.^^CHL yP^\ UBRARIES -X' Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/verticalanalysisOOcaba ii«:wtr Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts A Institute of "Verticar'Analysis of Crises and Intervention: Fear of Floating and |x-Ante Problems Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishnamurthy Working Paper 01 -25 Julys, 2001 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge fronn the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn. conn/paper.taf?abstract id= 276673 This MASSACHUSEHS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY AUG 1 5 2001 LIBRARIES Massachusetts Institute of Technology Departnnent of Economics Working Paper Series A "Verticar'Analysis of Crises and Intervention: Fear of Floating and Ex-Ante Problems Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishnamurthy Working Paper 01 -25 Julys, 2001 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at This http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf2abstract id= 276673 Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts A Institute of "Vertlcar'Analysis of Crises and Intervention: Fear of Floating and Ex-Ante Problems Ricardo Caballero J. Arvind Krishnamurthy Working Paper 01 -25 July Room 5, 2001 E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssrn Com/paper.taf?abstract id=xxxxxx This A "Vertical" Analysis of Crises and Intervention: Fear of Floating and Ex-ante Problems Ricardo J. Arvind Krishnamurthy* Caballero This draft: July 05, 2001 Abstract Emerging economies are prone crises, choice to crises triggered by external shocks. During these should the central bank stabilize the currency or domestic interest rates? We argue that these questions are best analyzed in a "vertical" framework, where the supply of external funds faced by the country and monetary policy crisis This liquidity. elastic at the is in affects (now higher) international crisis This asymmetry naturally However, while has negative ex-ante consequences as it this response is ex-post exacerbates the structiually insufficient private sector incentives to insure against crises. Ex-ante, optimal is countercyclical, and increasingly so as lining for countries with limited financial come this conservative-central-bank role of monetary policy financial development development that cannot time inconsistency problem, in the vertical view is one of incentives, (or Keywords: EO, E4, E5, FO, F3, F4, well as The it silver should not) over- main can be substituted crises. Gl External shocks, domestic and international liquidity, monetary policy, interest parity departures, 'Respectively: falls. monetary that since the is by ex-ante measures to induce the private sector to insure against JEL Codes: is has relatively limited output consequences, while leads to the widely observed fear of floating. it inelastic during In this vertical view, raising interest rate. not doing so causes a sharp exchange rate overshooting. rationalizable, is mostly the domestic cost of scarce international contrast to the standard "horizontal" framework where supply domestic interest rates during a policy the outside the central bank's control, as in a currency board, are there good is policy substitutes? the If exchange rate systems, overshooting. MIT and NBER; seminar participants at Northwestern University. We Brown and MIT. Caballero thanks thank Raghu Rajan the NSF caball@mit.edu, a-krishnamurthy@nwu.edu. First draft: April 11, 2001. for financial for comments, as support. E-mails: Introduction 1 Emerging economies are prone to crises triggered should the central bank stabilize the value of choice its by external shocks. During these crises, currency or domestic interest rates? the If outside the central bank's control, as in a currency board, are there good policy is substitutes? Uniformly, the analysis of these questions begins by describing the external shock as an upward shift in interest rate. the interest parity condition: a rise in the country-premium or international We depart at the outset and argue that for most emerging economies, this "horizontal" approximation of the external supply of funds (unlimited funds available at a high and fixed price) this view, that is misleading for the questions at hand. an emerging economy mired in an external The crisis proposition, implicit in could attract capital flows by adopting an expansionary monetary pohcy, seems counterfactual Instead, elastic what during the context, is needed at best. a 'Vertical" approximation, where the supply of funds is is in- the country faces an international liquidity constraint. In this crisis as monetary policy predominantly affects the domestic cost of the scarce international Expansionary monetary policy brings about a sharp overshooting in the exchange liquidity. rate depreciation, without any substantial gain in terms of real activity. In contrast, con- monetary policy servative A modern central stabilizes the bank concerned with by tightening during the crisis. observed "fear of floating" The exchange rate, its inflation vertical among emerging with little additional output loss. target will respond to this view thereby accounts natturally for the it during external of crises. we show that if the central bank could should in most circumstances pledge expansionary policy Importantly, the optimality of the latter stems not from the impact monetary pohcy during a efi"ect it crisis, it is exacerbates the structural underinsurance problem that a- icts emerging economies. Quite the contrary, conamit to a monetary policy, widely economies. While a contractionary monetary policy may appear as optimal during the not from an ex-ante perspective as asymmetry as the standard argument has crisis, it, but from the ex-ante the policy has on the incentive to insure against episodes of international liquidity scarcity. When demand firms in need of international resources face domestic financial constraints, their for international liquidity is constrained as well. financial constraints generate 'See Calvoand Reinhart a wedge between the marginal value of the international (2000) and among emerging economies with In equilibrium, these domestic Hausmann flexible et al (2001) for extensive exchange rate regimes. re- documentation of fear of floating and the market price sources to the domestic firms of these resources. This underpricing reduces the private sector's incentive to carry international hquidity into crisis-states and hence insure against crises (see CabaJlero and Krishnamurthy (2001a)). Expansionary mon- etary pohcy, while not directly alleviating the international financial constraint constraint during an external crisis — increases domestic reward of maintaining international monetary policy is to The time liquidity. Thus liquidity —the main and hence the private in the vertical view, the only role of affect the private sector's incentives to manage international liquidity. consistency problem that arises in the vertical context, coupled with the in- stitutional conservatism of monetary policy will modern independent central banks, suggests that in practice be rarely used for incentive purposes. This bias increases the underin- surance problem, in particular in those economies with more limited financial development (i.e. where firms face tighter financial constraints). The that there are substitutes for the international liquidity is policy. Since the primitive problem is economies silver lining for these management role of monetary one of underinsurance, either direct or indirect ex- ante measures that induce the economy to carry more international liquidity into crises states reduce the underinsurance problem. management, all For example, an active international reserve capital controls, or procyclical international liquidity ratio requirements, can substitute for monetary policy. Conversely, a credible monetary policy during crises is commitment to a countercyclical a good substitute for costly capital controls and ex-ante measures. The distinction we draw between international and domestic liquidity, coupled with the association of monetary policy to the latter, also offers a different perspective on several sues related to liquidity policy within different exchange rate regimes. The policy in a currency board or other inflexible exchange rate systems, ically, is not a serious impediment during crises. binding international financial constraint and thus currency board during a is instead due to the perverse ex-ante crisis generates; As before, these can largely irrelevant. eff'ects monetary somewhat paradox- Monetary policy does is loss of is- little to relax the The problem with a that the lack of credit expansion be handled with ex-ante measures.^ Within our perspective, international contingent credit lines are desirable regardless of the exchange rate regime, and thus should not be thought of as a substitute for domestic icy in a dollarized economy. ^Our analysis is meant to They monetary pol- are primarily about relaxing international rather than isolate the liquidity and financial market aspects of monetary policy. In so doing, we eliminate the important but better understood goods-labor markets dimensions of monetary and exchange rate in policy. All the conclusion. our remarks must be understood in this context. We briefly return to these issues domestic financial constraints, and flexible and it is the latter rather than the former that differentiates exchange rate regimes from a liquidity management perspective.