Emerging Dominance of Aquaculture: The Future of the Seafood Market and Fisheries Management James L. Anderson Department of Environmental and Natural Resource Economics University of Rhode Island Kingston, RI 02879 USA IIFET 2008 Nha Trang, Vietnam July 21-25, 2008 Key Themes Aquaculture will dominate the seafood market – esp. international trade Winners will control costs and manage for markets Fisheries managed more like ‘aquaculture’ --- win Aquaculture sectors managed more like fisheries (US marine aquaculture) --- lose Seafood Sector Extremely Complex and Diverse – 100s of species, many technologies, many areas Highly International Bureaucratic Regulatory Environment Fragmented Wasteful Marketing is Not Advanced Highly Misunderstood by Consumers including Chefs Volatile – in Prices and Quantities Simple Realities Demand for Fish Fishermen Catch Fish Poorly Defined Rights and Responsibilities (Traditional Fisheries Management) Overfishing, Rent Dissipation Reduced Supply and Unmet Demand Enter Aquaculture Inefficient Fisheries Management and/or Unmet Demands are the Stimuli for Aquaculture and Innovation Simple Realities People whose lives depend on the harvest of seafood want: – – – – – Better control of cost Minimize environmental/exogenous shocks Better control fish stock and growth rates Manage to meet the market demand Sustainable profits CONTROL of production and marketing through Ownership, Information and Technology If the Future will be Dominated by Aquaculture What does it mean for the future of the seafood sector? What does it mean for the future of fisheries/aquaculture management? U.S. Per Capita Consumption of Red Meat, Poultry, and Fish and Shellfish, 1909-2006 140 Pounds per Capita 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1909 1915 1921 1927 1933 1939 1945 1951 Red Meat 1957 1963 1969 Poultry Source: USDA/Economic Research Service. *2004-2006 Red Meat and Poultry data are forecasts. 1975 1981 1987 1993 Fish & Shellfish 1999 2005* Approximate World Production of “Food” Fish and Seaweeds Aquaculture accounted for 47% of world food fish production in 2006. 144 Aquaculture accounted for only 15% in 1984. 132 120 108 Million MT 96 84 72 60 48 36 24 12 0 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 Farmed Source: FISHSTAT (2008). 1994 1996 1998 Wild 2000 2002 Total 2004 2006 To develop expectations about the future of the seafood sector, we must consider aquaculture and fisheries interact? In the ecosystem? In the market ? Aquaculture and Fisheries: Ecosystem Use of wild fish for inputs Disease transmission and related interactions Intentional releases or unintentional escapes Use or enhancement of habitat The growth of aquaculture influences fisheries through its use of wild fish as inputs Feed – Small pelagics for fishmeal and fish oil Wild-Based Aquaculture – – – – – Tuna Post-larval shrimp Eel Grouper Mussel Broodstock – Salmon (in past) – Shrimp (mostly in past) A Note on “The Feed Issue” Using fish to feed fish is “unsustainable” (ex. salmon, shrimp farming) Growth of aquaculture farming will exhaust the fishmeal and fish oil supply and cause overfishing – This is a fisheries management/governance problem not an aquaculture problem Reality The majority of fishmeal is used by poultry and pigs Increasing relative price of fishmeal & fish oil – Provides economic incentives for innovation – Improving feed conversion ratios, new feed formulations/substitutes, new species Aquaculture and Disease Example: ¾ Parasite, B. ostreae, was introduced (probably) into France in oysters imported from California which originated from the NMFS Aquaculture Lab in CT NRC. 2004. Nonnative Oysters in the Chesapeake Bay. Nat. Academy Press. Washington DC. p 40. NRC. 2004. Nonnative Oysters in the Chesapeake Bay. Nat. Academy Press. Washington DC. p 16. Chesapeake Bay Oyster “Fishery” Management Options Replenish/Restore oyster habitat = Aquaculture Oyster sanctuaries (fallow