Opportunities and Obstacles for US Investors in Moscow; Office Market Comparative Return Study By Alexander V. Stolyarik Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Real Estate Development at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY September 2003 0 2003 Alexander V. Stolyarik. All Rights Reserved. The author hereby grants MIT permission to reproduce and distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author: Alexander V. Stolyarik Department of Urban Studies and Planning August 4, 2003 Accepted by: (J John T. Riordan Chairman MIT Center for Real Estate Thesis Advisor Certified by: David M. Geltner Chairman, Interdepartmental Degree Program in Real Estate Development MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY AUG 2 9 2003 LIBRARIES Opportunities and Obstacles for US Investors in Moscow; Office Market Comparative Return Study By Alexander V. Stolyarik Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning on August 04, 2003 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Real Estate Development. ABSTRACT Moscow in recent years has seen significant changes in the amount of investment grade office space. In the period before the financial crisis of 1998, in which Russia defaulted on its debt and the ruble was drastically devalued, many foreign investors saw great opportunity in the Moscow office market. What attracted foreigners then was the scarcity of suitable space for many foreign companies looking for offices in Moscow and the changes taking place in Russian law concerning ownership of land and real property. With the advent of the 1998 crisis the interest of foreigners waned, but that of cash-rich Russian companies and individuals, principally from the natural resources sector, grew in intensity. Since then and for myriad reasons that I shall examine in this study, Russian investors appear to have successfully held the foreigners at bay. Just what advantages do the Russians continue to have over foreigners other than their opportunistic entry post 1998? How are these advantages measured in risk-adjusted terms? What is the source of these advantages? Are they likely to be sustained to the point that foreign investors will be reluctant to compete in Moscow's real estate market? Using US investors as an example, this study seeks to find answers to these questions and, to a modest extent, forecast near-term returns while describing risks involved in the emerging Russian economy. Thesis Supervisor: Title: John T. Riordan Chairman MIT Center for Real Estate Table of Contents Page CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION..................................................................... 8 Hypothesis..............--------------------------------------------..................................................... 8 M ethodology................................................................................................................ 9 In tro ductio n.................................................................................................................. 10 CHAPTER TWO: SYSTEMATIC RISK & RETURN IN THE MOSCOW OFFICE MARKET---------............---------..--............................................................ A C ase for M oscow .................................................................................................... 12 12 * Land Use Segmentation in Moscow................................................................ 17 * Today's Product and Investment Markets in Moscow..................................... 18 * Eastern-European Space Market Comparison................................................. 19 * Eastern-European Asset Market Comparison................................................ 22 Systematic Risk and Return Analyses....................................................................... 24 P erio d ic R eturn s........................................................................................................... 27 Risk A nalyses............................................................................................................... 33 CHAPTER THREE: NON-SYSTEMATIC RISKS & THE REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT...----------------------. .------.................................................. In tro duction .................................................................................................................. 37 37 Devaluation and Default of 1998 38 * The Anatomy of the Crisis.............................................................................. 39 + Entrance and Exit of the Westerners............................................................... 41 * Another Turn-Around..................................................................................... 43 * The Real Estate Industry in Russia Before and After 1998............................ 44 The History of Economic Reforms and the Current Situation.................................... 46 * P rivatization ............................................................................................. ..... 47 * Post-1998 Economic Recovery....................................................................... 48 Oil and the Russian Economy Today.......................................................................... 50 L egisativ e Issu es............................................ ........ ................................................ . 52 Presidential and Parlam entary Elections..................................................................... 52 D ebt M arkets................................................................................................................ 54 * D om estic Governm ent D ebt............................................................................ 54 * Corporate 55 ................................................................................................ Banking Sector............................................................................................................. 57 Real Estate Lending..................................................................................................... 58 H ernando de Soto on Land as the Source of Capital................................................... 60 Land Ow nership Rights & D evelopm ent in M oscow ................................................. 61 * Land lease Rights Acquisition and Approval Risks..................... 63 Construction.........................................---.--.................................................................. 67 Legal Issues and Taxation........................................................................................... 68 Structuring Foreign Investm ent in Russian Real Estate.............................................. 69 Corruption and Self D ealing........................................................................................ 71 CH A PTER FO U R: FO RECA STIN G ..................................................................... 72 M arket Forecast........................................................................................................... 72 * R ent Only M ultivariate.................................................................................... 73 + R ent and V acancy M ultivariate....................................................................... 76 Forecasting Cap Rates................................................................................................ 85 IRR com parison........................................................................................................... 90 CH A PTER FIVE : C O N CLU SIO N S....................................................................... 91 An Overview of the U S M arket Participants.............................................................. 91 Conclusions.................................................................................................................. 93 Bibliography................................................................................................................ 94 List of Tables and Figures Pa2e TABLES 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 2.10 2.11 2.12 2.13 2.14 2.15 2.16 2.17 2.18 2.19 2.20 2.21 3.1 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 4.7 4.8 4.9 4.10 4.11 4.12 Moscow City employment indicators Moscow City selected revenues Federal vs. Municipal tax collection distribution Moscow City property related tax revenue Moscow City balance sheet Microeconomic indicators for CEE countries and Russia Moscow City office market supply side data Moscow City demand side data Nominal periodic return for US investors Real periodic return for US investors Risk and return for US investors Nominal periodic return for Russian investors Inflation adjusted nominal rent for Russian investors Real periodic return for Russian investors Risk and return for Russian investors Russian vs. US investor real returns Standardized mean deviation returns for US and Russian investors Global investment return benchmark Standardized mean deviation returns for Global benchma rk Global risk-free rate Beta/ Traynor ratio analyses Country indicators for permanent debt placement Russian macroeconomic indicators Independent variables significance for rent Independent variables significance for supply Regression table set-up for rent Regression table set-up for supply Regresion results for rent Regression results for supply Rent only multivariate forecast Independent variables significance for rent Independent variables significance for supply Independent variables significance for occupied stock Regression table set-up for rent 13 14 15 15 16 19 25 25 27 28 28 29 30 30 31 32 33 33 33 35 35 59 72 73 73 74 74 75 75 76 76 76 77 78 4.13 4.14 4.15 4.16 4.17 4.18 4.19 4.20 4.21 4.22 4.23 4.24 4.25 4.26 Regression table set-up for supply Regression table set-up for occupied stock Regression results for rent Regression results for supply Regression results for occupied stock Rent and vacancy multivariate forecast Rent only and rent and vacancy multivariate comparison Forecasting results from the rent & vacancy model: Market Dynamic / Percent Change: Cap rate regression output Cap rate forecast Real returns forecast for US investors Real returns forecast for Russian investors Historic and forecasted IRR's for US and Russian investors 78 79 79 80 80 81 81 82 83 86 86 87 87 90 FIGURES 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 2.10 3.1 3.2 3.3 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 Moscow City debt structure GDP growth comparison Rental Trends for CEE capital cities and Moscow Office space market indicators for ECC capital cities and Moscow Moscow City Supply and Absorption Real periodic return for US investors Nominal periodic return for Russian investors Real vs. Nominal periodic returns for Russian investors Russian vs. US investors real periodic returns Risk adjusted US and Russian return comparison to a global benchmark Exchange rate volatility World oil prices Gross Russian corporate bond placement Market Dynamic / Percent Change: Moscow office market real estate indicators growth rates (2001-2007) US vs. Russian investors real periodic returns forecast (1997-2007) US vs. Russian investors real periodic returns forecast (2000-2007) Supply and absorptio forecast Stock vs. cumulative absorbtion 16 19 20 21 26 28 29 31 32 36 41 50 56 84 85 88 88 89 90 Acknowledgements I would like to express my gratitude to all those who supported this research; especially: Eugene Golub from the GE Golub, Ludmila Goncharenko and Anna Danshina from the Plechanov Russian Academy of Economy (Department of Investment Policy), Jack Kelleher from the Noble Gibbons, Maksim Kunin from the FF&P, Veta Riabtseva from the Jones Lang LaSalle, Ilya Metelkin and Mikhail Yakoubov from the Institute for Urban Economics. CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION Hypothesis There are many US investors/ developers that have tried to enter the Moscow real estate market, but few have succeeded to date. Despite the rapid recovery of the Russian economy and improved investment climate there are few US players in Moscow's real estate market. I believe that after the devaluation of the ruble and default on debt in 1998, the composition of the Russian market changed in favor of domestic capital. The balance of economic power was repositioned and the new Russian conglomerates emerged in the aftermath of the crisis. Rich with money from the exploitation of natural resources, new Russian capital found its way into real estate. The proportion of the capital is now in favor of Russian investors who are crowding out US entrants. Besides hefty risk adjusted returns achieved by Russian developers, the complex regulatory environment is another advantage that Russians have in the competition for real estate investments. Without a solid partnership with Russian companies it is almost impossible for foreigners to get approvals for real estate development. In this thesis I propose that the reasons for the failure of the Americans to enter the Russian real estate market at large are the superior returns achieved by the Russian competition. If the results of the analyses are negative or inconclusive, then the Russian regulatory system is the main factor blocking foreign investment into real estate. Methodology Because rent in Russia is denominated in US dollars there are several factors that play a role in returns for Russian investors. Mainly, Russian inflation and exchange rate volatility are important when rent and reversion gains are converted into rubles and reinvested back into the domestic economy. (I will omit the cases where the rent is kept in dollars and invested abroad or domestically) For the US investors it is the US inflation and domestic benchmarks that matter in the game. First I will assess US investor real returns and analyze the systematic risk involved in the investment in Russian real estate. Then I will analyze Russian investor risk and return, and compare the two by way of Traynor Ratios (measures the performance with adjustment to risk in the investment). If the risk-adjusted return achieved by Russian investors is superior, then the crowding-out effect is justified. If the return rate is inferior or comparable, then my further analyses and assessment of the risk for Americans in dealing with the Russian regulatory system will explain their weak presence in the market. Using Wheaton's forecasting model, I will project rent and returns for both types of investors and make recommendations for investments and improvements in the Russian permitting process. Torto-Wheaton Research econometric forecasting Introduction Over the past decade many investors developed a so-called "love-hate" relationship with Russia. At various times all were tempted by the enormous potential and flourishing possibilities of the country. Starting from Robert Nobel in 1873, Rothschild in 1880 and Rockefeller in 1891 (whose investments were wiped out by the Socialistic Revolution of 1917), to the recent Multinationals and Investment Funds who abandoned the country after the devaluation of 1998; all learned the price of the unexpected. But in 2003, not even a full five years after the last crises, Moscow hotels are again are full of Western investors scouting for opportunities. It seems that this time Russia is determined to become a part of the World Trade Organization, and prove to be a worthwhile investment. One of the biggest steps toward the goals of liberalization became a new land code which allowed for the direct foreign ownership of the land. That, together with the government surplus, increased transparency, stable political situation, and GDP growth of 4+%, was sufficient enough to raise some interest among European and US investors. Magnified by the current recession and uncertainty in all areas of the capital markets in the US and Europe, investments in emerging markets became more and more attractive. It would seem that it is a match once again: steady demand for foreign direct investment is met with the need to deploy capital and demonstrate performance by earning decent risk-adjusted returns with Western "know-how". However intriguing the situation might seem, the majority of US investors remain skeptical even with the recent upgrade of county's credit rating. What seems to be different about Russia in the beginning of twenty first century is that it is characterized by privately-owned firms who are taking advantage of their excess capital developed from the oil and gas trade. In the aftermath of liberalization and after the early privatization programs of the 90's, as many as seven wealthy conglomerates emerged. Much like the Rockefellers' and Rothschilds', Russian "oligarchs" are now investing cash in all sectors of the economy including real estate projects in Moscow and St. Petersburg. Accepted by the Kremlin administration, new businessmen are controlling "the other half' of the economy. In order to compete on the world markets new Russian money is reinvent itself with the inflow of foreign management practices and increased transparency. Many are listed on the NYSE and are trading at 15-20 P/E ratios. However attractive real estate investments might look for both domestic and foreign players, there is an apparent shortage in the availability of investment grade real estate in Moscow and St. Petersburg. "Moscow developers have simply not been building with the idea of selling later and reinvesting the proceeds," - says Cameron Sawyer, the president of GVA Sawyer property advisors. Thus development of class "A" properties is the answer to the current booming demand in space and asset markets. Moscow developers are still building predominantly with equity capital and are holding their properties in order to reap cash flow. The return of the invested equity is so fast (5-6 years on average) that many simply do not care if the building burns down in year seven. Thus, the chief obstacle for investment is the lack of product on the asset market itself. Development is the answer to this problem. But the risks involved in Moscow development are so high that few can afford to compete in this arena. The winners in development are still Russian developers and a few joint ventures between Russian companies and the Western real estate giants. The latter are difficult to establish because Russians see little need for partnership. Rich in oil money and with foreign advisory services widely available, many Russian developers see the only reason for a partnership to be a cheaper foreign capital in the form of debt or equity investment. However, foreign money doesn't come cheap since Westerners see much risk in the investment. Another issue is that Russians don't want to be dominated by a foreign entity that needs control for either public reporting or internal qualifications purposes. By the time Americans are through with the joint-venture agreements many opportunities are simply gone from the market. However hard it might be for foreigners to enter, it is obvious that they are not loosing interest and are eager to evaluate any offer with the potential returns of 30-35% from this immature and highly competitive market. CHAPTER TWO: SYSTEMATIC RISK & RETURN IN THE MOSCOW OFFICE MARKET A Case for Moscow 2 The reason to analyze Moscow's real estate is its superior economic performance and political significance in Russia. Despite the fact that Moscow still doesn't have direct land ownership rights (leasehold only), real estate has for a number of years been a number one investment choice for foreign capital. The main reins of power are concentrated in Moscow, and most regulatory reforms are first tested in this city. The constitution of the Russian Federation divides Russia into 89 'subjects' or regions. The regions vary enormously in geographic size and economic importance. Two of the 89 subjects (Moscow and St. Petersburg) are defined as 'cities of Federal importance' and, although they are only cities, they enjoy the same powers as the other 87 regions. The administrative system of Moscow is set down in the City Charter, adopted in June 1995. The executive branch is headed by the Mayor, currently Yuri Luzhkov, who was elected on 19 December 1999 for his third four-year term. Judging by the popularity of Mr. Luzhkov, he will be reelected this year for his fifth term in office. The Mayor has the right to appoint senior officials to head the main administrative branches of the city; these officials constitute the City Government and are directly