^ fixed Section 2 presents the basic model and highlights the differences between the tradi- and the tional horizontal Our model rate overshooting and the related fear of floating. clear distinction The vertical emergence of exchange vertical analyses, including the natural between two forms of liquidity designed to establish a is international (collateral): view highlights the fact that during external crises it is and domestic. the former that is —such as monetary policy— cannot have binding and hence measures to relax the latter a significant immediate impact. The horizontal perspective, on the other hand, draws no distinction between these Section 3 asks two forms of liquidity. how ex-ante private icy measures and, in turn, how sector financing decisions are affected by ex-post pol- answer leads to the design of optimal this policies. We show that domestic financial underdevelopment implies that in equilibrium the private sector undervalues international liquidity and insurance. monetary policy reduces the extent A credible commitment to a While of this undervaluation. this countercyclical would appear to be a damaging criticism of dollarized regimes, we argue that this need not be the case since the primitive problem is one of distorted incentives rather than one of insufficient and the former can be resolved by alternative means. liquidity, Section 4 summarizes our message in the context of a standard political sion of rules-versus-discretion. We show that while if it is less all possible, commitment conservative than it Section 5 concludes and proofe of our between discusis a the vertical perspective inflexibility, in neither an inflation bias nor an advantage of ex-post flexibility. Quite the contrary, were at to be economy in the horizontal perspective there standard tension between inflation bias and ex-post there domestic main financial will is propositions. be in the vertical region be during a crisis. by two appendices. The inclined to followed would require the central bank The second one is more substantive. market development and international liquidity the main text, the monetary channel we superimpose on it is is first one contains the While the interaction explicitly reduced-form. modeled in The second appendix sketches a debt-deflation model of this monetary channel. See the recent work by Diamond and Rajan (2001) for a related perspective on financial crises based on two potentially binding constraints: a solvency and a liquidity constraint. Their analysis focuses on the ex-post effect of interventions during crises and, in particular, on the perils of pohcies that the binding constraint during the crisis. fail to identify The 2 Vertical we describe the environment and In this section and View and the Fear vertical views of crises. vertical We of Floating discuss the difference between horizontal show that when domestic financiaJ markets are illiquid, the view imphes that the exchange rate overshoots in response to monetary pohcy and central banks are naturally led to adopt a fear of floating strategy. Basic setup 2.1 We study an economy exposed to an external financial country's risk-adjusted international cost of is followed by a final date 2 with a date 0, which is when a fully period when make agents and precautionary decisions. The periods are indexed by f = rise occurs at date crisis We repay their outstanding debts. firms' flexible The capital.'' by the triggered crisis, of the and 1, start time investment, financing, 0,1,2, and there a single is (tradeable) good. There in the form foreigners rate Iq of receivables arriving at date (e.g., and w a unit measure of domestic firms, each endowed with is i| These date 2 goods have 2. prime exports), who axe willing to lend against from period to 1, and 1 units of collateral, collateral value to and at dates it to 2, respectively. Foreigners play 1 at no other the role in our model. Domestic firms also have access to a production technology. Building a plant of size k at date requires them to invest c(fc) — with > c{.) 0, cf > and 2 output proportional to the size of the plant (see below). resources at date 0, The expected plant profits at date 2. financing Since domestic firms have no and investment decisions To keep matters simple, we run by a domestic entrepreneur/ manager who has consumption — which yields date > they must import the capital goods and borrow from foreigners, to finance this investment. is c" shall axe taken to maximize assume that each firm risk neutral preferences over date 2 their expected output of the single good. Firms face significant financial constraints. Neither the plants nor axe valued as collateral by foreigners. When real investments are undertaken, firms a part of their international collateral in securing foreign funds. All financing fully collateralized debt contracts, thus, do,/ ^ is mortgage done via ^• 'Nearly the same analysis applies to a sharp decline binding. do,/, in terms of trade that makes financial constraints Date 2.2 For the remainder of the section, We focus on the crisis period. lending rate, 2| let Crises us take as given all date define a crisis as an event in decisions which a how financial constraints — k and rise in causes financial constraints to bind for firms. Let us , the financing need and explaining In our and financing needs 1 to defining to bind. economy the financing need stems from the normal ongoing maintenance of the productive structure. We capture this feature by simply assuming that the plants of one- from half of the firms receive a production shock at date 1 that lowers output per plant to a. This productivity decline can be 2 output oflFset by reinvesting 9k {9 We assume say that a crisis occurs A— 1 > i^. if much as possible to finance reinvestment. firms are curtailed in their date If this is shock, the firm first borrows against its is from foreigners. After this, it their fi-om foreigners vP if Our said to be distressed. is To cope with the = 10 — do J must turn to the domestic firms that did not receive 1 either, so they they are to finance the distressed firms. This they can do of financial slack. But why would intact firms lend to distressed firms assume that domestics value as either, any more than foreigners? collateral the firm's installed assets as well. a perfectly functioning domestic financial market economy 1. the case in equilibrium (see the appendix). a shock ("intact firms") for funds. Intact firms have no output at date must borrow shall <1, despite the reinvestment, 9 1 We net international collateral: u;" up to A—1 > the case, then firms are financially constrained at date firm that receives an idiosyncratic shock directly goods, to give date A=A-a. where assumptions on parameters are such that this A 1) that the return on reinvestment exceeds the international interest rate: This means that firms will borrow as fact that < A of, A{9)k={a + 9A)k<Ak, zj. — and the international now turn may come do,/ and this departure has is We However, since hardly a good description of an emerging central implications for our analysis, we assume that only a fraction of the output from domestic investment can be pledged to other domestics. It will simplify the formulae, without loss of insight, to make output: Xak. Since firms can use this collateral to borrow Xak as domestic liquidity.^ Likewise, since at date "Since we do not want insurance markets to is up to this minimum amount, we refer to firms can borrow from foreigners undo the ex-post shocks are non-observable and non-contractible. Moreover, pooling equihbrium 1 this a fraction of heterogeneity, we assume up to we assume that idiosyncratic that the coordination-fragile ex-ante not feasible (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2001b)). we w"' of international collateral, refer to u;" as the international liquidity After pledging u;" to foreigners, distressed firms pledge their who Xak during the to intact domestics, in turn pledge their ty" to foreigners to access foreign funds. All direct foreigners is done at the interest rate of crisis. borrowing from i|. The (standard) Horizontal VieAv 2.3 In the standard horizontal view, distressed firms are constrained in meeting their financing They have needs only to the extent that they have limited collateral. Xak + w'^ which they borrow against at the interest rate of total collateral of i^. Translated into our context, the horizontal view implicitly assumes that the country as a whole, at the margin, has an international liquidity slack. In other words, a foreigner would be willing to extend another loan at firms have limited collateral, it is to some domestic firm. happens that the worthy firm In our model, since intact firms borrow firms against Xak, there i| is |to" > since distressed not distressed. from foreigners against excess international liquidity But