fields) = Aquaculture Introduce disease resistant native oysters = Aquaculture Introduce triploid native oysters that grow fast enough to harvest before they get disease = Aquaculture Introduce triploid Asian C. ariakensis oysters = Aquaculture Introduce diploid Asian C. ariakensis oysters = Aquaculture Traditional Traditional Fisheries Fisheries Management Management isis Largely Largely Irrelevant! Irrelevant! Introduction of a Nonnative Species May become invasive but it may help save or create an industry Introduction of Asian Oyster in France and West Coast US – saved/created and industry Introduction of White Shrimp from S. America to Asia – reduced cost Introduction of Salmon to Chile, Australia and New Zealand – created an industry Introduction of Channel Catfish from the US to China – created an industry Introduction of Tilapia from Africa to Everywhere – created industries/became invasive some places Aquaculture (Hatchery)-Based Fisheries Can result in increased harvest - so fishermen like it, but….. It is inefficient In some cases it has resulted in large production of lower-valued species (ex. AK chum and pink; Japan chum; Russia pink and chum) Problems with genetic diversity and integrity of wild stocks Alaska Commercial Salmon Catches Since 1960: Natural Wild Salmon and Hatchery Salmon 250,000 150,000 Hatchery Natural wild 100,000 50,000 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 0 1960 thousands of fish 200,000 Source: Data for 1960-1978: ADF&G Catch Data; Data for 1979-2005: ADF&G Hatchery Data Aquaculture (Hatchery)-Based Fisheries: Integrity of wild stocks Hatchery fish do not face the same selective pressure as wild stocks Hatchery releases can displace wild stocks and compete for food and habitat Million Fish Historical Hatchery Contribution to Total Commercial Harvest of Pink Salmon Prince William Sound, Alaska 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 Natural Wild 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 Hatchery reared Source: Prince William Sound Annual Management Reports, ADF&G (2007, 2006). 2001 2003 Aquaculture and Habitat Negative for wild fish stocks Shrimp farms in the estuary - mangrove Excessive finfish cage culture and pollution Positive for wild fish stocks Oyster reef building Rotational Management of Scallops (like forestry) – creates marine protected areas (fallow fields) Aquaculture and fisheries interact in the ecosystem. Aquaculture is a fisheries management option. Very little economic research has been done to evaluate the interactions. Aquaculture and Fisheries: International Trade and the Market Aquaculture has had a Tremendous Influence on Fisheries through International Trade and the Market Increased supply has influenced prices – Influenced effort in some fisheries (ex. salmon) Changed consumer behavior and developed new markets (ex. catfish) Accelerated globalization (ex. shrimp, tilapia, salmon) – Reaction more trade barriers Increased concentration and vertical integration (ex. salmon) New product forms and improved quality and consistency (ex. tilapia, salmon) Forward thinking and market driven (ex. salmon, oysters) Improved stability and reduce uncertainty (ex. salmon) Growing Market Share and Product Innovation Consistently Available Consistent Quality Stable or Declining Cost Meet Consumer Demands US Seafood Consumption is Concentrating in Fewer Species Edible kg per Capita 1987 71% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Tuna Shrimp Cod AK Pollock Flatfish Clams Catfish Salmon Crab Scallops Other Total Source: NFI (2008). 