MIT LIBRARIES 661^ 3 9080 01917 Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/countryportfolioOOkraa DE\A/BY Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series COUNTRY PORTFOLIOS^ Bank Aart Kraay, The World Norman Loayza, Banco Central de Chile and The World Bank Luis S erven, The World Bank Jaume Ventura, MIT Working Paper 00-16 July 2000 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssm.com/paper.taf?abstract id=XXXXXX iNSTlTUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 'M^^'CHUSETTS OCT 2 5 LIBRARIES Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series COUNTRY PORTFOLIOS^ Bank Aart Kraay, The World Norman Loayza, Banco Central de Chile and The World Bank Luis Serven, The World Bank Jaume Ventura, MIT Working Paper 00-16 July 2000 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://papers.ssm.conVpaper.taf/abstract id=XXXXXX at Abstract How do countries hold their financial on capital located at countries from 1966 home and to 1997. wealth? We construct a new database of countries' claims abroad, and international borrowing and lending, covering 68 We find that a small amount of capital poor countries. Countries' foreign asset positions are remarkably form of foreign loans rather than foreign equity. To persistent, and mostly take the model of intemafional capital flo9ws that highlights between diminishing returns, production risk and sovereign risk. We show that in interpret these facts, the interplay we build flows from rich countries to a simple the presence of reasonable diminishing returns and production risk, the probability that international crises occur twice a century is enough to generate a set of counfry portfolios that are roughly consistent with the data. *We thank Mark Aguiar, Daron Acemoglu, Lucas and Mark Wright for insightful Giancarlo Corsetti, Raquel Fernandez, Robert E. comments on Ferretti for his advice in the construction a previous draft and Gian Maria Milesi- of our dataset. We are also grateful to Cesar Calderon, Alex Karaivanov, George Monokroussos, and Rashmi Shankar for excellent research assistance. The opinions expressed here are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its executive directors, or the countries they represent. Financial support from the Regional Studies Program of the Latm American Region of the World Bank is gratefully acknowledged. Introduction How do description of country portfolios main features. By country how it is Our countries hold their financial wealth? objective we portfolio, we the net foreign assets of a country, seem to net foreign asset positions? refer to the country's holdings of foreign equity is equity? With the answers at hand, To determine we go of to the theory and 1997 and includes 68 countries account trade. Constructing this them and draw from this regularities 1 . we fill in for database forces us make the gaps.^ Despite data are robust. highlight here. In fact, The How persistent are and ask: we Why? construct a there this, is over 90 percent of world production to choose among fragmentary and (heroic?) assumptions on we 20 percent in to we nothing subtle about the empirical following are all very striking features of the data: in absolute value and negative for most countries. Roughly 80 percent of the observations whose how feel confident the inferences Net foreign asset positions as a share of wealth are small consist of countries new Our sample covers the period 1966- loans. imperfect sources of information and then reconcile country characteristics domestic equity and loans, and domestic residents' holdings of foreign equity that We first turn to the the relative importance of foreign loans and the main features of country portfolios, database on foreigners' holdings and What positive net foreign asset positions? What and domestic capital and various foreign assets. By large are net foreign asset positions? be associated with of their refer to the financial wealth of the country and loans minus foreigners' holdings of domestic equity and loans. How to provide a and advance a parsimonious explanation distributed across holdings of data and ask: is in our sample net foreign assets as a share of wealth are less than absolute value. We also find that the net foreign negative for about 80 percent of the observations in asset position is our sample. See Sinn [1990], Rider [1994] and Lane and Milesi-Ferretti [1999] for alternative sources of data on foreign asset positions. ^ Introduction How do description of country portfolios main features. By country how it is seem to we portfolio, the net foreign assets of a country, and loans minus net foreign asset positions? we What is of their and refer to the country's holdings of foreign equity and loans. What We first turn to the country characteristics positive net foreign asset positions? equity? With the answers at hand, To determine to provide a domestic capital and various foreign assets. By large are net foreign asset positions? be associated with is refer to the financial wealth of the country foreigners' holdings of domestic equity How objective and advance a parsimonious explanation distributed across holdings of data and ask: Our countries hold their financial wealth? How persistent are the relative importance of foreign loans and we go to the theory and ask: Why? the main features of country portfolios, we construct a new database on foreigners' holdings of domestic equity and loans, and domestic residents' holdings of foreign equity and 1997 and includes 68 countries account and trade. Constructing this that them and draw from this regularities 1 . we fill in for database forces us imperfect sources of information and then reconcile Our sample covers the period 1966- loans. make the gaps.^ Despite data are robust. highlight here. In fact, The there this, is over 90 percent of world production to choose among fragmentary and (heroic?) assumptions we 20 percent in we nothing subtle about the empirical following are all very striking features of the data: in absolute value and negative for most countries. Roughly 80 percent of the observations whose to feel confident the inferences Net foreign asset positions as a share of wealth are small consist of countries on how in our sample net foreign assets as a share of wealth are less than absolute value. We also find that the negative for about 80 percent of the observations net foreign asset position in is our sample. See Sinn [1990], Rider [1994] and Lane and Milesi-Ferretti [1999] for alternative sources of data on foreign asset positions. ^ 2. There is a strong positive relationship between financial wealth and the net foreign asset position when in a cross-section of countries. financial wealth doubles, the by three to seems six even The share of net foreign assets a R^ of 93 percent. Since variation in wealth, it changes wealth increases in net foreign asset a set of variables that are designed to capture wealth is very persistent over time. seems reasonable A simple lagged value delivers a slope coefficient of 0.98 and its we in find that to between 40 percent and 70 percent of the conclude that persistence important source of persistence 4. find that financial wealth net foreign assets can be attributed to in in we aggregate production functions. in regression of this share on in sense) most of the variation after controlling for cross-country differences 3. share of net foreign assets percentage points. Cross-country variation to explain (in a statistical positions, In particular, in changes in relative in relative wealth is an foreign assets. Gross foreign asset positions are small and consist mostly of foreign loans rather than foreign equity. In developing countries, foreign equity assets and liabilities are roughly 0.3 and 2.8 percent of wealth, while foreign loan assets and account for 4.5 percent equity assets and liabilities foreign loan assets To sum up, and 8.8 percent and of wealth. In industrial countries, foreign are roughly 3.3 and 3.9 percent of wealth, while liabilities we observe liabilities account for 1 1 percent of wealth each. that net foreign asset positions are small relative to wealth and tend to be negative, except for a few rich countries. These net foreign asset positions are remarkably persistent as a fraction of wealth, and mostly consist of foreign loans rather than foreign equity holdings. This picture that the data is so clear that we think it emerges from should constitute the main target of any successful theory of international capital flows. It seems safe to argue that such a theory requires at least two ingredients. To explain the strong positive association between wealth positions, the theory must contain at least one force and net foreign asset that creates incentives for capital to move from poor countries. Natural candidates for rich to and country-specific production returns at the country level this role risk. If are diminishing either of these forces are present, the risk-adjusted rate of return to capital declines as is invested a country, creating an incentive to invest in capital. In the eliminated if absence keep most risk. we in rich While second ingredient variables popular view of their capital this why net foreign asset needs to recognize that ingredient to explain that the theory just is countries even is likely to this is why investors the presence of diminishing returns in be true to some extent, we look elsewhere of the theory, for three reasons. First, we find that standard (human think are associated with better aggregate production functions capital, quality of institutions, and others) seem to be either unrelated to the net foreign asset position of a country or, alternatively, explain very (See Table 3 and the discussion production functions in rich small, they cannot explain of it countries can explain why gross predict that they why of its variation net foreign asset positions are foreign equity positions are also small. risk, choose large gross foreign equity positions balanced. Finally, better aggregate production functions why most little below). Second, while better aggregate extent that investors have a desire to diversify production explain little would only be have better aggregate production functions, and and production for the A capital were equalized across countries. Hence the theory needs a second rich countries countries that have in of a counten/ailing force, this incentive capital stocks positions are so small. ^ more two To the the theory would that are roughly in rich countries cannot international trade consists of loans rather than equity. While both assets are useful to transfer capital across countries, equity has the additional benefit of allowing countries to share production risk preferred over loans. Why and should therefore always be are observed foreign equity positions so small? foreign loans rather than foreign equity the asset that To answer these questions, we would still need to add theory anyway. See Lucas is [1990] for a review of alternative possibilities. Why are most traded internationally? additional elements to the In this paper we explore the alternative hypothesis that sovereign be the second ingredient that the theory needs. ^ In hedge against the demand Should for capital that we positions? in risk of foreign default. might explain why might the presence of this sort of domestic capital offers domestic investors not only the value of also a risk This creates a its risk, production flow, but home bias in the net foreign asset positions are small. also expect that sovereign risk leads to small gross foreign equity Is it even possible that sovereign risk explains why most international trade assets consists of loans rather than equity? The answers to these questions depend crucially Assume on the consequences first that if for investors of a country defaults on its a foreign foreign obligations, foreign owns abroad and then using countries respond by seizing the assets that this country these assets to (partially) compensate Assume creditors. which assets are seized and transferred default. to creditors also that the process by does not give loss of value. In this case, the loss suffered by creditors in rise to any costs or the event of default is determined by their net foreign asset position vis-a-vis the defaulting country. To minimize exposure to sovereign positions. But they do not have risk, choose small net foreign asset investors then to hold small gross foreign equity positions. In fact, to the extent that investors have a desire to diversify production risk they would again choose large foreign equity positions assumptions, sovereign are small, but can it explain If it risk that are roughly balanced. provides a rationale for why Under these net foreign asset positions cannot explain why gross foreign equity positions are small. Neither why most we want international trade consists of loans rather than equity. to hold sovereign risk responsible for the small gross foreign equity positions observed in the data, we need to remove at least one of the assumptions of the previous paragraph. Perhaps legal systems do not allow creditors to seize the foreign assets of defaulting countries. Or, even ^ if they do, the transfer of ownership Obstfeld and Rogoff [1996, p. 349] define sovereign risk as referring to "... any situation in which a government defaults on loan contracts with foreigners, seizes foreign assets located within its borders, or prevents domestic residents from fully meeting obligations to foreign creditors." This is a good description of what we have in mind. might involve large costs and a substantial loss of value. exposure to sovereign risk is no longer case, investors' In this their net foreign asset position vis-a-vis the defaulting country, but instead sonne fraction of their gross foreign asset position. Now the existence of sovereign risk can potentially explain why investors choose small gross foreign equity positions. With the help of the additional (and ownership of equity transferring sovereign risk is we think realistic) costlier than transferring assumption that ownership of loans, can also explain why most international trade assets consists of in foreign loans rather than foreign equity. Investors issuing foreign loans willing to sell they receive these assets at a discount that reflects the value for them of the gain in the event of What default.'' borrowed abroad receives the full claims to foreigners receives the so on). This gain is to better gain? A domestic investor who has full is exactly equal to the A domestic investor who has sold equity value of the equity, but loses any valuable advantage that foreign investors brought know-how, access is this value of the loans. This gain loss experienced by the foreign investor. in and equity are to the firm (experience, managerial skills, technology or relationships, firm-specific knowledge, and less than the loss experienced by the foreign investor. Therefore the event of default, foreign loans give rise only to pure transfers while foreign equity creates losses. While the latter allows investors to risk, it is hedge against production a worse hedge against sovereign risk than the former. If the desire to avoid diminishing returns induces investors to transfer capital from rich to poor countries, foreign loans production will risk. be a more attractive asset Thus, sovereign risk if sovereign has also the risk is high relative to potential to explain why loans are the preferred asset to finance capital flows. The notion that foreign equity novel or controversial interesting issue "* It Is among observers whether reasonable to sovereign risk of international financial markets. probabilities of default is hardly The can quantitatively in loan contracts shows up In the Interest rate. The evidence Is overwhelming developing countries usually command a higher Interest rate than domestic much less clear whether we could find any comparable discount on equity. This discount that loans to loans. is and loans are subject explain the main features of country portfolios. To determine this, we construct a simple North-South model of international capital flows. The production technology exhibits diminishing returns at the country level model, the world assets, which economy experiences end up in a crisis period and country-specific risk. In this periods with substantial international trade in which South defaults on its in foreign obligations. North investors seize South's foreign assets, but this transfer of assets costly. The default initiates a crisis period in which international financial markets shut down. Eventually, international trade above. is It seems If sovereign clear that this in assets resumes and the cycle starts again. model can, in risk is sufficiently high, principle, explain the facts net capital flows will either diminishing returns or country-specific production risk observe a tendency for capital to flow from is be small (Fact important, poor countries (Fact rich to extent that transferring ownership of foreign equity is discussed 2). we 1). If should To the costlier than transferring ownership of loans, gross foreign asset positions should be small and consist primarily of loans rather than equity (Fact 4). If the model generates persistence in the world distribution of wealth, this can naturally explain the persistence of foreign asset positions (Fact 3). It is much less clear however whether a reasonable quantitative description of the data. even in A this model able to provide is perhaps surprising finding the presence of reasonable diminishing returns and production probability that international crises occur twice a century is enough to risk, is that, the generate a set of country portfolios that are roughly consistent with the data. The paper is organized as follows: Section I provides a brief description of our database and extensively documents the four facts mentioned above. Section presents the model and discusses Appendix A its main qualitative provides a detailed discussion of Appendix B contains some proofs. how we and quantitative II implications. constructed our database, while A I. Description of Country Portfolios In this section, we describe the main characteristics of country portfolios using overview of the sources and We first provide an methodology used to construct the data. We then summarize in a new database covering 68 countries from 1966 its main features the data and describes A New 1.1 to 1997. the form of four facts. Appendix how we account for changes in A provides details on the value of stocks of assets. Database on Country Portfolios Our database contains estimates assets of countries. ^ In particular, of domestic capital stocks and foreign we have measures for the following quantities: k = Domestic capital stock e = Domestic equity owned by foreign residents. e* = Foreign equity owned by domestic residents. = Loans issued by domestic residents and owned by foreign residents. I I* = Loans issued by foreign residents and owned by domestic residents. We measure these quantities per domestic resident in constant 1990 US dollars. We define a=k+e*-e+r-l and f=e*-e+r-l as the financial wealth or portfolio of the country and its its net foreign assets, respectively. First, we use as a creditor (debtor) if initial value. Second, We abstract from capital. component of financial wealth in two steps. the limited available information on stocks of these assets to determine we use these assets to extend the ^ refer to a country net foreign assets are positive (negative). We construct estimates of each an We other initial flow data and estimates of changes in the value of stocks forward and backward over time. components of wealth such as land, natural resources, We rely on and human this method available in of cumulating flows even for those countries where more stock data is order to avoid a potential bias. Since long time series of stock data are few available only for a essentially result rich countries, using these as the primary source would methods being used in different and poor to construct stocks for rich These differences would then contaminate our inferences regarding how countries. portfolios vary with wealth. We rely on of data from a number of standard sources. We obtain initial stocks domestic capital from the Penn World Tables, and use flow data on gross domestic investment to build up stocks of capital valued in US PPP. dollars at In order to determine foreign holdings of domestic equity and domestic holdings of foreign equity, we rely primarily Investment reported Yearbook. Statistics reported in this in on data on stocks and flows of direct and portfolio equity the International Monetary Fund's Balance of We again and a variety use the limited available information of other sources to determine the Payments on stocks initial level of each asset for each country, and then use corresponding flow data from the balance of payments to construct stocks for remaining years. the debts of developing countries reported in Finally, we combine stock data on the World Bank's Global Development Finance with data on stocks and flows on debt from the Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook to build up stocks of borrowing and lending for all countries in our sample.^ Our sample with a sample of of countries is determined primarily by data 98 countries with population greater than one GDP greater than 1 000 US dollars at PPP in 1 990. Of these with missing, incomplete, or inconsistent balance of with an unbalanced panel of between 1966 and 1997. In availability. million we We begin and per capita discard 25 countries payments data. This leaves us 73 countries spanning on average 25 the empirical work that follows we of the years restrict attention to a We assume throughout that stocks of debt reported in these sources constitute solely the assets and liabilities of domestic residents. To the extent that these reflect debt issued by or owed to foreign-owned firms operating in the country, we are overestimating the loan assets and liabilities of domestic residents. Given that foreign holdings of domestic equity are small relative to wealth this mismeasurement is unlikely to be empirically important. ® set of 68 countries excluding classified all five transition economies. Table 1 lists these countries by geographical region. As the table shows, our sample includes basically and a substantial number industrial countries regions of the world. The countries in It is reasonable to think that these countries also account for a similar fraction of world trade coverage, we do sample. the case of claims on equity, not find that net foreign assets claims on foreign equity is all our sample account for over 90 percent of world production and commodity trade. In of developing countries from we in assets. sum to find that the '' Despite this wide zero across countries sum of all in our countries reported on average about 3 percent less than reported foreign claims on domestic equity. In the case of lending the discrepancy is world larger, with reported borrowing exceeding lending by about 12 percent. While these discrepancies are not trivial, known discrepancies in 1.2 they are of a comparable order of magnitude to well- flows on foreign assets. Main Features of Country Portfolios In this subsection we examine database described above. the main features of country portfolios using the We organize the discussion around four main facts or findings. Fact 1 Net foreign assets as a share of wealth are small and negative for most countries. Figure t shows the distribution of the share of foreign assets in wealth, — a pooling the available 1717 observations for all countries and years. Overwhelmingly, net foreign assets represent a small fraction of the wealth of domestic residents. Our procedure results in estimates of wealth that are very small (and occasionally negative) few country-year observations, corresponding to countries with very large external debt. We exclude these observations by limiting the sample to those where the ratio of wealth to '' for a GDP is greater than 0.5. Roughly 80 percent of the country/year observations are less than 20 percent in absolute value. Also, about 80 percent of the country-year observations are negative. Perhaps Figure is 1 concealing important variation across regions and over time the size and sign of the net foreign asset position. reports the share of net foreign assets regions and time periods. different Clearly, the finding that rule out this possibility, (median) country stock. in each group most countries have a small but negative net and over time. Since net foreign asset positions are small relative is in reports wealth-weighted averages, for the typical foreign asset position holds across regions there Table 2 wealth, aggregating across countries The top panel and the lower panel reports the share and period. in To in to wealth, it follows that a strong relationship between countries' financial wealth and their capital To see this, Figure 2 plots the capital stock, k, against financial wealth, averaging the available years over the period 1966-1997 for each country. a, A simple regression of the capital stock on domestic wealth delivers and R^ of 98 percent and a slope coefficient of 0.93. Clearly, the world distribution of capital stocks to the world distribution of wealth. This between these two appears coefficient one is and countries in to be very close random is is zero. That is, that differences to one, the null hypothesis that this coefficient on average the We also reject the capital stock null is hypothesis exceeds wealth in poor less than wealth in rich countries. This leads us to the next fact: The share of net foreign assets 2: very close or uninteresting. Although the slope rejected at conventional significance levels. that the intercept Fact distributions are does not mean however is in the country portfolio increases with wealth a cross-section of countries. The wealth apparent is wealth, strong positive association between the share of net foreign assets and — , in Figure 3, which plots the average share of net foreign assets against the logarithm of wealth, ln(a), for each country over 1966-1997. a Virtually all (44 out of 47) developing countries are debtors, as are two-thirds of 10 in our sample are mostly industrial countries (14 out of 21). Tiie ten creditor countries in rich industrial countries (Belgium/Luxembourg, Switzerland, Germany, France, United Kingdom, Japan, and the Netherlands), and three developing countries (Saudi Arabia, Singapore, and Lesotho).