xv" and lend to distressed if, ^Xak. (1) Since intact firms are not saturating their international financial constraint, the interest rate they charge on the loan to a distressed firm, against domestic collateral of Xak, is simply determined by the arbitrage condition: - Total reinvestment is ^i = il then determined by the individual firms' financial constraints: ,,,^rul±X^^2^^^ ^''<1, (2) where the superscript h denotes the horizontal equilibrium. The inequality in the main expression reflects that the economy has not used indicates that the economy is all its international liquidity, while 6^ in a crisis: distressed firms are unable to meet all < I financing needs because of the binding financial constraint. We refer to this as the horizontal view, the quantity of them. interest rate ^|, A is not affected by distressed firm could in principle continue borrowing at the given as long as an experiment where A because the price of loans is its domestic financial constraint raised slightly, leading to increased loans at ij we would is if we imagine relax the domestic collateral constraint, and increased reinvestment. after introducing the vertical view. relaxed. Thus, We return to this discussion 2.4 The Vertical View In this view, the international supply of funds that external crises is vertical - faced by emerging economies during The country has enough domestic inelastic.^ i.e. is collateral to aggregate the international liquidity available to agents in the economy, so that inequality 11 (1) is reversed: < -Xak. -u;" However, there of the is insufficient international liquidity in the economy's needs so that the economy - > 2 When is still i| (see the for all in a crisis: 1+iJ on loans against domestic the above conditions hold, the interest rate departs from aggregate to raise finance collateral appendix for restrictions on primitives). Since intact firms, and not foreigners, accept as collateral the Xak, and intact firms are borrowing up to their maximum capacity from foreigners and lending to distressed firms, the domestic price of a dollar-loan, if, rises above z|: ii>ii. Importantly, the fact that the international liquidity constraint does not mean that the domestic collateral is binding at the margin problems that dominate the horizontal approach disappear. This observation will be central in understanding the desirability monetary policy. As we show below, as long as domestic firms continue to strained, the domestic (dollar) interest rate is less and impact of be credit con- than the marginal product of investment for the distressed firm: if<A-l. This is collateral, the rate at date and is 1 on a one-period domestic loan against a unit of domestic both the dollar cost of capital for firms in need of funds, as well as the expected return on loans for collateral of distressed firms domestic lenders. and the amount of international liquidity of intact ones. The aggregate collateral of distressed firms intact firms in exchange for date there is determined by both, the amount of It is 1 is Xak/2. Thus they pledge Xak/2 of date 2 goods to goods of w"/2. If domestic collateral is not too limited, a scarcity price for the international hquidity, and the price needed to clear the domestic loan market, if, will exceed the international interest rate, ^ak d '^ W^/{l+il] "See Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2001a). l>tl i*: (3) This expression highlights the effect of domestic collateral and international liquidity on date 1 cost of capital. A shortage of the latter former means that the cost of capital investment at date 1 (A): ij < A— means that will generally be if less > zj; while a shortage of the than the marginal product of 1. In other words, in the aggregate, a shortage of international liquidity yields a spread between domestic marginal product and international cost of on the other hand, determines the sharing of this capital. Domestic collateral, spread between domestic lenders and borrowers of a marginal dollar. In this region, domestic collateral plays no role in determining aggregate reinvestment. In equilibrium, all international liquidity is e^k where the superscript v stands 2.5 Date i 1 monetary aggregated, so that reinvestment = is: 2t(;" (4) 1+iV for vertical equilibrium. policy, overshooting, and fear of floating d w"/(l+i,*) Figure As an introduction 1 : Vertical and Horizontal Supply to our discussion of monetary policy, the main distinction between the vertical and horizontal views can be seen by considering the experiment of increasing 8 collateral) by A (boosting domestic On a small amount. 1 illustrates this diflFerence. the vertical axis we measure the domestic dollar-interest rate on loans against domestic On collateral. the horizontal axis we capture domestic represent efTective (collateralized) loan the supply is horizontal {d) Note that in and demand from distressed firms in regions the horizontal case a shift in an increase in where vertical {d'). demand (say by increasing A) investment, while leaving the domestic price of loans unaffected. vertical region, The loans or domestic reinvestment. supply of loans from intact firms, d and solid flat-and- then- vertical curve correspond to the d' Figure On raises date 1 the other hand, in the has no effect on equilibrium investment, and instead only d' pushes up the domestic interest rate of if. Let us take a reduced form approach to monetary policy whereby the central bank can indeed affect A (see the appendix for an explicit model of this channel). chooses a combination of peso-interest rates, by the (domestic) The and expected appreciations, ij, (61 central bank — 62), traced interest parity condition:^ ii=^? + (ei-l), where A can be written as A(z^, ej), and without Most models with a monetary channel models and scenarios. domestic collateral by raising we will take the liabilities (i.e., < 0, latter we have set 62 = 1. while the sign of Agj varies across is positive, or not too negative, a reduction in domestic peso-rates) also expands A. above configuration as our reference case, although in the conclusion discuss briefly the case of Ae domestic yield Ajp However, as long as the an expansionary monetary pohcy We loss of generality, — as this is « —^perhaps capturing an extensive dollarization of one of the main reasons given in the literature to prefer constrained monetary regimes over more flexible monetary arrangements.^ It to notice, nonetheless, that our main argument is is important very distinct from the issues raised in this debate. The tradeoff of the in this context. (increases A), An monetary authority in the horizontal perspective expansionary monetary policy relaxes the domestic financial constraint and by doing so it increases investment (see (2)): de^k ak dX ~ 'By domestic can be understood interest parity condition we mean l + il' the relationship between the return on peso and dollar instruments backed by domestic collateral. See appendix A3. ^See, e.g., Aghionetal (2000), Gertleretal. (2001), Cespedes et al. (2000), and Christiano et al. (2000).} The standard tradeoff is that this investment increase must be weighed against the inflationary costs brought about In the midst of a by the monetary expansion and exchange and within a reasonable range, the crisis, dominated by the output gains of the expansionary Our main and opposed to the domestic and output from noticing that the weights in the vertical region. closely related reasons. First, since the latter costs are likely to be policy.^ results in this section follow directly above tradeoff change abruptly rate depreciation. This happens main binding constraint is for in the two important the international as collateral constraint, relaxing the latter does not affect reinvestment (see (4)): 86" k -^ = Second, while all choices of i^ and '- ei that leave the the same real investment decisions, they do not from (3) we see that ii is same asset prices. In fact, ak d\ difference lead to the in the vertical region yield increasing in A: dii Thus a key all economy + u;"/(l from the horizontal region ij)' is that an increase in the (domestically determined) interest parity condition. That is, in A results in a shift in the vertical region there are two effects of an expansionary monetary policy on the exchange rate that need to be considered. There is the standard interest parity effect: Fixing if if + ei - 1 = if > in, ii, the exchange rate weakens by the same amount as the peso-interest rate this new point, A rises as well. Since if is interest parity condition shifts upwards, amount. We refer to this phenomenon is lowered. But at increasing in domestic collateral, the (domestic) and the exchange rate depreciates by a larger as exchange rate overshooting because, relative to the horizontal region, in the vertical region peso-interest rate reductions lead to proportionately larger depreciations in the exchange rate. With little direct real consequences, dictated by secondary considerations fear of floating to be an example of date 1 from the shock to i\. 