The Feasibility and Functioning of Public Mortgage Insurance An International Comparison STi INSTTE eh.TECHNOLOGY FEB 15 2006 by LIBRARIES Liou Cao Master in Urban Planning, Tsinghua University, P.R. China (2000) Bachelor in Architecture, Tsinghua University, P.R. China (1997) Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN URBAN ECONOMICS AND URBAN INFORMATION SYSTEMS AT THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY SEPTEMBER 2005 © 2005 Liou Cao. All rights reserved. The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author: " C Department of Urban Studies and Planning ~ /ff/ sJune ) 102005 / Certified by: p1i/'~ ~Jo reira Jr. rfessor of Urban Planning and Operations Research v'~y~ "·3 Dissertation Supervisor Accepted by: Frank Levy Chairman, Ph.D. Committee Department of Urban Planning and Planning Abstract Public mortgage insurance (MI) is one type of supply-side government intervention in housing finance. It is an important component of the modem housing finance market, employed to expand homeownership and provide credit enhancement to mortgage loans. This research explores the feasibility and functioning of public MI, by conducting an international comparison of three representative public MI programs: the U.S. Federal Housing Administration; the Dutch Homeownership Guarantee Fund; and the Mexican Federal Mortgage Corporation. The main purpose is to build an integrated framework for policymakers when considering a public MI scheme, from institutional, financial, and operational perspectives. Research methodologies used include case studies, interviews, Monte Carlo simulation models, and regression analyses. The analytical framework of this research comprises three research questions: a) What are the primary economic problems in housing and housing finance markets that cause market inefficiency and hence call for government intervention in the form of public MI? b) What are the implied liabilities imposed on the backing government of sponsoring a public MI enterprise? and c) What are the potential economic problems that can result from the creation of a public MI system? Answers to these questions indicate that public MI can be an effective policy tool to address particular housing market inefficiencies. However, a good fit between public MI and a nation's housing and housing finance markets entails many factors, including economic, financial, legal, political, institutional, and even cultural. Public MI should be designed and priced properly to maintain its financial soundness over the long term, without imposing "hidden" liabilities on the backing government. Certain institutional arrangements and operational strategies are necessary to ensure public MI's relative independence and to control market distortions stemming from its presence. This research contributes to the knowledge base for any country considering a public MI scheme to boost its housing market development. It is intended to offer much needed insight into the economic rationale, financial viability, institutional and legal infrastructure, and operational strategies of government-sponsored MI programs, and help policymakers make informed decisions based on a holistic socio-economic view of the public MI. -2- Dissertation Committee: Joseph Ferreira Jr. (Chair) Professor of Urban Planning and Operations Research Department of Urban Studies and Planning, MIT Hugo Priemus Professor of Housing, Urban and Mobility Studies Dean, Faculty of Technology, Policy and Management Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands David Geltner Professor of Real Estate and Finance Director, Center for Real Estate, MIT Department of Urban Studies and Planning, MIT Lynn Fisher Assistant Professor of Center for Real Estate, MIT Department of Urban Studies and Planning, MIT Robert M. Buckley Senior Housing Advisor, The World Bank -3- Acknowledgement The completion of this dissertation is one of the most significant milestones in my life. It would not have been possible without the generous support of many people. First, my deep gratitude goes to Professor Joe Ferreira for his mentorship and friendship. He has fostered an inquisitive, open-minded academic attitude and quantitative spirit in me. He has also encouraged me to explore a wide range of research areas, which has helped make my five-year stay at MIT such a wonderful journey. Thanks also go to my other dissertation committee members. Professor Hugo Priemus has offered me the great opportunity of conducting research at the Delft University of Technology in the Netherlands. His academic insights and rigorous research methods have benefited me far beyond this dissertation. Professor David Geltner and Professor Lynn Fisher have helped me structure the research and turned several interesting ideas into a coherent dissertation. Meetings with them have always been sources of inspiration. Mr. Robert Buckley, with his research expertise in international housing finance and decades of experience in the field, has helped me gain a deeper understanding of the international context of this research and guided me from the very beginning. Thanks also go out to those who have contributed enormously to this research: Ms. Kasia Kozinski and Mr. Charles Capone, who are my great mentors and best of friends; Ms. Judy May, Mr. Ed Szymanoski, and Mr. Darryl Getter at the FHA; Mr. Hans Mersmann at the WEW; Mr. Sybo Bruinsma at the WSW; Ms. Marja Elsinga and Ms. Marietta Haffner at the OTB of TU Delft; Mr. Guillermo Babatz Torres, Mr. Jesus Alan Elizondo Flores, and Mr. Gerardo Bazan Morante at the SHF; and Mr. Roger Blood at Mercer Management Consulting. Their support made this research possible. I am also indebted to the community of the Department of Urban Studies and Planning at MIT, especially Professors Bill Wheaton, Karen Polenske, and Larry Vale; and Sandy Wellford, Karen Yegian, and numerous other individuals. Acknowledgements also go to special friends such as Lijian Chen, Ruijue Peng, Zhan Guo, Ning Ai, Jinhua Zhao, Xiaoyu Shi, Zhanbin Jiang, Ming Guo, Ayman Ismail, Uri Raich, Ari Goelman, Pierre Fallavier, Yan Zhang, Jiawen Yang, Mizuki Kawabata, and more. They have made my life the more colorful. I dedicate this dissertation to my loving parents, Kangping Wu and Hua Cao, and to my sister, Likun Cao. Their love, encouragement, and confidence in me have always pushed me forward and held me when I fall. Lastly, I am deeply grateful to Duncan, who has been a wonderful sounding board for ideas, and has been extremely caring, encouraging, patient, and loving. -4 - List of Abbreviations ADB Asian Development Bank ARM Adjustable-Rate Mortgage BKN Government-Sponsored Guarantee Fund in Sweden CMHC Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation CONAFOVI National Housing Commission DIM Dual-Indexed Mortgages EU European Union Fannie Mae Federal National Mortgage Association FCRA Federal Credit Reform Act FGI Financial Guarantee Insurance FGIC Government-Sponsored Guarantee Fund in Kazakhstan FHA Federal Housing Administration FIEH Fuente Integral de Estadistica Hipotecaria (Statistical Mortgage Integral Source) FONHAPO Low-Income Housing Fund FOVI Financial Housing Aid Fund FOVISSSTE Housing Fund for the Social Security Services Institute of the Public Workers Freddie Mac Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation FRM Fixed-Rate Mortgage FY Fiscal Year GDP Gross National Product Ginnie Mae Government National Mortgage Association GSE Government-Sponsored Enterprises HKMC Hong Kong Mortgage Corporation HLGC Home Loan Guarantee Company HOC Homeownership Center HUD The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development IFC International Finance Corporation IIF Insurance-In-Force IMGC India Mortgage Guarantee Company INFONAVIT Institute for National Housing Fund for Public Workers LTV Loan-To-Value Ratio -5- MBS Mortgage-Backed Securities MC Marginal Cost MI Mortgage Insurance MMIF Mutual Mortgage Insurance Fund MPB Marginal Private Benefit MPC Marginal Private Cost MW Minimum Wage NAHA National Affordable Housing Act NGO Non-Governmental Organization NHB National Housing Bank NHG National Mortgage Guarantee NIBUD Consumer Credit Counseling Service NPV Net Present Value PMI Private Mortgage Insurance RHS Department of Agriculture's Rural Housing Service Housing SGFGAS Government-Sponsored Guarantee Fund in France SOFOLES Financing Societies with Limited Purposes SHF Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (Federal Mortgage Corporation) U.S. The United States UDI Unidades de Inversion (an investment unit in Mexico) UGC United Guarantee Company UPB Unpaid Principal Balance VA Department of Veteran Affairs VaR Value-at-Risk VNG The Association of Netherlands Municipalities VROM The Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment WEW Stichting Waarborgfonds Eigen Woningen (Homeownership Guarantee Fund) WSW Stichting Waarborgfonds Sociale Woningbouw (Social Housing-Building Guarantee Fund) -6- Table of Contents Chapter 1 Introduction ........................................................... 11 I. What Is Public Mortgage Insurance ........................................ ......................................... 11 II. The Purpose and Significance of This Research .............................................................. 14 III. Three Research Questions ................................................................ 15 IV. The Structure of the Dissertation ................................................................ 15 Appendix I. 1 Various Types of Insurance in Mortgage Finance................................. 17 Chapter 2 Theoretical Framework ........................................................... 19 I. Housing Finance Market Imperfection and Government Intervention............................ 19 II. Credit Risks in Mortgage Contract and Mortgage Insurance ........................................... 22 III. Comparative Research on Different Housing Finance Systems and International Mortgage Insurance Models ................................................................ 26 IV. Added Value of This Research ................................................................ 27 Chapter 3 Research Methodology and Three Study Cases................................... 29 I. II. Research Methodology ......................................... 29 Three Study Cases ......................................... 29 A. The United States and the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) .......................... 30 B. The Netherlands and the Homeownership Guarantee Fund (WEW) ......................... 33 C. Mexico and the Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF). .................................. 35 III. Choice of the Three Cases ................................................................................................ 38 Chapter 4 Market Inefficiency And Economic Rationales For Public MI ............... 41 I. Market Inefficiency and Uncertainty Risks ................................................ 41 A. Public MI Addresses Market Inefficiency .............................................................. 41 B. Uncertainty Risks .............................................................. 42 II. Different Stages of Housing Finance Market Development and Public MI..................... 45 III. Economic Rationales for Public MI - Case Studies ......................................................... 48 A. The U.S. FHA Program ........................................ ...................... 48 B. The Dutch WEW Program.............................................................. 52 C. The Mexican SHF Program .............................................................. 57 IV. Comparison of the Three MI Programs' Economic Rationales. ............................. 62 Appendix 4,.1 Mexican Housing Finance Main Market Participants ........................................ 67 Chapter 5 Analysis of Implied Government Liabilities.............................................. 69 I. Implied Government Liabilities In Supporting Public MI ............................................... 69 II. Methodology .............................................................. 73 A. Existing Methodologies - Literature Review ............................................................ 73 III. B. My Approach .............................................................. Model Setup .............................................................. A. The Model . ............................................ .... .......... B. Modeling Processes .............................................................. C. Parameter Settings .............................................................. -7- 74 75 ..................................75 76 79 IV. Modeling and Simulation Results ........................................ ......................... A. The U.S. FHA Program ................................................................. 81 81 B. The Dutch WEW Program................................................................. 99 C. The Mexican SHF Program ................................................................. 116 V. Comparison of the Three Cases and Implications .......................................................... 129 Appendix 5.1 Regression Analysis of FHA Cohort Prepayment Rates, 1975-2003 ............... 134 Appendix 5.2 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the U.S. FHA Program ............. 135 Appendix 5.3 Regression Analysis of FHA Multi-Year Cohort Default Rates, 1975-2003 ... 136 Appendix 5.4 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the Dutch WEW Program........... 137 Appendix 5.5 Regression Analysis of WEW Multi-Year Cohort Default Rates, 1981-1999. 138 Appendix 5.6 Explanations of Some Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the SHF Mortgage Guarantee................................................................... 139 Appendix 5.7 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the Mexican SHF Program......... 140 Chapter 6 Potential Economic Problems Resulting from the Establishment of Public MI ............................................................. I. Potential Economic Problems ......................................................................................... 143 143 A. Adverse Selection ........................................ 143 B. Moral Hazard ........................................ 144 C. Non-optimal Risk Taking and Risk Allocation..... ......................... 145 D. Constraining Participation and Development of the Private Sector....................... 146 E. Abuse of Public MI for Political Reasons.................................. 147 II. Addressing Potential Economic Problems - Case Studies ......................... 148 A. The U.S. FHA Program ........................................ 148 B. The Dutch WEW Program.................................. 155 C. The Mexican SHF Program......................................... 162 III. Comparison of the Three MI Programs' Potential Economic Problems .................... 166 Chapter 7 Conclusions And Policy Implications ................................................... 171 I. Research Purpose and Method ........................................ 171 II. Major Research Findings ................................................................................................ 172 A. Economic Rationales for Public MI....................................... 172 B. Implied Government Liabilities of Backing Public MI ........................................ 174 C. Potential Economic Problems Resulting from Public MI ........................................ 178 III. Policy Implications and Recommendations ........................................ 179 A. The Government Role in MI Provision ..... ............................... B. Public MI as a Housing Policy .................................... C. Public Versus Private ........................................ IV. Future Research ................................................. References ...................................................................................................................... -8- 180 181 182 184 187 List of Tables Table 1.1 Table 4.1 Table 4.2 Table 4.3 Table 5.1 Table 5.2 Table 5.3 Table 5.4 Table 5.5 Table 5.6 Table 5.7 Table 5.8 Table 5.9 Table 5.10 Table 5.11 Table 5.12 Table 5.13 Table 5.14 Table 5.15 Public Mortgage Default Insurance Schemes Worldwide ................................. Development Stages of the Three Public MI ................. .......................... Market Imperfections Addressed by the Public MI ...................................... Prerequisites for Public MI to Function....................................... ............... Parameters Categories and Explanations .............................................. Cash Flow Components ................... ............... Cumulative Default Rates of FHA-Insured 30-Year Fixed-Rate Mortgages ........... Cumulative Prepayment Rates and Total Termination Rates of FHA-Insured 30Year Fixed-Rate Mortgages ................................................................. Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the FHA Program ...................... Erlang Parameters for Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rate Distributions - The FHA .. ..... .............................................................. Simulation Results of the NPV and Profitability Rate of the FHA 2003 Cohort ...... Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions - The FHA ...................... Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions from the "Loss Zone"........... The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The FHA ............... .... Projected Cumulative Default Rates of WEW Guaranteed Cohorts, 1981-2003...... Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the WEW Guarantee ................... Erlang Parameters for Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rate Distributions - The WEW ..................................................................... Change of Monthly Payment Due to Interest Rate Reset ................................. Simulation Results of the NPV and Profitability Rates of the WEW's Three Types ofCohorts ................................................ Table 5.16 Table 5.17 Table 5.18 Table 5.19 Table 5.20 Table 5.21 Table 5.22 Table 5.23 Table 5.24 Table 6.1 Table 6.2 ....... . 13 48 63 65 80 80......... 82 83 84 88.. 88 89 91 94 97 101 102 106 107 .............. 108 Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions - The WEW ...................... The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The WEW ......................... Marginal Default Rates of FOVI-Guaranteed Cohorts ....... ............................. Projected Cumulative Default Rates of SHF Guaranteed Cohorts, 1996-1998......... Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the SHF Mortgage Guarantee......... NPVs and Profitability Rates of the SHF-Guaranteed Cohort Under Different 111 115 118 119 120 DefaultScenarios................. ........................ 125 The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The SHF ........................... Comparison of the Modeling Results for the Three MI Programs ....................... Sustainability of the Three Public MI Programs in the Worst Case Scenarios......... Potential Economic and Social Problems Resulting from Public MI .................... Operational Strategies to Control Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard ............... 128 130 133 167 168 ................. -9- ... ......... List of Figures Figure 4.1 Figure 4.2 Figure 4.3 Figure 4.4 Figure 4.5 Figure 4.6 The Market for Residential Mortgage Credits in Developing Countries................ 43 Evolution of the Housing Finance Market and the Position of the Three Countries... 46 Credit Enhancement for Government Insured Secondary Mortgage Market........... 52 Foreclosure Sales in the Netherlands, 1975-2003 ......... ................. ........... 54 Capital Sources for Mortgage Loans in Mexico ................. ......... ......... 58 SHF's Evolving Role ............................................................... 61 Figure 4.7 SHF's Role in the Secondary Mortgage Market ............................................ Figure 5.1 Figure 5.2 Figure 5.3 Figure 5.4 Figure 5.5 Figure 5.6 Implied Government Liabilities of Supporting a Public MI .............................. 70 Modeling Processes ................................................................. ..... 78 Modeling Parameters ................................................................. ..... 79 The Distribution of Macro Economic Conditions by Loan Age - The FHA ........... 82 The Frequency Distribution of FHA Cohorts' Ultimate Default Rates .................. 86 The Frequency Distribution of 10,000 Simulated Ultimate Default and Prepayment Rates - The FHA ............................................... .......... ............. 87 The Probability Distribution of Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rates - The FHA ............................................... .......... ............. 88 The Frequency Distribution of the Simulated Profitability Rates ......... ............. 90 Frequency Distributions of Multi-year Cumulative Profitability Rates .................. 92 The Frequency Distribution of 6-year Cumulative Profitability Rates .................. 94 Revenue Components of the FHA MMI Fund, FY2003 ......... .................. 97 The Distribution of Macro Economic Conditions by Loan Age - The WEW ......... 99 The Frequency Distribution of WEW Cohorts' Ultimate Default Rates ................ 104 The Frequency Distribution of 10,000 Simulated Ultimate Default Rates - The Figure 5.7 Figure 5.8 Figure 5.9 Figure 5.10 Figure 5.11 Figure 5.12 Figure 5.13 Figure 5.14 W EW ...................................................................... Figure 5.15 The Probability Distribution of WEW's Annual Unconditional Default Rates ......... Figure 5.16 Frequency Distributions of Profitability Rates for WEW's 10-year, 15-year, and 30-year Fixed Rate Cohorts................................................................... Figure 5.17 Development of House Price and Long-term Equilibrium Price, 1965 - 2000) ........ Figure 5.18 Cumulative Mortgage Loan Delinquency Rate of Consolidated Commercial Banks in Mexico ...................................................................... Figure 5.19 The Prepayment Pattern of the SHF-Guaranteed Mortgages .............................. Figure 5.20 Projections of Annual Unconditional Default Rates of the SHF 2003 Cohort ......... Figure 5.21 Projections of Annual Unconditional Prepayment Rates of the SHF 2003 Cohort.... Figure 5.22 Relationship Between Cohort Ultimate Default Rates and Profitability Rates......... Figure 6.1 The Institutional Structure of the FHA ........................................................ Figure 6.2 The Loss Mitigation Procedure Required by the FHA .................................... Figure 6.3 The Institutional Structure of the WEW ............... ....................................... Figure 6.4 The Distribution of WEW-Guaranteed Loans and Owner-Occupied Dwellings' Prices within WEW's Loan Limit, 2003..................................................... Figure 6.5 The Average Mortgage Delinquency Rates in EU Countries, 1994-2001............... Figure 6.6 The Institutional Structure of SHF........................................................... Figure 7.1 The Interpolated U.S. Treasury Yield Curves of 1981, 1986 and 1993................. Figure 7.2 Projected Six-Year Cohort Ultimate Default Rates Starting from 1981, 1986 and 1993................... - 10- 62 105 106 109 115 118 120 123 124 125 148 153 155 157 162 163 176 1...................7............. Chapter 1 Introduction I. What Is Public Mortgage Insurance Housing plays a significant role in the social and political arenas of most societies. Almost all governments intervene in housing markets through an array of policies and programs intending to stimulate housing provision and consumption. Public mortgage default insurance (MI) is one type of program promoting access to formal and affordable housing finance to the general population or targeted groups. Mortgage default insurance is a credit guaranty for financial institutions making residential mortgage loans to individuals. The credit guaranty is payable if the specified loan becomes delinquent and enters into foreclosure, and the lender fails to recoup its outstanding principal and other associated costs. The guarantee is payable in an amount up to the level of "coverage" specified in contract between the lender and the insuring entity. Claims may include not only the principal, but also delinquent interest, foreclosure and auction costs, and routine maintenance (Merrill and Whiteley, 2003). MI is one of a range of insurance products that serve to protect lenders and investors from loss (Blood, 2001).1 A public MI enterprise, directly operated or backed by the government, offers to take over from private lenders all or a portion of the credit risks associated with all or a targeted sector of mortgage loans. Public MI represents supply-side government intervention in the housing finance market. It is employed for two main reasons: 1. To encourage and expand homeownership, especially for lower and medium income households. Access to homeownership has become a policy priority in many developing as well as developed countries. The economic rationale for increasing homeownership is the belief that it has positive externalities, namely that ownership makes people better citizens and causes them to invest more in their neighborhood The other lines of insurance products include fire and extended coverage, borrower life and disability of liability insurance, lender errors and omissions insurance, fidelity bonding, flood and earthquake (special hazard) coverage, and title insurance. It may be useful to consider MI in the broader context of all possible events that can result in non-repayment of a home loan (Blood, 2001). Detailed explanations of these products can be found in Appendix 1.1. and human capital. A number of recent studies attempt to measure the benefits to homeownership, such as increase in the success of children (Green and White, 1997), citizenship (DiPasquale and Glaeser, 1999), and a variety of family outcomes and attitudes (Rossi and Weber, 1996). Acting on the economic rationale that increased homeownership boosts total social welfare, public MI addresses the issue of homeownership accessibility and affordability. 2. To provide credit enhancement to mortgage loans, thereby facilitating the development of a mortgage securitization market. By removing or reducing credit risks involved in mortgages, public MI reduces investment risks in the secondary mortgage market and mortgage-backed securities (MBS). It can stimulate the flow of funds from capital markets into the housing and mortgage sectors. This reason tends to receive greater attention in developing countries today, as they are eager to develop robust secondary mortgage markets to channel funds. In countries where public MI already exists, the historical experience has been for public MI first to help expand and improve the primary mortgage market. Then, as a by-product of that primary market momentum, public MI has tended to help accelerate development of the secondary market and MBS (Blood, 2001). However, evidence from the most recent development of public MI in emerging economies (like Mexico) has shown that the government weighs the two reasons equally important and tries to achieve them simultaneously when establishing a public MI program. A mortgage default insurance system plays an important role in the modem housing and mortgage finance markets of many developed countries, including the United States, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, United Kingdom, France, The Netherlands, China's Hong Kong, and Sweden. They have demonstrated that a MI system offers a workable and versatile credit enhancement to support expanded homeownership. Since the mid 1990s, a growing number of emerging countries and transitional economies have expressed interests in building such a system of their own. Mexico, South Africa and Lithuania have just established MI programs; in Kazakhstan, India, Latvia, and Thailand, MI is under active development; and in Russia and Poland the preliminary research and - 12- dialogues have begun to explore the feasibility of setting up a MI model. A commonality of these new or expected MI models in emerging and transition markets is the initial active involvement of the government. The forms include government-run MI programs, government-backed MI enterprises, or public-private partnership with international finance institutions providing support. Table 1.1 summarizes all existing and expected (under active development) public MI schemes worldwide. Table 1.1 Public Mortgage Default Insurance Schemes Worldwide Country with public MI Start of the program Targeted population Government involvement Premium structure (for the major product) Loan coverage Maximum Loan-tovalue ratio 1934 Low incomes Upfront 1.5% Annual 0.5% 100% 100% 1944 Veterans Operated by the U.S. government - The Department of Housing and Urban Development Operated by the U.S. government - The Department of Veterans Affairs 1954 1993 Operated by the government insurer, Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation Government-managed fund: SGFGAS 95% France: SGFGAS Low and medium incomes Low incomes Up to 100%, varies with LTVs 100% 100% Canada: CMHC Borrowers pay a funding fee to help defray costs of the VA home loan, including the MI. Varies according to LTV. Highest upfront 4.50% Upfront 2% Annual 0.15% 100% 100% The Netherlands: WEW 1995 Low and medium incomes Housing associations Low and medium incomes Low and medium incomes A private, non-profit fund backed by the government Upfront 0.3%. To be lowered to 0.28% in 2005 0.28% 100% 112% 100% - Annual 0.5% 30% 95% Floating rates, around 2.50% 30% or less 90% Annual 0.69% for UDI loans Annual 0.83% for Peso loans Maximum upfront 4.43% 25% 90% Initially 100%. In 2002 it was cut to 25% 30% initially 95% United States: FHA VA WSW 1983 Sweden: BKN 1992 Hong Kong: HKMC 1999 Mexico: SHF 2002 75 percent of all income levels Lithuania 2002 Low incomes Kazakhstan: FGIC (expected) Under active developm ent Under active developm ent Low and medium incomes India (expected) - A private, non-profit fund backed by the government Operated through the National Housing Credit Guarantee Board under the Ministry of Finance Operated through Hong Kong Mortgage Corporation Ltd., a public sector entity created to add liquidity to the Hong Kong residential mortgage market Operated by SHF, a government development bank for housing. However, the government's backing will expire in 2013. Operated by the governmentowned Lithuanian Mortgage Insurance Company FGIC will be established as a public company first. Ultimately it is to be privatized or evolve into a public private partnership. Operated through India Mortgage Guarantee Company. The National Housing Bank will hold 26% stake in the company. Other stakeholders are private MI companies and international -13- Single premiums will be offered initially - 85% Up to 100% financial institutions (ADB, IFC). Latvia (expected) Thailand (expected) Poland (expected) Russia (expected) Note: Countries that only have private MIs are: Australia, New Zealand, United Kingdom, Italy, Spain, Israel, and South Africa (operated by a NGO). In Australia, the public MI had existed until 1997 and then was taken over by the private sector. II. The Purpose and Significance of This Research The burgeoning public MI development, especially the start-up efforts in developing countries, has motivated this comparative research because the author believes that there are many important economic issues related to the establishment of public MI that are not well understood by policymakers. The questions that need to be answered include: What are the housing market failures or incompleteness that justify the government intervention? Can these imperfections be effectively and efficiently addressed through a public MI scheme? Does the government understand the financial liabilities involved in public MI provision and how they fluctuate under various economic conditions? Does the government have the administrative capability to manage or monitor a public program and deal with potential economic problems that could result from the creation of a public MI? The choice of setting up a public MI program, among other alternative housing policies, must be based on a thorough understanding of the underlying causes of a nation's housing market, and opportunity costs and risk factors for the backing government. In some countries, policymakers' preference to finance-linked housing subsidies and programs, such as public MI, is due to the "advantage" that the real costs of these programs can be "hidden," off-budget or deferred and cannot be easily quantified. However, this kind of thinking is dangerous because: i) public MI may not address the fundamental problems in the housing market; ii) there are high, often uncertain and volatile costs to the government for sponsoring a public MI program or enterprise. Even though those costs may not show up in the current budget, they have to be borne by the government (hence taxpayers) eventually; and iii) public MI may pose restrictions on the efficiency of housing finance markets and create market distortions. - 14- This research builds an integrated analytical framework for policymakers to consider the feasibility and functioning of a public MI scheme. This framework accommodates three perspectives: institutional, financial, and operational. By conducting an international comparison of three representative public MI programs - the U.S. Federal Housing Administration (FHA), the Dutch Homeownership Guarantee Fund (Stichting Waarborgfonds Eigen Woningen, abbreviated to WEW), and the Mexican Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF, Federal Mortgage Corporation) - this study analyzes fundamental economic issues with regard to the creation of public MI, government risks in supporting it, and potential economic problems resulting from it. The ultimate purpose of this research is to better inform practices in other countries, especially developing countries and transitional economies that are showing great interest in setting up their own mortgage insurance programs. Understanding the questions raised in this research bears important policy implications and helps policymakers make informed decisions. III. Three Research Questions The three research questions reflect three fundamental aspects confronting policymakers in any country wishing to create or maintain an effective and cost-efficient public MI program. They comprise the analytical framework of this comparative study: * What are the primary economic problems in the housing finance market that cause market inefficiency or market imperfections and hence call for government intervention in the form of a public MI? * What are the implied liabilities imposed on the backing government (hence taxpayers) of sponsoring a public MI enterprise? * What are the potential economic problems that can result from the creation of a public MI system? IV. The Structure of the Dissertation The dissertation is organized as follows: Chapter 2 reviews the literature on housing market imperfection and government intervention, option pricing theories that evaluate credit risks in mortgage contracts, and comparative research on housing finance systems. They constitute the theoretical foundation for this research. Chapter 3 presents research - 15 - methodology, three study cases and the rationale for their selection. Chapter 4 investigates the first research question by analyzing market imperfections in each of the three countries that justify the establishment of public MI. Chapter 5 answers the second research question by applying quantitative models and simulation techniques to measure the implied liabilities imposed on the public MI program and the supporting government under the current program regime. Multi-year and sensitivity analyses are also conducted to evaluate the magnitude of potential liabilities under different economic scenarios. Chapter 6 explores the final research question by investigating the major potential economic problems that can result from the creation of a public MI program: adverse selection, moral hazard, non-optimal risk taking and risk allocation, constraining private sector development, and the abuse of public MI for political purpose. To address these market distortions, institutional and regulatory improvements and management strategies are discussed. Chapter 7 concludes the research and discusses policy implications for any country considering MI. - 16- Appendix 1.1 Various Types of Insurance in Mortgage Finance Insurance Type Title insurance Definition Title insurance for mortgage lenders and investors provides a Risk factors Value or marketability of guarantee that they have a valid and enforceable lien on the the property securing residential real estate covered by the policy, including the mortgage is compromised priority of their lien relative to others. Title coverage assures by a defect in the title. that, in the event of borrower default and foreclosure, the value of the underlying property serving to secure the mortgage loan will not be lost as a result of a title defect or an undisclosed encumbrance that interferes with the realizable value or marketability of the property. Title/closing agent's A special title insurance/loan closing agents' errors and Mistakes by the loan E&O insurance omissions policy has been designed for damages caused by negligent acts committed by agents for title insurance companies. This specialized professional liability coverage also includes legal defenses. This coverage extends to the loan closing process itself. Wrongful acts relating to the loan closing-e.g. documentation, disclosure, or funds disbursement--can undermine the integrity of the mortgage security such that mortgage guaranty insurance coverage could be jeopardized, or lender liability under consumer protection laws might be triggered. closing agent compromise the value/integrity of the newly created mortgage security. Errors & omissions insurance (E&O) Mortgage impairment insurance Mortgagees errors and omissions coverage (an expanded form of which is also known as mortgage impairment insurance) is a specialized form of professional liability insurance which protects mortgage lenders and their secondary investors against certain liabilities and losses resulting from an error or accidental omission in the performance of certain customary operations. Failure of the mortgage servicer to perform necessary actions to maintain the investment quality status of the mortgage. Directors and officers liability insurance (D&O) Directors' and officers' liability insurance is a form of professional liability insurance which can serve the needs of financial institutions, including those engaged in mortgage lending and the servicing of mortgage loans for third party investors. D&O coverage written for mortgage bankers may have special provisions especially applicable to this particular business. D&O protects those engaged in home mortgage lending, selling and servicing against loss exposure arising from the wrongful (though not dishonest or criminal) acts of the business enterprise's executive managers and outside directors. The D&O policy covers damages, judgments and settlements. Failure of the mortgage lending and servicing institution's management to fulfill their fiduciary obligations. Homeowners' property insurance Individual homeowners almost always carry their own homeowners' property insurance policy which protects against loss by fire and, typically under 'extended coverage' provisions of the policy, a variety of other perils associated with homeownership. Extended coverage normally refers to theft, and personal liability and causes of physical damage other than fire. Value of the property securing the mortgage is reduced by fire, other physical damage, or related perils. Homeowners flood insurance Flood insurance is a specialized form of property and casualty insurance which in the U.S. involves a unique participation of the federal government in the underwriting and assumption of Value of property securing the mortgage is reduced by flood damage. financial risk. Flood insurance for residential dwellings covers loss from damage or destruction of a home caused by temporarily rising waters, unusual and rapid runoff of surface water, or mudslides or collapse of waterfront land caused by abnormal waves or currents. Coverage can be extended for both the building itself and its contents. 17- Mortgage redemption life and mortgage disability insurance The closely related life and health insurance lines, respectively, provide personal coverage for the home mortgage borrower in the event of his death or disability. Mortgage life and disability coverage offers some additional assurance of timely repayment in the event that the borrower were to die or be disabled. Mortgage redemption life insurance basically pays off the full outstanding balance of the mortgage loan if the covered borrower dies. Companion disability insurance normally makes monthly mortgage payments for a stipulated maximum term in the event of borrower disability, i.e. inability to continue working. Mortgagor is unable to make scheduled monthly payments due to death or disability. Cash flow insurance Financial guaranty insurance Cash flow insurance is a corollary coverage to mortgage guaranty insurance that is especially important to institutional investors in mortgage-backed securities. These investors are relying upon the timely, as well as the ultimate, repayment of their invested capital. Although private insurers today do not normally provide such cash flow insurance, investor requirements for timely payment are satisfied by timely payment guarantees on their mortgage-backed securities from Fannie Mae Payments received on loans in a mortgage pool fail to produce cash flow needed for required payments on mortgagebacked security. and Freddie Mac or, alternatively by the federal government's GNMA cash flow guaranty in the case of government securities backed by pools of mortgages loans that carry governmentsponsored (FHA) mortgage guaranty insurance. Financial guaranty insurance guaranties the timely payment of principal and interest, as well as ultimate repayment, on privately issued mortgage-backed securities that are not issued by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. Source: http://www.usaid.gov/locations/europeeurasia/ demgov/localgov/pdf - 18 - ddocs/annexb.pdf Chapter 2 Theoretical Framework This research is mainly built on three strands of literature, which comprises the theoretical foundation of the study: i) imperfection of the housing market and housing finance market, and government intervention; ii) evaluating credit risks in mortgage contracts and mortgage insurance based on option-pricing theories; and iii) comparative research on different housing finance systems and international mortgage insurance models. I. Housing Finance Market Imperfection and Government Intervention Broadly speaking, housing finance market imperfection is mainly caused by a whole class of "information costs." One such information cost resulting in market failures is "credit rationing". The theory of credit rationing is developed by Jaffe (1971), Jaffee and Modigliani (1971), and by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). They argue that lenders' concerns about credit risk cause them to ration credit rather than to charge higher interest rates. The resulting equilibrium of a loan market is characterized by excess demand over supply. Potential borrowers who are denied loans would not be able to borrow even if they indicated a willingness to pay more than the market interest rate, or to put up more collateral than is demanded of loan recipients. Lenders fear adverse selection - higher rates will attract risky borrowers and drive away good borrowers; thus higher rates do not lead to greater returns. As a result, they apply various nonprice rationing techniques (underwriting and collateral requirements) that limit default risk. These binding credit constraints reflect lenders' uncertainty about borrower abilities to repay the loan or uncertainty about the collateral value behind the loan (e.g., location in a declining neighborhood). In the U.S., some empirical studies compare the characteristics of FHA and conventional borrowers. The study by Canner, Gabriel, and Wolley (1991) evaluates the likelihood of obtaining a conventional versus an FHA loan as a function of various borrower and neighborhood characteristics that reflect default risk. They find that young and lowerincome borrowers living in lower-income census tracts are more likely to choose FHA, as - 19- are borrowers with a high probability of mortgage payment delinquency. Other studies have also found that FHA financing mitigates the effects of credit rationing and redlining (Rosenthal, Duca, and Gabriel, 1991; Shear and Yezer, 1983; Holmes and Horvitz, 1994). Another type of "information cost" is the uncertainty risk of the housing market as a whole. During the 1930s in the U.S., high information costs of each mortgage and the local housing market made housing finance a very local industry, resulting in an imbalanced capital demand and supply across regions. However, this kind of information cost hardly exists today in advanced economies, thanks to the development of communication and transportation technologies and the deregulation of a nationalized housing finance market. But high information costs do exist in developing countries and emerging economies where there is no history of private lending and tracking of borrower credit. Information costs there can be so high that the private sector is reluctant to invest in housing finance markets. Uncertainty risks are a special type of information cost. Foster and Herzog (1981) argue that the ability of individual homeowners to repay their loans is highly dependent upon the economy of the nation. Therefore mortgage insurance is an economic (or fundamental) risk. The uncertainty risks of the whole market's behavior in the future suggest that mortgage insurance involves risks that are not appropriately treated through the private sector, and therefore should be handled by the government. Much has been writen on government intervention and subsidy programs for housing finance markets. Hoek-Smit and Diamond (2003) provide a good summary of various housing subsidy policies and programs. They emphasize that in overcoming policy or market failure or extending incomplete markets, policymakers must understand the causes of the supply or demand constraints. If poor access to, or high cost of, housing finance is the main bottleneck, relevant policy or regulatory changes and/or financelinked subsides may be considered - among them public default insurance. However, if the high cost of finance is related to monopolies or other major inefficiencies, subsidies will merely pay for these inefficiencies. In their view, state-sponsored insurance or guarantees can be used as a policy tool to encourage mortgage lending in general in the - 20 - face of legal, economic or political uncertainties. However, they argue that it is very important not to use it when the underlying problem is such that the legal, social or political environment does not permit management of default risks. Academic discussions on the economic and social welfare impacts of government intervention are abundant. Within the context of public mortgage insurance, the comprehensive study by Bunce et al (1996) concludes that FHA helps complete the mortgage lending market by serving the populations that are unserved or underserved by the private sector. They argue that the range of service provided by FHA extends beyond that available from private MIs enabling it to accommodate higher risk borrowers. Pennington-Cross and Yezer (2000) analyze FHA's role within the U.S. mortgage markets as creating regional stabilization, information externalities in mortgage scoring schemes, reducing lending discrimination, and generating homeownership externalities. Follain and Szymanoski (1995) discuss the government's evolving role in the U.S. multifamily mortgage markets and the experience of the FHA program in multi-family insurance. Diamond and Lea (1992) argue that the distortionary effects of the U.S. government guarantees in the mortgage market are declining rapidly as the capital requirements for banks and federally sponsored agencies have been strengthened and FHA premiums raised. Government intervention can cause problems in the housing finance marketplace as well. Adverse selection and moral hazard have been thoroughly discussed by Kihlstrom and Pauly (1971), and Spence and Zeckhauser (1971). Pauly (1974) further explores the overinsurance and public provision of insurance and argues that in the presence of adverse selection and moral hazard, the competitive outcome in the markets for insurance may be nonoptimal. One solution to this nonoptimality is some form of public intervention. But he emphasizes that the advantage of public provision lies in its ability to generate a particular kind of information. Through public provision of insurance, firms are provided with information on the total amount of insurance bought by each prospective purchaser. Either this information could be provided directly, or a law could require the purchaser to provide correct information on total purchases to all firms. With - 21 - this information an optimal market outcome may occur. Diamond and Lea (1992) made an international comparison of five developed countries' government intervention of housing finance markets in the form of "special" circuits, characterized by a significant degree of regulation, segmentation from the rest of the financial markets, and often substantial government subsidy. They conclude that many of these special circuits created certain degrees of distortion and inefficiency in the housing finance systems, and all subject countries have converged significantly toward competitive market allocation of mortgage credit since the 1980s. However, they also point out that in many developing countries where barriers to the market-oriented operation of housing finance are serious, the government intervention may still be necessary to overcome the difficulties of the market in pricing and allocating risk. The study by Hoek-Smit and Diamond (2003) compares various demand- and supply-side government interventions for housing finance from aspects of efficiency, equity, transparency and implementation. They point out that government-sponsored insurance or guarantee for primary mortgage market risks can be a relatively efficient way of encouraging mortgage lending, especially to targeted groups. However, such programs can be highly damaging if they deter the resolution of economic and political