^ The subperiods. (shown in between wealth and net foreign asset positions holds across relationship The the row of Table 3 confirms that the simple results first first in Figure 3 column) hold across the different subperiods (shown the in remaining columns). The estimated coefficients range from 0.04 to 0.08 and are from zero significantly different in each subperiod. The magnitudes when wealth coefficients indicate that doubles, the share of foreign assets increases by three to six percentage points. regional of these dummies. With the exception In the next row of Table 3 we row of Table 3 we check whether the changes an artifact of in wealth introduce on the of the first subperiod, the coefficient logarithm of wealth increases slightly, and remains significantly positive. is in the third In the wealth elasticity across periods the changing composition of the sample by restricting attention to a balanced panel of 8-year average observations. The results do not change substantially. There are reasons foreign asset position easy is to think that the relationship between wealth and the net even stronger than what a simple regression would to think of factors that are positively correlated with wealth and are negatively correlated with the net foreign asset position of a country. strongly correlated with human capital, technology and likely to First, institutional quality, which raise the returns to capital and make foreign assets less attractive countries. Second, the variability of returns making foreign assets less effects whereby sample. Lesotho is in some of the larger, richer arguments can be summarized by saying All of these is somewhat of 11 be wealth all is is of for rich may also be scale economies that it in is likely an anomaly, as it runs large current account surpluses South Africa. primarily workers' remittances from It also negatively correlated with wealth, attractive for rich countries. Third, there returns are higher find. our that rich reflecting countries have better aggregate production functions and therefore find foreign assets less To attractive. the extent that this is the case, the simple regressions of the net foreign asset position on wealth contain omitted variables that bias downwards We therefore introduce a number of additional control variables We proxy for human capital with the number of years of the slope coefficient. into the regression. secondary education the workforce, and control for scale effects using the in logarithm of population. We include openness to international trade measured as M2 to trade volumes as a share of GDP, financial depth GDP, government consumption as a share of measured as the GDP, and an ratio of index of civil liberties, as proxies for the quality of the institutional environment. We measure the variability of returns using the standard deviation of real per capita GDP period. Finally, we dummies include a set of regional growth over the indicated to control for other unobserved region-specific heterogeneity. The remainder of Table 3 summarizes the results of regression. Averaging over remains very significant. make domestic capital all this augmented years, the coefficient on wealth rises to 0.07 and Consistent with the view that high levels of more we attractive, find that level. surprisingly, population size enters positively, suggesting that there diseconomies of scale or congestion effects that make domestic large countries. Public consumption as a share of approaches significance demand for foreign at the 10 percent financial which may coefficients may be capital less attractive enters negatively and may reflect an increased reflect the fact that countries with well- markets have less need for recourse to international financial markets. The remaining control variables, openness, growth do not enter GDP Somewhat loans to finance public consumption. Finally, financial depth enters positively and significantly. This developed level, capital years of secondary education enters negatively although not quite significantly at the 10 percent in human significantly. on these variables qualitatively similar to civil liberties, and the volatility of Although the magnitude and significance of the differs those obtained somewhat across subperiods, in the first 12 column. the results are From Table 3 we can also obtain a sense of the magnitude and relative importance of wealth relative to other factors as a determinant of foreign assets Consider the regression positions. in the A one data over the period 1966-1997. first column of Table 3 based on average standard deviation increase in the logarithm of wealth (which corresponds to roughly a three-fold increase) leads to roughly twothirds of a standard deviation increase in the net foreign asset position, or percentage points. In contrast, a one standard deviation increase significant control variables leads to an increase (in the the net foreign asset position. Another in importance of wealth explaining the cross-country variation perform a variance decomposition of the fitted can be attributed to wealth. that almost 60 percent ^ in all but the first in the (in pooling figures it vertical axis, against its is is due in is (in to we find (in we is due similarly find that to variation in wealth. wealth value lagged one year the second panel) and 10 years all foreign assets predicted foreign assets country portfolio Figure 4 plots the share of net foreign assets years in subperiod predicted foreign assets The share of net foreign assets year on the see the of the cross-country variation in predicted foreign assets the majority of the variation 3: to Averaging over the entire sample period, to cross-country variation in wealth. In Fact in way values from these regressions. The bottom row of Table 3 reports the share of the variance that the remaining in absolute value) of only one-third of a standard deviation in about 10 is persistent over time. in a given country and the first panel), five the third panel) on the horizontal axis, country-year observations over the period 1966-1997. From these three clear that the share of foreign assets in wealth is very persistent.^" The We use a decomposition of the variance of the sum of two correlated random variables suggested by Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare [1997]. In particular, if Z=X+Y, they define the share of the variance of Z attributable to X as COV(X,Z)A/AR(Z). This number has the following natural interpretation: If we observe that Z is one percent above its mean but we did not observe X and Y separately, then we would infer that X is COV(X,Z)A/AR(Z) percent above its mean value. We apply this defining Z as fitted foreign assets, and X as the estimated coefficient on wealth multiplied by wealth. ^° This fact was also noted by Kraay and Ventura [Forthcoming] in a smaller sample of 13 OECD economies, who argue that this observation can explain the long-standing puzzle raised by Feldstein and Horioka [1980]. ® 13 simple correlation between the share of foreign assets year and the same share simple correlation foreign assets in is lagged one year country portfolios holds roughly -10 percent of is around 2. country portfolios in a given Even over a 10-year horizon the a respectable 0.55. This very strong persistence of the share of is all its wealth more the small foreign assets are relative to wealth. GDP 0.96. is in surprising our sample the typical (median) country In foreign assets, in when one considers how and ratio of its wealth to GDP This implies that a current account surplus of 5 percent of sustained for only four years would be sufficient to entirely erase a country's net foreign asset position. Yet we see the data in that net foreign assets as a share of wealth on average barely change over this horizon, as indicated by the estimated slope coefficients which are very close to one. The pooled data over time in Figure 4 nevertheless in the persistence of foreign assets in year indicated on the horizontal axis, we its the vertical axis as a one-year dashed lag, line. average of these estimated slopes. the foreign assets of to the all country portfolios. all Figure 5 we solid line When in wealth plot the resulting slope coefficients this on shows a three-year centered moving slope greater than (less than) one, is countries on average expand (contract). mid-1980s, the slopes are In regress the share of foreign assets and then The interesting variation the top panel of Figure 4 by year. For each disaggregate the annual persistence on a constant and in mask some From the mid-1970s greater than one. This reflects primarily the rapid buildup of debt of developing countries financed by borrowing from rich countries and oil producers, followed by an even greater increase of these countries debt crisis was eventually resolved fall in share of net foreign assets immediate is in recorded debts as crisis of the 1980s. the late 1980s, the portfolios of below one. Somewhat near one during the 1990s, providing Why their suspended payment during the debt contracted and the slopes is in little all many As the countries surprisingly, the estimated slope evidence of systematic increases in country portfolios during this period. the net foreign asset position as a share of wealth so persistent? possibility is that the persistence of net foreign assets reflects the persistence of wealth, which the we have seen to 14 be an important determinant of the One cross-country variation empirically by regressing the change logarithm of wealth and the changes 3, We investigate this net foreign assets. in net foreign assets on the in in change in the the other control variables considered in Table using the three eight-year changes implied by the four 8-year averaged periods using Table in 3. We then perform the determine what share of the variation same in variance decomposition as before to changes We find that between 40 changes in wealth. changes in net foreign assets can be attributed to to iiypothesis us that persistence in wealth is in net foreign assets are due to percent and 70 percent of the variation changes in in wealth. This suggests an important source of persistence in foreign assets. Fact 4: Gross foreign asset positions are small and consist mostly of foreign loans rather than foreign equity. Net foreign assets consist of net claims on foreign equity (e*-e) and net lending abroad, (l-l*). We illustrate the cross-country variation in the relative importance of the latter country portfolios in explaining two ways. Table 4 shows the in composition of foreign assets as they vary across regions, income groups, and time. Averaging over all years, claims on foreign equity consist of only 0.3 percent of the wealth of developing countries, while foreign claims on domestic equity account for 2.8 percent of wealth. Among industrial countries claims on domestic equity are only and 3.9 percent somewhat claims on foreign equity and foreign larger and consist of only 3.3 percent of wealth." In contrast gross borrowing and lending account percent and 4.5 percent of wealth of developing countries, and each for industrial countries. Finally, borrowing and lending in it is 1 1 for 8.8 percent of wealth interesting to note that the share of gross the wealth of industrial countries is much larger than that of developing countries, especially during the 1990s. " A documented that the holdings of foreign equity of investors in a few are very small (French and Poterba [1991], Tesar and Werner [1992] and others). Lewis [1999] provides an excellent survey of alternative explanations for this empirical large literature has rich countries regularity. Our data confirms that it applies to a much broader 15 set of countries and assets. In contrast with Table 4 which focuses on gross positions, Figure 6 provides evidence on the importance of net lending net foreign assets. We plot net the share of foreign assets in in explaining the cross-country variation lending as a share of wealth on the vertical axis, and wealth on the horizontal axis, averaging over the period 1966-97. The top panel shows the results for shows the same relationship is in all countries, while the bottom panel information for industrial countries only. Since the slope of this more than the covariance between net nothing foreign assets and net lending divided by the variance of net foreign assets, this slope can be interpreted as the fraction of the variance sample In our in our sample full in net foreign assets attributable to variation of countries this fraction this is not surprising at all, is in net lending. 