c 2 ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT A RATIONAL ANTICIPATIONS GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ASSET PRICING MODEL: THE CASE OF DIFFUSION INFORMATION by Chi-fu Huang" May 1983 Sloan School of Management Working Paper No. MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 1553-8A A RATIONAL ANTICIPATIONS GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ASSET PRICING MODEL: THE CASE OF DIFFUSION INFORMATION 1 by Chi-fu Huang" May 1983 Sloan School of Management Working Paper No. f 1 553-8A The author would like to thank Doug Breeden, John Cox, and especially Darrell Duffie and David Kreps for discussions and comments. Any errors are of course my own. Department of Economics and Sloan School of Management, MIT. Abstract We prove existence of an equilibrium in a continuous trading economy with diffusion infor- mation. Equilibrium asset price processes are Ito integrals. Under some regularity conditions, equilibrium asset price processes and the vector of ing information form a vector diffusion process. A "state variable processes" generat- martingale representation technique is used to characterize agents' optimal portfolio rules in an equilibrium context. Introduction and 1. summary In the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing tended by Breeden [4], Model, developed by Merton [34] and ex- the story goes roughly as follows: Let there exist a (perhaps en- dogenously determined) vector diffusion process (F(t)} that describes "states of the world". Assume that prices for traded assets can be represented by stochastic of the Ito type with coefficients that are functions of Y(t) the price processes and sume that asset prices as given, tion. Y and t differential equations at each time together form a vector diffusion process. each agent maximizes his expected Markovian stochastic dynamic programming is utility of life-time tions on equilibrium asset prices are derived first and Taking consump- exists, restric- by inverting the "aggregate demand" for assets, order optimality conditions for agents' dynamic programs. The two main assumptions made above tinuous trading economy and the finite are the existence of an equilibrium in a con- dimensionality of Y. The latter is an assumption involving endogenous properties of an economic equilibrium. Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross in a production economy, identify the finite dimensionality of that there is as- then used to characterize agents' consumption-investment choices over time. Assuming that an equilibrium calculated by adding the t, a single representative agent which prices are "smooth" functions of Y in . the They Y . They assume, however, economy and that an equilibrium also rely [10], exists in on Markovian stochastic dynamic programming methods. The purpose of this essay is First, the existence of three-fold. tablished in a Merton/Breeden-like economy. 1 an equilibrium is es- Equilibrium asset prices are Ito integrals whose coefficients are "nonanticipative functionals". shown to be Pareto tion will be efficient. Furthermore, the equilibrium alloca- Second, conditions are provided under which the value of these "nonanticipative functionals" at each time Z(t) and t, where "state variable processes" can be written as functions of a finite-dimensional vector of exogenously specified diffusion is {•£(<)} t the vector of equilibrium price processes for In particular, . Z traded assets and the vector of state variable processes together form a vector diffusion process. Finally, a martingale-representation technique, similar to one proposed is used to characterize agents' optimal portfolio behavior. representation technique stochastic more powerful a is It is [9], argued that this martingale- than Markovian tool for equilibrium analysis dynamic programming. In Section 2 of this paper, a continuous-time frictionless uncertainty with time span consumption commodity in by Cox [0, T] in the is formulated. It is consumption preferences. assumed that there economy, consumed only number, are characterized by their endowments pure exchange economy under at times at times zero common Agents are endowed with a is one perishable