issues that are elevating default risks. Also, without any objective risk assessment such schemes can be very expensive in the long run. II. Credit Risks in Mortgage Contract and Mortgage Insurance The major concern for mortgage insurance is credit risks from borrower default. Many studies view the mortgage contract as containing a compound put (default) and an American call (prepayment) option. The contingent claims models, developed by Black and Scholes (1973), Merton (1973), Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1985), and others, provide a coherent motivation for borrower behavior. A number of studies have applied this model to the mortgage market. Hendershott and Van Order (1987) and Kau and Keenan (1995) have surveyed much of the literature related to mortgage pricing. Early studies using option models focused on explaining either prepayment or default behavior, but not both. A series of papers by Kau, Keenan, Muller, and Epperson (1992, 1995), Kau and Keenan (1996), Titman and Torous (1989), and Deng, Quigley, and Van Order (1996, 2000) have provided theoretical models and empirical tests that emphasize the - 22 - importance of the jointness of prepayment and default options. In recent years, survival analysis (especially proportional hazard estimation) with prepayments and default treated as competing risks has become the preferred empirical approach to investigating mortgage credit. Some researchers explore the "nonruthless" exercise of the mortgage default or prepayment options. Deng, Quigley, and Van Order (2000) show that there exists significant heterogeneity among mortgage borrowers; a pure option model is not enough in itself to predict borrower behavior. Vandell (1992, 1995), Vandell and Thibodeau (1985), Foster and Van Order (1985), and Lekkas, Quigley, and Van Order (1993) have also found evidence of nonruthless default behavior. Four facts about the nature of the decision-making process with respect to prepayment and default impact the nonruthlessness in exercising mortgage options (Vandell, 1995): various transaction costs among borrowers and lenders; borrower's solvency or ability to service the debt; loss mitigation efforts; and the value of waiting. Literature on credit risks of mortgage portfolios and mortgage insurance is mainly focused on risk-based capital requirements or insurance pricing, built upon the underlying mortgage portfolio performance. The performance measures include conditional probabilities of delinquency, foreclosure, and prepayment. Existing models of measuring credit risks can be categorized into three broad types: econometric models, stochastic simulation models, and "hybrid" models incorporating the two. The econometric models estimate mortgage default and prepayment rates based on empirical loan data (LTV, loan type, etc.) and various borrower characteristics (downpayment, income, race, age, neighborhood, etc.). Then the estimated coefficients are applied to new portfolios of loans to project the adequate capital requirements or mortgage insurance premium. Among them, multi-variant regression models are often used by government agencies and auditors. Academic research using the econometric models generally includes proxy variables for the default and prepayment options, measuring the extent to which these two options are "in-the-money. " The contingent - 23 - claim model specifies the probability of exercising these options as a function to the extent to which they are in-the-money, and the "trigger events" that effect the decision on how far the options need to be in-the-money for it to be optimal to exercise. Several recent empirical studies have applied the Cox Proportional Hazard model (introduced by Cox and Oakes, 1984) to estimate mortgage risks (e.g. Quigley and Van Order, 1991; Deng, Quigley, and Van Order, 1995, 2000; and Tiwari, 2001; among others). Instead of solving for the unique critical values of the state variables in the contingent claim model, the proportional hazard model assumes that at each point of time during the mortgage contract period, the mortgage has a certain probability of termination, conditional on survival of the mortgage. The stochastic simulation models use option-pricing techniques to determine the impact of changes in the mortgage contract or in the economic environment on mortgage insurance values. The value is obtained numerically as the solution of a two-dimensional partial differential equation in backward time, whose terminal and boundary conditions embody the terms of the contract. In particular, two stochastic processes for interest rate movements and housing price fluctuations are simulated, as well as the correlation between the two. Both of the decisions to default and prepayment are simulated through a set of decision rules based on numerical models - certain algorithms take discrete increments (or decrements) in the housing price and interest rate in every specified interval until the insurance contract expires. If the house price hits certain critical value defined by boundary conditions, borrowers default or prepay. The net present value of losses from a portfolio of loans is to be compensated by the insurance premiums charged. Cunningham and Hendershott (1984) apply this approach to the pricing of FHA mortgage insurance. Kau, Heenan and Muller (1993) use a similar model to price private mortgage insurance value through a set of numerical solutions with different economic environments and mortgage contracts. Kau and Keenan (1996) improve the model by introducing catastrophic events into the model, incorporating a Poisson distribution into the building process. - 24 - The third type of models combines part of the econometric model and part of the stochastic model, creating a "hybrid" model incorporating both historic experience and simulation techniques. Calem and LaCour-Little (2001) develop estimates of risk-based capital requirements for single-family mortgages held in portfolio by financial intermediaries. They first use Cox's proportional hazard model to estimate the probability distributions of default and prepayment, and then apply the estimated coefficients in stochastic simulation models to project credit loss probability distributions. Similar approaches are employed by Rodda, Lam and Youn (2004) to study the FHA HECMs (Home Equity Conversion Mortgages) refinancing option. A series of papers by Capone (2000, 2002, 2003) simulate the distribution of potential lifetime default and prepayment rates and their patterns based on historic FHA loan data, and then analyze the cash flows associated with each default rate. The simpler version of his model (2000) is to parameterize the default rate distribution to match the limited information available on expected lifetime default rates of the FHA historical books of business. With some simple prepayment rules and assumptions, simulations using random draws from the default rate distribution are used to develop a distribution of mortgage insurance values. Capone (2003) further improves the model by incorporating a stochastic economic model based on a vector autoregressive system of equations. At the institutional level of valuing public MI provision, a recent study by Buckley, Karaguishiyeva, Van Order and Vecvagare (2001) has extended the early work by Merton (1977) that demonstrated an isomorphic correspondence between loan guarantees and common stock put options. Buckley et al. assume that government provides implicit guarantee (backing) to the public mortgage insurance enterprise, in case it cannot cover its liabilities. Public transfers arise when the value of the mortgaged housing and the insurance company's capital is less than the value of outstanding loans. The probability of exercising this option by the insurance company imposes a risk to the government. The authors apply Merton's model to the terms and conditions of 12 forms of mortgage insurance now in use in 9 countries and discuss the relative risks of the various programs. - 25 - III. Comparative Research on Different Housing Finance Systems and International Mortgage Insurance Models Comparative studies of various housing markets and housing finance systems is a recent addition to the literature of housing finance. Diamond and Lea's study (1992) compares the housing finance markets between the United States and United Kingdom, to conclude that these countries have exhibited a significant degree of convergence toward competitive market arrangements in the last decade. However, significant differences remain, and those differences seem to derive partly from historical precedents and partly from different goals of public policy. Jaffee and Renaud (1996) have conducted a comparative study among transitional economies on their mortgage market development and concluded that a housing finance system is an essential component of the development of an efficient financial system in a transitional economy. However, a housing finance system is unlikely to emerge without government support. With growing interest in mortgage insurance systems in many developing countries since the 1990s, more research has been done analyzing particular mortgage insurance schemes in some countries. Blood (1998, 2001) analyzes the feasibility of building a mortgage guarantee system in Mexico and Poland, identifying certain prerequisite market conditions for a viable mortgage guarantee model, including economic and financial stability, contract enforceability, data availability, title to real property, loan underwriting and servicing, real estate markets, regulation, and credit and homeownership culture. Blood and Whiteley' s (2004) report for the Russian Federation analyzes the market readiness for a mortgage insurance system in Russia and concludes that a public MI is hard to justify in the immediate near term even if needed laws and data are present. Papers by Merrill and Whiteley (2002, 2003) are focused on the experience of establishing Guarantee Insurance Fund for Mortgage Credit (FGIC) in Kazakhstan and how to export that to other transitional and emerging markets. Several conference presentations provide an overview of existing mortgage guarantee models in Hong Kong (Lamoreaux, 1999), The Netherlands (Mersmann, 2001), to name a few. - 26 - Among the existing studies, however, very few have taken the task of comparing various guarantee models in a comprehensive way. Blood (2001) provides a good general international overview of the existing mortgage default insurance programs and some key issues for their survival or success, and points out that government supportive policies are indispensable. However, his research is more focused on empirical summaries than theoretical analysis. Buckley et al (2001) compare several mortgage guarantee schemes from one specific perspective: the implied housing market volatility that can be accommodated by a public MI model if that model does not impose liabilities on the government. The model they use for comparison is highly simplified and static in the sense that the interest rate is considered fixed and the fluctuation in the value of the "debt" (the liability to the insurer) is ignored. Nonetheless, their model suggests how to quantify government credit risks in sponsoring a public MI program, and how to conduct comparable analysis across countries. IV. Added Value of This Research This research adds significantly to the existing literature of housing finance and international comparative study. As an important component of the increasingly unbundled mortgage finance market, mortgage insurance plays a significant role in both primary and secondary markets. However, there are very few studies on the systematic and quantitative comparison of different mortgage insurance models. As more papers introduce individual cases of new MI models, the development of a holistic and comparative view on some representative MI systems becomes increasingly necessary. This research fills gaps in the current academic literature in the following respects: * It is the first integrated framework for analyzing the feasibility and functioning of public: mortgage insurance systems. It explores the three fundamental questions of Chapter 1 regarding a public MI model, and answers them from three distinct perspectives: institutional, financial, and operational. The framework has general implications for a country wishing to establish or is in the process of developing its own public MI system. * It is the first comprehensive comparative study of three public MI models at different development stages, ranging from a mature model to a model still in its - 27 - infancy, in developed countries as well as the developing world. This international comparison can shed new light on the socio-economic rationales and functioning of a public MI model for a wide range of audience. * It is among the first few studies that apply numerical simulation models to quantify the scale of credit risk in supporting a public MI system, and analyze the magnitude of that risk under different economic scenarios and across different countries. - 28 - Chapter 3 Research Methodology and Three Study Cases I. Research Methodology The nature of this research lends itself to both qualitative and quantitative methodologies. I have used a multi-case study approach for this research and put it into a comparative framework to demonstrate the commonalities and variations among the three public MI systems. Qualitative methodologies include intensive semi-structured personal and phone interviews, conducted not only with personnel from the three public MI entities, but also with their regulators, competitors, close partners and lenders. In quantitative analysis, relevant data are collected from monthly and annual management reports, financial statements, actuarial review reports, various documents and mortgagee letters, and program websites. Methodologies deployed are regression analysis, Monte Carlo simulations and discounted cash flow analysis. The quantitative analysis does not intend to provide an accurate projection of the implied liabilities for the public MI program and the backing government in each of the three countries. Rather, it serves as an analytical tool to demonstrate and compare the magnitude of credit risks imposed on the government under different program design and country characteristics, in a consistent and quantifiable manner. II. Three Study Cases I have chosen three existing public MI programs as my study cases: the U.S. Federal Housing Administration (FHA), the Dutch Homeownership Guarantee Fund (Stichting Waarborgfonds Eigen Woningen, abbreviated to WEW), and the Mexican Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF, Federal Mortgage Corporation). The following is a brief introduction of each of the three countries' housing and housing finance markets, housing policies, and government involvement, followed by the description of their public MI programs and the reasons for their selection. - 29 - A. The United States and the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) The U.S. housing and housing finance markets There are about 290 million people and 121 million housing units in the United States. The U.S. housing market features free market forces and very moderate government intervention. Public housing accounts for less than 5 percent of the total housing stock. Almost 65 percent of all houses are detached and slightly less than 15 percent are built in a complex comprising more than 5 dwellings (The WEW special report, 2004). The homeownership rate was quite high, at about 69 percent in 2004. The rental sector is run by private landlords. The U.S. housing and mortgage markets play an important role in the U.S. economy. Housing is the primary source of wealth for most Americans. Spending within the housing sector (including rents, utilities, furnishings, maintenance, repair, and remodeling) has accounted for about one-fifth of the national economic activity for decades. The U.S. government has been actively promoting homeownership. As a result of that, and also the strong house price appreciation, U.S. mortgage debt outstanding is currently around 6.1 trillion dollars, having grown at a 7.5 percent compound annual rate since 1994 even after adjusting for inflation. Mortgage debt now accounts for 43 percent of residential value, up from 31.6 percent in 1980. The U.S. housing finance system is often regarded as one of the most efficient and effective capital market structures in the world. Between the end of World War II and the 1970s, American mortgage markets were dominated by depository institutions (mainly savings and loan associations or, more broadly, thrift institutions). The mortgages were financed with low-cost, short term, government-insured deposits. The rise in the secondary markets in the 1970s and especially in the 1980s came about largely because of standardization of pools of mortgages brought on by three government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs): the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae), and for government-insured loans, the Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae). Annual sales of mortgages to these three institutions have risen to over $700 billion in 1998; they now - 30- own or are responsible for about half of the outstanding stock of single-family mortgages in the U.S. The U.S. government is actively involved in the housing finance markets mainly through operating the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) and Ginnie Mae, and regulating Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The FederalHousingAdministration The history of the FHA finds its origin in the Great Depression with the failure of the housing and financial systems. In 1934, Congress passed The National Housing Act and established the Federal Housing Administration (FHA). The objective of the FHA was to encourage banks, building and loan associations, and other approved institutions to make loans for building homes, small business establishments, and farm buildings, by insuring all loans underwritten to its standards. Since its inception, the FHA has experienced periods of great success and failure. The historic impact of the FHA mortgage insurance program has been significant. In addition to laying the financial infrastructure for the vibrant secondary market that exists in the U.S. today, the FHA helped raise physical housing standards by publishing the FHA Minimum Property Standards, which provided detailed specifications for new middle-income housing. Later, the FHA was essential to developing appraisal standards that help set market values, minimize fraud, and establish quality control features that are used today. Currently, the FHA is one of the largest credit programs within the U.S. government. It continues to provide mortgage insurance to encourage lenders making credit available to expand homeownership to unserved or underserved populations. The FHA covers 100 percent loan losses due to borrower defaults. Since its inception, the FHA has provided mortgage insurance to 32.6 million single family households and 45,000 multifamily projects containing 5 million units of housing. The FHA currently has 5.3 million insured single family mortgages and 12,706 insured multifamily projects in its portfolio (FHA Management report, FY2003). In FY 2003, FHA insured about 1.3 million loans, a value of 159 billion dollars of new mortgage originations, and its total insurance-in-force (IIF) -31 - was 490 billion dollars. 88.9 percent of its IIF is the single-family mortgage insurance business.2 The FHA's major insurance fund, the Mutual Mortgage Insurance (MMI) fund, was estimated with an economic value of 22.7 billion dollars at the end of FY 2003. 3 Targeting lower income borrowers, the FHA-insured loans have a ceiling that is 87 percent of the conforming loan 4 ceiling or 312,896 dollars in 2005 for high-cost areas and 48 percent of the conventional loan limit in low cost areas or 172,632 dollars in 2005. As with conventional loans, the financing limit is higher for properties with multiple units two-to-four with at least one owner-occupied. The challenge of the FHA is to remain meaningful and valuable to the nation's housing system, while relinquishing business that can be well-managed by a viable private MI sector. Today the mission of the FHA MI program within national mortgage markets is to: * Encourage homeownership among low-income, first-time homebuyers and minority borrowers; * Counteract lending discrimination nationwide; * Establish mortgage loan quality standards and explore new financial instruments and insurance products; * Generate useful information and develop technology that will positively impact the provision of housing; and * Support multifamily projects for affordable housing. While the main business of the FHA program is to provide insurance for single-family and multifamily residential housing and healthcare facilities, other businesses include: property acquisitions, maintenance and servicing of the property, foreclosure sales (for FHA portfolios borrower defaults and loan foreclosure), and loss mitigation incentives and mortgage notes assignment activities. 2 FHA's multifamily and health care insurance business comprised 10.8 percent of its IIF. 3 At the end of FY2003, the MMI Fund comprised 82.48 percent of the FHA Insurance Fund. The other funds are: the General Insurance (GI) Fund, 16.55 percent; the Special Risk Insurance (SRI) Fund, 0.92 percent, and the Cooperative Management Housing Insurance (CMHI) Fund, 0.05 percent. 4 If a borrower borrows at or below the conventional loan limit for non-government mortgages, he/she would have what is generally known as a "conforming" loan. If the amount borrowed is above the conventional loan limit, he/she would have a "jumbo" loan and face a somewhat higher rate because larger loans imply more lender risk. - 32 - B. The Netherlands and the Homeownership Guarantee Fund (WEW) The Dutchhousing and housingfinance markets Over 16 million people live in the Netherlands. The Dutch housing system is known for being effectively and stringently regulated by the government, mainly through housing policies and spatial planning policies. The Dutch housing market has several defining characteristics: the strong position of the social rental sector, broad rental subsidies and rent controls.,and significant provision of developable land by municipalities. At the end of 2003, the Dutch housing stock consisted of about 6.7 million dwellings, of which 2.4 million were in the social rental sector (35 percent); the owner-occupied sector comprised 54% of the housing stock; and the private rental sector was much smaller, only about 11%. Traditionally the Netherlands has not had a large owner-occupied housing sector and government policy was more focused on constructing social rental housing owned and managed by housing associations. Since 1989, the Dutch housing policy has changed in favor of market forces and less government intervention. As a result, demand for homeownership surged. In 2000, the Dutch Parliament accepted a policy paper "What People Want, Where People Live" that defined national housing goals through the year 2010. One of the core objectives is to increase homeownership to 65 percent by 2010. The establishment of the WEW guarantee fund for homeownership is one of the government measures to achieve that goal. The Dutch mortgage market has grown enormously over the past decade, in line with the owner-occupied market. Outstanding mortgages for housing were 363 billion euros, accounting for 81 percent of the national GDP in 2001 (The WEW special report, 2004). The major players in the housing finance market are commercial banks, special mortgage banks, insurance companies and savings banks. The government involvement in housing finance is embodied in two guarantee funds: the WEW (Stichting Waarborgfonds Eigen Woningen) fund to facilitate homeownership, and the WSW (Stichting Waarborgfonds Sociale Woningbouw) fund to ensure the financial stability of housing associations. - 33 - The Homeownership Guarantee Fund (WEW) The WEW was created by the Dutch Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment and the VNG (the association of Netherlands municipalities) in November 1993. It is a private, non-profit organization with close ties to the central and local governments through their continuous backing. 5 Since 1995, the WEW has been issuing its insurance product - the National Mortgage Guarantee (NHG) - to provide mortgage guarantees to borrowers who purchase an existing or newly built owner-occupied house. The guarantees for home improvements were issued from the beginning of 1999. WEW's guarantee covers 100 percent of the loan amount. As a result, borrowers can obtain high loan-to-value ratio (LTV) loans, even with LTV exceeding 100 percent. Lenders also benefit from WEW guarantees because of the "zero solvency" with the guarantee, so that they do not need to keep capital reserves on their balance sheets. The WEW aims to serve low and middle income populations. The loan ceiling for WEW's guarantees is C230,000 in 2004, which includes all the transaction costs such as notary costs, commission fees, etc. Loans for home improvements fall under the same conditions. On average, the Fund provides approximately 60,000 guarantees a year. In 2003, the WEW provided an all time high of 73,889 guarantees of Cl billion loan value. The potential market share (the market segment qualifying for WEW guarantees) of the WEW is about 50 percent of the total mortgage market in the Netherlands, within which the Fund actually reached about half of it. Therefore, its guarantee product penetration is around 25 percent. Since its inception in 1995, the Fund has issued 521,181 guarantees with a value of C60 billion. As of the end of 2003, the WEW's equity was C286 million. This amount serves as capital reserves to cover the risk of a nominal amount of about C52 billion guaranteed mortgages (i.e., insurance-in-force). The capital ratio of the WEW fund in relation to its guaranteed capital was approximately 0.55 percent in 2003. 5 They agree to provide the WEW interest-free loans to top up its capital reserves if these reserves fall below a minimum obliged level. The critical limit of the fund reserves is fixed at 1.5 times the average loss level during the last 5 years. If the fund reserves drop down below this critical level, both the central government and participating municipalities will provide the fund with subordinate interest-free loans. Therefore, the Dutch Central Bank considers the guarantee as a government guarantee. - 34- The WEW is a lean organization with the sole business of providing mortgage guarantees to single-family owner-occupied houses, for purchases or home improvements. It stipulates regulations for the guarantee issuance, and delegates all other tasks to lenders, including underwriting the guarantees, property acquisition and foreclosure sales, and recourse to defaulted borrowers. C. Mexico and the Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF) The Mexican housing and housing finance markets As a developing country with huge housing pressure, Mexico is at a crossroads. Restoration of macroeconomic stability after the 1994-1995 financial crisis, coupled with strong government commitment to housing reforms, provides the nation with a unique opportunity to strengthen its housing finance markets and improve housing conditions to meet increasing demand. The current population of Mexico is about 105 million, most of whom live in cities larger than 100,000. The estimated shortage of housing amounts to over 10 million houses and the needs of new financial and infrastructure programs are huge. 750,000 new homes are needed annually in Mexico just because of household formation. Mexico's housing market is highly segmented. 6 Its housing stock consists of about 24.5 million homes, twothirds of which are in the bottom three market segments (Minimum, Social and Economic). However, half of the housing stock value is concentrated in the higher-end houses in the Middle, Residential and Residential Plus segments (The State of Mexico's Housing, 2004). The substantial value contained in the existing housing stock is highly under-leveraged. Only 12.6 percent of the housing stock is currently mortgaged. The 6 Mexico's existing housing stock and its value distribution Price range (000s of pesos) Minimum Avg. price (Pesos) Price (minimum wage equivalents) 5.4 MW Number of units (Millions) 1.85 Value (Billions of pesos) $14.6 <80 79,000 80-200 151,000 10.4 MW 7.17 $108.1 Economic Middle 200-380 380-1,000 217,000 568,000 14.9 MW 39.0 MW 6.46 6.96 $139.9 $395.2 Residential 1,000-2,000 1,230,000 84.6 MW 1.18 $145.4 >2,000 3,628,000 249 MW 0.81 $292.8 24.43 $1095.9 Social Residential plus Total Source. Softec 2003 35 - primary emphasis of Mexican housing policy for at least the last 30 years has been homeownership, and with considerable success: 78 percent of households own their own homes, and about 13 percent of households rent. However, The most significant challenge in Mexican housing markets continues to be the presence of a large informal sector, creating substantial negative externalities. Mexico's current housing finance system is probably more complex, fragmented, and "outside the banking system" than in any other emerging markets. Access to housing finance has been dominated by political and administrative processes rather than market driven. Major players in the housing finance system are segmented according to markets: i) low income (people earning less than 3 minimum wages (mws); ii) social interest (earning 3 to 8 mws); and iii) middle and upper income (earning 9 mws and above). A spectrum of private to public entities serves their targeted populations. Overall, the housing finance system in Mexico serves only a small portion of the total potential market, and relies on government-sponsored financial institutions and mandated housing finance revenue streams (The State of Mexico's Housing, 2004). Public or publicly mandated institutions provide the majority of housing finance. The housing sub-accounts of the pension programs (INFONAVIT and FOVISSSTE) are financed through mandatory contributions by firms and employees. They primarily finance the sale of new homes to low-wage employees in formal private and public sector jobs. Currently, the private sector provides very little capital for housing finance because of the damage caused by the 1994-95 peso crisis. The Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal (SHF) The SHF was chartered in 2001 as a federal development bank and is currently owned by the federal government. Its predecessor, FOVI (Fondo de Operacion y Financiamiento Bancario a la Vivienda), was established in 1963 as a trust fund to channel federal government money to housing. From February 2002, the SHF took on FOVI's trust role. The SHF was created in order to grant loans and guarantees to intermediary finance organizations. It does not have a retail operation, but channels funds through Mexican - 36 - commercial banks and SOFOLes,7 acting as a second-tier bank. Currently SHF offers loans for purchase of new or existing homes by individuals for ownership or rental, land development and commercial infrastructure (The State of Mexico's Housing 2004). It serves a broad target market of households earning between 2 and 50 minimum wages (3,000 to 75,000 U.S. dollars), qualifying 75 percent of all families in Mexico, and specifically, 91 percent of families in the 80 largest cities. Over the most recent few years, the management and strategic direction at the SHF has changed such that mortgage default insurance has become its main focal point. Now its primary mandate is to develop the mortgage securitization market in Mexico by granting guarantees and standardizing the origination and administration of mortgage loans. The SHF provides intermediary financiers with a 25 percent first-loss mortgage default guarantee, in addition to the other two guarantee products it offers - the construction loan guarantee and on-time payment guarantee for MBS. SHF's guarantees carry the full faith and credit of the Mexican government until October 2013. After then, whatever liabilities undertaken by the SHF will be supported by the institution's own financial strength. Eventually the SHF hopes to see private MI companies come into the Mexican mortgage market after it demonstrates the viability of the MI business and it then can become a resinsurer and share the risks with private partners. The SHF's MI product has been in existence for only a little more than two years. 8 From 2002 to 2004 (August 31), SHF issued about 140,000 guarantees of a total loan value of 35 billion pesos (about 3 billion U.S. dollars). In 2003, it issued 53,149 loans with a total amount of 15.5 billion pesos (equivalent of 1.36 billion U.S. dollars). As of 2003, SHF's capital reserves for its first-loss mortgage guarantees are about 197 million pesos, to cover the potential losses of its 24.3 billion pesos insurance-in-force, indicating a capital ratio of 0.81 percent. 7 Sofoles are special purpose financial companies, also known as non-bank banks. Since their inception, mortgage Sofoles have concentrated on originating and servicing FOVI (now SHF) products. Sofoles are the most dynamic sector of the Mexican housing market. They have grown from zero in 1995 to controlling over 95 percent of the SHF program by December 2002, originating, underwriting, and servicing almost 300,000 loans in that period. 8 There was an old MI product, the Pari-Pasu, under the previous FOVI regime. Some of the Pari-Pasu guarantees are transferred to be under the SHF's first-loss guarantees. - 37 - The SHF's mortgage guarantee program will likely exert big influences on Mexico's housing and mortgage markets, such as the following: * Establish consistent mortgage origination standards; * Consolidate consumer credit information across a large number of institutions; * Develop standardized servicing guidelines; and * Build up the market confidence and set up clear rules for the private sector to participate in mortgage insurance business or invest in MBS. III. Choice of the Three Cases I choose the FHA, WEW and SHF as my study cases for comparison, for the following reasons: a) They are representative models. The world of public MI programs can be categorized by two main criteria: the direct operator of the program and the macro economic context of the country where the program is operated. As shown below, the three cases are exemplars of each of the three existing scenarios: Government- Government- run public MI backed, privately rpublic MI FHA i)~ w Developed countries Non-existent Developing FHA: directly run by the government, operating in a developed economy WEW: backed by the government and run by a privately foundation, operating in a developed economy SHF: directly run by a government agency, operating in a developing country countries The U.S. FHA is a full-fledged public MI program completely managed by the government. It operates in a developed economy with the fully private housing market and mature housing finance market, including both the primary and secondary mortgage markets. Similar public MI models can be found in Canada and Hong Kong. The Dutch WEW is operated by a private, non-profit organization with the full backing of the central and local governments. It functions in an advanced economy with strong government intervention in the housing and housing finance markets. The WEW is to reduce barriers to homeownership rather than to promote it. As a result of Dutch government policy in the past, a significant portion of the housing stock is - 38 - social rental housing. Similar context is shared to some extent by many other European countries, such as France. The Mexican SHF is a government development bank with a limited period (until 2013) of full government backing. It is developing fast as a major player in Mexico's primary market and to jump-start the development of the secondary market. By issuing mortgage insurance, the SHF hopes to achieve multiple goals such as accumulating market data, setting clear rules, and building the necessary legal, social and financial infrastructure. Challenges faced by the SHF reflect a lot of common legal and socio-economic problems shared among developing countries and emerging economies. In short, the FHA stands for a mature and complex public MI entity fully embedded within the government in an advanced and developed private housing market; the WEW represents a relatively young and simple public MI entity, in the form of a private, non-profit organization, that operates in a developed economy with both the private housing market and social housing sector; and the SHF typifies a nascent yet aggressively developing public MI program run by the government, in an emerging economy facing severe housing shortage and housing finance market flaws. b) They are at different stages of the public MI development. The U.S. FHA has existed since 1934 and its purposes and products have been adapting to housing policy and housing market changes ever since. The Dutch WEW has been operating in its current form only since 1995, and has not yet been through any severe economic downturns. The Mexican SHF was created recently, post the severe financial crisis of 1994-1995 that essentially damaged the confidence of the mortgage market. The SHF is expected to restore and stimulate mortgage lending and channel much-needed funds to the housing sector. The comparison among the evolutionary paths of the three public MI schemes can provide valuable insights applicable to a wide range of countries. FHA: mature WEW: developing/stabilizing SHF: sarting Moreover., the evolution of a public MI system cannot be separated from the broader housing finance market development and changes of the national housing policy. The three chosen countries have similarities and differences in these aspects as well. - 39 - c) The structure and design of their public MI systems differ in significant and interesting ways. The differences range from institutional context, organizational framework and operational management, to MI product details such as the premium structure, target populations, loss coverage, claim payment method and timing, and risk containment. The variations among the three cases illustrate that a public MI scheme is country-specific. The comparison shows how they fit into the unique context of their nations' housing markets and housing finance systems and the mechanism they use to address specific housing finance problems. - 40- Chapter 4 Market Inefficiency And Economic Rationales For Public MI I. A. Market Inefficiency and Uncertainty Risks Public MI Addresses Market Inefficiency Economic theories distinguish four main types of market inefficiency: externalities, information imperfections, market power, and public goods. Public MI, as one type of government intervention, has to be justified by certain economic rationales that address housing finance market inefficiency. As discussed earlier, public MI is usually established for two main purposes: promote or expand homeownership, and provide necessary credit enhancement to facilitate secondary market development. In a complete housing finance market, as usually found in developed countries, the fundamental reason for government involvement in increasing homeownership is its positive externalities. This suggests that homeownership is likely to be undersupplied from a social perspective because private sectors cannot reap the full benefits of homeownership and therefore will not provide it to the socially optimal level. The government steps in to provide MI to private lenders, lowering their investment risks and the cost of capital, and thereby boosting the supply of mortgage credits or lowering the barrier (e.g. downpayment threshold) to obtaining a mortgage. In many cases, the housing finance market is incomplete in emerging and developing economies. Only a small proportion of households can afford newly constructed housing - recent calculations show that this figure is around the 7 0 th percentile of the income distribution in countries like Brazil, Mexico and Indonesia (Hoek-Smit and Diamond, 2003). Owing to the lack of access to formal housing finance, most newly formed households in these countries are left with the choice of doubling up with relatives, building informal and substandard housing (slum formation), or squatting. In these situations, the public MI brings foremost public goods such as better public health, improved fairness and societal stability, in addition to expanding the boundary of homeownership affordability to create positive externalities. In providing credit enhancement for developing the secondary mortgage market, especially mortgage securitization, public MI addresses the market inefficiency of information imperfections. In developing countries and emerging economies, there is - 41 - often little history of formal mortgage lending and no tracking of borrower credit. Investors lack confidence in the country's macro economy and its mortgage market stability, or they are concerned about the quality of the mortgage portfolio backing the MBS issuance because of asymmetric information. These concerns of evaluating uncertain risks involved in mortgages can not only lead to a prohibitive level of private cost of capital in mortgage lending, but also hamper the advancement of the mortgage securitization market through which many developing countries hope to channel much needed capital to the housing sector. A government-sponsored MI system lowers the information costs for private lenders and eases the uncertainty concerns of MBS investors by essentially reducing their need for mortgage performance information, because part or all of the default-related credit risks are borne by the government. B. Uncertainty Risks Why cannot the functions of a public MI system be completely fulfilled by the private MI sector? Why do developing countries jumpstart the MI provision with a public entity? The key reason is the various uncertainty risks involved. The capital market for housing credits can be highly restricted when there is potential risk for high default rates, due to: i) political or economic uncertainty; ii) legal framework (or lack of thereof) allowing for valid collateral and security interests; or iii) sub-market of borrowers with limited wealth or volatile income for which private capital would be very expensive if available. These risks could result in an unviable private housing finance market in general or among particular population groups. The uncertainty risks involved in the MI provision differ between developed countries and developing economies. In developing countries, uncertainty risks are a function of a country's political and economic instability, that is, the idiosyncratic risks of potential catastrophes such as financial crisis or depressions. In developed countries, the level of catastrophic uncertainty risks due to economic or political instability is very low. There, the uncertainty risks are with regard to expanding the underwriting envelope to include marginal borrowers (low-incomes, low credit score borrowers, etc.). For private mortgage insurers, these borrowers are vulnerable to economic shocks or recessions, which would - 42 - incur potential huge losses. These losses are either hard to project with some certainty, or the necessary insurance premium would be too high. As a result, the private MI sector will not supply insurance to certain borrower classes (credit rationing). For the government to take risks that the private sector is not willing to take, there must be some economic rationale. The belief must be that the marginal social benefit of including marginal borrowers into homeownership exceeds the marginal cost of bearing the additional credit risks by the government. To illustrate this argument, I set up a model as following (Figure 4.1): Figure 4.1 The Market for Residential Mortgage Credits in Developing Countries Cost of homeownership risks cepremium+ costof capitalfor political/economic r risks) lium+ u*(costof capitalforpolitical/economic emium- PMIpremium)- (1- u)*(costof capitalfor rL rP inds+ PublicMIpremium self-insurance premium- PublicMIpremium)- (costof orpolitical/economic risks) rO rl rc K Supply of mortgage credit So: supply schedule of mortgage credit without MI S : supply schedule of mortgage credit with only the private MI sector S: supply schedule for borrowers of mortgage credit with the presence of a public MI S: supply schedule of lenders of mortgage credit with the presence of a public MI D: demand schedule of borrowers MPC: marginal private cost MC: marginal cost MPB: marginal private benefit K: supply of mortgage credits r: cost of homeownership - using mortgage interest rate as the proxy In a housing finance market of developing countries and emerging economies, households' demand for homeownership is depicted by the demand schedule D, which represents the marginal private benefit of owning a home. The cost of homeownership is - 43 - represented by the mortgage coupon rate r (including the mortgage insurance premiums paid by borrowers). Without any form of mortgage insurance, private lenders provide mortgage credit according to the supply schedule of So. Their marginal private cost has three components: cost of funds, implied premium for self-insurance, and cost of capital for bearing uncertainty risks of political and/or economic instability. The last risk component is fairly high in those countries for private lenders. Therefore the resulting market equilibrium is at (Ko, ro),with restricted mortgage credits and high mortgage coupon rate. If there exists a private mortgage insurance industry, the marginal cost for lenders becomes the sum of cost of funds, private mortgage insurance premiums, and a proportion (v ) of the cost of capital for political and/or economic risks, because the private mortgage insurer takes on a small part of those risks. However, v is only slightly less than 1 (100 percent) for lenders because private mortgage insurers cannot (or are not willing to) take a substantial part of the uncertainty risks, due to the same reason - the cost of capital for insuring those risks is too high. Usually private MIs only provide partial coverage for lenders. Compared to the situation of lenders' self-insurance, the marginal cost for lenders is slightly lowered mainly by the efficiency gain from the private sector: (self-insurance premium - PMI premium), because, presumably, private MIs have better risk management skills and diversification capacity than individual lenders. However, the magnitude of this efficiency gain is limited so that it expands the mortgage credit supply only modestly and moves the supply schedule to Sp. The new market equilibrium is then at (K1 , rl). The increased supply of mortgage credit lowers the mortgage rate to r. However, the government wants to further expand the mortgage credit supply and considers the optimal equilibrium in the residential mortgage credit market be at (K*, r*), because it believes that positive externalities with increased homeownership increase total social welfare. At (K*, r) the marginal cost of providing mortgage credit and the marginal social benefits (instead of marginal private benefit) of homeownership equate. But private mortgage insurers will not take on more risks to reach the credit supply level - 44 - of K*, because then the insurance premium they will have to charge to compensate for the cost of capital would be too high, resulting in an unaffordable mortgage rate of r. To achieve the supply schedule depicted by S*, the government establishes a public MI program that usually provides 100 percent coverage and therefore completely removes uncertainty risks of political and/or economic catastrophes from lenders. Now the marginal cost for lenders becomes cost of funds plus public MI premium, which is substantially lower than the original marginal private cost because of the removal of cost of capital for uncertainty risks. The new equilibrium (K*, r*) greatly expands the mortgage credit supply and lowers the mortgage rate. The government-sponsored public MI charges an insurance premium of (r*-r() to cover the expected losses under normal economic conditions, while the potentially large credit risks imposed on the government (represented by the segment of rL-r ) are borne by taxpayers collectively. Again, the economic rationale for bearing these risks by taxpayers is the belief that positive externalities to the society as a whole outweigh potential costs. The model of the market for mortgage credits in developed countries is similar to the model presented before (Figure 4.1), except that the uncertainty risks are with regard to including marginal borrowers into homeownership, and the cost of capital for doing so is too high for both lenders and private mortgage insurers. In some cases, the strongest economic rationale for the public MI provision lies in addressing market failure rather than reducing uncertainty risks. For example, when the banking regulations require only high down payment loans and/or bank-lending markets are geographically concentrated - as they were in the U.S. in the Depression - then public provision of MI can be the only supply curve for the credit market of low down payment mortgage loans, not the shifted supply curve from the private provision. II. Different Stages of Housing Finance Market Development and Public MI Today public MI is an important component of the broader housing finance market. The discussion of economic rationales for public MI must be put into the context of the overall housing finance market development. So, first I examine the different development stages of the housing finance market (Figure 4.2). - 45 - Figure 4.2 Evolution of the Housing Finance Market and the Position of the Three Countries ,ii........................ii.............. Stage I i Stage II . Self-finance . Informal sector Direct finance Primary market with two L parties: lenders and I borrowers The housing finance system in many developing A variety of countries' housing finance systems are countries is still largely at Stage I, with a large informal sector. mostly at Stage II, including A ads lIICeniCall Mexican market both developed and developing countries ad ... L X Stage III Indirect finance Secondary market with financial intermediaries unbundling of the market Majority developed economies have well-functioning secondary markets, although some emerging nations are trying to establish it too. .