82 percent. For the developing countries since we have seen that gross equity same number positions are small. What industrial countries where cross-border claims on equity are much more prevalent than in is more surprising developing countries. From country variation rather than in in up, portfolios is small and evidence we conclude that most that the share of net foreign assets typically negative (Fact 1), exhibits association with wealth in in of the cross- net lending and consists in country a strong positive a cross-section of countries (Fact persistent over time (Fact 3), applies to portfolio equity investment. we have seen and foreign equity (Fact that the net foreign assets can be attributed to differences foreign direct To sum this is 2), is remarkably primarily of foreign loans rather than 4). 16 II. Towards an Explanation of Country We next develop a model that emphasizes the interplay of diminishing returns, production risk and sovereign risk in a world populated by variance investors. ^^ Diminishing returns and production these were the only forces at work, and the world portfolios, we would observe homogeneous mean- risk adjusted rate of return to capital declines as more capital same Portfolios all is imply that the risk- invested in a country. If countries choosing the distribution of capital stocks would be determined by the equalization of risk-adjusted rates of return. Sovereign risk however generates a home bias in the demand would hold only domestic mimic the world for capital. capital A Model is were the only force this and the world distribution of wealth. distribution of capital stocks 11.1 If The at work, countries distribution of capital stocks set of country portfolios shaped by the and the world interaction of these forces. of International Capital Flows The world contains two countries, North and South; one factor capital; and a single good good used as the numeraire. Each country contains a continuum is would that can be used for of production, consumption and investment. This of identical consumer/investors that evaluate consumption sequences as follows: (1) where c EJlnc(t)e"^' is dt (5>0) consumption. The time index confusing. Throughout, North has higher initial we use an will be omitted whenever this is not asterisk to denote South variables. wealth than South, i.e. We assume a(0)>a*(0). ^^ The key property of these investors is that the share of each asset in their portfolio does not depend on their wealth, but only on the menu of available assets. By homogeneous, we mean that all Investors have identical (homothetic) preferences, although possibly different wealth and menu of available assets. 17 The production technology North and South. To produce one required. Since capital is is is quite simple. Let k processes with independent increments. That and E[do>do/]=0. Then the flow 7t=9k"^ in and (0<y<1; 9>0) measures the strength is, unit is and co* in its return be two standard Wiener E[do)]= E[dco*]=0, E[dco^]=E[dcL)*^]=dt is given by South; where n and n* are short-hand for and a is a positive constant. The parameter y effect. ^^ The parameter a measures the importance country-specific production risk. Therefore, this formulation same technology and embodies adjusted rate of return to capital decreasing for capital to always one and is of diminishing returns which, for simplicity, are treated here as an externality or congestion countries have the capital stocks of consumption good of production net of depreciation North and 7T;*dt+adco* 7i:*=0k*"'' co be the k* unit of the each reversible, the price of the flow of production net of depreciation. Let Ttdt+adca one unit of capital, and move from rich to in assumes of that both the two forces that make the risk- the capital stock and create incentives poor countries. Domestic investors own the domestic stock of and equity contracts with foreign capital and can enter investors. International loans promise to into loan pay an instantaneous interest rate rdt. At the beginning of the period, the lender gives the principal to the borrower. At the The borrower might honor plus interest. its end of the period there are promise, The borrower might in two possible outcomes. which case the lender receives the principal also default on its promise, in which case the borrower keeps the principal and interest and the lender receives nothing. North (South) equity has price v generated by one unit of (v*) and promises North (South) capital. At the buyer gives the value of the equity to the unit of capital at the end promise, and allows him/her of the period there are in to to seller. The A share of pay the net flow of production beginning of the period the seller provides the operate the production technology. two possible outcomes. The seller buyer with a Once again, might honor its which case the buyer receives the value of the equity and keeps the net flow of production. The seller might also default on its promise, in which case the ^^ At the cost of further notation, we could generate this dependence by assuming there is a production factor that is not priced. Since this is well known, we dispense with the formalities. 18 seller keeps the value unit of capital amount of the equity and the net flow and then pays a cost X (0<X<1) The buyer receives of production. South and e of lending from North to (e*) to repossess the nothing. Let I be the be the number of North (South) shares owned by South (North). It is equilibrium evident that international loan and equity contracts if and only if the probability that they are honored will be used in high enough. This is observation raises a familiar time-inconsistency problem. Since governments cannot punish foreign citizens, international trade willingness to punish their foreigners. 'Ex-ante' both own citizens if in assets relies on governments' they default on their obligations towards governments would commit like to to do this and allow investors to exploit beneficial trade opportunities. However, 'ex-post' governments not have an incentive to punish default of default are clear. But, if the benefits exceed the costs. what are the costs of default? We shall The do benefits assume they vary overtime. Let s={0,1} be the state of the wortd. During 'normal times' (s=0) both countries can credibly commit to retaliate with penalties that are large ensure that default never occurs. During credibly commit (North) defaults Ae* to penalties if its beyond 'crisis (v* e*+l-ve<-A,e).^'* Let a and dt |3dt to periods' (s=1) countries cannot retaliation in kind. net foreign asset position enough is be the As a result, negative enough, if s=1 South i.e. ve-l-v*e*<- probabilities that the wortd transitions from 8=0 to s=1 and vice versa; and assume these transitions are independent of production shocks, E[dcods]=E[dca*ds]=0. The value of ds is revealed after the beginning-of-penod payments of loan and equity contracts have already been made. What is the equilibrium probability of default? probability of default is zero. If investors believe the a*>a(1-A), the country portfolios chosen by investors are consistent with this belief.^^ ^'* Assume In this The seminal papers on sovereign risk case, the equilibnum probability of default and the ability of is various types of penalties to sustain trade are Eaton and Gersovitz [1981] and Bulow and Rogoff [1989]. Eaton and Fernandez [1995] and Obstfeld and Rogoff [1996, chapter 6] are two excellent surveys of this topic. ^ If investors believe that the probability of default v=v*=1, k=k*=(a+a*)/2, e=a*/2, e*=a/2 and if s=1 , is zero, the equilibrium of the no country defaults a*>a (1-X). 1=0. Naturally, North does not default and neither does South 19 if if model implies s=0. But even zero and sovereign risk is on that a*(0)<a(0)-(1-X). dependent. Assume the simply not an issue. case, the equilibrium probability of default In this state initial We shall therefore assume from is is now state- s=1 and investors believe that default occurs if the state does not change. Then, investors do not purchase foreign loans and equity since they expect default to occur with probability close to one, both countries are indifferent on whether to default or not. equilibrium exists we assume i.e. 1-|3dt. To ensure believe that default occurs If is restrict in To sum up, the world in s=0 and investors economy The parameters a and it will A. in the cycle starts again. Although is probability, small. This implies that exhibits periods of trade s=0 to s=1) in measure the occurs, a period ensues Eventually, international trade i.e. strategies followed by investors. is We shall the in in assets that which the debtor country probability which there assets resumes in adt is and the destructiveness no trade (s transitions in from s=1 to s=0) and normal times there might be substantial trade We describe these strategies We in on the next. can construct a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium as follows: Let p be the probability of choose country portfolios such that ve-l-v*e*=-Ae*. South is indifferent between defaulting or not. There is an equilibrium in which South defaults with default that leads investors to probability (p/a)dt. 20 of assets. assets, the (small) probability that a crisis occurs has an important effect ^^ purchase 'normal times'. crises (s transitions from this crisis. After In the chosen country portfolios are consistent which a in equilibrium probability of default defaults. is which the country follows a pure strategy.^® in the analysis to the case in state no trade the unlikely event the state of the world changes. Otherwise, no Nash equilibrium culminate initial is the state changes. In this case, investors this probability is not too large, with South defaulting there if next that the and equity since default occurs only with a very small foreign loans adt. Assume 'crisis periods'. an that they default (on their non-existent foreign obligations) so that the beliefs of investors are consistent. This implies that there assets during But then 11.2 Investment Strategies In crisis periods, and save. This the only decision that investors face limited choice embedded is in this is how much to consume budget constraint which applies only during crisis periods: (2) da = (7ia-c)dt + In aadco normal times there trade is in constraint of the representative investor (3) in and we can write the North as follows: restriction applies: k-ve + v*e*+l a = The first two terms of the budget constraint expected return and volatility of state of the world not changing. (3) are standard and schemes and impose last restriction is The third consumer in short-sale constraints on the holdings North maximizes (1) rule out Ponzi of foreign equity. This risk. subject to (2)-(4) and the dynamics of asset phces i.e. Since the representative consumer the laws of motion of is infinitesimal, r, v , v*, n, n*, a and the South solves a similar problem. Appendix The representative B shows that the first-order conditions associated with the investor's problem can be written as follows: 21 a*. he/she understands that his/her actions have no influence on these prices and their evolution. in we the optimal consumption and portfolio rules, the representative their return characteristics, consumer the term describes the wealth shock that the a logical implication of sovereign To determine show how wealth depends on asset choice, conditional on the investor experiences at the onset of a crisis period. Throughout, and budget da = [7r(k-e) + 7i*e*+rl-c]dt + (7-[(k-e)d(o + e*d(o*]+[(v-A)e-v*e*-l]ds where, of course, the following (4) assets, 6a (5) c = (6) 7T:-p =a k-e 2 a p = a a-_ (7) r (8) p-v-n = -a k-^e ^ k-e 2 ,, a , + a(A-v) k-Xe a (9) 7i*-r-v*<0, e*=0. If where p is Otherwise, re e* -p v* = a^ * • +a v k-Xe the multiplier associated with constraint (3) divided by the marginal utility of wealth. This quantity can be interpreted as the risk-free rate that applies on loans between North residents. Equation (5) is familiar result that of time preference A similar set of first-order conditions apply to South. the first-order condition associated with c; and shows the consumption equals the annualized value of wealth. Since the rate is used as the discount factor, the consumption rule is independent of the state of the world. Equations describe (6) how (6) and (7) are the first investors value production says that the premium order conditions associated with k and and sovereign risk, I; and respectively. Equation for holding production risk, n-p, is the covariance between the return to one unit of capital and one unit of the investor's portfolio, a^(k-e)/a. Equation (7) says that the premium proportional to the covariance portfolio, i.e. a . for holding sovereign risk, r-a-p, between one But since unit of is also loans and one unit of the investor's this time the effect of the shock is 'large' or a non-local, the factor of proportionality wealth before and after a crisis is occurs, not i.e. one but the . k-Ae 22 ratio of the marginal value of Equations (8) and and describe the supply (9) of North equity to sell equity. is at a discount, i.e. in this the event of a v<1. Using Equations (6) and equal to the gain obtained income 1-A. in in crisis. (7), e*; South equity, for at which North Each share sold by the North reduces income by one output, but also provides a gain of be sold and the demand can be interpreted as determining the price respectively. Equation (8) is willing are the first-order conditions associated with e and This we is why unit of equity will find that this discount the event of a crisis times the price of one unit of state of the world, - 1-v =(1-^) i.e. Equation . (9) defines the r demand for South equity. This asset contains both production and the required premium risk and sovereign risk reflects just this. This completes the description of the model. Equations (4)-(9) and their counterparts for South jointly determine asset prices distribution of capital stocks (k,k*) trade (e,e*,i) (n,7i*, a,a*). (p,p*,r,v,v*), and consumptions (c,c*); as a function of the distribution of wealth We use this set of (a, a*) the world and the pattern of asset and technology equations to derive the cross-sectional implications of the theory. Then, the budget constraints (2)-(3) determine the law of motion of the world economy as a function of the the realizations of the shocks. initial distribution of wealth We use this additional and technology and set of equations to derive the time-series implications of the theory. 