LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT WEAK-FORM EFFICIENCY IN THE GOLD MARKET* by Adrian WP1013-78 E. Tschoegl August 1978 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 WEAK-FORM EFFICIENCY IN THE GOLD MARKET* by Adrian E. Tschoegl WP1013-78 August 1978 ABSTRACT This paper investigates the efficiency of the gold market with respect to the information contained in sequences of successive price changes. Tests for serial correlation and modelling the changes as first-order Markov processes indicate some short-term dependence. While there is no reason to believe outsiders can profit from knowledge of these In addition, relationships, insiders might, though this is not certain. the application of a market model to monthly returns for the period 1974-1977 results in the finding that gold's 'alpha' and 'beta' were positive, but not significantly different from zero. * I would like to thank Richard A. Cohn, Edwin Kuh, and Donald R. Lessard for their criticism, advice, and assistance. Weak-Form Efficiency in the Gold Market I. Introduction This paper treats gold as from a financial asset and investigates its point of view of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis(EMH) the strong form of the EMH proposes that all information will be in security prices in such a way as research into . The impounded to leave no opportunity for extraordinary returns based on any information. begin price logical One way to the degree to which this formulation holds is to take some extremely simple, widely available item of information and to see whether one can use it for profitable trading. inefficient with respect to simple information improbable that it would be efficient with respect the If it to market is extremely is which some is more complex or less freely available. The paper examines a series of twice-daily prices for gold to determine whether successive price changes are independent, and if one can use not, whether knowledge of the dependence to generate trading profits. The techniques used are tests for serial correlation and modelling the change sequences as first-order Markov processes. The paper also applies returns on gold. over a standard one-factor market model to monthly This Is an itnorphous test In that it simply oheoks If some period holders of gold achieved excess risk-adjusted returns 3- their investment. on In realizations. while Thus the expected ante ex One can, however, only observe ex excess risk-adjusted return is zero. post market efficient an prove tests the grossly nothing, discrepant results would cause one to question either market efficiency or the model. Academic research in the field gold. Inter national finance finance of as has by-and-large sub-field of economics has of course a discussed it in the context of international reserves considerations. payments ignored balance and However while there are innumerable articles Spanish, investigating the efficiency of the US, UK, W.German, French, Japanese, and Israeli stockmarkets and , market the exchange, there is no comparable study of the gold legally or are 197^^ is Americans In There sense it dropped from view. a number of reasons the gold market might be of interest. represents First, it financial asset market. the This forbidden to hold gold in any form other than as jewelry coins of numismatic value. a foreign for market. probably due in large part to the fact that from 1933 to were of value a substantial Pick (1977) efficient highly estimates that at the end of 1976 of the stocks of gold held by governments and international organizations was in the vicinity private probably and of US$203.7 billion holdings US$104.9 billion (both amounts based on price of US$135/oz.). This compares with a and a that of free-market capitalization for the New York Stock Exchange of US$856 billion, and US$65 billion for the London Stock Exchange (Capital International Perspective, Jan. 1977). 4- There are major gold markets in Zurich London, , world's countries therefore expect markets in most of the centers. augment the trading is potentially almost efficient: between would One New , Informal, and often illegal, Chicago, Hong Kong, and Singapore. York, Frankfurt, Par is the main trading gold market to be highly continuous competition and markets should reduce the commissions and transaction costs in The widely dispersed markets any one market. not only increase the overall market's liquidity, but also act as sensors so that information arising anywhere can very quickly begin to influence prices market gold enables Thus the . one to test the theory of efficient markets in market in which it was not developed, but where a priori a would one expect it to hold. The second reason gold might be of interest is related to to for the first. opposed