responsible to the Mayor. The City Duma is the legislative arm of the administration and is composed of 35 directly elected deputies, each representing a specific area of Moscow. Moscow is economically the largest and best performing of all Russia's 89 regions. With just 6% of Russia's population, the city of Moscow accounts for 15% of Russia's GDP and provides approximately one-third of the entire revenues of the Federal budget. GDP per capita is over twice the Russian average and average incomes are four times the Russian average. The 1998 devaluation caused the City revenues to contract in dollar terms from US $5.Obn in 1998 to US $4.3bn in 1999. Revenue levels bounced back in 2000 to US $6.9bn and US $6.8bn in 2001. Although debt service on its foreign currency debts increased in ruble terms after the 1998 devaluation, the City met all obligations fully and 2 The data for this section was gathered from Moscomstat, IngBarings, and Federal Ministry of Finance on time. Even though refinancing was not available, the City repaid US $1.4bn of foreign credits plus interest over two and a half years. In terms of employment, Moscow has a higher percentage of the workforce in registered employment than the overall average of the Russian Federation, and also a higher percentage employed in the private sector. The gap between public and private sector employment is widening rapidly throughout Russia, though the trend is more marked in Moscow due to the strength of the city's growing private sector. Table 2.13 (in millions) Moscow City employment indicators Year Econom. Active Employed Unemployed % 1996 4,100 3,900 200 1997 4,000 3,800 200 1998 4,000 3,800 200 1999 4,200 4,000 200 2000 4,200 4,100 100 2001 4,300 4,200 100 5% 5% 5% 5% 2% 2% Moscow's economy is strongly service-oriented, as one would expect for a major capital city. In 1998 services accounted for 66.5% of Gross City Product (GCP), against less than 50% for the Russian Federation as a whole. The decline in manufacturing is much in line with the experience of the whole of the former Soviet Union, as previously inefficient enterprises have been either restructured or closed. The drawback is that after closing they are left in the center of the city as abandoned ruins (see Chapter x). An important feature of the City of Moscow's economy is that the city is headquarters to a large number of Russian companies, the bulk of whose activities are situated outside the city. This includes a very large proportion of Russia's sizeable oil and gas sector. Many of these companies have their exporting and financial subsidiaries situated in Moscow, and these are not included for reporting purposes in GCP. In 1999, Moscow was headquarters to 14 companies that accounted for 58% of the total sales of Russia's top 200 companies, and one of these - Gazprom - provided 23% of the city's total tax revenues. In evaluating Gross City Product it is interesting to note the decreasing role of revenue collected from the industry and the increasing role of the revenue collected from real estate services in the city: 3Moscomstat Table 2.2 Moscow City selected revenues Total Rev. from Industry Total Rev. from Services Rev. fromReal Estate 1996 1997 1998 1999 26.4% 59.2% 0.9% 22.9% 64.1% 2.6% 22.1% 66.5% 2.6% 19.0% 67.2% 3.8% The City Government's main areas of responsibility and activity are: + Moscow's economy and infrastructure, including public transport, utilities and communications and engineering infrastructure. + The provision and supervision of social services, such as public health, education, cultural activities and social assistance for targeted groups. + The development, management and sale of the city's property and other assets. + Construction activities. Each of these areas is headed by an official, appointed by and directly responsible to Mayor Luzhkov. The City Administration consists of approximately 14,000 employees. The largest unit is the Social Services department with 7,500 employees. Within Moscow, the City Administration is the largest single employer. Tax revenues are by far the largest component of the city's budget, averaging over 68% of total revenues over the past few years. Direct taxes - corporate income tax and personal income tax - are the most important taxes, which comprised about 56-60% of total tax revenues up until 2000. From 2001 on, the proportion increased because 15% of the VAT tax retained by Moscow is no longer available and was directly transferred to Federal jurisdiction. Additionally, Moscow instituted its own 5% sales tax to partially compensate for the loss. Corporate profit tax is the largest single source of revenue for Moscow. Federal law requires 11% be paid to the Federal budget with the balance of taxes paid accruing to the city. Moscow clearly benefits from being the financial and political center of the Russian Federation. The distribution of tax collection is as follows: Table 2.3 Federalvs. Municipal tax collection distribution --31% 100% City 100% 50% 100% 100% 100% 69% --- Water tax --- 100% Land tax 15% 85% Taxes and Fees Excises on ethyl alcohol (spirit) Excises on alcohol (vodka, wine etc.) Excises on jewelry Personal Income tax Corporate tax Single social tax Federation VAT 50% --- Property taxes as a percent of total city tax revenue are as follows: Table 2.4 (in millions of US dollars) Moscow City property related tax revenue 1997 $745.10 Property Tax $169.40 lease prop. Rev. from Rev. from prop. sales $159.70 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 $458.90 $202.50 $51.60 $266.80 $111.10 $69.50 $392.90 $212.90 $538.40 $675.40 $0.20 $535.20 $314.10 $439.40 $1,074.20 $713.00 $447.40 $605.80 $1,214.00 $1,288.70 Total prop. $9,532.30 $5,002.80 $4,311.80 $6,958.20 $7,819.00 $8,775.70 Total City rev. 14.68% 15.53% 8.71% 10.38% 14.25% % Prop. to City total. 11.27% We can see the effect of devaluation on the city budget in 1998-1999, and the lack of property sales in 2000. These effects are due to Luzhkov's retention of city property for leasehold purposes and the revival of sales in 2002 to certain insiders who realized the drawback of land rent vs. direct ownership. The drop in leased property revenue can be explained by the shortage of supply in the space market and the subsequent drop can be explained by the following addition of a large amount of sq. in., lagging from the demand of 2000. Non-tax revenues associated with property consist mainly of payments and rentals for the use of city property, asset sales and privatization proceeds. The property portfolio of the City of Moscow is very large and diverse, and it generated relatively large revenue totaling US $213m in 2000 and rising to US $314m in 2002. It is projected that by the year 2003 the city of Moscow will increase supply in the space market, and property related revenues will rise to '%of the budget. Moscow City balance sheet is as follows: Table 2.5 (in millions of US dollars) Moscow City balance sheet 1998 1997 2001 2000 1999 2002 $9,532.30 $5,002.80 $4,311.80 $6,958.20 $7,819.00 $8,775.70 Total City Rev. Total City Expend. $9,203.40 $4,991.90 $4294.40 $6,154.10 $7,002.60 $9,089.20 $17.4 $804.10 $816.40 $ (313.50) $10.90 $328.90 Surplus/ (Deficit) Even though during the devaluation of 1998 Moscow managed to realize a surplus, the recent deficit can be explained by the large amount of debt repayment in 2002. The budget is expected to result in another surplus by 2003. Figure 2.1 Moscow City debt structure Debt Size -*- 2.5 - - - - - - - - - Debt as % of revenue - - - - - - - - - - - 120% 2 -100% US $ bn. 1.5 80% 60/0 1 40% 0.5 20% 0 0% 1997 1998 2000 1999 2001 2002 Year Considering all the factors, Moscow probably has the most opportunities for rich returns in Russia. This is apparent to many foreign and domestic investors, as the fight for a share in the market has already began without much investment from US capital in Moscow. Land Use Segmentation in Moscow Under central planning, construction primarily evolved on the existing perimeters of the city. Like a tree's cross-section, the urban structure of Moscow reflects alternating periods of residential and industrial construction that mirror changes in central planning emphasis. Considerations of commuting time and energy efficiency have played little role. For many years, large-scale, high-rise housing construction was assigned to raw land remote from the city center. Effectively, industry has not yet left the center of the city. This is true despite the fact that factories are under-performing in the current location and are better served on the outskirts of Moscow. There are simply no resources to relocate them. The situation is such that the highest and best use for the land in the center is residential and commercial, but the banks of the Moscow River are still full of manufacturing and production facilities. On the other side, the outskirts of Moscow have a residential density that is higher than in the center of Paris as considered by the experts of the World Bank. At the same time millions of citizens are traveling in and from the center causing congestion as the transport systems are lengthy and costly to operate. This special evolution of cities reflects the absence of land market as an instrument of land redevelopment.4 If there is a municipal monopoly on land ownership then the administrative mechanism for allocating sites is not sufficiently sensitive to market demand. In these circumstances, bribery can be rationalized as a mechanism for making officials attentive to the market. If local authorities allow for privatization of lands the situation would most likely result in construction activity on industrial lands converted to housing use. Another reason for the residential development on the perimeter of the city is the technology of the urban utilities developed during the Soviet era. The centralized supply systems do not provide individual metering or adjustments for heat, water, and gas. These systems are costly to redevelop in the center of Moscow, even if they have sizable internal losses that could be monetized if systems were properly reconstructed. The utility companies don't have an incentive to redevelop the city center since they are private monopolies or city-owned agencies. 4 Bertaud and Renaud 1997 Today's Product and Investment Markets in Moscow In the retail sector Moscow brokers are predicting increased vacancy in shopping centers; even though the city has the lowest square footage of retail as compared to other capitals in Europe. While currently the amount of retail in Moscow is nearly 1 million sq. m. with occupancy of 85-90%, it is rapidly dropping with the addition of the new supply such as Mega Mall, Ikea, and the like, comprising nearly 800,000 sq. m. by 2003. In the office sector income yields are coming down from 15-20% to 12-13% as estimated by the specialists at the Noble Gibbons CB Richard Ellis brokerage house in Moscow. The tenant demand demonstrates the Russian economy's continued reliance on oil and gas exports. The most active sector drivers are oil and gas (17% of net absorption), metallurgy and metal trade (15.5%), followed by the professional services companies (11.7%) and financial and banking services (11.7%); telecom firms contracted 8.6%; information agencies, mass media and TV took sixth place among the most active tenants5. Demand is still growing in the office sector as more and more companies are demanding quality space, which they can now afford due to the booming economy and the return of foreign enterprise. With a recovering economy, starting in year 2000 the demand for industrial space soared. The outstanding demand comes primarily from both Russian and international retailers with local production facilities. Both prefer built-to-suit projects. The market is far from being saturated, as only few projects meet the Western standards commanded by many potential occupiers. 5 Stiles & Riabokobylko Commercial Real Estate Services When investing in Moscow real estate many investors first consider its closest rivals from the adjacent former Soviet block. The following is a comparison of the economic and real estate market performance: Eastern-European Space Market Comparison6 Figure 2.2 GDP growth comparison N Russian CEE Year The main macroeconomic indicators are as follows: Table 2.6 Microeconomic indicatorsfor CEE countries and Russia Poland Czech Rep. Hungary Russia 1.6m 1.2m 2m 8.7m Real GDP $171b $55b $49.5b $356.2b GDP per Capita $4,400 $5,400 $4,900 $3,100 GDP growth 1.50% 2.90% 5.20% 4+% Moody's Rating BBB+ A- A- BB- Unemployment 16% 9.80% 5.90% 7.90% 4.20% 3.90% 6.20% 11% Popul. in Capital City Inflation 6 Data for this segment is provided by JJL and GE Golub The tables show that Russia by 2003 is catching up to its former allies with very volatile but high growth rates. Real Estate Markets in Capital Cities: Figure 2.3 Rental Trends for CEE capitalcities and Moscow -$80.00 Moscow - Budapest - Prague - Warsaw .... . ... $70.00 $60.00 Rent per Month $50.00 $40.00 $30.00 $20.00 $10.00 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Year While most of the countries showed a slow down around 2000, Moscow's rent still grew at a slow rate. Figure 2.4 Office space market indicatorsfor ECC capitalcities and Moscow asem Stock 2,500.000 - -- - - - - - - - Supply -.-*Vacancy - - - - - - - - 25% - - - - - - - - -- - - - - --.-. 20% 2,000,000 Sq. m. 1,500,000 15% 1,000,000 10% 500,000 5% -0% Moscow Budapest Prague Warsaw Moscow is still responding to the high demand for office space as demonstrated by low vacancy and a supply higher than in other capitals. The reason for such disparity with other countries of the Eastern block is that Moscow is much less open to the influence of the West. Mainly, after the iron curtain was lifted, Prague, Warsaw and Budapest instituted liberal investment and development policies for foreigners. The market was quickly overbuilt by the year 1999 and rents started to decrease with increased vacancies. On the other hand, Russia had much more control of foreign involvement in its economy and real estate in particular. Corruption, unresolved property rights, a complex regulatory environment and the crises of 1998 slowed the process of potential over-supply in the market. While its neighbors were going through their first real estate down-cycle, Moscow was still trying to identify development opportunities. Despite the fact that land ownership issues are still being sorted out, the demand for space is going strong, responding to a growing economy in Moscow. Thus, by way of small dosages of the real estate market discipline, Moscow is still riding the growth era of its real estate. Eastern-European Asset Market Comparison 7 Moscow The investment market is thin, as few transactions are actually taking place in Moscow. There are more transactions of the owner-occupier nature, as Russian companies prefer to own the property they occupy. An estimated volume of such deals in 2002 was approximately US $600 million8 . Despite the fact that there is an increased interest, there were no transactions in 2002-2003 on investment/ speculative bases. Only two legitimate transactions were recorded in 2001 with total volume of US $80m. Nevertheless, there is much hope for supply entering the market that is targeting sale at the end of construction. There still is a chance that developers will hold on to the property as senior debt availability improves and cash flows entice developers to hold on to assets. One example of such a hold-back was Berlin House, which was built with the intention of sale, but was taken off the market once fully stabilized. Budapest The lack of investment product is the main problem in Budapest. There has been a significant slowdown in the market in recent years. The demand is low and so is supply in the market. The investors are predominantly focused on the office market. Only one transaction was registered in the industrial market in 2002. Retail had no speculative investment transactions recorded last year. The market is producing 5-7 transactions a year with an approximate volume of EUR 200m and cap rates at around 9%. Prague There is a strong interest for investment in Prague by German investment funds. However, only ten transactions were observed with only two on the open market. Cap rats are around 9-10%. The overall volume of transactions only reached EUR 177m. The general prognosis is that the cap rates will continue to fall awaiting the accession into EU. Unlike Russia, senior debt is readily available on the market with increased competition for placement. 7 Data for this segment is provided by JJL and GE Golub 8 JJL, Richard Ellis Warsaw Warsaw remains the number one choice for investors in Eastern Europe. Despite the overcrowding on the market and apparent drop in rent levels, last year's transaction volume exceeded EUR 650m in the office sector and EUR 410m in retail. The market is projected to remain stable and grow, with cap rates at 10-11%. The asset market in Moscow is one of the most immature in comparison to EEC countries. Although the reason for the very limited number of transactions at the moment is a lack of sellers, not a lack of potential buyers, market liquidity remains a concern. Nevertheless, what differentiates Moscow in the sample is its upward trend in rents. With the predicted cap rate compression Moscow can be a winner with high gains on exit. Systematic Risk and Return Analyses As noted earlier, office properties appear to be one of the most profitable investments in Moscow. Of all the office space in the city, Class A and upper Class B are still considered investment-grade material. Many market observers might argue that there is no Class A office space in Moscow. Nevertheless, the majority of the consultants ascribe to the following gradations: + Al: Complete new building; fully controllable 4-pipe HVAC system; raised floors and suspended ceilings; slab to slab height of 3.6 meters (11.8 ft.) or better (no less than 2.7 meters (8.85 ft.) from the top of finished floor and to the suspended ceilings); efficient column spacing (no less then 6 meters (19.7 ft.)) with rational window spacing; sufficient underground parking (1car per 100 sq. in.); advanced building management and security system; excellent utility capacity; UPS; modem high speed lifts with maximum waiting time of about 30 seconds; proper legal documentation. + A2: Complete new building or reconstruction; fully controllable HVAC system; advanced building management and security system; sufficient utility capacity; UPS; possibility to install raised floors; modem high speed lifts of sufficient capacity; may lack underground parking. + A3: Either newly built or fully reconstructed in early 1990s', less efficient floor plates and design, (including capital walls etc.); often with 2-pipe HVAC or comfort cooling. It is very ambiguous which buildings in Moscow should be in the A category since some of the factors are very similar with the subsequent B class. In some cases it is the location that makes the break in this tough allocation decision. However nebulous the gradation might be, the following data is accumulated from the buildings that best fit the parameters above including A and the upper B layer: Table 2.79 Moscow City office market supply side data Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 New Supply 40,000 90,000 100,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 220,000 240,000 260,000a 280,000a 2006 a - Stock 120,000 160,000 250,000 350,000 650,000 900,000 1,100,000 1,320,000 1,560,000a 1,820,000a Adj. Stock 114,000 152,000 237,500 332,500 617,500 855,000 1,045,000 1,254,000 1,482,000a 1,729,000a 2,100,000a 1,995,000a Projected. These numbers reflect the supply side of the equation. The stock is adjusted by 5% for depreciation and broker data discrepancy. The rents in Moscow are generally quoted exclusive of insurance and operating expenses. Table 2.810 Moscow City demand side data Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Vacancy 6.0% 7.0% 14.0% 16.0% 11.0% 7.5% 4.5% 4.5% Occupied 107,160 141,360 204,250 279,300 549,575 790,875 997,975 1,195,062 Absorption 34,200 62,890 75,050 270,275 241,300 207,100 199,595 Asking Rnt. $ 850 $ 820 $ 620 $ 500 $ 550 $ 560 $ 570 $ 580 Adj. Rnt. $ 807.50 $779.00 $ 589.00 $475.00 $522.50 $532.00 $541.50 $551.00 Rent is paid quarterly in advance. The numbers above reflect the demand side and are adjusted for 5% overage of operating expenses and assumptions about actual contractual rent amount. Analyzing the two sides of the market, I will