2006 1.59 1.04 0.76 0.40 0.33 0.30 0.27 0.20 0.15 0.15 2.16 7.35 56% 90% Shrimp Tuna Salmon AK Pollock Tilapia Catfish Crab Cod Clams Scallops Other Total 2.00 1.32 0.92 0.74 0.45 0.44 0.30 0.23 0.20 0.14 0.75 7.48 % change +92 -17 72% +359 +86 N/A +63 +101 -70 -33 -8 -65 +2 U.S. Retail Sales, 1994 vs. 2007 Source: Seafood Business Best Sellers (Seafood Case) 1994 2007 1 Shrimp Shrimp 2 Salmon Salmon 3 Pollock, Cod, Haddock Crab 4 Catfish Tilapia 5 Flounder Catfish Sources: Perkins, C. (1994) and Robinson, F. (2004) Large Retailer and Chain Restaurant Demands have: Encouraged vertical and horizontal integration Stimulated globalization Encouraging various certification programs – Sustainability and Safety – – – – Farmed Salmon Wild Salmon Shrimp Alaska Pollock Note on Selling Sustainability and Health to US Consumers Sustainability and Safety are essentially required esp. now that companies like WalMart and Darden Restaurants are involved Healthfulness is important but secondary to the US consumer – We are Fat! Priorities for the Bulk of Real Consumers (not Green Peace members, Gourmets, pregnant mothers or movie stars) – Convenience – Taste – Price – Perceived Value Photo: Jingjie Chu Photo: Jingjie Chu Real Price Trends of Seafood 7.50 7.00 Wild Cod, fillet, frozen 6.50 6.00 5.50 2000 US$/lb 5.00 4.50 4.00 Farmed Salmon, 2-3 lb fillet, fresh 3.50 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 Farmed Catfish, fillet, frozen 0.50 0.00 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Sources: USDA, 1990-2008; Urner-Barry Publications, 1990- 2008; USDC/NMFS, 1990-2008. % Standard Deviation -20 6 4 1985-1992 3 1993-1999 5.62 5 3.77 2.83 2 1 0 2000-2008 Jan-08 Jan-07 Jan-06 Jan-05 Jan-04 Jan-03 Jan-02 Jan-01 Jan-00 Jan-99 Jan-98 Jan-97 Jan-96 Jan-95 Jan-94 Jan-93 Jan-92 Jan-91 Jan-90 Jan-89 Jan-88 Jan-87 Jan-86 Jan-85 % Rate of Change 20 US Fresh Atlantic Dressed Imports – Price Monthly Percentage Rate of Change and Standard Deviation 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 Cost Share: Aquaculture vs. Fishery Item Labor Maintenance Fuel Fingerlings Feed Aquaculture Fishery 4-10% 2-4% 1-4% 2-15% 40-60% 25-45% 9-23% 4-11% — — Cost Factors Influencing Competitiveness Aquaculture Biotechnology Disease Management Feed Cost/ Quality Consolidation/ Restructuring Farm Management Regulations Fishery Fisheries Governance Fish Stock Environment Crew-share Arrangements Maintenance/Repair “Technical Progress has been Futile” Rolf Willmann, FAO, Loss in Resource Rents Session, IIFET 2008 Production Cost: Salmon Aquaculture vs. Capture Fisheries 100 9.00 90 8.00 Salmon Aquaculture in Norway 7.00 70 2 0 0 6 U S $ /k g 2 0 0 6 N O K /k g 80 60 50 40 30 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 20 2.00 10 1.00 0 0.00 1985 1988 1991 Export Price 1994 1997 2000 2003 Production Cost Sources: Norwegian Directorate of Fisheries (2005); Guttormsen (2007). Bristol Bay Drift Gillnet Sockeye Salmon Fishery 2006 1985 1988 1991 Ex-vessel Price 1994 1997 2000 2003 Production Cost Sources: ADF&G (2007); Valderrama (2008). 2006 Norway: Salmon Farming Photos: J.L. Anderson Wild Salmon Fishery MSC Certified Sustainable Alaska Sockeye Fishery Alaska’s Bristol Bay drift gillnet salmon fishery -2005. (Photograph by Bart Eaton, Source: Gunnar Knapp) Norway: Salmon Processing Photos: J.L. Anderson Alaska Salmon Handling Sockeye salmon in a Bristol Bay gillnet at low tide –Source G. Knapp Internal bruises in a wild chum salmon fillet -Source G. Knapp Permit Market Value and Percent of Permits Fished in the Bristol Bay Sockeye Fishery Drift Gillnet Fishery 300 80% 240 60% 180 40% 120 20% 60 0% 0 1988 1990 1992 1994 Permit Market Value Source: CFEC (2007). 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Percent Permits Fished T housand Dollars Percent Permits Fished 100% Competition with farmed salmon has increased efficiency through reduction of effort – Bristol Bay Salmon, Alaska Competition with farmed salmon has increased efficiency through attempts to restructure the fleet – Chignik Salmon Coop., Alaska The Aquaculture Sector Creates New Markets Salmon Farmers created new markets in southern US Farmed Salmon created new markets premium wild salmon New Products – Pin-Bone-Out Salmon Fillet New markets are all being developed by aquaculturists: ex. sturgeon, barramundi, tilapia, basa, oysters, cobia, mussels and many other species Diesel Fuel: Producer Price Index 1990 = 100 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2008). 