but While one would expect the market to be highly efficient the reasons listed above, nevertheless gold is popularly associated with hoarding, price 'gold bugs', and apocalyptic visions of the future. might therefore reflect 'mispricing' risk-adjusted excess return), if buyers pay value to them as political a hedge against the Its (in the sense of a negative a premium because of gold's complete collapse and monetary systems, or because, being in national of form, 'bearer' it enables them to evade taxes or confiscation. The third reason is a technical one. The London morning and afternoon gold price fixings give the researcher ready access to two transactions prices per day. At 10:30am and 3:30pm each business day, representatives of the five firms that form the London gold market meet 5- and shortly thereafter fix a price that clears the market. price series are therefore relatively uncontaminated by of prices carried The fixings the over from some earlier transaction. inclusion The data does suffer from some problems since the times are not exact and the volumes traded are secret. Even if the volumes traded were known, these approximations represent since orders internally and only clear however imbalances. their any particular fixing, the price is still internally. do not receive dividend payments. find, we fact is traded at Finally, gold Therefore we can be fairly confident that any signs of non-independence between that last This transaction price since the a firms will use it in matching some orders changes many buy and sell it reasonably certain that even if no gold makes holdings offset firms the would successive price especially in day-to-day data, is due to real phenomena and is not an artefact of the way prices are recorded or dividends attributed. The basic model used is as follows: Z'(t) (P'(t) = where Z'(t) P(t) return P(t-1))/P(t-1) - is the = r(t)+ e'(t) percentage return on gold over the period t-1 to the price of gold at time t, is on assets of component of the return. time t-1. e'(t) the same risk r(t) and The prime indicates is assumed is the e'(t) a normal of is the unexpected random variable to have the properties: rate t, as of 6- E[e' (t)] cov = (e'(t), e'(t-k)) If r(t) is a E[Z'(T)] = = 0, = t =1,2, ...k, k<t constant then E[r(t) e'(t)] + r(t) and therefore cov ( Z ' ( t) ,Z ' ( t-k) ) = 0. This further implies that: E[Z'(t)] = E[Z'(t) |Z(t-1 that is, the marginal knowledge of the expected ), and this equals zero. Z(t-k)] returns conditional return over implies that the next period equal, or that that already not is Since the covariance of the returns equals the correlation However suppose that r(t) function of other variables which change knows are the past series of returns provides no information about incorporated in the return. zero, Z(t-2)... between Z'(t) is not a over and Z(t-k) constant but rather time. If the a market the relationship, the unexpected portion of the return may still follow the model: E[e' (t)] X 7- cov(e' (t) and ,e' (t-1 )) = , E[Z'(t) lZ(t-1 ),Z(t-2), ...Z(t-k)] = r(t) but E[Z'(t) |Z( t-1 ),Z(t-2),...,Z(t-k)] at E[Z •(!)], except by chance, and similarly, cov(Z'(t) ,Z'(t-k)) i This means that the expectation of the next period's return depends the past series of returns, the serial correlation of the returns is not equal to zero, but no consistent excess returns are possible prices r(t) already is returns on fully incorporate not constant, the presence the relevant information. of serial does not prove market inefficiency. correlation However if r(t) and furthermore the period over which one measures it is since Thus if the in is small short, then one can treat it as constant, and assume cov(Z'(t) ,Z'(t-k) ) - 0. The presence of serial oorrelatlon In the returns then remains us un 8- indicator that market the may with respect to the inefficient be information contained in the return series. In Section II we report the means and standard returns first-order processes. Section monthly returns. takes IV the V applies a two with series the largest standard market model to four years of Section VI summarizes the results. Distributions The data consist of the morning (AM) in London from Jan. observations several and models them as first-order Markov correlation serial Section Section II. of Section III presents the results of tests for serial series. correlation. deviations the in to Jun series and 1975 2, AM . interpolated for the PM fix for Dec 24, series to the same length. fixing prices and afternoon (PM) 30, 1977. There were 631 629 in the PM. Two prices were 1975 and to 1976 bring both Over the period the price of gold fell from US$l85/troy ounce at the begining of the period to US$143/troy ounce at the end. The AM and PM series were used to generate four series of the form