and T. Agents, T and finite and by their information structure generated by an exogenously specified vector diffusion process Z. That is, Z F describes the evolution of the exogenous uncertain environment. It is assumed that there are zero net supply. as to at most a Each agent's problem is maximize consumption preferences. finite number manage a to The of traded long-lived securities in portfolio of long-lived securities so equilibrium concept used is Radner's [37] equilibrium of plans, prices, and price expectations. Given the nice properties of F, a diffusion select long-lived securities appropriately, location is sense that securities. Pareto all if we an equilibrium exists and the equilibrium al- filtration, Section 3 shows that Furthermore, markets are complete efficient. in equilibrium in the contingent claims not traded can be replicated by trading on long-lived (Equivalently, price processes for all all contingent claims are priced by arbitrage.) The equilibrium contingent claims are Ito integrals whose integrands are nonan- ticipative functionals (Theorem machinery developed in Duffie 3.3.1 and and Huang its corollary). [13]. 2 The existence proof exploits the T time If endowment aggregate C 3 with functions which are utility (Assumptions 4.2.1, 4.2.2), independent (Proposition with a time- additive is path-independent, 1 bounded derivatives, and if if agents have time-additive agents are at interior T consumption then the societal shadow prices for time function which C 3 with is bounded derivatives on an open subset of the real line can be constructed to support the equilibrium at the aggregate point (Propositions 4.1.1 and very roughly, the product of are path- Here we have exploited the fact that a representative agent 4.2.1). utility maxima 4.1.2). Since the equilibrium price of a contingent claim payoff and the societal its endowment shadow prices, it is, then follows that the equilibrium price process of any contingent claim with a nice payoff structure has a nice representation (Proposition 4.2.2), which can be described by a partial differential equation with a boundary condition. nice representation Conversely, any contingent claim whose price process has a must have a nice payoff structure (Proposition nice in each context will be made precise. In addition, and when some regularity conditions are nice, this claim forms, satisfied, dynamic choice either Ross [10]). of claim's payoff structure is the equilibrium price process of with Z, a diffusion process. Markovian stochastic dynamic programming [32,33]) or in when a The meaning 4.2.3). in a is a useful tool in characterizing an agent's purely microeconomic context under uncertainty an equilibrium setting with a representative agent Sufficient conditions for the existence of (cf. Merton (cf. Cox, Ingersoll, and an optimal control are quite severe; compact for example, the space of admissible controls [8] recently proposed an alternative using a martingale-representation argument. method Kreps is [20, controls is Section 3] and Kreps a linear space. (This Merton [34] is stochastic and Breeden [26].) vector diffusion process say that time T Y is [3], Chapter IV). Cox (This See, for example, Harrison and implicit in Cox's setup.) dynamic programming [4], Bismut In Cox's work, however, the space of admissible the purpose is choices and to characterize equilibrium relations 'We (cf. vaguely foreshadowed in the earlier literature. When Markovian as in is assumed to exist, aggregate endowment is 3 is used in an equilibrium setting, both to depict agents' optimal dynamic among asset prices. A finite one whose value at each time path-independent if it is t dimensional along with an a function of Z(T). agent's wealth are sufficient statistics for this agent's is shown that, in equilibrium, agents hold the portfolios relations portfolio. dynamic program. In market most highly correlated with each component of Y, respectively. among The above procedure is )' exists. agents' optimal flawed, however. we fix after an equilibrium is after an equilibrium established and agents' optimal portfolio behavior. of long-lived securities.) It is its established, known whether such a dynamic programming