1, in the vertical region (e.g., inflation targets). this. At date monetary policy We The central bank wishes may be take the widely observed to protect the exchange at the output costs to raising interest rates are minimal 'in this sense, the monetary policy problem with financial frictions in the horizontal perspective different from the standard closed economy problem applied to developed economies as Gertlerand Gilchrist (2000). 10 in, e.g., is no Bernanke, (beyond the direct costs of the external shock), and instead the action has a substantial on the exchange effect = Zj, the point where if Does this making icy, rate. The logical conclusion is to raise interest rates, lowering A to and thereby defending the exchange rate. that emerging economies should abandon countercyclical monetary pol- mean explicit what they have de-facto adopted through their fear of floating? This is one of the main questions we turn to in the next section. Optimal Policy Regime: The menu of date 0/date 3 mea- 1 sures In the vertical view, international hquidity and hence the supply of external resources to the country is agent, can Date predetermined during a do to to more on the other hand, can we show that efficient date monetary This section We affect is nothing that a central banJk, or private the date 1 external position of the country. the anticipation of an expansionary date private sector decisions. - as in a currency board? loss of There alter this reality. actions, In particular, crisis. We But what if 1 monetary policy leads monetary policy is constrained measures can substitute argue that exphcit date for the policy. ofi^ers a menu of date 0/date 1 policies that are optimally taken together. show that the conclusions one draws regarding optimal policy and the choice of also exchange rate regimes hinges crucially on separately identifying domestic and international liquidity. Structural Underinsurance 3.1 and Optimal Monetary Policy Commit- ment Let us date 1 revisit the private sector's date investment and financing decisions, taking the policy of the central bank as given. Moreover, let us for now summarize bank's policy by the value A takes, and disregard any decision that specific that date is, arise from the combination of (ii,ei) that achieves this A. To make our that may the central 1 the points, we do not depend on the presence of aggregate shocks. We aggregate conditions are fully anticipated to be those of an external economy will be in the vertical region, assume crisis — with binding financial constraints (see the appendix for parameter conditions to arrive at this scenario). Let us consider firms' incentives to precaution against the date 11 1 crisis and, particularly, how these incentives are aifected by the domestic cost of capital, ante decision to reduce date the date Precautioning is an ex- investment, borrow less of doj and save this debt capacity for Equivalently this 1 crisis. if. is a date some private decision to hoard international liquidity. The net return on On pieces. -I- goods at date is 2. composed On of two the cost side, which would have yielded a return io)c'(^) units of international liquidity the domestic financial market at date if in Ak the gross return side, the firm obtains sacrifices (1 it investing an extra unit of k for an intact firm Thus, at the margin increasing k yields an 1. ex-post return, net of opportunity cost, of A-c/{k){l It follows edness is immediately from + ii){l is (5) i*o). that the opportunity cost of increasing date (5) undervalued by an intact firm as long as external funds + if < A— 1. Since the 1 is for date 1 constrained by the distressed firms' limited domestic collateral, the value of holding on to a unit of international liquidity in order to supply date demand indebt- depressed relative to the socially efficient it to distressed firms at — and the distressed firm's — valuation, A. Now goods can be pledged as collateral in the domestic loan market at date be multiplied by the private return that each generates loan secured by Xa goods at date 2, cost side, which yield a private return of A investment in k yields a net return a ({1 It it - (its Thus 1, that firaction must A value as a collateral asset). generates proceeds of each can be reinvested at a gross return of A. — A)a-f- Aa—^. On the the gross return side, at But because a fraction A of these the margin the firm obtains a unit of goods directly. (1 On consider the same net return for a distressed firm. 7^ goods at date 1, which the gross benefit to increasing k is sacrifices (l-l-iQ)c'(A;) units of international liquidity to a distressed firm. Thus, at the margin increasing of: A) + Ay^) - c'(fc)A(l + z5). (6) follows immediately from (6) that while the cost of sacrificing a unit of international liquidity A- is properly valued by a distressed firm, the domestic investment 1, a distressed firm if < its overvalued domestic collateral. an external crisis is able to keep some is not. As long as of the surplus from reinvestment by selling A central planner, on the other hand, realizes that during only international liquidity generates social surplus, and hence discounts domestic assets at A rather than (1 '"Since the analysis above takes date + if)}^ decisions as given, the expected return 12 on domestic loans splits the Although for different reasons, both intact and distressed firms overvalue (from a point of view) domestic investment relative to its opportunity cost — namely cost in terms of the international liquidity used. Since the ex-ante decision average of these two outcomes, precaution for the date 1 based on the and under- shock. ^^ is an equilibrium problem. only in the vertical It arises region, as the supply of international funds faced by distressed firms others' actions in the horizontal region, and it policy now. Since increasing A at date commitment 1 so that zf is increases if to ex-post <A— independent of 1. in the vertical region should be apparent by and reduces the spread between the distortion caused by limited domestic collateral monetary policy commitment is stems from distorted asset prices due to - limited Xak constrains demand The optimal monetary if, is opportunity follows that firms will overinvest, overborrow it The over-borrowing problem financial constraints its social falls as A during the (i.e., 1 and Thus the optimal rises. crisis) A— choose the maximum possible A.^^ Aside from the standard inflationary concerns associated to the need for a very active monetary between ex-ante (countercyclical) and ex-post (pro-cyclical) policy, the contrast optimal policy during crises highlights an unusual commitment problem. The central bank should certainly commit to not "fear floating," but should ideally commit to exacerbate the exchange rate depreciation during a — its crisis. not credible, the incentive benefit If this is — of coimtercyclical monetary policy vanishes and only benefit in the vertical world the cure for the structural underinsurance problem must be sought elsewhere. We return to such an alternative after introducing constrained monetary regimes. reinvestment surplus, A— 1, between domestic lenders and borrowers but the economy. Total reinvestment is, the sum fully is does not affect the real side of determined by the total availability of international liquidity (that of the international collateral available to distressed (1 it + i;)^ek = ^{w - do,/) and intact firms): + ^{w-chj), to imply (in a crisis): (1 This dichotomy between the ment and portfolio decisions. one. In particular, It is this it gives real and When is il)k a domestic decides to up some of financial decision that -I- financial side disappears at date 0, its make a investment, it also their invest- makes a financial international liquidity, w, in exchange for domestic collateral, Xak. affected by if. This opens the door to international liquidity management namurthy (2000a). See real when domestics make also Harberger (1985) policies, as and Aizenman (1989), we study for alternative in Caballero and Krish- models of over-borrowing based on the undervaluation of the country's monopsony power in international financial markets. See the appendix for a formal proposition and proof of this result. 13 Constrained Monetary Regimes 3.2 One is main of the criticisms of doUarization that the central bank criticism would appear to be all the more damaging value at the time of a vertical Under the fixed exchange rate systems unable to implement countercyclical monetary is are appended to standard arguments.^'' little and other hard when policy. financial accelerator As we have argued, however, This mechanisms this policy option has crisis. vertical view, the concern with these type of exchange rate regimes is close to that of the free insurance criticism of fixed exchange rate systems, whereby the latter is perceived as a central bank subsidy on dollar-borrowing.