Z(t) = P(t)/P(t-1 ) -1 and four series of absolute changes: A(t) = P(t) - P(t-1) 9- representra) series The four afternoon): the b) morning): morning-to-morning the c) (afternoon change overnight Table change. afternoon-to-afternoon change within-day the I (morning to subsequent to change: and presents their d) the , means and standard deviations. While the means for all eight different negative, are none zero at the 90% confidence level. from significantly are This indicates that swamped over very short periods anticipated changes are completely the effect of hypothesis that E[r ( t) +e( t) ]=0 , One would not reject the changes. unanticipated the by and one cannot infer E[r(t)]<0. that Histograms and Gaussian probability plots all show the distributions of the changes be to lepto-kur totic Gaussian, and have fatter tails. Mandelbrots' (1965) They . are results These more peaked than the are consistent findings for cotton and stock and Fama's (1965) We will not in this paper enter the debate price changes respectively. not on the nature of the generating processes since this is for our with essential purposes. Serial Correlations Section III. Even if the distributions of the price changes do variance, the serial correlation coefficient not have (RHO) is a finite still from some unbiased estimate of the true serial correlation (Fama, 1965, results of Wise, concerning appropriate 1964). distribution below are only indicative. In view of the questions an the and the constancy of r(t), the RHOs reported Nevertheless, the discovery of strongly TABLE I MEANS AND STANDARD DEVIATIONS Variable 10- significant serial uncomfortable about correlation our coefficients hypothesis of the would leave independence us of the unexpected component of successive price changes. In that vein we have calculated RHOs for four sets of successsive changes. Asterisks indicate significance at the 5% level. a)Z20(t) and RHO = Z4(t) .208* The change from the evening to the following morning is strongly and positively related to the subsequent morning to afternoon change. b) Z4(t) RHO = and Z20(t+1) .061 The within-the-day change is positively weakly related to the The morning-to-morning change is negatively and weakly related to the and following over-night change. c) Zam( t-1 RHO = ) and Zam( t) -.034 previous morning- to-morning change. - d) Zpm(t-I) RHO = 11- and Zpm (t) -.099* change The afternoon-to-afternoon tends reverse the indicating some to previous afternoon-to-afternoon change. Two of the RHOs four independence significant, are successive changes. between of the RHOs were estimated by 7(1 /n-1 ) Fama As . notes, if the distributions of returns are 'fat-tailed' rather (1972) than Gaussian, this significance. In method addition, results the an in two overstatement day-to-day series of the both have negative first-order serial correlation coefficients, whereas sets of However the standard errors expression: the lack of changes the two shorter periods both have positive first-order over RHOs. Osborne Niederhoffer and market-makers, < 0) a (1966) argue that in sequence of orders will generate reversals (i.e. (RHO > 0) when one type of order predominates. underlying economic mechanism involves the exhaustion of which form in balance. a RHO generate when buy and sell orders are equally numerous, and will continuations with markets limit The orders 'reflecting barrier' when buy and sell orders are roughly Our results are consistent with this argument, especially when one supplements it with the possibility that the morning fixing is less important than the afternoon one. Each fixing price then is an - 12- one to continuation in outcome of two opposing tendencies: run, and the short the other to reversal over the longer periods. Over longer intervals prices are more likely to have adjusted to reflect fully information and the by afternoon fixing in particular buy and sell orders are likely to be present in equal afternoon-to-afternoon series reversals proportion. dominate Hence for change. the If the continuations, and there is only weak continuation from the within-the-day change overnight new to the morning fixing is less important than the afternoon it will not completely adjust to late in the previous afternoon and overnight. occurring information new The very strong tendency to continuation from the overnight change to the within- the-day change will then almost match the tendency to reversals due to the longer elapsed period between morning-to-morning changes. This explanation depends strongly on the assumption fixing that morning the on average represents a smaller volume of trading than does the afternoon. The assumption however is not unreasonable if one remembers that 10:30am in London is 7:30am in New York and 6:30am in Chicago, and that