is established and characterized. is stochastic nature characterized, the martingale- Cox [9] seems to be a very useful way to describe (The meaning of version is that we choose a particular shown that agents hold pure hedging a numeraire security (Proposition 5.1). This characterization is valid securities and when Markovian not applicable. Recall that, in our setting, information. not is a version of the equilibrium established in Section 3 and argue that representation technique proposed by set and the market Before an equilibrium it is Equilibrium Thus, stochastic control of the Markovian type should be used to depict dynamic choices In Section 5, Y shown to be determined by asset prices are then it and those portfolio, the riskless asset, and equilibrium relations among asset prices are examined, process this approach, Z is the vector diffusion process that generates agents' Denoting the price system for long-lived securities by 5, we show that the state-price vector process (Z,S) is a diffusion process provided certain regularity conditions are satisfied (Assumptions 4.2.1, 4.2.2, 4.2.3). If an agent's time T endowment is path- independent (with respect to Z), the number of shares of a hedging security held by this agent at each time t depends only upon security held by this agent at each time optimal portfolio rule is t Z(t). The number of shares of the numeraire depends only upon Z{t) and path-independent with respect to Z and 5. S(t). The Thus this agent's functional relation between this agent's optimal portfolio rule for pure hedging securities and Z is described by a system of partial differential equations with boundary conditions (Proposition Agents in the economy can all, however, have path-dependent optimal portfolio rules, with respect to (Z, 5), without destroying the strong up agents' first 5.3). Markov property of (Z S). Thus, , summing order conditions from their dynamic programs to characterize equilibrium asset price relations may be ineffective. Concluding remarks are given in Section 6. The economy 2. we present a model In this section of a continuous-time frictionless pure exchange economy under uncertainty with time span [0, 7"]. Let (ft, 7,P) be a complete probability Each u £ ft denotes a complete description of the exogenous environment. The set of trading dates is [0, space. T], with a common 2.1. The information We where T is a strictly positive real number. Agents are endowed probability measure on the measurable space assume that there defined on the basic probability space, is W = {VK(t);0 the tribe 2 generated by {W(s);0 augmented by the filtration fact that cr "tr" Fu — ' all Fw is (cr < < s P-negligible sets Vt£ = T) {7J";0 < t < < T,P), an TV- T}. The component processes T]. It is — assume that 7^ clear that 7$ increasing, that m ,„) a matrix, is we write | 2 a | is, almost is C 7? 7 and 7", = tr (<ro' T ), where T that trivial if t < e. o*f Tf is and that For the t-Ktahf [Z&\ denotes the inner product, denotes (race. Let : RN X [0, T] - R NxN t, 3 (a Lipschitz condition), I Tribe" may and /*(y, : RN X - RN T] [0, such that \y-y\ \o-{y,t)-<j{y,t)\<K \»(yJ)-fi(V,t)\<K \y-y\, 3 We t). [0, is be given functions, continuous in y and is t a continuous information structure, see the piwviuus £say.-I tr{y, t) and < (ft, W}v(<) are independent one-dimensional Standard Brownian Motions. Let 7J" be Wi(t) and denoted by P. 7), structure dimensional Standard Brownian Motion If (ft, (2.1.1a) and MV.O 2 | < 2 A' (l+ 2 I y | ), | 2 a{y,t) | < 2 AT (1+ 2 | y | ) (2.1.1b) be read as "sigma-field" or "sigma- algebra", but the former term seems simpler more modern. This implies that a and n are measurable with respect to the product Borel tribe on RN X [0, T\. (a "growth condition" cr(y,t) ), nonsingular for each y and is K some constants for t. Z Let We and K. assume that the N X N matrix be a (measurable) process adapted to Fw satisfying the Ito integral equation Zm = Z(0)+ Jo/ < for Z that t is < T, where Z(0) / <r(Z(«),«)dH^(«) (2.1.2) Jo 4 a constant TV-vector. is the unique solution of (2.1.2) and Theorem Arnold 9.3.1 in [1] ensures a diffusion process with drift vector ft(y,t) is Here we should note that the above