & Pressey 2000), we
414
demonstrate that the direct democracy process might actually enhance the efficiency of
415
conservation budgets.
416
417
While we illustrate one way in which conservation planners might be able to interact more
418
systematically with the land vote process, our results also hint at other ways conservation
419
planners might be able to interact more systematically with the land vote process. For example,
420
a conservation organization may find it cost-effective to allocate resources to help referenda with
421
a low probability of occurrence but a relatively high predicted percent voting yes to get on the
422
ballot. Resources could also be allocated to help referenda already on the ballot pass.
423
14
424
425
To inform such efforts, organizations could investigate the role of demographic, political,
426
economic, and other factors in predicting the probability of referenda occurring and the percent
427
voting yes as a means to better inform the allocation of their resources. Some groups including
428
The Conservation Fund and The Trust for Public Land already have manuals regarding how to
429
support conservation through ballet measures (see SI for more detail). As an illustration of how
430
statistical models could enhance current conservation efforts, we estimated a probit regression to
431
predict the probability of referenda occurring and a log-odds regression to predict the percent
432
voting yes (see Table SI-1, Figure SI-2, Figure SI–3). Our results, for example, suggest that
433
counties with higher percentages of the population with at least a bachelor’s degree have larger
434
number of voters voting yes. Previous econometric work related to open space referenda has
435
identified additional characteristics of a jurisdiction associated with having and passing a
436
referendum using a variety of different models (Kline 2006; Kotchen & Powers 2006; Nelson et
437
al. 2007; Banzhaf et al. 2010; Wu & Cutter 2011).
438
439
Given the diversity of RSS approaches in the literature, we use our formulations as a benchmark
440
for comparison and as a representation of “idealized” top-down planning, and do not view our
441
results as offering a management prescription (see the SI for a discussion of various elements to
442
account for when choosing an RSS-set). Some recent advances in RSS literature, for example,
443
formulate a return on investment approach that combines multiple attributes, such as
444
vulnerability to development, land prices, spatial contiguity and/or complementarity benefits (see
445
e.g., Murdoch et al. (2007), Polasky (2008), Underwood et al. (2009), Murdoch et al. (2010),
446
and Withey et al. (2012)). While our benchmark considers only the role of land prices, our
447
analysis can be tailored by organizations to particular conservation objectives and datasets to
448
make management decisions.
449
450
A possible concern about the potential use of ballot box measures for conservation is the
451
presence of taxonomic bias in the species covered. In RSS planning efforts, for example, the
452
species to use as a surrogate for biodiversity and the weights used in the objective are chosen
453
based on the objectives of the conservation exercise (Margules & Pressey 2000). In our RSS
454
analysis, we give all species, regardless of their taxa, equal weight. To check for potential
15
455
mismatches between the set of species conserved in the two processes, we calculate the
456
percentage of each taxa-type covered in the RSS (base budget) and the ballot measures. Our
457
results suggest that any taxonomic bias may be small (~10% for plants and vertebrates, see
458
Figure SI-19) at least for county-level referenda.
459
460
In this paper, we focus on the potential role of county-level ballot initiatives. Further work
461
should integrate data on land set aside via municipal and state level initiatives and other
462
protected lands into RSS type planning exercises to get a more holistic view of all of the
463
conservation activities being undertaken in the U.S. A possible hypothesis for such an analysis
464
might be that the potential gains from ballot measures are lower, after taking into account all of
465
these other types of protection. In our efficiency gains experiment, for example, we do not
466
account for land held by Federal and state governments. Using information from the Protected
467
Area Database (US Geological Survey 2012), we test the robustness of our findings by
468
conducting auxiliary analysis with protected area data. We assume that species in a county are
469
covered if greater than 25% or 50% of the county land area is protected (achieves GAP 1 or GAP
470
2 status). We find there are still large efficiency gains available through consideration of the
471
land vote process. For example, the budget gains when holding the number of species constant
472
and when only considering land vote are ~45%, when only considering protected areas are
473
~13%, and when both past referenda and protected areas are considered jointly are ~52%. (See
474
SI for additional details of the robustness check.)
475
476
We leave for future work incorporating complexities such as spatial configurations of reserves,
477
institutional arrangements such as partnering with local land trusts, and interactions between
478
conservation efforts such as attraction and repulsion of new reserves to current reserves and
479
crowding out by government (Albers et al. 2008a; Albers et al. 2008b; Parker & Thurman 2011).
480
We also do not consider the anti-growth/development ballot measures, which are the other side
481
of the coin to the land conservation referenda (see, e.g., Gerber & Phillips (2005)).