~-1- IIIarKei Dutch maiket i b~~~~~~~~~~~~~l The evolution of the housing finance market can be divided into three stages: selffinance, direct finance and indirect finance. Self-finance is prevalent in developing countries with a large proportion of very low income households that cannot afford a mortgage. Instead, they self-build houses with the assistance of extended family, financed primarily with cash to buy building materials and get some technical assistance from people trained in design and construction. Self-built housing usually lacks clear land title and is not formally connected to urban services, posing threats to public safety and health. Self-financed and self-built housing comprises roughly half of all newly constructed housing and nearly two-thirds of the existing stock in Mexico. Direct finance involves two parties: mortgage lenders and borrowers. Lenders, usually banks, provide all the major aspects of mortgage lending - they originate loans, service them (i.e., collect payments and manage defaults) and are the ultimate investors. They hold mortgages in their portfolio and finance them through short-term deposits or issuing long-term bonds. Therefore, lenders accept all risks including credit risk, interest rate risk, business risk, and management and operation risk. This form of housing finance prevails in both developing and developed countries and is usually the predominant form of financing. In the Netherlands, around 85-90 percent of the mortgage funding resources are supported by general funding methods including banks' savings accounts, other - 46 - accounts, bank bonds, loans from other mortgage finance institutions and insurance premiums (EMF HypoStat 2001). In the United States, 25-30 percent of the mortgages are retained in lenders' portfolios and funded by their resources. Indirect finance refers to the existence of secondary mortgage markets where mortgage portfolios are sold to secondary market entities or pooled together with other similar mortgages to form mortgage-backed securities (MBS). The secondary markets have been proven an efficient and low cost way of raising money and managing cash flows, primarily because of economies both in raising money "wholesale" in the capital markets, in processing the purchase and servicing of large numbers of mortgage loans, and in managing risks through diversification and in some cases implicit government guarantees (Van Order, 2000). The unbundling of the mortgage markets results in specialized intermediaries such as mortgage originators, servicers, secondary market institutions and mortgage insurers, between the final investors of MBSs (funding sources) and mortgage borrowers. Secondary market financing mostly exists in developed economies with sound legal and regulatory infrastructures and good market information. It has become a major source of mortgage funding in a few countries such as the U.S. where 73 percent of the 2..5trillion dollar new mortgage originations in 2002 were funded through MBS issuance (about 1.8 trillion dollars). In the Netherlands, the annual gross lending against mortgage in residential property was about 96 billion euros in 2002. During the same year, 5 million euros of mortgage bonds and 17.6 billion euros of MBSs were issued, comprising about 18 percent of the total lending. The growth of MBS issuance in the Netherlands has been rapid, increasing from mere 227 million euros in 1996 to about 17.6 billion euros in 2002. Developing countries are active in jumpstarting their secondary markets in order to channel more investments and funds to their housing sector. In Mexico, the first MBS issuance was done by Su Casita, one of the biggest Sofoles, in December 2003. The first tranche was sold for 0.5 billion pesos and the second tranche (sold in Aug 2004) was about 1 billion pesos. More MBS deals are expected in 2005 with the involvement of the SHF guarantees. - 47 - III. Economic Rationales for Public MI - Case Studies The economic rationales for public MI change over time as the housing finance market evolves and housing policy changes. Market inefficiencies that caused the creation of public MI may be very different from those that justify its continuation. In this section, I answer the first research question: What are the primary economic problems in the housingfinance market that cause market inefficiency or market imperfections and hence call for government intervention in the form of a public MI? I analyze the three public MI programs to compare the housing market inefficiencies they address at different stages of the housing finance market respectively, from their policy context, market imperfections, program goals and barriers, prerequisites, institutional framework, and the relationship with other supplementary housing policies. The development timeline of public MI for each study case, defined by the three stages of each country's housing finance market, are outlined below (Table 4.1). Table 4.1 Development Stages of the Three Public MI Stage I FHA WEW* SHF* 1963-now Stage II 1934-now 1956-now 1963-now Stage III 1970s-now Mid 1990s-now 2003-now : startingfrom theirpredecessor'sestablishmenttime A. The U.S. FHA Program Stage II: Primary market stimulation The FHA was created in 1934 to fill the gap caused by the failure of the housing finance systems and private mortgage insurance industry due to the Great Depression. Prior to the depression, there was very little federal intervention in or supervision of mortgage lending transactions, which were viewed essentially as local in character. The lack of regulation and discipline in mortgage lending and mortgage insurance, combined with the severity of the depression, resulted in wide-spread losses that were not capable of being recouped by lenders. As a result, mortgage lending virtually ceased, and government intervention was required to stimulate the housing sector. Therefore, the original objective of the FHA was to encourage banks, building and loan associations, and other approved institutions to make loans for building homes, small business establishments, - 48 - and farm buildings, by insuring all loans underwritten to its standards. In many ways, the focus was on economic stimulus through housing construction and hence mortgage lending. Lack of confidence in the marketplace among lenders was the fundamental market inefficiency. However, the FHA insurance product, while stimulating construction, did not stimulate the desired level of mortgage lending. Lenders did not trust the insurance product, and wanted to remove all the "mortgage risk" from their balance sheets. Therefore, Congress established The Federal National Mortgage Association (in 1938), with the objective of improving credit flows by putting cash back to the banks via purchasing FHA-insured loans, and also removing funding risks from the lenders' balance sheets. With the creation of the Federal National Mortgage Association (now known as Fannie Mae), the federal government, in effect, legislated a market for mortgage insurance9 and added liquidity to the market. A very important contribution of the FHA program was the establishment of the innovative mortgage product with lower down payments, higher payment-to-income ratios, and longer terms to maturity than had been observed before. In the 1950s and 1960s, as concerns with inner city housing conditions rose the economic rationales for the FHA have changed from stimulating lending based on quite stringent and economically sound criteria (as a substitute for failed private MIs) to promoting adequate, owner-occupied housing. FHA's mortgage insurance was deemed as one form of subsidy in mortgage financing. The 1960s saw FHA mortgage insurance increasingly combined with other housing programs. Supply-side housing policy had identified capital subsidies, usually below market interest rate financing, as a major tool for either extending homeownership or subsidizing multifamily units. FHA's purpose in this was to insure these financial instruments (Pennington-Cross and Yezer, 2000). The economic rationale for the FHA's activities was the belief that homeownership generates positive externalities and that it should be subsidized. However, the large number of economically unsound, very high-risk mortgages insured in support of special housing subsidy 9 As Fannie and Freddie are prohibited - in their congressional charters - from purchasing a loan that exceeds 80% loan-to-value ratio unless the loan has private mortgage insurance or other credit enhancement for the portion of the loan above 80% of value. - 49 - programs led to accusations of fraud and abuse in FHA programs. The negative externalities associated with high risk mortgages, such as the concentration of defaulted and foreclosed properties in certain communities and the resulting deterioration of the housing stock, were not carefully evaluated. The 1980s and 1990s saw the gradual narrowing down and focus of the FHA insurance on low-income borrowers, partly because of the national housing policy and partly because of increasing competition from the conventional market and private MIs. The goal of the FHA is to complement not compete with the private sector, although in reality there is considerable overlap between the households served by FHA and conventional lenders (Ambrose, Pennington-Cross and Yezer, 2000; Canner and Passmore, 1995). The target population has increased the FHA's average loan-to-value ratio substantially and therefore its vulnerability to economic downturns. The 1980s recession caused huge losses to FHA. By 1990, the estimated actuarial value of its insurance fund was just 1 percent of the insurance in force, and even that was projected to evaporate by the year 2000. Every book of business underwritten from 1980 to 1989 was either already losing money or was expected to over the course of its life. It was clear in 1990 that the FHA's major insurance fund, the MMI Fund, was no longer sound (Capone, 2001). To restore its financial health, FHA doubled its premiums and adapted its mortgage limits to local area housing costs. With the "implicit" support from Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac due to their affordable housing goals set by their chartersl° and the robust economy after the recession, the FHA has returned to economic soundness. Since the 1990s, the FHA has been focusing on the provision of credits to households not served or underserved by the private sector, most notably first time and minority homebuyers. In FY 2003, 77 percent of FHA-insured purchase loans involved first-time homebuyers, and 37 percent of those first-time buyers were minorities. The main economic rationale for the FHA to target these populations is still homeownership 10The Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act of 1992 requires Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to meet annual percent-of-business housing goals established by HUD for three categories: low- to moderate-income households (50% in 2003); underserved areas (31% in 2003); and special affordable housing (20% in 2003). These mandates have forced the GSEs to lend to a sector of the low-tomoderate-income population likely to need low down payments and MI. - 50 - externalities and social equity. But the new underwriting criteria stipulated by the Federal National Affordable Housing Act of 1990 requires that each new book of business in the MMI Fund must be fully funded at the time it is endorsed, i.e. be self-supporting, to avoid repeating the 1980s experience. Another economic rationale is regional stabilization and balance of mortgage credit provision. Some researchers (Canner and Passmore, 1995; Caplin, Freeman and Tracy, 1997) have argued that private MIs do not penetrate far into the higher-risk mortgage markets or declining housing markets in areas experiencing falling wages and rising unemployment. The resulting market failure is the potential vicious cycle of lenders lowering LTVs (more downpayments required), therefore lowering housing prices that can be afforded by local residents, which could cause lenders to further lower required LTVs. Since the FHA has the same underwriting criteria across all regions, without any discriminations against declining markets, to some extent it helps "attenuate housing market slumps by serving as lender of last resort." (Pennington-Cross and Yezer, 2000). Stage III: Secondary market credit enhancement FHA mortgage insurance plays an important role in the U.S. secondary mortgage market by addressing the key element of the principal-agent problem: information asymmetry. In the U.S., virtually all government-insured loans become mortgage-backed securities. The MBS investors are concerned with credit risks of the mortgage pool because mortgage originators (or sellers), with superior information about loans, may adversely select against them by keeping good loans and selling the ones that are riskier than they appear to be to the secondary market. To remove the burdens of monitoring credit risks of individual loans off the MBS investors, FHA covers the bulk of credit risks related to borrower defaults, and Ginnie MaeI1 guarantees timely payment of principal and interest on MBS even if the issuer does not make the payments. Together, the two layers of guarantees provide enough credit enhancement to Ginnie Mae MBS so that it is " Ginnie Mae (the Government National Mortgage Association) is one of the three government agencies that brought on the standardization of pools of mortgages to form mortgage-backed securities. It was created in 1968 as a successor to the old Fannie Mae when it was privatized. What Ginnie Mae does is guaranteeing investors the timely payment of principal and interest on MBS backed by federally insured or guaranteed loans -- mainly loans insured by the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) or guaranteed by the Department of Veterans Affairs (VA). Ginnie Mae securities are the only MBS to carry the full faith and credit guaranty of the United States government. 51 - considered one of the safest investments in the capital market and helps channel funds into the mortgage market for the affordable owner-occupied housing sector. Figure 4.3 illustrates the structure and mechanism of the credit enhancement for government-insured MBS markets. Figure 4.3 Credit Enhancement for Government Insured Secondary Mortgage Market ........ . ... .. .W ..-........................... : _Insura fe ta o1." s prilction. . Mortgage pit Insurers: FHA VA,& :RHS* : : :: : iT__ Paying Agent: Receives and - i ___ _ Wall Street Investment Banks package MBS in issuer's name and market to investors Ginnie Mae MBS Investors . Guarantqefees- ... : MBS i payments Guarantor: . Ginnie Mae * Timely payment Principal and interest pass throughs :........ . i : disburses mortgage , . . . --... *: VA: Department of Veteran Affairs; RHS: Department of Agriculture's Rural Housing Service Housing B. The Dutch WEW Program Until 1956, only specialized mortgage banks were allowed to lend mortgages in the Netherlands. House purchase was difficult for households without sufficient savings. Downpayment proved to be a big barrier to homeownership and caused market inefficiency. In 1956, a municipal guarantee system backed by the central government was founded to support the availability and affordability of homeownership. At first, the guarantee was only available for mortgages of purchasing newly built housing. Later in 1973, the municipal guarantees were extended to mortgage loans for the purchase of existing dwellings. The guarantee made mortgage lending attractive to other types of financial institutions and commercial, co-operative and savings banks entered the mortgage market. In the - 52 - municipal guarantee system, the central government and municipalities share the debt risks fifty-fifty. As a result of the guarantee, the downpayment necessary for the financing of a home was reduced from 30 percent to 10 percent. The demand for mortgages increased greatly and led to an increased competition for funds between lenders. The cost of mortgage credit supply was lowered, therefore lowering mortgage interest rates for borrowers as well. However, this fragmented municipal guarantee system created new market inefficiencies while addressing inadequate homeownership, due to its structural and operational flaws and lax regulations. The municipal guarantee system was inefficient (the application process could last 6 months) and lacked transparency because each municipality set its own standards and had its own guarantee products, causing inconsistency in the marketplace. Moreover, no capital reserves were created either in municipalities or the central government for the guarantees issued. The lack of risk assessment resulted in potential resource allocation inefficiency in the governments. Despite these inefficiencies and significant flaws in program design, this guarantee system had worked well until the beginning of the 1980s, largely owing to a booming economy and rising home prices. In the period of 1978 1982, the Dutch economy went into a recession. Home prices dropped significantly; longterm interest rates increased and unemployment figures soared. Not surprisingly, the number of defaults increased sharply. After some years (mid 1980s), the number of foreclosure sales of dwellings reached 2,500 on an annual basis with an estimated loss of £56.8 million (Boelhouwer and Neuteboom, 2003), compared to only a few hundreds normally (Figure 4.4). Mortgage lenders experienced increased losses during the late 1980s when interest rates were consistently above 10 percent and some borrowers were unable to maintain payments on their loans. Municipalities and the central government covered all losses of default claims from the guarantees issued. - 53 - Figure 4.4 Foreclosure Sales in the Netherlands, 1975-2003 0000 0000 3 0000 % 0o 0Z o 0000 0000 8 o, E z o 'E Year -- number ofdefault -- '--claim amount Source: WEW database The bad experience made local and central governments re-evaluate weaknesses in the structure of the guarantee provision, and led to the decision to make the mortgage guarantee program organizationally efficient and financially self-supporting. The restructuring emphasized three features: standardization of rules, efficiency in the fund operations, and solid capital reserve fund management. The result was the formation of the Homeownership Guarantee Fund (abbreviated to WEW in Dutch) in November 1993 by and under the supervision of the Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (VROM) and the VNG (the Association of Netherlands Municipalities). The WEW is a private, non-profit organization backed by the full faith and credit of both central and participating local governments. It took over all the existing guarantees from the participating municipalities. As a result, nearly all municipalities stopped issuing new guarantees. For the mortgage default risks of the existing guarantees transferred to the WEW, the central government and municipalities deposited some capital as a separate reserve to cover claims from the old municipal guarantees when WEW started operation in 1995. The amount was based on projections of the old loans' performance. If the actual payouts exceed the reserves, WEW has the right to ask for more funds from the governments. The relationship between the WEW and the central government and participating municipalities is structured in a backstop agreement. This agreement serves to secure the payment of debts for lenders in case the fund's reserves drift into a state of illiquidity. In - 54 - that case, the government provides the WEW unlimited interest-free loans to pay off the accepted debt claims. Through this backing the Dutch Central Bank considers the National Mortgage Guarantee (NHG) as a government guarantee. Contrary to the municipality guarantee, the NHG issued by the WEW is organized on a national scale. Therefore, all borrowers in the Netherlands abide by uniform terms and standards. The institutional change of the MI provision did not alter the crucial role played by both the central and local governments. The Guarantee Fund's board of supervisors is appointed by the central government, the association of municipalities, the union of financiers, and the national consumers' association of owner-occupants. The WEW's premium levels and contract structure must be approved by the Ministry of Housing and the union of municipalities every year. The Fund is responsible for the policy and implementation of the NHG. It draws up regulations for issuing the NHG, which require the approval of the Minister of VROM and the VNG. Historically the Netherlands had a low homeownership rate, lagging behind most other European countries. The main purpose of the WEW is to reduce barriers to homeownership, especially among lower and middle-income populations in the Netherlands. The policy goal, however, is not pure promotion of homeownership, but more of increasing the citizen's freedom of choice in housing tenure decisions. It is closely related to the history of the Dutch housing shortage and the consequent housing policy of emphasizing quantity rather than quality of housing and the strong presence of social rental housing.' 2 As the Netherlands has overcome the acute housing shortage that dictated its housing policy for many decades, people are no longer satisfied with the limited choices in terms of residential environment and housing supply that has been strictly controlled by the government. Many have indicated a preference to own their homes' 3 and have a say in "how and where they live." It was clear that past housing policies constrained people's options in housing consumption and therefore the total 12 At the end of 2003, the Dutch housing stock consisted of about 6.7 million dwellings, of which 2.4 million in the social rental sector (35 percent); the owner-occupied sector comprised 54% of the housing stock; and the private rental sector became much smaller, only about 11%. 13However, most recently the demand for owning a house has tempered and even shifted a bit to renting as a result of the economic stagnation. - 55 - social welfare was not maximized. This inefficiency was caused by decades long housing policies that restricted free market forces. The Dutch government has been making housing policy transitions since the late 1980s and early 1990s towards more market forces and less government intervention, and implemented tenure-neutral policies. The aim of the government is to boost homeownership to around 65 percent by 2010. WEW mortgage guarantee is one of several approaches to stimulate homeownership. It not only helps households to buy new homes more easily, but also makes the transition from renting to buying smoother.'4 Unlike the U.S. FHA program, WEW's target populations do not include low-credit quality, high-risk borrowers. In fact, it has strict rules on applicants' qualification and checking of their creditworthiness. WEW guarantees do not specifically extend to minority households or first-time homebuyers. The WEW stipulates that eligible applicants for its guarantee must have the Dutch nationality or the nationality of a member state of the EU or the European Economic Area Agreement, or have a Dutch residence permit for an indefinite period of time. These requirements exclude many immigrants from countries like Turkey and Morocco who do not acquire the status of Dutch citizens. This segment of the population is left for the social rental market. Whether there is market inefficiency in this arrangement needs further research and is beyond the scope of this study. The secondary mortgage market, in the form of MBS, started in 1996 in the Netherlands and grew rapidly. In 2003, the volume of residential MBS issued in the Netherlands totaled 23.4 billion euros (approximately 30.3 billion dollars). However, its credit enhancement is provided by various subordinate classes carved within the MBS plus the reserve fund of the issuer. WEW guarantee is not utilized. 14 The Dutch government encourages the development by parties of intermediate forms that are neither lease nor purchase, or a more fluid transition from renting to buying. In particular, constructions granting tenants the right to buy the dwelling at a later date (wholly or partially, via an ownership share) are being considered. Starting in 2001, such intermediate forms qualified for the National Mortgage Guarantee scheme. This facilitated the development of intermediate forms ("What People Want, Where People Live" report). The WEW guarantees are granted to owner-occupied dwellings that are at least for 50 percent in the hands of the owner. - 56 - C. The Mexican SHF Program The Mexican housing finance market has fluctuated significantly over the past half century with the government entities and private sector taking control alternately. In the 1960s, commercial banks were quite active in mortgage lending. High inflation discouraged private capital in the 1970s, prompting the formation of federal public and publicly mandated housing finance programs. During the 1980s, banks, newly under the ownership of the federal government, had required quotas for social interest housing loans. Then following re-privatization in the early 1990s, banks rapidly expanded mortgage lending, but were devastated by the peso crisis in 1994-1995. Currently the private sector provides very little capital for housing finance, although in recent years it expressed interest in returning to the market. Public or publicly mandated institutions'5 provide the majority of housing finance (The State of Mexico's Housing, 2004). A description of the current main market participants in the Mexican housing finance system is provided in Appendix 4.1. StageI and I: Informal and primarymarkets A wide range of market inefficiencies exist in Mexico's informal housing sector and primary mortgage markets. In the informal sector (50 percent of the housing stock), formal lending programs and mortgage credits are not accessible to low-income or selfemployed workers, so that they cannot purchase a house that requires financing. Their only option, progressive self-built houses, exerts negative externalities on surrounding areas and deteriorates urban environment. The primary mortgage market has three major imperfections. The first is the lack of confidence in the marketplace among both borrowers and lenders following the financial crisis. The inflationary macro economy and real estate bubble bursting caused banks experiencing massive delinquencies and severe losses in mortgage loans. Borrowers There are three major pubic or publicly mandated institutions. The housing sub-accounts of the pension programs (INFONAVIT and FOVISSSTE) are financed through mandatory contributions by firms and employees. The housing trust fund, FOVI, has evolved into the national mortgage bank, SHF. SHF receives direct budget appropriations and funding from international donors, which it channels through the 15 SOFOLes, which are privately-owned specialized financial institutions, to reach new markets (The State of Mexico's Housing, 2004). - 57 - found themselves in deep negative equity position with no possibility of ever paying off the loan. To this day, bank mortgage lending has not returned to the pre-crisis level and households are very wary of mortgages provided by banks. The second problem is the non-transparency and potential corruption in resource allocation within publicly mandated housing finance funds or institutions. FONHAPO (a federal social housing agency), INFONAVIT and FOVISSSTE (off-budget provident funds that receive mandatory contributions from, respectively, formally employed private sector employees and federal government employees) currently provide about 80-85 percent of the total mortgages issued each year. They operate with their own agenda and target narrow population segments, providing subsidized mortgage loans. Their funds come from the federal government or mandatory worker contributions (Figure 4.5). As demand for these types of subsidized loans exceeds supply, the allocation process breeds corruption and distorts market forces. Private market players such as banks are not mobilized in the primary markets. Figure 4.5 Capital Sources for Mortgage Loans in Mexico Public Private Banks INFONAVIT SHF .4 FOVISSSTE FONHAPO Public capital; Public management; Public sector borrowers; Public capital; Public management; P ; Private capital; Private management; No subsidy Private capital; Private-public representation on board; publicly mandated mission; Private sector borrowers Interest rate subsidy Public and private capital; Public management; No subsidy Market catalyst Upfront subsidy Interest rate subsidy from "The State 2004" ofMexico's ....................................... Housing, adapted Source: adapted from "The State of Mexico's Housing, 2004" The last issue regarding Mexico's primary market is the inefficient use of private capital in the housing sector and the resulting serious under-leverage of properties. Mexico's homeownership rate is around 79 percent, higher than that of the U.S. (70 percent) and the Netherlands (54 percent). However, its mortgage debt as percentage of Gross Domestic Product is only about 2 percent in 2003, compared to about 70 percent in the U.S. and 88 percent in the Netherlands. Other developing countries such as Brazil (4%) and Chile (12%) have much higher percentage than Mexico. This is due to the fact that a - 58 - large portion of Mexican housing stock is not formally financed. Indeed, only 15 percent of the housing stock has ever had a mortgage. The total value of the unleveraged housing stock is estimated at 700 billion U.S. dollars (Merrill Lynch report, 2003). The SHF, established in 2002 as a government development bank for housing to replace FOVI,1 6 addresses housing finance market inefficiencies in several ways: i) It extends its products to a broad range of populations, serving households earning between 2 and 50 minimum salaries (3,000 to 75,000 U.S. dollars, covering 75 percent of the households in Mexico). It is currently the only formal lender that offers loan products for which informal workers are eligible. Its mortgage insurance covers a wide spectrum of loans with the lower range competing with INFONAVIT loans and higher end overlapping with commercial bank loans, therefore filling the previous market gaps; ii) It tries to restore market confidence and reduce uncertainty in mortgage lending by building essential infrastructures in market information, mortgage standardization, legal framework and operational transparency. The SHF has been building Mexico's first centralized mortgage loan database, FIEH (Fuente Integral de Estadistica Hipotecaria), to identify, control and monitor loans covered by its guarantees. The database will have four types of information: socio-demographic information about the borrower, information on his monthly payments; information on the property, and information on the loan recovery once it becomes a delinquent loan. This centralized information center has significant implications to all current and future market participants including banks, rating agencies, regulators, credit risk insurers, and MBS investors. It lowers uncertainty risks of all parties. The SHF also establishes minimum criteria and universal standards in mortgage origination, servicing and documentation for approved lenders and intermediaries (Sofoles), as well as clear rules of capitalization and reserves for them. This brings transparency to the market and offers a level playing field. In terms of legal infrastructure, the SHF is improving 16 FOVI was established in 1963 as a trust fund to channel federal government money to the housing sector. FOVI obtained its funds from the Mexican Central Bank and distributed them to SOFOLes. In 1994, the Central Bank became independent (autonomous, not depending on the government) and FOVI entered a transitional period. In 2002, SHF replaced the FOVI. - 59 - foreclosure laws and appraisal and registry systems. It is looking to adopt international standards in operational and risk practice for its MI business, and encourages international private MIs to come in to Mexican markets; and iii) With the full faith and credit of the Mexican government behind its mortgage insurance and financial guarantees,' 7 SHF acts as a market catalyst to mobilize private capital and increase leverage in housing stock. With its MI coverage, the maximum LTV is raised to 90% with a term of 25 years. SHF is gradually phasing out previous FOVI's loan granting function' 8 and instead pushing intermediaries to seek private market capital from commercial banks, international financial institutions (the World Bank, Inter-America Development Bank, etc.) and secondary market investors, with the support of its insurance products. The SHF is trying to correct the market distortion created by predominant public entities historically existing in Mexico's housing finance sector, and encourage the system to evolve so that in the long run it will look to the secondary market and long-term bond investors for capital. The goal of SHF's MI program is to stimulate private lending and jumpstart the housing finance market development by standardizing the market and expanding funding mechanisms. The SHF views its role as an evolving one, comprising three phases (Figure 4.6): This backing of the federal government will expire on October 2013. After that, the guarantees will be supported exclusively by SHF's own financial strength. 18 Currently, as a transitional period, the SHF lends money to registered financial intermediaries, banks and mortgage banks (Sofoles), which in turn lend SHF-guaranteed funds to individual borrowers. The SHF also 17 provided construction lending to private housing developers. Starting from January 2003, SHF stopped funding construction loans but instead provide loan guarantees. Its ability to grant mortgage loans only extends to October 2009. From then on, the only function of the SHF will be granting MI and guarantees. - 60- Figure 4.6 SHF's Evolving Role Source: SHF Presentation 2003. * * Short Term: SHF offers MI and financial guarantee insurance, looking for reinsurance with specialized international insurance companies. Medium Term: Private insurance companies, including affiliates of international firms, offer cover for * risks not covered by private monoliners. Long Term: Private insurance companies offer cover for all market segments, SHF offers reinsurance residential and medium segments of the market, while SHF offers cover for social housing and special to these companies to undertake risks that private markets are not willing to hold. Stage III: Secondarymarketcatalyst The SHF is also expected to be the catalyst for the secondary market development in Mexico, through its two major products: mortgage default insurance, and on-time payment guarantee for MBS similar to those offered by U.S. Fannie Mae.' 9 Promoting mortgage securitization was a main incentive for the creation of the SHF due to the awareness that Mexican pension funds are and will be a significant element of the country's long-term financial savings and they must be exploited to finance housing.20 Also private capitals and foreign investments must be channeled into the housing finance sector more actively, breaking the current dominance of government funds and entities. The market imperfections of the nascent Mexican secondary market are multi-fold, including mainly the lack of market information and investors' confidence, and the asymmetric information problem similar to the U.S. secondary market situation. SHF's 19 However, SHF's on-time guarantee of MBS payments differs from that of Fannie Mae's in that it would not be a 100% guarantee, since, in principle, partial classification must be maintained in such a way that a fraction of the risk will be assumed by the intermediary financiers and another part by the investors. Although SHF-guaranteed MBS should be triple A bonds, they should not be risk-free bonds, in order to force the market to undertake the necessary risk monitoring (Babatz, 2004). 20Laws require these pensions funds to be invested in bond securities and prohibit them from being invested directly in individual mortgage loans. -61 - MI and financial guarantee insurance (FOI) provide necessary credit enhancement to get MBS deals to be AAA rated on local scale. SHF's role as a catalyst for standardization of documents and origination and servicing procedures will be played through its role as guarantor either through MI, FOI or both. The first MBS issuance in Mexico of 1.5 billion pesos occurred in 2003 by Su Casita, one of the biggest Sofoles, as a demo issuance. The standard agency MBS carrying SHF insurance and guarantees is expected to launch in 2005 by Sofoles. The SHF is the market maker, insurer and information provider (Figure 4.7). Figure 4.7 SHF's Role in the Secondary Mortgage Market Financial Guarantee Insurance Companies Intermediaries Debt capita~ Markets ~ SHF Market Makers Originators (Special Purpose Vehicle) Capital at Risk bj K ... Investors -I Universal Type ______ 1 1 1 1 • 1 Rating Agencies L L _ Mortgage Insurance Companies • Source: SHF presentation IV. Derivatives MBS Trusts Servicing Instruments + & Cash Regulators J ----------~ Information I "Opportunities in Housing in Mexico UCLA May 2004.ppt" Comparison of the Three MI Programs' Economic Rationales Previous case studies offer valuable insights into each of the three countries' housing finance market inefficiencies that justified the establishment of the public MI and the evolution of these economic rationales (Table 4.2). - 62- Table 4.2 Market Imperfections Addressed by the Public MI FHA Primary market At establishment Now · Lack of market confidence · Inadequate homeownership and huge uncertainty risks for lower-income families, after the Great Depression. minority households and · Insufficient housing downpayment barrier for construction and mortgage first-time homebuyers. lending. · Lending discrimination in · Gaps in the market caused by unserved or underserved the disappearance of private regions. · Secondary market Nowa . Information asymmetry for MBS investors. MIs. Lack of sound regulations and standards in mortgage underwriting. WEW * SHFb Inefficiency and nontransparency of the existing municipal guarantee systems. Lack of MI risk assessment * * Limited housing style and tenure choices for historical reasons. Inadequate homeownership and regulations on capital for the overall populations, requirements, resulting in resource allocation inefficiency in governments. especially lower-income households. Lack of market confidence and huge uncertainty risks (macro economic and political) after the financial crisis of 1994-1995. Lack of trust among lenders in previous FOVI's loan default guarantees. · · · · · · · Not utilized. · Lack of confidence for the investors - needing credit enhancement . Information Serious shortage of funds for mortgage lending due to the asymmetry for MBS complete retreat of commercial banks. No access to formal financing for informal workers and very low income populations. Low affordability of mortgage financing for majority of the population. Non-transparency and distortion of the housing finance market by public or publicly mandated funds/entities. Inefficient use of private capital and under leverage of residential properties. Lack of sound regulations and standards in mortgage underwriting. Lack of laws in foreclosure, appraisal and MI business. Lack of data on housing and mortgage markets. investors. Note: a: The secondary market did not exist in either of the three countries when the public MI was created. b: The SHF was established in 2002. The market inefficiencies then were similar to the current situation. The comparison indicates some commonalities in the economic rationales for public MI among the three countries. The most common market imperfections to be addressed by public MI include: high uncertainty risks perceived by market participants due to macro economic or political instability; lack of regulation and standardization in mortgage - 63 - markets; inadequate homeownership among general population or specific groups; and lack of market information to assess risks. All these market inefficiencies tend to cause credit suppliers reluctant to enter the market as it cannot carry higher rates to compensate for the high uncertainty. For a generic country to start a public MI program, policymakers must first understand the causes of the supply or demand constraints in the housing finance market to decide whether the problems can be tackled by a supply-side intervention as public MI. "Unaffordable" housing can be because (i) prices of dwellings are too high; (ii) cost of financing is too high; or (iii) incomes of some populations are too low and redistribution is desired in the specific form of housing. Thorough analysis is needed to provide clear understanding of the reasons. For instance, if low or unstable income is the dominant constraint in the market for owner-occupied housing and not access to housing finance, then demand-side subsidies on increasing households' ability to consume housing may be more effective. These subsidies can be housing allowances or vouchers for rental or owner-occupied housing, upfront grants tied to housing finance, or tax benefits that lower the recurring cost of housing payments. Even if the problems lie in the supply side of housing, the underlying causes may still render different strategies than public MI, or in addition to public MI. For example, if the housing finance problems are due to public or private monopoly systems or the regulatory environment (in the reliability and speed of foreclosure procedures, planning and building standards, etc.), setting up a public MI scheme alone is not likely to mitigate the problems. In such cases, developing or reforming institutions and policies, and improving the regulatory and legal systems will be needed before implementing public MI. Simply put, if government does not do what is necessary to encourage the housing finance industries to function efficiently, housing supply cannot respond to price signals, and higher incomes or subsidies will not translate into better housing (Hoek-Smit and Diamond, 2003). The comparison also illustrates the necessary prerequisite conditions for public MI to function (Table 4.3). Policymakers need to check the readiness from multiple perspectives of their housing market and infrastructure to determine the best timing for - 64 - launching a public MI. As shown in the following table, the newly established Mexican SHF has been making great effort to catch up in several key aspects of the infrastructure building for its MI program. Table 4.3 Prerequisites for Public MI to Function Prerequisites Political and Social Political initiatives and attitudes Government. housing policy Social environment FHA WEW SHF Focus on the provision of credits to households not served or underserved by Facilitate homeownership among low- and Expand access to formal housing finance to the general population and the private sector medium-income populations encourage private capital into the sector One of the most important components in the U.S. An important component among The leading factor to mobilize the market and housing policy other policies, such initiate changes in primary as a counterpart in social rental housing market and jumpstart the secondary market sector Borrowers, lenders and investors trust the government backing - zero risk reserves required Lack of trust in financial institutions and government guarantees. Improving gradually Borrowers, lenders and investors trust the government backing Regulation and Legal Regulation of banks Regulation of insurance Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Regulation for mortgage Yes. Must be mono-line Non-existent Non-existent. In the insurance business, with specific capital requirements Laws (especially foreclosure) Sound process of stipulating regulations and adopting international standards Sound Not sound but improving. In many places foreclosure is still impossible or takes a long time. Court system Information Market information & Mortgage lending performance Pricing model data Sound Sound Not tested Good market information gathered through FHA's various databases and reporting systems Centralized in-house loan databases Good quality market data non-existent before. Now Data available Data available start to build housing price index and FIEH database by SHF requirements Not enough data. Pricing model based on some assumptions Credit reporting (credit bureau) Internal Scorecard system and external credit reporting from Fair, Isaac Credit information & Co., a credit scoring Office bureau from the 1950s - 65 - from the Central Credit Registration Non-existent. Start to develop. Property title registration Sound Sound Lack of agreement on basic legal and administrative principles. Antiquated systems. Real estate appraisal Yes Yes information Source: the author, some items adaptedfrom Blood and Whiteley, 2004 Non-existent. Now start to gather the information When addressing housing finance market imperfections, all three public MI programs emphasize actuarially sound pricing and sustainability over the long term under normal market ups and downs. Public MI becomes a subsidy only when the market encounters catastrophic economic or political events, that is, to cover the systemic risks. This is to control the uncertain and mostly "hidden" costs to the backing government, keep the system transparent, and reduce the distorting impacts on the private market of the intervention, so that public MI does not create new market inefficiencies while curing the existing ones. It is very important, however, to understand and be able to measure the potential costs to the government under different risk scenarios including rare, adverse economic situations because the program can be very expensive in the long run. The next Chapter analyzes implied liabilities of public MI in details. - 66 - Appendix 4.1 Mexican Housing Finance Main Market Participants Infonavit _Z_*[__P =111611 r Infonavit is a mandated pension programme for private sector workers. Infonavit has approximately 15million workers affiliated ffmwtw Funded by a mandatory 5% levy on private employee wages Typical loans are in the US$10,000 to US$50,000 fr.n Lends typically at Planning to grant inflation + 6% 300,000 loans in 2003, up from For buyers that qualify, Infonavit 275,000 in 2002 terms often make it the most attractive of the lenders Currently issues range around 75% of all new mortgage volume in Mexico Infonavit finances almost 80% of all government housing credits in Mexico FOVISSSTE FOVISSSTE (not to be Funded by a Lends typically at Around 20,000 confused with FOVI) is a mandatory 5% levy inflation + 6% loans per annum mandated pension programme for public sector workers. on public employee wages Lends at inflation + 11% Funds construction and around 50,000 end-user loans per annum Typically at inflation + 12% Around 5,000 loans per annum Typically at inflation + 12% Around 10,000 loans per annum Fovissste has 1.5 million affiliates Typical loans are in the US$10,000 to US$50,000 range SHF (formerly FOVI) Formerly FOVI, the SHF funds developers and end buyers, primarily distributed by Sofoles Loans are in the US$10,000 Funded by contributions from the federal budget, as well as capital market issuance to US$150,000 range Moving to a role as a Mexican "Ginnie Mae," insuring MBS issues, but not providing direct funding itself Sofoles Lend mostly to lower and some middle income segments, Funded by SHF (former FOVI), although now starting to capital markets, bank compete head to head with banks loans, development banks and, more recently, Typical loans are in the securitization US$50,000 to US$300,000 range Banks Lend mostly to middle and upper income segments Funded from bank deposits, capital markets and Typical loans are in the securitization. US$50,000 to US$300,000 to FOVI/SHF funds, range, although banks are now offering to lend as little as but not active US$24,000 Source: Softec, Merrill Lynch - 67 - Access - 68 - Chapter 5 Analysis of Implied Government Liabilities I. Implied Government Liabilities In Supporting Public MI Understanding the essence of risks and the magnitude of implied liabilities imposed on the government under various economic scenarios is extremely important for policymakers in evaluating the feasibility and soundness of a public MI program. There are two characteristics of a public MI program that merit especial attention. First is the long time horizon of mortgage insurance commitments. Typically mortgage loans span over fifteen to thirty years, during which the nation's macro economy could experience recessions or even depression. Therefore it is dangerous for policymakers to think that a public MI program costs the government (taxpayers) nothing even if it is currently selfsupporting. Second, since most government-backed MI programs or enterprises do not aim to maximize profits and usually target lower to middle income households, their premium levels vis-h-vis the risk profile of their borrowers make them much more susceptible to adverse economic shocks than their private counterparts, and their potential losses are more severe too. Naturally, the important question to ask is: What are the implied liabilities imposed on the government (hence taxpayers) of sponsoring a public MI program or backing such an enterprise? This is the second research question of this dissertation, and constitutes the second component of the integrated analytical framework. A conceptual model (Figure 5.1) is constructed to depict the relationship between various macro economic conditions, indicated by the mortgage loan portfolio's ultimate cumulative default rates, and the magnitude of mortgage insurers' (both private and pubic) liabilities. - 69 - Figure 5.1 Implied Government Liabilities of Supporting a Public MI Depression scenario Recession scenario Star! to eat up capiial ! Point of insolvency~) ................... ..... "'i ~ ~~.:: Normal economic conditions : ... 9 :~ . ~~ii!~!j! i! i!~ . + .. roba~ility distribution of portfolio' ultimtte default rates - developed countries y * Pflibability distribution ofporlfolio. ultimate ielfUllt rates - developing countries Default rates* Public: NPV > 0 NPV of public mortgage insurance NPV of private mortgage insurance *: The default rate numbers are based on the U.S. mortgage market experience, as an example. The upper part of Figure 5.1 is the probability distribution of a mortgage portfolio's cumulative ultimate (at the end of the loan term) default rates, divided into three zones: normal economic conditions, recessions, and depressions. The distribution is skewed to the left with the mean portfolio default rate of J.1 at point D. The probability that default rates will be less than J.1 is 0, indicating a favorable portfolio performance. Taking the general U.S. mortgage market portfolios for example, under normal economic conditions, a cohort's (a book of business originated in one year) ultimate default rate varies between 2% and 10%, with the mean around 6%.21 If a cohort is hit by recessions during its early loan ages (usually between year 3 and year 7), the most vulnerable period in terms of defaults, its ultimate default rate can increase to the level between 10% and 15%. In the worst condition when serious recessions or even depressions hit the national economy during the early years of the mortgage cohort, a small probability event represented by These default rate figures serve illustrative purposes as examples of the general U.S. mortgage market. On average, the FHA mortgage market segment will have higher cohort default rates than the figures presented here due to its borrowers' risk profile. For instance, the estimated mean cohort ultimate default rate of FHA cohorts (l975-2003) is around 9.76% as presented later in this Chapter, instead of 6% assumed here. Also these figures cannot represent the mortgage market performance in other countries. 