statement implies the diffusion matrix a(y,t). and + tt(Z(a), s)ds conditions: T < \lt{Z{t),t)\dt I oo a.s., and rT \a(Z(t),t) / Jo 2 |2 < dt | oo a.s. io Let 7\ be the tribe generated by {Z(s);0 fact, use Tw equivalent to Fw . F F filtration 7 The sets of r is to denote both from the context, Agents struction, in the F is all F1 < at least as fine as is 8 F* < <} augmented by since the process For this point see Harrison and Kreps . and Fw Z is [20]. from now on. Furthermore, unless all the P-negligible adapted to F"\ In We it is shall therefore clearly otherwise processes will be adapted to F. economy are increasing and endowed with the common information structure F. By conis a continuous information structure. The interpretation is that the exogenous uncertain environment can be described by an ./V-dimensional Brownian motion VV, which agents in the economy may not actually observe directly. Agents can, however, observe a vector of "state variable processes" Z, whose evolution over time depends upon W in an unpredictable fashion. That is, the information content of the vector of state variable processes can only be less than that of process, however, provides agents with the W . The same information structure of the state variable as if they could in fact observe A vector random process Y = {Y(t);t 6 [0, T\}, is called measurable if, when viewed as a mapping defined on n X [0,r], for all Borel sets B in its range, {(w,«) Y(w,<) € B) € 7<g)B([0,r]), where B([0,T]) is the Borel tribe of [0,T]. A vector (measurable) random process Y is said to be adapted to F w if for every t 6 [0,T] the random variable Y(t) is /("-measurable. For brevity, such a random process will be denoted Y = {Y(t), 7f,t 6 [0,T]} anc* called F^-adapted or Donant/c/pat/ve. 4 : W directly, the evolution of Z since W generate the same information. and cautioned to note that the vector of state variable processes assumed that there It is consumed only 7 , Thus P). consumption and T. at times at x) G V time T in state (r, The consumption space The L2+ (P) set R the set {(r, x) G V if x > L%(P); x Similarly, for v = and > i' z 3> > if r : G r > [0, 6 (r,x) endow V There are a agent ^ V G L?(P) P{u G : ft : x{u) 0; we » and x if will write v For v, z x > L2 (P), we € £+(P) and P > if E V, the v G = l}, while 0} V"+ ; relation for the other relations just defined t; v W€ > > ft if z : is i finite number of agents in the characterized by a consumption set V, x(w) > if 0} and x G = 1. v^O; taken to mean that is on V. economy indexed by Vj-, endowments {>,• = i = 1,2, ...,/. (ri,ii) assume that (i)v; £ utility V{ for every 1 f u t{r,x{u))P(du). = 1,2,...,/: = y+; (2) u;(r,y) in r : and denoted R+ X y, /?+ with ^ — R is finite right «i(r,y) and continuous in hand # r, concave and strictly increasing partial derivatives with respect to r u,(r,y), respectively, and ^ u,(0, z(w)) and y G L'(P) VzG4(P). (3) there exist if Ui(r (r,-, z,) G V+ and e,- > such that, for every -kr + s,x-kx + y)> U{ {r, x) then (« 2 («, y) G V and + /n y 2 (u;)P((/a;))2 > Jfc G k^. Each C V", function — R of the form: Ui(r,x)= We > > v V+ denotes x will write and consumption preferences represented by a von Neumann-Morgenstern : on variables defined Agents 2.3. Ui R X with the product topology r generated by x G L\{P)}. For any x G i»0. and random of square-integrable = V is and the L2 (P)-norm topology on L?(P). oo), and x and likewise 0, We oj. defined as {x is for agents represents r units of consumption at time zero and x(u>) units of the Euclidean topology on — exogenously specified. is a single perishable consumption commodity in the economy, is L2 (P), where L?(P) denotes the space v is The consumption space 2.2. (ft, The reader i?+, Note that + that Ui(r above implies that (2) + 8,x y) > r-continuous, and strictly increasing in the sense is whenever x) (/,(r, {/,• («, y) > and 0; (For a general definition of properness see Mas-Colell condition for (3) ^ + > i'i that for € L2 (P), u,(0,x(u>)) (4) is for every i where for = #- all I, all Ui(r,y) i 6 L%(P), and 2 1,2, ...,/, ui 6 (5) there is at least one agent, say agent all r We 6 R+ c is mean agent There are a indexed by j L?(P). time T °» aQ d Ei=i (r,y) £ J?