482
483
484
485
16
486
487
Acknowledgements
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
We thank Andrew Chua for research assistance; Lynn Kutner, Data Management Coordinator at
NatureServe, for NatureServe species data; several colleagues, including Michael Bode, Martin Smith,
Alex Pfaff, Chris Timmins, Susan Harrison, and Andy Sih, as well as four anonymous referees, for
helpful comments and suggestions. Sanchirico acknowledges support from Agricultural Experimentation
Station project CA-D-ESP-7853-H. Kroetz acknowledges support of the National Institute for
Mathematical and Biological Synthesis at The University of Tennessee, Knoxville where she was a shortterm visitor.
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
518
519
520
17
521
522
523
524
525
526
527
528
529
530
531
532
533
534
535
536
537
538
539
540
541
542
543
544
545
546
547
548
549
550
551
552
553
554
555
556
557
558
559
560
561
562
563
564
565
566
567
568
References
1.
Abbitt R.J.F., Scott J.M. & Wilcove D.S. (2000). The geography of vulnerability: incorporating species
geography and human development patterns into conservation planning. Biological
Conservation, 96, 169-175.
2.
Albers H.J., Ando A.W. & Batz M. (2008a). Patterns of multi-agent land conservation: Crowding in/out,
agglomeration, and policy. Resource and Energy Economics, 30, 492-508.
3.
Albers H.J., Ando A.W. & Chen X. (2008b). Spatial-econometric analysis of attraction and repulsion of
private conservation by public reserves. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
56, 33-49.
4.
Ando A., Camm J., Polasky S. & Solow A. (1998). Species Distributions, Land Values, and Efficient
Conservation. Science, 279, 2126-2128.
5.
Armsworth P.R., Fishborn I.S., Davies Z.G., Gilbert J., Leaver N. & Gaston K.J. (2012). The size,
conservation, and growth of biodiversity-conservation nonprofits. BioScience, 62.
6.
Balmford A., Gaston K.J., Blyth S., James A. & Kapos V. (2003). Global variation in terrestrial conservation
costs, conservation benefits, and unmet conservation needs. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, 100, 1046-1050.
7.
Banzhaf H.S., Oates W.E. & Sanchirico J.N. (2010). Success and design of local referenda for land
conservation. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 29, 769-798.
8.
Bode M., Probert W., Turner W.R., Wilson K.A. & Venter O. (2011). Conservation Planning with Multiple
Organizations and Objectives. Conservation Biology, 25, 295-304.
9.
Camm J.D., Polasky S., Solow A. & Csuti B. (1996). A note on optimal algorithms for reserve site
selection. Biological Conservation, 78, 353-355.
10.
Chang K. (2011). The 2010 National Land Trust Census Report. In: (eds. Aldrich R & Soto C). Land Trust
Alliance.
11.
Church R.L., Stoms D.M. & Davis F.W. (1996). Reserve selection as a maximal covering location problem.
Biological Conservation, 76, 105-112.
12.
Deacon R. & Shapiro P. (1975). Private preference for collective goods revealed through voting on
referenda. American Economic Review, 65, 943–955.
13.
Erasmus B.F.N., Freitag S., Gaston K.J., Erasmus B.H. & van Jaarsveld A.S. (1999). Scale and conservation
planning in the real world. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological
Sciences, 266, 315-319.
14.
Fuller R.A., McDonald-Madden E., Wilson K.A., Carwardine J., Grantham H.S., Watson J.E.M., Klein C.J.,
Green D.C. & Possingham H.P. (2010). Replacing underperforming protected areas achieves
better conservation outcomes. Nature, 466, 365-367.
18
569
570
571
572
573
574
575
576
577
578
579
580
581
582
583
584
585
586
587
588
589
590
591
592
593
594
595
596
597
598
599
600
601
602
603
604
605
606
607
608
609
610
611
612
613
614
15.
Gerber E.R. & Phillips J.H. (2005). Evaluating the Effects of Direct Democracy on Public Policy California’s
Urban Growth Boundaries. American Politics Research, 33, 310-330.
16.
Heckman J.J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica: Journal of the
econometric society, 153-161.
17.
Jordan N., Boody G., Broussard W., Glover J.D., Keeney D., McCown B.H., McIsaac G., Muller M., Murray
H., Neal J., Pansing C., Turner R.E., Warner K. & Wyse D. (2007). Sustainable Development of the
Agricultural Bio-Economy. Science, 316, 1570-1571.
18.
Kark S., Levin N., Grantham H.S. & Possingham H.P. (2009). Between-country collaboration and
consideration of costs increase conservation planning efficiency in the Mediterranean Basin.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106, 15368-15373.
19.