^'^ However derinsurance does not stem from the fixed value of the exchange rate central bank's inability to optimally expand A during crises our model un- in itself, and reward but from the the hoarding of scarce international liquidity. Thus, for example even in a flexible exchange rate system, policy is not sufficiently counter-cyclical, there There is policy options emerges. crises, problem be the underinsurance problem. a "silver-lining" for constrained monetary regimes in the above discussion. the problem of doUarization during will is shifted from an ex- post to an ex-ante distortion, a new Rather than seeking hard-to-find substitutes that directly. A — (1 + ii) may set of monetary policy ^^ take commit to expand credit at date remains high, and thus the return to hoarding international hquidity until date 1 remains undervalued. liquidity for As the policymaker can introduce measures to solve the ex-ante underinsurance Recall that the problem induced by not being able to 1 is if many While in practice this undervaluation of international forms, in our simple do,/) or, equivalently, excessive investment in model it is just high external leverage (high domestic firms (high k)}^ In our environ- ment, there are two obvious ex-ante policy measures that can deal with the underinsurance problem: capital inflows taxation during normal times (date requirements at date e.g., Gertler et and international liquidity 0. These ex-ante options, of comse, are also available "See, 0), al in a flexible exchange rate system. (2001) and Cespedes et al (2001). '•See.e.g., Dooley (1999). '^Note, however, that even hard currency board systems can effectively implement some degree of monetary policy by, e.g., temporarily allowing domestic Treasury instruments denominated in dollars to count as international reserves, or relaxing the banks international liquidity ratios, as Argentina has done over the last decade. '*With a slightly richer model, in Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2000a, 2000b) we show that this un- dervaluation also leads to increased doUarization of contingent liabilities, lines. 14 increased short term debt, and insufficient To the extent that A cannot at date 1 in order to align the date move sufficiently of the central planner and private sector, perhaps as a result of the More discussed earlier, these measures are desirable. of the previous subsection tax and commitment problems generally, let us return to the analysis and characterize the relationship between the optimal ex-ante A. At the aggregate of problems '^. The level, building a marginally larger plant always generates date 2 output opportunity cost of doing this 1 at which point, since is cf{k){l + io)A. is to save this internationalliquidity until date one of the distressed or intact firms In total, the social return will be reinvesting, the return is, ^-c'{k){l+i*o)A. private and social incentives Aligning the date Suppose that the central bank policy. in a lump sum fashion. Then, from of international Hquidity as where if^. represents the As we concluded policy r = is levies (6) and a matter of choosing a tax/transfer a tax r per unit of (5), is no reason zi = A — 1, A clearly decreasing with respect to ^fr and all We is (7) and (8) coincide for not the case, the optimal few steps of algebra, and identifying the social planner's quantities with a hat, gives us that the optimal tax is returned to firms a domestic dollar-loan. for intervention at date 0. If that tax must equate these two expressions. which is domestic financial markets are well developed or monetary powerful enough so that in the absence of taxes and there which it, is: (after taxes) equilibrium cost of earlier, if k, the private sector return to hoarding a unit opposed to investing new is (7) A is: since: - ak A the social planner's quantities are independent of A. think of the above as an "iso-internationaJ Hquidity" menu: a schedule of (r, A) such that the private sector and social incentives are aligned. Thus, for example, in the case of a A that cannot respond to external shocks, as T would be beneficial. 15 is the case of a dollarized system, a positive Of course, come with in practice taxes their own of taxation, costs of enforcement, evasion, etc. measures date in our model is that if international liquidity will 1 sector hoard liquidity. — deadweight costs sets of distortions Moreover, a significant drawback of date they are not fully reversed at date more than undo the date 1 the reduction in , benefit of having the private Thus these measures do require the authority to be very responsive to economic conditions. These active along with the credibility (see above) and inflationary problems of an issues, monetary policy, need to be weighed monetary policy arrangement in to point out the existence of a exchange rate system is a in deciding of options. the optimal exchange and in this section is In contrast to prevailing views, a fixed not strictly at a liquidity disadvantage to the flexible system. This wisdom contrast arises from the fact that the prevailing perspective, while is Our main purpose specific country. menu which we argue that during severe crisis it is based on a domestic liquidity is international rather than domestic liquidity that matters the most. International Credit Lines and Reserves 3.3 International credit lines are often perceived as a necessary supplement to constrained monetary regimes. In a vertical framework, however, these lines are desirable regardless of the exchange rate regime, and thus should not be thought monetary policy in a dollarized economy. Since a in crisis the international one, any effort to loosen this constraint is of as a substitute for domestic the main binding constraint is desirable. Indeed, the usual view that credit lines are valuable in a currency board because they allow for of this. some ability to expand This argument makes credit in crises little and prevent bank runs sense in a horizontal view because, country would simply borrow the dollars to expand banking credit in be no need to have contracted ex-ante view, the country alleviate the is for a credit just a version if it crises. magagement There would the other hand, in the vertical crisis, thus the only policy that can problem are ex-ante measures to ease this constraint. ^'^ The same to international reserves could, the On line. internationally constrained in a is logic applies considerations. '^International credit lines should in principle be contracted directly by the private sector, but the underinsurance problem will do so (see we have highlighted in the core of the paper will limit the extent to which they Caballero and Krishnamurthy {2000a) of capital inflows). Of course, if it particular exchange rate arrangement in place, lack of for a related argument in the context of a sterilization the central bank or government has access to international contingent instruments that the private sector does not, domestic monetary same should use eis it it. is justified policy. 16 Again, however, this is true regardless of the by the vertical constraint rather than by the 4 Political Economy In the standard discussion of rules versus discretion in monetary policy, there between the inflation-bias costs and the ex-post tal tension and Gordon (1977), Barro Kydland and Prescott (e.g., often extrapolated to the debate on fixed versus flexible optimal system typically involves a central bank that but that commits to do In this section fails when less we show smoothing than it (1983), Rogoff (1987)). This logic exchange an that while this logic is is reversed in this case. In this context, the with some ex-post discretion is left applicable in the horizontal region, As we discussed inflationary bias nor an ex-post commitment problem rates. is would be tempted to do ex-post. -^^ external crises are of the vertical type. neither is a fundamen- flexibility benefits of discretion the vertical region the ex-post incentive for the central bank there is is it in previous sections, in to tighten excessively, so smoothing advantage. In a sense, the Partly as a result of institutional design to prevent the traditional inflationary problem and partly due to the time inconsistency issue we have described, central banks are likely to behave too conservatively during crises. If so, the exchange rate/ monetary policy combination problem, and the solution To analyze these let may have issu^, let A now depend not on the expected rate fi^om rates. For unlikely to solve the structural incentive is to be looked for among ex-ante measures. us introduce two modifications to our basic model. First, level of peso-interest rates simplicity, let us also make but on the gap between actual and this function linear and drop the exchange it: A(2? - Eoi?) = A - 77(2? - Eoi?), Second, suppose that the central bank objective at date as well as meeting its inflation target. A, 1 7? > covers both real investment, 9k, For this purpose, let the gap between actual and target inflation be proportional to the depreciation of the nominal exchange: (ei let — 1), and the central bank's objective be to maximize. 