2002 2004 2006 2008 Implications of Rising Fuel Cost Stronger competitive position of farmed fish and shellfish over: Wild-caught seafood Fishmeal and Soymeal Prices 1,500 Fishmeal Soybean meal US$/MT 1,200 900 600 300 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 Fishmeal: 64/65%, any origin, wholesale, CIF Hamburg. Soybean meal: 44%, any origin, CIF Rotterdam/Hamburg. Source: Oil World / GLOBEFISH (2007). 2003 2005 2007 Implications of Rising Feed Cost Stronger competitive position of farmed shellfish (clams, oyster, mussels, scallops) compared to: Farmed Finfish and Shrimp Beef, Pork and Chicken 3.5 3 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 C a tc h (M ill. m e tric to n n e s ) Global Cod Fisheries – A Stimulus for Aquaculture Atlantic cod Pacific cod 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Farmed Atlantic Cod 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 FAO and Tveteras MT World Tilapia Production 2.8 2.4 Global production of tilapia grew at an average annual rate of 7% (farmed 12%) between 1981 and 2005. Tanzania Mexico 2.0 Million MT Other Taiwan 1.6 1.2 Brazil Photo: J.L. Anderson Thailand Uganda Philippines 0.8 Indonesia 0.4 Egypt China 0.0 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Source: FISHSTAT (2007). US Imports of Tilapia 180 160 Average annual rate of growth between 1992 and 2007: 30% 140 MT (000's) 120 100 80 60 Photo: J.L. Anderson 40 20 0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Tilapia Fresh Fillets Tilapia Frozen Fillets Tilapia Frozen (Exc. Fillets) Total Source: USDC/NMFS (2008). Tilapia Market Very rapid growth Competition for flatfish, snapper and other whitefish Fillets – Market innovation Many environmental NGOs are positive about tilapia Increase globalization Wal-Mart Photo: J.L. Anderson 500 U.S. Imports of Salmon vs. Tilapia Actual (1989-2006) and Forecast (20072015) 450 437 400 360 MT (000's) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 Salmon & Trout 2003 2005 2007 Tilapia Source: USDC (2006); Seafood Market Analyst, SeafoodReport.com: U.S. Imports Edition, 2006. Upper and lower bounds represent 95% confidence intervals. 2009 2011 2013 2015 Expect Continued Rapid Growth Rough Est. 2006 Tilapia – 2.8 million MT Pangasius – over 500,000 MT Channel Catfish – over 400,000 MT Flatfish – 140,000 MT Barramundi – 35,000 MT Cod – 15,000 MT Cobia - ? Blue Revolution? With all this technological change, one might expect countries that think they are adaptive and entrepreneurial - like the US – to be leaders Maybe Not Times are Changing Marine/Coastal Aquaculture Production in China, Norway, and the U.S. Why isn’t the US participating in the ‘Blue Revolution”? 20 China - Million MT 1.00 0.80 15 0.60 10 0.40 5 0.20 0 0.00 1985 1987 1989 1991 China Source: FISHSTAT (2008). 1993 1995 1997 Norway 1999 2001 USA 2003 2005 Norway & USA - Million MT 25 Fisheries Management “The integrated process of information gathering, analysis, planning, decision-making, allocation of resources and formulation and enforcement of fishery regulations by which the fishery management authority controls the present and future behavior of interested parties in the fisheries, in order to ensure the continued productivity of the living resources.” (FAO 1999). The difference between traditional fisheries management and “aquaculture” management boils down to: Who is in CONTROL What is being CONTROLLED Traditional fisheries management – Governing institutions CONTROL individual or group behavior – but not the aquatic organism Aquaculture – The individual or group, CONTROLS the production, harvest and marketing of the aquatic organism - the individual or group receives rights for CONTROL from by the governing institution Typical Fishery Management Regulated Access Management Institutions CONTROL