since 1974 these have become increasingly important gold markets. Table II presents the the serial correlation day-to-day series with lags of from the daily 1 coefficients to 60 trading days. changes seem random and to damp-out over time. cannot reject (at the 5% significance level) the for auto-correlation function for the lags of equal to zero. The RHOs for In fact, we the null hypothesis 1 two that to 10 days is flat and The Q statistics for Zam and Zpm are 14.96 and 17.03 respectively, with the latter being significant at the 10% significance o w M u M b o u z o o M M CO 13- level Q , £j n = and where (RH0(j))»»2 distributed as chi-square with is degrees of freedom. j the serial correlation coefficient of lag j, the number of observations. While the Q ( j= 1 , . . . , 10) , RHO(j) is and n is the must statistics are high, one remember that the significance is exaggerated because of the fat-tailed distributions of daily the returns (Cornell & Dietrich, The 1978). magnitudes of the serial correlation coefficients of the lagged changes and of the Q statistics in this study are quite similar to those just cited in their study of efficiency in the market authors by the for foreign exchange. gold There is one surprisingly large relation in complex trading strategies While the results do not rule next Section the question out than taking advantage of day-to-day dependence, no simple rules spring to mind. the the data between the morning- to-morning changes twenty days apart but this could easily be due to chance. more found We will defer to later in of whether we can use the short-term dependence we have found to make extraordinary profits. Section IV. An Ma»"kov alternative investigate Transition Probabilities approach successive to price the use changes of is serial to correlations model the changes as to a - Markov process. 14- Doing so requires no assumptions as to the nature of the distribution of the changes. A number authors of have Niederhoffer and OsborneC 1 966 did Fielitz(1975) and Fielitz and BhargavaC , market 1 973 ) Kingdom, index, and the latter for for and the sample of stocks quoted on a works fuller description of the underlying mathematics and some of the a Goodman (1957) state Transition Probability Matrix(TPM). states of process be state in j in in the previous period. i X(t) , ( is first-order Pr[x(t) = ...x(t-k) The TPM is The elements are estimates of will system from one a matrix of conditional the process at time (t), and the vertical by the states at the time (t-1). a The horizontal dimension of the matrix is given by probabilities. and Any Markov Process is completely described by its another. to Anderson to the derivation of the tests used below. for Markov theory is concerned with the transition of chain first the further potentialities of this line of analysis, and state Dryden(1969) . The interested reader is referred to these the London exchange. for particular, In investigated stock prices in the US, as ) did the same for the United Ryan(1973) overall technique. this used t=0 , 1 , . . . , T) , with a probability that the given period, given that it was in For a the a stationary discrete, Markov finite number of states, the process Markov if s(j)|x(t-1) =s(i)] = s(i)]= Pr[x(t) =s( j) I x( t-1 ) = s( i) , x(t-2) = s(i), - That is, the probability that x(t) 15- is in state prior to at time (t) depends and not on the sequence of only on which state it was in at time (t-1) states j The transition probabilities Pij satisfy the (t-1). following conditions: Pr[X(t) s(j)|X(t-1) = with (i,j for all T, ( j=1 ,2, . . . = = s(i)] = 1.2, ...,m), Pij(t) = Pij(t+1)= Pij ^ Pij ^ 1, and £j Pij = 1, ,k) Anderson and Goodman (1957) have shown the that Likelihood Maximum Estimator of Pij is: Pij = n(ij)/n(i) Where n(ij) or is the number of observations in a cell, and n(i)'=Sj n(ij) the total number of observations in the ith row. In this have classified all price changes into one of three states: change (NC), and down (D), defined paper we up (U), no by the percentage change being greater than, equal to, or less than zero respectively. We assume that the direction of the most recent change depends only on the of the preceeding change. hypothesis that direction We then test the assumption against the null successive changes are independent. We also test whether the results we observe are stationary over the sample period or not. We prepared Transition Probability Matrices for the two sets of changes 16- - with significant serial correlation coefficients. results for the sequence Z20(t) the Zpm(t-I) and Table ZM(t), and Table IV those for and Zpm(t). As one can III continuations (an up followed in Table see, by are more probable than reversals (an up followed by etc.) vice-versa), which is consistent with the positive