21 - 70- the long tail of the probability distribution, the cohort ultimate default rate could further escalate to more than 15%. Over the lifetime of an insured mortgage portfolio, if the MI provider is to make zero profit, the net present value (NPV) of the mortgage insurance premiums it receives should exactly cover the expected losses (claims) from defaulted loans, i.e., NPVMI = E[losses]. In other words, a non-profit-seeking MI provider's break-even point for its insurance business is at point D, where NPV MI equates expected losses when the ultimate default rate is at the mean u. Private mortgage insurance companies are in the business to make money and therefore quite risk-averse. They charge insurance premiums so that the net present value of their mortgage insurance business is zero (breaking-even 2 2) at point B, to the left of point D, meaning that higher default rates are needed before the private insurers stop earning profits. For private MIs, when default rates distribute within zone 0 and y around the mean default rate ji, their business generates profits and has "surplus" that can be put into loss reserves. When the economy deteriorates and default rates increase to levels represented by zone r, the NPV of their mortgage insurance on a cohort becomes negative. Excess reserves have to be used to pay out claims. If the recession scenario persists, the escalating losses could deplete private MI companies' loss reserves and start to eat up their private equity. If things worsen further, i.e., under the depression scenario, the cohort's default rate may increase to zone a and private MIs could become insolvent and go bankrupt, as exemplified by the Great Depression in the U.S. in the 1930s. Profit- maximization and risk-aversion of private MI companies make them set the premium levels so that their break-even default rate (point B) is far away from the mean default rate (point D) to create a comfortable "cushion" in order to accommodate economic fluctuations and housing market volatility. 22 "Break-even" is defined by a NPV calculation that discounts at the cost of capital, that is, the cost of holding its equity capital reserves. -71 - Compared with private MI companies, public MI programs are much more risk-tolerant. In many countries, public MI embodies the government's role in promoting formal housing finance among lower-income families. It is usually free from the pressure of earning profits. Also, the public MI might hold loss reserves, but it does not have to hold equity capital, which by itself is a big cost saving compared to the private sector. Therefore, when serving similar segments of clients, public MI charges a lower premium than its private counterparts. The break-even cohort default rate of the public MI is very close to the mean default rate u, with a slight cushion. In the example shown in Figure 5.1, the break-even default rate is around 7% at point C when the mean default rate is 6% at point D. Under stable economic conditions the probability distribution of cohort default rates is concentrated around or less than u (within zone 0), and the public MIs generate positive NPV for writing mortgage insurance. However, this NPV can easily become negative due to the small "buffer" space between point C and D, even under normal economic scenarios (within zone y). Therefore, public MI is vulnerable to unfavorable economic situations (depicted by the shaded areas with default probability of a, and fl). This vulnerability is worsened by its borrowers' profile and characteristics. The losses beyond public MI's own loss reserves become liabilities imposed on the government and have to be shouldered by taxpayers collectively. It is crucial for policymakers to understand the shape of the distribution of cohort ultimate default rates, the implied break-even default rate based on the MI program design, and the magnitude of potential losses imposed on the government under various economic scenarios. In developing countries and emerging economies with relatively risky and unstable macro economy, mortgage default rates tend to be higher and more volatile than in developed countries. Hence the shape of the probability distribution of cohort default rates in those countries tends to have a longer and fatter tail (the dotted curve in Figure 5.1), indicating the larger probability for those markets to experience recessions or depressions. For both developed and developing countries, it is particularly important to be able to measure the potential liability impact on the government budget resulting from sponsoring a public MI program. - 72 - II. A. Methodology Existing Methodologies - Literature Review There are two major methodologies to assess the contingent liability and capital adequacy of housing finance companies (such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) and mortgage insurance enterprises: stress tests and value-at-risk measures. Stress tests are widely used by rating agencies and government regulators in the U.S. and abroad. The method postulates stressful economic situations and estimates the amount of capital necessary to survive these situations. The advantage of the stress test approach lies in that it is easy to understand and relatively straightforward to implement without requiring too many historical data. The disadvantage, however, is that it does not attach a probability of failure to the computed capital adequacy standard. Therefore it is difficult to tell if different stress tests are equally probable, and hard to judge their comparability when applied to programs in different countries. The value-at-risk (VaR) method applies more sophisticated models (such as simulation models) to analyze the probability of "failure" for the overall portfolio. With this method, the capital adequacy is defined as the amount of capital needed to limit the probability of "failure" (zero or negative NPV) over a specified period of time to a low level. The value of a portfolio that is "at risk" is the amount that could be lost were a given bad event to occur within a defined period of time. That event is defined by a critical value along the frequency distribution of outcomes, where the critical value identifies a risk-tolerance level. VaR models so far have mainly been used to evaluate the risks of trading investment portfolios. They are not as widely used as stress tests because of their data requirements and complexity. Enough data need to be available to derive the frequency distribution of negative events. Their application in analyzing the contingent liability of the mortgage insurance industry is at a nascent stage. In the U.S., a few academic studies explored this method with stochastic models for the mortgage insurance business (Kau, Keenan and Muller, 1993; Kau and Keenan, 1996; Calem and LaCour-Little, 2001; Capone, 2000, 2003). In other countries, such models are absent (in the sphere of public information). - 73 - The implementation of the VaR method is directly related to the statistical models that evaluate mortgage default and prepayment behaviors. Like other duration- or agedependent processes, mortgage terminations are highly amenable to analysis using a variety of statistical survival-time models, including parametric hazard models, semiparametric or proportional hazard models, and discrete-time models (Calhoun and Deng, 2002). B. My Approach In this research, I choose the value-at-risk approach and apply parametric models to simulate the mortgage cohort performance. Parametric models provide a complete parameterization of the probability distribution of survival times (or default occurrences). Examples include the exponential, Weibull, gamma, log-logistic, and various mixtures of these and other parametric distributions. I follow and improve the methodology proposed by Capone (2000) to conduct a cross-country comparison of the magnitude of implied government liability (the implied "value-at-risk") for the three public MI programs. I choose this methodology because: i) it provides a comparable approach to comparing different MI models with regard to their credit risks imposed on the government; ii) it incorporates both historical experience of mortgage loan performance and stochastic simulation techniques, therefore having certain advantages over the discrete-time models or pure simulation models where the interest rate and housing value movements are assumed to follow some predefined stochastic processes; iii) it has the flexibility of controlling country-specific characteristics through various parameter settings and therefore allows sensitivity analysis; and iv) from the practical point of view, this methodology is data-parsimonious, since relatively few parameters are needed to describe the distribution of portfolio performance (defaults and prepayments). Some other methods such as proportional hazards models or econometric models are data demanding, requiring detailed loan-level characteristics and borrowers information. These data are either confidential, or simply do not exist in many developing countries and emerging economies, and therefore would greatly limit the applicability of this research to a broader audience. In short, the proposed methodology provides a flexible and workable - 74 - way to obtain some quantifiable measures of implied liabilities in providing public MI across countries. Applying the VaR method and parametric models, I intend to examine the following questions in the three study countries: i) Whether their public MI scheme is properly designed so that its pricing covers expected risk exposure - the solvency of the public MI enterprise; ii) Whether the government understands and is ready to bear the implied liabilities resulting from a catastrophic event if the public MI's loss reserves become insufficient - what is the implied capital outlay for the government under situations with loss probabilities like a or [3in Figure 5.1; and iii) What is the magnitude of potential liabilities over a longer period of time or under different macroeconomic situations - multi-year analysis and sensitivity analysis that can serve as the basis for further discussions of the public resource allocation efficiency. III. A. Model Setup The Model The model is constructed to find the net present value of the mortgage insurance contracts on a particular book of business (cohort) that involve uncertain, but measurable cash flows. Each possible economic path, n, produces a net present value, or NPV(n): NPV(n) = f (P(n,t) - C(n,t))erttdt Where T is the life of each insurance contract (life of loans); Pt is net premium income of each time period, t; Ct is net claims expense; and rt is the spot, risk-free interest rate used for discounting. Across all possible states of the world, the expected value summary statistic is: E[NPV]= f (n)f (P(n,t) - C(n,t))er"dtdn Wheref(n) is the probability of each economic path, n. - 75 - The various economic paths that a cohort of loans can potentially experience are the result of a combination of macro economic environment, public MI program designs and portfolio performance, which can be measured by cohort default and prepayment rates and their patterns. Forecasts of the cohort performance provide the foundation for setting up calculations of cash flows from public mortgage guarantees. B. Modeling Processes For comparability purposes, I choose to model the performance of the 2003 mortgage loan cohort (all the loans originated in year 2003) that is guaranteed by public MIs of the three countries. 1) The modeling processes can be divided into three main stages: Simulate the cohort's ultimate default and prepayment rate distributions and their annual patterns, by parameterizing frequency distributions for lifetime default and prepayment rates to match the limited historical experience and expected future performance for the existing books of business; 2) Based on assumptions of macro economic conditions, housing market performance, and program characteristics, calculate discounted cash flows for the public MI in providing guarantees for the 2003 cohort. Obtain the NPV of the 2003 cohort for all simulated pairs of cohort default and prepayment rates; and 3) Conduct multi-year NPV analyses for the public MI programs to measure the longterm liabilities on the backing government. Regression models are used to explore the correlation of cohort ultimate default rates between consecutive years and the impact of interest rate movements. Then the cumulative NPV of multiple years is calculated for each simulated pair of cohort default and prepayment rates. In the analysis of the worst-case scenarios, repeated samples are drawn only from the negative tail portion of the NPV distribution obtained from Step 2 - the "loss zone." It embodies the interdependency of higher default rates during tough economic situations. 23 The choice of 2003 cohort is due to the fact that it is the latest year for which all the data are available for all three countries. - 76 - The detailed implementation of the modeling processes above is illustrated in the following flow chart (Figure 5.2). Parameters used in the modeling process are described as well (Figure 5.3). They are further explained in the next section. - 77 - Figure 5.2 Modeling Processes Data Examination Macro economic conditions by loan age, across all outstandin cohorts filii ...... The Flow Chart of the Modeling Processes . , .[). Distribution of Cohort Ultimate Default Rates Fit an Erlang distribution based on historical experience of COhO~:~~ti:~w~!~Ult I rates ~--....-~. ~~~,..J Monte Carlo Simulation of Cohort Ultimate Default Rates based on the Erlall2 distribution Simulation of Cohort Ultimate Preoavment Rates Obtain 10,000 cohorts' ultimate lifetime prepayment rates based on the simulated ultimate default rates Draw 10,000 random samples from the Erlang distribution of cohorts' ultimate lifetime default rates f .. ,.-.....-.~., .. Regression analysis to explore the correlation between ultimate default and prepayment rates ,~~ ~ Patterns of Annual Unconditional Preoavment Rates Patterns of Annual Unconditional Default Rates The distribution of cohort's annual unconditional prepayment rates based on historical experience, under various economic conditions The distribution of cohort's annual unconditional default rates based on historical experience, under various economic conditions f=I~~--, •. --- .[). .[). 1': ~ ...... . I: ~' .• -: : ~ Discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis for each simulated cohort ultimate default rate NPV Distribution of the 2003 Cohort The NPV (or profitability rate) distribution of the 2003 cohort based on the discounted cash flow analysis -,..~ .-....-.- .....----- .[). Correlation between multi-year cohorts' ultimate default rates - regression analysis to project future 6-year and 10-year cohorts' default rates and calculate the cumulative NPV Multi-vear NPV Analvses The cumulative NPV (or profitability rate) distribution over the 6-year and 10-year cohorts Worst-case scenarios: resampling multi-year NPV sequences only from the negative tail portion of the NPV distribution to simulate the recession scenario Sensitivity Analvses Explore how the NPV of 2003 cohort will change if some modeling parameters change - 78 - Figure 5.3 Modeling Parameters Macro Economic Environment * Various duration Treasury yields * 30-year mortgage rate * Inflation rate · Housing price index Public MI Program Characteristics * Program size * Loan portfolio composition * Insurance products and pricing or - 1 40. o. Portfolio Performance Measures * Ultimate cumulative default rate and prepayment rate * Annual distribution factors ........................................... · Macro economy · Housing market conditions · Program management ............................................ bs - -----flaim - fa1c ll.ll Ctors S ... -£_. * utner reatures or ne program design w factors Interpolation of other Doints on the vield curve Historical cohorts' records Project the Portfolio Performance of the 2003 Cohort * Default and prepayment rates distribution * Claim expenses and property recoveries Compute discount factors for converting future cash flows into present values as of insurance endorsement year I Fu Future cohorts' roiection Time to foreclosure v I I Property disposition time Property value recovery rate I~~~~~ -JhJ I - alcae - Cash flow rcmnnnent _-L_~ - 1 - 1- ... -11 me lnrv lstnouon OIme lvll provision I_ -- for the 2003 cohort of business *: These items may be specific to some public MI models. Source: adaptedfrom Capone (2002), andfrom the author C. Parameter Settings The parameters used in the modeling process can be grouped into three categories: macro economic environment, public MI program characteristics, and portfolio performance measures and projections (Table 5.1). Their settings reflect a country's characteristics (economic outlook, legal and financial infrastructure, borrowers profile, etc.) and its public MI program's uniqueness. The country's future economic outlook will impact the parameters values and the corresponding cash flows (Table 5.2). - 79 - Table 5.1 Parameters Categories and Explanations Parameters Meaning Macro Economic Environment Interpolated curve from 1-year, 5-year, 10-year and Yield curve 30-year Treasury bonds (U.S.) or government bonds An indication of the macro economic stability. Directly related to mortgage performance Interest rate charged on fixed rate mortgages (FRM) Mortgage rate with long terms (10-year, 15-year, 25-year, or 30year) Indication of housing market conditions: appreciative Housing price index or depreciative market Public MI Program Characteristics The volume of new loans (number and dollar amount) Program size Inflation rate Loan portfolio insured in a particular year - the cohort size The composition of the 2003 cohort, classified by composition various criteria: LTV classes, the length of interest Insurance products and pricing rate fixation, mortgage types, etc. The terms of the insurance contract and its pricing structure - upfront fee and/or annual premium Examples are: upfront premium refund, recourse to Other features of the defaulted borrowers, etc. program design Portfolio Performance Measures The cumulative cohort default rate and prepayment Ultimate cumulative Future conditions Unfavorable Favorable economic outlook economic outlook Upward trending Flat or even downward trending High and volatile Relatively low and stable Fixed nominal rate (developed countries) Appreciating Fixed real rate (developing countries) Depreciating Tend to be large Uncertain N/A N/A Pricing tends to go down Pricing tends to go up N/A N/A Low ultimate High ultimate default rate default rate default rate and rate at the end of the loan term prepayment rate Annual distributions of The annual unconditional default and prepayment Annual default Annual default defaults and rates throughout the loan term for the cohort - the rates peak early rates may remain prepayments shape of the distribution is specific to each country and narrowly Claim expenses The costs of paying out insurance claims due to borrower defaults, including unpaid balances, foreclosure-related expenses, and accumulated interests Low relatively high for a prolonged period of time High Property recovery rate The ratio of the sales revenues from foreclosed High Low properties over the total claim payment on defaults Note: N/A means "not applicable". Table 5.2 Cash Flow Components Cash Flow Components Meaning Future potential changes Favorable Unfavorable economic outlook economic outlook Cash inflows Premium income Upfront fees and/or annual premium paid by insured borrowers Income stream larger due to increased volume Income stream smaller due to high defaults Net revenues from property sales (per After the foreclosure, pubic MI enterprises take over the property and sell it to make up for the High due to housing market Low due to housing market property) Recourse to borrowers* delinquent payments. Mortgage insurers can capture other assets of defaulted borrowers to cover the debt appreciation N/A depreciation N/A Insurance claim Claim payments when insured borrowers default on Low High payments their mortgage loans Cash outflows 80- Premium rebates* Rebate of part of the upfront premiums to early prepayers *: These items may be specific to some public MI models. Note: N/A means "not applicable". IV. A. N/A N/A Modeling and Simulation Results The U.S. FHA Program A.1 The data Data used for the modeling and simulation are mostly obtained from the Fiscal Year (FY) 2003 Actuarial Review of the FHA Mutual Mortgage Insurance (MMI) Fund, which includes most of the FHA's unsubsidized single-family mortgage insurance business. At the end of FY 2003, the MMI Fund comprised 82.5 percent of the FHA insurance funds. The MMI Fund Actuarial Review provides both historical portfolio performance data on insured books from 1975 to 2003,24 and projections at the end of the loan term for each outstanding book of business. Projections of ultimate default (claim) rates on books underwritten between 1975 and 1993 will be most accurate because they are all seasoned for at least 10 years. Default projections on cohorts seasoned between 5 and 10 years (1993-1998 books) will also be fairly accurate. Other data are collected from the FHA's Management Report (2003), internal website, and interviews. For this analysis, I focus on the 30-year fixed rate mortgages, the mainstay of FHA-insured loan products. The period of 1975-2003, a 29-year time horizon covered by the available data, is quite representative of the U.S. macro economy, with three recessions (1980-1982, 1990-1991, and 2001-2002) and three booms (1976-1978, 1983-1984, and 1997-1999). The experience of economically favorable, normal, and unfavorable years is distributed quite evenly across various loan ages (Figure 5.4), and therefore should not be of a concern of causing bias in deriving default rate and prepayment rate distributions. - 24 Although FHA has been in existence since 1934, the agency does not trust its records on early books of business, meaning anything before 1975 (Capone, 2000). 81 - Figure 5.4 The Distribution of Macro Economic Conditions by Loan Age - The FHA Macro Economic Conditions by Loan Age • Favorable economies C Normal economies C Unfavorable economies 120% 100% - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 80% - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 60% - - - - - - - - - - I- - - - - - - - ~ 40% - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - I- - 20% - - - - - - - - - - - - - 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Loan Age (1st - 20th Year) A.2 Modeling parameters for the 2003 cohort Ultimate default rates The cohort's ultimate cumulative default rate,defined as the ratio of the number defaulted over the total number of insured loans in the cohort in itslifetime, has the biggest impact on the performance MMI of loans of the insurance fund. Throughout FHA's Fund cohorts' potential default rates for 30-year fixed rate mortgages history, its of each outstanding book of business exhibit a large variance, ranging from a low of 4.01 percent for the 1977 book of business to a high of 20.53 percent for the 1981 book (Table 5.3). The mean default rate is estimated around 9.76 percent. Table 5.3 Cumulative Origination Year 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 "Default Rates of FHA-Insured To-date (2003) cumulative default rate (%) 4.50 4.32 4.00 5.61 9.53 14.85 20.51 19.06 15.69 19.32 17.64 13.28 9.97 10.70 9.48 30-Year Fixed-Rate Mortgages Projected 30-year default rate (%) 4.50 4.33 4.01 5.61 9.54 14.86 20.53 19.09 15.71 19.36 17.70 13.36 10.09 10.88 9.69 - 82- 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 8.19 7.27 2000 4.09 2001 1.92 0.25 0.02 8.43 7.54 6.34 5.86 6.75 6.39 6.83 8.72 8.63 6.17 7.58 7.16 7.94 7.04 6.27 4.85 4.17 2002 2003 Mean Median Standard Deviation 6.78 7.43 5.81 6.74 8.62 9.76 8.43 4.75 Source: Actual (to-date) and projected default rates arefrom FHA Annual Actuarial Review of the MMIF, FY 2003, by Deloitte & Touche Ultimateprepaymentrates The ultimate prepayment rate of an insured cohort also has a significant impact on the insurance fund, as borrowers stop paying annual insurance premiums when they terminate their mortgages earlier. In a low interest rate environment, borrowers tend to exercise their "call option" embedded in the mortgage contract and prepay the loan. Considering both defaults and prepayments, the total termination rates before the end of the loan term are quite high and relatively stable for FHA's 1975-2003 books (Table 5.4). Table 5.4 Cumulative Prepayment Rates and Total Termination Rates of FHA-Insured 30-Year Fixed-Rate Mortgages Origination Year 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 Ultimate Default rate 4.50% 4.33% 4.01% 5.61% 9.54% Ultimate Prepayment rate -86.51% 86.73% 86.24% 84.78% Sum (Total termination rate) 91.01% 91.06% 90.25% 90.39% 91.10% 92.19% 1981 1982 20.53% 81.56% 77.32% 72.37 % 19.09% 74.53% 1983 1984 1985 15.71% 19.36% 17.70% 78.63% 74.95% 94.34% 77.48% 95.18% 14.86% 92.90% 93.63% 94.31% - 83 - 1986 13.36% 80.90% 94.26% 1987 1988 1989 1990 10.09% 83.41% 93.50% 10.88% 94.13% 8.43% 83.25% 85.10% 86.99% 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 7.54% 88.12% 6.75% 88.95% 89.86% 9.69% 94.79% 6.83% 8.72% 8.63% 89.16% 87.74% 87.75% 95.43% 95.66% 95.70% 96.24% 95.99% 96.46% 96.39% 7.94% 88.54% 96.48% 89.07% 89.33% 96.12% 2000 7.04% 6.78% 7.43% 2001 5.81% 6.39% 96.11% 98.11% 90.68% 91.04% 6.74% 2002 8.62% 2003 Mean Median Standard deviation 96.84% 94.22% 87.48% 80.63% 89.25% 84.45 % 86.51% 5.30% 94.21% 94.34% 2.32% Source: Actual (to-date) and projected prepayment rates are from FHA Annual Actuarial Review of the MMIF, FY 2003, by Deloitte & Touche Borrowers' default and prepayment behaviors are both correlated with interest rate movements, among other factors. A simple regression model is run to capture the interdependency between cohort default rates and prepayment rates from 1975 to 2003 (Appendix 5.1). About 81 percent of the variation is explained by the model: Ultimate Prepayment Rate = 0.942 -1.004*Ultimate Default Rate Otherparameters All additional parameters used for this simulation can be found in Table 5.5. Table 5.5 Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the FHA Program Cohort size Year Cohort LTV <=80 3.2% 97<LTV 16.8% composition by 80 < LTV <= 90 15.2% Streamline refinance 5.0% loan types 90 < LTV <= 95 95 < LTV <= 97 20.0% 24.8% ARM (all LTV) 15.0% Premium structure and pricing For all types of 30-yr fixed rate mortgage loans originated in FY 2003: Up-front premium rates (% of original loan amount): Annual premium rates (% of beginning of the year (BOY) balance): 1.5% 0.5% Loss coverage (including unpaid balance, delayed interest payments and 100% 2003 Loan insured (million $) 57,796 Number of loans 550,000 other miscellaneous fees: - 84 - Average size of the loan ($) 105,084 Duration of the annual premium payment FHA stipulates that borrowers can terminate their mortgage insurance when their mortgage loan's LTV drops below 78% through amortization. Therefore, the duration of the annual premium payment is (in years): LTV <=80 7 95 < LTV <= 97 12 80 < LTV <= 90 7 97<LTV 30 90 < LTV <= 95 12 ARM (all LTV) 12 Upfront premi urn refund The FHA Commissioner determines how much of the upfront premium is refunded when loans are terminated. For loans closed on or after January 1,2001, no refund is due the homeowner after the fifth year. The refund factors (percent of total upfront premiums paid) are: Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Premium refund schedule: 0.85 0.65 0.45 0.25 0.1 Loan term: 360 months 30-yr fixed rate 6.375% Loan interest rates: 30-yr streamline 6.375% Mortgage loan features Default costs and property recoveries Default rate scaling factors & Prepayment rate scaling factors 4.750% Unpaid Balances + foreclosure expenses (10%) + interest (8%) Recovery rate on defaults: Fixed 68 % These figures are obtained from rate 30-:year loans D&T Annual Actuarial Review, Recovery rate on defaults: 74% based on FHA's historical Streamline refinance 30-year loans experience These scaling factors differentiate risk levels of default and tendency to be prepaid among different mortgage loan categories. The overall sum of the weighted averages of default and prepayment factors (the product of scaling factors and product weights in the cohort) equals 1. Default scaling Weighted factor average 0.55 0.0176 0.78 0.1186 0.86 0.1720 0.95 0.2356 1.15 0.1932 LTV < 80 80<= LTV < 90 90 <=LTV <95 95 <= LTV < 97 97<=LTV Streamline refinance ARM Yield curve for discounting future cash flows 30-yr adjustable 1.18 Claim cost (% of UPB) LTV < 80 80 <= LTV < 90 90 <= LTV < 95 95 <= LTV < 97 97<= LTV Streamline refinance ARM _Prepayment scaling factor 1.1 0.99 0.98 0.98 0.9 1.8 0.0900 0.9 1.15 0.1725 1.18 Sum: 1.0000 Sum: Derived from 1-30 Year U.S. Treasury Constant Maturity Rates of 2003 ( http://www.federalreserve. gov/releases/h 15/currentlh 15.pdf) I-year Treasury maturity rate 1.24% 7-year Treasury maturity rate 2-year Treasury maturity rate 1.65% 10-year Treasury maturity rate 3-year Treasury maturity rate 2.11 % 20-year Treasury maturity rate 5-year Treasury maturity rate 2.97% Interpolated U.S. Treasury Curve of 2003 Weighted average 0.0352 0.1505 0.1960 0.2430 0.1512 0.0450 0.1770 1.0000 3.52% 4.02% 4.96% Yield The smoothl y upward trending yield curve projects a stable economy 6.0 5.0 'Cft. 4.0 32 3.0 Q) > 2.0 10 0.0 o o " 0 MahJrity , , (t) ~ 0 , CD 0> 'r" 'r" Source: Values in this table come from, or are based on, data in the FY2003 Annual Actuarial Review of the FHA MMIF, prepared by Deloitte & Touche; FHA's 2003 Management Report; and Capone, 2000. - 85 - A.3 Modeling processes and results Simulate the distributions of lifetime default and prepayment rates A standard approach to bankruptcy simulations is to assume that available experience is the best information on the distribution of potential default/claim rates, to draw repeated samples of subset portfolios, and to look at resulting value-at-risk measures (Capone, 2000). Based on FHA's past experience of its 29 outstanding cohorts (1975-2003), I map the frequency distribution of their ultimate default rates (Figure 5.5). Although the number of observations is limited, they can be fitted to a continuous Erlang distribution, from which random samples can be drawn. The Erlang distribution is one form of the Gamma distribution, which serves well as a general measurement model of engineering variables because of its shape flexibility, positive sample space, and closed form solution (Bury, 1999).25 Figure 5.5 The Frequency Distribution of FHA Cohorts' Ultimate Default Rates The Actualand Fitted (ErlangDistribution)FHA 30-Year CohortDefaultRates (1975-2003) I . 0.2 0a r 1_____ I r __ -- 0.05 - __ O- - FHA 30-year mortgage portfolios' ultimate default rate distribution: _1___ a) 0 0.1 - --- Erlang parameters for the - -Actual Data FittedDatawithEdangDistnbution - n1 -f ___.__..__.._i ----- -- . r r Il \ ------r .· --- -------- E \r\r ,............................. Lifetime N im) te- efa) N LifetimeUMtm~le MefaliltH~te ) ) N N N ) CM · Mean: Std dev: 9.76% 4.75% Erlang b: 2.309 Erlang c: 4 Based on the fitted Erlang distribution, I apply Monte Carlo simulation techniques to draw 10,000 random samples from it, representing 10,000 potential outcomes of the 25 That is, if nothing is known about the physics of the measurement phenomenon, the Gamma distribution is a good choice tofit the data. The Erlang distribution takes two parameters: the scale parameter b and the shape parameter c. Erlang distribution has closed form solution, because it requires that the shape parameter be an integer. Assume the mean and standard deviation of the projected 30-year ultimate default rates are x-bar and s, the Erlang parameters are computed as following: b 2 _ - ; c - X 2 ; andftx)= (x/b)l S exp(-x/b) b(c -1)! fix) is the probability density function of x. - 86- cohort ultimate default rate (Figure 5.6). The simulation has the benefit of broadening the outcomes beyond the range of the observed limited experience, therefore allowing the exploration of some out-of-range events with small probabilities (frequencies). 10,000 ultimate prepayment rates are then obtained through the relationship of Ultimate Prepayment Rate = 0.942 -1.004*Ultimate Default Rate Figure 5.6 The Frequency Distribution of 10,000 Simulated Ultimate Default and Prepayment Rates - The FHA The FrequencyDistributionof 10,000Ultimate Prepayment Ratesof FHA2003Cohort The FrequencyDistributionof 10,000SimulatedUltimate DefaultRatesof FHA2003 Cohort 1000… .... -. 1200 1200 1000 - . 800 60 =3 600 400 2 400 200 - -- 1 _ 8--- 0 CM _ e -_ 200 0 CO COC 0 11) C '-0 t Ultimate Default Rate) Ultimate Default Rate C' CO) LO 0) ) U) N CD 0 t UltimatePrepaymentRate Simulatethe annual distributionsof unconditionaldefaultand prepaymentrates The unconditional annual default rate and prepayment rate patterns - percentage of total defaults and prepayments occurring in each year - are also modeled based on FHA's historical experience using Erlang distributions. For each book of business, a pair of Erlang parameters are computed based on the relationship between the cohort's age (year) and annual unconditional default and prepayment rates. Considering that the annual distribution patterns of a cohort's default and prepayment rate differ under different economic scenarios, I classify the existing books' performance into three categories: good (ultimate cohort default rate < 6%), normal (10% > ultimate cohort default rate > 6%), and bad (ultimate cohort default rate > 10%). Within each group, I choose the median value of the scale parameter b and shape parameter c to construct the corresponding Erlang distribution. Table 5.6 presents the Erlang parameters for annual default and prepayment rate distributions, and Figure 5.7 illustrates the patterns. - 87 - 0 Table 5.6 Erlang Parameters for Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rate Distributions - The FHA Good performance Bad performance Ultimate default rate < 6% Normal performance 6% < Ultimate default rate < 10% Annual distribution patterns of unconditional default rates Scale parameter b 3.47 1.91 Shape parameter c 2 3 Ultimate default rate> 10% Annual distribution patterns of unconditional prepayment rates Scale parameter b 4.86 3.01 Shape parameter c 3 2 1.78 4 2.21 3 Figure 5.7 The Probability Distribution of Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rates - The FHA Annual Unconditional Default Probability (1975-2003) I-.-Good performance -'-Normal performance --'-Sad performance 0.16 ~ 0.14 :5 0.12 11l .g 0.1 ~ 0.08 ~ 0.06 ~ 0.04 0.02 - o ~ MOO ...... 01 Annual Unconditional Prepayment Probability (1975-2003) -+-Good performance -'-Normal performance --'-Sad performance 0.14 ~ 0.12 ~ 0.1 £. 0.08 .c - C ~ 0.06 >- ~ 0.04 - <D a: I Under the "normal performance" scenario, the annual unconditional default rates peak between the 3rd and the 6th year, then fall rapidly. Under the "bad performance" situations, the annual distribution of defaults has a wider peak window (a flatter middle section) between the 3rd and the 8th year, and tapers down more gradually, indicating a larger probability of default during the later lifetime of the loan. Under the "good performance" scenario, the annual unconditional prepayment rates distribute more evenly than other scenarios, which may reflect the fact that portfolios with low default rates contain many loans originated in the low interest rate environment, e.g. during the recessIOns. 0.02 o ~ M It) ...... 01 ~ M It) ~ po1Tcy year ...... 01 "1-30 Discounted cash flow analysis Assuming the size of FHA's 2003 cohort of 30-year fixed rate mortgages is 50 billion dollars, I conduct the discounted cash flow analysis and portfolio performance evaluation (measuring annual conditional and unconditional default and prepayment rates, survival rates, and cumulative rates) over the lifetime of this cohort. Monte Carlo simulation is - 88 - used to obtain 10,000 ultimate default rates. The parameters employed (Table 5.5) represent the projections of future macro economic conditions and housing market performance in the U.S., based on FHA's own experience and forecasts of its independent auditors. Cash flows of different loan products, categorized by their LTV ratios, are analyzed separately. All future cash flows, over the life of the loans or guarantees, are discounted by the future spot rates implied by the Treasury yield curve as of mid 2003. Appendix 5.2 describes the components of the cash flow analysis. The net present value (NPV), both in the aggregated amount for the whole cohort and in the percentage term as the NPV per dollar of insured loan, is calculated for each simulated cohort ultimate default rate, resulting in a NPV distribution (Figure 5.8). For comparability purposes, I use "profitability rate" to measure the NPV per dollar of insured loan, which is the ratio of the NPV of the 2003 cohort's guarantee contracts over the cohort's total dollar amount (face value). Table 5.7 summarizes the results. Table 5.7 Simulation Results of the NPV and Profitability Rate of the FHA 2003 Cohort Simulated ultimate default rates NPV of the guarantee contracts on the 2003 cohort (million $) Profitability rate (NPV per $ of insured loan, %) Statistics Mean Minimum Maximum Breakeven 9.2% 0.7% 34.2% 13.1% 427 1,656 -3,063 12.7 0.85% -6.13% 3.31% 0% Percentile 5 th 3.3% 1,245 2.49% 1 0 th 4.1% 1,119 2.24% 5.9% 8.4% 11.8% 15.4% 18.0% 22.9% 834 439 202 -323 -702 -1,416 1.67% 0.88% 0.40% -0.65% -1.40% -2.83% 2 5 th 50 h 7 5 th 9 0 th 9 5 th 9 9 th Breakeven percentile t 8 2 nd percentile* 8 2 nd percentile *: This breakeven percentile means that losses (negative NPV) can be expected 18 percent of the time. - 89 - Figure 5.8 The Frequency Distribution of the Simulated Profitability Rates - The Frequency Distribution of Profitability Rates of FHA 2003 Cohort (based on 10,000 simulated default rates) 1200 IUU- , 800 @ 600 400 _ 200 I ppp_ n.. 0 Profitabilityrates(NPVof Ml / Facevalueof the cohort) For FHA's 2003 cohort, the simulation shows that its mean profitability rate is around 0.85%, fairly close to the break-even zero percent, which supports the argument that a pubic MI's pricing usually only has a small cushion. Under the model's parameters setting, the cohort's break-even default rate is around 13%. That represents the 8 2 nd percentile event, meaning that losses can be expected 18 percent of the time, or once every 5.6 years on average. If the experience of FHA's 1981 book of business, the worse default experience in the last three decades with a projected ultimate default rate of 20.5%, were to repeat in the 2003 cohort, the estimated losses would be about 1 billion dollars, or 2% of the cohort's total value. Multi-yearresamplinganalysis Given the long time horizon of mortgage loans and hence mortgage guarantees, it is important to measure the cumulative potential liabilities over multiple years, to determine how much the burden could be on the backing government within a long period of time. Examining the projected 30-year ultimate default rates for the existing FHA cohorts (Table 5.3), we can see that they are strongly correlated - good years or bad years tend to come in bunches instead of randomly. The recession of the 1980s provides the best evidence - the estimated ultimate default rates exceeded 10 percent for nine consecutive years from 1980 to 1988. To explore this yearly interdependency and how external factors such as interest rates influence the ultimate default rates, I conduct several regression analyses and obtain the following model with the best fitness (Appendix 5.3): - 90 - Cohort ultimate default rate ,t = -0.005 + 0.635* Cohort ultimate default rate (,-) + 0.605* I-year Treasury bond rate (-0.57) (7.71) (4.80) R' = 0.88 The model explains around 88 percent of the variations in cohort ultimate default rates. The coefficients for the lagged default rate variable and the interest rate are both statistically significant, indicating that a cohort's ultimate default rate is correlated with the cohort default rate from the previous year and the current interest rate. Based on the regression model, I conduct multi-year NPV analyses by picking every one of the 10,000 simulated 2003 cohort default rates, projecting the next 5 (and 9) years' of cohort default rates based on the regression model derived above - from 2004 to 2008 (and 2012), and calculating the aggregate NPV over the total 6-year (and 10-year) period. The future 1-year Treasury rates are derived from the Treasury bond yield curve as the forward interest rates. Repeating the process for 10,000 simulated cohort default rates, I obtain multi-year cumulative NPV (or profitability rate) distributions for 6-year and 10year periods respectively (Figure 5.9). When a multi-year cumulative NPV (or profitability rate) is positive, it means that FHA generates surplus from its insurance business over this period. If the cumulative NPV is negative, it gives us a magnitude of the potential losses over the specified period that have to be sustained either by FHA's capital reserves or by the government in case that reserves are not sufficient. Table 5.8 summarizes the statistics of the multi-year NPV and profitability rate distributions. Table 5.8 Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions - The FHA 6-Year Accumulationa Cumulative NPV of the guaranteed cohorts (million $) 10-Year Accumulationa Profitability rate (Cumulative NPV over 2003 cohort's face value, Cumulative NPV of the guaranteed cohorts (million $) Profitability rate (Cumulative NPV over 2003 cohort's face value, %)b %)b Statistics Mean Minimum Maximum 3,542 -4,479 6,801 7.08% -8.96% 13.60% 5,030 -3,305 8,493 10.06% -6.61% 16.99% 5 th lOth 25t h 756 1,488 2,608 1.51% 2.98% 5.22% 2,047 2,828 4,034 4.09% 5.66% 8.07% 5 0 th 3,684 7.37% 5,191 10.38% Percentile -91 - 75th 90th 95th 99th Breakeven percentile 4,696 5,425 5,749 6,275 97 percentileC 9.39% 10.85% 11.50% 12.55% 12.53% 14.07% 14.76% 15.87% 6,263 7,035 7,378 7,935 99 percentileC Note: a: Every one of the 10,000 simulated ultimate default rates for the 2003 cohort is drawn to project the next 5-year (and 9year) cohort default rates. Therefore, 10,000 multi-year cumulative NPV (or profitability rate) outcomes are included in the distribution. b: Profitability rate is calculated as the ratio of cumulative NPV over one year's business volume - 2003 cohort's face value. c: The breakeven percentile means that losses (negative cumulative NPV) can be expected 3 percent and 1 percent of the time respectively, for 6-year and 10-year periods. Figure 5.9 Frequency Distributions of Multi-year Cumulative Profitability Rates The Freque ncy Distribution of 6-Year Cumulative Profitability Raes, Based on Regression Analys is 350 300 (/) 250 .~ g 200 Q) ::J 0'" Q) u: 150 100 50 o 'eft. "#. "#. 'eft. "#. ~ OJ) t"? "7 ~ 'eft. 'eft. ..- C'Il "#. l[) 'eft. "#. OJ A'ofitability Rates CJ ..- 'eft. 'eft. 'eft. N~to(J) "#. The Frequency Distribution of 10-Year Cumulative Profitability Rates, Based on Regression Analysis 350 300 (/) 250 Q) .0 c 200 Q) ::J g LL 150 100 50 0 ~ 0 CJ '"7 ~ 'eft. 0 O? ~ "#. C? '"7 ~ 0 C'Il 'eft. l[) 0 ~ 0 ~ 0 OJ CJ ~ N ~ ~ 0 ~ 0 to '(J) eft. A'oUability Rates The multi-year simulation under the expected subsequent "#. '..eft. results show the financial stable economic strength of the current FHA program outlook in the future for the 2003 cohort and its cohorts. The mean profitability rate is about 7% for the next 6-year cohorts and 10% for the next 10-year cohorts, or on average about 1% profitability - 92- rate per annual book of business over the 6-year and 10-year time frames. The break-even percentile is very high, 97% for 6-year cohorts and 99% for 10-year cohorts, indicating very small probabilities of losing money over the multi-year horizon. The multi-year analysis captures the correlation between adjacent years' cohort performance. If this yearly correlation has not been taken into consideration, the positive cumulative NPV or profitability rate of the FHA cohorts will be underestimated. For comparison purposes, I conduct the resampling analysis by drawing random multi-year sequences repeatedly from the profitability distribution (or NPV distribution) derived earlier (Figure 5.8). The results show that the 6-random-year period is estimated to generate cumulative NPV of 2.5 billion dollars, or 5.06% profitability rate over one year's cohort volume, compared to the NPV of 3.5 billion dollars (7.08% profitability rate) when six correlated cohorts are analyzed, a substantial 40 percent underestimation. Also, for the 10-year period, random draws generate a cumulative NPV of 4.3 billion dollars (8.56%7 profitability rate), while the correlated cohorts are projected to have a cumulative NPV of 5 billion dollars (10.06% profitability rate). A caveat of the multi-year analysis is that it heavily depends on the projection of future interest rates, which can be quite volatile as the yield curve changes constantly. An important question to ask is how bad things can go over multiple years into the future, based on FHA's past bad experiences. In other words, what will be the magnitude of liabilities for the FHA if there were six or ten consecutive years of losses from its insured cohorts? These events can be considered as catastrophic risks with very low probabilities - 3% over a 6-year period of time and 1% over a 10-year timeframe based on the previous analyses. To answer this question I adopt the method proposed by Carey (1998, 2001) in sampling only from the simulated outcomes with losses. Based on the profitability rate distribution derived from the 10,000 simulated cohort default rates (Figure 5.8), I take repeated samples only from the truncated negative tail part of the distribution. Resampling from the " loss zone" for multi-year sequences simulates the recession scenario and helps us understand how large the liabilities could be if FHA were to experience a period of consecutive high default rates like the 1980s. Table 5.9 - 93 - summarizes the results of resampling 6-year sequences from the negative profitability rate and NPV distribution and Figure 5.10 shows the distribution. Table 5.9 Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions from the "Loss Zone" 6-Year Accumulation when resampling only from the "loss zone"* Profitability rate (Cumulative NPV 2003 cohort (million $) over 2003 cohort's face value, %) Cumulative NPV of the guaranteed Statistics Mean Minimum Maximum -3,107 -6.21% -15.04% -0.96% -7,518 -478 Percentile 5 th -5,230 h 25 -10.46% -9.12% -7.70% -6.06% -4,561 -3,848 -3,029 -2,271 -1,658 -1,367 th 0 th th 75 50 90h th 95 -4.54% -3.32% -2.73% -1.80% th -900 *: 1,500 resampling sequences were drawn randomly only from the negative segment of the profitability/NPV distribution. Each resampling sequence has 6 data points, or profitability rates, from the distribution. 