note a couple of trends: 9 Noble 1 Ibid Gibbons, DTZ, JJL, Colliers, Stiles Riabokobylko. Figure 2.5 Moscow City Supply and Absorption Sq. M -+- -- Supply Absorption 300,000250,000200,000 150,000 100,000 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Year Many developers found themselves in a difficult situation after the devaluation of 1998. The construction projects in Moscow were virtually frozen. The flight of tenants from the country paralyzed the space market, and construction money allocated in Russian banks was unavailable for access. Those who were unable to wait went bankrupt and had to sell or simply abandon unfinished buildings. Nevertheless, within a year development resumed with the newly growing economy. The jump to finish the construction started in 1998 is demonstrated by the positively sloped of the curves through 2000. Subsequent construction didn't have the same volume and it took couple of years to pick up the velocity. When it became apparent that the Russian economy was getting back on track (see Chapter Three), many international companies started to come back or scale up in Moscow, demanding quality space. In order to accommodate re-entrants and domestic new-comers, the market responded with increased enthusiasm, as we see by supply from 2001 on. But how much is enough? Considering that it takes 2-3 years to complete a 20,000 sq. m. (215,278 sq. ft.) building in Moscow, the new supply is still responding to the demand of post-devaluation. It is interesting to note that the composition of the post-devaluation Russian market is very different. Many more Russian businesses were able to take advantage of the lower production costs and get into the game. Periodic Returns Most of the rent is paid in dollars or rubles converted into dollars exclusive of expenses, insurance and taxes. I will take adjusted rent (as a close approximation to net operating income), and gathered information on estimated historic cap rates, and compare the returns from investment grade office space for both Russian and US investors as an all equity investment: E(r) = (Vt - Vt-1 + CF) / Vt-I Table 2.9 Nominalperiodic returnfor US investors Year Adj. Rnt. Cap Rt. Nom. V 1996 $ 807.50 22% $3,670.45 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 $779.00 $ 589.00 $475.00 $ 522.50 $ 532.00 $541.50 $551.00 23% 25% 24% 22% 20% 16% 14% $3,386.96 $2,356.00 $1,979.17 $2,375.00 $2,660.00 $3,384.38 $3,935.71 Nom. r 14% -7% 9% 44% 34% 47% 32% As the table above shows, the returns were all over the map with a significant downswing in 1998 due to the abrupt drop in rent in 1998 - the year of the Russian default and currency devaluation. However, the geometric return of the combined data shows that a rapid comeback of the market in subsequent years well overcompensated for the year of the crisis: (1.14*(-)* 1.09 * 1.44 * 1.34 * 1.47 * 1.32)^ 1/7 - 1 = 24% As compared to the arithmetic mean of 25%. Compared to the absorption and supply dynamic in Graph X, the downswing in 2000 reflects the end of the construction started in 1998 and an immediate response to the new rise of the economy. Even with the introduction of US inflation the returns still look attractive: Table 2.10 Real periodic returnfor US investors Year Adj. Rnt. 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 $ $ $ $ $ $ $ $ US inflation Inf. Adj. Rnt. Cap Real V Real r 3.32 1.7 1.61 2.68 3.39 1.55 2.69 2 $780.69 $765.76 $579.52 $462.27 $504.79 $523.75 $526.93 $539.98 22% 23% 25% 24% 22% 20% 16% 14% $3,548.60 $3,329.38 $2,318.07 $1,926.13 $2,294.49 $2,618.77 $3,293.34 $3,857.00 16% -7% 8% 43% 36% 46% 33% 807.50 779.00 589.00 475.00 522.50 532.00 541.50 551.00 Figure 2.6 Real periodicreturnfor US investors Return 50% Real - ..... ........ ............. ................. .............. -. -... ---.. ............ - - .-... . -.. . -.. . --.. ............... -.... -... .. -.. ... . -.. .. --.. ... ..... .. ....-... .... -.. ..-.. .. .. .-.. - 40% 0/ 30% 20% 10% M\ 0% 1997 -10%4- \V, 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Years To introduce the risk component into the picture I will compute the standard deviation for the time series using the risk free rate of the intermediate term US treasuries: Table 2.11 Risk and returnfor US investors Risk Free Rate 4.64% Arithmetic Average Standard Dev 20% Thus for one unit of return Americans accept .86 units of risk. 23% The most important reason for the disparity between Russian and US returns is the volatility of the exchange rate and inflation. After the devaluation of 1998, Russian investors were offered an abnormal escalation in the rent base for the properties. The rent was still pegged to a dollar but after the conversion into rubles, the profits for Russian investors could only be curbed by the sky-high inflation. For comparison to Russian investors I will convert dollar-denominated rent into rubles using the historic exchange rate and construct the domestic return index: Table 2.12 Nominal periodicreturnfor Russian investors Rub. Rnt. Cap Nom. V Nom. r 5.60p. 9.80p. 20.65p. 4,522.00p. 7,634.20p. 12,162.85p. 22% 23% 25% 20,554.55p. 33,192.17p. 48,651.40p. 83% 70% $ 475.00 27.00p. 12,825.00p. 24% 53,437.50p. 35% $ 522.50 $532.00 $541.50 $551.00 28.16p. 30.14p. 31.78p. 31.70p. 14,713.60p. 16,034.48p. 17,208.87p. 17,466.70p. 22% 20% 16% 14% 66,880.00p. 80,172.40p. 107,555.44p. 124,762.14p. 49% 42% 54% 32% Year Adj. Rnt. 1996 1997 1998 $ 807.50 $ 779.00 $ 589.00 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Exch. Rt. Figure 2.7 Nominalperiodic returnfor Russian investors Return 90% +-Russian Investor Returns - .. ... ... ...... .... ... .. .-..... -.. ..... ...-... ... .. .. - --.. .. ... .. .. .. - ..... ... .... -... --... -...... - .. -.. - - .. - .... - .... 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1997 1998 1999 2000 Year 2001 2002 2003 The exchange rate before the crises played quite a significant role in the nominal returns for Russian investors; nevertheless few saw an opportunity or knew how to take advantage of real estate as an investment vehicle. The real investment from the Russian side didn't come until after the crises. As you can see, the returns are moderate compared to 1997. To compare US and Russian investors, I will adjust nominal Russian returns by US/ Russian inflation because rent is pegged to the US dollar. The following formula is applied: Adj. Rnt. -+ US inflation -> Nominal Exch. Rt. -- Real Exch. Rt. -> Nom Rnt. Table 2.13" Inflation adjusted nominal rentfor Russian investors Year Adj. Rnt. US infl. Nom Exch. Rt. Real Exch. Rt. 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 $ 807.50 $ 779.00 $ 589.00 $475.00 $522.50 $532.00 $ 541.50 $551.00 3.32 1.7 1.61 2.68 3.39 1.55 2.69 2 5.60p. 9.80p. 20.65p. 27.00p. 28.16p. 30.14p. 31.78p. 31.70p. 5.41p. 9.63p. 20.32p. 26.28p. 27.21p. 29.67p. 30.93p. 31.07p. Nom Rnt. -- Rus. Infl. -> Nom. Rnt. 4,371.87p. 7,504.42p. 11,967.03p. 12,481.29p. 14,214.81p. 15,785.95p. 16,745.95p. 17,117.37p. Real Rnt. Table 2.14 Real periodicreturnfor Russian investors Nom. Rnt. 4,371.87p. 7,504.2p. 11,967.03p. 12,8.29p. 14.,214.81p. 15,785.95p. 16,745.95p. 17,117.37p. Rus. Infl. Real Rnt. 22.00% 11.00% 84.40% 36.50% 20.00% 19.00% 15.00% 11.00% " US Census Bureau, Goscomstat, JP Morgan 3,410.06p. 6,678.93p. 1,866.86p. 7,925.62p. 11,371.85p. 12,786.62p. 14,234.06p. 15,234.46p. Cap Real V Real r 22% 23% 25% 24% 22% 20% 16% 14% 15,500.26p. 29,038.84p. 7,467.43p. 33,023.41p. 51,690.21p. 63,933.08p. 88,962.87p. 108,817.54p. 109% -51% 367% 81% 46% 59% 38% Figure 2.8 Real vs. Nominalperiodic returnsfor Russian investors Return Real Returns -a- Nominal Returns -- 400% 350% 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 1999 9 8 1997 2000 2003 2002 2001 -50%Y -100% -- - - - - - - - - - - - - - -- - Year The abrupt jump from 84% inflation to 36% in 1998-1999 and simultaneous devaluation is the cause for the distortion around the time of the crisis. The returns are negatively correlated around the time of default and are positively correlated thereafter with stable exchange rate and inflation. Taking the Russian inter-bank rate as a risk-free rate, the following table will demonstrate risk / return curve for Russian investors: Table 2.15 Risk and returnforRussian investors Risk Free Rate 19.60% Standard Dev Arithmetic Avarage 132% 91% Thus for one unit of return Russians accept 1.45 units of risk So far the analyses show that the risk for the Russian investors is higher than the returns from the market; for US investors it is just the opposite. The returns for the Russian investors are almost 4 times US ones and the risk is 7 times higher. But much of it comes from the fact that the Americans are just more risk-averse than Russian investors as represented by the respective units of risk above. Table 2.16 Russian vs. US investor real returns 1998 367% 8% 359% 1997 -51% -7% -44% 1996 109% 16% 94% Year Rus us Spread 1999 81% 43% 37% 2001 59% 46% 13% 2000 46% 36% 10% 2002 38% 33% 5% Comparing real Russian and US investor returns: Figure 2.9 Russian vs. US investors realperiodic returns Returns 400% -- *- Russian Returns -- US Returns - 350% 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% -50% -+ 1997 8 1999 2000 2001 2 -100% Year Just like the nominal vs. real returns for Russian investors, US and Russian returns are positively correlated approximately from 2000 with the reducing spread trend. So risks aside, Russian returns are still 10% higher in 2002. It is interesting to note that Russian nominal returns and US ones are very similar due to the peg of the rent to a dollar denomination. Risk Analyses So, are risks and returns really lower for US investors, or is it that the systematic risks are lower following the diversification theory? To start analyzing that I will conduct B analyses for both types of investors, using a global investment portfolio as a benchmark. Then, by way of Traynor Ratio's I will compare the two. To avoid additional noise I will eliminate 4 in the regression equation by regressing mean deviations. Table 2.17 Standardizedmean deviation returnsfor US and Russian investors Year Rus Arith. Av. Mean Dev. US Arith. Av. 91% Mean Dev. 23% 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 18.82% -141.81% 276.71% -10.00% -44.84% -31.38% -67.50% -7.04% -30.24% -14.77% 20.26% 13.27% 22.90% -4.39% The following is the data for Global investment return from Ibbotson Inc.: Table 2.18 Global investment return benchmark DJGI World TR 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 13.% 20% 29% -13% -15% -19% -19% Setting up mean deviations for global returns for the same years: Table 2.19 Standardizedmean deviation returnsfor Global benchmark World TR 13.13% 19.92% 29.47% -13.02% -15.45% -18.61% -19.12% Arith. Av. -0.53% Mean Dev 13.66% 20.45% 30.00% -12.49% -14.92% -18.08% -18.59% Regression output for Russian returns onto world returns: SUMMARY OUTPUT Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.51 R Square 0.26 Adjusted R 0.11 Standard Error 1.25 Observations 7 ANOVA df SS Regression Residual Total 1 5 6 2.68 7.79 10.47 Intercept World Ret Coeff -8E-17 3E+00 Stand Error 0.47 2.47 MS 2.68 1.56 F 1.719 SignifF 0.247 t Stat -1.7E-16 1.3E+00 P-value 1 0.25 Low95% -1.21 -3.11 Upp 95% 1.21 9.58 Low 95% -1.21 -3.11 Upp 95% 1.21 9.58 The significance is pretty low, due to a low R2 and t-statistics. However I will proceed to US investor output: SUMMARY OUTPUT Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.80 0.64 R Square Adjusted R 0.57 0.13 Standard Err Observations 7.00 ANOVA df SS Regression Residual Total 1 5 6 0.15 0.08 0.23 Intercept World Ret Coeff -5E-17 -0.7595 Stand Error 0.05 0.26 MS 0.15 0.02 t Stat -1E-15 -2.9659 F 8.797 SignifF 0.0313 Pvalue 1 0.03 Low 95% -0.13 -1.42 Upp 95% 0.13 -0.10 Low 95% -0.13 -1.42 Upp 95% 0.13 -0.10 The statistic is much better for US investors with t-statistics above 2 and much higher R2 . To set up Traynor Ratios I am selecting World 1-year Government treasuries to provide the risk free rate. The following is the data from Ibbotson Inc.: Table 2.20 Globalrisk-free rate SB World Gov 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Avrge. 0.23% 15.31% -4.27% 1.59% -0.99% 19.49% 5.23% Traynor ratio: Average Return - Risk Free Rate / B For Russian Investors: 91% - 5.23% / 3.2 = 0.26 For US Investors: 23% - 5.23% / -7.6 = -0.23 Setting up the comparison table: Table 2.21 Beta/ Traynor ratio analyses World Rus US Risk Free Historic Retern Beta T ratio 5.23% 5.23% 5.23% -0.53% 23.0% 91.0% 1 -0.7595 3.2 -0.0576 -0.2340 0.2680 Because Traynor Ratio is a slope of the return line we can construct the following graph: Figure 2.10 Risk adjusted US and Russian return comparison to a global benchmark " World -Russia US . .... ..... .................... 0.80 Average Return 0.00 0.40 I0.2 Beta -1150 0.0 -1.00 iooo 00 1.00 1.503.50 -0.20 -0.40 -0.60 The results show that with a beta of -0.76, the market should reward an investor with a return of 10%. The US investors in the Russian real estate market earned on average return of 23%. They beat the market by 13%. So too for the Russian investors, their realized return of 91% exceeds the market prediction of -13% by 104%. This means that both set of investors earned more then their measure of systematic risk suggests they should. It looks that Russians earned greater abnormal returns. However, the time period analyzed is very volatile with the dramatic event of the devaluation in 1998, and the time series is short due to the youngness of the market. Furthermore, the observations have too much noise. The analyses paint a big picture, but are inconclusive for investment decision purposes. CHAPTER THREE: NON-SYSTEMEATIC RISKS & THE REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT Introduction The preceding chapter assumes that both US and Russian investors were receiving an equal amount of rent or revenue, thus equating non-systematic risks faced by the entities. But most of the foreign entrants face risks in the emerging market environment, which are greater than risks faced by domestic investors. The following is the risk gradation used by a risk management team of an international development company: Business Risk The risk of failing to achieve business targets due to inappropriate strategies, inadequate resources or changes in the competitive environment. Credit Risk The risk that a counterpart may not pay amounts owed when they fall due. Sovereign Risk The credit risk associated with lending to the government itself or a party guaranteed by the government Market Risk The risk of loss due to changes in market prices. This includes interest rate risk, foreign exchange risk, commodity price risk, and share price risk. Operational Risk The risk that is due to actions on or by people, processes, infrastructure or technology and that has operational impact, including fraudulent activities. Liquidity Risk The risk that debts or accounts payable cannot be paid due to a lack of available funds. Accounting Risk The risk that financial records do not accurately reflect the financial position of an organization. Country Risk The risk that foreign currency will not be available to allow payments because of lack of currency or government rationing of what is available. Political Risk The chance that there will be a change in the political framework of the country. Industry Risk The risk associated with operating in a particular industry. Environmental Risk The risk that an organization may suffer loss as a result of environmental damage caused by themselves or others which impacts their business. Legal/ Regulatory Risk The risk of non-compliance with legal or regulatory requirements. Reputation Risk The risk that the reputation of an organization will be adversely affected. Systematic Risk The risk that a small event will produce unexpected consequences in local, regional or global systems not obviously connected with the source of the disturbance. This risk cannot be diversified away. From interviews with US development companies, I've ascertained that the value of capital for investment in Russia is estimated at around 30-35%; which coincidently, equals the historic return from the Russian stock market. Similar interviews with Russian investors revealed a return requirement of 50-55% for equal projects. If Americans are facing lower Systematic Risk (as it appears from the Traynor Ratios in the preceding chapter) and are receiving lower returns, then risks other than those that are systematic should account for the higher discount rate used by US investors. Several non-systematic risks accounted above are the subject of this chapter. Devaluation and Default of 1998 Many US investors have been frightened away from investment in Russia following the default and devaluation of 1998, which led to the loss of millions of dollars for US equity and debt investors. But what really happened in Russia that year: In 1998 Russia reported a budget deficit of 3.2%, or R86.5 billion. International estimates of Russia's budget deficit, however, tend to be at least a few percentage points higher than Russian estimates. In 1997, for example, the Russian Government reported a budget deficit of 3.3% of GDP, but other sources, such as the IMF, estimated Russia's budget deficit to be closer to 7.7%". Despite increasing corruption, misuse of funds and growth in the control of the economy by criminal elements, the Kremlin administration was still trying to display its adherence to the course set forth by the IMF. Early in 1998 Russia demanded $15bn to rescue its economy. IMF declined additional aid, instead proceeding to negotiate interest payments on already outstanding loans. This left the Russian economy exposed to the possibility of a financial disaster. Left with holes on domestic and foreign fields' the Russian administration quickly turned its attention to internal debtors. In the summer of 1998 the government made desperate attempts to collect taxes from large and politically influential oil and gas companies. Some success was achieved in forcing such companies as Gasprom, Sidanko and Onako to pay after the government resorted to various threats that could potentially damage the cash flows of these companies. With this, the energy sector remained one of the last sources of government revenues due to its relatively high profitability and foreign currency earnings. Indeed, exports of oil and gas constituted around 40% of exports to non-CIS countries, and tax revenues from the energy sector in the consolidated budget were around 25%13. The Anatomy of the Crisis With such close links to its energy sector, the Russian budget was excessively exposed to shocks in the world oil price. By fixing the exchange rate in such an environment, the Russian government lost an independent monetary policy, putting an excessive weight on the fiscal side of the policy mix. The subsequent liberalization of capital markets turned that exposure into vulnerability. Nevertheless, the Russian Federation persisted in displaying its credibility by adhering to a fixed rate regime. To elaborate, additional vulnerability came from the fact that in 1998 all domestic financial markets were opened to international investors. After Russia was awarded its first financial credit rating in 1996, foreigners were allowed to invest in Russian government bonds, initially only through the primary market. Then, they gradually were allowed to Business Information Service for the Newly Independent States, Commercial Overview of Russia (Washington, DC: Dept. of Commerce, June 1999). 12 13 Estimated by the author from data of State Revenue Service trade fully in the secondary market. With financial liberalization under the fixed exchange regime, the investors in domestic-currency denominated instruments had an opportunity to attack the currency peg (they were finally given an option to expatriate funds)". Also, Russian citizens had no confidence in the policy of the Central Bank at large. For instance, in 1993 and prior to that in 1991, Russia's Central Bank, governed by Viktor Gerashchenko, decided to institute mass exchange of old rubles to new ones. In particular they announced one Saturday that all ruble notes printed before 1993 would be worthless on Monday. The move was designed to gain control of Russia's ballooning money supply. Needless to say many Russians lost money that week and lost their confidence in Central Bank's policies. After that many Russians preferred to keep their savings in hard currency that would be readily available at a premium on the black market". In the summer of 1998 the Central Bank was trying to buy rubles by issuing treasuries at 30%-50% interest rates. However, demand for bonds had plummeted so much that yields were more then 50% and the government failed to sell enough bonds at its weekly auction to refinance its debts1 6 . Additionally, from January to August the Russian stock market lost more than 75% of its value, 39 % in the month of May alone. 