11.3 Three Examples Before we embark examples or special cases that the theory in in a quantitative analysis of the model, that help build intuition emphasizes. In these examples, normal times and then ask: What does it is the initial evolve over time? 23 on the we discuss three role of the different forces we assume the world pattern of trade in economy assets and starts how EXAMPLE no discount on #1 Let : a^O so that there international assets, i.e. choose the same As portfolios. risk. In this case, there effectively, the a result, there is same menu of assets, they no borrowing or lending. Since technologies are identical, both countries invest 50 percent of their wealth capital and the rest in foreign equity. each country and the world is p=p*=r and v=v*=1. Since countries have and homothetic preferences and, identical no sovereign is Thus, half of the world capital stock in domestic located is in interest rate equals the marginal product of capital: ^^ (10) k = k* (11) r = -^ ^a+a*v^ =e ^ \ If one countries in + 2 J interprets North Table 1 , we have and South as the = 0.8 that set of industrial ; and developing and net foreign asset positions (as a a + a* percentage of wealth) of North and South are 37.5 and -150 percent, respectively. The distribution of wealth portfolios ^ = An a* 2 implication of this The is predictions of this exhibits rate: ^ ^ that net foreign asset positions are time invariant. example are both well-known and dead wrong. The two features that are present in the data: net foreign asset positions are positively associated with wealth (Fact 2) and very persistent (Fact model also predicts net foreign asset positions data (Fact same da ^^ = (r-p).dt + -(dco + dco*) a model constant over time, since both countries choose the and therefore have the same growth da (12) is 1). It that are much shows that countries hold little 24 in the and no borrowing and foreign equity of their net foreign asset positions with foreign loans (Fact 4). But the larger than those also predicts very large foreign equity positions lending, while the data 3). and finance most EXAMPLE poor countries the same same return assets asset. is in : a^O so that the only reason to exploit higher rates of return. is return #2 Let in normal times. If why capital flows Now foreign equity from rich to and loans deliver X=0, foreign equity and loans also deliver the the event of default and, consequently, the composition of foreign indeterminate. If X is strictly positive, foreign equity becomes a dominated case, countries do not hold foreign equity and finance their net foreign In this asset positions with foreign loans. The world distribution of capital stocks and the world interest rate are implicitly determined by: (13) r = ek-^+a- (14) r = ek*"^+a- (15) k k k^ \3' + k* = a + a* Equations (13) and (14) describe the Equation (15) is demand the market-clearing condition. home demand risk creates a rate exceeds the marginal product risk premium required bias to in the for North and South These equations show for capital. Also, capital, that sovereign note that the world interest of capital in both countries. This difference compensate lenders for and sovereign risk. is The top panel the of Table 5 computes the foreign asset position of North under alternative assumptions for Y and a (Remember the net foreign asset position North). Net foreign asset positions for North 37.5 and -150 percent (as a^O). instance, a=0.02 is What consistent with the episodes of large-scale defaults in value of aggregate production 9 is if South is -A times are reasonable values for 20'*^ that of and South range from zero (as a^'>=) to a and y? For century experience which features two the 1930s and the 1980s. Since the expected k^'^, values of y around 0.6 correspond to the neoclassical growth model, while values of y near model. Table 5 shows that of one are close to the linear growth a=0.02 and y=0.6, the net foreign asset positions of North and South are 20.3 and -81.2 percent. These numbers are roughly half of those we found in the previous example. If y=0.1, the net foreign asset positions are 25 These nunnbers are now seven times smaller than 5.4 and -21 .6 percent. previous example and start to resemble those A nice feature of the first and the world be the case also ^ (16) = 3 distribution of wealth in this ^ same was second example, portfolios, of constant net foreign they had the albeit for different reasons: = (r-a-p).dt 3 North capital and lends the rest to South. South invests more than and borrows the difference from North. Since there obtains a higher return on rate same growth constant. Interestingly, this turns out to Countries choose quite different portfolios. North invests part of capital the find in the data. example was the prediction asset positions. Since countries chose the rate we in its its less wealth wealth South in in South capital, South domestic capital than North does. But since the interest on foreign loans exceeds the marginal product an even higher return on is its its of capital of South, North obtains foreign loans during normal times. and both countries share the same growth rate. An implication These is effects balance that net foreign asset positions are constant over time. This example shares with the first one the positions are positively associated with wealth they have in common. Although large relative to those in substantially. Moreover, arbitrarily small) we and very persistent. But this sovereign example risk is a To counteract still a bit are willing to assume that X is positive (although the model also predicts that foreign equity holdings are zero and net is It seems therefore that this a major improvement over the previous one, and a small dose of moves us bit that gap between theory and data has narrowed foreign asset positions are financed through foreign loans. second example is all the predicted net foreign asset positions are the data, the if predictions that net foreign asset a long way towards misleading since this impression, we it reconciling theory and data. But suggests that X plays a small explain what theory. 26 this role in the analysis. happens when we leave X out of the EXAMPLE #3 Let X-^0 so equity. In this case, production : no costs of transferring ownership of that there are follows from Equations (6)-(9) that countries share it all the risk: e k-e k e* k*-e* k* a* a a+a* a a* a+a* (17) This equations state that countries receive a fraction of each of the outputs that is equal to their share of world wealth. The the exposure to sovereign risk against this type of risk by holding small net foreign asset positions. This does not preclude them from hedging against production equity positions that are roughly balanced. no borrowing and lending of the first hedge the net foreign asset position, countries is Since intuition for this result is simple: example? Not if Does A,=0. quite. A this risk In fact, mean it by holding large gross foreign is that possible to we show that there is are back to the predictions major departure from the first example is that countries hold smaller net foreign asset positions. The distribution of capital stocks implicitly determined by: (18) = r k ek"^+a- a + a^ vay kM /i.*^-'' (19) r = ek*^^+a -a k 2 va k (20) again. Equations (18) and (19) describe the capital, interest rate capital also and Equation still command commands panel of Table 5 this (20) is demand the market-clearing condition. need not exceed the expected marginal product foreign loans choose a+a + k* = a + a* Once South is show for Now the a premium to compensate for production the predicted net foreign asset positions it is world of capital. Although a premium to compensate for sovereign number because North and risk, risk. domestic The middle when o is 0.05. We the average standard deviation of the growth rate 27 in a sample of 88 countries from 1960 to 1994. Since production creates an risk additional incentive for capital to flow from North to South, the net foreign asset positions are larger here than A second is now the second example, but only slightly so. in difference with the consistent with a example first measured home bias creates a discount on foreign equity, that is, in is that full sharing of production country portfolios. Sovereign v<1 and v*<1. This means that risk risk full sharing of production risk does not require countries to invest a fraction of their wealth in foreign equity that stock. For instance, is proportional to the share of foreign capital assume discounts were zero, v=v*=1 25 percent that , sharing of production full invest 25 percent of their wealth in South discounts are 50 percent, v=v*=0.50, invests 52.5 percent of percent. This is its enough of the world capital wealth in for North to full capital is in the world capital located risk implies that and the in South. If both countries rest in North capital. If sharing of production risk implies that South South capital, while buy the rights to North invests only 12.5 75 percent of South's output. If the discounts are large enough, the model might be consistent with the observation that foreign equity holdings are small. Table 6 The discount on South equity (not not large shown enough in shows these discounts when a=0.05. equity ranges from 20 to 30 percent. Table 6) is a little bit larger. The discount on North Nevertheless, these discounts are to reconcile theory with data. This example shares with the other two the result that both countries have the same growth (21) ^ /^ = a .^^ 9 k + k* a This production rates: result, risk, p dt +a V k . dco + k+k* which follows from the fact that there implies that net foreign asset positions 28 is do \ Ir* k L- dco* k+k complete sharing of not change over time. As the previous two examples in we have the prediction that net foreign asset and very positions are positively associated with wealth persistent. As the second in example, predicted net foreign asset positions are small enough to resemble those we observe in its in the data. But this example departs dramatically from the previous one predictions regarding the composition of net foreign assets. example, we have now large foreign equity positions determined is in losses. If risk. a-X is But in the event of default, equity large relative to o^, investors hold finance net foreign asset positions. This where o^O. If a-X is 11.4 is is it is first how lending. the composition is a better allows countries to share a worse asset since equity little what happens in it generates and instead use loans to the second example small relative to (/, investors hold large equity positions and do not use foreign loans. This This the the theory. During normal times, equity asset to transfer capital from North to South since production in and no borrowing and This difference between the second and third example illustrates of foreign assets As as far as is what happens the third in we go with examples. example where X^O. We next turn to the full-fledged model. Quantitative Implications Can the model developed here replicate the main features of the data with a reasonable set of parameter values? The key issue 'reasonable' set of parameters values. Y=0.2, a=0.05, a=0.02 somewhere because in and A,=0.20. A choice of y=0.2 average standard deviation countries from 1960 to 1994.