99 Figure 5.10 The Frequency Distribution of 6-year Cumulative Profitability Rates The Frequency Distributionof 6-YearCumulative Profitability RatesWhenResampling OnlyFromEventswithLosses 4~,ItU 140 120 *o 100 ) 80 o 60 L. 40 20 0 ° c| ' '- I C t C)rofi)P bility o Rates ProfitabilityRates The results indicate that if the 2003 cohort were to experience a recession of six consecutive years with net insurance losses, the magnitude of liabilities on the FHA would be around 3.1 billion dollars on average, or 6.2 percent of the cohort's value. The maximum possible losses could amount to 7.5 billion dollars, or 15 percent of the cohort's value. For one-year's book of business, the profitability rate is about -1.03 - 94 - percent on average and -2.5 percent maximum. Therefore the current requirement of 2 percent capital ratio of the MMI Fund is sufficient to cover a six-year recession scenario. However, this conclusion assumes that the future cohort size is similar to that of the 2003 cohort. If new insurance cohorts were larger and initiated during the bad years, the capital ratio needed to maintain the overall solvency throughout would rise. The 1980s saw seven years (1980 through 1986) in the history of FHA for which default rates were high enough to exceed the breakeven level (13%) and incurred losses. We can be reasonably confident that the outcome for books of business underwritten from 1987 to 2000, which have at least 5 years of seasonality, will have ultimate default rates below their breakeven point. This means that the loss years of the 1980s represent 7 out of 67 cohort years (since the FHA's inception), or just over 10 percent of historical experience. But all of the loss years came together. Thus the frequency is actually 1 out of 62 potential six-year periods in FHA's history, or about 1.6 percent. Sensitivityanalysisof FHA's liabilities The simulation analyses show that the FHA mortgage insurance business is in good shape going forward, and its capital requirement can withstand a relatively rare event of sixyear recession. This conclusion, however, is contingent upon the modeling parameters and thus sensitive to their changes. The first factor is the FHA borrowers' risk profile of its new business. FHA insurance premiums are far below PMI premiums for high LTV (above 95 percent) loans. The extent to which lower premiums will enable more marginal borrowers to qualify for FHA-insured mortgaged home purchases as they now meet payment-to-income requirements will have an impact on the risk profile of FHA's new business. In recent years, FHA has been pushing hard to expand homeownership to firsttime homebuyers and minority borrowers, which increases the risk of its books of the past several years. The movement to this direction has two direct impacts on the modeling parameters: the composition of the new cohort in terms of different LTV categories, and the projected ultimate default rate. As FHA brings in new business and existing books mature, its portfolio will move into higher and higher risk categories, leading to potentially higher default rates. In addition, its borrower profile is becoming - 95 - more vulnerable to economic fluctuations. The combination of the two could make a repeat of the 1980s experience more likely than a mere 1.6 percent event in the future. As an example, if the percentage of high LTV loans (those over 95 percent) doubles for the 2003 cohort, the NPV of the insurance on this cohort is projected to decrease by 44 million dollars, or 11% (Table 5.10). The second factor is the premium structure. In many occasions policymakers are under pressure to take actions based on short-term results instead of taking a long-term view toward the public MI program. In 1990 when Congress learned that the FHA's MMI Fund had been losing money for the past several years and was not considered financially sound, it ordered to double FHA's insurance premium, among other measures. The FHA has now been generating surplus for the government and the discussion has shifted to lowering the premium levels. Without an understanding of the long time horizon of the risks involved in sponsoring a public program like the FHA, any actions to raise or lower premium levels based on short-term performance can be irrational and create unnecessary volatility in the program performance. Table 5.10 shows that if FHA cuts its annual premium rate in half, the NPV of insurance on the 2003 cohort will become negative 184 million, a decrease of 146%. The size of the new business also matters. As discussed earlier, if the new insurance cohorts were larger than existing books, say on the order of $100 billion instead of $50 billion set in the parameter, and if these new cohorts were to experience a multi-year recession, the capital reserves (or profits generated by the earlier smaller cohorts) may not be enough to cover the large amount of losses caused by the larger new cohorts. Taking the FHA's 1980s experience for example, the accumulation of losses over multiple years of bad insurance cohorts was especially bad because these books of business were larger than the profitable books that preceded them (Capone 2000). Needless to say, changes of the macroeconomic environment and national housing market conditions play a big role in FHA liabilities. Housing market conditions directly impact the recovery rate of foreclosed properties. During FY2003, the biggest revenue - 96 - Figure 5.11 Revenue Components component for FHA's single-family insurance of the FHA MMI Fund, FY2003 business was "Property Sales and Income," exceeding its premium income (Figure 5.11). Business Revenue Components of the FHA HI FY03 "".1tC:M An upward trending U.S. housing market and Uninvested Funds SF 2% Periodic appreciating property values greatly helped mitigate the FHA losses. The sensitivity analysis shows that a 20% increase in FHA's recovery rate of foreclosed properties will boost 54% the NPV by 1300/0 (Table 5.10). The macro economic outlook of the country will affect the mortgage interest rates and the shape of the yield curve, which in turn exert comprehensive influences on many factors such as the mortgage default and prepayment rates (implied value of the put and call options in the mortgage contract) and the discount factors of the future cash flows. For instance, if the future economic outlook becomes unfavorable, say, similar to the 1980s situation, and if we use the inverted yield curve of 1981 for discounting cash flows, the NPV of the 2003 cohort will decrease by 10% (Table 5.10). Table 5.10 The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The FHA Current Model Current parameter settings Borrowers riskprofileLoan composition NPV (mil $) NPVI cohort face value Alternative Scenarios New parameter settings NPV (mil $) 80 < LTV <= 90 15.2% IfFHA moves toward higher L TV compositions - double the percentage of high L TV loans: 90< LTV <=95 20.0% 65<LTV 95 <LTV 24.8% 80< LTV <=90 65<LTV <=80 <=97 97<LTV Streamline refi ARM (allLTV) 3.2% 16.8% 404 0.8% 5.0% 15.0% <=80 Premium structure 1.5% 0.0% 95 < LTV <=97 49.6% 97<LTV 33.6% Up-front premium rates Annual premium rates 0.5% - 97 - -11% -184 -0.4% -146% 0.0% 5.0% ARM (allL TV) 11.8% Scenario 1:halve the annual premium Up-front premium rates Annual premium rates 360 0.0% 90< LTV <=95 Streamline refi ChaIl2e NPV I cohort face value 0.7% 1.5% 0.25% -1,253 Scenario 2: apply the Dutch premium Up-front premium rates Annual premium rates 0.30% 0% Scenario 3: apply the Mexican premium Up-front premium rates Annual premium rates Housing market conditions Recovery rate on defaults: Fixed rate 30-year loans 68% Recovery rate on defaults: Streamline refinance 30-year loans 74% 0% 0.70% Scenario I: Favorable (20% increase in recovery rate) Recovery defaults: Recovery defaults: refi rate on FRM rate on Streamline 81.6% 88.8% Scenario 2: Unfavorable (20% decrease in recovery rate) Recovery defaults: Recovery defaults: refi rate on FRM rate on Streamline 54.4% 59.2% Scenario 1: 1981 (worst) Interest rate environment - the Yield Curve Interpolated U.S. Treasury Yield Curve of 1981 15 15 ~ 14 Qj :; 14 13 13 Maturity Ol ~atunW II) N N Ol N Scenario 2: 1993 (best) Interpolated U.S. Treasury Yield Curve of 1993 8 ::l!6 o "0 ]14 > 2 o II) Ol - 98- Matur1lY N II) N Ol N -2.5% -210% B. The Dutch WEW Program B.1 The data Most of the data are provided by the Homeownership Guarantee Fund (abbreviated to WEW) and its 2003 Annual Report. Although the WEW has been issuing its guarantee products, the National Mortgage Guarantee, only since 1995, municipal guarantee programs were in place long before that (since 1956) and their guarantee liabilities were transferred to the WEW at its establishment. Unfortunately, the data of earlier years were not well organized due to the fragmentation of the municipal guarantee systems. At the national level, the available and reliable data on guaranteed mortgage performance dated back to 1981, therefore offering a 24-year history to conduct this analysis, within which the latest nine years are under the current program regime. The macro economy of the Netherlands has experienced three downturns (1981-1982, 1992-1993, and 2001-2003) and two boom periods (1989-1990 and 1997-2000) between 1981 and 2003. WEW's outstanding cohorts originated within this duration have experienced favorable, normal and unfavorable macro economic situations fairly evenly throughout their early loan ages, i.e., the first ten years of their loan life when majority of the defaults occur (Figure 5.12). Therefore I view the distribution patterns of ultimate default rates derived from the data of 1981-2003 cohorts as unbiased and representative of the Dutch macro economy. Figure 5.12 The Distribution of Macro Economic Conditions by Loan Age - The WEW Economic Conditions by Loan Age (1st - 20th Year) I• Favorable economies C Normal economies C Unfavorable I economies 120% 100% 80% 1- - 60% - - 40% - - - - - - - - - - - - - - f- - - f- - - - - - 20% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Loan Age (1st - 20th Year) B.2 Modeling parameters for the 2003 cohort Ultimate default rates of cohorts 1981-2003 - 99- Historically, the default rate of the Dutch mortgage loans has been very low. Mortgage portfolios have experienced negligible losses and low delinquency levels compared with most other European countries and the United States. At the moment, the Netherlands has the lowest foreclosures and loss rates in Europe. 26 Mortgage loans more than 90 days in arrears range from 0.25% to 0.75%, although an upward trend has emerged in recent years (FitchRatings, 2004). The worst experience so far was the 1981 cohort with 2.87 percent cumulative default rate in its 23 years of seasonality. After the recession of the early 1980s, the Dutch economy and its housing market have been upward trending until 2001 or so when the market stabilized and became stagnant due to the minor recession. It is fair to say that the WEW's guarantee products, issued since 1995, have yet to be tested in tough economic environments. The actual up-to-date cumulative default rates are available for WEW's 1981-2003 books of business. However, there are no projections for the ultimate cohort default rates at the end of the loan term, usually 30 years. According to the experience and projections of the U.S. FHA fixed-rate 30-year portfolios during the same period (1980-2003), the cumulative default rates within the first 10 years of the loan life capture about 88% of the overall 30-year end ultimate default rates, and the first 15 years' cumulative default rates represent 97% of the ultimate default rates. This is consistent with the general observation that defaults occur in early stages of the loan life, usually between the 3 rd and the 7 t h year. I project the ultimate default rates for WEW's 1981-2003 cohorts (Table 5.11) based on the following assumptions: Loan Age (seasonality) Greater than 20 years Between 15 and 20 years Between 10 and 15 years Less than 10 years Up-to-date cumulative Ultimate 30-year end cohort default rate default rate x (1.03 = 1/97%) 1.03*x (1.14 = 1/88%) 1.14*x Cannot be predicted accurately. x x x x 26 The main reasons for this are: (i) the sharp increases in property prices, which have helped increase recovery amounts to levels that exceed the lender's default exposure; (ii) the buildup of equity in the acquired property, which gives borrowers a strong incentive to protect that value and avoid default. In addition, in the Netherlands there is still a strong (albeit declining) cultural aversion to defaulting on debts. Borrowers perceive their relation with the lenders as a personal one, and have a strong commitment to maintaining debt payments. Furthermore, Dutch borrowers benefit from a good, reliable social security system that offers them protection in the event of unexpected situations such as unemployment prolonged illness (FitchRatings Report, 2004). - 100 - and Table 5.11 Projected Cumulative Default Rates of WEW Guaranteed Cohorts, 1981-2003 Origination Year 1981 To-date (2003) cumulative default rate 2.87% 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Projected 30-year ultimate default rate 2.87% 2.47% 2.55% 0.85% 0.85% 0.42% 0.29% 0.30% 0.22% 0.19% 2.47% 2.55% 0.85% 0.88% 0.43% 0.30% 0.31% 0.23% 0.21% 1991 0.18% 0.20% 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 0.11% 0.12% 0.08% 0.04% 0.08% 0.07% 0.05% 0.07% 0.12% 0.13% 0.09% 2000 0.11% 2001 0.11% 2002 2003 0.01% 0.00% Mean Median Standard Deviation Source: WEW and the author 0.83% 0.30% 1.01% Ultimate prepayment rates Dutch mortgage lenders typically limit the penalty-free annual prepayments to 10%-15% of the original mortgage balance. A prepayment of this nature is permitted once a year and, for any prepayment above this percentage, borrowers are required to pay a penalty equal to the difference in the mortgage funding cost between the contracted rate and the applicable market mortgage rate. They may also prepay the mortgage without penalty at the reset date on a fixed-rate mortgage. 2 7 Historically, prepayments have been stable, with annualized conditional prepayment rates ranging between 5% and 15% (FitchRatings, 2004). Another factor impacting the prepayment rate is that contrary to American mortgage contracts, Dutch mortgage interest rates are commonly fixed for a 27 Borrowers may prepay without penalty under certain circumstances - for example, when moving house, or in the case of divorce or death. - 101 - period between 5 and 20 years. At the end of each fixed-rate period, the mortgage rate is reset to the prevailing market mortgage rate. This acts as an incentive for borrowers not to prepay their mortgages until the reset date, to avoid significant fees. Although there was a gradual upward trend in prepayment rates in recent years, it remains uncertain whether the trend will continue in the future as interest rates are already at a historical low and penalty fees are relatively high once certain prepayment limits have been breached (FitchRatings, 2004). As WEW's guarantee pricing only contains a one-time upfront fee of 0.3% without annual premiums and any refund of upfront fees, the prepayment rate does not influence the cash flow analysis in any significant way. The WEW does not have data on cumulative prepayment rates of its outstanding books of business. Charlier and Van Bussel's (2003) study on the prepayment behavior of Dutch mortgagors showed that in 2001, about 18% of the newly issued mortgages were refinances to replace existing loans. The authors believed "these replacement numbers illustrate that, despite significant costs, prepayment is an important feature when managing a Dutch mortgage portfolio." Based on their research and the recent up trend in prepayment rates, I assume that on average the ultimate prepayment rate of WEW-guaranteed cohorts is around 30%, which is substantially lower than the FHA prepayment level of 84% on average. Other parameters All other parameters are constructed to reflect the characteristics of the Dutch mortgage market in general and WEW-guaranteed segments in particular (Table 5.12). Table 5.12 Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the WEW Guarantee Cohort size Year Loan insured Number of loans Cohort composition by loan types 2003 9,932 By LTV categories: LTV <=80 80 < LTV <= 90 90 < LTV <= 100 100< LTV <= 110 LTV> 110 Average size of the loan () (million C) 64,641 8.8% 5.6% 9.7% 44.7% 31.3% - 102 - 153,649 By years of interest rate fixing: Less than 10 years: 10-15 years: 15 to 20 33.4% 24.7% 21.4% 20 to 25 25 to 30 5.3% 15.2% Premium structure and pricing Mortgage loan features For all types of mortgage loans: Up-front premium rates (% of original loan amount): 0.3% Loss coverage (including unpaid balance, delayed interest payments 100% and other miscellaneous fees: Loss coverage for interest-only loans: 50% Typical loan term: 360 months Loan interest rates: average 10-yr fixed rate average 15-yr fixed rate 4.30% 4.80% average 20-yr fixed rate 5.30% assume: after 10 years the rate will be reset to the implied yield of Euro bonds for year 10 to 20 assume: after 15 years the rate will be reset to the implied yield of Euro bonds for year 15 to 20 assume: after 20 years the rate will be reset to the implied yield of Euro bonds for year 20 to 30 Note: these assumptions are based on the Euro yield curve. Default costs and property recoveries 5.40% 5.50% 5.30% Claim cost (% of UPB) 1.16 Unpaid Balances + foreclosure expenses (10%) + interest (6%). (According to the Fitch report, foreclosure expenses are around 5,000 Euros (3.25% of the average loan size) plus 6% of the property transfer tax. So in the range of 10%. ) Recovery rate (average) on the original loan amount 54.8% This percentage is from FitchRating (2004), defined as: (Property value after indexation - Market value discount amount - Repossession costs) / Current loan balance Recourse of the claim (loss) by 5% This is the level of year 2003. The recoveries 5 years from recourse of defaulters' other assets are very low currently, due to the difficulty of tracing after defaulters, administrative expenses, banks inertia, etc. WEW's right of recourse will disappear after WEW Duration for recourse to happen 5 years since foreclosure. % of defaulted borrowers who 20% are in good faith (exempt from In 2002, 30% of the defaulted households were in good faith. In 2003, 17%. In the first 3 Default rate recourse) months of 2004, 15% These scaling factors differentiate risk levels of default and tendency to be prepaid among scaling factors different mortgage loan categories. They are based on the U.S. FHA experience and adjusted & Prepayment (interpolated) according to the high LTV categories of the WEW guaranteed loans. For the lack rate scaling factors of loan-level data on the WEW portfolios, the author believes that the LTV levels exert similar impacts on portfolio default and prepayment rates in both the U.S. and the Netherlands. Default scaling Weighted factor average Yield curve for discounting future cash LTV < 80 80 <= LTV < 90 90 <= LTV < 100 0.55 0.78 0.86 100 <= LTV < 110 110<= LTV Prepayment scaling factor Weighted average 0.0482 0.0435 0.0835 LTV < 80 80 <= LTV < 90 90 <= LTV < 100 0.98 0.4380 100 <= LTV < 110 0.98 0.4380 1.24 Sum: 0.3875 1.0000 110<= LTV 0.9 Sum: 0.2813 1.0000 1.3 1.1 1 Euro Yield Curve as of 2003 (Obtained from http://epp.eurostat.cec.eu.int/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/EYC/EN/page4.htm#yields) - 103 - 0.1140 0.0614 0.0971 ~~r="'" ........... flows Euro Yield Curve, 2003 The smoothly up trending yield curve projects a stable economy 1 ~ v ,.... ~ 0 co M Maturity ~ Ol CX) ll) C\/ C\/ C\/ C\/ Source: Values in thistable come from, or are based on, data provided by the WEW, "Dutch RMBS Default Model 2004" by Fitch Ratings. WEW's Annual Report of2003, and B.3 Modeling results Simulate the distribution of WEW cohort default rates Limited to the data availability of the portfolio performance previously municipality-guaranteed) of WEW-guaranteed (or mortgage loans, and their seasonality levels, I only have 14 data points (cohorts from 1981-1994) on cohort ultimate default rates. They are mapped to a frequency distribution and a continuous Erlang distribution is constructed based on this very small sample (Figure 5.13).28 Figure 5.13 The Frequency Distribution of WEW The Actual and Fitted (Erlang Distribution) WEW Cohort Default Rates (1981-1994) -Fitted Data with Erlang Distribution - - - - - .Actual Data 0.25 ~ 0.20 Cohorts' Ultimate Default Rates Erlang parameters for the ultimate default rate distribution of WEWguaranteed cohorts: '0 a5 0.15 :::l CT ~ 0.10 u.. 0.05 ,, , , , Mean: Std dev: Erlang b: Erlang c: 0.832% 1.009% 12.224 1 0.00 ~ M ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ M ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ N M N ~ N ~ N ~ N Cohort Ultimate Default Rate (1/1000) 28 The frequency distribution of the historical cohort default rates of the WEW exhibits a bimodal pattern, which may not be accurately captured by an Erlang distribution. The fittedErlang distribution is likely to concentrate density between the high default rates and the low default rates, where not enough historical experience exists. Because of the short history of the WEW data (only has one recession period and then all economically favorable years since 1995), itis hard to justify the application of other forms of distribution as well. For comparability purposes, I chose to stilluse the Erlang distribution to fitthe data. When more data become available in the future, other alternative forms of distribution (such as Beta distribution) may be more appropriate to fitthe data. - 104 - Although the representativeness of the derived Erlang distribution is questionable due to the scarcity of the data, it is the best assumption I can make to reflect the ultimate cohort default rate patterns. This analysis is to showcase a framework to understand the magnitude of potential liabilities. As more data become available, they can be incorporated into this framework to improve the projections. Similar to the approach used in analyzing the U.S. FHA program, I apply a Monte Carlo simulation to draw 10,000 random samples from the Erlang distribution of WEW cohorts' ultimate default rates (Figure 5.14). Figure 5.14 The Frequency Distribution of 10,000 Simulated Ultimate Default Rates The WEW Simulated ultimate default rates Statistics The Frequency Distribution of 10,000 Simulated Ultimated Default Rates of WEW 2003 Cohort 4W r - - - - ·--- · ·---- ···--- Mean Median Maximum Minimum -- 400 lb 350 · 1.2336% 0.8682% 12.3863% 0.0001% 300 Percentile a) 250 a' 200 L 150 100 50 O 5 th 10th 25 a 'n o o cD 0 C U - o cD 0 - a ! U -^ 0a o ) N ~2 0 U N C 7 .. ..I. .. I - 1 o ' o o co 0 \T 0a) s) I . II . . .1., . - o I0 U) 'o ) U) I) o 0 0 a) ) Ultimate Default Rate th 0.0647% 0.1347% 0.3585% 75h 0.8682% 1.7352% 90" 2.8086% Qgth 9 9 th 3 -4N~o 50 5.5865% Simulate the annualdistributionsof unconditionaldefaultand prepaymentrates During the past two decades, the Dutch economy has experienced only one serious recession in the early 1980s and some stagnant years between 1991 and 1993. Based on the projections of ultimate default rates (Table 5.11) of 1981-1994 cohorts, I group them into three categories in terms of their performance: good (ultimate cohort default rate < 0.3%), normal (2% > ultimate cohort default rate > 0.3%), and bad (ultimate cohort default rate > 2%). For each cohort, I calculate the pair of Erlang b and c parameters based on its annual marginal (unconditional) default rate. Then I select the median value pair of the scale parameter b and shape parameter c within each group to construct the - 105 - corresponding annualized Erlang distribution of default rates. As for the distribution of prepayment rates, there are no data available either at the aggregate level or annual level. So I apply the Erlang parameters derived from the U.S. FHA's annual prepayment pattern of the "good performance" group, as all the WEW cohorts are projected to have ultimate default rates under 6%, the threshold defining the "good performance" group in the FHA case. Table 5.13 summarizes the Erlang parameter settings and Figure 5.15 depicts the annual distribution patterns for default rates.29 Table 5.13 Erlang Parameters for Annual Unconditional Default and Prepayment Rate Distributions - The WEW Good Performance Ultimate default rate < .3% Normal Performance .3% < Ultimate default rate < 2% Bad Performance Ultimate default rate > 2% Annual distribution patterns of unconditional default rates Scale parameter b Shape parameter c 0.52 0.73 0.96 7 6 7 Annual distribution patterns of unconditional prepayment rates Scale parameter b 4.86 4.86 Shape parameter c 3 3 4.86 3 11 -~~~~~~ Figure 5.15 The Probability Distribution of WEW's Annual Unconditional Default Rates AnnualUnconditional DefaultProbability, WEW30-yearloans (1981-1994) ---U.Oa) 0.3 Goodperformance----- Normalperformance A Badperformance -- - -----1 I 0.25 ° 0.2 v 0.15 o 0.1 0.05 0 ______ _ - - -_-- -_ - - - ce- a0U Nr0 a c 0 ---N~- 0) -~~~~ -N - a) r m- Policyyear 1-30 Figure 5.15 illustrates the annual unconditional default probability distribution for WEW 30-year fixed rate mortgage portfolios. However, most of WEW-guaranteed loans have a period of interest rate-fixation less than 30 years. The length of the interest rate fixation 29 The annual distribution patterns for prepayment rates are the same as those of FHA cohorts presented in Figure 5.7 ealier. - 106 - ranges widely from only one year (ARMs) to 30 years, with some apparent clusters: 5-7 years, 10-year, 15-year, 20-year, and 30-year. For simplicity, I analyze three most popular types: 10-year, 15-year and 20-year fixed interest rates. I assume that after the first 10 (or 15, 20) years, the mortgage interest rate will be reset to the prevailing market rate then and keep fixed for the rest of the loan life. Based on the interest rate assumptions (Table 5.12), there will be some "payment shock" after the initial interest rate-fixing period, in the 11th year for the 10-year fixed rate loans and in the 16t h year for the 15-year fixed rate loans (Table 5.14). Table 5.14 Change of Monthly Payment Due to Interest Rate Reset 30-yr interest rate fixed mortgages: monthly payment per euro of loan: 20-yr interest rate fixed mortgages: monthly payment per euro of loan: 15-yr interest rate fixed mortgages: monthly payment per euro of loan: 10-yr interest rate fixed mortgages: monthly payment per euro of loan: 0.0056 First 20 years monthly pmt Next 10 years monthly pmt % of payment changes from the 30-yr fixed loans 0.0056 First 15 years monthly pmt 0.0052 First 10 years monthly pint 0.0056 Next 15 years monthly pmt 0.0055 Next 20 years monthly pmt 0.0% 0.0049 0.0054 4.7% 9.7% In order to account for the impact of payment adjustments on annual unconditional default rates, I apply an adjustment coefficient to translate changes in monthly payments (due to changes in the mortgage interest rate) into some proportional effect on the annual default rate. I tested various adjustment coefficients ranging from 0.1 to 1 and they did not change the default pattern in any significant way. The reason may be because unconditional default rates are fairly low after year 10 as the property has always appreciated in value and borrower incomes are likely to be higher and more stable. I use 0.5 as the adjustment coefficient to translate the payment shocks into proportional annual default rate changes. Discountedcash flow analysis Unlike the FHA portfolios in its MMI Fund, the WEW 2003 cohort is far from being homogeneous. It is a complex mix of various types of mortgage loan products with different LTVs and interest rate fixing periods. I focus on three major types of loans in - 107 - WEW's portfolio: 30-year loan term, annuity-type mortgages with 10-year, 15-year or 30-year interest rate fixing period. For simplicity purposes, I first analyze them separately, assuming that there are three cohorts of homogenous WEW-guaranteed mortgages with face value of 10 billion euros each. Appendix 5.4 presents the details of the cash flow analyses. The NPVs of the three types of cohorts and their profitability rates are summarized as following (Table 5.15): Table 5.15 Simulation Results of the NPV and Profitability Rates of the WEW's Three Types of Cohorts Simulated NPV of the guarantee contracts ultimate (million C) Groupedby the lengthof interest-ratefixing default rate Profitability rate (NPV per C of guaranteed loan, %) Groupedby the lengthof interest-ratefixing 10-yr 15-yr 30-yr 10-yr 15-yr 30-yr 1.234% 0.868% 12.386% 0.0001% -22 -7 -416 29 -22 -7 -418 29 -24 -8 -422 29 -0.22% -0.07% -4.16% 0.29% -0.22% -0.07% -4.18% 0.29% -0.24% -0.08% -4.22% 0.29% 0.065% 0.135% 0.359% 0.868% 1.735% 2.809% 3.643% 5.587% -102 -72 -43 -7 14 24 27 29 -102 -72 -43 -7 14 23 27 29 -126 -91 -46 -8 14 23 27 29 -1.02% -0.72% -0.43% -0.07% 0.14% 0.24% 0.27% 0.29% -1.02% -0.72% -0.43% -0.07% 0.14% 0.23% 0.27% 0.29% -1.26% -0.91% -0.46% -0.08% 0.14% 0.23% 0.27% 0.29% Statistics Mean Median Maximum Minimum Percentile 5t h 10th 25 t h 50t 7 5 th 90 t h 95t h 99th Breakeven percentile* Breakeven default rate 43 rd 0.71% 4 3 rd 0.70% 42 nd 0.68% *: The breakeven percentile means that losses (negative NPV) can be expected 57 percent, 57 percent, and 58 percent of the time respectively, for loans with 10-year, 15-year and 30-year interest rate fixing period, respectively. 108 - Figure 5.16 Frequency Distributions of Profitability Rates for WEW's 10-year, IS-year, and 30-year Fixed Rate Cohorts Frequency Distribution of Profitability Rates of WEW Cohort with 1D-Year Fixed Interest Rate 900 800 en 700 .~ 600 c 500 ~ 400 c:T 300 ~ 200 u.. 100 en Q) 0g Q) 5Q) u: o ~o ~ e ~~ ~0 ~ ~ 0 I 0 ~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 0 ~ ~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 0 N ~~ ~ N ~ ~ 0 ~ Portitabillty rates (NP\t per Euro alloan) ~~ I"- ~ 0 N c? ~ Frequency Distribution of Profitability Rates of WEW Cohort with 15-Year Fixed Interest Rate 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 o ~o o ~ e ~~ ~ ~0 <D ~ ~ 0 ~0 ~ ~~ 0 ~ ~~ ~0 0> 9 9 ~ ~ ~ ~ CO ~ ~ ~ c? ~~ I"- ~ 0 N c? ~ Porfitability rates (NPV per Euro 01 loan) Frequency Distribution of ProfitabIlity Rates of WEW Cohort with 3D-Year Fixed Interest Rate 900 800 Q) 700 .0 600 ~ 500 :J 400 300 200 100 en g u: o ~ 0 ~ 0 ~ ~~ 0 ~ 0 0 <D e 9 9 ~ ~ ~~ 0 I ~ 0 ~~ 0 I ~ ~ ~~ 0 I ~ 0 ~ ~ 0 ~ ~ CO ~ 0 ~ 0 ~ 0 ~ ~l"0 ~o o N c? c? ~ Porfitability rates (NPV per Euro 01 loan) The simulation results (Figure 5.16) show that the cohort performance does not vary too much among 10-year, IS-year, and 30-year fixed rate mortgages. For all three types, the clusters (bars) with highest frequencies are concentrated in the range of 0% to 0.30/0 in profitability rates. The mean cohort profitability rate is around -0.20/0, meaning that the cohort loses 22 to 24 million euros on the 10 billion euros face value on average. Out of 10,000 outcomes, about 42-430/0 have positive NPVs, indicating a breakeven cohort default rate around 0.7%. If the worst experience so far, the 1981 book of business with the cohort default rate of 2.870/0, were to happen again for the 2003 cohort, the projected losses would mount to 74 million euros for the 10-year and IS-year fixed rates respectively, and 93 million euros for the 30-year fixed rates. These estimates are based on the simulated 10,000 ultimate default rates derived from the mortgage loan performance between 1981 and 1994, which contains a major economic downturn of 1980-1983. Since the early 1990s, the Dutch economy has been steady and - 109 - growing, so has its mortgage markets. The default rates have been extremely low for the past decade. Between 1995 and 2003, 511,244 guarantees were issued and only 566, or 0.11%, defaulted. The simulation outcomes of default rates presented before may be biased upwards. If we pick the worst performing cohort within the last 10 years,30 the 2001 book of business with an estimated ultimate default rate of 0.22%,3 1 the NPV of the guarantee is projected to be around positive 20 million euros, or a 0.2% profitability rate. This estimate is likely to be in the reasonable range, considering that since its establishment in 1995 the WEW has been building up its capital reserves to about 247 million euros, from its 10 books of business (1995-2004). Multi-yearNPV analysis Similar to the analysis of the U.S. FHA program, I conduct the multi-year NPV analysis to understand the range of potential liabilities on WEW-guaranteed cohorts. As there are no projections of ultimate default rates for the WEW outstanding cohorts, I select the cohorts with at least five years of seasonality (19 cohorts, from 1981 to 1999), and apply the multipliers derived from the FHA historical experience to convert their up-to-date cumulative default rates into the estimated ultimate cohort default rates. We can also observe the pattern that higher default rates tend to come together, such as the early years of the 1980s. A regression analysis is used to explore the correlation between adjacent years and with the short-term interest rates (Appendix 5.5). The three months Aibor/Euribor rates are used to represent short-term interest rates.32 The best fitting model is the following: Cohort ultimate default rate (, = -0.003 + 0.678* Cohort ultimate default rate (,.-)+ 0. 050* short-term interest rate (-1.09) (7.01) (1.30) R2 = 0.83 30 This is, of course, an estimation as the most recent 10 cohorts are not seasoned enough to be accurately projected in terms of their ultimate cohort default rates. Based on the limited available annual marginal default rates of the most recent 10 cohorts, I apply the Erlang distribution of annual unconditional default rates derived earlier to back out the 30-year end cumulative default rate. 31 For the 2001 cohort, the annual unconditional default rate is 0% for the 1 year, 0.029% for the 2 nd year, and 0.083% for the 3'd year. Applying the Erlang distribution factors, we can get an estimate of 0.22% for the cohort's ultimate 30-year end default rate. 32This is the only type of interest rate that has been available and consistent for the whole period of 1981- 1999. Data on other types of interest rates such as the 1-year Euro bond have been available only since January 1999. - 110- The model explains about 83 percent of the variations in cohort ultimate default rates. The coefficient for the lagged default rate variable is statistically significant, indicating the interdependency of cohort default rates between consecutive years. For simplicity, I assume that in the 2003 cohort and its following cohorts, 35% of the guaranteed mortgages are 10-year fixed rates, 45% are 15-year fixed rates, and 20% are 30-year fixed rates.33 Based on the regression model above, I conduct multi-year NPV analyses over the next 6 and 10 years respectively. The future short-term interest rates are obtained from the Euro bond yield curve. Table 5.16 summarizes the statistics of the multi-year NPV and profitability rate distributions. Table 5.16 Multi-year NPV and Profitability Rate Distributions - The WEW 6-Year Accumulationa Cumulative NPV of the guaranteed cohorts Profitability rate (Cumulative NPV over 2003 cohort's face value, %) (million C) 10-Year Accumulationa Profitability rate Cumulative NPV of the guaranteed cohorts over 2003 cohort's face (million C) value, %) (Cumulative NPV Worse Case Scenario A repeat of the 1981-1983 recession: three consecutive years of high default ratesb Cumulative NPV Profitability rate (million C) Statistics Mean Minimum Maximum 55 0.55% -1,091 -10.91% 2.02% 202 167 -1,090 -10.90% 327 3.27% 318 309 280 214 3.18% 3.09% 1.67% Percentile 5 th 10 25 50 75 194 186 159 98 th th th th -4 9 0 th 95 99 -117 -200 -403 th th Breakeven percentile Note: 1.94% 1.86% 1.59% 0.98% -0.04% -1.17% 103 -21 -113 -335 -2.00% -4.03% 75 percentile' -210 -2.1% 2.80% 2.14% 1.03% -0.21% -1.13% -3.35% 89 percentilec a: The statistics of the 10,000 simulated ultimate default rates for the 2003 cohort are used to project the next 5-year (and 9-year) cohort default rates and calculate the cumulative NPV and profitability rate. b: The ultimate default ratefor the 1981 cohort is estimated to be 2.87%, for the 1982 cohort, 2.47%;for the 1983 cohort, 2.55%. c: The breakeven percentile means that losses (negative cumulative NPVs) can be expected 25 percent and 11I percent of the time,for6-year and 10-yearperiods respectively. 33 The actual composition of the 2003 cohort in terms of interest rate-fixing periods is as following: Less than 10 years: 10-15 years: 15 to 20 20 to 25 25 to 30 Actual figures 33.4% 24.7% 21.4% 5.3% 15.2% My assumption 35% 45% 20% 111 - The multi-year analyses show that under the current stable economic outlook indicated by the Euro yield curve, the 2003 cohort and its subsequent cohorts are expected to generate positive values of 55 million euros for the next 6 years and 167 million euros for the next 10 years. The mean profitability rate is about 0.55% for the 6-year cohorts and 1.67% for the 10-year cohorts, or it ranges within 0.09% - 0.17% for one-year's book of business on average going forward. The break-even percentile is around 75 percent for 6-year cohorts and 89 percent for 10-year cohorts, which means that under the current program design and economic outlook, the probability of net losses over the next 6-year cohorts is 25 percent, and 11 percent over the next 10-year cohorts. How bad could things go? If the worst experience so far, the recession of three consecutive years between 1981-1983, were to happen again, the estimated total losses would amount to around 210 million euros for the WEW. Uniquenessof Dutchmortgageproductsand sensitivityanalysis of WEW's liabilities The previous NPV analyses made some simplified assumptions about WEW's 2003 cohort. In reality, the cohort is a complex mix of various types of mortgage products with very different risk profiles that are not captured in the cash flow analysis.3 4 Savings 34 The Dutch tax system allows full deductibility of mortgage interest and tax exempt returns, with no capital tax on linked repayment vehicles. It therefore encourages homeowners to increase their leverage for purchasing a property rather than use equity. As a consequence, in the 1990s an extensive system of mortgage types was developed that offered maximum advantage of the tax opportunities. The mortgage products currently available are as following: Definition Mortgage types Linear/Annuity Mortgage Savings Mortgage Life Insurance Mortgage These mortgages require borrowers to make principal repayments to amortize the principal balance of the loan on a monthly basis. Under a savings mortgage a borrower pays the principal into a savings account, which accrues the same rate of interest as the one on the mortgage. The principal built up in this account simulates an annuity profile. Unlike insurance and investment funds, the principal balance of the savings fund cannot decline; it is therefore, effectively, a 'synthetic' amortizing loan. This product is a combination of an interest only loan and a life insurance policy, into which the borrower pays monthly premiums. Amounts accumulated by the policy are used to repay the mortgage on its maturity date. The provider of the policy can guarantee a minimum yield on amounts paid in by the borrower. However, the overall maturity amount depends on the insurance company's success in achieving an assumed benchmark return. - 112- % in 2003 cohort 12% 27% 12% mortgages are essentially the same as traditional annuity mortgages. Two of them combined represent about 40% of the portfolio. The remaining 60% loans are riskier than annuity type loans. Life insurance mortgages and investment mortgages link the borrowers' monthly payment to an insurance policy or an investment vehicle. Borrowers' ability fully to repay the loan is therefore connected to the performance of these investments, which adds volatility to the default rate of the cohort guaranteed by the WEW. The interest-only loans (33% of the cohort) are the most risky ones. If the housing market is trending downward and prices drop, borrowers with interest-only loans will have negative equity in their house much more quickly than borrowers with amortizing loans, a strong incentive for borrowers to default. Taking these mortgage types into account, the magnitude of potential liabilities computed earlier for the 2003 cohort is likely to be underestimated. Fortunately, there are several risk mitigating measures taken by the WEW. For instance, it only provides 50 percent coverage to interest-only loans instead of 100 percent, and the LTV of interest-only loans cannot exceed 70 percent. Also, guarantees provided by the WEW amortize over time on a monthly 30-year annuity basis, even if the mortgage itself does not amortize at the same schedule. This rule limits the claim amount to WEW regardless of the underlying mortgage products, while creating a potential shortfall in protection for lenders. To some extent, these factors counteract the increase in cohort riskiness resulting from the cohort loan composition. Further analyses are needed to explore how much they mitigate each other, which is beyond the scope of this study. Investment Mortgage, Switch mortgages, and Miscellaneous Investment mortgages involve an interest only loan, whereby, on a monthly basis, borrowers only make interest payments to the mortgage lender and pay, separately, premiums to an investment policy. Amounts built up in the policy are earmarked for redemption of the mortgage on its maturity date, but are entirely dependent on the performance of the investment fund. 16% Instead of choosing beforehand between a savings and an investment mortgage, mortgagors can switch between building up the principal amount through a savings account or by an investment account. Similar to a savings or an investment mortgage, the borrower does not pay back any principal during the term of the contract. Interest-Only Mortgage With an interest-only mortgage borrowers are only required to pay interest to the lender. No scheme is arranged for the repayment of the principal; hence the responsibility of the final mortgage repayment lies exclusively with the borrower. Lenders will only offer interest only loans to a 75% loan to foreclosure value, beyond which some form of repayment fund is required. - 113- 33% Insurance pricing always plays a very significant role in the liability analysis. Thanks to the booming housing market and the extremely low default rates, the WEW has been generating surplus and building up capital reserves since its inception. In 2005, WEW is going to lower its one-time upfront insurance premium to 0.28% from its current level of 0.3%. Based on the mean cohort default rate simulated earlier, this change will lead to a 9% decrease in insurance NPV, or 2 million euros more in losses, from its previous 22.4 million (Table 5.17). The management of the program exerts big impacts on its performance as well. The right of the WEW to recourse to borrowers' other assets if they default on their mortgages strengthens the WEW's position. But currently this ability has yet to be fully utilized as only about 5% of the losses were recovered through recourse in 2003 for the WEW. However, the awareness of the WEW's right of recourse may act as a deterrent on borrowers and therefore reduce the defaults. The WEW relies on lenders to trace after defaulted borrowers and the process has not been working effectively so far. If the WEW could double the recovery rate from recourse, from the current 5% of the claim amount to 10%, the cohort insurance NPV will increase by 27% (Table 5.17). Since 1991, the favorable economic situation in the Netherlands has brought about a combination of rising incomes and falling interest rates. As a result, the housing market has taken off and sustained continuous price increases (Figure 5.17). However, this continuous price increase of the previous years has been broken since the second half of 2001 (Boelhouwer and Neuteboom, 2003). In 2002, real housing prices seemed to be stabilizing, and even falling slightly. During the history of 1966 to 2002, the real house price volatility in the Netherlands was around 17%, ranking the third (only after Finland and Ireland) in EU countries. - 114- Figure 5.17 Development of House Price and Long-term Equilibrium Price, 1965 2000) Source: Boelhouwer et al (2001 ) The volume of mortgage debt has increased by 35% between 1996 and 2002. As of 2002, the mortgage debt to GDP ratio in the Netherlands was 88%, the highest in all ED countries (Hypostat 1992-2002). With this large volume of mortgage debt, the fluctuation of housing prices would exert great influence on the national economy. For example, if the housing prices increase by 20%, i.e., the sales of foreclosed properties up by 20%, the cohort NPV will increase by 540/0 (Table 5.17). Table 5.17 compares the NPV ofWEW's 2003 cohort35 under different parameter settings and economic scenarios. The cohort's volume is 10 billion euros at origination. Table 5.17 The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The WEW Model (assuming the mean default rate of 1.23%) NPVI NPV cohort Current parameter settings face (mil €) value 0.3% One-time up-front Alternative Current Premium level -22.4 premium rates Housing market conditions Recovery rate on defaults -0.22% Scenarios -24.4 -9% -10.2 -0.1% 54% NPV New parameter settings New premium since 2005: Up-front premium rates Recovery rate on defaults (mil $) 0.28% Scenario 1: Favorable (20% increase in recovery rate) 54.8% Cball2e NPV I cohort face value -0.24% 65.8% Here I assume the "simplified version" of the WEW's 2003 cohort that only contains annuity type mortgages. It is composed of 35% of the 10-year fixed rates, 45% of the IS-year fixed rates, and 20% of the 30-year fixed rates. 35 - 115 - Scenario 2: Unfavorable (20% decrease in recovery rate) Recovery rate on defaults: FRM Program management Interest rate environment -the Yield Curve -0.35% 43.8% Scenario I: Stronger recourse recoveries % of losses recovered through recourse Duration of recourse -34.6 -16.4 5% % of losses recovered through recourse Duration of recourse 5 years 10% 5 years If the future economic outlook is unfavorable: the yield curve of U.S. 198 I Treasury bills Euro Yield Curve, 2003 - I 2;8 15 "0 Q;3 >= 15 2 ~ 14 Qi >= 14 13 13 C. The Mexican SHF Program C.I The data The Mexican SHF (Federal Mortgage Corporation) was created in February 2002. Currently the SHF operates in essentially the same way as its predecessor, FOVI, used to, i.e. granting loans to intermediary finance organizations and issuing mortgage insurance and loan guarantees. But its primary mandate is to standardize mortgage origination in the primary market and promote development of the secondary market by granting mortgage guarantees. The SHF is moving out of the loan granting role to be solely focused on three major guarantee products: mortgage insurance, construction loan guarantee, and on-time payment guarantee for MBS. The implied government liabilities to support SHF's new guarantees will expire in October 2013. From that point on, whatever guarantees the SHF undertakes will be supported by the institution's own financial strength. Therefore, this analysis is focused on the projections of the cohort performance for 2002 to 2013 books of business, on the SHF's first-loss partial mortgage guarantees. -116- Reliable data on the mortgage portfolio performance, such as default rates and losses, and prepayment rates, are very limited in Mexico. Although before the establishment of the SHF, FOVI had been granting mortgage guarantees under its "Pari-Passu" program, the poor management and non-standardized underwriting process compromised the data credibility. For example, no claims were ever submitted or paid under the old "PariPassu" program, despite numerous defaults suffered by lenders during Mexico's 1995 currency crisis.3 6 Another reason for the lack of usable historical data is due to the fact that after the crisis the mortgage products changed in 1996. The Mexican government provided several measures to increase liquidity to banks and payment support for mortgage holders, among which was to allow borrowers to restructure their mortgage loans into an inflation adjusted accounting unit, the Unidades de Inversion (UDIs) at a low (subsidized) fixed real interest rate. The restructuring of the mortgage product changed the portfolio risk profile. Of the SHF-guaranteed 2003 cohort, 93 percent are UDI denominated mortgage loans. Considering the factors above and data availability, I focus my analysis on the first book of business, the 2003 cohort, guaranteed by the SHF's new MI product. Most of the data are provided by the SHF extracted from its newly established 300,000-loan database, known as Fuente Integral de Estadistica Hipotecaris (FIEH, Statistical Mortgage Integral Source). A lot of information is also obtained through field work and interviews. Data date back to 1996 when UDI loans started. C.2 Modeling parameters for the 2003 cohort Historical default rates, 1996-2003 Even before the financial crisis of 1995 - 1997, the Mexican real estate market showed signs of weakening as the previous property price bubble generated between 1991 and 36 This is because under the FOVI's Pari-Passu guaranty program, lenders can only collect money after they foreclose the loan, obtain the property, sell it, and then fill out all the documents. This process in itself was extremely difficult, if not impossible. In addition, lenders had to prove that their origination documents fulfill the requirements of FOVI, which was impossible due to the non-standardization of mortgage loan origination and the lack of monitoring from the FOVI. As a result, lenders lost trust in FOVI's guarantee program. - 117- 1993 burst.3 7 The mortgage delinquency rate has been climbing up since 1993 and skyrocketed during the crisis and the years afterwards (Figure 5.18). Figure 5.18 Cumulative Mortgage Loan Delinquency Rate of Consolidated Commercial Banks in Mexico 40% 33.7% 35% 34.5% V 28.1% 25'% 20% 15% 10%14 N0.2% ' C -- 3% C C -.. Sl'turcl': 1lltcl t.. N.ixico. lIt.S.. . Not In Jantluar I 97. M hNexicadtkpt l ISk ( .A\ AP aountii standardsandlthusbeganincluditi entir laince in pa.t dc lo I l as part o' th1kdlinqt enlt ptrllklit). lhe The Mexican Banking Commission (CNBV) estimated that the percentage of delinquent loans as compared to current loans was as high as 13.9 percent by the end of 1993. After the crisis, as shown in the graph, the delinquency rate of some consolidated commercial banks reached around 35% of the total outstanding mortgage portfolio in 1997. Broken down by cohorts, i.e. origination years, the marginal default rates of previous FOVIguaranteed cohorts are as the following (Table 5.18): Table 5.18 Marginal Default Rates of FOVI-Guaranteed Cohorts Origination year 1996 1996 P.00% 1997 1998 1997 1998 1.14% 3.51% 0.02% Age of Loan 1999 2000 3.86% 4.36% 19.20% 0.53% 1.73% 1.96% 2.22% 2.88% 9.33% 0.00% 0.47% 1.36% 1.66% 2.13% 5.62% 0.42% 1.70% 2.77% 3.77% 8.66% 1.32% 2.35% 0.14% 0.73% 4.00% 0.86% 0.01% 0.01% 0.33% 2001 2002 -` Y, -- Cumulative default rate to-date 2.89% 2000 . 