Kline J.D. (2006). Public Demand for Preserving Local Open Space. Society & Natural Resources: An
International Journal, 19, 645 - 659.
20.
Kotchen M.J. & Powers S.M. (2006). Explaining the appearance and success of voter referenda for openspace conservation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 52, 373-390.
21.
Mace G.M., Balmford A., Boitani L., Cowlishaw G., Dobson A., Faith D., Gaston K., Humphries C., VaneWright R. & Williams P. (2000). It's time to work together and stop duplicating conservation
efforts…. Nature, 405, 393-393.
22.
Margules C.R. & Pressey R.L. (2000). Systematic conservation planning. Nature, 405, 243-253.
23.
McCarthy D.P., Donald P.F., Scharlemann J.P.W., Buchanan G.M., Balmford A., Green J.M.H., Bennun
L.A., Burgess N.D., Fishpool L.D.C., Garnett S.T., Leonard D.L., Maloney R.F., Morling P., Schaefer
H.M., Symes A., Wiedenfeld D.A. & Butchart S.H.M. (2012). Financial Costs of Meeting Global
Biodiversity Conservation Targets: Current Spending and Unmet Needs. Science, 338, 946-949.
24.
Meretsky V.J., Maguire L.A., Davis F.W., Stoms D.M., Scott J.M., Figg D., Goble D.D., Griffith B., Henke
S.E. & Vaughn J. (2012). A State-Based National Network for Effective Wildlife Conservation.
BioScience, 62, 970-976.
25.
Murdoch W., Polasky S., Wilson K.A., Possingham H.P., Kareiva P. & Shaw R. (2007). Maximizing return
on investment in conservation. Biological Conservation, 139, 375-388.
26.
Murdoch W., Ranganathan J., Polasky S. & Regetz J. (2010). Using return on investment to maximize
conservation effectiveness in Argentine grasslands. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, 107, 20855-20862.
27.
Naidoo R., Balmford A., Ferraro P.J., Polasky S., Ricketts T.H. & Rouget M. (2006). Integrating economic
costs into conservation planning. Trends in Ecology & Evolution, 21, 681-687.
28.
19
615
616
617
618
619
620
621
622
623
624
625
626
627
628
629
630
631
632
633
634
635
636
637
638
639
640
641
642
643
644
645
646
647
648
649
650
651
652
653
654
655
656
657
658
659
660
661
662
Nelson E., Uwasu M. & Polasky S. (2007). Voting on open space: What explains the appearance and
support of municipal-level open space conservation referenda in the United States? Ecological
Economics, 62, 580-593.
29.
Önal H. & Briers R.A. (2002). Incorporating spatial criteria in optimum reserve network selection.
Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 269, 2437-2441.
30.
Parker D.P. & Thurman W.N. (2011). Crowding Out Open Space: The Effects of Federal Land Programs on
Private Land Trust Conservation. Land Economics, 87, 202-222.
31.
Polasky S. (2008). Why conservation planning needs socioeconomic data. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, 105, 6505-6506.
32.
Press D. (2002). Saving open space: The politics of preservation in California. University of California
Press, Berkeley, CA.
33.
Pressey R.L. (1994). Ad Hoc Reservations: Forward or Backward Steps in Developing Representative
Reserve Systems? Conservation Biology, 8, 662-668.
34.
Sarkar S., Pressey R.L., Faith D.P., Margules C.R., Fuller T., Stoms D.M., Moffett A., Wilson K.A., Williams
K.J. & Williams P.H. (2006). Biodiversity conservation planning tools: present status and
challenges for the future. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour., 31, 123-159.
35.
Stein B.A., Kutner L.S. & Adams J.S. (2000). Precious Heritage: The Status of Biodiversity in the United
States. In. Oxford University Press, Inc. New York, New York.
36.
Sundberg J.O. (2006). Private Provision of a Public Good: Land Trust Membership. Land Economics, 82,
353-366.
37.
Trust for Public Land (2012). Landvote Database. Trust for Public Land.
38.
Underhill L.G. (1994). Optimal and suboptimal reserve selection algorithms. Biological Conservation, 70,
85-87.
39.
Underwood E.C., Klausmeyer K.R., Morrison S.A., Bode M. & Shaw M.R. (2009). Evaluating conservation
spending for species return: A retrospective analysis in California. Conservation Letters, 2, 130137.
40.
US Geological Survey G.A.P.G. (2012). November 2012 Protected Areas Database of the United States
(PADUS), version 1.3 Combined Feature Class.
41.
Wilson K.A., Carwardine J. & Possingham H.P. (2009). Setting Conservation Priorities. Annals of the New
York Academy of Sciences, 1162, 237-264.