7 It is hard to say what came first - a fear of government insolvency in the eyes of Russians, the fact that the Asian currency crises in 1997 fostered a speculative attack on the ruble (due to which Central Bank defended losing nearly $6 billion), or simply that world oil prices fell to $12 per barrel. The history shows that on August 1 7 th of 1998 the Russian Federation was forced to default on its foreign debt and almost simultaneously devalue the ruble (loosing 2/3 or its value), with a moratorium on all payments to foreign creditors. Tatiana Kirsanova, Government Budget, Oil Prices and Currency Crises in Russia, 2002 James Rupert, Washington Post Foreign Service, 1993 16 Shleifer and Treisman, 2000, p. 149 17 A. Chiodo and M. Owyang, A case study of a currency crisis, 2002 14 15 Figure 3.1 Exchange rate volatility Exchange Rate Volatility -+- Exchange Rate -- -- --------- 35.00p. - -- -- - - -- 30.00p. 25.00p. o 20.00p. U) Z 15.OOp. 10.OOp. 5.00p. -P. 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Year Entrance and Exit of the Westerners It was not surprising that many Western companies found themselves in a very difficult situation in the summer of 1998 in Moscow. Many companies came to Moscow right at the initial signs of liberalization and privatization in 1992. U.S. businesses in particular were interested in Russia for very good reasons. Russia has an educated work force, a strategic location straddling two continents, and a generous supply of natural resources, including gold and timber. But energy is the true jewel in the Russian crown. Oil and natural gas represent 60% of Russian exports and 25% of federal revenues. However high American interests were in the stake for Russian natural gas, oil and mining, their participation was intentionally limited at the privatization tables. Instead, familiar multinationals entered markets of consumer products, agriculture, telecommunications and aerospace. The majority of the companies such as Proctor & Gamble, Coca-Cola and Boeing had enough bargaining power to enter into direct partnerships (official or unofficial) with Kremlin administration. For those entering export sectors such as timber and metals, strategic partnerships with the newly developing private sector were more common. Consultancies such as PWC, Ernst & Young and McKinsey were at one or anther time invited by the Russian government to participate in the pricing and restructuring of the industries as well as follow their existing clients who were establishing offices in Moscow. It is interesting to note that the entrance of foreigners was welcomed for different reasons. On one hand Russians viewed western know-how with great respect, but on the other hand they were ready to take any advantage they could of the naive early entrants. Bureaucracy, corruption, and lack of reliable suppliers and distribution systems became a major road-block for the foreign companies. Improved corporate governance was a far-cry from Western standards along with any accounting or reporting procedures. Nevertheless, investment in Russia was viewed by the majority as a long-term investment. 1998 was met in different stages of progress among the foreign community in Russia. By that time some producers had sunk large amounts of capital into the infrastructure for manufacturing, while others had just finished replicating their entire value-chain in order to gain protection from the still volatile political and economical environment. Those raising funds were showing the first signs of positive outlook on early investments. But no one was hurt as much as those engaged in financial-engineering, stocks and elaborate hedging. In 1998 the US Fed had to rescue several funds that were threatening to bring down a major portion of the financial market at home. Many Western companies folded their operations and left Moscow. Companies remaining on the ground through the devaluation and default reported rising inflation and shrinking production. Many had to freeze trade because they could not predict hard currency exchange rates, which were changing daily. All foreign enterprises laid off staff and began observing a "wait and see" policy. However, firms producing in Russia were not cutting back on advertising as much as importers, since foreign companies saw a need to protect and preserve their market share and brand images from domestic producers whose costs were lower than those of foreigners. But companies whose equipment was domestically sourced, or which had paid in full for imported equipment were better able to hold the line on their prices, because their cost of production has not increased. Those that bought equipment on credit with hard currency or leased it under hard currency contracts also needed to increase ruble prices, but faced immediate market-share erosion in the latter case. Many importers as well as locally-producing companies that used foreign ingredients or parts had suffered heavy losses because their revenues were frozen in Russian commercial banks. Companies that accepted rubles for payments could not convert them into hard currency. In such an environment the ruble devaluation benefited Russian exporters as well as producers who faced heavy competition from importers. The weak ruble greatly restricted imports and decreased the purchasing power of Russians to buy foreign products. Some Russian companies were profiting and replacing foreign products in specific market niches. In the short term, few Russian banks became interested in processing operations, but in the long term increasing inflation decreased the benefits to the Russian exporters, since the cost of even domestic inputs rose dramatically. In an effort to alleviate some pain, Russia's State Customs Committee removed the 20% value added tax on imported goods. But the real relief came through new commitment to reforms and subsequent aid from IMF. Another Turn-Around Yeltsin was not expected to do well in the presidential election of June 16, 1996. He had suffered two heart attacks and a drop in popularity as a result of the separatist war in Chechnya and the hardship caused by economic reforms. Still, Yeltsin won the lead over Communist rival Gennady Zyuganov in the June election and defeated him in a runoff in July 1996. But in 1998 Yeltsin's situation was less then promising. After dismissing his entire cabinet and switching prime ministers back and fourth for a period of a year, it became obvious that the one factor that was not changing was Yeltsin himself. Yeltsin had to step down as a leader of the country and a new energetic leader, Vladimir Putin, entered the office. Putin was first appointed by Yeltsin in 1999 and later elected by the people of Russia in 2000. Putin, an ex-KGB field officer and more recently ex-deputy mayor of St. Petersburg, managed to quickly lift the falling spirit of the country. He immediately engaged in a battle with "oligarchs" who were tightly controlling private sector development and withholding taxes from Oil and Gas trade. Putin threatened to cut-off access to the pipeline controlled by the state. But on the other hand he invited them into the Kremlin and reassured of his commitment to end organized crime, support business, and increase the transparency and competitiveness that was needed to enter world markets. Putin lifted foreign exchange control measures introduced after devaluation and began restructuring the entire banking system. Putin was pushing production and output and projected a nominal increase in GDP in 1999. He maintained a flexible exchange rate policy and made an effort to reschedule all Soviet-era debt that was coming due in 19992000. Putin then calmed the public by promising to reform the malfunctioning pension system, land code, contract and investor protection laws. World oil prices were increasing and the Russian stock market responded favorably - up 35% in the three months since Vladimir Putin took over as acting president18 . Along came IMF's aid that approved 17-month credit of $4.5 billon for Russia's 1999-2000 economic programs. Seven installments of $640 million depended on quarterly reviews dependant on performance criteria and structural benchmarks. The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, or EBRD - the biggest single foreign investor in Russia's private sector- returned to favor Putin's policies and signaled the return of investors and foreign operators into Russia. The Real Estate Industry in Russia Before and After 1998 The real estate sector under the centralized economy was in a deteriorated condition at the dawn of the first reforms in 1992. Gosplan (the Central State Planning Committee) designated the amount of funding that was available for all building types, determined the number of square meters to be built, and worked with Gosgrazhdanstroi and Gosstroi (two subordinate committees) to establish the overall construction program for the Soviet Union. Gosstroi was responsible for defining what constituted the main technical and scientific problems in the field of construction and architecture1 9. The concept of a real estate developer as a single governing force behind the process was absent in the system; thus quality control suffered greatly and output rarely satisfied demand for space. Holding real estate as an investment vehicle was also non-existent because all property belonged to the people of the state and was controlled by the government. When Western companies first moved their operations to Moscow in the early 90's, they found a total absence of adequate space for their office workers. Many Western real estate developers and investors became excited about the opportunity arising from the unsatisfied demand for office, retail and industrial space in Russia. The housing market in Russia was off-limits for western developers because of the heavy subsidies for living units 18 By Daniel Williams Washington Post Foreign Service, 1999; Page Al 19 Kimberly McKay, Business opportunities in the Soviet Union. available to Russian companies alone. The Russian government further altered the demand for housing by giving all state-owned housing back to the residents for full ownership. Despite the satisfaction that Russians received by owning their homes, they quickly became aware of the poor conditions of management and quality of the space. New space was needed on the market, yet housing development was still subjected to strict state regulations. Furthermore, the housing market became one of the most corrupt sectors in real estate. Very few foreigners succeeded in office and retail development and investment, and those who did attribute their success mostly to luck. It is not surprising because in the early 90's they faced enormous challenges in regulatory, legal and tax practices, which at the time were developing parallel to the frustration of impatient investors. One of the biggest challenges Westerners faced was an ambiguous system of property rights, which was necessary for financing the development and acquisition of properties. Early years were spent in clarifications and research of the Russian market, which was ill with corruption and lack of recognition of contractual obligations. When the crises of 1998 hit in August, the real estate industry was instantly paralyzed. Those in the middle of construction were forced to stop and abandon their projects. Developers who took out debt financing from various sources left and swore to never do business in Moscow again. The only investors who managed to survive were those who had fully stabilized building. But even the lucky ones experienced the flight of Western tenants. If it was difficult to be in real estate before the crisis, afterwards it was deemed nearly impossible. Nonetheless, the devaluation gave some advantages to Russian investors. Coupled with the rapid recovery of the oil market, new Russian capital began investing into unfinished projects left by the foreigners. Westerners were slow to come back, but the rapid recovery and increased opportunities of 1999 were hard to neglect. Obviously the ones that stayed had an enormous advantage, and for the rest of the days will proudly proclaim that they survived the crisis. It took three years for foreigners to come back into real estate but by this time Russians were dominating the market. English and German investors were first to come back into retail and office construction. There were few US real estate investors before the crisis, and considering that US financial markets suffered the most from the default and devaluation, Americans were extra cautious in their return to Russia. Even today, only a handful of US investors are operating in real estate and most of them are still negotiating their entry. The History of Economic Reforms and the Current Situation Before the crisis of 1998 foreign investors were attracted to Russia because it had various opportunities to buy things at a discount. They also hoped that the reforms dictated by the IMF and World bank would put the Russian economy on its feet and turn their investments into cash cows. However, acquisitions in Russia proved to be difficult to complete since the competition from the Russian black market and the government itself was hard to neglect. The history of economic reforms started with Gorbachev's decree of "cooperatives". Cooperatives were designed to create non-state owned businesses and thus provide an alternative to a centralized economic system. The major flaw in the system was its tax structure. All profits made through non-government contracts were taxed at 90%0. Needless to say it was more than difficult to enter into any legal contract and make a profit. Gorbachev also tried to increase foreign capital flow into the country by instituting a joint venture structure that could theoretically open a still closed economy to foreign participation. Nevertheless, such ventures were highly taxed and profit repatriation was extremely difficult with the non-convertible ruble. However difficult it might have been for foreign businesses to enter the Soviet market, some corporations responded favorably to the first signs of an economic turn-around. One example is the McDonald's Corporation, which entered the market in 1988. A partnership was formed between McDonald's (49%) and Glavobschepit, the food service agency of the City of Moscow. McDonald's brought its experience in building, training and operating, as well as capital, while the City of Moscow contributed real estate and the permission to operate in the city. McDonald's got around the obstacles of profit repatriation by reinvesting sales proceeds into real estate in the center of Moscow. Major foreign tenants paid in hard currency by simply transferring rent into offshore accounts from home base abroad. In later years, ease on repatriation of profits led to most of the buildings being sold to the city of Moscow 2 1 . Today a Moscow operation is the number one profit maker for the entire Corporation. 20 21 From personal experience of trying to start a family owned cooperative in Odessa, Ukraine in 1991. Maximilian Yacoub, McDonald's in Russia, 2002. It was not until Boris Yeltsin stepped into the office of the newly formed Russian Federation cabinet that truly radical economic reforms took place. Until then, all prices were governed by the centrally planned economy, and the prevailing domestic substitution policy was protected by high tariffs and subsidization. In 1992, instigated by policies of "shock therapy" propagated by the IMF, price controls were lifted practically overnight. Because the state did not simultaneously disband the monopolized production and distribution system, the result was hyperinflation and the destruction of personal savings. Incomes fell. Russian industry suffered instant deterioration. Agricultural production dropped. And in came a flood of imports that few could afford. Privatization In an effort to decentralize the Russian economy on August 14, 1992, Yeltsin signed a decree on the institution of the system of privatization checks. Every Russian citizen had those checks, and people could do anything they wanted with the first national stock of new Russia. Those checks theoretically gave the opportunity to the people of Russia to receive a piece of one-third of the national wealth, which was to be exchanged into privatization checks. However, Russians at large didn't know what to do with privatization checks. They didn't understand that they could buy a ticket to an exchange and make a real stock deal. Instead people were trying to sell their checks and get some money for them. Criminal structures were eager to acquire checks at discount and gain control over larger shares of stock, thus creating the first signs of income disparity in the early stages of privatization . Another example of an unprecedented theft became the hand-over of thousands of enterprises to insiders, rather then the public at large. In 1995, Anatoly Chubais, the new deputy prime minister, fostered loans-for-shares privatization. The program distributed Russia's best performing enterprises into the hands of former "apparatchik" and outright criminal elements of the black market. Oil companies like Surgutneftegaz and Sidanko went for bargain prices. Chubais's attitude toward the diversion of aid to shadowy business types was to "let them steal", for money would transform the crooks into legitimate capitalists 2 3 . That of course generated a huge 22 Dmitry Slobodanuk, Pravda.Ru Quoted in Anatol Lieven, Chechnya. Tombstone of a Russian Power (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1998), p. 176. 