2002 3.44% 1999 " 2001 - Source: 1ne nr 37Between 1993 and 1995, urban land prices decreased about 10 percent in real terms and social-interest housing prices declined similarly. Residential, medium, and economic housing - the three categories on which commercial banks concentrate their lending - suffered a much deeper price decline at about 30 percent in real terms (Pickering 2000). - 118- These cohorts had been transferred to SHF's guarantee program. As the SHF-guaranteed 2003 cohort has only one-year history, I will base my assumption of its ultimate cohort default rate on the range of the default rates projected from the existing books of business since 1996. The 1996-1998 cohorts have more than 5-year seasonality so far and provide a good starting point for estimation. Using the experience of the U.S. FHA fixed-rate 30year portfolio's cumulative default rates as a reference, I obtain the following factors: the cumulative default rates within the first 5 years of the loan life capture about 37% of the overall ultimate default rates, the first 6 years represent 50%, and the first 7 years represent 61%'oof the ultimate default rates. Based on these percentages I project the ultimate default rates for the 1996-1998 cohorts (Table 5.19). Table 5.19 Projected Cumulative Default Rates of SHF Guaranteed Cohorts, 1996-1998 Origination Year 1996 1997 1998 To-date (2003) cumulative default rate Projected ultimate default rate 19.20% 9.33% 5.62% 31.5% 18.7% 15.2% Prepaymentrates, 2000 -2003 Data on mortgage prepayment rates were not available before 2000. A close examination of the mortgage performance during and after the financial crisis of 1995 suggests that the prepayment rate should be fairly low. During that period, nearly all mortgages originated in Mexico were dual-indexed mortgage (DIM), which allowed lenders to earn a variable market interest rate on loans while also keeping payments affordable for borrowers.38 However, the financial crisis and the resulting highly inflationary environment, worsened by declining housing prices, have caused accelerated negative 38 The novel feature of the DIM is that the monthly payment is not determined by the "effective" or "debiting" rate but instead by a separately calculated "payment" rate. The debiting rate determines the interest accrued on the outstanding debt at any time, and is the interest owed by the borrower over the life of the loan. The payment rate, on the other hand, specifies the amount paid by the borrower in any given month. DIM payment rates grow over time. Payments are adjusted periodically, usually at longer intervals than the debit rate, and determine the rate of amortization of the loan at any given time. Payment adjustments in Mlexicohave typically followed minimum wage adjustments. These mortgages were designed to negatively amortize over the early period of the loan's life, allowing banks to keep payments affordable (Pickering 2000). - 119- amortization in a large number of mortgages. Excessive negative amortization induced high default rates while discouraged prepayments. The SHF's new database has information on monthly prepayment rates of its portfolio (Figure 5.19). Considering both complete prepayments and partial prepayments, SHF portfolio's cumulative prepayment rate for the last 48 months was around 15 percent. For lack of better data, I assume the prepayment pattern of the SHF cohort is similar to that of the FHA's. That is, the first 4-year's cumulative prepayment rate represents about 33% of the ultimate prepayment rate. So the projected ultimate cohort prepayment rate approximates 450/0. Figure 5.19 The Prepayment Pattern of the SHF-Guaranteed Mortgages Prepayment Rate of SHF-Guaranteed Mortgages _ Curtailment -Log. (Prepayment Curve) _ Total Prepayment -Prepayment Curve Annual prepayment rate 0.60% 15t 2nd 0.50% 0.40% 3rd 4th Cumulati ve 151 -4 th 0.30% 0.20% 0.00% 15.08% year 0.10% ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ Month re M ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 1.99% 4.22% 4.50% 4.38% Projected ultimate prepayment rate 45.3% Source: The SHF Other parameters As a new entity that started operation in 2002, the SHF has much less historical data on its loan performance than the U.S. FHA program or the Dutch WEW fund. Table 5.20 presents the other parameters used in the analysis. Assumptions are stated when there are no actual data. Explanations of some parameter values are presented in Appendix 5.6. Table 5.20 Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the SHF Mortgage Guarantee Cohort size Year 2003 Loan insured (million) 15,519 Pesos, or 1,361 U.S. $ Number of loans 53,149 - 120 - Average size of the loan (Pesos) Prosavi Profivi Peso 79,288 358,559 607,702 Cohort composition by loan types There are three types of mortgage loans guaranteed by the SHF: Prosavi loans, UDI loans, and Peso loans. Prosavi (Programa de Subsidios a Vivienda) loans are subsidized mortgages offered to families with incomes below 5 minimum wages, while Profivi (Programa de Financiamiento a Vivienda) loans are unsubsidized. Both Prosavi and Profivi loans are denoted in UDIs. Peso loans are unsubsidized mortgages denoted in Pesos. More details on SHF mortgage products can be found in Appendix 5.6. Product type Prosavi Profivi Peso loan Premium structure and pricing Mortgage loan features Percent 6.4% 92.8% 0.8% Average LTV 73% 86% 86% Average loan term (year) 25 25 25 Up-front premium rates: Annual premium rate charged on the outstanding loan balance: 0% UDI loans Peso loans 0.70% 0.83% Loss coverage (percentage of unpaid balance plus the capital, ordinary interests, delayed payments and the collection and cover commissions, as well as the other miscellaneous costs): Typical loan term: 300 months Lan interest 25-yr fixed real rate (UDI) 25-yr fixed real rate (Peso 25% 13.7% 17.5% Note: majority of the loans are UDI loans, fixed in real rate (variable rates when inflation fluctuates). That is, the principal is adjusted with inflation each month. If the real interest rate is constant, monthly payments are adjusted only by the rate of inflation (which increases the principal).Real interest is then charged on this inflation-adjusted capital. Inflation and implied UDIPeso relationship 2003 Inflation (% change) UDI - Peso rate (1 UDI) 2004 3.9 3.272 3.6 3.390 2005 3.8 3.518 2006 3.4 3.638 2007 onwards 3 3.747 Source: Mexican government. Bank of Mexico. Default costs and property recoveries UDI Loans: Claim cost (% of UPB) 1.56 Recovery rate (average) on the original loan amount 56% Unpaid Balances + foreclosure-related expenses (24%) + interest for 2.3 years (13.7%*2.3)) -- the average foreclosure time lasts for 27 months, i.e. 2.3 years. Suppose the original house value is 100 UDIs. Get a loan of 85% LTV, i.e., the loan amount is 85 UDIs. As the majority of defaults occur between the 3 rd and the 5th year: 7 th year, I assume it happens in the UPB = 0.9710 * 85 = 82.5 UDIs outstanding Default amount = 82.5*1.56 = 128.75 UDIs Assume the house value depreciates by 2% per year (see Appendix 5.6). At the 5th year, the house value is 100*(1-5*2%) = 90 UDIs, if no depreciation. Suppose the house can be sold at 80% of that value. Then the recovery rate = 90*80%/128.75 = 56% - 121 - Peso Loans: Default rate scaling factors & Prepayment rate scaling factors Claim cost (% of UPB) 1.64 Recovery rate (average) on the original loan amount 87% Unpaid Balances + foreclosure-related expenses (24%) + interest for 2.3 years (17.5%*2.3» -- the average foreclosure time is 2.3 years. Suppose the original house value is 100 Pesos. Get a loan of 85% LTV, i.e., the loan amount is 85 Pesos. As the majority of defaults occur bIt the 3rd and 7th year, I assume it happens in the 5th year: UPB = 0.9844 * 85 = 83.67 Pesos outstanding Default amount = 83.67*1.64 = 137.22 Pesos Assume the house value appreciates by 10% per year (see Appendix 5.6). At the 5th year, the house value is 100*(1 +5*10%) = 150 Pesos, if no depreciation. Suppose the house can be sold at 80% of that value. Then the recovery rate = 150*80%/137.22 = 87% Both UDI and Peso loans are 25-year term, fixed rate (real vs. nominal) with an average LTV of 85%. They behave differently because: 1) the early stage monthly payment is different. Peso loans' payment burden is larger than UDI loans for the first 8 years; 2) there exists negative amortization in UDI loans but not in Peso loans. Risk profile of UDI vs Peso loans: a) UDI loans have a swap protection against inflation for borrowers; 2) initial payments in Peso loans are bigger than UDI loans -- initial years with high default probability; 3) If inflation shoots up again, fixed rate Peso loans will be repaid fast. Default scaling Weighted factor average VOl loans 0.99 0.9821 UOI loans Peso loans 1.2 0.0096 Peso loans Sum: 1.0000 Therefore I assume the following scaling factors: Yield curve for discounting future cash flows _Prepayment scaling factor 0.99 1.2 Sum: Weighted average 0.9821 0.0096 1.0000 Government Bond Yield Curve as of 2003 (Obtained from Bank of Mexico. (http://www.banxico.org.mx/siteBanxicoINGLES/elnfoFinancieralFSinfoFinanciera.html) 8.0 7.0 6.0 :!2 5.0 ~ 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Interpolated Yield Curve, 2003 .. ...-... " '" -: .. . ./ - , ~ r-- 0 (') MaturitY ~ ~ C\l C\l The yield curve slopes gently upward, indicating a stable economy LO C\l Source: Values in this table come from, or are based on, data provided by the SH F, interviews conducted by the author, and reference from the U.S. FHA experiences. C.3 Modeling results Cohort ultimate default and vrevayment rates and their annual distributions Based on the previous analysis (Table 5.19), I assume the 2003 cohort default rate falls within the range of 10% to 35%. The lower bound of 10% is based on the improving - 122 - performance of SHF-guaranteed cohorts. The SHF's own estimate of the cohort's ultimate default rate is around 22.8%. The annual distribution of the marginal (unconditional) default rate is modeled after the Erlang scale and shape parameters from the U.S. FHA cohorts with ultimate default rates over 10%, the "bad performance" group (b = 1.78, c = 4). The SHF made its own projection regarding to the default rate distribution, based on its limited loan performance data to-date (66 months of data) and the U.S. Freddie Mac portfolio experience.3 9 My projection of the cohort default rate distribution for the SHF is based on the U.S. FHA cohort experiences. I believe it is better than the projection based on the Freddie Mac data because: i) FHA serves lower-income and higher-risk borrowers while Freddie Mac's market segment is conforming loans. FHA borrowers' risk profile bears more similarities to that of SHF borrowers; ii) given the high ultimate default rate of the SHF cohort, a relatively wider default "peak window" (a curve with wider mid peak section) between the 2n d and the 8th year is more likely than the narrow peak zone under favorable economic conditions, as depicted by the projected curve based on Freddie Mac experience; and iii) my projection fits the actual data from SHF's 2003 cohort quite well (Figure 5.20). Figure 5.20 Projections of Annual Unconditional Default Rates of the SHF 2003 Cohort -- --- Estimated Distribution of Annual Unconditional Default Rate (Assume Ultimate Default Rate = 20.6%) --- SHF Experience andProjection --- My Projection ] 3.5% 3.0% - .. _PrjelonsJasednnI S -- ...-- Freddie Mac experience projections0based on 1.5%. 1.0% aj/~~~ ~~1.5% |U.S. .- 0.5% * FHA experience iMyprojections based on . 0.0% co) LO N_ 0) n Age c' L 0Loa Loan Age 39 The SHF's detailed forecasting model for future default rates based on Freddie Mac experience and models is considered confidential and thus not provided to the author. Its projected annual conditional default rates are graphed in Figure 5.20. - 123 - As discussed in the previous section, I assume the cohort ultimate prepayment rate to be around 45.30/0. Based on the Erlang distribution from the U.S. FHA cohorts (bad performance group, b = 2.21, c = 3), I project the SHF cohort's annual unconditional prepayment rates over the lifetime of the loan (Figure 5.21). Compared with SHF's actual prepayment rates for the past four years, my projection is biased upwards. This may be due to the fact that Mexico's mortgage market is still in its early development and borrowers are not sophisticated enough to exercise their "call option" (prepayment option) whenever it becomes in-the-money. The situation can change as the mortgage market matures in the future. Figure 5.21 Projections of Annual Unconditional Prepayment Rates of the SHF 2003 Cohort Estimated Prepayment Distribution of Annual Rate (Assume Ultimate Unconditional Prepayment Rate = 45.3%) -+- My * a: E Projection __ SHF Experience 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% Q) E >co ar 0: 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% M C\l Lt) C\l Discounted cash flow analysis For simplicity, I round up the numbers and assume that in 2003 SHF guaranteed 15 billion pesos, or 4.6 million UDls, of mortgage loans. Within the cohort, there are three types of loans: Prosavi, Profivi, and Peso loans. Prosavi and Profi vi loans are quite similar, both denoted in UDls, unsubsidized in their interest rates, with payments linked to the minimum wage and protected by the Swap fund.4o Hence, I group them together as UDI loans. They are designed for the volatile inflation environment. As Mexico's macro Borrowers pay in minimum wage terms, but the intermediary financier receives flow in UDI, and in the middle is the Swap offered by the SHF. The Swap fund works as follows: the SHF charges a premium of 71 basis points and uses that to create a fund so that if the minimum wage falls behind inflation, the fund will cover those losses. The pricing of the swap is designed such that it can sustain a fall of 25% of the minimum wage compared with inflation over a period of 30 years (Babaiz, 2004). 40 - 124 - economy stabilizes and inflation is put under control, the mortgage market will see the growth of the more traditional, fixed-rate long-term mortgages denoted in the local currency, Pesos. Even though Peso loans only made up about 0.80/0 of the 2003 cohort, they are expected to grow fast in the future. The SHF is taking great effort to promote Peso loans. For this analysis, I distinguish the cash flow calculations between 001 loans and Peso loans. Table 5.21 summarizes the NPVs and profitability rates under different default scenarios for UDI loans, Peso loans and the cohort as a whole. Figure 5.22 illustrates the relationship between the cohort ultimate default rate and the profitability rate. Appendix 5.7 presents details of the cash flow calculation. Table 5.21 NPVs and Profitability Rates of the SHF-Guaranteed Cohort Under Different Default Scenarios UDI Loans: 14,880 mil peso Ultimate default rate NPY (mil Peso) 10% 15% PESO Loans: 120 mil peso 677.1 Profitability rate 4.6% 509.9 3.4% 20% 342.6 2.3% 3.1 25% 175.4 1.2% 30% 8.2 0.1% 35% -159.0 -1.1% The Cohort: 15,000 mil peso NPY (mil Peso) Profitability rate NPY (mil Peso) 5.3 4.4% 682.4 4.2 3.5% 514.1 3.4% 2.6% 345.8 2.3% 2.1 1.7% 177.5 1.2% 1.0 0.8% 9.2 0.1% -0.1 -0.1% -159.2 -1.1% Profitability rate 4.5% Break-even default rates: 30.3% -1.86 -0.01% 0.91 0.76% -0.95 -0.01% 34.5% -142 -0.96% 0.00 0.00% -142 -0.96% 1.7% 2.5 2.1% 251.5 1.7% Expected 2003 cohort NPV: 248.9 22.8% Figure 5.22 Relationship Between Cohort Ultimate Default Rates and Profitability Rates Profitability I --+-- UDlloan Rate Under Various ----- Peso loan Default Rates -6-- Cohort aggregate I 5.0% ~ ~ 15 .!B 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% ~ 1.0% a: 0.0% -1.0% -2.0% Ultimate Default Rate - 125 - The analysis shows that at the current pricing level the cohort's NPV is estimated to be 252 million pesos, or 1.7 percent profitability rate, assuming the cohort default rate is 22.8 percent as projected by the SHF. The cohort as a whole can sustain a 30 percent cumulative default rate and just breaks even. In other words, the 2003 cohort could survive a recession or crisis almost as severe as that of 1995-97. The cohort profitability rate ranges from -1.1% to 4.5%, or NPV from -159 million to 682 million pesos of the 15 billion pesos cohort, assuming the cohort default rate falls within 10% to 35% sphere. In the cohort, SHF's guarantees on peso loans have a higher profitability rate than on UDI loans (Figure 5.22). The guarantee pricing level on peso loans has a break-even default rate of 34.5 percent, higher than that of UDI loans (30.3 percent). On the other hand, peso loans have higher risk than UDI loans because the UDI loan design protects borrowers from the possible mismatch of inflation and minimum wage adjustments. The swap coverage, provided by the SWAP fund, on UDI loans enables borrowers' payments only to increase in accordance with the minimum wage, despite the loan being stated in UDI that traces inflation. But peso loan payments are fixed every month in the nominal term. If there are unexpected or permanent drops in real terms in the minimum wage, UDI borrowers will not be adversely affected, as the shortfall in payments will be covered by the swap fund. Again, as Mexico's economic environment improves, the risk premium charged on peso loans may reduce. Sensitivity analysis of SHF liabilities in its mortgage guarantee business Over the most recent few years, the climate for housing finance in Mexico has improved and the government has determined to strengthen housing supply and affordability. As a newly established entity, the SHF has progressed in full speed rolling out a range of new products in mortgage guarantee, construction loan guarantee, and MBS on-time payment guarantee. Focused solely on its first-loss, partial mortgage guarantee products, this analysis identifies several factors that can influence SHF's potential liabilities significantly. - 126 - The foremost factor is the legal infrastructure and social recognition for foreclosure. There are still some states in Mexico where the process of foreclosure and eviction for collateral recovery purposes remains basically unachievable. Even for places where foreclosure is possible, it takes on average 27.6 months from payment delinquency to foreclosed property sale or auction. The accumulated delayed payments, interests, and other fees and insurances during the foreclosure process are substantial. In comparison, the average foreclosure time in a mature market like the U.S. FHA program is less than half of that length, about 12 months. As Mexico's mortgage finance market develops, home foreclosure and collateral recovery should become a practical and predictable process, which means cost-savings for the SHF's first-loss partial MI product. For instance, if the foreclosure process shortens to one year, the 2003 cohort's NPV will increase by 9%, from 252 million pesos to 275 pesos (Table 5.22). SHF's own operation and management are evolving rapidly, which has important implications on its liabilities as well. In analyzing the 2003 cohort, I assume that the SHF grants an advance claim payment in the sixth consecutive month that borrowers have been delinquent, which is equivalent to 25 percent of the amount owed by the defaulted borrower. Then the property will be foreclosed and sold/auctioned, and the actual claim amount (losses) is the difference between the value of the sale and the amount owed by the borrower plus administrative costs incurred. The SHF should only cover up to 25 percent of the updated gap, or actual losses incurred to the intermediary. If the advance granted by the SHF earlier was greater than the updated amount, the intermediary would have to reimburse the difference to the SHF. Starting from the 2004 cohort, the SHF changed the rules and decided to defer the point of its claim payment from the time at which a delinquent loan reaches six months in arrears to the time when the lender has secured a court foreclosure or other legally assured control of the collateral property. Though not preferred by lenders, this change improves SHF's MI program from both a risk management and operational standpoint, while at the same time giving lenders greater certainty and finality with regard to the claims proceeds they receive (Blood, WB report 2004). A simple analysis shows that if the claim payment time is shifted from the - 127 - sixth month in delinquency to the end of the 27th month when the foreclosure process completes, the cohort NPV will increase by 170/0 (Table 5.22). Another key parameter, the long-term projection of the baseline frequency of defaults (claims) over the lifetime of the cohort, was set to be 22.8 percent. It is quite high, both in terms of international experience - even in times of stress - and also a bit pessimistic reading of limited Mexican experience. Lenders' improved ability to foreclose and recover collateral property - which will influence future borrower behaviors - together with the continued strengthening of financial sector and the overall economy suggest that the ultimate default rate of SHF cohorts will trend down. Also, a larger percentage of defaulted loans could be "cured" by various risk mitigation methods that are currently being developed by the SHF rather than going to foreclosure. If the SHF's 2003 cohort default rate lowers to be similar to that of the FHA's average default rate over the past 30 years, 9.8%, its NPV will increase by 173% and its profitability rate will reach 4.6% (Table 5.22). Table 5.22 illustrates the NPV of the SHF's 2003 cohort under alternative parameter settings and future economic outlooks. The cohort size is set to be 15 billion pesos at origination. Table 5.22 The Sensitivity Analysis of Alternative Scenarios - The SHF Current the mean default rate of 22.8%) NPVI NPV cohort (mil Current parameter settings face Peso) value Premium structure Model (assumin Up-front premium rates: Annual premium rate: UOI loans Peso loans Foreclosure process Foreclosure process takes about 2 years on average. Timing of the claim payments In 2003' s cohort, the SHF pays claims in the sixth month of the borrower delinquency. Cohort default rate Mean default rate Scenarios New parameter settings If add an upfront premium - similar to the FHA premium structure: 0% 0.70% 0.83% Alternative 252 1.7% = 22.8% - 128 - Up-front premium rates: 1.5% Annual premium rate: UOI loans 0.50% Peso loans 0.50% If the process shortens to I-year NPV (mil $) 226 275 From 2004 onwards, SHF pays tclaims at the end of the 27th month when the foreclosure process completes 295 Mean default rate = 9.8% (The U.s. FHA experience) 689 4.6% 173% Housing market conditions Recovery rate on UDlloans Recovery rate on Peso loans Scenario I: Favorable (20% increase in housing prices) 56% 87% Recovery rate on 67% UDlloans Recovery rate on 105% Peso loans Scenario 2: Unfavorable (20% decrease in housing prices) Recovery rate on 45% UDlloans Recovery rate on 70% Peso loans If the future economic outlook is unfavorable: the yield curve of U.S. 1981 Treasury bills Interest rate environment - the Yield Curve Interpolated 328 2.2% 30% 176 1.2% -30% 133 0.9% -47% Yield Curve, 2003 Interpolated U.S. Treasury Yield 8.0 Curve 15 6.0 of 1981 15 '0 ~ 4.0 ~ 14 CD 14 2.0 >= 0.0 r-. 0 M 13 <0 Maturity .... 13 .... II) Ol The implied liabilities on the government by supporting SHF's mortgage guarantee programs will be constantly changing as the SHF progresses to establish freestanding financial credibility in the future marketplace, independent of the current full government backup. That backup is scheduled to stop by 2013. Meanwhile, the SHF is actively seeking private sector and international participation, even competition, in Mexico's mortgage credit enhancement business. Beyond its recent dialogue with many U.S. private mortgage insurers, with an initial eye toward early risk sharing through quota share reinsurance, the SHF has stated the intent to reorganize its credit guaranty activities under an insurance company charter, in contrast to the current development bank structure (Blood, 2004). All these future legislative, regulative, and structural changes of Mexico's mortgage market and the SHF itself will have important implications on its liabilities. V. Comparison of the Three Cases and Implications The simulations and analyses of the three public MI programs appearing above provide a framework for understanding the magnitude and volatility of implied liabilities imposed on the government to sponsor a public MI enterprise. The three programs are analyzed in - 129 - a comparable manner on their 2003 cohort's NPV distribution, multi-year NPV distribution, and potential losses in worst-case scenarios (Table 5.23). Table 5.23 Comparison of the Modeling Results for the Three MI Programs FHA WEW SHF* 9.2% 1.23% 22.8% 0.85% -0.22% 1.7% 13.1% 0.7% 30% 82 percentile 43 percentile 7.08% 0.55% 2003 Cohort Simulated (or projected) mean default rate Cohort profitability rate at mean default rate Break-even default rate Break-even default rate Break-even default rate percentile Multi-year Analysis 6-year accumulation - mean profitability rate (over one year's business volume) Break-even percentile of 6year accumulatiole 10-yearaccumulation - mean profitability rate (over one year's business volume) Break-even percentile of 10year accumulation 75 percentile 10.06% 1.67% 99 percentile 99 percentile 89 percentile 89 percentile Worst-Case Scenarios 6-year accumulation when resampling only from the "loss zone" - mean profitability rate -1.03% (over one year's business volume, annualized number) The worst experience so far, the recession of 1981-1983, were to happen again, the profitability rate (over one -0.7% year's business volume, annualized number) The high default rates during the 1995-1997financial crisis, for 3 consecutive years (over -1.07% one year's business volume, annualized number) *: There is not enough historical data to simulate the distribution of cohort ultimate default ratesfor Mexican SHF. Therefore many entries are blank. Now the questions raised at the beginning of this Chapter can be answered. First, can the public MI design and pricing cover expected risk exposure for a single cohort? At the mean cohort default rate, FHA and SHF's 2003 cohort will have a positive profitability 130 - rate of 0.85% and 1.7% respectively, indicating that both of them are expected to generate positive NPV (profit) from their MI contracts. FHA's single cohort profitability rate is quite close to zero, the break-even point, supporting the argument that public MI programs tend to have a smaller "buffer" zone against losses and are not profit maximizing. Mexico's SHF MI program has a higher cohort profitability rate of 1.7%, which can be due to the fact that as a newly established entity the SHF is trying to build up its capital reserves and make sure that its MI program is self-sufficient. It may also reflect the relatively higher risk and more volatile macro economic environment in Mexico. At the simulated mean default rate of 1.23%, the Dutch WEW-guaranteed cohort will have a negative profitability rate, or loss rate, of 0.22%. This means that if the distribution of WEW's cohort ultimate default rates, derived from the historical experience of the 1981-1994 books of business, is a good indication of the WEW's future cohort default rate patterns, then its current pricing level is insufficient to cover expected losses. However, as discussed earlier in Section B.3, the Erlang distribution of ultimate default rates based on only 14 data points can raise a lot of concerns over its validity of accurately estimating the mean cohort default rate for the future. Moreover, the 1981- 1994 cohorts were originated under the old municipal guarantee systems and later transferred to the WEW. So they may not be underwritten to the WEW's standards, which could have an implication on their lifetime default rates. For instance, if WEW's underwriting requirements are higher and stricter than those of the municipal guarantee systems, then the estimate of mean cohort default rate based on old books' performance is likely to be upward biased. Unfortunately, there are not enough seasoned cohorts originated under the WEW's regime (since 1995) at this point to conduct the distribution pattern analysis. Judging from the satisfactory, yet short, performance of the WEW's cohorts originated after 1995, we can conclude that if a cohort default rate varies between 0.1% and 0.2%, a reasonable guess based on WEW's recent cohorts' figures, it is estimated to generate a positive profitability rate around 0.2%, quite close to the breakeven point as well. - 131 - Secondly, what is the scale of potential liabilities over a longer time horizon? The analyses show that under normal conditions, on average both FHA and WEW programs are financially sound over the next six-year and ten-year period, generating positive profitability rates.4 1 Comparatively speaking, the WEW is exposed to greater potential risks than the FHA over a period of multiple years. For instance, the probability of net losses over a 6-year period is 25 percent under the WEW program (75 is the breakeven percentile), while it is only 3 percent under the FHA program (97 percentile breakeven). The breakeven percentiles for 6-year periods are lower than the 10-year percentiles for both FHA and WEW, indicating that there is a larger probability of incurring losses over 6 consecutive years than over 10 years. In particular, WEW's 10-year breakeven point is projected to be at the 89 percentile, versus its 6-year breakeven point of 75 percentile - a 14 percentage points difference - meaning that the probability of WEW's cohorts losing money in a 6-year period is estimated to be 14 percent higher than in a 10-year duration. These numbers indicate that the two programs' financial strength is stronger over the long term than the short term. This conclusion has important policy implications. If in the future there are one or several new books of business that are predicted to incur losses, it may not be necessary for policymakers to increase premium rates or take other immediate measures because the program can still be self-sufficient over the long term. On the other hand, policymakers should also be cautious about reducing premium rates if the program has experienced some good years, unless the probability of losses over the long term is truly small. The last question is that if the worst scenario happens, what is the implied capital outlay for the backing government (taxpayers) to bail out the program? In other words, can the program survive recession or catastrophic events, and for how long? The first layer of protection is the loss reserves of the public MI program. If the reserves are depleted, the remaining liabilities are to be borne by the government. Table 5.24 presents the comparison among three programs. For each program, the worst-case scenario is based on the most severe historical experience of that country's mortgage market. The analysis shows that the FHA and the WEW can survive the assumed worst-case scenarios without 41 There is not enough historical data to conduct multi-year analysis for the Mexico SHF program. - 132 - imposing additional liabilities on the backing governments. However, their levels of sustainability differ. The FHA can survive about 22 consecutive years of net losses as bad as its 1980s experience, while WEW can only be self-sufficient for less than 4 years. The SHF's current reserves can only sustain one cohort of high default rate as severe as the 1997 experience. If the crisis scenario were to persist for 3 consecutive years, the Mexican government would have to bear the extra liability of approximately 280 million pesos. Table 5.24 Sustainability of the Three Public MI Programs in the Worst Case Scenarios Loss reserves for its MI FHA (Billion $) WEW (Billion C) SHF (Billion Peso) 22.742 0.245 0.197* program, as of 2003 Insurance-in-force (IIF) Capital ratio (reserves/IIF) Worst-case scenario Potential losses Implied liabilities on the 42 435.7 24.3* 5.21% 9 consecutive years of 0.58% Similar to the recession 0.81% High default rate of 35% high default rates (>10%) of the 1980s - 3 for 3 years, similar to the as experienced between 1980-1988 consecutive years of high default rates situation of 1997 after the financial crisis 9.2 0.21 0.48 22 years42 3.5 years 1 year backing government Sustainable period if the worst-case situation were to persist * Here I only include mortgage loans (Prosavi and Profivi loans) guaranteed by the SHF's 1S'loss MI product. Of course, the program's ability to sustain economically stressful situations is closely related to its age. The longer the program has existed, the more likely it is able to build up loss reserves and survive economic downturns. 42 The FHA took a $7 billion hit to its insurance Funds in 2004 because it had over-valued the positive NPV of its existing books of business and therefore over-promised the Treasury of its cash inflows. If we take that into account, the FHA's capital reserves for its MI business was around $15.7 billion as of 2004, which would sustain the program for the worst case scenario for about 15 years. - 133 - Chapter 5 Appendices Appendix 5.1 Regression Analysis of FHA Cohort Prepayment Rates, 1975 - 2003 Origination Ultimate Default Year rate 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 4.50% 4.33% 4.01% 5.61% 9.54% Ultimate Prepayment rate 86.51% 86.73% 86.24% 84.78% 81.56% 77.32% 72.37% The model: Ultimate Prepayment Rate = a + b*Ultimate Default Rate 74.53% 78.63% 74.95% 77.48% Regression result: 14.86% 20.53% 19.09% 15.71% 19.36% 17.70% 13.36% 10.09% 10.88% 80.90% 83.41% 83.25% 85.10% 86.99% 88.12% 9.69% 8.43% 7.54% 6.75% 88.95% 6.39% 6.83% 89.86% 89.16% 87.74% 8.72% 8.63% 87.75% 7.94% 88.54% 89.07% 7.04% 6.78% 2000 7.43% 2001 2002 2003 5.81% Ultimate Prepayment Rate = 0.942 -1.004*Ultimate Default Rate 89.33% 90.68% 91.04% 87.48% 80.63% 6.74% 8.62% - Regression output: Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.8994045 R Square 0.8089285 Adjusted R Square 0.8018518 Standard Error 0.0235789 Observations 29 ANOVA df SS Regression MS 1 0.063551 0.063551 Residual 27 0.015011 0.000556 Total 28 0.078562 Coefficients Standard Error Intercept X Variable 1 t Stat F 114.3084 P-value SignificanceF 3.3186E-11 Lower 95% Upper 95% 0.9424341 0.010151 92.84054 2.29E-35 0.921605761 0.96326243 -1.0036671 0.093875 -10.6915 3.32E-11 -1.196282923 -0.81105134 - 134- Appendix 5.2 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the U.S. FHA Program FHA 30-year fixed rate mortgages - Cash flow analysis for Cohort 2003 Assume a cohort of $50,000,000,000 (50 billion) 30-year fixed rate FHA-guaranteed Within this cohort, there are the following 8 types: 65<LTV <=80 80 < LTV <= 90 90 < LTV <= 95 95 < LTV <= 97 loans. 97<LTV Streamline refinance ARM (all LTV) Investor Basic Loan Amortization Factors * Year * loan age at midyear (months) 6 2 3 4 5 6 30 18 30 42 54 66 354 * loan balances, BOY 1.000 0.9886 0.9764 0.9634 0.9495 0.9348 0.0723 * loan balances, mid year 0.9944 0.9826 0.9700 0.9565 0.9422 0.9270 0.0367 * loan balances, EOY 0.9886 0.9764 0.9634 0.9495 0.9348 0.9190 0.0000 Unconditional rates Default and Prepayment Rates for Cohort: scaled by ultimate Annual unconditional Default rate 0.0026 0.0061 0.0082 0.0086 0.0080 0.0068 0.0000 Annual unconditional Prepay rate 0.0697 0.1000 0.1076 0.1030 0.0923 0.0795 0.0001 Cash Flow Analysis: Cash Flows Commitments (loan amount, face value) (+) Upfront premiums received Annual premiums Other inflows Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year 6 Year 30 1600 24 7.68747 (+) 6.84202 5.8346 4.8286 3.90867 3.111 0 0 (+) 2.6927 Default payments (-) Recoveries on defaults Year 1 by loan product 6.3076 8.3038 8.6289 7.8724 6.6113 0.0000 1.83102 4.28919 5.6466 5.86767 5.3532 9.28E-05 1.68678 1.24041 0.64998 0.22964 0.00143 0.00338 0.0045 0.00474 0.00439 0.0037 3.27E-07 0.07671 0.11005 0.11841 0.11325 0.10155 0.0874 0.000151 0.00143 0.00481 0.00931 0.01405 0.01845 0.0222 0.033539 0.07671 0.18675 0.30516 0.41841 0.51996 0.6074 0.959542 0.92187 0.80844 0.68553 0.56753 0.4616 0.007069 0.006919 (+) 1.556 Premium refunds (-) 0 0 0 Other outflows (-) Loan Performance Unconditional default rate Unconditional prepayment rate Cumulative default rate Cumulative prepayment rate 1 BOY survival rate EOY survival rate 0.92187 0.80844 0.68553 0.56753 0.46159 0.3704 Conditional default rate 0.00143 0.00367 0.00557 0.00692 0.00774 0.0081 4.62E-05 Conditional prepayment 0.07671 0.11937 0.14647 0.1652 0.17893 0.1894 0.021298 Mid-year payers rate of annual premium 0.96093 0.86515 0.74698 0.62653 0.51456 0.416 0.006994 30-year CUM. DEF. RATE 0.03354 30-year CUM. PREPAY. RATE 0.95954 rate Note: The same cash flow components were analyzed for the rest types of loan products by L TV categories. cumulative cash flows were obtained by aggregating all loan types. - 135 - Then the Appendix 5.3 Regression Analysis of FHA Multi-Year Cohort Default Rates, 1975 2003 Projected 30-year Origination Year I-yr T yr Treasury bond rate Default rate default rate - 4.50% 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 4.33% 4.01% 5.61% 9.54% 14.86% 20.53% 19.09% 15.71% 19.36% 17.70% 13.36% 10.09% 10.88% 9.69% 8.43% 7.54% 6.75% 6.39% 6.83% 8.72% 8.63% 7.94% 7.04% 6.78% 7.43% 2000 2001 2002 2003 5.81% 6.74% 8.62% 4.50% 4.33% 4.01% 5.61% 9.54% 14.86% 20.53% 19.09% 15.71% 19.36% 17.70% 13.36% 10.09% 10.88% 9.69% 8.43% 7.54% 6.75% 6.78% 5.88% 6.08% 8.34% 10.65% 12.00% 14.80% 12.27% 9.58% 10.91% 8.42% 6.45% 6.77% 7.65% 8.53% 7.89% 5.86% 3.89% 3.43% 6.39% 6.83% 5.32% 5.94% 8.72% 8.63% 5.52% 5.63% 7.94% 7.04% 6.78% 7.43% 5.81% 5.05% 5.08% 6.11% 3.49% 2.00% 6.74% 1.24% The model: Cohort ultimate default rate (,)=a + b* Cohort ultimate default rate (,4~ + c* -year Treasury bond rate Regression result: Cohort ultimate default rate ,) = -0.005 + 0.635* Cohort ultimate default rate (,4o + 0.605* I-year Treasury bond rate Regression output: Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.93679173 R Square 0.87757875 Adjusted R Square 0.86778505 Standard Error 0.01716896 Observations 28 ANOVA df Regression Residual Total 2 25 27 SS 0.052827 0.007369 0.060196 Coefficients Standard Error Intercept X Variable 1 X Variable 2 -0.00486747 0.63530555 0.60468706 MS 0.026414 0.000295 t Stat F Significance F 89.60646 3.965E-12 P-value 0.008587 -0.56685 0.575872 0.082363 0.125931 7.713491 4.801718 4.54E-08 6.23E-05 - 136 - Lower 95% -0.0225525 0.4656761 0.3453267 Upper 95% 0.012818 0.804935 0.864047 Appendix 5.4 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the Dutch WEW Program WEW-guaranteed Mortgage Cashflows analysis for Cohort 2003 Assume a cohort of Euro 10,000,000,000 (10 billion) WEW-guaranteed loans. Within thiscohort,there are the following5 types of LTV loans --Iassume thatLTV isthe most important factorimpacting defaultrates. Other factorsinclude:the eriodof interestratefixing;mortgage types. LTV <=80 0< LTV <= 90 0< LTV <= 100 100 < LTV <= 110 LTV>110 Basic Loan Amortization Factors * Year * loan age at midyear (months) 6 30 42 54 * loan balances, BOY 1.000 0.9860 0.9713 0.9558 0.9394 0.9221 0.0648 * loan balances, mid year 0.9931 0.9788 0.9636 0.9477 0.9309 0.9131 0.0328 * loan balances, EOY 0.9860 0.9713 0.9558 0.9394 0.9221 0.9039 0.0000 Annual unconditionalDefaultrate Annual unconditionalPrepay rate 2 18 3 4 Unconditional Default and Prepayment ultimate rates 0.0001 0.0018 0.0031 0.0025 0.0028 0.0082 0.0139 0.0184 5 6 66 30 354 Rates for Cohort: scaled by 0.0014 0.0215 0.0006 0.0232 0.0000 0.0005 Cash Flow Analysis: by loan product Cash Flows Commitments (loanamount, face value) Upfront premiums received (+) Other inflows(+) Defaultpayments (-) Recoveries on defaults(+) Recoveries through recourse (periodpmt) Recoveries through recourse:cumulative (+) Loan Performance Unconditionaldefaultrate Unconditionalprepayment rate Cumulative defaultrate Cumulative prepayment rate BOY survivalrate EOY survivalrate Conditionaldefaultrate Conditionalprepayment rate Mid-year payers rateof annual premium 30-year CUM. DEF. RATE 30-year CUM. PREPAY. RATE Year 1 Year 2 876.7319 2.6302 0 0.0791 0.00063 7.78E-05 0.00358 7.78E-05 0.00358 1 0.9963 7.78E-05 0.00358 0.99817 0.00547 0.38729 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year 6 Year 30 1.0070 1.6630 1.3533 0.7468 0.3222 0.04336 0.55184 0.91134 0.7416 0.40925 0.00806 0.01330 0.01083 0.00597 0.00258 0.00063 0.00869 0.02199 0.03282 0.03879 0.0000 2.24E-17 3.02E-20 9.18E-16 0.001 0.01071 0.00108 0.0143 0.99634 0.98462 0.00101 0.01075 0.99048 5.73E-20 0.000703 0.005469 0.387289 0.607945 0.607241 9.43E-20 0.001157 0.607593 0.00168 0.01802 0.00277 0.03232 0.98462 0.96492 0.00171 0.01831 0.97477 0.00139 0.02396 0.00416 0.05628 0.96492 0.93956 0.00144 0.02483 0.95224 0.00078 0.02799 0.00494 0.08427 0.93956 0.91079 0.00083 0.02979 0.92518 0.00034 0.03014 0.00528 0.11441 0.91079 0.8803 0.00038 0.03309 0.89554 Note: The same cash flow components were analyzed for the rest types of loan products, firstby the interest rate-fixation period, then by L TV categories. Then the cumulative cash flows were obtained by aggregating allloan types. - 137 - Appendix 5.5 Regression Analysis of WEW Multi-Year Cohort Default Rates, 1981 - 1999 Origination Projected Year 30-year default rate Default rate 1-yr (t- 1) Euribor rate 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 default rate 2.874% 2.474% 2.552% 0.850% 0.875% 0.429% 0.303% 2.874% 2.474% 2.552% 0.850% 0.875% 0.429% 10.69% 11.59% 8.37% 5.65% 6.13% 6.36% 5.68% 1988 0.306% 0.303% 5.36% 1989 0.227% 0.306% 4.82% 1990 0.212% 0.227% 7.39% 1991 1992 1993 0.201% 0.123% 0.134% 0.212% 0.201% 0.123% 8.68% 9.28% 9.35% 1994 1995 1996 0.093% 0.049% 0.097% 0.134% 0.093% 0.049% 6.82% 5.17% 4.37% 1997 0.090% 0.097% 3.00% 1998 0.077% 0.090% 3.34% 1999 0.131% 0.077% 3.45% The model: Cohort ultimate default rate (, = a + b* Cohort ultimate default rate (,u+ c* short-term interest rate Regression result: Cohort ultimate default rate (,)= -0.003 + 0.678* Cohort ultimate default rate (,) + 0. 050* short-term interest rate Regression output: Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.913333 R Square 0.834176 Adjusted R Square 0.812067 Standard Error 0.003323 Observations 18 ANOVA df 2 SS 0.000833 MS 0.000417 Residual 15 0.000166 1.1E-05 Total 17 0.000999 Regression Intercept def (t-l) Interest rate Coefficients Standard Error -0.00259 0.002373 0.678413 0.09683 0.050297 0.038648 t Stat -1.09281 7.006237 1.301399 - 138- F Significance F 37.7288 1.40393E-06 P-value 0.291716 4.24E-06 0.212756 Lower 95% Upper 95% -0.00765243 0.00246509 0.472024886 0.88480107 -0.03208014 0.13267402 Appendix 5.6 Explanations of Some Parameters Used in the Cash Flow Analysis of the SHF Mortgage Guarantee 1. SHF Mortgage Products for Individual Home Purchase Product Price limit in UDI Price limit in Peso Down payment Subsidy Payment adjusted Prosavi 45,000 $140,400 2.5% With MW Profivi 250,000 350,000 500,000 $ 780,000 $ 1,092,000 $ 1,560,000 10% 15% 20% Up to 25,000 UDI No No No No I Peso With MW With MW With MW No Initial monthly payment (Peso/1000) $15.4 $12-13 $12-14 $12-15 Source: Mexican Housing Overview, 2003 (by Softec) 2. House Value Appreciation/Depreciation Rates Derived from Historical Housing Price Changes in Mexico Housing Price Appreciation after the Crisis Average unit price per m2 in UDIs, 1997-2002 Home prices ('000) 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Annual appreciation Social 1,229 1,180 1,101 1,206 1,141 1,054 -2.85% Economic 1,396 1,322 1,273 1,449 1,285 1,270 -1.81% Middle 1,734 1,898 1,761 1,887 1,758 1,820 0.99% 1998 1999 Home prices ('000) 1997 Social 2,243 2,489 2,815 Economic 2,548 2,788 3,257 Middle 3,164 4,003 4,504 Source: Mexican Housing Overview, 2003 (by Softec) 2000 3,084 3,706 4,827 2001 3,423 3,854 5,273 2002 3,320 4,000 5,733 Average unit price per m2 in Pesos, 1997-2002 Annual - 139- appreciation 9.60% 11.40% 16.24% Appendix 5.7 Components of the Cash Flow Analysis for the Mexican SHF Program SHF-guaranteed Mortgage Cashflows analysis for Cohort 2003 Assume a cohort of Peso $15,000,000,000 * (15 billion) SHF-guaranteed Cohort face value ($) loans. 15000 million Pesos 4585 million UDls, using the mid-year (2003) UDI-Peso rate. Or Within this cohort, there are the following 2 types of loans -- UDls and Pesos (assuming average LTV of 85%). Scenario 1 - with tile UDI-MW swaR fund: sUp'P.Qse25-~ar fixed rate of lTV 85% UDI: Basic Loan Amortization Factors - All units are in UDI * Year 1 2 3 4 * loan age at midyear (months) 6 18 30 42 * loan balances, BOY 1.000 0.9950 0.9892 0.9827 0.9751 0.9665 0.1317 * loan balances, mid year 0.9976 0.9922 0.9861 0.9790 0.9710 0.9617 0.0681 * loan balances, EOY 0.9950 0.9892 0.9827 0.9751 0.9665 0.9566 0.0000 3.2554 3.3531 3.4574 3.5475 3.6216 3.6920 0.0000 * 1 UDlloan balance, EOY -- in Pesos! (from 03) Loan size 1 UDI, 3.2718 Pesos = Peso Basic Loan Amortization 5 54 6 25 66 294 Factors - All units are in PESO * Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 25 * loan age at midyear (months) 6 18 30 42 54 66 294 * loan balances, BOY 1.000 0.9975 0.9945 0.9910 0.9868 0.9818 0.1616 * loan balances, mid year 0.9988 0.9961 0.9928 0.9890 0.9844 0.9789 0.0843 * loan balances, EOY 0.9975 0.9945 0.9910 0.9868 0.9818 0.9758 0.0000 3.2636 3.2539 3.2423 3.2286 3.2122 3.1927 0.0000 * 1 UDlloan balance, EOY -- in Pesos! (from 03) Loan size 1 UDI, 3.2718 Pesos = Unconditional Default and Prepayment ultimate rates Rates for Cohort: scaled by Annual unconditional Default rate 0.0009 0.0043 0.0083 0.0112 0.0125 0.0123 0.0000 Annual unconditional Prepay rate 0.0133 0.0340 0.0486 0.0549 0.0546 0.0500 0.0002 Cash Flow Analysis: by loan product IUDI Loans - First all comDutina in UDls J Cash Flows Commitments (Joan amount, face value) Upfront premiums received (+) Annual premiums (+) Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year 6 30.6278 28.9673 26.8687 24.6142 22.4245 1.8999 77.5158 85.6624 83.6535 0.0191 Year 25 4547.955 0.0000 31.6104 Other inflows (+) 0.0000 Default amount SHF's claim payment (-) - pay at the 6th month 6.6490 30.1774 57.7374 1.6623 7.5444 14.4344 19.3790 21.4156 20.9134 0.0048 Recoveries on defaults 2.9921 13.5798 25.9818 34.8821 0.0542 The "Real" amount of loss 3.6570 16.5976 31.7556 42.6337 0.0662 The "correct" amount SHF should pay 0.9142 4.1494 7.9389 10.6584 0.0166 Refund to SHF (+) 0.7480 3.3950 6.4955 8.7205 0.0135 Other outflows (-) 0 Loan Performance - 140- 2.0417E-05 Unconditional default rate 0.0009 0.0043 0.0082 0.0111 0.0124 0.0122 Unconditional prepayment rate 0.0132 0.0336 0.0481 0.0544 0.0541 0.0495 .. 1.5870E-04 Cumulative default rate 0.0009 0.0052 0.0134 0.0246 0.0369 0.0491 . 9.8977E-02 Cumulative prepayment rate 0.0132 0.0468 0.0949 0.1493 0.2034 0.2529 . 4.4805E-01 BOY survival rate 1.0000 0.9858 0.9480 0.8916 0.8261 0.7597 ... 4.5315E-01 . 4.5297E-01 ... EOY survival rate 0.9858 0.9480 0.8916 0.8261 0.7597 0.6979 Conditional default rate 0.0009 0.0043 0.0087 0.0125 0.0150 0.0161 Conditional prepayment rate 0.0132 0.0341 0.0508 0.0610 0.0654 0.0652 .. 3.5021 E-04 Mid-year payers rate of annual premium 0.9929 0.9669 0.9198 0.8589 0.7929 0.7288 ... 4.5306E-01 30-year CUM. DEF. RATE 0 30-year CUM. PREPAY. RATE 0 4.5054E-05 Convert UDI payments to Pesos Commitments (loan amount, face value) Upfront premiums received (+) Annual premiums (+) 14880 0 103.423 Other inflows (+) 0.0000 SHF's initial claim payment (-) 5.4386 103.816 101.918 97.7487 12.8584 25.572 50.7857 70.5009 80.2476 80.7166 ·. 