participants “Aquaculturalized” Management Rights & Responsibility Based Management Institutions transfer CONTROL to participants Wild ‘Fishery’ Sector Rent Dissipation, High transaction cost – ex. many fisheries Positive rents ex. NZ Fisheries ‘Aquaculture’ Sector Rent Dissipation, High transaction cost ex. US Marine Aquaculture Positive rents ex. Norway Salmon Farming Bureaucracy is large Regulatory costs are very high Special Interests greater influence Bureaucracy stable or limited Regulatory costs relatively low Special Interests reduced influence Bureaucracy, Police & Non-Government Special Interest “Aquaculturization” of Fisheries - Taking Control Assign Ownership Rights Individual or community fisheries quota Cooperative area management fisheries Plant the Field / Breed the Animals: Salmon hatcheries (nearly 40% of AK harvest originates in hatcheries) Oyster/scallop enhancement Crop and Forest Rotation Rotational Scallop Fisheries Fallow Fields/Range Management Marine Reserves/Sanctuaries Land/Habitat Restoration Rebuild Oyster Beds Remove dams Artificial Reefs Feed/Fertilize Maine Lobsters get ~ 80% of the feed from bait Capture-Based Aquaculture - Bluefin Tuna farming Control Predators/Provide Protection Lobster pots Harvest starfish in oyster beds Eliminate Costless Access (Cattle Rustlers) Eliminate unregulated open access Marine Aquaculture Norway – Well defined Rights and Responsibilities China – Late 1970s Rural Reforms and rapid market liberalization – trend toward shifting more responsibility from the government to individuals US – Moving toward more government over sight in aquaculture – – – – Costly, time consuming, fragmented and uncertain regulation Multiple agencies at all levels – local, state and federal Fishery management regulations imposed on aquaculture Don’t even have enabling legislation to regulate offshore aquaculture in federal waters ! Note on China Photo: Jingjie Chu Photo: Jingjie Chu Photo: J.L. Anderson China: International Seafood Trade ($1000) 10,000,000 9,000,000 8,000,000 7,000,000 6,000,000 Export Value Import Value 5,000,000 4,000,000 3,000,000 2,000,000 1,000,000 0 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 China: #1 Seafood Exporter #6 Seafood Importer Source: FishStat, FAO 2008 China: International Seafood Trade (MT) 4,000,000 3,500,000 3,000,000 2,500,000 Export Quantity Import Quantity 2,000,000 1,500,000 1,000,000 500,000 0 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 China: #1 Seafood Exporter #1 Seafood Importer Source: FishStat, FAO 2008 US Imports from China: 2007 (Source: NMFS 2008) Breaded Shrimp - #1 (Thailand #2) Squid - #1 (Thailand #2) Scallops - #1 (Canada #2) Tilapia - #1 (Ecuador #2) Alaska Pollock - #1 (South Korea #2) Flatfish Fillets - #1 (Canada #2) Cod Fillets - #1 (Iceland #2) 2006: Total - #1 in Quantity.. #3 in Value (Canada #1) US Exports to China:2007 (Source: NMFS 2008) Salmon - #1 (Canada #2) Flatfish - #1 (Canada #2) Groundfish - #1 (Germany #2) Frozen - #1 (Japan #2) Total - #1 Quantity: #3 Value (Japan #2 Quantity: # 1 Value) Conclusion Aquaculture grows because managed fisheries have failed to meet market demands Aquaculture will dominate and lead the seafood industry Aquaculture is forcing change in fisheries: ¾ Through competition (supply) ¾ By developing new technology (hatchery-based fisheries) ¾ By example (marketing & quality control) ¾ By creating new demand – both for inputs and outputs Control of cost and marketing is essential for growth Conclusion In the Long Run All significant commercial Seafood supplies will come from three sources: Fish Farms/Aquaculture Aquaculture-Enhanced Fisheries Fisheries that adopt systems of management that are more like “aquaculture” management clearly define rights and responsibilities incorporate principles of husbandry, range management, forestry and farming More market and quality driven – Fisheries that do not will be marginalized or driven into niches Thank You