^'' to agree on what constitutes a We propose the following between the neoclassical and the this is the is means linear of the that benchmark we settle growth models. growth rate We also choose a=0.02 in because the We set o=0.05 a sample of 88 20'^ century experienced two episodes of large-scale defaults by developing countries 1930s and the 1980s. Admittedly, we have little 29 intuition values: in the as to what a reasonable has value for X good We therefore chose A,=0.20, which is. results. parameters, we assume Since there we also is is a value that delivers relatively substantial uncertainty regarding the values of show how the results vary with that the share of world wealth in North each is 0.8, which capital is located in in is consistent with the Table 1. predicts net foreign asset positions for the North 10.5 percent and -42 percent, respectively. This North and 28.5 percent in means the of the them. Throughout, interpretation of North as the set of industrialized countries Our base case all and South of that 71.5 percent of the world South. Therefore, only 8.5 percent of The North the world capital stock flows from North to South. portfolio contains 89.5 percent of North capital, and 6.25 and 4.25 percent of foreign loans and equity, respectively. North does not percent of South capital. This and 17 percent much trade in is The South equity to South. sell 142 financed by selling foreign loans and equity worth 25 of South's wealth, respectively. Overall, this assets relative to the data (See Figure numbers show portfolio contains that substantial progress dose of sovereign risk in the theory. This case to the has been 1 and Table made by becomes apparent standard model without sovereign predicts net foreign asset positions of 37.5 risk in 4). But these including a very if we compare (See Example and 150 percent implies that half of the capital would be located base case predicts too in 1). The modest this base latter North and South. This each country and 30 percent of the world capital stock would flow from North to South. Moreover, the country portfolios are predicted to be identical and contain 50 percent of domestic capital and 50 percent of foreign equity. The next step, of course, to the particular choice of is to determine how sensitive are these predictions parameter values. Figure 7 shows how the predictions of the model vary with the two parameters that describe sovereign the Figure we change one benchmark values. Not " of the risk. In parameters holding constant the rest each panel of at their surprisingly, increasing the probability of crises (a) and/or the same sample, the average growth rate was 0.02. We set the rate of time preference 6=0.02 and choose a value for G=0.04 so as to match this average growth rate given a choice of units such that a+a*=1 In this at 30 destruction these generate {X) leads to a reduction in net foreign asset positions. Halving the probability of crises from twice to once a century almost doubles the predicted net foreign asset positions (from 10.5 and -A4 to 18.75 and -75 percent). Doubling the probability of crises from twice century to four times a century almost halves the predicted net foreign asset positions (from 10.5 and -A4 to 5.75 and -23 percent). It seems changes sensitive to example therefore, that predicted net foreign asset positions are quite to the in a. This second and is what we found also when we moved from the ones. Figure 7 shows that third asset positions are not very sensitive to changes case when we moved from the second Figure 7 also shows with a and X both a and X make to the third We this predicted net foreign also found this to be the example. the base case predictions for the South portfolio vary (the implications for the North portfolio follow immediately). Increases enough to close the enough to close the North foreign equity market, but not South foreign equity market. Moderate increases in a and X are sufficient to close the South foreign equity market. While moderate reductions a and X would open the North equity market, it would take large reductions parameters to raise foreign equity holdings substantially. for the composition of foreign assets changes a and in the value of X. If in equity less attractive relative to loans. In the base case, these variables are already high large how in X. first On A,. this in the other hand, It seems in in these that the predictions our base case are not very sensitive to small we have also a lot of uncertainty regarding value were close to zero, the predictions regarding the composition of foreign assets would change substantially, as shown in the second example above. Figure 8 shows how the predictions of the model vary with the parameters that describe technology. Simple inspection of this Figure reveals that predicted net foreign asset positions are quite sensitive to our assumptions about diminishing returns (y), example, if but not very sensitive to our assumptions on production risk (a). For we (from 10.5 and raise y from 0.2 to 0.6, the net foreign asset positions basically double -44 to 20.5 and -82 percent). As y goes to zero, net foreign asset 31 positions collapse to zero as well. This reflects the fact that there are no longer any return differentials to provide incentives for capital flows and, for our choice of parameters, the risk of default diversifying production risk. values), it is necessary changes that in to a have is sufficiently high to aX>a^ (which If assume that y>0 is outweigh any benefits of a restriction satisfied by the benchmark to generate capital flows. small effects on net foreign asset positions The observation was already made when we moved from the second to the third example. Not surprisingly, the relative importance of y and a for the Increases in production and induce investors to composition of country portfolios risk raise is just the opposite. the diversification benefits of holding foreign equity use more of it and less loans. We see that as a increases first the North begins to purchase South equity and eventually the South also holds North equity. In the process, holdings of foreign loans decline. An important feature of the data is the persistence of net foreign asset positions. This requires that relative wealth positions Figure 9 confirms this is likely to do not change much over be the case, since the expected values growth rate of wealth are quite similar across countries. average growth rate the same year). is is slightly each our base case, South's true for the standard deviation of this growth rate (6 vs. 4.7 percent per Over the 30-year horizon covered by our dataset 6%. This sensitive to for the higher than North's (2.7 vs. 2.5 percent per year);and growth rates would lead to a cumulative increase only In time. finding of changes of the three To sum in an almost constant world the parameters. We in average this difference in the relative wealth of the South of distribution of wealth had already encountered is not very this result in examples discussed above. up, if diminishing returns at the country level are weak, a small doses of sovereign risk can move us a long way towards reconciling the theory's predicted capital flows with those we observe positions are small (Fact persistent (Fact 3). If 1), in the data. Both indicate that net foreign asset positively associated with wealth (Fact 2), and very diminishing returns at the country level are strong, the theory predicts net foreign asset positions that are too large relative to those 32 in the data. A natural In way to reduce them would be to assume that North has a better technology. any case, the key parameters regulating the size of crises and the strength portfolios, have in we of diminishing returns. With respect to the composition of find that the theory can replicate the data only the event of crises and/or production risk does the theory of capital flows are the probability is if is financed with loans (Fact 33 is a bad asset to not very important. Only then predict that foreign equity holdings are small foreign asset position equity 3). and most of the net Appendix A: Data Sources In this appendix we describe estimates of country portfolios. To do stock, foreign claims data and methodology used to construct tine on the domestic we this, require data on the domestic capital capital stock, the stock of domestic residents' holdings of capital located abroad, and domestic residents lending to and borrowing from abroad. Data on stocks of for some years some coverage Second, estimates of stocks time. set of countries, years, stock is is limited to rich countries of assets are constructed using on flows of investment in and assets. The flow of investment flows on international assets in countries and is available in methodologies which are and countries, assets, in much larger the domestic capital and a consistent treatment (B0PSY4 and B0PSY5). Payments In Statistics order to expand country coverage and ensure a consistent methodology across assets and countries, we up estimates of stocks of assets existing estimates of stocks, (A1) where in S,, Set is based primarily on constant 1990 build some identity that: =V,tS,,,_i+F„ US US this available flow data, and the standard accounting the value of the stock of a given asset constant 1990 of the balance of payments statistics the International Monetary Fund's Balance of Yearbook, Revisions 4 and 5 to recent years. these assets exist for a readily available from national accounts data, reported and documented and may vary considerably across contrast, data In some a variety of sources. This existing stock data suffers from two in deficiencies. First, the often poorly of these assets are available for dollars, dollars, F^ and is the flow of Vet is the the value of the stock of that asset in in country c at the end of period new investment in that asset, also gross change between periods period 34 t-1 t-1 and in t in t In its stock order to implement this approach for each asset, some in initial period, data information on changes describes how we do in require an estimate of on the corresponding flow of investment, and the value of the asset. each asset this for we The remainder of this appendix of interest. Domestic Capital Flows: PPP We use data on gross domestic investment in constant 1990 dollars at Summers and Heston Penn World Table Version from the (IxRGDPCHxPOP).^^ This covers and equipment, and changes in non-residential and 5.6 residential building, We depart from the inventories. machinery usual practice of cumulating only gross domestic fixed investment (which excludes inventory accumulation) since inventories themselves form a (small) component of wealth. Initial Stocks: countries starting start GDP initial delivers Since We then capital stock for GDP capital output ratios initial many We 1965 (KAPWx(1+KRES/100)xRGDPCHxPOP/RGDPW). per capita. data on per capita and all use the fitted of the countries and investment are GDP per capita is in of the countries in our final on our estimated stocks measurement after ratio on the log-level values of this regression to estimate our sample, available. in the first year for which Since the correlation between very large, this procedure by construction capital stocks that are very similar to the the 1950s, unavoidable ^® report estimates of capital stocks for 61 by estimating a cross-country regression of the capital/GDP of real the in Summers and Heston Summers-Heston estimates. sample have data on investment beginning errors in initial stocks will in have minimal impact 1966 when our data on foreign assets begins. We work with an expanded version of the Penn World Tables which extends the coverage GDP, investment, and population by using growth rates of local-currency constant price GDP and investment, as well as population, as reported in the World Bank World Tables, of real per capita 35 Valuation. be measured at we would In principle like the capital stock, and market value. An obvious choice would be value of capital by changes a share price index. This in to changes is may be developing countries where markets are and proxy changes Finally, we need in this thin. by the change in We is in the inappropriate for in not representative of the stock of capital as a whole. share prices and the underlying value of firms in other assets, to proxy changes several reasons. Capital listed on the stock market, especially countries, all developing The link between tenuous, especially in instead consider replacement cost, the local currency investment deflator. account physical depreciation. This of course varies to take into across assets, and probably also across countries (consider the adverse effects of poor infrastructure). the In absence of better information we are forced to rely on the average value of 6 percent used by Summers and Heston. summary, we measure the gross change In stock during period t Pt where 5=0.06 is value of the domestic capital as: Pf-I v„=(l-5)-!