42.
Withey J.C., Lawler J.J., Polasky S., Plantinga A.J., Nelson E.J., Kareiva P., Wilsey C.B., Schloss C.A.,
Nogeire T.M., Ruesch A., Ramos J. & Reid W. (2012). Maximising return on conservation
investment in the conterminous USA. Ecology Letters, 15, 1249-1256.
43.
20
663
664
665
666
667
668
669
670
671
672
673
674
675
676
677
678
679
680
681
682
683
684
685
686
687
688
689
690
691
692
693
694
695
696
697
698
699
700
701
702
703
704
705
706
707
708
709
Wu X. & Cutter B. (2011). Who votes for public environmental goods in California?: Evidence from a
spatial analysis of voting for environmental ballot measures. Ecological Economics, 70, 554-563.
21
710
711
Tables
712
Table 1: Summary statistics
Median Levels
Federal Endangered Species
NatureServe G1G2 Species
Median Household Income ($1,000s)
Median Home Value ($1,000s)
Percent in Poverty
Percent Age > 65
Percent Age < 18
Percent No High School Degree
Percent Bachelor's Degree
Population Density
Farmland Price per Acre
713
714
715
716
All
counties
3
1
33.69
71.80
15.08
14.43
25.34
20.80
14.40
42.21
$1,668
No successful
referenda
2
1
33.23
70.40
14.78
14.54
2534
21.10
14.10
39.73
$1,611
At least one
successful
referendum
4
3
48.66
140.00
26.96
11.38
25.06
13.80
28.50
435.82
$4,485
ES RSS
8
10
31.79
80.10
12.64
13.55
25.57
22.15
15.15
20.50
$1,183
G1G2 RSS
6
11
31.54
78.50
11.98
14.13
25.66
21.80
15.20
11.08
$763
Note: Counties are categorized according to whether the county has held at least one successful referendum from
1988-2006 and whether or not it was selected via RSS at the base budget that is ~14% of the amount needed to
cover all G1G2 species and ~33% of the amount need to cover all ES species (see Methods and SI).
717
718
719
720
721
722
723
724
725
726
727
728
22
729
730
Figures
731
Figure 1: Comparison of counties with past successful referenda and optimal RSS with
732
G1G2 species. This figure shows the overlap between the counties with prior successful referenda between 1988
733
and 2006, and the results of the RSS algorithm. The RSS results are based on maximizing the number of G1G2
734
species covered subject to a budget. We use a base budget similar to that of Ando et al. (1998) but adjusted to
735
account for differences in the cost of farmland. The base budget represents ~14% of the total budget needed to
736
cover all G1G2 species (see Methods).
737
738
739
740
741
742
743
744
745
23
746
Figure 2: Relationship between G1G2 species covered and predicted probability of
747
referendum success. We calculate, for counties with a predicted probability of a successful referendum greater
748
than the threshold probability, the number of G1G2 species covered under two assumptions: (1) species covered by
749
counties with prior successful referenda are included in the count; and (2) species covered by counties with prior
750
successful referenda are not included in the count.
751
752
753
754
755
756
757
758
24
759
Figure 3: Comparison of counties predicted to have future successful referenda and our
760
benchmark (RSS using G1G2 species data and base budget). The figure shows an overlay of the
761
RSS results on the predicted probability of having a successful referendum, by percentile group, along with the
762
counties that have had successful referenda from 1988-2006. The probabilities of holding a successful referendum
763
associated with the percentile groups are as follows: 75th percentile (1% or less), 76th-80th (1-2%), 81st-85th (2-
764
3%), 86th-90th percentiles (3-5%), 91th-95th (5-13%), 95th-100th (13% or greater).
765
766
767
768
769
770
771
772
25
773
Figure 4: Efficiency gains for G1G2 species covered. We solve a series of RSS problems maximizing
774
the number of species covered, but varying the budget. In panel A, we plot the species covered for each budget
775
under two scenarios. In our Without Ballot Measures scenario, a site must be purchased to preserve it. In our With
776
Ballot Measures scenario species in sites with successful referenda from 1988-2006 are preserved for free and all
777
other sites must be purchased to be preserved. We present the species as a proportion of the total number of G1G2
778
species and the budget as a percentage of the total budget required to cover all G1G2 species. Panel B represents the
779
changes in the set of sites chosen by the RSS planner when the ballot measures are incorporated directly into the site
780
selection problem at the base budget. In particular, the map corresponds to the gains in species covered labeled in
781
panel A.
782
783
784
785
786
787
788
789
790
791
792
793
794
795
796
797
798
799
800
801
802
26
A.
B.
803
27
Download