earlier. observed coefficients In In both tables down, and Table IV reversals are more likely the series' RHO. continuations are almost as likely as reversals and this contrast some in a up, an correlation serial than continuations, and this too is consistent with stands presents III to Niederhoffer and Osborne's findings that reversals were twice as likely as continuations. Their data however covered much shorter trading intervals than does this study. The test of the null hypothesis that all the rows are identical is from Anderson and Goodman. The statistic: Zij n(i)'- (Pij -P' j)^ /P' is is distributed as chi-square with m(m-1) the number degrees of freedom, of states of the process (i.e. P'j=2i n(ij)/Ei Ej n(ij) (i.e. the total number the results significant at the significant reject the of observations in For Table are X**2=20.809 with six degrees of freedom which is ^% level. For Table IV, X*»2=13.2749 at the 5% level, but not at the 2.5% level. null m m=3 in this case), and the jth column divided by the total number of observations). III where hypothesis that the within-the-day and is Thus we would change is TABLE in MARKOV TRANSITION PROBABILITY MATRIX OVER-NIGHT CHANGE AND WITHIN-THE-DAY CHANGE Z4 Z20 TABLE IV MARKOV TRANSITION PROBABILITY MATRIX ^^^^^^^^^^=^2zEVENIN^a^^ ^^^^ Zpm(t) m(t-l) Note: elements are actual TZl f^^^°"^^ elements are probabilities and sum for rounding error. counts. Below diagonal to 1 across rows, except '^^'^^P'^ ' 17- of the overnight change, but would be much more ambivalent independent about dependence between successive evening- to-evening changes. We also tested whether or not these The period. sample relations were P'(j) are replaced P''(ij) by and m(m-1)(t-1) X**2=m.1351 Zpm(t-I) 5% (T=1,...,5). t level. the are the cell summation the that over is statistic is distributed as X**2 with The degrees of freedom. For the series Z20(t) which is not significant at the 5% level. and Zpm(t), except above, P''(ij) where probabilities based on the entire sample, and i,j, over series were divided into five six-month periods. The relevant test statistic is similar to the one the stable and For Z4(t), the series X**2=21.263 which also is not significant at the Thus in both cases we would not reject the null hypothesis that the processes were stable over the sample period. The next question of course is whether one evidenced in Table III for profitable trading. the can use the dependence To test this we derived means and variances for Z4(t), conditional on knowing the state of Z20(t-1 ). with 1) ELZ4IZ20 > 0]= 2) E[Z4|Z20 = 0] = -.033% 3) E[Z4|Z20 < 0] = -.1% Green (1968) .13% , , , standard deviation of .55% a with with a a standard deviation of .63% standard deviation of .66% reports that the commission charged on a purchase or sale - 18- conducted via the fixing was .00025%. While this may have changed, the implication is that if one could buy or sell at the fixing prices, could make albeit profit, a with some However to use this risk. strategy one must know the fixing price and make one's decision it is set. normal one before Purchases or sales outside of the fixing are subject to the bid/ask spreads. For the sample period this spread seems to have been on the order of .5 to 1.1%. Outsiders would thus seem to have been unable to make consistent profits from betting the transition probabilities of the most dependent sequence of changes. On Traders at the other hand, this may not hold for insiders. are in telephone contact with their parent organizations are in contact with traders in Zurich, fixing a who turn in All these New York, etc. individuals therefore do have some idea of what state will prevail, and may be able to conduct their transactions at However we changes in do the not know what price elasticities pertain. quantities of gold be no more Very small move might offered prices Finally, the profits sufficiently to severely limit potential profits. may commissions. fixing the than is required to compensate traders for the time, telephone bills, and similar costs that they incur in policing the price. The results from modeling gold price changes as process are the Section. successive a first-order Markov similar to those of the authors cited at the beginning of between All have found some tendency to non-independence price changes. In inversely related to the size of general though the tendency seems to be the oompany whose atook is belnK 19- examined. Fiel itz( 975 1 also found that the dependency tended not to ) be stable over time. Section Market Model V. This section reports the results model exercise was two-fold: systematic applying one-factor a of monthly returns on gold. years four to from first, to estimate gold's market The purpose of the 'beta', i.e. its risk to see whether