2.6318 12.3509 24.3395 33.6575 ·* Refund to SHF (+) Other outflows (-) 92.2334 86.5489 0.0323 -0.0917 0 Note: The same cash flow components were analyzed for Peso loans. Then the cumulative cash flows were obtained by aggregating both UDI and Peso loan types. - 141 - - 142 - Chapter 6 Potential Economic Problems Resulting from the Establishment of Public MI I. Potential Economic Problems All housing subsidies distort markets to some degree. Because of this, subsidy programs, particularly in developing countries and emerging economies, should be designed thoughtfully to avoid the unhealthy development of housing finance, housing development, and land markets (Hoek-Smit and Diamond, 2003). Public MI, usually considered as a supply-side government intervention, can create new market inefficiencies, undermining the benefits it brings through increased homeownership and credit enhancement for the secondary mortgage markets. Essentially these new inefficiencies result from the change of behaviors of the participating lenders and/or borrowers, and the role of the private sector in the presence of a public MI system. The major potential economic problems include: adverse selection and moral hazard by lenders, non-optimal risk-taking by borrowers and sub-optimal risk allocation in the society as a whole, and the constraint of participation and downward expansion of the private MI sector. A. Adverse Selection Adverse selection occurs when the insurer bases its premiums on the average risk of a sample of participants in which the higher-risk participants are under-represented. This results in a higher average risk level than what was estimated by the insurer. Adverse selection is the result of asymmetric information: the insured (lender) in the insurance contract has information that is not available to the insurer. This situation occurs mostly in voluntary insurance programs that have large pools of potential customers with differing levels of risk (Follain and Szymanoski, 1995). Mortgage insurance is susceptible to adverse selection, especially the public MI backed by the government and targeting lower income households. For example, in the U.S., some mortgage lenders will keep the high LTV loans with good borrower's credit rating (hence lower risks) in their - 143 - own portfolio by offering the borrower an 80-10-10 loan4 3 (a form of lender's self- insurance), while requiring those low-credit quality borrowers to obtain private MI or FHA insurance. Insurers in life and health insurance markets deal with this problem by gathering information about those being insured in order to reduce the information gap. Similarly, private mortgage insurers also gather a lot of information through the insurance underwriting process in order to learn about loan applicants and to rate more accurately the risk of the loan. For public MI, the situation is different from private companies. In developed countries, public MI often facilitates higher-risk (lower-income or lower-credit quality) populations to become homeowners. Without a public MI, those borrowers are rationed out of the housing finance market. In emerging markets, there are usually no private MI companies and major lenders only serve the upper end of the market (high-income populations), leaving a large proportion of the population without formal financing approaches. Public MI is used as a tool to provide access to formal financing for the majority of the households. Therefore, for both developed and developing countries, if a public MI program understands its expected insurance population and bases its insurance premium on the average risk of this particular group of borrowers instead of on the average risk of the whole spectrum of mortgage borrowers, the problem of adverse selection will not impose unexpected threats. B. Moral Hazard In the context of mortgage insurance, moral hazard arises if the behavior of the insured is riskier with insurance than without it. Critics argue that the knowledge that mortgage insurers' coverage of losses will be made available in the event of loan defaults makes defaults more likely to occur. Follain and Szymanoski (1995) argue that moral hazard problems can result from the provision of MI in one of two ways. The first involves the behavior of the borrower. The borrower pays the cost of MI, either as an explicit mortgage insurance premium or as an implicit amount embedded in the interest rate of the mortgage. Once the loan is made, the default insurance has the effect of giving the borrower a "put option" with which he or she may force a "sale" of the property to the 43 The "80-10-10" loan means that the borrower obtains a mortgage for 80% of the purchase price (LTV of 80%), puts 10% down and borrows the remaining 10%. That second loan is called a "piggy back loan." - 144 - lender at a price equal to the unpaid balance of the mortgage. In situations in which the borrower has negative equity in the house, it creates moral hazard incentives. The second type of moral hazard involves the behavior of financial intermediaries, such as insured lenders. With MI coverage, lenders may become less responsible when underwriting financially sound loans as they can earn substantial upfront fees from mortgage originations. Also, they may not monitor the performance of the insured loans as closely as they would have without the MI. Public MI programs with 100 percent coverage are more prone to experiencing moral hazard problems than their private counterparts that usually only provide partial coverage of losses. However, some public MI programs have the right of recourse to defaulted borrowers (like the WEW in the Netherlands), which decreases the risk of moral hazard substantially. C. Non-optimal Risk Taking and Risk Allocation Although public MI enables relatively low-income people to enter homeownership earlier, in particular to overcome the barrier of downpayments, a balance needs to be struck between the positive externalities from increased homeownership and the negative effects of expanding the envelope too far. Some criteria must not be compromised (such as a minimum income-to-payment ratio), in order to maintain a sustainable homeownership in the long term for the low-income households. Public MI should not be considered a subsidy. Therefore it should help households with the timing of entering homeownership (earlier than later), but not the underlying ability of affording monthly mortgage payments, which may be addressed with other types of housing subsidies. Entering homeownership and affording it are two different things and thus need to be distinguished. Otherwise a public MI system may unintendedly encourage some borrowers to consume much more housing than they can reasonably afford and therefore take more housing risk, which in turn can result in a sub-optimal risk allocation for the society as a whole. For example, within the U.S. FHA program, high LTV borrowers (9597%) have much higher default rates than relatively low LTV borrowers (80-95%). On the one hand, this fact may simply exhibit people's rational behavior of exercising their default options, as high LTV borrowers have less equity in the house than low LTV borrowers. When housing prices fluctuate (decline), high LTV borrowers' option - 145 - becomes "in-the-money" faster than that of low LTV borrowers. On the other hand, it indicates the financial vulnerability of high LTV borrowers and raises the question of whether their risk-taking level in housing consumption is optimal for themselves and for the society as a whole. Unnecessarily high levels of default and foreclosure create deadweight losses to the society due to legal fees and the costly foreclosure process, impairment to borrowers' credit history, and the destabilizing impacts on certain low- income communities with concentrated public MI-insured properties. These deadweight losses should be carefully weighed against the potential social benefits from increased homeownership and better credit enhancement in the marketplace, in order to see whether public MI, as a housing policy, is cost-efficient. Constraining Participation and Development of the Private Sector D. The presence of a public MI entity may create distortion in the marketplace by influencing the participation and development of private housing finance players and limiting the downward expansion of the private sector. In the U.S., the FHA avoids crowding out private sector MI providers by setting its loan ceiling for single-family mortgages to 261,609 dollars in high-cost areas and 144,336 dollars in lower-cost areas in 2003. But there is still considerable overlap between the FHA and private MI providers in the lower end of the mortgage market. However, this does not seem to adversely impact the private MIs as their market share has been increasing over the recent years.4 4 In the Netherlands, the WEW is the sole MI provider. Its loan ceiling of 230,000 euro in 2003 44 The market shares of FHA, VA, and Private MIs are as follows: a. Number of Insured Mortgage Originations in the U.S., 1998-2002 VA44 Private Private MI as a % insured 2002 2001 2000 1,246,561 1,062,867 783,990 FHA 328,502 281,510 186,695 2,305,709 2,035,546 1,236,214 59.41% 60.22% 56.02% 1999 1,138,086 441,642 1,455,354 47.95% 1998 1,110,530 384,601 1,473,344 49.63% b. Dollar Volume of Insured Mortgage Originations ($ in millions), 1998-2002 2002 2001 2000 FHA VA Private Private MI as a % insured 145,053 131,240 78,669 41,945 35,443 22,208 337,053 282,506 163,136 64.32% 62.89% 61.79% 1999 108,106 49,580 188,871 54.50% 1998 103,165 42,584 187,437 56.26% Source: MICA Fact Book 2003-2004 - 146 - covers about 50 percent of the mortgage market. The absence of private MIs may reflect the lack of demand for mortgage insurance, as homeownership has not been a favored choice for lower income families and the credit enhancement for MBS is currently done through structured finance. It may also reflect the fact that lenders prefer to self-insure mortgage loans implicitly because of the historically satisfactory loan performance (low default rates) and therefore the perception of low risks in insuring them. In addition, the very low insurance premium charged by the WEW is likely to make the private sector unviable in the lower-end of the market. The WEW is pushing to increase its loan limit, which would further expand its market reach. In Mexico, currently the SHF's MI loan ceiling accommodates about 75 percent of all the mortgages. No private MIs ever existed. In contrast to the Dutch situation, the SHF is actively creating the necessary environment for the private sector to enter, with the vision of ultimately becoming a reinsurer for private MIs. E. Abuse of Public MI for Political Reasons The biggest potential problem of public MI is the abuse of the program to suit changing political agendas. If the risk management or financial soundness of public MI is compromised, the hidden costs of the program can impose huge inefficiency on the housing finance system as a whole and create unnecessary market fluctuations. A classical example is during the 1950s and 1960s, when the FHA program took on a wide range of narrowly targeted programs to support piecemeal housing policies generated by a hyperactive political process. When urban blight became an issue and urban renewal was seen as the answer, the FHA was to facilitate both relocation of residents and resettlement of new residents. Consequently, special programs for cooperatives, condominiums, nursing homes, and home improvement were added to FHA's portfolio (Pennington-Cross and Yezer, 2000). The short-term fiscal soundness of the FHA's insurance fund led to the perception that it could support virtually any aspect of housing policy. That situation did not last long, and the large number of economically unsound mortgages insured and resulting losses caused a quick retreat in high-risk insurance activities in the 1970s. The FHA was criticized as producing negative as well as positive neighborhood externalities. The lesson to be learned is that the clear objectives and - 147 - principles of public MI, especially its financial independence, have to be maintained at all times. II. Addressing Potential Economic Problems - Case Studies The three public MI programs considered have addressed some of the potential economic issues while perhaps remaining susceptible to other problems. A comparison of the three models in their institutional structure and operational strategies provides valuable insights and recommendations for other countries. A. The U.S. FHA Program MaintainFHA's financialsoundnessundervariouspoliticalenvironments The U.S. FHA program lies within the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) (Figure 6.1). Because it is directly operated by HUD, FHA has sacrificed some operational efficiency. The FHA budget must be approved by Congress each year; therefore appropriations, policy changes and new product development requires approvals that would not be required by the private sector. Figure 6.1 The Institutional Structure of the FHA As part of a government agency, the FHA is inevitably influenced by the changing housing policies as previously discussed. Its insurance funds (capital reserves) fluctuated greatly because of the shifts of political emphases in housing policy throughout the 1950s to the 1980s. Worsened by the 1980s' recession, the capitalization of the FHA insurance fund caused serious concerns and led the U.S. Congress to pass two landmark pieces of legislation in 1990: the National Affordable Housing Act (NAHA) and the Federal Credit - 148- Reform Act (FCRA). These two laws have a significant impact on how the FHA measures its books of business and maintains its financial soundness. Before the Credit Reform Act, the FHA recorded its business activities on a cash-flow basis and was reflected in the U.S. Government Budget in its cash-based, current-year net income. After Credit Reform, the FHA is required to project the lifetime net present value (NPV) of each year's new book of business (cohort), prior to insuring any loan in a given fiscal year. Currently, only the FHA's multifamily insurance business may have cohorts with projected negative NPVs (meaning the government subsidies the insurance beyond the premiums paid by borrowers). All basic single-family insurance cohorts, excluding the special programs' higher risk cohorts, must be self-supporting and generate positive NPVs (creating an inflow of funds to the government). When positive NPVs are expected, the additional premiums are transferred by the FHA to the U.S. Treasury as the FHA reserves. In the case of projected negative NPVs, the funds are transferred from the U.S. Treasury to the FHA. Also, before Credit Reform there was no limit on how much the FHA could borrow from the Treasury. If the FHA did not have enough money to pay claims, the Treasury would cover the losses because the FHA program was backed by the full faith and credit of the U.S. government. The Credit Reform Act established the rule of "pay as you go," which means that the FHA loan guarantees must be fully funded at the time they are endorsed. Now, the bulk of the FHA's business - the single-family mortgage insurance - must be self-supporting. If the FHA was to run out of money to pay claims, Congress will need to appropriate the money and then give FHA the authority to borrow it from the Treasury. The National Affordable Housing Act (NAHA) set the capital requirements for the FHA's MMI fund, and requires it to maintain a capital ratio of at least 2 percent.45 This capital ratio is expected to be sufficient to withstand unexpected losses without exposing 45 This capital ratio is calculated as: Economic net worth of the MMI Fund Unamortized insurance-in-force "Economic net worth" means the current cash available to the MMI Fund, plus the net present value of all future cash inflows and outflows expected to result from the outstanding mortgages in the MMI Fund. - 149 - the taxpayers to financial risk. For each fiscal year, an independent audit and actuarial review is mandated by Congress to check the MMI fund's soundness. This legislation aims to avoid the abuse of the government MI products because of changes in political environment. It has been effective since the 1990s to keep the FHA's capital reserves at a comfortable level.46 However, it is not flawless. The projection of NPVs over the lifetime of a cohort at its endorsement often proves far off the actual performance and therefore adjustments to the projection and the resulting budget / appropriation have to be made annually. Transfers between the Treasury and the FHA add a lot of operational complication and inefficiency to the system. Controladverseselectionand moral hazard One of the most distinctive features of the U.S. secondary mortgage markets is the virtual mandate by GSEs that all home loans over 80 percent LTV be insured. This mandate serves to restrain adverse selection of risk by lenders and assure a large and growing volume of new insurance. Then there is the choice between private MI providers and the FHA. Since the FHA targets low-incomers and minority households, and these populations are usually shunned by the private MIs for their high risks, adverse selection does not appear to be an unexpected problem. FHA's insurance premium pricing is slightly higher than that of a private MI company. But this will not result in "even worse adverse selection" as argued in the literature47 because many of the targeted borrowers have no access to mortgage loans without the public MI. There is simply no other choice for them. However, in good economics times, some high-LTV borrowers with slightly better credit quality may be able to get private MI-insured or lender self-insured loans, which could hurt the FHA's performance. As analyzed earlier in Chapter 5, if all borrowers with LTV lower than 95 percent leave the FHA, the program's single cohort's profitability rate will decrease by 11%. 46 At the end of FY2003, the MMI Fund's capital ratio was estimated at 5.21 percent, well above the 2 percent minimum requirement. 47 Literature on adverse selection argues that the insurer may not be able to correct the adverse selection problem by merely raising premiums for everyone, because the higher premiums may cause lower-risk individuals to leave for other choices, leaving only the higher-risk individuals in its portfolio and further raising the average risk of the participating group. - 150- Moral hazard proves to be a real concern. It can manifest itself in several ways such as in the increase in cohort default rates or the decrease in recovery rates of the defaulted properties due to the lack of responsibility of the insured lenders and/or borrowers. The impact is substantial. For instance, if the FHA's 2003 cohort's ultimate default rate increases by 20%, from 9.2% (the estimated mean default rate) to 11%, the NPV of the insurance contracts will decease by 48.5%, or by 207 million dollars on the 50 billion dollars cohort face value. If the recovery rate of defaulted properties decreases by 20%, from currently assumed 68% to 54.4%, the cohort's insurance NPV will decrease by 130%, resulting in losses of 121 million dollars. Moral hazard is managed by the FHA through a variety of techniques and operational strategies. The first method of preventing moral hazard is the screening and approval process of the participating lenders prior to their involvement in the insurance program. There are approximately 12,000 approved lenders (mortgagees) for the FHA programs. The approval depends mainly on the mortgagee's financial strength and past performance. A mortgagee must have had an acceptable claim and default record for at least 2 years prior to its application for participation in the FHA Lender Insurance Program.4 8 When a lender applies for FHA, he needs to submit his financial documents, photos of facilities, and some fees. On-site inspections are conducted at selected lenders' shops to verify their financial strength. The second strategy to reduce moral hazard is post approval lender monitoring, inspection, and recertification. The FHA set up an institutional and informational structure to hold lenders responsible even though the full coverage of losses is available through its MI provision when borrowers default. FHA monitors lenders through its office of lender activities and program compliance in the HUD headquarters, 4 homeownership centers (HOCs), and about 140 monitors stationed in the field throughout The acceptable claim and default record is determined by HUD. Right now they are as follows: (1) A mortgagee is eligible for the Lender Insurance program if its claim and default rate is at or below 150 percent of the national average rate for all insured mortgages. (2) A mortgagee that operates in a single State may choose to have its claim and default rate compared with the average rate in the State in which it operates, in which case the Single State mortgagee is eligible for the lender Insurance program if its claim and default rate is at or below 150 percent of the Sate average rate for insured mortgages. 48 151 - the United Sates. Lenders are evaluated every year to decide whether their participation in FHA insurance programs will be renewed. Inadequate performance or reserves can be grounds for revocation of delegated underwriting arrangements, thereby providing an incentive for lenders to perform. The lender approval and recertification division checks and approves 2000-3000 mortgagees a year on average, and terminates unqualified mortgagees at about the same scale. The quality assurance division, together with 4 HOCs, monitors lenders for program compliance. Every HOC targets its own lenders according to risk-based criteria, while the division at the headquarter sets policies and oversees the overall performance. The headquarter staff monitor lenders in two ways: on-site monitoring and a computer system called "Neighborhood Credit Watch." The decision of whom to pick for on-site monitoring is based on many risk factors related to a lender, including: defaults, claims, underwriting review, higher-risk programs, internal referral, external referral, fluctuations of the volume of business, late MI premiums, etc. This division usually does about 10 percent on-site monitoring of all the approved mortgagees per year. In addition to on-site monitoring, this division also uses two computerized monitoring systems: Neighborhood Credit Watch and Third-party Appraiser Watch. The Neighborhood Credit Watch System helps identify poorly performing lenders. It was initiated in 1999 and now covers about 30,000 branches. It serves to warn marginally performing lenders to improve their performance if they wish to maintain their status as approved FHA lenders, helps screening out problematic mortgagees for on-site review, and refers the really bad performers to the mortgagee review board, who then decide on civil monetary penalties, status terminations, or other punishments. The Appraiser Watch Monitoring System is used to identify appraisers who either knowingly or unintentionally put homeowners at risk for losing their homes to foreclosure because of inflated valuations. The Appraiser Watch monitoring system relies on historical risk factors to help identify appraisers whose work will be reviewed by FHA staff. Included among the risk factors are an appraiser's association with mortgages of high default rates, or a high volume of appraisals on higher risk mortgage programs such as loans for multi-unit properties. The - 152- use of technology and advanced information systems improves FHA's operational efficiency and helps control the extent of moral hazard. The third approach to controlling moral hazard is implementing mandatory loss mitigation efforts among lenders, when borrowers become delinquent in their payments. Without any enforcement of loss-reducing procedures, lenders may simply choose to assign the delinquent loans to the FHA as defaulted ones and collect the full loss coverage. This has two negative results: borrowers will lose their homes and the FHA will suffer big losses due to the costly foreclosure - the prolonged foreclosure process, accumulated claim amount, and servicing and maintenance after the property acquisition by the FHA. In answer, the FHA launched the Loss Mitigation Program which requires lenders to first go through the loss mitigation procedure before they can file insurance claims. The procedure is composed of five types of strategies: special forbearance, loan modification, pre-foreclosure sale, partial claims, and deed-in-lieu (Figure 6.2). Under this program, lenders must provide more options to help some homeowners keep their homes. When borrowers default on their FHA-insured mortgages, they can resolve a default (90-day delinquency) in several ways short of foreclosure: by paying down the delinquency (cure), by a pre-foreclosure sale with the FHA perhaps paying an insurance claim in the amount of the shortfall, or by surrendering a deed in lieu of foreclosure. Figure 6.2 The Loss Mitigation Procedure Required by the FHA Source: Office of Evaluation, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) If after all the loss mitigation alternatives have been exhausted and a defaulted loan still cannot be cured, it then goes into foreclosure. On average the FHA single-family loan 153 - foreclosure process takes about 1.3 months. After the foreclosure is completed, the lender files a claim to the FHA and also files a deed to the Secretary of HUD. Then FHA pays out the claim, takes possession of the property, and has its Management and Marketing (M&M) contractors mange and sell the property. The FHA's loss mitigation program has effectively lowered the foreclosure rate among all 90-day delinquencies from 77 percent in 1998 to around 50 percent in 2003. Manage other "non-transparent"risks As a public program with social objectives, the FHA is exposed to some "non- transparent" risks, which to some extent create market distortion within the low-income segment of the housing market. For example, although FHA allows sellers to pay certain costs on behalf of borrowers, the practice entails risks that sellers may inflate the sales price of the home, which is why FHA limits the amounts of these concessions. With regard to its minimum borrower downpayment requirements, the FHA does not allow seller gifts, although it does permit relatives, local governments, and non-profit organizations to provide downpayment assistance as a means of assisting first time buyers attain the benefits of homeownership. In recent years, certain non-profit organizations have instituted downpayment assistance programs for borrowers funded directly by donations received from property sellers. This practice has had the effect of circumventing the FHA's policy against seller downpayment assistance, and becomes a new potential risk factor that could raise FHA defaults and claims to higher levels than predicted. It influences the FHA's risk profile and reinforces both the adverse selection and moral hazard problems. The FHA is stepping up its effort to discern the involvement of non-profit organizations in downpayment assistance with the help of its advanced loan evaluation system, the Total Scorecard. This system is embedded in automated underwriting systems used by lenders. It evaluates mortgage applications and predicts the likelihood of borrower default in an objective and consistent manner. If loan applications obtain a score above certain threshold, they can pass the system for automatic underwriting. Otherwise, the applications will get "referred decision" because of their low scores. The lender must manually underwrite these loans to ensure that the applicant receives maximum consideration. - 154- B. The Dutch WEW Program Relative independence of the WEW The WEW is a private, non-profit organization, supervised and backed by the central government and local municipalities in the Netherlands. It has a relatively simple and straightforward institutional structure (Figure 6.3). Figure 6.3 The Institutional Structure of the WEW Supervised by Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment and the Association of Netherlands Municipalities Being a private entity helps maintain the WEW's financial independence and makes it less prone to political pressure. Moreover, the WEW has been focused on only two types of products since its inception in 1995: guarantees for owner-occupied single-family mortgages and for home improvement loans.49 Unlike the FHA's experience, no other miscellaneous or special standalone housing programs are imposed on the WEW, mainly because the WEW's current policy priority is to expand homeownership across both low and middle income segments. For instance, the policy could serve as an instrument to encourage relatively higher-income tenants in the social rental sector to move to the purchase sector (Boelhouwer and Neuteboom, 2003).50The situation is determined by the history of Dutch housing policies and its current housing market composition with a significant portion of the housing stock in the social rental sector. The WEW is facilitating the transition toward market-oriented housing supply and demand. 49 Guarantees on home improvement 50 Until loans started later, in January 1999. the 1990s, there was a marked difference in rental and housing-for-purchase markets. In the 1990s, the important distinction was no longer drawn between rental and purchase, but rather between subsidized and unsubsidized housing and the extent to which the government should provide financial support (Boelhouwer and Neuteboom, 2003). - 155- The supervision and monitoring of WEW's performance and financial soundness are conducted by a consortium of two public entities, the Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment and the Association of Netherlands Municipalities. There is a long tradition of collaboration and compromise among different political parties in the Netherlands. Plus, the central government and local governments share the backstop responsibility of supporting WEW's guarantees 50-50. The risk sharing aligns the interests between the two in supervising the performance of the WEW. Managepotentialadverseselectionand moral hazard Unlike in the U.S., there is no requirement that high LTV mortgage loans must carry mortgage insurance in the Netherlands. Therefore, lenders have the option between self- insurance and the WEW guarantee, which may promote "cherry-picking," or adverse selection, among loans. They might be inclined to self-insure good credit-quality loans but require the weaker borrowers to obtain a WEW guarantee. To some extent, this is shown in the distribution of WEW-guaranteed loans vis-a-vis the sale price distribution of owner-occupied houses within the WEW-guaraneeable range in 2003 (Figure 6.4). The guaranteed loans were concentrated in the lower part of the WEW-guaranteeable range, while the dwelling's sale prices nationwide s within the WEW's loan limit were comparatively more concentrated in the upper part of that range. For instance, mortgage loans below 140,000 euros accounted for about 39% of the total WEW-guaranteed loan amount in 2003, while the general loan distribution below 140,000 euros was about 29.7%. On the other hand, WEW-guaranteed loans over 180,000 euros (but below its ceiling of 230,000 euros) represented 32% of its total guaranteed loans while this figure was about 40% within the general, WEW-guaranteeable loans. The over-representation of smaller-sized loans and the under-representation of relatively larger-sized ones within WEW's guaranteeable range indicate the possible existence of lenders' self-insurance: purchasers of more expensive houses (hence larger loan sizes) are usually relatively higher-incomers, considered in good financial standing and less risky. They are more likely to be self-insured by lenders and less often appear in the WEW-guaranteed A dwelling's sale price is an approximation of the mortgage loan size because of the commonly high LTV mortgages in the Netherlands. 51 - 156- portfolio, while the less expensive houses (hence smaller-sized loans) are more likely to be purchased by lower-income people and insured by the WEW. However, a caveat is that it is hard to judge the extent of potential adverse selection based on only one year's data. The more recent data from Kadaster (the database recording transactions of owneroccupied houses in the Netherlands) and WEW show that the price distribution of houses sold had similar patterns to the corresponding price categories in the WEW guaranteed loans. For example, around 58% of all WEW guarantees were granted in the price range above 155,000 euros for the first quarter of 2005, while the percentage of owneroccupied houses sold in that range accounted for about 60% in the Kadaster database for the year 2004.52 So there was almost no over-representation of the WEW-guaranteed loans in the lower half of its guaranteeable universe, compared to the general mortgage markets in the Netherlands. Another argument is that the WEW guarantees are more concentrated in the four largest cities in the Netherlands, where there is overrepresentation of lower priced houses. Therefore the mismatch between patterns of house sales prices nationwide and WEW -guaranteed loan sizes may merely reflect the differences in the geographic distribution rather than the presence of adverse selection by lenders. More time-series data are needed to explore the existence and extent of the potential adverse selection. Figure 6.4 The Distribution of WEW -Guaranteed Loans and Owner-Occupied Dwellings' Prices within WEW's Loan Limit, 2003 Owner-occupied within Dwellings the WEW's by Sales Price, Loan Loan Limit (2003) 200,000-220,000 4% 180,000-200,000 7% '" 18.3 140,000-160,000 E ::I 0 c: (tJ 0% 5% 10% 142,941-154,285 17% 100,000-120,000 11% 0 ...J 7% up to 80,000 15% .1110/_ 0% 20% Source: WEW, aTB 52 10% 10% 10% ~% 167,899-180,000 7.6% up \0 100,000 0 8% w E .1% 100,000-120,000 by WEW (2003) 4 « 1~ 0% 120,000-140,000 Guaranteed '0 190,588-200,000 :; ~ 11.9% 160,000-180,000 Ranges These figures are provided by the WEW. - 157 - 5% 10% 15% 20% The WEW controls adverse selection by requiring lenders to check borrowers' credit worthiness before endorsing guarantees. The lender must request a statement from the Central Credit Registration Office for every applicant. In order to be eligible for the WEW guarantee, the income standards drawn up in co-operation with the Consumer Credit Counseling Service (NIBUD) also have to be met. The borrower can only participate in the WEW guarantee if he meets the income requirements adopted by the NIBUD. 53 Many recent immigrants who have not yet established their credit history, and other low-incomers who have impaired credit quality are excluded from the WEW guarantee provision. Moral hazard has not been a serious problem so far for the WEW, as the portfolio default rates have been very low (less than 1 percent). When a lender files claims to the WEW, it will examine the loan documents processed by the lender. If the lender did not issue the guarantee according to WEW's underwriting requirements, the WEW will ask for reimbursement from the lender for the claim amount paid out. This acts as an incentive for lenders to maintain good faith. Currently, the WEW is contemplating the launch of a new program called "home expense program," in order to promote "sustainable homeownership." This program may increase moral hazard occurrences of both lenders and borrowers. Similar to the payment insurance program in some other countries like Australia and the UK, the program brings additional safeguards to the borrower. It works as follows: currently if a borrower cannot make his mortgage payment for nine months, his house will be sold forcibly, either before a foreclosure or in an auction. Under the new program, this period is extended to two years before any forced sale. Lenders will work out a payment reduction plan with the borrower in this two-year period - an extra loan will be granted from the lender to the troubled borrower. The WEW provides guarantee to the new extra loan without charging any extra guarantee fees. The rationale for this program is the belief that most borrowers cannot make their payments because of economic reasons (e.g. unemployment). Giving them more time will help them recover from the bad situation and resume payments again later, therefore avoiding the costly - There is only one income requirement: the home expenses-to-income ratio. The maximum loan amount that can be accepted as safe and sound is about 4 - 4.5 times the annual household income. 53 - 158 foreclosure. However, the added risk of this program is substantial. It may cause both borrowers and lenders not to take the first 9-month delinquency seriously and result in bigger losses to the WEW later. It will take some time to learn whether its benefits outweigh its costs. Full recourseand problemsof risk allocation In the Netherlands, unlike in many other EU jurisdictions, there is full recourse against borrowers who have defaulted on a mortgage. During foreclosure, one method of recourse is through a borrower's earnings. Under the Civil Code and Code of Civil Procedures, a lender in the Netherlands is allowed to apply for an attachment to the borrower's income at any stage during the foreclosure process. This allows the lender legal recourse to a proportion of a borrower's salary and other income decided by the judge at court. Lenders' right of full recourse to borrowers' non-housing assets and income can result in non-optimal risk allocation of the society as a whole. With 100 percent guarantee coverage and very low premiums, households may obtain a bigger mortgage (higher LTV) than they would under a partial guarantee program or higher insurance premium. Therefore, they have a larger risk exposure to the housing market volatility, and are more likely to default during economic downturns. With full recourse, the losses from default are ultimately borne by the borrower. That is, individual households actually face the risks of the whole housing market fluctuation. This raises the question of whether such a public MI system allocates housing market risks efficiently. A nationwide public MI enterprise should have a much better risk diversification capacity than individual households, and can cross subsidize borrowers of different LTV classes and loan cohorts. Therefore, by concentrating risks on individual borrowers, the WEW system with strong recourse is likely to create sub-optimal risk allocation. This inefficiency, however, is mitigated by the WEW's policy to forgo the right of recourse to those defaulted borrowers who are believed in "good faith." That is, if in the opinion of the WEW, the forced sale cannot be attributed to the borrower and the borrower has assisted in limiting the residual debt as far as possible, the WEW will waive the residual debt. However, the majority of defaulted households carry their debt forward. In 2002, - 159- only 30 percent of the defaulted households were remitted from the debt. In 2003, the figure was about 17 percent. On the other hand, an argument may be made that borrowers will take the potential recourse into account and consider the shadow price of the mortgage insurance premium accordingly. However, there is the concern of information efficiency. Households may not be able to project properly the shadow price of the mortgage insurance with recourse, due to their lack of information on the national or regional housing market conditions. Individual households' mispricing of the insurance premium with the recourse clause can result in negative externalities (such as general over-exposure to the housing market risks) that will not be internalized by individual households, but to the society as a whole. Again, a nationwide organization like WEW should have better market information and a more holistic picture than individual households. The risk allocation inefficiency because of recourse to borrowers only becomes prominent during economic downturns when defaults increase, which has not happened since the WEW's establishment. The process of recourse is time-consuming and staffextensive. As a lean organization, the WEW has to resort to the lender (usually a bank) to follow up with defaulted borrowers and manage the recourse process. Banks may not have enough incentives to do the job well while the WEW does not have the expertise or staff to handle recourse by itself. As a result, in many cases the WEW gave up the recourse to borrowers after a short period because the recoveries may not even cover the operation costs of tracing these borrowers. In 2003, the WEW recovered 27,110 euros from recourse, which accounted for only about 5 percent of the total claim amount paid out. Therefore it is safe to say that so far the inefficiency in risk allocation due to recourse is negligible in the Netherlands. Nonetheless, policymakers ought to be aware of its potential impacts should the economy worsen and defaults increase. Privatesectordevelopment There is no private MI sector in the Netherlands, mainly because of the two reasons discussed earlier. First, there is no regulatory requirement for high LTV mortgage loans 160 - to carry MI, unlike the situation in the U.S. As a result, lenders have the incentive and the option to sel'-insure loans in the higher-end of the market where borrowers' income and credit quality are relatively high. Second, in the lower end of the mortgage market, the WEW has the funding advantages of enjoying the backing of the full faith and credit of the Dutch governments and also being free from earning profits. Therefore, the WEW's insurance premium can afford to be so low that private MIs cannot compete in pricing. Even though it is not as well capitalized as the U.S. FHA in terms of capital ratio, defined as the ratio of capital reserves over the total insurance-in-force, 54 the WEW guaranteed, securitized mortgage portfolios enjoy triple-A rating from major rating agencies. Some discussions are raised as to whether the WEW should be completely privatized, without government backing. The fundamental question is whether the functions provided by the WEW right now can be accomplished by the private sector at a similar or lower premium rates, stably and sustainably. The private insurers can add more efficiency and risk diversification to the market, as most major private MI companies are internationally diversified. The disadvantage of a complete privatization is the loss of the WEW's functions in stabilizing the national economy and the low premium rates because of its non-profit status. There are risks that the private MI sector will not be able or willing to take on lower credit quality borrowers (e.g., immigrants). But these risks are not currently dealt with by the WEW either. There is potential market space for private mortgage insurers in the Netherlands, because the WEW has a loan limit which disqualifies guarantees to about 50 percent of the mortgages in the Netherlands. Currently WEW's market penetration rate is about 29%, covering the lower-end of the market. The private MI sector can enter the higher end of the mortgage market, a potential size of 50%-70% of the entire market, and further expand mortgage credit provision. In the future, lenders may see the benefits of unloading mortgage default risks to private mortgage insurers who can manage them more internationally and efficiently, especially considering the increasing integration of 54 In FY2003, the capital ratio of the FHA's MMI Fund was 5.21%, while the capital ratio of the WEW was 0.58%. - 161 - the European Union (EU). These trends might change the long-standing Dutch culture of honoring one's debt and timely payments, and lead to higher default rates as those exhibit in other ED countries (Figure 6.5). Figure 6.5 The Average Mortgage Delinquency Rates in EU Countries, 1994-2001 Average Mortgage Delinquency Countries, Rates in EU 1994-2001 Netherlands Austria UK Luxembourg Denmark France Portugal 5.00 5. Yo .8% 6.0% Belgium Italy Ireland Spain 10.5% Finland 0.0% 2.0% 4.0% 6.0% 8.0% 10.0% 12.0% Source: Diaz-Serrano, 2002; the European Community Household Panel (ECHP). c. The Mexican SHF Program Institutional structure to keev MI's indevendence The SHF was chartered in 2001 as a federal development bank and is currently owned by the Mexican federal government. Compared to its predecessor, FOVI, which was a trust fund within the Central Bank receiving subsidized funding from the Bank of Mexico, SHF has much greater financial independence. It received one-time funding from previous FOV!' s assets and some loans from the World Bank and the Inter-America Development Bank at its establishment.55 From that point on, the SHF is responsible to raise its own funding in the capital market by issuing bonds. SHF's guarantee products enjoy the full backing of the government until 2013. After that, SHF is fully responsible for its liabilities. The SHF is regulated by CONAFOVI - the National Housing Commission in charge of developing housing policy and coordinating national housing institutions (Figure 6.6). 55 In February 2002, the SHF was created and took $10 billion pesos from FOVI's. Four months after its establishment, SHF received U.S.$500 million loan from the World Bank and U.S. $500 million from the Inter-America Development Bank. - 162 - Figure 6.6 The Institutional Structure of SHF .............................. International private * MIs as insurers Regulated by CONAFOVI (National Housing Commission) l SHF Mexican government *: SHF has stopped granting construction loans and is gradually phasing out direct loans to Sofoles for individual mortgages. They are encouraged to raise money through securitization. The wide range of financial guarantee products currently offered by SHF raises potential problems of liability overlap and conflict of interest among different programs. For example, the UDI-minimum wage swap fund supports SHF's guarantees to cover possible unexpected or permanent drops in real terms in the minimum wage, so allowing borrowers to pay a mortgage stated in UDI in minimum wage terms. The fluctuations of the gap between inflation and the minimum wage also impact the borrowers' default behavior, therefore related to SHF's MI products. Currently these two guarantee products are both offered by SHF. Although there is separation between its capital reserve funds for the first loss guarantee and for the UDI swap program within the organization, there is still potential risk of violating the rules internally in stressful circumstances, especially given the fact that the federal government provides backup for both guarantees. One solution to the problem is to establish permanent separation of the two programs by putting them in different entities. SHF may be able to convert its first-loss MI program's legal entity from within a development bank to an insurance company (or subsidiary of the bank) and to seek adoption of new regulations specifically applicable to mortgage default insurance. As the Mexico macro economy further stabilizes, SHF should phase out the UDI swap program as rapidly as the market will permit. The high cost of this product to the borrower, especially when superimposed upon the cost of the fist loss mortgage insurance, reduces affordability and demand (Blood, 2004). - 163 - Controladverseselectionand moralhazard Currently, commercial banks only lend to the top income percentile populations who do not need credit enhancement to make good on their mortgages. The SHF channels most of its funds to Sofoles to fund individual mortgage loans for middle- to low-income households, covering 75 percent of all households in Mexico. The funding automatically carries SHF's mortgage insurance. Therefore adverse selection by lenders, in this case the Sofoles, does not exist. However, situations can change soon as the SHF is encouraging Sofoles to obtain mortgage funding from the capital markets by securitization. SHF is planning to reduce the direct funding dramatically since 2005, and will provide MI to mortgage loans whose funding comes from sources other than SHF. From the beginning of its operation, SHF emphasizes and requires individual loan-level review as the centerpiece of its mortgage insurance underwriting program, in order to establish its credibility and discipline in the marketplace. SHF plans to have "delegated underwriters" when portfolio and customer risk experience justifies a prudent clientbased transition to a lower-cost, more rapid turnaround business model involving delegated insurance approval authority, which will be accompanied by on-site follow-up audits of insured loan files. SHF will establish its performance criteria required for lenders to earn the elevated status of "delegated underwriter." Periodic renewal of this status can act as an incentive to prevent moral hazard. Another effective approach of controlling moral hazard is through risk sharing with the insured. SHF's first-loss guarantee provides coverage of losses up to 25 percent of the unpaid balance of the defaulted loan. Therefore lenders have incentives to monitor the performance of their insured loans to prevent losses exceeding the coverage threshold. SHF also keeps a close eye on its counter party risks and monitors Sofoles' financial strength regularly. It uses a standardized model called "CAMEL" to examine the financial health of each Sofol, by examining the balance sheet of the Sofoles on five aspects: Capital, Asset, Management, Earnings, and Liquidity. The system rates the factors and derives a composite score for each Sofol. SHF also requests each Sofol - 164 - submit its financial information to rating agencies and be ranked by them. Rating agencies assign an investment grade to each Sofol every three months. In addition, SHF developed a multi-variable regression model to assign weights to different variables that are linked to the default rates. By conducting these monthly evaluations, SHF accomplishes three goals: i) controlling the risk of moral hazard by constant monitoring and inspection of lenders (Sofoles); ii) gathering data input about lenders into its default projection models; and iii) increasing the credibility of its MI product by involving internationally acknowledged rating agencies. Private sector development SHF acts as a catalyst to encourage and facilitate the development of the private MI sector. It is in active talks with some North American MI companies to attract them to enter the Mexican mortgage market. SHF is laying the informational, legal, and regulatory infrastructure so that private participants will be ready to take on the credit risks. SHF will remain in the market to provide MIs only if there are no private bodies interested in doing this. It is likely to become the ultimate backing for private MI providers in the future to maintain investors' confidence. This arrangement, very different from the FHA and WEW's situations, minimizes the impact of public MI provision on the private sector development and aims to fully privatize the MI sector if feasible. In the short- and medium-run, this process can benefit the Mexican mortgage market and improve its transparency and efficiency, because of the unique, historical housing finance market distortions caused by the long-time dominance of public funds and housing entities. In the long run, however, public MI should still remain in the Mexican mortgage market to serve the very large lower-income, higher-risk segments for which the private MI would be too expensive. Risk allocation efficiency The Mexican housing stock is severely under-leveraged as many households have no access to formal housing finance. Only about 12.6% of the housing stock is currently mortgaged (Merrill Lynch report, 2004). Lower income and self-employed persons and those in the informal sector have almost 100 percent equity in their houses. It not only - 165 - greatly limits the liquidity of the housing finance market, but also results in inefficient risk allocation because those households bear all the housing market risks individually without any cushion or risk pooling. SHF's MI products are expected to expand the underwriting envelope and allow more people to leverage their savings in housing consumption (through higher acceptable LTVs by lenders). This will distribute risks among SHF, lenders (Sofoles or banks) and borrowers. The diversification capacity of the SHF is much better than both lenders and individual borrowers, which should result in a better risk allocation in the market as a whole. The key is to price correctly the risks SHF is taking in its MI premiums, so that the federal government does not end up paying for unexpectedly large liabilities. III. Comparison of the Three MI Programs' Potential Economic Problems The analyses of the three public MI programs illustrate the major potential economic and social problems that can result from the establishment of public MI (Table 6.1). Its distorting effects on the housing finance market reflect the "indirect" costs of implementing such a government intervention, in addition to the direct costs of managing and operating it and the financial liabilities of backing it. Policymakers should understand the scale of the total costs, direct as well as indirect, and weigh them against the potential benefits to decide whether such a program is the most cost-efficient option, now and in the future. A country's historical context in housing policy and the uniqueness of its housing markets matter. - 166- Table 6.1 Potential Economic and Social Problems Resulting from Public MI Adverse selection FHA WEW SHF* Moral hazard Risk allocation inefficiency Medium High Medium Constraint on private sector development Low All loans over 80% LTV have to be 100% loss coverage. Unnecessarily high level of Private MI sector is Historically the program was insured if to be Lenders become defaults exists gaining market heavily sold to the GSEs. less responsible among higher- share and serve impacted by Program targets lower-income, higher-risk populations. in underwriting and monitoring insured loans. risk borrowers. majority of the market. various housing policies. Medium No requirement for carrying MI. Guaranteed loans concentrate on the Low Historical culture of treating debt and payments. Default rates Potentially High The right of full recourse to defaulted borrowers can High Its loan ceiling covers 50 percent of the market, with Low A private organization. Relatively new program with lower end of the have been low, result in very low only two types guaranteeable range. which may change as EU inefficient risk allocation of the premiums and government of MI products. becomes more society. It is backing. integrated. The right of recourse reduces moral hazard. mitigated by the fact that some borrowers are exempt from the recourse. Low All mortgage funding from SHF carries its guarantee Medium Only 25% loss coverage. Banks do not utilize SHF, Low SHF helps increase the overall risk allocation Low SHF is laying the foundation for private MI providers to High Historically government policies dominate public automatically. In the future Sofoles may obtain while Sofoles are completely dependent on it efficiency by encouraging more leverage in come in to the market. Private sector housing entities. Many guarantee products are funding from other sources and the adverse selection currently. housing consumption. development is strongly encouraged. currently offered by SHF and backed by can be a concern. Abuse of the program for political reason High the government. *: SHF is undergoing rapid development and changes. For example, it will dramatically reduce its mortgage funding to Sofoles if they start to raise capital through securitization, hopefully in 2005. This may change the extent of impact of some problems above, such as adverse selection and moral hazard. The three public MI programs have deployed various operational strategies to cope with the actual and potential economic problems described above. Most efforts are focused on controlling and reducing adverse selection and moral hazard (Table 6.2). - 167 - Table 6.2 Operational Strategies to Control Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard FHA · · · · · Screen and approve lenders prior to their participation in the insurance program. Post-approval lender monitoring and inspection: on site and electronically. Annual recertification of participating lenders. Apply information systems and databases to monitor lender and appraiser performance. Implement mandatory loss mitigation efforts when borrowers become delinquent. WEW · · Require lenders check borrowers' credit worthiness and make sure it meets certain criteria. The right of full recourse to defaulted borrowers' other assets, as a disincentive to prevent borrowers' moral hazard. · The right of WEW for reimbursement from lenders after the claim payout, if lenders did not abide by its underwriting rules. SHF · · · · · · Automatically impose its insurance on all the funding distributed by SHF. Risk sharing with insured lenders: MI only covers losses up to 25% of the unpaid loan balance. Individual loan-level review and underwriting by SHF. Closely monitor Sofoles, its counter party, on its financial strength and management quality. Require credit rating of Sofoles from internationally acknowledged rating agencies. Apply information systems and databases to track the relationship between lenders evaluation and default rates. They share some common strategies that prove to be effective in practice and can be emulated by other countries, such as active monitoring and recertification of lenders, using information systems to track lenders performance and link it to loan default rates, etc. Also, various forms of risk-sharing techniques are applied in each of the three models depending on that country's characteristics and its mortgage market's uniqueness, such as the mandatory loss mitigation process in FHA, the right of reimbursement from lenders in case of unqualified underwriting and the right of full recourse to ill-intentioned borrowers in WEW, and the first-loss partial coverage in SHF. Risk sharing creates incentives for the insured party to remain responsible and diligent. Such mechanism should be incorporated in the public MI design, especially in developing countries and emerging economies. Loss mitigation has proven quite successful with the FHA program - not only reducing monetary payouts of the FHA but also bringing positive social impacts by helping borrowers keep their homes. In places where foreclosures are difficult or timeconsuming, a very common problem in many developing countries, loss mitigation efforts can be particularly effective. In Mexico, the SHF encourages alternatives such as restructuring the delinquent loan