0fc-|(ei-l)2, with 4.1 a > 0. Horizontal region At date 1 the central bank takes as given expected interest rates and maximizes: max The w" -I- A(i? H - — - —a, Eoi?)afc ^ (ei - ,o l)"' discussion of fixed with escape clauses, or flexible exchange rate systems with tight inflation targets, and so on, is largely rooted in this view. 17 This yields as a which in the order condition (where the superscript first absence of aggregate shocks H denotes horizontal): we equal to the expected interest rate. Thus is obtain the standard inflation bias of the non-commitment solution: eiWithout aggregate shocks there date 1 since the latter of real investment. is fully The is ak 1 V = ---—: a 1 + >o. zj no advantage of keeping the option to devalue at anticipated and results on higher inflation but no expansion role for discretion comes from the presence of aggregate shocks and the fact that the underlying contracts cannot fully insure these expected inflation that enters into the A expression shocks away, so the the unconditional rather than the is state contingent one. Let us introduce aggregate shocks, so international interest rate The bad needs. state, is now low enough that there all is a good state of the world where the firms can fully finance their investment on the other hand, leads the economy to be in the constrained horizontal region. Starting firom the good state, in terms of real activity target. In the rate is is bad state, set as in (10). The is apparent that since the central bank gains nothing from lowering interest rates, it on the other hand, the problem The important that the expected interest rate reinvestment it is is will set e^ is difference with the now lower than Zj 1 to meet its inflation exactly as above, and the interest full , certainty (as of date 0) case, which means that A enhanced by the expansionary ex-post monetary latter establishes the = > A, and policy. standard tradeoff between the stabilization role of discre- tionary monetary policy and the inflationary bias that such option generates. 4.2 Vertical These tradeoffs change when the bad state of the world brings about a At date real 1, vertical constraint. regardless of whether this was fully anticipated or not, the central reward in lowering interest rates as reinvestment be only concerned with In this case, there is its inflation no target and set ei inflation bias as there is no longer depends on = 1 A. bank sees Thus it no will in all states of the world. no advantage of ex-post opportunistic behavior by the central bank. Leaving the central bank with ex-post discretion does not help smoothing real fluctuations. 18 — Quite the contraiy, as we described above, the optimal commitment solution the central bank to be expansionary during the bad state of the world even have any ex-post reward. but by in exchange for it If such commitment monetary to force that does not then the inflationary bias re-emerges incentives to precaution axe improved. date the ex-post impact of exists, if is policy, real fluctuations are That is, rather than smoothed by inducing the private sector to do something about them. In practice, however, especially those still it is aflFected highly unlikely that a modern independent by the standard reputation issues of and inflation — bank central prone past will be willing to follow this countercyclical recipe very actively. If so fear of floating , must be recognized as a positive statement on policy, in which case central bank discretion has little advantages and the exchange rate discussion becomes more or less moot from a liquidity provision perspective. The underinsurance problem has to be resolved by ex-ante means such as the capital taxation of the previous section. To summarize this section, the standard debate of rules versus discretion, and its appli- cation to the exchange rate selection debate, applies to countries that are reasonably well integrated to international flnancial markets {w large) and hence have crises that the horizontal region. fall into does not apply well to countries that are frequently affected by It sudden stops. Under the modern rules of independent central banking, with concerns narrow The inflation targets, inflationary bias is not the latter is problematic because itis main concern but fear of floating for is. exacerbates the structural underinsurance problems of these economies. 5 Final Remarks There are three main a sudden-stop crisis insights highlighted has hmited while the main problem ineffectiveness is will First, monetary policy during real effects since it primarily aflects domestic liquidity, this real- the large sensitivity of the exchange rate to monetary pohcy. Fear of is from this asymmetry. Second, private sector decisions tion of a sudden-stop crisis are affected crisis. analysis: one of international hquidity shortages. The dual of floating follows naturally during the by our in anticipa- by the expected actions of the monetary authority In particular, anticipation of increased domestic liquidity during a crisis induce the private sector to preserve more international liquidity for the eventual Third, since the role of monetary policy in this context is crisis. one of incentives rather than one of (international) liquidity provision, loss of monetary discretion can be substituted for with ex-ante measures that induce the private sector to save international liquidity for crises. 19 Of course there are many caveats that a stylized model like ours example, in practice expanding domestic liquidity during neous positive we have assumed that once effects. Similarly, We expand international liquidity. to monetary policy. The standard argument when nominal wages are sticky applies here as well collateral is then a devaluation may Equally styhzed many can relax this is have some contempora- in a crisis, there are assumption and even connect if much if is dollarized, crisis. are either vertical or horizontal. all crises and external borrowing becomes gradually more expensive, be- fore falling into a sharp vertical in this context is the environment may be around what to do with monetary policy is still A sudden stop phase. fairly horizontal but there central question for pohcymakers at the early stages of the crisis, is a the corner. At this stage, tightening monetary policy destroys financially jecture that this tradeoff can be analyzed in terms similar to those commitment to an aggressive to arrive is countercyclical credible, then there is little the commitment is need we have used throughout: during the horizontal phase. But not credible or feasible, then the appropriate response was advisable in our simplified of the additional financial distress liquidity, model in very much such case. In to provide a policy to tighten the costs in terms fact, sector, we already recommendation but is as taxing capital flows imposed upon the domestic private extent comparable in nature to that of the ex-ante measures Our goal has been not We con- monetary policy were the sudden stop to tighten during the early phase to protect international at date when concern that a sudden stop real constrained projects but saves international liquidity for the potential sudden stop. if In instances crises build up, going first through a horizontal phase, where domestic financial conditions tighten K the directly it the prime companies of a country are in reduce international collateral during the our assumption that no tools to of the country's international energy and telecommunications) and their debt (e.g. For subject to. that a devaluation helps the export sector linked to export firms. Conversely, the non-tradeable sector crises will is is to a large discussed. to identify the nature of the tradeoff involved and, in particular, to highhght the contrast between these tradeoffs and those identified in the traditional horizontal view. Nevertheless, in closing, for the question of what is is it worth speculating on the relevance of our perspective the optimal exchange rate system for emerging economies. We conjecture that for this purpose our distinctions are most relevant for an intermediate range countries. In fact, for countries with a history of inflation problems, the gains of currency boards probably outweigh the costs. ^^ does not change the calculation. "in addition to those we mention in Looking at crises as vertical rather At the other extreme, the text and to the strong 20 with no credibility for countries credibility anchor than horizontal it offers, some speculate problems and a precedent of good central banking, floating is probably the best choice, as long as fear of floating does not become the perceived rule. Quite the opposite, a credible commitment to a countercyclical monetary policy during crises, countries that lie in between are those with good central banking, but which - perhaps for historical reasons - are taining inflation. fear floating a good substitute for and ex-ante measures. costly capital controls The is Whether still in a currency and hence de facto give concerned with estabhshing a reputation board or not, the evidence up ex-post monetary discretion. is for con- that these countries Our analysis suggests that these countries ought to look toward ex-ante measures to balance out the incentive- based need for active monetary policy that will not take place. Indeed, for those countries with very limited financial development, which require overly-active monetary policy in order to restore adequate incentives, this advice is particularly pertinent. They may be best served by adopting a currency board and focusing efforts on improving international liquidity management in the private and public sectors. that the advantages include a lower interest rates and inflation risk premia due to the enhanced credibility in controlhng inflation, and the potential positive impact that the latter On the cost side, there is the loss of seignorage. 