this was negative as has been suggested by some (e.g. MacDonald Solnik, & and second, 1977) estimate its instance by portfolio, and to ex post risk-adjusted excess return. The market model is standard a one used as for Jensen( 1968) Rg - Rf = where Rg Rm , the + a , riskless b(Rm -Rf) and Rf are the asset systematic risk i.e. portfolio + divided by e returns on gold, respectively, (b) the ratio its the of is market a measure the covariance with variance of the latter, (a) measure of the excess return, and (e) is the of gold's the market is the Jensen classical stochastic error term. The perspective of the test is that of a US investor who can construct 20- - a portfolio by choosing from amongst gold, Treasury Bills, and market portfolio, all of which are denominated in US dollars. period is from January 1974 to December 1977. calculated from the PM fixing price on the The test The returns on gold are last trading day of the The proxy for the riskless asset is the one-month T-bill rate. month. For world a the world market Perspective's portfolio Market World have we This Index. market national The indexes International is a market-value weighted index based on indexes of the eighteen largest world. Capital used stock markets of the are also market-value weighted portfolios of stocks, but converted to US$ at current exchange We also used two different ways of calculating the return on rates. gold and degree the the market: a) b) Rg = P(t)/P(t-1 Rm = Index Rg = ln(P(t)) Rm = ln( ( t) - ) 1 /Index (t-1 - - ) 1 + Dividends ln(P(t-1)) Index(t)) - InCIndex ( t-1 ) ) + Dividends The reason for doing this was to take into account to some mis-specification of the investment horizon. regression gives the more accurate estimate downward. of Thus (b), This situation reverses for the first model. but the second biases (a) 21- The regression results were (with t-statistics in parentheses): a) Rg - Rf = 0.00539 + 0.02765(Rm H2 =-0.02138 SER =0.0685 DW =1.25 Rg - Rf = 0.00321 + 0.03135(Rm (0.3338) Rf) ( /46 - Rf) (0.1272) (0.5439) b) - F ) = 01 62 (0.1467) R2 =-0.02126 SER =0.0665 DW =1.30 F(1/46) In . =0.0215 neither regression are the coefficients significant at even the significance level, and F-tests the clearly have to reach to reject the are similarly weak. hypothesis null 40% One would that all the (b) for gold coefficients were equal to zero. The positive, albeit insignificantly different from zero, may surprise some readers. might have (1977) for a There has been instance, found the period 1971 the a correlation of -0.07 to 1976. collapse market portfolio & MacDonald between & gold Solnik percentage Poors Composite Index over One must remember though that around early to of the Smithsonian agreement resulted in the floating of the major world currencies. the general feeling that negative correlation with the market. changes in the gold price and the Standard mid-'' 973 a The prices of both are determined in world markets. gold and Therefore the effect of exchange rate changes impart some positive correlation to the US$ values of both. The results for the intercept term (a) are not aonsistent with those 22- - Jensen, & Scholes (1972) of Black, sub-periods that Logue Hughes, , betas were computed Companies' risk-adjusted betas When the performance et al., of were using a ) assets consistent are These authors found that when . market domestic Multinational index. performance exceeded that of domestic firms. computed using a world index though, the two sets of companies were quite similar. credence argued that their results lent financial intercepts had results However the Sweeney( 1 975 & portfolios zero-beta their significantly greater than zero. with who found that in three out of four are priced internationally Hughes, notion the to the that that this in turn and implies that financial markets are integrated internationally. Gold is pre-eminently an international surprising asset zero. In any still a normal return that ex ante gold had a of net These are minimal though (on the order of 0.1% possible for / storage annum). It is negative expected excess to pay a its special services, but that later developments awarded them an unexpected offsetting bonus. this possibility. We can neither confirm nor reject The most likely explanations for however remain chance, and/or missing factors. Section VI. different insignificantly risk-adjusted return because of buying by investors willing premium not case one might expect that it should be positive merely because investors wish to earn costs. perhaps is it that it should have been correctly priced in the sense that the risk-adjusted excess return ex post was from so Summary the positive (a) 23- - This paper has investigated the efficiency of the gold market primarily sequences with respect to