23 disproportion in income and continuing aggravation of Russians at large. Many commented at the time that "oligarchs" jumped from being to millionaires to billionaires virtually over night. Post-1998 Economic Recovery Today foreigners are attracted to Russia for very different reasons. The investment is still opportunistic but much more conservative at large. The economy proved to be stable and consistent for the past four years after the crisis and with the new leadership of Mr. Putin, it is promising to remain on course. But a closer look may demonstrate that many more issues need to be addressed before it can be considered to be a viable investment. The Russian economy grew at a relatively fast pace in 1999-2000, changing the social and economic face of the country. However, much of the capacity for further growth, based on increased output using existing capacities, the mobilization of temporarily available labor resources, and the channeling of financing into the industrial sector, has been exhausted. Those opportunities originally arose as a direct consequence of the 1998 crisis (the devaluation effect, reduced yields on government bonds, etc.) and the favorable global economic environment. This is why we are now seeing a slow-down in economic growth. Economic growth in 1999-2002 followed a parabolic line, with industrial output falling from 11.9% in 2000 to 4.9% in 2001, and 3.7% in 2002. Accordingly, GDP growth fell from 9.9% to 5.2% and 3.9% in 2002. If the Russian economy continues to evolve through inertia along these lines, economic growth rates will continue to fall and the economy may even contract. If such an outcome is to be averted, however, a whole new set of factors has to be considered: Growth in the export sector outstripped growth in the domestic consumption sector. The oil and gas sector expanded by 8%, while the non-ferrous metals sector expanded by 9%25. Secondary industries focused on domestic consumption grew at a substantially lower pace. This means that Russia's raw materials sectors are expanding at the expense of other sectors offering greater added value. Thus there is the potential of GDP growth converging 24 25 Ministry of Economic Development and Trade Goskomstat with growth in raw materials exports, and with the fall of oil prices this could threaten the entire economy again. At the same time the share of conglomerates that made their capital in oil and gas is increasing; the gap between the rich and the poor is widening. A similar picture is observed with the regions. There is a saying in Moscow that everything would be even better if the rest of Russia wasn't there. Also as the laws are being signed their actual implementation is lagging. For instance, there is no clear mechanism for the implementation of the land code itself. As it is, it's open to interpretation and misuse by such cities as Moscow. Growth in consumer demand, which so far has been a major factor for growth, has not been accompanied by increased productivity and investment demand, and thus, sooner or later, will be negated. Imports will increase, and in the worst case we will see a disproportional relationship between disposable income and prices for goods and services. By the year 2003 cumulative FDI are at $18.6b. The largest investors in the economy were: United States (22%), Cyprus (19%), the Netherlands (12%), the UK (11%) and Germany (8%). It is interesting to note that Cyprus is a favored offshore zone for Russian capital. Effectively the investment was rerouted back from "Russian" companies 26 . It also should be pointed out that most of the investments during the past two years can be classified as venture capital, which will be withdrawn if the environment becomes less favorable. In 2002, there was a sharp decline in the growth of investments into fixed capital. According to Goskomstat, in 2002 the growth of investments into fixed capital was only 2.6%. This can be partially explained by the reinvestments into the oil industry. But for the fist time since 1999, investment growth fell behind production growth. The Russian economy in the past four years has been characterized by a very high degree of savings (30-35% of GDP). In this share Russia holds the third position among major economies, behind China and Malaysia. At the same time, almost half of the savings are used to repay foreign debt and finance capital outflow. The macroeconomic situation in the Russian economy is still stable, and there is every reason to predict that economic growth in 2003 will continue, as investments whose rates decelerated somewhat will increase. However, negative tendencies show that the economy is under threat of 26 Economist Intelligence Unit stagnation and is seriously dependent on the world oil price. Fuel commodity stabilization is not supported by the emergence of the market of new export products with high added value. An institutional environment conducive to investment and commercial activities and transformation of the people's savings into investments has not materialized. Modernization processes are still slow both due to lack of investment resources and low incentives for business entities. Could it be that American investors have a low risk tolerance with Russia due to the economic stability on the surface but high possibility for another crisis underneath? My quick survey of the major US investors shows that when it comes to emerging market investments, China, India and Brazil are still considered first before Russia. Thus the inability to forget the 1998 crisis and the tendency to use a magnifying glass evaluation of the economy is still reality when it comes to the Russia proposition. Oil and the Russian Economy Today A regression shows that federal budget revenues were highly dependent on world oil prices in September 1998 and December 2000: each extra dollar per barrel of oil corresponded to an extra RUB 10 billion to RUB 11 billion of monthly budget revenues in 1999 and RUB 12 billion to 13 billion in 2000. Figure 3.2 World oil prices -- US dollars per barrel World Oil Prices $30.00 $25.00 V $20.00 $15.00 $10.00 $5.00 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Year 2000 2001 2002 2003 In 2001 there were some structural changes in the economy, and as a result the correlation between the budget revenues and oil prices was disrupted. However, in 2002 there was a relatively strong correspondence between budget revenues and the fluctuation of world oil prices. Roughly, each dollar of the oil price results in RUB 23 billion of budget revenue monthly. The correspondence was less evident than in 1998-2000, but still significant. There are therefore reasons to believe that a drop in oil prices will result in problems for the Russian budget coupled with foreign debt repayments to the Paris club scheduled for 2004. According to BP, Russia's proven oil reserves increased 23% during 2002, while output averaged 7.7mn barrels per day, second only to Saudi Arabia2 7 The situation in the OPEC is such that any agreement is difficult to reach between the members. In the current situation, even with the slow recovery of Iraq there are some 8 million barrels from the reserves that are put up for sale. By the end of the year the export from Iraq might reach 2.5 million barrels a day. If the world production is not reduced, the reduction of the price to $19-20 is inevitable. There are at least two countries that are against the reduction in the production volume - Algeria and Nigeria. They opened to international investors who invested heavily in the production, and they need to maintain maximum output to justify the investment. Additionally, if the political disputes were resolved in Venezuela the world production would increase. It is interesting to note that Saudi Arabia usually benefits more from the reduction since they hold 32% of the world production. Based on the lobbying by the United States, the Saudis had also reduced their production in 1998 in order to up the price on the world markets. The request was intended to help Russia, as well as to return their capital on the investments they made in the Caspian region and Western Africa. Additionally, Americans are investing in Iraq to secure the production of the restored oil sector. Their investment in Iraq has to be around 100 billion dollars; obviously low prices on oil would not satisfy Americans as well. If the prices drop below $20 per barrel American production in Texas might be in danger. The vehicle for the control of Iraq's oil is the process of privatization which Americans are structuring in the new "free" Iraq. As foreign investors are welcomed to the privatization rounds, very few can afford to participate, politically and economically. Nevertheless, the former head of the Saudi Ministry of Oil, Zaki Yamani, believes that the future export of 27 Economist Intelligence Unit and OPEC oil that Americans secured in Iraq will eventually (within 10 years) bring prices to the midteens. By that time all of the investments would be returned and it might not matter for the biggest consumer. However it presents a great danger for the Russian Federation as they have an artificial deadline to diversify their economy. As the dependency on Russian oil might diminish in Europe due to the new exports by Americans from Iraq through the Israeli city Haifa, Russians are looking to open Siberian oil to either Japan or a promising economic giant, China. To brace for the impact Russia is also collecting a special fund for "rainy days" to buy time. But whether or not American investors believe all the precautionary measures that Russians are putting forth in preparation for the hit still remains to be seen. Legislative Issues The quality of laws remains an essential problem in Russia. This can be partially attributed to errors and the insufficient qualifications of lawmakers, who are not always able to anticipate the specific consequences of applying the law. At times, this is the result of a compromise seeking to put together various proposals from lobbying groups. For instance, the bankruptcy law and the Tax Code chapter on the taxation of small business entities were subject to repeated amendments. Oddly enough, Russian laws are often excessively detailed, yet insufficiently specific, and cannot be implemented without additional clarifications and additions. There also remains an issue involving the late development of by-laws, which are essential to making new laws workable, regardless of how liberal, progressive, or timely they seem. As the key problem for the Russian economy is weak enforcement, it is also essential to improve judicial proceedings. Presidential and Parliamentary Elections To a large extent the current political situation is a consequence of the historic absence of democratic traditions, the totalitarian heritage, traditionally paternalistic governmental policies, and the absence of effective and influential institutions of civil society over a period of many decades. The disparity of power between the office of the president and the people and organizations with influence on the government represents one of the main obstacles to a coherent government policy and effective structural reforms. Broad sections of the political elite habitually shirk their responsibility to formulate and implement government policy during difficult periods that call for reforms, which inevitably leads to the redistribution of wealth from certain categories of economic agents to others, who continue to thrive based on their position in the social hierarchy. Government policy and reform efforts are being carried out in a context of covert and opportunistic resistance from opponents of reform, who, while being too weak to call a halt to the reform process, are strong enough to slow the process down and distort its realization. This creates certain political risks for the Russian economy. The system of the government is inherently unstable owing to the colossal role played by the office of the president, and the absence of the stable political system capable of assuring the continuity of government policy during and after the presidential elections. This in turn means that reform is only possible when public confidence in the president is high. However, public confidence in institutions such as the office of the president is unstable. If public confidence in the president falls, it brings down with it the president's influence on the reform process in particular and the broader social and economic situation as a whole. The Russian leadership has stated its intention of intensifying the reform drive in 2003. However, the fact that parliamentary and presidential elections are due to take place in December 2003 and April 2004, respectively, suggests that although the legislative effort may well continue, the prospects for real progress on the reform front in the coming year are not great. If the reform process is postponed until 2005, we will only begin seeing tangible results in terms of increased investment and economic growth in 2006-2007. That is incompatible with the government's long-term economic growth strategy on the one hand, and raises the risk of economic crisis on the other. The structural and institutional reforms required by the Russian economy were defined back in 2000, and the conceptual framework for most of them is set forth in the Gref Program. However, due to enchantment from high economic performance, the pressure from the lobby groups, resistance from public service, and a reluctance on the part of the authorities to destabilize the social situation on the eve of the parliamentary and presidential elections, the reform process lost momentum. Much of the stability in the country, politically and economically, can be attributed to the leadership of Mr. Putin. Opinion polls show that President Putin enjoys a high level of public approval for his overall performance and his re-election as President in March 2004 appears virtually assured. Consequently the political risk of Putin not being able to continue with his restructuring of the Russian Federation appears to be low. Debt Markets Domestic Government Debt The Russian debt market has three components: the government sector, municipal sector and corporate sector. The Government sector, represented by the issuance of T-bills and T-bonds, is very stagnant. There simply hasn't been any new issuance into the market. It is not very dynamic simply because its primary buyers are state-owned or statecontrolled entities. According to the Central Bank of Russia, the total market value of all GKO's and OFZ outstanding amounts to some RUB 218 billion. If it hadn't been for the slight expansion in the market during 2002, it would already have folded completely. Comparing the capacity of the Russian domestic bonds market with that of other countries at the end of 2001 reveals a depressing picture. Russian domestic government bonds outstanding expressed as proportion of GDP amount to about 2% - the lowest level in the world 2 8 . In the US, the level is 87%, in Czech Republic and Hungary - 36%, in India 27%, in China - 23%, and even Argentina - 9%. The low capacity of the market means that it cannot be used for the macroeconomic regulation process. Sustainable economic development requires mechanisms that enable the monetary mass, interest rate, and other macroeconomic parameters to be controlled. In other countries, the government bond market provides that mechanism. The interest rate (yield) on the government bond market acts as a guide-line for other sectors of the financial market, and first and foremost of the corporate bond market. Unfortunately, the financial sector continues to be dominated by traditionalists, who believe that the issue of government debt and budgetary deficits are one and the same. In the US, meanwhile, about US$3 trillion of a total of US$8 trillion in domestic government bonds is the Treasury Papers. The bulk of the US government bond market is made up of mortgage bonds, which are used by tens of millions of Americans to buy homes. Government borrowing is an important factor for kick-starting the investment process in sectors and regions that are unable to attract private capital on their own. This is not the case in Russia. 28 Yuri Danilov. Indicator 2002, issue 11. On the Municipal side there are 47 bonds in circulation, with Moscow taking the largest share of the market. But the development of the market will be limited by new federal restrictions on the funding requirements in the amount of debt ratio of the local governments. Corporate Debt The corporate side the bond market in Russia was virtually non-existent until 2001. The issue was not necessarily with the perceived interest rate risk or fear of inflation, but the with liquidity. Gradually the maturity of the bonds was raised from 3 months to 16, 18 and now up to two-year transactions with minimal intermediary costs. The reason for this change is the increased inflow of capital, which is returning back from companies' accounts overseas and being reinvested locally. It is not surprising that before and shortly after the crisis in 1998 many domestic corporations were transferring money offshore, thus diminishing the muscle of the market. Now with improved corporate governance and numerous reforms this capital is coming back to aid the development of the corporate debt market. The outflow of capital decreased from 20 billion last year to less then 10 billion today. Also last year the amount of money entering the country exceeded the amount leaving the country. Thus with declining country risk, declining inflation and increased liquidity the market grew from 2 billion dollars to 4 billion in a period of a year. The daily trading is estimated at 50 million dollars and will likely increase as the yields have collapsed and are down from 20-23 percent to 14-18. The investment specialists at Renaissance Capital in Moscow are predicting next year issuance to be nearing single digits and overall market capitalization of 5 billion dollars by the end of the year, growing to 10-15 by 2004. As the yields are coming down the market will increase in its volume due to the perceived liquidity as well. It is a radical change from three years ago when few large banks held corporate bonds at high par without further sales. The number of banks participating in the transactions is now up to 30 with the recent addition of the insurance sector. The reason for the past cautious approach to the debt side of the market is partly explained by cultural factors. Russians still have a negative attitude toward taking on debt. It took time for people to start realizing that the risk of borrowing can be rewarded with higher returns. Nevertheless many still perceive debt as a "sell out". Others have the unfortunate attitude that borrowed money is just a "freebie", and they borrow without taking any contracts seriously. There prevalence of such dealers is diminishing as the court system is getting more and more developed in Russia. The growth of the corporate bond market, which is the closest counterpart to the CMBS and RMBS markets in the US, is partly due to the inefficiency of the Russian banking system. Compared to the banking sector, the corporate bond market is much more transparent and the pricing mechanisms are much more competitive. Because of this efficiency the cost of capital will be lower than for bank loans. Therefore, the money will go where the highest returns are. Another reason for the bond market to take business away from banks is that Russian banks issue loans in dollars, but in the emerging market economy firms are receiving their revenues in rubles. This means there is always the risk of devaluation. Thus it is safer to raise debt in rubles and have a perfect currency matching. Also there is still credit risk with the bank institution in Russia; this is one more thing that is eliminated in the bond issuance process. Despite the warning, Russian companies borrowed quite a lot in recent years from the issuance of their Eurobonds: Graph 3.329 Gross Russian corporatebond placement (US$ mn) $3,000.00 0 Eurobonds - $2,500.00 $2,000.00 Value $1,500.00 $1,000.00 $500.00 1999 2001 2000 Year 29 EY assembled data 2002 Further expansion of the corporate bond market will be due to new pension reform that is scheduled to be in effect by the first quarter of 2004. The system will change from the payas-you-go system to a fully funded system, which will allow Russian pension funds to invest in non-governmental securities. As the economy leverages itself out the system will become more and more vulnerable to major economy shocks due to the dependence of the economy on commodity prices. The specialists in Renaissance Capital believe that the next major crisis would not come from the government-led debt problem, but from the corporate-led debt problem. However there is a reason to believe that after-crises the restructuring the assets will finally concentrated in the hands of more sophisticated players and the market once again will allocate the resources efficiently. Banking Sector One of the most talked-about issues related to Russian accession into the WTO is the reform of the banking sector. The requirement for WTO accession is reduction of barriers to entry for international firms. Foreign capital can re-capitalize the banking system, increase domestic competition to benefit consumers, and help build confidence in the sector. But low capitalization isn't the only issue with the sector. The situation is such that only a few state-owned banks are dominating the banking sector. At the same time there are a number of smaller banks, which are not really banks, but a financial institutions of the large conglomerates, which in are in turn only financing their owners. There are no standards for financial reporting and transparency in the country. The Federal Government does not yet insure bank deposits. Despite the fact that credits to the private sector increased to 20% of GDP and there has been an inflow of money into the country, the bankruptcy and money laundering laws has just been instituted but not yet tested by the market. Living primarily on deposits, Russian banking is missing its most important element - the flow of money that generates capital. The danger is also the volume of currency inflow into the country. In the last ten years 250 billion dollars was transferred out of the country, as compared to last year's GDP of 340 billion. Today the inflow of capital is 5% of the GDP but with stability and a favorable economic situation it can increase to 10%-15%. This would be is on top of the inflows from the exports of natural resources. Inflow of petrodollars is threatening to destabilize the domestic economy. Hard currency inflows are pressuring the ruble higher, especially against the US dollar. In an effort to slow the upward movement of the ruble, the central bank halved the proportion of hard currency earnings exporters are required to exchange for rubles, from 50% to 25%30. The real issue is that the banking system is unable to process and