21 may have on financial deepening. References [1] Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee, "Currency Crises and Monetary Policy with Credit Constraints, mimeo Harvard 2000. [2] Aizenman, rowing," [3] J., "Country Risk, Incomplete Information and Taxes on International Bor- Economic Journal Barro, R., 99, and D. Gordon, "A March 1989, pp. 147-161. Theory Positive of Monetary PoHcy in a Natural Rate Model," Journal of Political Economy 91, 1983, pp. 589-610. [4] Bemanke, B., M. Gertler, tive Business Cycle and S. Gilchrist, "The Financial Accelerator in a Quantita- Framework," Handbook of Macroeconomics, Taylor and Woodford, eds., 1999. [5] Caballero, RJ. and A. Krishnamurthy, straints in a Model of "International Emerging Market and Domestic Collateral Crises," forthcoming in Journal of Con- Monetary Economics, 2001a. [6] Caballero, R.J. and A. Krishnamurthy, "Smoothing Sudden Stops," mimeo MIT, May 2001b. [7] Caballero, R.J. and A. Krishnamurthy, "International Liquidity ization [8] Pohcy Caballero, in Ilhquid Financial Markets," RJ. and A. Krishnamurthy, Calvo, G.A., and CM. NBER WP # Reinhaxt, "Fear of Floating" Steril- 7740, June 2000a. "Dollarization of Liabilities: and Domestic Financial Underdevlopment," [9] NBER WP # Management: Underinsurance 7792, July 2000b. mimeo University of Maryland, 2000. [10] Cespedes, L.F., R. Chang, and A. Velasco, "Balance Sheets and Exchange Rate Pohcy," NBER [11] Working Paper No. W7840, August 2000. Christiano, L.J., C. Gust, and J. Roldos, "Monetary Policy in a Financial Crisis,' preliminary mimeo. Northwestern, [12] Diamond, November 2000. D.W. and RG. Rajan, "Liquidity Shortages and Financial Crises," U.Chicago mimeo, June 2001. [13] Dooley, M., "Responses to Volatile Capital Flows: Controls, Asset-Liability Manage- ment and Architecture," World Bank Conference on Capital Flows, Financial and Policies, April 1999. 22 Crises [14] [15] Gertler, M., S. Gilchrist and F.M.Natalucci, "External Constraints on Monetary Policy and the Financial Accelerator," NYU Harberger, Debtor-Country Managers and Pohcymakers," A., "Lessons J.Cuddington and G.Smith for (eds.), working paper, Feb 2001. in International Debt and the Developing Countries. Washington: World Bank, 1985. [16] Hausmann, Ricardo, Ugo Panizza and Ernesto Stein, "Why do countries float the way they float?" Journal of Development Economics forthcoming (2001) [17] Kydland, F., and E. Prescott, Optimal Plans," Journal of [18] [19] "Rules rather than Discretion: Political Economy The Inconsistency of 85, 1977, pp. 473-90. Lorenzoni, G., "Excess Interest Rate Volatility in an Intennediated System of Liquidity Provision," mimeo MIT, November Rogoff, K., "A Reputational Constraint on Monetary Policy," Carnegie Rochester Con- 2000. ference Series on Public Policy 24, 1987, pp. 199-217. 23 A Appendix A.l Detailed programs, definitions and assumptions There axe three main assumptions we have made Assumption in the model: (Non-observability of Production Shock) 1 The production shock The at date 1 is idiosyncratic. identity of firms receiving the shock is private information. Assumption A domestic (Domestic Borrowing Constraint) 2 lender can only be sure that a firm will produce \ak units of goods at date production based on physical reinvestment at date Assumption 2. Any excess neither observable nor verifiable. 1 is 3 (Liquidity Bias) Foreigners lend to domestic firms only against the backing of w. Domestics lend against both w and Xak. < debt constraint with respect to foreigners of do,/ This gives a date takes on additional debt with foreigners, the date do.f 1 debt constraint + dif < w. At date 1, if a firm is: w. Since domestics lend against Xak the debt constraint for domestic lending at date 1 is, -^Jl+il)<w + -^{l+il)-d,j-doj The program for a distressed firm (PI) V^ s.t. = at date maxe,di,/,di,d the firm at date for di^d and (n) are balance sheet constraints (net marketable while constraint (Hi) reflects that firm. doj - dij - 1 in new investment must be 1 how much has only one decision: Suppose that the firm accepts claims at date making a date 1 fully assets greater contribution of (P2) V, s.t. f^ = which maxx, J is 1 than is finance will purely technological. it extend to the distressed of Xi y (face value of date 2 goods) in return financed with new external debt df w + Ak + Xi^j ~ doj + d\ f < w 24 liabilities), paid with the resources received by taking on debts of dj,/ and dij. Constraint {iv) intact firm at date i;) 9<1. [iv) An w + A{e)k - ^,{i+ii} + d,,, + doj<w + f^{i + 9k = ^^+j^^ {Hi) (i) is: dij+doj<w [i) (") Constraints 1 do,/ — d\j ,. Then, Date At date problem. distressed or intact. 0, a firm looking forward to date the decision at date Thus (P3) iVs+Vi)/2 maxk.doj do,/ <w c{k)= Market clearing in the itself as either is, s.t. Egmlibrium. can expect to find 1 (i+,5)(i+,j)- domestic debt market at date 1 (capital letters denote aggregate quantities) requires that the aggregate amount of domestic debt taken on by distressed firms is fully funded by intact firms: 1 Therefore, market clearing, Di,d determines the domestic dollar-cost of capital, An equilibrium of this respectively, prices. and prices At these Let us economy (11) Xi^d, if. and date consists of date 1 decisions, (fc, and do,/) (^,<ii,/,di,d, Xid), Decisions are solutions to the firms' problems (PI), (P2), and (P3) given if. prices, the now study = market clearing condition (11) holds. equilibrium in more detail. investment choices of the distressed firm given would choose to save as many of its (fc, Starting from date 1, consider financing and A—1 > ij, then the distressed firm do,/)- First, production units as if can. it It may borrow up to its international debt capacity, di,/ K the amount raised =w- (12) do./. from international investors, "', 1' ^ , , restructuring, k, the firm will have to access the domestic debt will choose to do this as long as A— 1 > if of capital. If the firm borrows fuUy up to , raise funds right hand than the funds needed for market to make up the shortfall. It or the return on restructuring exceeds the domestic cost its domestic debt capacity, dud and is less = it will issue debt >'ak, totalling, (13) with which to pay for imported goods of -^f^. As long as the sum of -^'^ and the side of (12) is more than the borrowing need, the 25 firm is unconstrained in its reinvestment at date 1 and all production units domestic debt capacity (and perhaps Intact firms can tender at for purchasing domestic debt. their excess international debt capacity of They will > A— moment that is is w - do,/ in return choose to do this as long as the return on domestic loans i{. 1 > and intact firms lend as much as they which its than the international debt capacity). less most exceeds the international rate, if Assvune for a In this case, the firm will borrow less than be saved. will > ij ij Then, can. A directed to the distressed firms. so that distressed firms in total borrow as much as they can, the economy can import ~ "j ' goods, necessary condition for all production units to be saved that, h^lILzA^^ We (14) shall refer to this constraint as the international liquidity constraint. (14) binds, all production units are saved. Since there relative to domestic demand for fimds, there is When neither (13) nor excess supply of funds from intact firms no international liquidity premium, and is if is equal to the international interest rate. The other extreme case market requires when both is and (13) (14) bind. Equilibrium in the domestic debt that, Xak 1 ~ + if w — dpj 1 + i^ Since (13) binds, distressed firms borrow fully up to their debt capacity. purchase this debt with all of their excess funds. Solving for _^afc w- That market is, in this case if is ^^^ if, As (14) binds, intact firms yields ^_^^ (15) do J above the international interest rate in order to clear the domestic for scarce international liquidity. transferable domestic resources owned by One half times the numerator in (15) corresponds to the distressed firms. Define the index of domestic illiqmdity as the difference between the marginal profit of saving a distressed production unit and the domestic interest rate of if. When (14) binds, this is, 5d= A-if-1, Equilibrium at date 1 can place the economy in one of four regions, classified according to view which of the two (domestic and international) liquidity constraints are binding. The horizontal not. corresponds to the case where the domestic constraint binds, and the international one does The vertical view corresponds to the case where the international constraint binds and the domestic 26 one may or on may in the text. not. sj > if and only At the aggregate if both constraints bind, and the economy level, is domestic liquidity Technical Assumption the scenario we focused with respect to other domestics since they are in aggregation; real are positive; and the domestic cost of capital of is liquidity constrained with respect to foreigners; at the individual level, firms are liquidity constrained selling all of their this investment constrained; domestic spreads is above the international interest Zj is rate. (Conditions for Crisis) 1 (13) and (14) bind in equilibrium as long as the following conditions are met. Define, ,2(l+Zo)A and, (l To ensure that in equilibrium 1 \ak +i1 ' + This comes from noting that A— + (1 .