the information contained in price changes. first-order changes as dependence. profit tests Both from for serial correlation and modelling the processes Markov successive of indicated short-term some There was no reason to believe though that outsiders could knowledge of relationships. these makers and Market professional traders might, but it is not clear that they can do so in excess of their costs. The application of that for a standard market model to monthly returns the period 1974-1977, the covariance of the return on gold in excess of the riskless rate with that of the market was not revealed significantly different zero. from Similarly, positive, the but excess risk-adjusted return was also positive, but not significantly different from zero. Further research might proceed in the direction market's efficiency with respect series of price changes, structural publicly available information. of investigating the to more complex models of the time models At this of price point formation, and though there is no reason to suspect that the gold market in general is any less efficient than any other international asset market. 2U- - BIBLIOGRAPHY Anderson, T. W. and Goodman ,L A. 1) 1 957 ,' Statistical Markov Chains', Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 28, . , Inference 89-110, about International S.A., , Capital 2) International Per spective Geneva, Switz.), Jan. 1977. ,( Capital Cornell, W. Bradford, and Dietrich, J. Kimball, 'The 3) 1978, Efficiency of the Market for Foreign Exchange Under Floating Exchange Rates', The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60, 111-120. Price 1969, 'Share Dryden,M., Approach' Journal of Finance, 24, 49-60. Movements: 4) A Markovian , Fama, Eugene F., Journal of Business, 38, 5) 1965, 'The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices', 34-105. Fama, Eugene F., 1970, 'Efficient Capital Markets: A Review 6) Theory and Empirical Work', Journal of Finance, 25, 383-417. Fielitz, Bruce D. Stationarity 1975, 'On the Probability Matrices of Common Stocks', Journal of Quantitative Analysis, 10,327-339. 7) Fielitz, Relatives - 9) of Transition Financial and , 8) B. A Green, T., of and Bhargava, T.N., 1973, 'The Behavior of Stock Price Markovian Analysis', Operations Research, 21, 1183-1189. 1968, The World of Gold, (Michael Joseph, London), Chap. 5. Hughes, J.S., Logue, D.E., and Sweeney, R.J., 10) 975 ,' Corporate International Diversification and Market Assigned Measures of Risk and Diversification', Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 10, 627-637. 1 11) Jensen, M.C., 1968, 'The Performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945-1964', Journal of Finance, 10, 389-416. MacDonald, John G., and Solnik, Bruno Strategy for Gold Stocks', Journal of 12) 'Valuation and Portfolio Management, 3, 2, H. 1977, , 29-33. Mandelbrot, Benoit, 1963, 'The Variation 13) Prices' .Journal of Business, 36, 394-419. of Certain Speculative - 25- and Osborne ,M. F .M. V., 1966, 'Market Making and Niederhoffer Statistical Reversal on the Stock Exchange', Journal of the American Association, 61, 897-916. 14) , 15) Corp . , Pick, Franz, New York) , 1977, Pick's Currency Yearbook, 1976-77, (Pick Publ. . 16) Ryan, T.M., 1973, 'Security Prices as Markov of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 17-36. Processes', Journal Wise, John, Oct. 17) 1963, 'liinear Estimators for Linear Regression Systems having Infinite Variances', presented the paper at Berkeley-Stanford Mathematical Economics Seminar. f Date Due JAN 4 f £8 iy8( ^v"* 1 *^J? 'H J -r^^^N IW2B' JIIN28'8Z ,$• T.iflg -\M990 9AN 1 3 '66 I.ib-26-67 HD28.M414 no-1019- 78 HD28,IVI414 no 1009- 78 Robinson, Rich/The quality and relevan OfRKS 735340 . 00.059560. Li'tle. DDl 125 TOflD 3 til3 HD28.M414 no.lOlO- 78 Lewis, Tracy R/Cartel deception in non nr,7685 nxBKS 818318 nil TOaO DOl 102 3 HD28.M414 no.1011- ?t.D 78 Von Hippel, Er/Product designs which e D»BKS 81831 Pg057G 83 TOAD 001 HD28.M414 no.1012- 02 p»BKS 735338 ^OflO fl2fl 78 Jame/Coping with role Dnscoll, confli im 001 125 hSM HD28.IVI414 no 1013- 78 Tschoegl, Adri/Weak-form efficiency 822505:.. p*BKS „ M060872 in . OflO 001 i^i"545 no 1014- 78 Rober/Job creation and the ec D*BK§, 735342^, .,(?,9.0S9S|^| H028.M414 Jerretl, , TOflO 3 001 125 5T7 HD28M414 no.l015- 78 Paddock, James/Corporate investment un 735344 .D»B.KS 00.0595 TOaO 001 125 571 3 HD28-M414 no.lOlG- 78 Allen, Thomas /The relation D*BK 73534 OflO of interna 'm, 001 125 555 H028.M414 no.l017- 78 fVlass, Nathanie/Destabilizing 73564? 3 TOflO impacts o 0006217^ 0*M5, 001 15T flMM HD28.M414 no.l018- 78 Mass. Nathanie/A microeconomic theory 735647 D»BKS 00062382 iiii;,,;' „ III 3 TOaO 001 bO John D/Decision support 822506 _ OOfl r 3 _ for ma ..D*BKS.. .000508 73 TQflO 001 im SS?