hold such a volume and is in danger of total collapse in the not-so-distant future. The immature banking sector would have to issue new loans in order to preserve the value of money, but without real experience in underwriting procedures or depth in risk evaluation and credit history research, many loans might default and will eventually cause a domino effect in the whole financial sector. Real Estate Lending There are very few institutions in Moscow that lend money for real estate projects. With the exception of the three, there virtually are no foreign banks on the debt side of real estate. The risks are just too high for domestic investors and are even higher for foreign investors. To start with, the law in Russia does not recognize the concept of step-in rights for secured lenders. Any enforcement will take the security of the asset being charged and put it on the proceeds sale; avoiding the holder of the mortgage. The only enforcement of the «mortgage in possession is via (i) judicial proceedings and (ii) a public auction. The pre-lease agreements are not recognized by registration bodies like Moscomregistratsiya. (Legal rights registration agency). A Debt Service Reserve Account is hardly possible in Russia, since its enforcement is complicated and problematic. To avoid some of the risks, several banks are coming out with the Mortgage Bond Issue. Under the issue the bonds are secured by the pledge of the real estate object, then a bank forms an underwriting syndicate and the bank acts as an agent for placing shares. This innovation is very similar to the CMBS in the US, but the construction financing securitization is too high of a risk in Moscow. So far there are no issues of such structure. First and foremost, banks require collateral. The collateral is required on four levels. The first, most common in all parts of the world, is the ownership rights to the land (or the rights to the lease in Moscow) and the building to be constructed. Second is the collateral unrelated to the development project from the LLC (limited liability company), that is developing the project in the amount of the loan. Third is the collateral from the parent company that is a general partner in the LLC. And fourth is the guarantee from the 30 Economist Intelligence Unit third party individual or company. All assets or rights to the collateral held by the bank have to be insured. The insurance for the property shall be assigned to the bank. If the project is developed as a rental property, the bank has to hold rights to the leases and the agreement of sale with respect to the sale of the property. The letter from the parent company shall be provided for additional financing in cases of cost overruns during construction. An equity position for the bank is not accepted as collateral. If the parent company is offering its stock as collateral all books must be opened for review by the bank. The banks also require partial pre-leasing of the property as well as the construction completion guarantee from the general contractor. Most of the banks finance 50-65% of the construction cost, with a rate of 13-15% for a period of 3 years with a grace period of 18-24 months. The permanent financing is of a similar character with 6-year full amortization and an interest rate of 9-12%. The following is the comparison table for permanent financing with developed and developing countries: Table 3.1 Country indicatorsforpermanent debt placement Russia USA Japan Central Europe LTV Rate Amortization 50-65% 70-80% 80% 65-75% 9% 5-6% 2.50% 2.25% 6 years 25-30 years 30 years 15-18 years The reason for the banks to hold ownership of the asset other than the project is the risk that the developer does not have either proper documentation or simply does not own the building until it is fully complete, inspected and transferred into ownership from the city. The immature bankruptcy law is another reason for the strict requirements by the banks. Hernando de Soto on Land as the Source of Capital In his book «The Mystery of Capital , Hernando de Soto argues that most of the developing countries already possess the assets they need to make a success of capitalism. Capital is prevalent in the underdeveloped world, but it is held in defective forms. Even the poorest people have the ability to extract capital from things we know exist but cannot see. But the mystery of capital is one that needs to be unlocked by the third world, and the new force that raises productivity of labor and creates wealth of nations can finally be put to use. In his book he presents five mysteries of capital: * The mystery of missing information is the lack of properly documented systems or capacity for accumulating assets. * The mystery of capital is the way capital relates to money. * The mystery of political awareness is the capital result of the movement of population into the cities. * The missing lesson of US history is the missing documented path to success of the capitalist system. * The mystery of legal failure is the lack of property law in the third world. a'magine a country where nobody can identify who owns what, addresses can not be easily verified, people can not be made to pay their debts, resources can not conveniently be turned into money, ownership can not be divided into shares, description of assets is not standardizedand can not be easily compared, and the rules that govern property varyfrom neighborhoodto neighborhoodor even from street to street. You have just put yourself into the lfe of a developing country or former communist nation.>> Hernando de Soto. There is no reason to deny that Russia in 1992 fit the description painted by De Soto in this quote. However, much has been done since then and many intangible assets have been converted into capital in Russia. The emergence of the equity and debt markets gave way to secondary markets, and the Federal Land Code of 2001 fostered the new wave of land privatization. The legal and administrative environment has been improved and tax and labor codes have brought transparency to the country. Nevertheless, «the mystery of missing information is yet to be unlocked by Russians. Moscow's land development and land rights remains the worst if one considers the amount of «dead capital in the city. The absence of direct land ownership in Moscow limits the ability to use land as collateral for a loan. Even if the potential borrowers own buildings but have only use-rights for land, bankers do not include a potential land value in the property's mortgage value. As a result, the mortgage value, which can unlock the mystery of capital for Moscow, is reduced. Secondly, the inability to recycle land for new use, which results from absence of land ownership, postpones redevelopment and involvement of urban land in economic turnover. (See section Land Use Segmentation in Moscow) The resistance to change comes from Moscow authorities of various levels, who are unable to let go of land since it seems to be their most abandoned source of control. Land Ownership Rights & Development in Moscow On July 3, 1997 the Russian Federation adopted a new Land Ownership Registration Act and in October 2001 the Land Code was signed which was supposed to facilitate outright land ownership by non-governmental organizations and private individuals. At the same time the Federal government transferred the control of approvals for the development of plots unoccupied by federal or local governments into the hands of local municipalities. Under the new code two forms of land development are offered to future developers. One form is without municipal predevelopment documentation and price. The other form is with a schematic development plan pre-approved by the municipality for the given plot of land and a stated price. In the latter case city government already predetermines use classification for the potential project, available number of square meters for the site, set-backs and other limits of construction and price of the plot. Generally, the disposition of plots differs with each form of land development. In the first case the city government organizes a competition for best price/ use development or simply waits for an interest from the private sector in a particular plot of land. In the case of a predetermined scheme, the municipality offers the plots to certain individuals or organizations that are capable of implementation of the predetermined development scheme. Obviously both methods are open to a number of subjective decisions which leaves numerous opportunities for corruption and self-dealing. So far no rule has been developed for the clear implementation of either method of disposition. In either case local governments only receive 50% of proceeds from sale of land, and the rest is allocated to the federal and regional governments. The method favored by the local governments is the one without pre-approved documentation and price. In this case they can gain from sale in various forms. One form of gain that remains undetected by the federal government is a forceful share in the ownership of the future development in its physical form or stocks of the holding company of the project. Therefore any further entrance of the project into the secondary market for resale or lease-hold is blocked by the partnership with the governmental agencies. Further, no mechanism exists for the sub-division of land between municipal share of the project and a private owner in the case of physical ownership, which makes the private sector forever married to a given municipality. Despite the fact that the federal government clearly stated its intentions in the land code for the development of zones with pre-determined use parameters, it also allowed for individual case-by-case use determination. Thus, instead of a unified zoning plan, the land approval process is separately investigated and determined by the municipal boards of architects and urban development organs. It is obvious that municipal share from the proceeds can only grow under the case-by-case determination method. Many municipalities hide behind the budget deficit statements, which delays the development of comprehensive zoning parameters. Even if the comprehensive package of allowable construction parameters is developed for a given plot, it often is unacceptable for the profit driven private sector. The city of Moscow has by far the most complicated set of approvals on land development. Right after the land code was signed by the state Duma, mayor of Moscow Mr. Luzhkov quickly signed a decree which states that the city of Moscow will only enter into the leasehold agreements (25 and 49 years with extension rights) with potential developers. Under no circumstances will it sell the land outright based on the very low prices (in his opinion) set by the federal government. The division of ownership between federal and city owned land is the source of many disputes between the two parties. But in this dispute, mayor Luzhkov seems to be a bit more aggressive in his position. The federation is constantly threatening to reevaluate the division with a potential 20% reclaimed by the Fed. Currently less then 20 entities are occupied by federal organizations, including the Kremlin, Supreme Court, Constitutional Court, and Federation Council. The city is split into 10 administrative areas and 125 districts. It should be noted however that they do not coincide with the administrative divisions. The land tax structure in Moscow is based on the cadastre blocks. There are some 14 categories of value, depending on how the land is used or intended to be used. Cafes and restaurants are in one category, industrial enterprises are in another, for example. The value of each cadastre is then multiplied by the usable square meters and then by the appropriate tax to determine the payment. The cadastre value also varies with location, i.e. its proximity to landmarks and transportation nodes. But the cadastre values do not reflect the market price of land; it is an approximation that is quite artificial. Currently, the cadastre for Moscow has not yet been approved and no precise figures are available. Based on this decree any developer has to first acquire the rights to investigate the possibility of development - (the equivalent of the sales and purchase agreement in US but with no guarantee on the part of the city), and then purchase the rights to produce a project for the site. Then, after the formal agreement by the city, the developer may purchase the rights to lease a given plot. All three steps might take from a year to a year and a half, with numerous associated expenses. The developer can never be certain whether he will be allowed to construct the desired project or not. Parallel to that there is no mechanism to prevent one's competitor from going through the same process for the same site. There also is not guarantee that adjacent plots would not be developed as a negative externality to the proposed project. In the absence of zoning there is no way to know what exactly will be coming "next door" in the near future. Land Lease Rights Acquisition and Approval Risks The first risk element in the process is the identification of the existing ownership of a given plot of land. The only way to discover the availability of the site and the ownership structure is through private relationships with various Moscow city organizations, which on your behalf (for an undisclosed fee) will further set in motion their connections and relationships to uncover a vague answer on the developer's request. One of the cleanest methods to retain the information is to hire the so called lobbyists who will contact an associated deputy of the Moscow city Duma who would in turn put in the deputy's request for information. The Deputy's request by law has to be answered by the city but can come in various degrees of certainty. It is hard to estimate the time and money dedicated to this stage, but it probably is the least expensive and efficient method. This procedure would have to be employed for each individual site separately. Once the developer determines the ownership structure, there is virtually no way to insure that the owner's documentation for the ownership of the site is indeed correct. There are no underwriters as in US who can guarantee that in a few years some governmental agency such as a university or a municipal sewer committee would not claim the rights to the site with a document that was not found through the due diligence process. Additionally, as-ofright development documentation for the site disclosed through the lobbying process would most likely not satisfy the developer because the existing approved schemes for each site were developed many years ago and were never updated. Thus he would have to go through the rezoning or reconditioning of the design parameters set by the city. But that is not after he would have to negotiate with the seller (a hypothetical city agency which owns the site) on the purchase of the rights for the feasibility of the project. The price for the land in Moscow is also ambiguous and intentionally not disclosed by the agencies. The determination seems arbitrary. It depends on the proximity to the metro station and to the historic center, but is never quantified by any method. Latest land rights sales range from US $6m. to US $8m. for a hectare (107,639 sq. ft.). Assuming that the developer reaches an agreement with the governmental agency, he then has to submit his architectural concept for the site to the Moscow Committee on Architecture and Urban Planning (Moscomarchitektura); this agency will determine the use group, number of square meters, property lines and over-all design style of the building including the color scheme. There are some 200 parameters that the Committee uses in the evaluation of the proposal. The codes are available and published in a form of a SNIPS Code (similar to Uniform Building Code in US) and supporting directives that have stylistic orientation. The issue for example, could be with the adjacent buildings- whose size and shapes determine the shade and light pattern of the neighborhood. Any proposed building might cast a shadow on a playground or a metro station in a way that is unacceptable for the Committee. The example is only one of many parameters in the evaluation, which obviously is exposed to corruption and self-dealing. It is estimated that from the first rendering to the final approved elevations and plans for the site the developer must allot up to a year and a half. The end result is a list of signatures from up to 29 agencies related or vaguely associated with Moscomarchitektura. One of the biggest risks is not from the local fire department or a municipal sewer agency - it is with from the local district committee which in turn can require so called linkages as we know them in US. A new school or an exit ramp can be forced on the developer in turn for the much needed signature. Any and all of the risks associated with this stage in the development are not quantifiable and are a reality of an emerging market environment. To summarize at this point, it is interesting to note that unlike in the US, architects have a lot more control over the face of the Moscow streetscape. The developer has virtually no say in the determination of the shape, number of stories or style of the building. He simply has to evaluate an already negotiated project from the cost benefit standpoint and either forfeit or go forward with the project. Hopefully the architect and the lobbyists employed by the developer have enough experience and relationships with the city architects, and the approximate FAR desired by the developer could be achieved with a minimal amount of cupolas on the fagade of the building. The Institute of Urban Economics in Moscow estimated that 40 city agencies are involved in the process; the developer has to produce 77 official documents for the approval with 4-6 contacts for the same agency on average. After the approval of already detailed documentation, the developer may purchase his final land lease rights from the Moscow government in the face of the representative agency who is the seller of the site. In the rare case of private ownership, the owner has to repurchase the rights for the leasehold and still enter into the concept approval process with the Moscomarchitektura, regardless of the previously approved scheme for the site. This virtually eliminates land speculation and at the same time diminishes the value of the subdivision and ready-to-go approvals, as we know them in US. To detail this point - there is no value created in the receipt of the approvals if the given developer does not develop the site himself. The way around it is found through the purchase of the organization that lobbied for the project, i.e. original developer, but there are no guarantees that such organization doesn't own other assets or holds an unacceptable amount of debt from the previous project. There are numerous construction risks that are standard across the borders, but one issue is unique to the process - the developer does not own the building until it is complete and approved by the city inspectors. Only then is it allowed into the ownership through the official entry with Moscomzem - Moscow Committee on Land. There also are so called "special investment projects" that guarantee the developers immunity from future increase in taxation and the return on investment. This so far is the only vehicle to aid the private sector in the development process. However, most of the projects offered with such status are either unfeasible or highly political. The only reason for the City of Moscow to offer such guarantees is the share of the project proceeds that is negotiated in the beginning of the project. Needless to say, the city of Moscow has their preferred group of developers who are selected for the few reasonable projects. Many companies are partly owned by the state through some opaque, convoluted structure. Additional breaks offered to the foreign investor include immunization to the changes that may affect the return for a period of seven years. In the volatile environment of the Russian emerging market where laws are being revised every other month this would seem like a reasonable protection. However, this might be neglected in cases where the interests of the Federation might change in circumstances such as profit repatriation and tariffs important in development and construction. Also, the building and the land can be taken by the government - eminent domain; but