-i- (A2) in ^ct "^c,! ©ct-i Pi,,_i the depreciation rate, Pt is the US price level, ectis the in local currency units per US time A with the timing of these prices. t. small concern end-of-period stocks exchange is dollar, we would like to rates. Unfortunately gross mid-year averages for and P^^ is the investment deflator Since some in country c at are measuring domestic investment deflators are reported as in countries with very high inflation, timing we find is extremely large revaluations of the domestic capital stock that probably only reflect errors timing of we exchange leave them in rate and but discard rate use corresponding end-of-period prices and most countries, so that some mismatch unavoidable. Finally, for we exchange price data. in the Rather than censor these from our dataset, them when appropriate 36 in empirical work. Cross-Border Claims on Equity order to isolate the portion of the domestic capital stock In we need residents, measure domestic to subtract foreign claims residents' claims on on owned by domestic this asset. Similarly, capital located abroad. we need to These claims can take the form of direct investment or portfolio equity investment, although the dividing line between the two is vague. For example, ownership stake to constitue this paper, distinction we do is However, we construct data on the two other applications. We rely on flows Flows: investment as reported in In between majority and minority ownership as the irrelevant for our purposes. in countries consider a 10 percent direct investment, but this threshold varies for others. not distinguish stocks separately for use many the of inward B0PSY5 and outward (lines direct and portfolio equity 4505, 4555, 4610 and 4660). Data on these items are also available under the Revision 4 presentation of the Balance of Payments Statistics definitions between the between the countries, B0PSY4 We therefore almost perfect extend the coverage of the Stocks: The B0PSY5 and equity investment data from the first is practice, the in for in correspondence these items for most B0PSY5 backwards using data wherever possible. and 8660), and the B0PSY4 and B0PSY5, B0PSY5 and B0PSY4 Initial of direct Yearbook (B0PSY4). Although there are minor changes for some for reports data on the stocks corresponding to flows most industrial economies (lines 8505, 8555, 8610 countries these stocks can be extended backwards using B0PSY4. For most available stock reported in where these stocks are countries the available, BOPSY4 and B0PSY5, and then we use use Equation (A1) and the data on valuation changes discussed below to construct stocks for years for which flow data are available before and after stocks of direct investments are provided in the sources, they are quite similar to those reported OECD and UNCTAD, which rely BOPS in this date. Note that since as reported by country other publications such as the on the same national sources. 37 all For most developing countries, estimates of the stock of inward direct investment originating use this to aware in measure OECD in initial economies or originating in available stocks of direct investment any comprehensive source of is of data in (1970) for 1967. We are these countries. in on stocks OECD We not of portfolio equity investment developing countries, other than the B0PSY5 where coverage of this variable is very poor. For countries we sources, relative to for infer initial which no stock information an estimate of a zero Valuation. We capital. method as Applying this more observed stock, which initial is same difficult for the this use the since for each country we need type of information starting in direct to we and know distribution of the stock of direct investment in therefore use the in 6c',t-1 38 same Equation (A2). portfolio equity investment the destination by recipient OECD economies, value of capital located V,,=(l-5)-Zw,,,..%l.^^.^ rt of this OECD. across recipient countries to recipient country: cVc most the value of the mid-1980s as reported by the construct a weighted average of the changes (A3) in domestic capital stock, as summarized outward the probably correct. do not vary systematically with the ownership principle for valuing In in flows are zero, and so this country of their investment abroad. For direct investment by have that asset the average investment ratio For inward direct and portfolio equity investment, valuation in of these available to implement this approach. is initial we use proceed from the assumption that changes capital located in a country is portfolios, for portfolio equity investment, the in any order to smooth out year-to-year deviations from the equality In three years for which flow data results in stocks as the ratio of the flow of investment between marginal and average cases available gross domestic investment, multiplied by the domestic capital stock obtained above. first is Pc',t-i in each we We where w^ ^.j the share of foreign direct investment by country c located is We use this weighted c'. investment average to measure changes our sample, FDI across destination countries similar to that of is For portfolio equity investment, is distribution that the distribution of of the VctS for the 13 countries the data required to implement Equation (A3). distribution across recipient countries its in OECD economies. We therefore measure Vd for these countries as a simple average we have the value of outward direct we assume in which country 13 countries for which data on FDI by destination are available for the 1990, For the remaining countries for in in across countries possible to use the same is we do not have comparable data on We therefore assume that by source country. sufficiently similar to that of direct valuation adjustment as its we do investment that for direct investment. it ^^ Cross-Border Borrowing and Lending Flows: B0PSY5 credits We rely on (lines 4619+4703, and 4669+4753). This includes and other loans. with equity, there are B0PSYY4, which sample, and so inward and outward non-equity flows as reported in we all Data on these items are also available some changes in definition between the practice turn out to be minor for extend the coverage of the most in the debt securities, trade in the BOPSY4. As B0PSYY5 and of the countries in our B0PSY5 backwards using B0PSY4 data wherever possible. Initial Stocks: Stock data corresponding to these flows are available from a variety of sources. For developing countries, the most comprehensive available data ^^ It is worth noting a small caveat here. Data on flows of direct investment include reinvested earnings of foreign-owned firms, while data on flows of portfolio equity investment do not. In principle changes in the stock market valuation of equities will reflect these reinvested earnings, while changes in the replacement cost of capital do not. To the extent these reinvested earnings are important, our procedure will understate the stock of portfolio equity claims. However, the alternative of using stock market data to value equity Is even less attractive, given the weaknesses of stock market data noted above. 39 on stocks of debt is the World Bank's Global Development Finance (GDF) report, which provides data since 1970 (line DT.DOD.DECT.CD). For most countries, data on stocks of borrowing and lending are reported B0PSY4. The only source of data that countries B0PSY5 and B0PSY4, where is the those countries where lending, we infer Changes for three in reasons. denominated may change Finally, the value of debt repayment. In principle coverage information at all is very weak. Finally, for on stocks of borrowing and the dollar value of outstanding debt net of amortization The value of the currencies relative to the US dollar. may change each of these with will changes in which the debt difficult. country debts, we in will We therefore rely on the include adjustments for full changes change over in changes in time. and makes comprehensive the secondary recent, valuation adopt a more limited strategy. For developing time series of stocks reported by the in of the perceived probability of Unfortunately, secondary markets are thin of debt. is Depending on the structure be reflected especially for developing country debt, which adjustments B0PSY5 and are aware of for lending by developing debt and the term structure of interest rates, the value of debt market price the stocks from flows as described above for equity. Valuation: can occur we have no we in industrial GDF, as these the value of denominating currencies. For developing country lending, and for the borrowing and lending of industrial countries, we do not have data maturity structure. of debt is We therefore can do constant, so that the V„ = (A4) where even on the currency composition Pt is the change of these assets, let alone their no more than assume that the nominal value in the real value of debt outstanding is simply: ^ t-1 US consumer price index. It is interesting to note that for industrial countries with high-quality stock data on borrowing and lending, this simple method yields very similar estimates. 40 other Items The stocks in of cross-border assets described above cover the majority we For completeness, countries' international investment positions. of items measure also the reserves of the monetary authority, distinguishing between gold and non-gold reserves. Stocks of gold are a component on foreigners. For the purposes domestic capital stock. as reported in of wealth that of this paper, we does not constitute a claim therefore include We measure the stock of gold in it with the ounces millions of fine troy the International Monetary Fund's International Financial Statistics (IFS) (line 1ad) multiplied by the dollar price of gold. For most countries, short-term dollar-denominated debt instruments are an important component of non-gold reserves. For the purposes of this paper part of lending abroad. reported in the IFS We we therefore count non-gold reserves as a measure the stock of non-gold reserves directly as (line 1ld). Data and Results We implement these to the GDP sample in of ideas using data described above. 98 countries with population greater than 1990 greater than 1000 1990 US dollars at with fewer than five years of data on balance of there are substantial anomalies were unable in PPP. payments is the million We then items, and per capita discard countries and those for which the reported balance of payments statistics that to resolve with reference to country sources. problematic source of data 1 We restrict attention B0PSY5 By far the most and B0PSY4. The electronic versions these sources often report zero stocks when there are positive flows of assets. B0PSY4 the In we of the data occasionally contain outright errors which needed to be eliminated by inspecting the data for each variable, country and year. Since data coverage weak and we is the prevalence of these types of difficulties increases sharply prior to 1966, begin our sample in this year. This leaves us with an unbalanced panel of 73 countries covering an average of 25 years per country over the period 1966-1997. 41 Finally, occasionally our procedures described above result stocks of assets that are negative in some years, most extrapolating flows backwards from a stock estimate estimates of In commonly as a in later years. In result of the vast majority of cases these negative stocks are very small, less than 0.5 percent of in absolute value. If the minimum observation no smaller than -0.5 percent of GDP, we shift in a given stock series up the series is The data are available at www.worldbank.org/research/growth. 42 negative but to eliminate these. handful of remaining negative stocks are discarded. GDP The Appendix B: Solution Details we appendix, In this that Equations (5)-(9) describe his/her optimal consumption and investment opportunity set that the consumer faces We shall X=(v,v*,r,Tc,Ti*,a,a*). dynamics (A1) dt dX| =|i, In denote the element be given as of this + xi/, dco + xi/* equilibrium, the representative i^i, \\iu \^*, consumer is is fully element of portfolio rules. The described by the vector this vector as x,. Let the follows:^" •dco*+E,i and i'" ^i ds might be functions of aggregate variables, but infinitesimal and does his/her choices affect these aggregates. Let V° representative show solve the representative consumer's problem and consumer when s=0 and s=1, not take into consideration and V^ be the value functions respectively. Then, we have how of the that: .y^.i.!iii.yi!yl.a.a.^,. (A2) ZZ^(M',-v^+^:w;).pk-v^] j'^x^ax, , and the (A3) first-order condition = 1 c"' Also, 20 is: - dy' da we have During crises, state associated with this Bellman equation v, v* that: and r are to be interpreted as the asset prices that would apply changed. 43 if the 5 V° = maxl In • <c> c+ [jt • (k - e) + n * -e * +r • I - + c] da [ I ^ aa' a-[v^-V°] and the ^V 2 ' subjectto a = I first-order conditions = (A5) k- v-e + v *e*-l associated with + I 2 ' 9xf [i-. 9Xi "^ .2 2 (A4) V ^ ; k >e > ; e* > 0. equation are: this Bellnnan ^^ c-^ aa (A6) 0=— — —^-cf ^+ 9a —— r-- = (A7) da ^ dV° = ' where Tt * av° is + — ^-^—-^ +Xv3 ^dadx, 9a P+ ili - da • k-e da da p k-e —— — 7^-—^c^ da (A9) a-^ da -— = (A8) • 3a d^V° — da^ , • a* e * -Xv^ ^dady.^ -e^a^V" +> ^dadx; a-(t)-(X-v) + — da . a -^ f^V, dV'' W; ^' aa a pv-Tii+r|2 da • (b • v dV° * ^ the multiplier of the constraint a=k-ve+v*e*+l; and * +ri, " rjs are P v ^ aa and rii ri2 aa the multipliers associated with the constraints that k>e, The usual Kuhn-Tucker complementary-slack ri3e*=0. It is straightforward to verify that e>0 and e*>0, respectively. conditions apply: rir(k-e)=0, •r|2e=0 and 1 1 V° = — •lna + f°(X|) and V^ = — 5 Ina + f\X|) 6 solve the Bellman equations (A2) and (A4). Using these value functions and the order conditions, it follows that (A5)-(A9) correspond to Equations (5)-(9) 44 in first- the text. References Bulow, Jeremy and Kenneth Rogoff, "Sovereign Debt: Is to Forgive to Forget?," American Economic Review LXXIX (1989), 43-50. . Eaton, Jonatiian and Mark Gersovitz, "Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis," The Review of Economic Studies XLVIII (1981), 289-309. , Eaton, Jonathan and Raquel Fernandez, "Sovereign Debt," in Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff, eds. Handbook of International Economics Amsterdam, . Elsevier, 1995. and Charles Horioka, "Domestic Savings and Economic Journal XC (1980), 314-329. Feldstein, Martin, Flows," International Capital , French, Kenneth and James Poterba "Investor Diversification and International Equity Markets," American Economic Review LXXXI (1991), 222-226. , International Monetary Fund, "Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook," various issues. International Monetary Fund, "International Financial Statistics," various issues. Jaume Ventura, "Current Accounts in Debtor and Creditor Countries" Quarterly Journal of Economics forthcoming. Kraay, Aart and , Klenow, Peter J. and Andres Rodriguez-Clare, "The Neoclassical Revival in Growth Economics; Has It Gone Too far?" in Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg eds. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997 . Lane, Philip and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, "The External Wealth of Nations: Measures of Foreign Assets and Liabilities for Industrial and Developing Countries," International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 99/115, 1999. Lewis, Karen, "Trying to Explain Economic Literature , Home Bias in Equities and Consumption," Journal XXXVII (1999), 571-608. "Why doesn't capital flow from rich to poor countries?," American Economic Review LXXX (1990), 92-96. Lucas, Robert E., , and Kenneth Rogoff, Foundations of International Macroeconomics Cambridge, MIT Press, 1996. Obstfeld, Maurice , 45 of Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, "Stocl<s of Private Direct Investments by DAC Countries in Developing Countries End 1967, Paris, OECD. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, "International Direct Investment Statistics Yearbook", various issues. Rider, Mark, "External debt and Liabilities of Industrial Countries," Research Discussion Paper 9405, Reserve Bank of Australia, 1994. Sinn, Stefan, "Net External Asset Positions of 145 Countries: Estimation Interpretation," Institut fiJr and Weltwirtschaft, University of Kiel, 1990. Summers, Robert and Alan Heston, "Penn World Table Mark 5: An Expanded Set of International Comparisons", Quarterly Journal of Economics CVI (1991), 327, 68. Tesar, Linda, and Ingrid Werner, "Home Bias and the Globalization of Securities," National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 4218, 1992. United Nations Center on Transnational Corporations, "World Investment Directory", various issues. 46 > _ w >2O OOO CO _l 2W< 2 N til J3 o z d. °- n <2 E .— *j — IS u Q. ce a: .2 c ra c .Q CO o ^ o ro w < < CO CD •a n <^ m ^ _i CL "^ .-Oi6^o$i<>='3 QL1J£5^t2OOTC0I-H ™ bi 5 < LU i E CO >, OWW " : 15 3 -5 c' t: CO 3 " c CO CD uj ' j»: 2 — "2 C O (D 10 CD O OOO 3 CD < 3 m ^ CD d) 2 o CO OT CO (A 0) c ra 4) C 3 O n z _ ce CO _j Q. < I o>IOX y ^ Q_ CO H O^ to O >sr o e)-i<_j-i-2z3^Q3X,, q: -^ >; z QiOccxoarOoH-z^iuyiu > o ^1 a: <mcQOOOQliJOl-S^ZQ.CO H 3 m > JO o 0) O) o CD Q. c 3 j: E O ac ni w XI •D n O) c OL o <u > <1> (A < CO CD ro CD _- 5? f- ro >^ S 2 c o -p Q. CL ^ o ro ro O "o ^m = z ^ ^ D. -c "a CJ OJ 5; q: != ro I- CO ro c tu E ^" < .= .E -- lCO "c ro cu ^o 2^ < m .9 E ro 1- CD CD -Ij= O CD X 2 ^ => ^ D- ^ < K O 33_!<XlUZcoltt:COD^d< <<CDOCJQQUJU-Li-OOtt CO '-' '-' OQ => c F o m ? OX _i ON CC S CO ro c CJ) 0) CO -Q 3 5 3 E E CD 3 0 Ul T. _J c gium- Stralia 3 DC << itzeria nada stria 3 3 CD CD ro ^ CO ro t= != CD "D c E E 1CD n cz CO CO c Cl) Q >. CD CO LL u_ CD CD en C K 3 i^ to CO > "O _ ,„ CD ro 3 CO c §> c= CD ro O) V) 0) — o CO o ^ o o o CJ o C CD CD y o E CO I- U) * X3 ro re h- H 0) re (0 to O S M CO > ^ 3 ^ ^- Q.=; E ? t: S o O) Z Z o 5 Q. CO 0) = 3 c; ro ; Z E CL LU H3> Table 2: Net Foreign Assets Are Small (Share of net foreign assets 66-73 in country portfolios 74-81 f/a) 82-89 90-97 66-97 Weighted Average Industrial Countries 0.013 0.007 0.000 -0.006 0.004 Developing Countries -0.099 -0.037 -0,081 -0.065 -0.068 EAP LAC -0.090 -0.036 -0.051 -0.036 -0.037 -0.095 -0.102 -0.150 -0.101 -0.112 MENA -0.169 -0.034 -0.121 -0.068 SA SSA -0.054 0.133 -0.043 -0.054 -0.063 -0.054 -0.195 -0.138 -0.118 -0.069 -0.137 -0.011 -0.028 -0.025 -0.037 -0.016 -0.120 -0.116 -0.167 -0.139 -0.137 EAP LAC -0.098 -0.113 -0.117 -0.080 -0.093 -0.116 -0.122 -0.215 -0.150 -0.153 MENA -0.108 -0.072 -0.164 -0.165 -0.171 SA SSA -0.086 -0.102 -0.115 -0.095 -0.085 -0.202 -0.185 -0.112 -0.035 -0.206 Median Industrial Countries Developing Countries • Notes: Weighted averages are computed Dver an un balanced Danel 8- year averages for 68 countries. As a result, changes across periods to a small extent reflect changes in the composition of the sample. Results using a smaller balanced panel are similar. 48 t h- in m ^ CO CD CNJ d o d CM CD o d r-- x— CM CD ci CD CO cz> O CM q d CD ^ O o O O o CO o oo CD CM q o q d o d d d d d d CD CM CM CD CM CM CO CO 'S- ,-^ CT) 6 a> o O i- LU 6 CO ^ o d q d C7> CD CD ^ CD CD in o d * "^_ 1 CD in CO in CO in CD 'Sh- ^ CO CM CO 00 T— CD CD ^ o o m o O ^ d dd9 d ^ 00 00 00 oo in t^ d d ,_ CM in CD in CD CO CM en CM •* CD ^ o o ^ CO CO •* in CM CO CO o o o X— CO O O oo d d d d d dd d d CO T cT) o d T en op CNl CD o o M— a> CXI o O C3 in o d o o d o CD s 00 o o CM CO r^ o o 00 CM ^ d CD CD d X in CD CD r-^ ^ •* CO .,_ 00 00 ^ 00 CO in CD o d q d q d Vt^ d 1 d sz 1^ ro (V ^ ^ +J > a> (A (0 a> in CO oo o CO T— * o o O O T— CM o o O o d d d d d d d d d i_* u. CO UJ O S CO in CD CD h- CO CM CM "* h- CZ) o d o d ,_ in CD o d CM CO CT) CJ> 00 4 t-- H— O d § u O CO in CD CD o d CO "Y o CO q d ^ in CD t- CO * o 00 o o CO O o CM q d d d o CD d d CT> CT> r-- CM CD s d d to »-> 0) (A o o 1- < UJ C ^ D) CD o d o CN q d CO in o d o d c:^ CO 00 CD in o O in CM CO o CD CD CO CM o ^ o ^. q d d d d d d d d ^ CD r^ CM in .^— "51- ^ CO O U. CD CD CO rc^ 2 o 0) z o o CD r o o o q o o o O o 5 d d d d d q d d 1^ CD Oi CD 00 in lO T CO CM CM 00 CM T CO in CD CD CD m^ i^ CO in UO CO ro O CD CO d d Q. , , CO £ a> ro ^ <i> i-i .^ f— LU CO r~- CJ) S CO (0 q CD o ,— t-- CM ^ q d 5 o h- in CO ^ o ^ in CO CO LO o CO CM o o o T— CM o o r^ d d d d d d d dd ^ t~-- c T T q d ^ ^ V "D (1> a. s TO (A O ** .^ n 0) 0) o O g c c o c» ID o d 00 in o d 00 CO CD CD CD o d ^ E E 3 a c c CD 0> CJ O) c m 2 c o •-• o o z o o o o d d ^— a> CD CO CM CT) CO CD CD CD CL CO X CJ> CO 00 LU CO CD in en in d <D Z3 > "ra o en ^ ^ o o o d o d ro -a 1 O O in en 00 r- CD CD CD CM CO CO X— CD >, c O c ro « c o O CO 0) CO Q) E E D E Q ro c o en CD a: E D Q ro CO O) c "o <1> o a: Si D CO CJ c ro O Dc a oo n ni CD ro Q. "D cyi c en .9 .9 ro ro £ £ ro CD O) ro CD ro ^ JD O O IX CD tt ** c O o c CD en <X> en ro V) O *-• c o o CD Q. ro O -2 'n. CD CO en 5 CD £ > ro "a a Q O CL Q a en o E E + Q- 13 in c (D t Q O o Q. CD X CM LU !Z en en CD c o o -C Q. Q. en 0} g t: > > o 2 O O o ro o O zs > a. CD c (0 o a q X! c .5 ro > o ro > en en O ro =! o o CO ro x: tt a: CO d Table 4: Foreign Assets Consist Primarily of Borrowing and Lending fifi-73 74-81 82-89 90-97 fifi-97 Net Foreign Assets Owned by Foreigners 0.013 0.025 0.007 0.000 -0.006 0.004 Equity 0.024 0.042 0.033 Equity Held Abroad 0.028 0.029 Gross Lending Gross Borrowing 0.041 0.061 0.031 0.059 0.029 0.032 0.124 0.127 -0.099 -0.037 0,039 0.022 Equity Held Abroad 0.004 0.002 Gross Lending Gross Borrowing 0.024 0.088 Weighted Average Industrial Countries 0.053 0.039 0.158 0.112 0.175 0.114 -0.081 -0.065 -0.068 0.029 0.028 0.005 0.003 0.060 0.023 0.002 0.048 0.041 0.045 0.077 0.108 0.082 0.088 -0.011 -0.028 -0.025 -0.037 -0.016 0.021 0.021 0.030 0.061 0.035 0.007 0.007 0.023 0.053 0.028 0.046 0.050 0.119 0.140 0.105 0.044 0.083 0.161 0.199 0.145 -0.120 -0.116 -0.167 -0.139 -0.137 0.039 0.000 0.027 0.031 0.033 0.035 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.028 0.043 0.128 0.045 0.174 0.056 0.051 0.155 0.160 Developing Countries Net Foreign Assets Equity Owned by Foreigners Median Industrial Countries Net Foreign Assets Equity Owned by Foreigners Equity Held Abroad Gross Lending Gross Borrowing Developing Countries Net Foreign Assets Equity Owned by Foreigners Equity Held Abroad Gross Lending Gross Borrowing 0.105 Notes: Weighted averages are computed over an unbalanced panel of 8-year averages for 68 countries. As a result, chang es across periods to a small extent reflect changes in the composition of the sam pie. Results using a smaller balanced panel are similar. 50 Table 5: Examples 2 and 3 Foreign Assets / Wealth in the North Sigma=0.00 Alpha Gamma 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.00 0.375 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.10 0.375 0.098 0.054 0.037 0.028 0.023 0.20 0.375 0.161 0.099 0.071 0.055 0.045 0.40 0.375 0.229 0.163 0.126 0.102 0.086 0.60 0.375 0.264 0.203 0.165 0.138 0.119 Sigma:=0.05 Alpha Gamma 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.00 0.375 0.030 0.015 0.010 0.008 0.006 0.10 0.375 0.119 0.067 0.046 0.035 0.028 0.050 0.20 0.375 0.175 0.110 0.079 0.062 0.40 0.375 0.236 0.170 0.132 0.107 0.090 0.60 0.375 0.268 0.208 0.169 0.142 0.122 In this calculation, 9=0.04 we (k^"^+k*^"^)"\ set the average return We also set world wealth 51 to capital constant at equal to one, that is, 4 percent, that a+a*=1. is, we set Table 6: Example 3 Discount on South Equity (v*) Alpha Gamma 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.00 1.000 0.815 0.677 0.578 0.504 0.447 0.10 1.000 0.860 0.730 0.630 0.553 0.492 0.20 1.000 0.879 0.763 0.667 0.591 0.529 0.40 1.000 0.894 0.797 0.713 0.643 0.585 0.60 1.000 0.901 0.814 0.739 0.675 0.621 Foreign Investment Gamma 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.00 1.500 0.728 0.570 0.476 0.409 0.359 0.10 1.500 1.014 0.737 0.592 0.498 0.431 0.20 1.500 1.193 0.875 0.698 0.583 0.502 0.40 1.500 1.389 1.067 0.867 0.729 0.629 0.60 1.500 1.492 1.189 0.987 0.842 0.734 In this calculation, e=0.04(k^"^+k*'' South (e*v*/a*) Alpha in we ')"' set the average return to capital constant at 4 percent, that We also set world wealth equal to one, that 52 is, a+a*=1. is, we set Figure 1: Net Foreign Assets Are Small 0.4 0.35 0.3 > u c 3 oo 0.25 (1) 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 < -0.5 < -0.4 < -0.3 < -0.2 < -0.1 <0 < 0.1 < 0.2 < 0.3 < 0.4 < 0.5 > Net Foreign Assets/Wealtli Notes: This figure plots the frequency distribution of the share of net foreign assets all country-year observations in an unbalanced panel spanning 68 wealth, pooling countries over the period 1966-1997. 53 in .5 Figure 2: Domestic Capital Stocl<s and Wealth Are Highly Correlated CHE NOR 60000 y = 0.9345x+ 1624.1 .- 50000 R^ = 0.9776 Q. re u ^ 40000 NZLcAN 75 Q. 30000 re O o «) (U 20000 £ o 10000 10000 20000 30000 40000 50000 Wealth Per Capita Notes: Switzerland (a=$1 10000, k = $90000) is not 54 shown to scale. 60000 Figure 3: The Share of Net Foreign Assets In Country Portfolios Increases with Wealth 0.6 0.058X - 0.6427 CHE SVEffillW AUS CAN CMR JAM CIV -0.6 8 9 10 11 12 ln(Wealth Per Capita) Notes: Congo (ln(a)=7.22,f/a -1.55) and Egypt (ln(a)=7.2, f/a-0.98) are influential and are excluded. Including these two observations gives a slope of 0.09 with a standard error of 0.01. 55 Figure 4: The Share of Net Foreign Assets In Country Portfolios Is Persistent 1 y=0.98x-0.00 0.8 R' = 0.93 0,6 < -1 -0.6 -0.8 0.2 -0.4 0.4 0.6 O.f Foreign Assets/Wealth(t-1) 1 0.8 y = 0.84X - 0.03 R^ = 0.58 < -1 -0.8 -0.6 6 0.2 -p^' 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Foreign Assets/Wealth(t-5) 1 0.8 0.6 y=0.64x-0.06 R' = 0.30 0.4 y»0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Foreign Assets/Wealth(t-10) Notes: This graph plots the share of foreign assets in wealth against its one-year (five-year) (10-year) lag in the first (second) (third) panels, pooling all country-year observations in an unbalanced panel spanning 68 countries over 1966-97. 56 Figure 5: The Persistence 1970 1975 of the Net Foreign Asset Share 1980 1985 Changes Over Time 1990 1995 Notes: This graph plots the slope coefficient of a cross-sectional regression of the share of in wealth on itself lagged one year, for the year indicated on the horizontal foreign assets axis. The heavy line is a three-year centered moving average of these slope coefficients. 57 Figure 6: Foreign Assets Consist Primarily of Borrowing and Lending (All Countries) 0.5 1 0.4y = 0.8243x+ 0.0176 SAU " R" = 0.8857 °-2 1 0.20.1 ChJE^ SGP c BLX^-'^''^^ - TTO nding Le -0.4 -0.3 -0.2_^|M§^) 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.5 Net of 1 p > Share C_ V C^ -0.4 - -0.5 - Share of Foreign Assets in Wealth (Industrial Countries) 15 0.5 1 0.4 - y = 0.81 34x+ 0.0035 ^'^ R^ = 0.8994 0.2 0.1 c - BLX^/^ - #^ c yf^T*«c,uy Le en Net CHE -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 i^^^S' ) , 0.1 0.2 of Share -0.3 - -0.4 - -0.5 - Share of Foreign Assets 58 in Wealth ^ , , , ' 0.3 0.4 0.5 IT) CO CM o O o o o c o V c o o 3 DO E D) (0 D> * > o -c 3 O > ro *2 1 O 1 Si < c o '^ inoOT-aJt^LDcor-T-roLn E 3 w inrOT-CT)h~.incOT-T-coio T^t-'i-^ooocbcJooc) (A < o O CD 0) c o 00 o d D 0) Q si - T3 / O CO o i O > CD +^ W c O d 1 / 0) flj en O 00 1 / CM 0> o 3 / CNJ o 1 IT 1 LO CO T- /— ' T— CO LD I^ O) o o o o o c o O 1 1 1 r 1 >T1 00 ir> T1 1 tnco-^-T-coioh-co cziddddddd ns E Figure 9: Implications of Theory for Persistence of Foreign Asset Positions Average Growth Volatility of 5236 CkO 61 Growth Date Due Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 01917 6616