through Sofoles, or transferring the loan and the property to another borrower, rather than going into the expensive and lengthy foreclosure process. - 168 - The issues of constraining private sector development and potential abuse of public MI for political reasons can be addressed in one of two ways: i) establishing sound institutional framework to ensure the independence of the public MI enterprise and limit unfair or unreasonable competition to private MI providers; or ii) eventually privatizing the public MI when the market matures and the private sector is ready to take on the risks, maybe with the government providing some type of catastrophic risk backup. The U.S. FHA and the Dutch WEW chose the first approach; and the Mexican SHF clearly adopted the second one. The choice depends on a country's housing policy history and housing market context, housing finance market maturity, government credibility and the availability of various legal and regulatory infrastructures. For developing countries and emerging economies with perceived risks of corruption or bureaucracy of government agencies, the staged privatization of public MI can be a better and more realistic approach in the long run. - 169 - - 170- Chapter 7 Conclusions And Policy Implications I. Research Purpose and Method This research explores the feasibility and functioning of the public mortgage insurance programs and the role played by the government. The significance of this work lies in that it is the first comprehensive effort to provide an integrated analytical framework for policymakers to evaluate the prerequisites, potential costs and benefits, and possible consequences of employing public MI to advance housing finance markets. It proposes a quantitative, adaptable modeling process to measure and project the potential liabilities imposed on the government that backs the public MI. As one of many finance-linked housing policy alternatives, public MI can be an effective catalyst to promote homeownership affordability in primary mortgage markets and enhance credibility and liquidity of secondary markets. However, a good fit between public MI and a nation's housing markets and housing finance markets entails many factors, including economic, financial, legal, political, regulatory, institutional, geographic, and even cultural. This research comes at a time when a growing number of developing countries and emerging economies have expressed strong interest in establishing a public MI program, therefore offering important practical worth. The research uses a multi-case analysis approach and conducts an international comparison among three representative public MI programs: the U.S. FHA, the Dutch WEW, and the Mexican SHF. They are exemplars of the three partitions of the existing public MI programs worldwide. They represent three models at the different stages of MI evolvement, within different housing policy context and housing market situations. The main research methodologies include case studies and interviews, quantitative simulation models (the Monte Carlo simulations), and regression analyses. The value-atrisk (VaR) analyses used in this research have two major advantages over the traditional accounting-like assessments and stress tests of the three programs. First, VaR analyses not only measure the magnitude of potential losses at different levels on an insured cohort, but also assess the probability associated with specific levels of losses, therefore - 171 - giving policymakers a better idea of the likelihood and degree of losses. The VaR analyses offer the frequency distribution of potential results, rather than a single value point on that distribution as provided by the traditional methods. Second, this research combines the VaR analyses with the regression analyses to take into account the yearly correlation in cohorts' performance. When analyzing the NPV of mortgage insurance contracts over multiple-year cohorts, the VaR method with annual correlation factors measures more accurately the gains/losses over a long time horizon. As discussed earlier in Chapter 5, if the multi-year cohort performance correlation is ignored, the 6-year cumulative cohorts' NPV of the FHA mortgage insurance contracts will be underestimated by about 40 percent. In this study, I develop an integrated framework to analyze and compare public MI programs from institutional, financial and operational perspectives. The framework is composed of three inter-related research questions: a) What are the primary economic problems in the housing finance market that cause market inefficiency or market imperfections and hence call for government intervention in the form of a public MI? b) What are the implied liabilities imposed on the backing government (hence taxpayers) of sponsoringa public MI enterprise?and c) Whatare thepotential economicproblems that can result from the creation of a public MI system ? In the section that follows, I provide answers to these questions in major research findings. II. A. Major Research Findings Economic Rationales for Public MI There are two main purposes of utilizing a public MI scheme - to promote or expand homeownership, and/or to provide necessary credit enhancement to facilitate secondary mortgage market development. I differentiate the economic rationales for establishing public MI in developed countries and developing countries, by focusing on their uncertainty risks in the marketplace. A simplified model is developed to show that in developing countries, uncertainty risks include a country's political and economic instability - the idiosyncratic risks of potential catastrophes such as financial crisis or depressions. In developed countries, the uncertainty risks are taken when expanding the - 172 - underwriting envelope to include marginal borrowers - populations unserved or underserved by the private sector because of their perceived higher risk profile. In both cases, public MI takes on risks that are shunned by the private sector, because of the government's belief that positive externalities to the society as a whole from a more complete housing finance market, increased homeownership, and information efficiency outweigh potential costs. The answer to the first research question - the housing market inefficiencies that justify the establishment and continuing existence of the public MI - differs across three countries. In the U.S., the main initial inefficiency was the lack of confidence in the housing market and the hesitance in mortgage lending following the Great Depression. Now the market,inefficiencies mainly lie in the inadequate homeownership among lowerincome populations and in the information asymmetry in the secondary mortgage market. The FHA provides important credit enhancement to government-backed GinnieMae MBS. In the Netherlands, the housing market imperfections addressed by the public MI are the historically limited choices in housing tenure and the resulting low homeownership rate among the general population, especially low and medium income households. The WEW is used as one of many policy tools to redirect the Dutch housing market from its previous housing market model of heavy government regulation and subsidies, and mass production of social housing to a more market-oriented housing production and consumption model. Public guarantees, instead of direct subsidies, facilitate increased homeownership. In Mexico, the major inefficiencies in housing and housing finance markets that called for the establishment of SHF are multi-faceted. These inefficiencies include the great uncertainty of the country's macro economy and political stability, the serious shortage of capital in mortgage lending, and the lack of formal, affordable mortgage financing for the majority of the population, and the dearth of data for both primary and secondary mortgage markets. The comparison shows that as a nation's housing market develops and housing policy changes, the market inefficiencies addressed by public MI evolve as well. Three common market imperfections that can be effectively mitigated by public MI are: a) perceived - 173- high uncertainty risks due to macro economic and/or political instability, or due to the vulnerability of certain population groups; b) lack of standard market information and data; and c) absence of standardization and regulation in mortgage markets. In particular, the market information asymmetry for MBS investors is the most prominent reason why public MI is utilized in the secondary mortgage market for credit enhancement. In many developing countries, establishing a public MI program/enterprise can jumpstart the necessary regulatory and legal infrastructure for mortgage markets (such as establishing or improving laws on foreclosure, property title, appraisal, lenders' capital reserve requirements, etc.), can standardize mortgage loan origination and servicing, and can collect market data centrally and systematically. The comparison concludes with those prerequisites for public MI feasibility: a country's political and social, regulatory and legal, and information conditions. B. Implied Government Liabilities of Backing Public MI To answer this question, first I analyze the economics of the government in supporting a public MI program. The risk tolerance and loss magnitude between a public MI program and a private MI provider under various economic conditions is then compared. The model shows that public MI programs are more risk-tolerant than the private sector, and therefore their break-even cohort default rate is much closer to the mean portfolio default rate than that of the private sector. The answer to the second research question - the implied liabilities imposed on the government in backing public MI - is provided from these perspectives: a) whether the current public MI design and pricing can cover expected losses for a single cohort; b) what is the potential governmental liability under adverse events with small probabilities (recession scenarios and worst case scenarios); and c) what is the magnitude of government liability over multiple years. The value-at-risk method with parametric models is employed to analyze these questions for each of the three cases. - 174 - The results reveal that at the mean cohort default rate based on each country's historical mortgage portfolio performance, the FHA and SHF will have a small positive profitability rate (generating profits) for their 2003 cohort, while the WEW will have a slightly negative profitability rate, incurring some losses. However, a big caveat is that the mean cohort default rate in the WEW case is estimated based on very limited data firom the pre-WEW guarantee regime, which could cause an upward bias and overestimate the default rate. All three programs' profitability rates are very close to the break-even point, supporting the argument that public MI does not aim to maximize profit and is priced at the level such that the "buffer" zone against a single cohort's insurance loss is quite small. The multi-year NPV analyses on the FHA and the WEW show the financial soundness of both programs.56Over a six-year period and ten-year period respectively, both programs generate positive net present values, with FHA boasting a stronger result. For instance, the FHA cohorts for the next six years are projected to generate a profitability rate of 7.08%, with 3 percent probability of incurring losses; and the WEW cohorts are estimated to have a profitability rate of 0.55%, with 25 percent probability of losing money. The analyses reveal that the two public MI programs' financial strength is stronger over the long term than the short term. Therefore, the premium pricing of public MI should be based on business projections over a longer horizon, rather than narrowly focusing on yearly fluctuations. The multi-year NPV analyses also emphasize the importance of the current economic environment and its future outlook at the time when projections are made, as the macro economic conditions will render different trajectories for multiple, correlated cohorts' performance. Take the FHA's 2003 cohort as an example. Its projected cohort ultimate default rate is around 8.62%. If for the next six years, the U.S. macro economy remains positively stable as indicated by the smoothly upward trending yield curve,57 the estimated 6-year cumulative cohorts' NPV is about positive 3.6 billion dollars. However, if the economy enters a serious recession in the There is not enough historical data to conduct the multi-year simulations for the Mexican SHF program. implied Treasury rates for different maturities are derived from the yield curve as the following: 1year rate: 1.24%; 2-year rate: 1.65%; 3-year rate: 2.11%; 4-year rate: 2.54%; 5-year rate: 2.97%; and 6-year rate: 3.25%. 56 57 The - 175 - next six years, similar to that of the early 1980s,58 the next 6-year cumulative cohorts' NPV will be around negative 3.8 billion dollars - a substantial 7.4 billion dollar difference over the next six consecutive cohorts between the two different economic paths. A nation's macro economy and housing markets tend to experience cyclical movements. It is important to understand where the national economy stands in these cycles - whether it is heading to a recession, at the bottom of a recession and ready to pull out, or in a steady upswing trend. Based on the modeling procedures proposed in this research, it is possible for policymakers to make these projections. The shape of the current yield curve paints a picture of the future economy, and can be used to derive short-term interest rates over the next few years.5 9 Then based on the yearly correlation between adjacent cohorts' performance and short-term interest rates, a series of projections of cohort ultimate default rates can be made to compute the cumulative NPV of the insurance contracts on these cohorts. As an example, let us examine the recession period of the early 1980s and the recovery period afterwards in the U.S. The yield curves in the years of 1981, 1986 and 1993 (Figure 7.1) imply that the national economy was heading to a recession in 1981 (the inverted yield curve), gradually recovering in 1986 (the flat and slightly Figure 7.1 The Interpolated U.S. Treasury Yield Curves of 1981, 1986 and 1993 Interpolated U.S.Treasury YieldCurveof 1986 Interpolated U.S. Treasury YieldCurve of 1981 IU 145-- !, , - .. ..... Interpolated U.S. Treasury YieldCurveof 1993 "' , - ..................... ........ . . . ....... . ..................... 6 8 4 ` 5;13.5 b- 6 .Z_ 3 - 4 130 2 125 0 >2 1 0 11.11... I.... M-v t Nbturdy N- Maturity N- " . r~- 0 I--, ) ... 11- I (D Co N n (D Maturity The implied interest rates derived from the 1981 Treasury yield curve are as the following: 1-year rate: 14.80%; 2-year rate: 14.57%; 3-year rate: 14.46%; 4-year rate: 14.36%; 5-year rate: 14.25%; and 6-year rate: 14.16%. 58 59 The future short interest rates can be inferred from the yield curve of zero-coupon bonds as the (1 + y ), where n denotes the period in question and y, is the yield to maturity of a zero-coupon (1 + Yn-1 ) bond with an n-period maturity. r, is the short interest rate in period n. following: = - 176- upward yield curve), and growing in 1993 (a normal, upward trending yield curve). If policymakers were contemplating an FHA program in those years, they could project the program's potential performance over the first six years of the program's existence as follows: i) infer the future six-year interest rates from the yield curve; ii) make a baseline projection of the first cohort's ultimate default rate (mostly based on historical experience); iii) project the next five cohorts' ultimate default rates based on the multiyear correlation of cohort ultimate default rates (involving the previous year's cohort performance and the current short-term interest rate); and iv) calculate the estimated cumulative NPV over the first six years of the program launch. Suppose the baseline projection of a cohort's ultimate default rate is 10% in the U.S. As shown below (Figure 7.2), if the FHA program was launched in 1981, it would incur losses of about 3.5 billion dollars on its first six insured cohorts. If the program were to start in 1986 or 1993, it would generate profits of about 1.9 billion and 2.3 billion dollars respectively. Figure 7.2 Projected Six-Year Cohort Ultimate Default Rates Starting from 1981, 1986 and 1993 Projected 6-yearCohortUltimateDefault Rates,In1981 a 25% - 25% 25% - 20% - 20% - 15% 15% E, 10% X. 10% 15% 0%- Projected 6-yearCohort Ultimate Default Rates,in1993 Projected 6-yearCohortUltimate Default Rates,in1986 E, D- E 5% - 5%- E5% 3 0% 0% 0% 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Six-year cumulative NPV (million $): Starting FHA in 1981 Starting FHA in 1986 Starting FHA in 1993 -3,505 1,940 2,283 The example above illustrates that the timing of launching a public MI program is crucial for its initial success. For developing countries to decide the appropriate start-up time of a public MI program, policymakers need to conduct similar analyses to look at the current economic situation and the future economic outlook, the cyclical market behaviors, and the correlation between multiple years' cohort performance. - 177 - To further understand the magnitude of potential liabilities under unfavorable macro economic conditions, worst-case scenarios are analyzed in all three public MI programs, assuming that the most severe experience of economic depression so far in each country were to happen again. The results show that all three programs can survive the worst-case situation without imposing immediate burden on the backing government, but to different degrees. The FHA can survive about 22 bad years resembling the 1980s' books of business, and the WEW can be self-supporting for about 3.5 years if it encounters the recession of the 1980s again. The SHF's current capital reserves can only sustain one year of the post-1995-crisis situation. The comparison indicates that the longer the program has existed, without unusually bad times, the longer it can remain selfsupporting during economic downturns. Even if a public MI program is new and does not have enough capital reserves, as long as it can borrow from the federal government, then what matters is a long-run actuarially sound premium structure. If losses are incurred in the next few years, they can be paid back by earnings on future cohorts. This is ultimately the value of the government insurance: the insurance fund always has a credit rating equal to that of the federal government because it can borrow and lend to the federal government (or Treasury) at sovereign debt rates. C. Potential Economic Problems Resulting from Public MI Public MI, as a form of government intervention, inevitably distorts the housing markets to various degrees. The answer to the last research question - potential economic problems that may result from the establishment of public MI - is provided by first discussing five major types of potential economic and political problems and then analyzing the three study cases respectively. The five types of issues are: adverse selection, moral hazard, non-optimal risk taking and risk allocation, restraining the private sector development, and political abuse of the public MI program. Thorough analyses of the three cases show that for the FHA program, the main concerns are controlling moral hazard, reducing the political dominance over the program's development, and managing "non-transparent" risks; for the WEW, dominant issues include adverse selection, risk allocation inefficiency, and constraints on the private - 178- sector development; for the newly established SHF, the foremost tasks are ensuring the political and financial independence of the program and controlling moral hazard. In answering the research question, I also examine the institutional context and arrangement of the three public MI entities - their supervisors, auditors, close partners and government backing - that can help maintain the relative independence and financial soundness of these MI programs. The comparison of the three cases on what types of operational strategies each of them utilizes to manage and mitigate the aforementioned market distortions reveals some commonalities. The effective ones include: active monitoring and recertification of participating lenders, using advanced information systems and databases to track lenders performance and link it to portfolio default rates, and most importantly, some form of risk-sharing techniques that gives the insured lenders incentives to behave responsibly. Such techniques include mandatory loss mitigation efforts of FHA, the right of reimbursement of claim payout from lenders who did not underwrite the defaulted loans up to the standards of WEW, and the first-loss partial coverage of SHF. Some unique measures are adopted in each country to address the potential market distortions stemming from public MI presence. For instance the full recourse to defaulted lenders in the Netherlands, which are decided by that country's historical housing market conditions and the legal and cultural context. For developing countries where mortgage market risks are substantial, the implied co-insurance between the public MI and private lenders (through the partial loss coverage) adopted by the Mexican SHI program seems to be an effective strategy. III. Policy Implications and Recommendations This research has important practical policy implications for countries that are considering building a public MI system or in the process of doing so, especially developing countries and emerging economies that wish to develop their primary as well as secondary mortgage markets. The proposed framework and findings from comparing three public MI programs give policymakers a toolkit and benchmark to evaluate the feasibility and functioning of public MI in their own country. In the following section I - 179 - expand the discussion of public MI as a policy tool and present some policy implications and recommendations that are relevant to this research. A. The Government Role in MI Provision The government's involvement in MI provision can vary greatly, ranging from no involvement (such as in Australia where all MI is provided by private MI companies) to complete control (such as the U.S. FHA). Among the three case studies in this research, the U.S. government is actively involved in both financial and operational management of the program. The program's cost and efficiency may not be optimized. Nonetheless, when FHA-insured loans are sold as Ginnie Mae securities, the full faith and credit of the U.S. government provides an AAA guarantee that credit losses are covered and investors and financial partners consider MBS a good investment. The Dutch and Mexican MI models enjoy the full backing of the government as well, but their public MI entities are more stand-alone and independent, with a lot of the work delegated to lenders or intermediary financiers. What should be the role of the government in MI provision direct operator and manager, supervisor, backstop supporter, or a combination of them? It certainly depends on a country's specific housing market history and government credibility and capacity. In developing countries where political instability, government corruption and inefficiency are still of big concern, the government role is recommended to be clear and straightforward, such as only being the backstop supporter and program supervisor, rather than being the full fledged manager of the program like in the U.S. In this sense, the Dutch WEW model as a non-profit, private foundation provides a workable solution. The Mexican SHF has also started working on the creation of a mortgage insurance company as a subsidiary of the current SHF, therefore giving the insurance program more independence. Other alternative forms of a MI entity could be a government-owned joint stock company or a government-chartered special insurance company. Market size (annual numbers of homes insured, the average loan balance, etc.) also matters in deciding the government's role, as it impacts the program's operation scale and whether business revenues can cover costs. In countries where mortgages have lower - 180- loan balances and less premium income, fewer loans, and smaller insurance fund reserves, the public insurance program may not generate sufficient income to support a FHA-style operation. B. Public MI as a Housing Policy Public MI as a government housing policy is built upon many prerequisites besides the government's good will and supportive policies. These include a sound legal system for land titles and property foreclosure laws; a well-functioning primary mortgage market; and a culture of credit and availability of credit history. In many countries where these legal and regulatory conditions are absent, a mortgage guarantee model may not work. That is exactly the reason why in the Russian Federation "early introduction of MI is not recommended as substitute for resolving, even temporarily, serious legal and regulatory problems with home mortgage lending in Russia," (Blood, 2004) even though improving the country's system of housing finance and expanding mortgage credit supply have been a top economic development priority there. In most emerging economies, housing finance and housing production systems are marred by inefficiencies and inequities (Hoek-Smit and Diamond, 2003). For these economies, the policy priority is to improve the efficiency and transparency of the markets rather than establishing a public MI in an inefficient sector. Public MI alone can only address some of the housing market imperfections in the mortgage credit supply side. In many developing countries, the great majority of the households cannot afford the lowest priced house in the formal housing market sector, even if the financing is accessible. In that case, the main constraint in the housing market is the low income at the demand side, and the effective housing policies are more likely to include income subsidies, mortgage tax deductions, and upfront grants rather than MI. In some developing countries, such as in Mexico, both demand and supply sides of the housing finance system are defective. A combination of policy measures should be employed to reach the most effective remedy. In short, MI is a rather narrow and specialized component of the larger scheme of housing finance. It should be developed with an eye toward its proper place in the larger system, being combined and augmented - 181 - with other housing policies. Moreover, MI is not just a short-term "quick hit." Governments need policies that support a long-term and sustainable commitment to the housing sector. C. Public Versus Private There has always been policy debate as to whether a government-sponsored MI system should be privatized and rely on private capital to function without imposing any potential liabilities on the government. The bottom line is whether the benefits provided by public MI would be cost-effective and compelling for the private sector to provide. Take the U.S. FHA program for example. The advantages of the FHA remaining public are several: 1) The FHA does not need to earn a risk-adjusted profit to shareholders, which is FHA's principal cost advantage over the private MIs in serving riskier borrowers. 2) The FHA provides stability because its non-discriminatory underwriting policies offer all qualified borrowers the same price. When a region experiences economic downturns, private MIs may choose to reduce their business in that region or leave there completely, but the FHA will always provide MI, hence stabilizing the national housing markets. 3) The FHA provides social benefits such as expanding homeownership to lower- income people, first-time homebuyers and minority families. If the FHA loans were to be made through private MIs, the combined insurance premiums and GSE guarantee fees necessary to accommodate and integrate FHA's risk profile into the conventional market would be substantially higher than the combination of FHA's current premiums and the Ginnie Mae guarantee fee. FHA borrowers who attempted to use private MI would be declined or pay higher fees and enjoy less desirable terms. On the other hand, there are disadvantages of the FHA remaining public: 1) If the FHA does not price its risk properly, or experiences abnormally high losses, the government may need to assume the liability. This means taxpayers would pay for such insurance losses. A welfare transfer from all taxpayers to people who took out FHA loans may not be the most appropriate use of social welfare. - 182 - 2) As a program directly operated by the government, FHA has sacrificed some efficiency. The choice between public versus private provision of mortgage insurance is changeable. There are examples of an initially public MI system and its subsequent transition to the private sector. In Australia, MI began with a government-owned MI fund operating successfully for several decades before being sold outright to a private firm in the late 1990s. Banks using both government and private MI received risk-based capital incentives. Moreover, for developing countries and emerging economies, the form of ownership in MI provision can be very flexible and innovative, adapting to each country's unique situation. In India, the proposed India Mortgage Guarantee Company (IMGC) is co-owned by the Indian National Housing Bank (NHB), the Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation (CMHC), the Canada-based United Guarantee Company (UGC), the Asian Development Bank (ADB), and the International Finance Corporation of the World Bmank(IFC). In this partnership format, CMHC and UGC, as experienced and successful public and international MI provider respectively, will lend their expertise for the day-to-day operations of the new company, while the two international financiers, ADB and IFC, will be the strategic partners and funding-providers. The NHB will hold the majority stake of the proposed MI entity and take the initiative to promote MI in India, with the aims of mitigating severe housing shortage and developing secondary mortgage markets. In South Africa, the Home Loan Guarantee Company (HLGC) has been working in its own unique way to broader homeownership financing for the past decade. HLGC operates as an independent, non-profit, non-governmental organization (NGO). It pays neither taxes nor dividends, with all retained earnings accruing to its reserves (Blood, 2001). HLGC has been able to secure reinsurance for its guarantees from Centre Re, a subsidiary of Zurich Re. With this credit enhancement and its own conservative reserves, HLGC has earned an AA+ investment grade rating from major rating agencies and gained lender and investor acceptance. These examples of "hybrid" public MI provision in developing countries today emphasize that the fundamental issue is not so much about whether a MI scheme should be public or private, but about which form can best suit the country's housing markets and housing finance system, and work - 183 - efficiently with other components of the existing systems. One country's MI model is not directly replicable in another market (nor should this be encouraged). MI needs to be considered in the context of the unique historic needs and political objectives to ensure the success of the program. IV. Future Research This research can be furthered in a number of directions, as there are many interesting questions yet to be addressed. Pertinent research questions for the future include: (1) how to quantify the aggregated costs and benefits of public MI, including both direct and indirect components? (2) how does public MI compare with other finance-linked housing subsidies in efficiency, equity, and effectiveness, especially in developing countries and emerging economies? and (3) what synergies can public MI, in combination with other demand and supply side housing subsidies, create to address the incomplete housing finance markets in developing countries? In this dissertation I quantitatively analyze the implied governmental financial liabilities of sponsoring a public MI program in various economic scenarios. However, this is only one part of the total costs. Other indirect or induced potential costs can be quite substantial, including: the deadweight losses due to increased foreclosures among certain population groups or in certain communities; non-optimality of some borrowers' housing consumption based on their utility functions that factor in the presence of mortgage insurance coverage; and losses due to distortions introduced in the housing finance markets. At the same time, better quantifiable measures ought to be developed to understand the benefits of public MI. In this research, I generalize two main benefits of public MI: expanded homeownership and credit enhancement. There are other potential positive social externalities such as gains in housing market efficiency, liquidity, completeness or extension; redistributional improvements; and maybe even public health outcomes from better housing. A limitation of this research is the lack of systematic and quantifiable measurements to analyze the benefits from public MI, which is an indispensable component to conduct a holistic cost-benefit analysis. More efforts are worth putting into this aspect. - 184- The second and third research questions are focused on housing markets and housing finance systems of developing countries and emerging economies, where the physical shortage of housing stock, deteriorated dwellings or informal housing stock, and unaffordable housing costs are commonly shared problems. Housing, and housing finance in particular, is always considered a top priority on those countries' list of economic development goals and expected to become one of the growth engines. To achieve that goal, a great variety of policies and subsidy approaches can be applied and public MI is but one of them. A careful evaluation of the opportunity costs and risk factors of other housing subsidy alternatives besides public MI, and a thorough comparison among them with respect to their efficiency, equity and transparency are of great interest and importance to policymakers. This research provides a solid starting point for further discussions and comparisons of various housing policies. The analytical framework proposed here can be applied to a wider range of finance-linked housing intervention programs in analyzing their costs, benefits, and applicability to developing countries' housing markets. Further comparative analyses on how developing countries utilize different combinations of policy tools and programs to advance their housing markets and housing finance systems are of great significance. As an initial step, this research shows that mortgage insurance is but one component of housing finance - an important contributor, if implemented properly at the right time. - 185 - - 186- References Alink, Bjorn J. (2002) Mortgage Prepayments in the Netherlands. Ph.D. Dissertation, Twente University Press. Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale. (2000) Comparingfinancial systems. Cambridge: MIT Press. Babatz, Guillermo. (2004) The Role of the Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal in the Development of the Mexican Mortgage Market. Housing Finance International, March. Barry, Christopher, Gonzalo Castaneda, and Joseph Lipscomb. (1994) The Structure of Mortgage Markets in Mexico and Prospects for Their Securitization, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 5, No. 2. Barth, James P., et. al. (1988) Moral Hazard and the Thrift Crisis: An Analysis of 1988 Resolutions, Federal Home Loan Bank Board. Black, F. and M. Scholes. (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81. pp.6 3 7 -6 5 9 Blood, Roger. (1998) Prospective Role of Mortgage Insurance in Support of Housing Finance in Poland.East EuropeanRegionalHousingSectorAssistanceProject 180-0034, U.S. Agency for International Development. Blood, Roger. (2001) Mortgage Default Insurance: Credit Enhancement for Homeownership.HousingFinanceInternational,September. Blood, Roger. (2004)SociedadHipotecariaFederalFirst Loss Credit Guarantee Program: Findings and Recommendations, Report for the World Bank. Blood, Roger and Douglas E. Whiteley. (2004) Final Report: Mortgage Default Insurancefor the Russian Federation, The Institute for Urban Economics. Boelhouwer, Peter and Peter Neuteboom. (2003) Housing Markets, the Labor Market and Social Provision, Working paper of OTB Research Institute for Urban, Housing and Mobility Studies, Delft University of Technology, the Netherlands. Boelhouwer, Peter and Hugo Priemus (1990) Dutch housing policy realigned, NetherlandsJournalof Housingand EnvironmentalResearch,Vol. 5, pp.10 5 - 1 19 . Brennan, Michael J. and Eduardo S. Schwartz. (1976) The Valuation of American Put Options, The Journal of Finance, Vo. 32, No. 2. - 187 - Buckley, Robert, G. Karaguishiyeva, R. Van Order, and L. Vecvagare. (2001) Comparing Mortgage Credit Risk Policies: An Options Based Approach. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3047. Bunce, Harold, Charles Capone, Sue Neal, William Reeder, Randall Scheessele, and Edward Szymanoski. (1996) An Analysis of FHA's Single-Family Insurance Program. HUD-1579-PDR. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. Bury, Karl. (1999) Statistical Distributions in Engineering. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Calem, Paul S. and Michael LaCour-Little. (2001) Risk-based Capital Requirements for Mortgage Loans, SSRN publication: http://papers.ssm.com/sol3/cf dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per id=120508 Calhoun, Charles A. and Yongheng Deng. (2002) A Dynamic Analysis of Fixed- and Adjustable-Rate Mortgage Terminations, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 24, No. 1. Canner, G. B., S. Gabriel and J.M. Woolley (1991) Race, Default Risk and Mortgage Lending: A Study of the FHA and Conventional Loan Markets, Southern Economics Journal, Vol.58. Canner, Glenn, and Wayne Passmore. (1995) Credit Risk and the Provision of Mortgages to Lower-Income and Minority Homebuyers. Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol.81, No. 11. Capone, Charles A. Jr. (2000) Credit Risk, Capital, and Federal Housing Administration Mortgage Insurance, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 11. Capone, Charles A. Jr. (2002) Research Into Mortgage Default and Affordable Housing: A Primer, Paper for the LISC Centerfor Home Ownership Summit 2001, Washington D.C. Capone, Charles A. Jr. (2003) Risk Analysis of FHA Single-Family Mortgage Insurance, Paper presented at the ASSA/AREUEA Annual Conference, Washington D.C. Carey, Mark. (1998) Credit Risk in Private Debt Portfolio, Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, No. 4. Case, K. and R. Shiller. (1996) Mortgage Default Risk and Real Estate Prices: The Use of Index-Based Futures and Options in Real Estate. Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 7, No. 2. Charlier, Erwin and Arjan van Bussel. (2003) Prepayment Behavior of Dutch Mortgagors: An Empirical Analysis, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 31, No. 2. 188 - Cox, J.C., J.E. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross. (1985) A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates, Econometrica, Vol.53. Cox, D.R. and D. Oakes. (1984) Analysis of Survival Data, Monographs on Statistics and Applied Probabiity, Chapman and Hall: London. Cunningham, D.F. and P.H. Hendershott. (1984) Pricing FHA Mortgage Default Insurance, Housing Finance Review, Vol. 3, No.4. Cummins, J.D. (1998) Risk-Based Premiums for Insurance Guaranty Funds. Journal of Finance, September, 1988, pp. 823-839. Deng, Yongheng. (1997) Mortgage Termination: An Empirical Hazard Model with Stochastic Term Structure, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 14, No. 3. Deng, Yongheng, John M. Quigley and Robert Van Order. (1996) Mortgage Default and Low Downpayment Loans: The Costs of Public Subsidy. Regional Science and Urban Economics. Vol. 26, pp. 2 6 3 - 2 8 5 . Deng, Yongheng, John M. Quigley and Robert Van Order. (2000) Mortgage Terminations, Heterogeneity and The Exercise of Mortgage Options. Econometrica. Vol. 68, No. 2. Dennis, Barry, Chionglong Kuo and Tyler T. Yang. (1997) Rationales of Mortgage Insurance Premium Structures, Journal of Real Estate Research, Vol.14, No. 3. Diamond, B. Douglas and Michael J. Lea. (1992) Housing Finance in Developed Countries: An International Comparison of Efficiency, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 3, No. 1. Diamond, B. Douglas and Michael J. Lea. (1992) The Decline of Special Circuits in Developed Country Housing Finance, Housing Policy Debate, Vol. 3, No. 3. Diaz-Serrano, Luis. (2002) Income Volatility and Residential Mortgage Delinquency: Evidence from 12 EU countries, Working paper of National Universityof Ireland Maynooth, Department of Economics. Dipasquale, Denise and Edward L. Glaeser. (1999) Incentives and Social Capital: Are Homeowners Better Citizens? Journal of Urban Economics, Vol.45. Evans, Merran, Nicholas Hastings, and Brian Peacock. (1993) Statistical Distributions, 2nd Ed. New York: J. Wiley. - 189- Fisher Ernest M., and Chester Rapkin. (1956) The Mutual Mortgage Insurance Fund: A Study of the Adequacy of its Reserves and Resources. New York: Columbia University Press. FitchRatings. (2004) Dutch RMBS Default Model 2004, Criteria Report of FitchRatings. Follain, James R. and Edward J. Szymanoski. (1995) A Framework for Evaluating Government's Evolving Role in Multifamily Mortgage Markets, Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research, HUD, Vol.1, No.2. Foster, Chester C. and Thomas N. Herzog. (1981) Mortgage Insurance: The Role of FHA, Mortgage Banking, November 1981. Foster, Chester C. and R. Van Order. (1984) An Option-Based Model of Mortgage Default, Housing Finance Review, Vol. 3, No.4. Foster, Chester C. and R. Van Order. (1985) FHA Terminations: A Prelude to Rational Mortgage Pricing, AREUEA Journal, Vol.13, No.3. Green, Richard K. and Michelle. J. White. (1997) Measuring the Benefits of Homeownership: Effects on Children, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol.41. Hendershott, H. Patric, W. Lafayette and D. Haurin. (1997) Debt Usage and Mortgage Choice: The FHA-Conventional Decision, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol.41. Hendershott, H. Patric and Bengt Turner. (1994) The Determinants of Mortgage Default: Contrasting the American and Swedish Experiences. Housing Finance International. Hendershott, H. Patric and R. Van Order. (1987) Pricing Mortgages: An Interpretation of the Models and Results, Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol.1. Hoek-Smit, Marja C. and Douglas B. Diamond. (2003) Subsidies for Housing Finance, Housing Finance International, Vol. 17, No.3. Holmes, Andrew and Paul Horvitz. (1994) Mortgage Redlining: Race, Risk and Demand, Journal of Finance,Vol.49,No.1. Hypostat 1992-2002. European Mortgage Federation. Jackson, J.R. and D.L. Kaserman. (1980) Default Risk on Home Mortgage Loans: A Test of Competing Hypotheses, Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol. 47, No. 4. Jaffee Dwight M. (1971) Credit rationing and the commercial loan market. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. - 190 - Jaffee Dwight M., and Franco Modigliani. (1971) A theory and Test of Credit Rationing, American Economic Review 59(5): 850-872. Jaffee, D.M. and B. Renaud. (1996) Strategies to Develop Mortgage Markets in Transition Economies. Policy Research Working Paper, the World Bank. Jones, E.P. and S. Mason. (1980) Valuation of Loan Guarantees. Journal of Banking and Finance, March 1980, pp. 89-107. Kau, B. James and Donald C. Keenan. (1995) An Overview of the Option-Theoretic Pricing of Mortgages, Journal of Housing Research, Vol.63, No.4. Kau, B. James and Donald C. Keenan. (1996) An Option-Theoretic Model of Catastrophes Applied to Mortgage Insurance, The Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol.63, No.4. Kau, B. James, D. Keenan and W. Muller. (1993) An Option-Based Pricing Model of Private Mortgage Insurance, The Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol.6. Kau, B. James, D. Keenan, W.J. Muller and J.F. Epperson. (1992) A Generalized Valuation Model for Fixed-Rate Residential Mortgages, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol].24. Kau, B. James, D. Keenan, W.J. Muller and J.F. Epperson. (1995) The Valuation at Origination of Fixed-Rate Mortgages with Default and Prepayment, The Journal of Real Estate Financeand Economics,Vol. 1. Kihlstrom, Richard and Mark Pauly. (1971) The Role of Insurance in the Allocation of Risk, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 61. Lamoreaux, Pamela. (1999) A Busy Year for the Hong Kong Mortgage Corporation. HousingFinanceInternational,September. Lekkas, Vassilis, J.M. Quigley and R. Van Order. (1993) Loan Loss Severity and Optimal Mortgage Default, AREUEA Journal, Vol.21, No.4. Lipscomb, Joseph B. and Harold Hunt. (1999) Mexican Mortgages: Structure and Default Incentives, Historical Simulation, 1982 to 1998, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 10, No. 2. Liu, David. (2000) Exporting Mortgage Insurance Beyond the United States, Housing Finance International, June, 2000. Merrill, Sally, and D. Whiteley. (2002) Agency for Mortgage Insurance of Kazakhstan: Operational Framework, Working Paper of The Urban Institute. Washington D.C. - 191 - Merrill, Sally, and D. Whiteley. (2003) Establishing Mortgage Guarantee Insurance in Transition and Emerging Markets: A Case Study of Kazakhstan, Housing Finance International, September, Vol. 18, No. 1. Merrill Lynch Report. (2003) Mexican Mortgages: Tequila Sunrise or Manana, Manana? Paul Tucker and Felipe Cruz. Merrill Lynch Global Securities Research & Economics Group. Mersman, Hans. (2001). Applying Experience of Market Economy Countries in Housing Finance of Transition Economies: Public and Private Roles in Unbundling Risks, Presentation on the Mortgage Insurance Conference. Vilnius, Lithuania. October 2001. Merton, Robert C. (1973) Theory of Rational Option Pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol.4. Merton, Robert C. (1977) An Analytic Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantees: An Application of Modem Option Pricing Theory, Journal of Banking and Finance (June 1977). Merton, Robert C. and Zvi Bodie. (1992) On the Management of Financial Guarantees. Financial Management. Vol. 21, No. 4. Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment. (2001) What People Want, Where People Live: Housing in the 21st Century. The Netherlands. Moody's Investors Services. (2002) Sofol Mortgage Companies - Well Positioned Intermediaries in the Mexican Mortgage Market. Global Credit Research. Pauly, Mark V. (1974) Overinsurance and Public Provision of Insurance: The Roles of Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.88, No.1. PD&R Issue Brief. (1995) America's Homeowners Need FHA. HUD Reinvention: From Blueprint to Action. U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. Penner, Rudolph G. and William L. Silber. (1973) The Interaction between Federal Credit Programs and the Impact on the Allocation of Credit, The American Economic Review, Vol. 63, No. 5. Pennington-Cross, Anthony and Anthony M. Yezer. (2000) The Federal Housing Administration in the New Millennium, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 11. Pennington-Cross, Anthony and Joseph Nichols. (2000) Credit History and the FHAConventional Choice, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 28, No. 2. - 192 - Posch, Brigitte and Philip Kibel. (2002) Sociedad Hipotecaria Federal: Does the Mortgage Partial Guarantee Work? The Proof is in the Pudding. Moody's Investors Service, Special Report. Quigley, John M. and Robert Van Order. (1991). Defaults on Mortgage Obligations and Capital Requirements for U.S Savings Institutions. Journal of Public Economics Vol. 44. Rodda, David T., K. Lam and A. Youn. (2004) Stochastic Modeling of FHA HECMs with Low-Cost Refinancing, Abt Associates Inc. Rosenthal, S..S., J.V. Duca and S.A. Gabriel. (1991) Credit Rationing and The Demand for Owner-Occupied Housing, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol.30. Rossi, Peter and Eleanor Weber. (1996) The Social Benefits of Homeownership: Empirical Evidence from National Surveys, Housing Policy Debate, Vol.7, No.1. Schiffer, Karel. (2002) Dutch Guarantee Fund for Homeownership: Model for a Single Guarantee Fund for the European Union? Presentation on EuroCatalyst conference, Madrid, September 22-24. Schuetz, Jenny, Eric S. Belksy, and Nicolas P. Retsinas. (2004) The State of Mexico's Housing 2004, Special Report Prepared for CIDOC and CONAFOVI, by Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University. Shear, W.B. and A.M. Yezer. (1983) An Indirect Test for Differential Treatment of Borrowers in Mortgage Markets, AREUEA Journal, Vol.10. Softec. (2003) The Mexican Housing Overview 2003. Mexico City: Prisa, S.A. de C.V. Spence, Michael and Richard Zeckhauser. (1971) Insurance, Information, and Individual Action, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 61. Stiglitz Joseph E., and Andrew Weiss. (1981) Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information, American Economic Review 71(3): 393-410. Struyk, Raymond and Douglas E. Whiteley. (2002) Mortgage Default Insurance In the U.S.: Implications for Russia. The Urban Institute Project 07274-050-00. Titman, S. and W.N. Torous. (1989) Valuing Commercial Mortgages: An Empirical Investigation of the Contingent Claims Approach to Pricing Risky Debt, The Journal of Finance, Vol.44. Tiwari, Piyush. (2001) Home Mortgage Risk: A Case for Insurance in India, International Real Estate Review, Vol.4, No.1. - 193 - Vandell, Kerry. D. (1978) Default Risk Under Alternative Mortgage Insurance Instruments, Journal of Finance, Vol. 33, No. 5. Vandell, Kerry. D. (1992) Predicting Commercial Mortgage Foreclosure Experience, AREUEA Journal, Vol.20, No.1. Vandell, Kerry. D. (1995) How Ruthless Is Mortgage Default? A Review and Synthesis of the Evidence, Journal of Housing Research, Vol.6 No.2. Vandell, Kerry. D. and Thomas Thilbodeau. (1985) Estimation of Mortgage Defaults Using Disaggregate Loan History Data, AREUEA Journal, Vol.13, No.3. Weicher, John. (1992) FHA Reform: Balancing Public Purpose and Financial Soundness, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 5, No. 2. WEW Annual Financial Report, 2003. WEW Special Report. (2004) Government Guarantees in the Rental and OwnerOccupied Sector: an International Comparison 2004. Stichting Waarborgfonds Eigen Woningen. World Bank. (2002) Mexico's Low Income Housing: Issues and Options. Volume I: Main Report. Report No. 22534-ME. Zaltzman, Mark. (2003) Mexican Mortgage Market - Access to Housing, Housing Finance International, Vol. 18, No. 2. Websites: The FHA's website: http://www.hud.gov/offices/hsg/hsgabout.cfm The FHA Mutual Mortgage Insurance Fund Annual Audit Reports: http://www.hud.gov/offices/hsg/hsgrroom.cfm The Dutch Foundation Homeownership Guarantee Fund (WEW) website: http://www.nhg.nl The Mexican Federal Mortgage Corporation (SHF) website: http://www.shf.gob.mx/ - 194 -