not without compensation to the developer. The determination of the compensation is not yet determined by any decree. To summarize the risks: * No Zoning, no method to calculate FAR; each site is considered individually. + One has to first buy the right to develop land without knowing what can actually be developed. + No rules to calculate the escalators for land rent. + Lack of secure building rights during the construction period, since titles and longterm land lease agreements are available only after construction is completed. + Unreliable real property registration system. + Uncertainty concerning the expense requirements imposed by the city. Russian investors are apparently less concerned about these problems, although the absence of mortgagable right during construction is an issue for them as well. The courage of Russians to invest under uncertain and unclear conditions can presumably be explained by their relative inexperience and, in some cases, the priority of money laundering over investment return. Construction The Russian construction industry remains highly inefficient, with a great deal of power remaining with the large kombinat enterprises inherited from the Soviet past. Their power lays in relationships with the municipal agencies that provide land and construction approval, and in priority access to construction materials, both from established networks and from direct control (vertical integration). The construction scene in Moscow is still dominated by the Glavmosstroi, which was designed in the Soviet era to perform construction for the state. The function of the new Glavmosstroi is still the same government contracts financed with the state's and the city of Moscow's budgets. However, the function of the organization changed with the economy. Now it's a holding company that owns other construction companies while merely passing along the money received from the government budget. The trick is that it does not pay all at once but over a period of time after construction. The system is such that the contractor is getting paid first without the ability to pay the sub-contractor. The sub-contractor is the lag in the system. The general contractor first reports to Glavmosstroi on the work performed by the subcontractor and then Glavmosstroi pays directly to the sub-contractor without holding the contract with the party. Another trick is that the contractors are getting paid in bonds that are bought by Glavmosstroi from the Independent Construction Bank. If the contractor wants to get cash from the bank he is forced to wait until the maturity of the bond or take a loss on the redemption. Despite the situation many construction companies are tied to government work. They were developed in the Soviet era and are staffed for large capacity projects that only come from the city or the state. In order to survive they have to stick with Glavmosstroi's system. In such conditions contractors and sub-contractors are losing qualified workers and are cutting corners with substitutions, safety requirements and overall quality of work. It is interesting to note that Glavmosstroi has a small development arm that is supposedly financed out of the private funds separate from governmental moneys. This small business is advertising luxury condominiums at a high price. It would be safe to consider that the money delayed from the payments to construction companies for the municipal projects could be at work here. Legal Issues and Taxation There have been some significant improvements in the tax structure of the Federation. Lower tax rates and an improved tax administration have allowed the government to reduce the tax burden on the economy, yet the budget revenues have also grown thanks to the expansion of the tax base by 3% of GDP3 1 . A new procedure for the taxation of corporate profit came into effect in 2002: the profit tax rate was brought down from 35% to 24%; and the list of legal exemptions was expanded. Capital gains tax was also reduced to 20/24% and the loss carry-forward is now set at 10 years. However, only 30% of any current year profits may be sheltered with prior year losses. Value added tax (VAT) was also reduced to 20% and is expected to be further reduced by 2004. The privileges for investment were abolished, and instead the depreciation rate was accelerated. Personal income tax since 2001 is a flat rate of 13%. But further targeted reduction in taxes might lead to some unexpected consequences. For instance, the intended lowering of Unified Social Tax (currently 35.7%) will lower the excess tax pressure on businesses and stimulate economic growth, but Russia's pension age is one of the lowest in the world (55 years for women and 60 for men), and in a few years, due to the specific age structure of the population, the share of the pensioners will sharply increase. In Russia, for every 100 workers there are 69.2 pensioners, while in Germany there are 55.3, and in the UK 40.6. Russia might have to accept the painful, but absolutely necessary, decision to increase the retirement age. Amounts of tax paid in accordance with the legislation of foreign countries by a Russian organization shall be credited against the Russian tax payable by this organization. In this respect, the total amount of taxes paid outside of Russia and subject to credit may not exceed the amount of tax payable in Russia. The foreign tax on dividends received from foreign sources, however, can be credited against the Russian tax only if such credit is provided for by the double tax treaty (with the US in this instance). For other types of income, a tax credit can be made regardless of whether a treaty exists. Interest expense paid to a bank or non-bank company is deductible subject to arm's length and thin capitalization tests (a debt to equity ratio of 3:1, or 12.5:1 for banks and 31 32 American Chamber of Commers in Moscow Tax Code leasing businesses). Thus, interest on any type of loan taken out to finance business related expenses (current or capital expenses) is tax deductible. Interest expense on funds used to acquire or construct capital assets will be deductible against operating income. Generally, this was not previously deductible, although certain double tax treaties allowed deductibility where shareholders were resident in such countries. For real estate, stamp duty is not payable on real estate transfers, share sales or leases. Land tax is fixed and paid quarterly based on the charges set by the government. The tax determined based on location, proximity to metro, main roads etc. Complex ratios are used but the charges are relatively minor. The Transfer tax is paid as VAT on a building's value paid by the purchaser. However, recent changes may allow for full recovery of payments. Capital gains tax is present in all transactions. Input VAT charged, but only recoverable on completion and use of construction projects against rental income. Nevertheless if the tenant is a foreign representative office it is exempt from paying VAT, therefore full recovery may not be possible. Asset tax (up to 2%) is levied on net book value of property and fixed assets. This usually is recovered via service charges and is exempt during construction. Property's useful life is set to 30 years, with annual depreciation of 3.32%. Structuring Foreign Investment in Russian Real Estate It is uncommon for foreign investors to conduct real business in Russia through a branch of a foreign company. So, the classic offshore structure for the investment in Russian real estate proves to be very efficient. In this case, the foreign institution establishes an offshore development/ construction company that will in turn establish an SPV (special purpose vehicle) in Russia to hold the property. If a Russian company owns substantial real estate (more then 50% of its total assets), then it is advisable for an offshore holding entity to be located in a country with which Russia has a tax treaty. Capital gains from sales of shares in such Russian real estate companies are subject to a 20% capital gains tax in Russia unless exempt under a tax treaty. If the Russian company pays dividends, a tax treaty will reduce the normal 15% Russian dividend withholding tax to 10%, 5% or even to 0%. Cyprus has been the most popular location for such companies. Cyprus has a tax treaty with Russia and also has a low income tax rate for such offshore companies. Some investors in Russian real estate prefer the Netherlands, Luxemburg or Denmark. These three countries have participation exemptions that exempt them from local tax dividends and capital gains on qualifying investments. The Netherlands and Luxemburg also permit the tax-efficient repatriation of capital and profits to tax havens. When the company acquires real estate directly, the purchasing company obtains a fair market value cost basis in Russia for depreciation purposes. There is no assumption of liabilities for the selling entity. If debt financing is put in place at the level of acquiring the company, the tax benefits in Russia allow for greater flexibility in repatriation of capital and profits from Russia. However, the acquiring company is liable for 20% Russian VAT on acquisition. Theoretically, Russian VAT is refundable after three months and accrues interest until refunded, but there are no clear cases so far of such refund. Additionally an accruing company may (directly or indirectly) incur capital gains tax in Russia upon the sale as well as other tax costs in repatriating proceeds offshore. The more popular method is the acquisition of the Russian holding company. This method avoids the payment of VAT. However the company assumes the seller's historical basis for depreciation purposes in Russia. Additional risks are the assumption of the liabilities born by the seller company, difficulty in obtaining financing and issues with capital and profit repatriation. If debt financing is not an issue, the most tax efficient method remains an acquisition of the offshore company that holds Russian real estate. The benefits of debt financing in Russia are worth considering. If a Russian entity is used for the acquisition, the interest on debt can reduce the profits' tax exposure in Russia and be used for more tax-efficient repatriation of profits from Russia. As noted in the preceding segment (Legal Issues and Taxation), a Russian company with debt can deduct interest on the debt if on an arm's length basis. If the debt is loaned by a foreign person who is a more than 20% direct or indirect shareholder of the Russian borrower, then there are limitations on the deductibility of interest if the borrower's debt/ equity ratio is more then 3:1. However, an optimal debt structure may involve a foreign lender who is not taxable on interest received, is exempt form the 20% interest withholding tax in Russia and is allowed tax-free repatriation of Russian profits. As it relates to local laws, foreign entrants should realize that land lease agreements in Moscow prevent the secondary market. It only is possible to sell the building with the land right agreement, but land speculation itself is not permitted. In acquiring the lease rights one should examine for absence of material claims or lawsuits from competing owners, the ability to pledge property as security for debt finance and for the ability to sell the property in the future. Corruption and Self Dealin2 The blurring of the distinction between government and business is a reality in the Russian economy. In many regions, the executive bodies are headed by representatives of the major financial and industrial groups with economic interests in regions. These politicians make no distinction between the respective status of the businessman and public servant. In Moscow, mayor Luzhkov owns few businesses and has direct and indirect ownership in many more commercial organizations. His wife, for instance, controls all of the manufacturing of the construction materials and a financial investment group. This trend is detrimental to the emergence of fair competition in Russia, especially given that large sectors of the Russian economy are operated by monopolies as it is. The United States economy only became the world's most efficient after the adoption of tough antimonopoly legislation. Despite the fact that similar anti-monopoly stipulations exist in Russia its enforcement proved to be difficult due to politicians' involvement on various levels in the private sector. Also, the research by the INDEM, 2002, reveals that business involvement in corruption does not lead to enhanced efficiency. It reveals that the executive branch plays the greatest role in influencing business. Indeed the executive branch accounts for 98% of the bribery that takes place in the Russian Economy. Overcoming administrative barriers and pressure from official bodies costs business the equivalent of more then 10% of the GDP. 3 American Chamber of Commerce in Russia, Economic policy review. CHAPTER FOUR: FORECASTING Market Forecast Despite the limited number of observations and a significant discrepancy in sources (±25%) I will attempt to forecast rent in two ways; one with Rent only Multivariate and another using Rent and Vacancy Multivariate. The components of the forecast are: Table 4.13 Russian macroeconomic indicators INFLAT. EXCHG. UNEMPL. M. EMPL. REF. RT. Year FDI OIL GDP 1995 $2.1 $16.9 -4.0% 131% $0.200 8.45% 1996 $2.6 $20.4 -3.4% 22% $0.179 9.63% 3,900 84% 1997 $4.1 $18.3 1.4% 11% $0.102 11.76% 3,800 34% 1998 $2.9 $12.7 -4.9% 84% $0.048 13.22% 3,800 60% 1999 $3.1 $17.2 4.6% 36% $0.037 12.93% 4,000 55% 2000 $4.4 $28.5 9.9% 20% $0.036 9.90% 4,100 48% 2001 $3.9 $24.5 5.2% 19% $0.033 8.74% 4,200 35% 2002 $3.0 $25.0 3.9% 15% $0.031 8.00% 4,220 22% 2003 !4 0 1245 500/ 11% %0.032 7.92% 4.500 19% 180% 2004 2005 2006 2007 The independent variables are: Foreign Direct Investment (in billions), OPEC Oil prices per barrel, GDP, Inflation, Exchange Rate, Unemployment Rate, Moscow Employment (in millions), and Refinancing Rate. I will also use Supply, Stock, Occupied Stock, Vacancy, and Real Rent using Tables 2.7, 2.8, 2.10, and 2.14. 3 Goscomstat, Economist Intelligence Unit, IMF, EBRD, JP Morgan, OPEC Rent only Multivariate This tests the significance of the independent variables and lags for Rent as a dependant variable for the Rent Model. The results are as follows: Table 4.2 Independent variablessignificancefor rent RNT R2 t-STAT RNT-1 INFLAT STOCK2 FDI-1 OIL EXCHGE UNEMPL-1 MOS. EMPL-1 REF. RT-1 0.366643061 0.721324627 0.612201895 0.253284713 0.157711879 0.323784348 0.294201567 0.197174784 0.225349482 -1.52169 -3.94087 2.176232 -1.3023 1.059931 1.694966 -1.44367 1.108154 1.206036 The most significant variables are Rnt-1, Inflation, Stock-2 and Exchange Rate with above 2 t-stats but still lower R2. The highest R2 in the results is 72% for Inflation. Testing the significance of the independent variables and lags for Supply as dependant variable for the Supply Model. The results are as follows: Table 4.3 Independent variables significancefor supply R2 t-STAT 0.318695016 0.382545103 0.863979632 1.809530355 2.082513012 -5.635530192 SUPPL STOCK-1 SUPPL-2 RNT-1 Out of all the variables tested the most significant are in the table above with Rent-I having the highest significance - R2 of 86%. Setting up the regression tables: Table 4.4 Regression table set-up for rent Rent 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 $490.39 Rent-1 Inflation $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 $490.39 22.00% 11.00% 84.40% 36.50% 20.00% 19.00% 15.00% 11.00% 9.00% 7.70% Stock-2 Exchange 114,000 152,000 237,500 332,500 617,500 855,000 1,045,000 1,254,000 $0.179 $0.102 $0.048 $0.037 $0.036 $0.033 $0.031 $0.032 $0.031 $0.029 2006 7.50% $0.028 2007 7.00% $0.026 Table 4.5 Regression table set-upfor supply Supply 40,000 90,000 100,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 220,000 240.000 Supply-1 Stock-i Rent-i 40,000 90,000 100,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 114,000 152,000 237,500 332,500 617,500 855,000 1,045,000 $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 Regression Results for Rent: Table 4.6 Regresion resultsfor rent Intercept R2 Rent 0.99998 t-STAT Coefficient 437.85789_ Rent-1 Inflation 17.74376 -39.7599 0.090059 -594.133 Stock-2 4.771138 2.09E-05 Exchange 2.644807 1871.357 The Regression has a good significance with the high R2. Model for Rent: Rent = 437.85789 + (0.090059 * Rent-1) + (-594.133 * Inflation) + (2.09E-05 * Stock -2) + (1871.357 * Exchange) Regression Results for Supply: Table 4.7 Regression resultsfor supply t-STAT Coefficient Supply-1 Stock-1 -2.90738 6.217925 -0.15117 0.09252 Rent-1 -19.1841 -336.418 Supply R2 Intercept 0.994823 327415.1 The Regression has a good significance with the high R2. Model for Supply: Supply = 327415.1 + (-0.15117 * Supply-1) + (0.09252 * Stock-1) + (-336.418 * Rent-1) Model for Stock: Stock = Stock-I + Supply Solving all three formulas simultaneously: Table 4.8 Rent only multivariateforecast From the forecast it appears that rent, stock and supply are increasing. Rent and Vacancy Multivariate Using Tables 1 and 2, I am now testing the significance of the independent variables and lags for Rent as the dependant variable for the Rent Model. The results are as follows: Table 4.9 Independent variablessignificancefor rent R2 t-STAT 0.366643061 0.449223048 0.721324627 -1.521694476 1.564241356 -3.940866376 RNT RNT-1 VAC-2 INFLAT Out of all the variables tested the most significant are in the table above with Inflation having the highest significance - R2 of 72%. Testing the significance of the independent variables and lags for Supply as dependant variable for the Supply Model. The results are as follows: Table 4.10 Independent variablessignificancefor supply R SUPPL STOCK-1 SUPPL-1 RNT-1 VAC-3 2 0.318695016 0.382545103 0.863979632 0.774538511 t-STAT 1.809530355 2.082513012 -5.635530192 -4.144482634 Out of all the variables tested the most significant are in the table above with Rent-1 having the highest significance - R2 of 86%. Testing the significance of the independent variables and lags for Occupied Stock as dependant variable for the Occupied Stock Model. The results are as follows: Table 4.11 Independent variables significancefor occupiedstock OCC STOCK R OCC-1 OCC-2 RNT-2 FDI OIL-1 GDP-1 INFLAT EXCHANGE-1 UNEMPL MOS. EMPL REF. RT 0.975578981 0.914922068 0.161603822 0.420791436 0.479505477 0.426935889 0.242739768 0.515683652 0.691439697 0.941993242 0.676053186 2 t-STAT 15.48192463 7.332778906 -0.878074095 2.255095712 2.351063338 0.426935889 -1.4979486 -2.307342786 -3.960555911 10.66187571 -3.822104841 Out of all the variables tested the most significant are in the table above with Moscow Employment having the highest significance - R2 of 94% and a t-stat of 10; well above 2. Another winner is its own lag OCC-I - R2 of 97% and a t-stat of 15. Setting up the regression tables: Table 4.12 Regression table set-up for rent Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Rent $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 $490.39 Rent-i $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 $490.39 Vac-2 Inflation 22.00% 11.00% 84.40% 36.50% 20.00% 19.00% 15.00% 11.00% 9.00% 7.70% 7.50% 7.00% 6.0% 7.0% 14.0% 16.0% 11.0% 7.5% 4.5% 4.5% Table 4.13 Regression table set-upfor supply Stock-1 Rent-1 90,000 114,000 $629.85 100,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 220,000 240,000 152,000 237,500 332,500 617,500 855,000 1,045,000 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 Year Supply 1996 40,000 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 $490.39 $507.18 $516.39 $519.12 Vac-3 6.0% 7.0% 14.0% 16.0% 11.0% 1 7.5% 4.5% 4.5% Table 4.14 Regression table set-upfor occupied stock Occ. Stock-1 Year 1996 Occ. Stock 1997 141,360 107,160 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 204,250 279,300 549,575 790,875 997,975 1.195.062 141,360 204,250 279,300 549,575 790,875 997,975 1,195,062 1,400,190 Rnt-2 107,160 Mos. Employ. 