^ < .w I, = ' It is satisfied, guaranteed < k, i'^, z5)(l we jJ + A) need, > il)c{k) + w> \ak + (1+ + i\)c{k). and using the equilibrium expression that ^ak w-(l + ±i a < — il){l (1 + il)c{k)^ i*o){l A— 1 +zt) "- high relative to ij. 1. Given this assumption, 6 if 2A (A • and Welfare) In the case that Sj we show that "^l^ < step consider the h{k,X) > 0, welfare is increasing first Then we show that 0. welfare m \, is decreasing in order condition, = {1+ i;){l +ii + - A-a{l-X) A)c'(fc) 1 + -Xa = 0, z? where, ii Implicitly differentiating the = first Xak w- c{k){l + il){l order condition ^^^^ = c"(fc)(l + il) =^ dhjk.x) dX first + order condition. dm._ the 1 is and k is X. Proof: First >From < - decreasing in first + io){l k > if for example, by choosing Proposition: at the > 1 + we can z-)(l + dk sign, if + A) + (^(1 27 + A il)c'{k) ^ ;Aa {\+iif —r \ dii ) dk > it. To arrive and, A dh{k,X) Thus we conclude that ' J^ < (. ^ __A_s ..^,^,^ M + il r. 0. Consider welfare next. This can be written as, Now substituting in the market clearing condition for ^= By comparing the first ward to show that {jf~l - ^W(l + simplifies this to, zf A + h{A + a). ^S)) order condition for k in this expression to the previous one, this function is decreasing in > as long as s^ fc Thus we can 0. it is straightfor- also conclude that increasing in A in the vertical region. welfare is A. 2 Monetziry policy and domestic collateral In this appendix we sketch a model connecting monetary provide one explicit justification The mechanism we The to borrowers. constrained, firms. for linking policy to domestic collateral, and thereby A to monetary policy, as we did in the main text. on debt-deflation and the resulting transfer from lenders illustrate is based lenders will be large, less constrained firms, while the borrowers will be small, We do not introduce banks into the model, although in practice these institutions are surely affected by debt-deflation. In thismodel, a monetary system that tightens during crises has the interpretation of corresponding to an environment where there The latter We too little domestic insurance. equivalent to a decline in A in the text. is begin with the observation that tight monetary policy affects small firms more severely than large firms. before) is . Date There is a measure 5 of small firms, investment of both types builds of domestic collateral. However small firms afc' differ and a unit measure of (for i = s,l - small and large, respectively) units from large ones international collateral so that they are reliant on large firms for simplify matters, we shall assume that all in all two ways. is a reason for First, they have no investment needs. Second, to small firms are distressed at date large firms ensures that in equilibrium there large ones (exactly as 1 (this asymmetry with small firms to be (partially) insured against aggregate shocks by large firms). As firms, before, large firms borrow directly from the rest of the world to setup on the other hand, finance their date their plants. plants by borrowing from large firms, borrow from international markets. 28 who Small in turn We is introduce a role for monetary policy by assuming that done in non-contingent (on aggregate conditions) pesos and is face value of one period domestic debt that each small firm takes external shock to the foreign interest rate of ii(w), where monetary in conjunction with policy, results in a oj € {L, domestic borrowing all date at H} is 0. at Denote one period.^" At date 1 date b as the there is an the state of the world. This, nominal exchange rate of ei{uj) that satisfies the domestic interest parity condition, + i^i{uj) Thus at date 1 ei{uj) - = 1 ifiuj). the net worth of a small firm in terms of domestic collateral ak^ — b/ei(u}) Since large firms are at the other side of this transaction, and there the domestic collateral of large firms at date ak'- Monetary if either there for is the choice of is ei(uj) no aggregate uncertainty, monetary policy in this setup. in a debt-deflation channel for date +Sb/ei{uj). 1, The or rigidity if is w— do,/- Sk^+^k'< 1, L the debt We is contingent on state, there is no role transfers resources from large firms (domestic is Sk^ il is +-^k'-. The international low enough so that these is, shall Xa>l + and ^~J°j^y on the other hand, we ei, one on the debt repayment, resulting assrune that in the 7f-state, assume the economy iliH). is in the "crisis" equilibrium: with,22 much of the debt-deflation rather than relying on ^"^°-f l monetary policy economics, we do not address the issue of issue course, borrowers)."' ggy + Vfc'2 ^"As in Of in the latter expression. fully is we introduce monetary policy that investment needs are met by each firm. That hi the debt the total investment need of both small and large firms liquidity of the country 9\e' < firm's given the domestic interest parity condition. Note that lenders) to small firms (domestic date At date a unit measure of large firms, a private decision of the small and large firms respectively. pwlicy is is 1 is, To save notation, we have substituted the small domestic debt is, why + i*i{L)' literature, as well as in much of monetary the private sector does not write contingent contracts —or suffering from — the central bank. We are currently working on this and conjecture that adding an extra layer of segmentation, now among domestics, will allow us to address this deficiency more adequately. ^'See, e.g., Lorenzoni (2000) for a 5 = small S model of debt deflation in the context of an interbank market. corresponds to the model we analyzed in the main text. so that parameters lead to the situation we 29 analyze. It is always possible to choose a Since both large and small firms (3) gives us market clearing of their domestic collateral in the market, the analogue of sell all of, S{ak^-b/e,(L)) + ^(ak' + Sb/e,(L)) ., . j{w -do,/) 25a^lt£^^:^^Z£iI^(i+..(^))_i ',y-,, - = From the L What policy we can This dependence state. during expression last has happened? loose, ei(L) falls, firms. ^'' Since is amount of depreciation increasing in the if rises As monetary policy is the tightens (i.e., ei(L) is not allowed to depreciate) In contrast, toward the marginal product of rate is A — firms, in 1. a domestic insurance mechanism. Since date based on the expectations of exchange rate in both H borrowing from and L optimal states, policy will call for a strong exchange rate in the i/-state, while a depreciated one in the L-state. policy is not sufficiently expansionary in the L-state versus the //-state, there insurance. 0, it The latter depresses the eflFective The many Gertler of the limited domestic and hence, et al (2001), or is Chang date (money) is et al. rate. We draw this association see this, consider adding 1, the price of for fairly standard - is it either that in our money because the price of the nominal money. Since domestics only hold is linked to the price of domestic an infinitesimal amoimt of an agent that demands money, lends against domestic collateral, and has international collateral of solves at date is However, the one deviation (2000)). determined by domestics and their demand domestic collateral and money at date To mechanism through which the central For the most part the connection limited collateral in the vertical region does affect if and in turn the exchange rate/domestic interest collateral. at illiquidity. papers exploring the accelerator mechanism are not explicit about model, the fact that there asset explicit about the affects interest rates/exchange rates. indeed (e.g. for international collateral If interest parity condition Throughout the paper we have not been bank demand is reduces the incentive to precaution against shortages in aggregate international A. 3 if and resources are transferred from large intact firms to small distressed model the exchange small to large firms in equivalent to our A function in the main text. on net these resources loosen the financial constraint on investing equilibrium, hi this clearly see that if the amount of effective insurance from large to small firms declines. crises, is is (16) V- . w (say a bank). This agent 1, maix{v{in/ei) + m/eo + xif s.t. x + m/ei<w}. ^'Resources are also transferred away from large distressed firms, but since these firms have the same marginal product as the small firms at date 1, 30 this is a zero-sum transfer. Where v{-) is demand for real money balances. Normalizing 62 v'{m/ei) Monetary policy ?i = v'{m/ei) — is 1 + ei = = 1, this gives the F.O.C., if. the choice over m, which from this expression results in a vmique gives the parity condition we have used throughout the 31 text. ei. Setting -,Ri'.^ ni6 Date Due Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02246 0882