3,900 Exchange $0.179 3,800 $0.102 3,800 4,000 4,100 4,200 4,220 4,500 4,510 4,530 $0.048 $0.037 $0.036 $0.033 $0.031 $0.032 $0.031 $0.029 1,613,238 4,560 $0.028 1,838,158 4,563 $0.026 $629.85 $693.31 $91.88 $301.63 $418.00 $430.92 $460.28 $490.39 Regression results for Rent: Table 4.15 Regression resultsfor rent R RNT 2 0.999910294 Rent-1 Inflation Vac-2 Intersept t-STAT Coefficients 18.88493713 0.109650754 -117.4365847 -578.9905452 -2.59362407 -76.4583352 508.9557597 The Regression has a good significance with the high R2 - 99%. Model for Rent: Rent = 508.9557597 + (0.109650754 * Rent-1) + (-578.9905452 * Inflation) + + (-76.4583352 * Vac-2) Regression results for Supply: Table 4.16 Regression results for supply R Supply Intersept 2 0.981390868 t-STAT Coefficients 333220.4074 Stock-i 2.691916743 Rent-i -3.647112098 -282.4138873 Vac-3 -2.109661928 -415398.1666 0.080673758 The Regression has a good significance with the high R2 - 98%. Model for Supply: Supply = 333220.4074 + (0.080673758 * Stock-1) + (-282.4138873 * Rent-1) + + (-415398.1666 * Vac-3) Model for Stock: Stock = Stock-1 + Supply Model for Vacancy: Vacancy = 1.0 - Occupied Stock / Stock Regression results for Occupied Stock: Table 4.17 Regression resultsfor occupied stock Occ. Stock R2 Intercept 0.998707039 153298.8356 Occ. Stock-i Rent-2 Mos. Employment t-STAT Coefficients 12.41999849 1.050805736 -6.306609108 -341.6642451 .262935196 34.64643838 The Regression has a good significance with the high R2 - 99%. Model for Stock: Occ. Stock = 53298.8356 + (1.050805736* Occ. Stock-1) + (-341.6642451 * Rent-2) + + (34.64643838 * Mos. Employment) Solving all formulas simultaneously and adjusting forecasted stock for depreciation at 5%: Table 4.18 Rent and vacancy multivariateforecast YEAR 2004 2005 2006 2007 SUPPL 264,737 288,915 303,109 325,625 I STOCK OCC STOCK I VAC I REAL RNT From the forecast it appears that rent, stock and supply are increasing but with a slower rate than the first forecast model. The vacancy is decreasing with the high increase of supply, thus the rent is increasing. Comparing Rent only Multivariate and Rent and Vacancy Multivariate: Table 4.19 Rent only and rent and vacancy multivariatecomparison Rnt. Only $507.98 $519.12 $522.71 $ 525.97 Rnt. & Vac $ $ $ $ 507.18 516.55 519.55 522.90 % -0.16% -0.50% -0.60% -0.58% The rents from the forecasts of each model are very close to one another. The difference is less then one percent per year. Thus I would consider the outcome to be significant. I will use the results from the Rent and Vacancy Multivariate forecast from this point forward. Table 4.20 Forecastingresultsfrom the rent & vacancy model: NOM RNT YEAR SUPPL STOCK OCC STOCK VAC RNT 1996 40,000 114,000 107,160 6.0% $ 629.85 $ 807.50 1997 90,000 152,000 141,360 7.0% $ 693.31 $ 779.00 1998 100,000 237,500 204,250 14.0% $ 91.88 $ 589.00 1999 300,000 332,500 279,300 16.0% $ 301.63 $ 475.00 2000 250,000 617,500 549,575 11.0% $ 418.00 $ 522.50 2001 200,000 855,000 790,875 7.5% $ 430.92 $ 532.00 2002 220,000 1,045,000 997,975 4.5% $ 460.28 $ 541.50 2003 240,000 1,254,000 1,195,062 4.5% $ 490.39 $ 551.00 2004 2005 2006 2007 Table 4.21 Market Dynamic / Percent Change: YEAR SUPPL STOCK OCC STOCK VAC RNT NOM RNT 1997 125.0% 33.3% 31.9% 16.7% 10.1% -3.5% 1998 11.1% 56.3% 44.5% 100.0% -86.7% -24.4% 1999 200.0% 40.0% 36.7% 14.3% 228.3% -19.4% 2000 -16.7% 85.7% 96.8% -31.3% 38.6% 10.0% 2001 -20.0% 38.5% 43.9% -31.8% 3.1% 1.8% 2002 10.0% 22.2% 26.2% -40.0% 6.8% 1.8% 2003 9.1% 20.0% 19.7% 0% 6.5% 1.8% 2004 2005 2006 2007 Figure 4.1 Market Dynamic / PercentChange: As apparent from the graph the market is calming down in the beginning of the century. It would be useful to observe this part in detail: Figure 4.2 Moscow office market real estate indicatorsgrowth rates (2001-2007) % Change -- +- Supply -a- Stock -*- Vacancy -l-- Real Rent -.- Occ Stock Nominal Rent 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% 0.0% -10.0% -20.0% -30.0% -40.0% -50.0% Year As inflation is calming down Real and Nominal rent appear to be the same. Vacancy is increasing due to the still abundant supply coming to the market with the lag; however it will soon drop as the supply will slow down its pace and its rate will start to look a lot like stock. With increased demand and limited supply, vacancy will drop again, driving up nominal rent in 2004. The downward trend for vacancy from 2005 on continues with high demand for space, matching rent recovery at around 2006. Forecasting Cap Rates3 5 Using Tables 2.7, 2.8, 4.1, and 4.20, I am testing the significance of the independent variables and lags for Cap Rate as the dependant variable for the Cap Rate Model. The most significant regression was as follows: 35 Historic cap rates collected from Noble Gibbons, DTZ, JJL, Colliers, Stiles Riabokobylko. Table 4.22 Cap rate regression output SUMMARY OUTPUT Regression Statistics Multiple R R Square Adjusted R Square Standard Error Observations 0.98 0.97 0.93 0.01 8 ANOVA 4 3 7 SS 0.01 0.00 0.01 Coef -0.05 -0 0 1.86 0.04 Stand Err 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.35 0.02 df Regression Residual Total Intercept Supply Oil Price Unemployment Refinancing Rate MS 0.00 0.00 t Stat -0.93 -1.53 2.21 5.32 1.85 F 23.57 SignifF 0.013 Pvalue 0.42 0.22 0.11 0.01 0.16 Lower 95% -0.24 0.00 0.00 0.75 -0.03 Upper 95% 0.13 0.00 0.01 2.98 0.11 Lower 95.0% -0.24 0.00 0.00 0.75 -0.03 Upper 95.0% 0.13 0.00 0.01 2.98 0.11 The Regression has a good significance with the high R - 97%; most of the t-stat above 2. 2 Model for Cap Rate: Cap Rate = -0.0541047 + (-.00000001 * Supply) + (0.0032626 * Oil Price) + + (1.8647835 * Unemployment) + (0.0395307 * Refinancing Rate) Cap Rates are as follows: Table 4.23 Cap rateforecast Year 96 Cap 22% 97 98 23% 25% 99 00 24% 22% 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 20% 16% 14% 13% 12% 12% 11% Reconstructing Figure 2.10 to include forecasted returns for US investors: Table 4.24 Real returnsforecastfor US investors Year Real Rnt. Cap Rt. Real V 1996 $780.69 22% $3,548.60 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 $765.76 $579.52 $462.27 $504.79 $523.75 $526.93 $539.98 $552.60 $555.91 $557.79 $558.72 23% 25% 24% 22% 20% 16% 14% 13% 12% 12% 11% $3,329.38 $2,318.07 $1,926.13 $2,294.49 $2,618.77 $3,293.34 $3,857.00 $4,228.43 $4,470.63 $4,674.27 $4,864.83 Real r 16% -7% 8% 43% 36% 46% 33% 24% 19% 17% 16% Reconstructing Table 2.14 to include forecasted returns for Russian investors: Table 4.25 Real returnsforecastfor Russian investors Year Real Rnt. Cap Rt. Real V 1996 3,410.06p. 22% 15,500.26p. 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 6,678.93p. 1,866.86p. 7,925.62p. 1,371.85p. 12,786.62p. 14,234.06p. 15,234.46p. 16,343.22p. 17, 4 45. 5 5p. 18,367.94p. 18, 86 1.6 8 p. 23% 25% 24% 22% 20% 16% 14% 13% 12% 12% 11% 29,038.84p. 7,467.43p. 33,023.41p. 51,690.21p. 63,933.08p. 88,962.87p. 108,817.54p. 125,055.77p. 140,297.17p. 153,923.60p. 164,231.68p. Real r 109% -51% 367% 81% 46% 59% 38% 29% 25% 22% 19% Reconstructing the return index for both Russian and US investors (Figure 2.9): Figure 4.3 US vs. Russian investors realperiodic returnsforecast (1997-2007) Returns --- .. 400%........... ..- Russian Returns -- m- US Returns - -----.- ....- -- -. ---- 350% 300% 250% 200%150% 100% 50% 0%-50% 1997 - 8 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 -100% Year Figure 4.4 US vs. Russian investors realperiodic returnsforecast (2000-2007) -4*- Russian Returns Returns -m- US Returns 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 2000 2001 2002 2004 2003 Year 2005 2006 2007 As apparent from the graph, the returns are diminishing and stabilizing for both investors. Russian and American returns are becoming highly correlated with similar volatility from 2000 on. The comeback of the Russian market is projected to sustain itself; thus the rapidly growing Real Estate sector might take a similar position as it does in the US. The supply and absorption (reconstructing Figure 2.5) are projected to rise taking the shape of a healthy market: Figure 4.5 Supply and absorptioforecast Sq. M --- Supply -- Absorption 350,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 150,000 100,000 50,000 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Year 2005 2006 2007 Figure 4.6 Stock vs. cumulative absorbtion Sq. M -4- 2,500.000 - - - - - - - - Stock -M- Cumulative Absorption - - - - -- - - - - - -......... 2,000,000 1,500,000 1,000,000 500,000 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Year IRR Comparison Since most of the institutional investors would consider Russian real estate an alternative investment, it would be reasonable to conclude with historic and projected IRR's from Russian real estate: Table 4.26 Historic andforecastedIRR's for US and Russian investors US Investors Russian Investors 1996-2003 16.88% 54.87% 2000-2007 | 2003-2007 I As most of the opportunity and venture capital funds operating in the emerging markets report IRR's of 22%, Russia presents a mixed bag ranging from a historical 16% to a projected 30%. Despite the infamous devaluation of 1998, Russian real estate can still be considered an attractive alternative investment to hold in the portfolio of an institutional investor as it appears to be negatively correlated with World securities (Figure 2.10). CHAPTER FIVE: CONCLUSIONS An Overview of the US Market Participants There are several Western companies that are seriously involved in Russian real estate today. US representatives are Hines, AIG, Harbor Global Company, GE Capital Golub, Hiteman Group and NCH Capital. There also is a strong presence of Fleming Family fund from England, which is partially owned by US investors. All companies have global holdings and are well diversified in their assets. Hines is by far the most enduring company on the market. In the early 90's Hines entered the Moscow market as a property and construction manager. This method of entry allowed Hines to become familiar with the market. Hines can be considered one of the few real estate companies that until recently did not have a Russian partner. Their first development scheme was rather conservative. They secured a plot of land for the construction of the Russian-American school for the children of American diplomats in Moscow. Subsequently they developed a housing neighborhood for the whole diplomatic mission. The project enjoyed various benefits, including some tax relief, due to its diplomatic status. The houses are still held by Hines as rental properties, yielding high returns. The recent investment of Hines is a bit more aggressive in nature. Hines is developing a multistory office building with a Russian partner who contributed land to the partnership. The project is being financed from the Hines Emerging market fund and is scheduled to break ground this year. Harbor Global owns the Meridian tower through its Moscow company - PIO Global. The tower fully recovered the investment made by the company in 1996 and is operating as a pure profit-maker for the company. The tower is considered a class B building by location, as it is located in one of the most remote locations from the center of Moscow. However its proximity to the airport and traffic-free environment led to 100% occupancy by foreign companies. PIO Global is an asset management company that invests in Russian equities and debt instruments. The company recently came out with the first Russian index fund. The company holds high hopes on the restructuring of the Russian pension system. By the end of this year, some three billion dollars of Russian pension money is scheduled to flood the securities market. PIO Global is well positioned for the investment management service because they have fit the requirement for experience and sufficient capitalization on the market. The management believes that the cash stream from the Meridian tower could be further securitized and held as an asset in the portfolio of the future pension fund investors. Additional investments would allow the company to expand into real estate, as they have much experience with their star asset. Both AIG and GE Golub are in the early stages of entry into the Moscow market. The companies are being very careful in choosing strategic partnerships for their schemes. AIG and GE Golub, became interested in the market when their Eastern European holdings began showing the signs of weakness. Using their operations in the East, the two are evaluating a couple of acquisition opportunities; nonetheless both are more interested in development. Fleming Family dedicated US $60m. early this year for the acquisition of prime real estate in Moscow. The intention is to lever up to US $160-170m and become the only dedicated real estate Moscow fund. Despite such a bold commitment, property acquisition in Moscow has proven to be a difficult business. The only negotiations for an asset located in the city center were abandoned due to the lack of transparency in the ownership structure of the building. NCH Capital is the largest foreign owner of real assets in former Soviet republics. The fund currently has US $2b under management in their private equity portfolio. The investments are held in Baltic republics- Kazakhstan, Ukraine, Belarus and Russia. Moscow is the only place they are not. The strategy of this company is to dominate early on the markets where there is no competition. The management believes that Moscow is becoming too political and expensive to compete for; the lack of land rights and overall immaturity of the market steers the fund into second tier cities in Russia. All companies found it difficult to compete on the market due to its immaturity and high risks involved in the regulatory system. An undisclosed US fund lost as much as US $30m in the approval process, before its exit from the market. However, remaining entrants are counting on 25-35% IRR on their investment, while none, except for AIG are hedging the currency. To better manage regulatory risks, those involved in the development schemes are all negotiating with local partners. Despite the all the risks, the majority of the participants are as exited about Russian real estate as they were before 1998. Conclusions The source of the advantage for Russian investors/ developers in Moscow has been their opportunistic entry after the devaluation of ruble in 1998. Exchange rate volatility and inflation were the guiding factors for domestic capital that didn't need to cross borders to repatriate profits. Rising oil prices and economic stability secured the position of the domestic investors, while US institutions were still getting over the shock of the default. By the time foreigners began to come back into Moscow, lured by the rampant progress and political commitment to reforms, the Russian companies were already dominating the market by their superior returns and experience with the regulatory system. However, most of the abnormal returns can only be attributed to the volatility in the historic time period chosen for this thesis. As the inflation and exchange rate become more stable, the returns for Russian investors will come down to the conventional norms; thus allowing US companies to enter the market in an efficient way. As the spread between Russian and US risk-adjusted returns narrows, the only risk remaining for the US investors/ developers will be in the regulatory system. In order to become a globally recognized as a free market, Russia has to, and pledges full commitment to, continuing reform of its regulatory environment. It is important to reform the banking sector and reduce dependency of the Federation on the natural resource sector. Restructuring is needed in the governmental sector, as there are too many agencies involved in contradictory actions without clear hierarchy, direction and mismatched responsibilities. The involvement of the government in the quasi-private monopolies has to stop as its stake in private companies negates free competition and defies the rules of the open economy. In the area of real estate, free-hold of land has to become uniform throughout the Federation. Clarity in title registration and reform of the development approval system is needed. Land ownership will help to improve real estate lending. Zoning guidelines have to be instituted in all areas of the country to aid investment evaluation. Reduction of control of the municipal government in regulatory process and construction will unlock the power of the capital and reward Russian real estate with increased liquidity on the asset market. Bibliography Books: Olsson, Carl,Risk Management in Emerginz Markets, Person Education Limited, 2002. Hernando do Soto, The Mvsterv of Capital Basic Books, 2000. Geltner,David, and Norman, Miller, CommercialReal Estate Analysis and Investments, South-Western Publishing,2001. William Wheaton and Denise DiPasquale,Urban Economics and Real Estate Markets, Prentice-Hall,Inc. 1996. M.Hoesli & B.MacGregor, PropertyInvestment: Principles & Practiceof Portfolio Management, Pearson EducationLtd., Essex UK 2000 Articles and Papers: CB Richard Ellis, Market Index Brief 2003 Dwight Jaffee and Olga Kaganova, Real Estate Markets, 2000 Kaganova, Olga, Urban Real EstateMarkets in Russia: The CurrentStage, 1998 Kaganova Olga, MonitoringIndicators of Land and Real Estate Reform in Russia, 1999 Troika Dialog Research, Russia Stratagv 2003 RTS Index Research, 2003 Ernst & Young, Doing Business in the Russian Federation,2002 GE Real Estate, CentralEurope Research, 2003 AmCham News, Russia and WTO: A StrategicImperative, Volume 10, 2003 The Moscow Times, Companies Going Global One Step at a Time June 19th, 2003 DouglasLloyed, Linking Housing and CapitalMarkets in the FormerSoviet Block 2001 EIU Viewswire 12 Jun 2003, Russia: 5-year Forecast 2003 Ernst & Young, An Eye on Russia, 2002 The Institutefor Urban Economics, Economic Development Program for Moscow, 1999 Borsunova, 0. A., Economic Forecastfor Russian FedrationYear 2004, 2003 Time for News, The Issues in Moscow Development 2003 Time for News, Hugged by Glavmosstroi, 2003 Sergei Sharkov, ForeignInvestment in Real Estate, 2002 Anna Danshina,Real Estate Investment, 2003 E. K. Trutnev, Development: Regulatorv Environment 2002 Vedomosti, Moscow Totalitarism 2002 The Moscow Times, Land Reform: The Race Is On 2002 Stephen Jennings, Remarks on Russia's Domestic Bond Market, 2003 Ernst & Young, 2002 International,Audit Survey - Russia and the CIS, 2002 American Chamber of Commerce in Russia, The Economic Situation and Investment Climate in Russia 2003 John Delargy, The Moscow Office Market, 2002 Irina Dmitrieva,New Developments in Russian Real PropertyLegislation, 2003 Jones Lang LaSalle, Real Estate Guide to Russia, 2003 Olga Kaganova, Replies on DavidMammen's Questions 2001 Stiles & Riabokobylko, Office Market Profile, 2003 Jones Lang Lassale, Moscow City Profile, 2002 IngBarings, City of Moscow; ReturningAfter a Short Absence 2001 Euro Week, Finding the Right Pitch for Russia, 2001, EuroWeek, Moscow Heads up Russian Revival 2002 DTZ Research, Moscow Office Market Update 2003 Real Estate, ClassicalDeveloper, 2003 Web-sites: http://www.russianembassy.org/main.htm http://www.therussiajournal.com/index http://www.outsourcing-russia.com/kb/russia/ http://www.themoscowtimes.com/indexes/0l.html http://www.iie.com/ http://www.Itv.ru/owa/win/ort6 main.main http://www. etown. edu/vl/intldev.html http.//www. imf org/external/country/RUS/index.htm http://www.urbaneconomics.ru/eng/projects.php?folderid=3 http://www.ea-ratings.ru/middle.php htt://www. iss.nl/cestrad/index.htm http://www.rics.org.uk/global cities http.//www. cerean.com/index.htm http://www.corp-gov.org/news/arch.php3?news id=630 http://www.aiglincoln.cz/ http://www. bbc.co. uk/categories/ http://www.cs.indiana.edu/-dmiguse/Russian/bvbio.html http://home.businesswire.com/portal/site/home/index.Isp http://www.carnegie.ru/english/index.htm http://www.foreignpolicy-infocus.org/papers/russia/collapsebody.html http://www.simply-info. co.uk/funds/ http://www.giml. co. uk/ http.//www. ifc. org/ http://english.pravda.ru/diplomatic/2OO1/O7/02/9142.html http://www.einnews.com/russia/ http://www.sustainability.com/developing-value/definitions.asp http://www.aup.ru http://www.economv.gov.ru http://www.ivr.ru Interviews: Eugine Golub - Golub and Company; Kevin Fitzpatric,PeterSeeley - AIG Global Real Estate Investment Corp.; Alexei Balanin - Hines; Maksim Kunin - FFP;Mark Bartholomy - Clifford Chance; James Sheppard, Stephen Kasnet - Harbor Global; Artem Grigorian- GE Capital Golub; Ilya Metelkin, Mikhail Yakoubov - The Institutefor Urban Economics; Mikko Petrov - Skanska East Europe Oy; James Smyth - Baubetreuungs and Beratungsgmbh;Ivan Antonov - Moscow City Gov; Alla Svirschevskaya - Brunswick Capital;Pavel Barbashov - CMI; Stephen Wilson - DTZ; Andrei Tkachenko - Tonnex; Andrei Uspensky - PIO Global; Gerald Gaige - EYI; PeterRoshchin, Jack Kelleher Noble Gibbons, DaryaAfanasieva - Stiles & Riabokobylko; Igor Litvak - Delta Capital; Natalia Osipova - ColliersInternational,Veta Riabtseva - Jones Lang LaSalle; George Rohr - NCH Capital;Miff Chichester- CB HillierParker.