+, assume that ^ ^•'( u; ) such that lim „_oo §- 1, l's marginal £ f° r almost Ui(r, y) > 0, for utility for time T consumption is bounded finite = securities number 1,2,..., J. of long-lived securities of one share of security j in state w. The traded is Kreps (cf. Each long-lived security The holder endowments is [25]) traded in the economy, represented by an element dj entitled to dj{ui) units of securities are in zero net supply. 6 consumption at Agents have zero initial of these long-lived securities. The admissible 2.5. ^ shall further all sufficient zero. Traded long-lived 2.4. We for proper. . interpret (5) to away from vt - t Note also that a [30].) bounded away from zero (2). is (/,• a strictly positive real number; and every fi, is (3) implies that price systems and trading strategies Before any discussion of the admissible price systems and trading strategies, some technical definitions are in order. A continuous random process 7 Motion W) if there process <p, called is an ho process exists a nonanticipative process c , (relative to the vector and an Brownian TV- vector (row) nonanticipative such that and, with probability one for l(t) p\jo \c(t)\dt Pj[ M*)| 6 [0,T], all t = 7(0) + 2 d< <ool = <ool = l, l, c{s)d8+ c(e)d S + / <p(s)dvV(8). / / / Jo Jo (2.5.1) (2.5.2) (2.5.3) Returning back to economics, an admissible price system 5, S is a ./-vector Ito process of the form: Sj(t) = Sj(0) + with probability one for of the J traded I 6 all t Si (a)da [0, + 0j{s)dW(a) / V/ - 1, 2, . . ., J, T], with S{t) representing the ./-vector of relative prices long-lived securities at time b t. Given an admissible price system 5, an admissible trading strategy $ is a ./-vector (column) nonanticipative process such that El where the j'-th row of is 0j, J for every t £ [O.T ], the the Ito sense, that 1 < oo, (2.5.4) and the following conditions hold: 1 1. 0{t)i0(t)0it]t${t)dt stochastic integral /„ ^(s)TdS(s) is well-defined in is, / W)U(t)\dt < oo, a.s. Jo anc rT I \0(tW(tWY0(t)\ 2 dt < oo a. 8.; Jo 2. for every t € [0,7], $(t)i S(t) = 0{O)i S(0) + / 6(8JidS(s) jo a.s. (2.5.5) Let 0\S] denote the set of admissible trading strategies with respect to the price system 5. By virtue of (2.5.5), elements of ©[5] are all self-financing trading strategies. Equation (2.5.5) says that the initial value of the trading strategy (portfolio) 6 plus the 6 amount of Since F is a Brownian filtration, from thn p»n«innn essay we know any equilibrium price system can be represented as an Ito integral. Thus taking admissible price systems to be the set of Ito processes is not restrictive at all, once we know that an equilibrium exists. 9 capital gain or loss by That time. is, any time t is equal to the value of the strategy (portfolio) at that after the initial investment, there investment into the portfolio. (This is is neither withdrawal of funds out of nor stochastic integrals and a simple application of the shown to be a easily be Cauchy-Schwarz linearity of inequality, 0[S] can linear space. Equilibrium 2.6. Each agent's problem as to in the economy is to manage a portfolio of long-lived securities so maximize preferences on consumption at times zero and T. An equilibrium of plans, prices, and price expectations trading strategies {(0,) _, : at By the the obvious budget constraint.) f, (of Radner an admissible price system S, admissible [37]) is one for each agent, and a price a for the consumption good time zero (relative to the prices of the securities, given by 5(0)), such that, for all t = 1,2,...,/, I 2>;<<) and (r,- - {(u The 3. + e'(T^d) 0*(O)TS(O)/a, i, - among in the literature a vector Ito process [24] (Essay a.8., 1/,-maximal in the set + ocrpd) evr.ee e\s}}. existence of an equilibrium has been popular is is v«e(o,n o, *(o)Ts(o)/a, *i The continuous-trading model assumed = I) (cf. of financial markets formulated in the previous section financial theorists for more than a decade. It has always been that an equilibrium exists and that the equilibrium price system Merton [34], Breeden [4], Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross studied a similar model and showed that, if Huang indeed an equilibrium exists in the continuous-trading economy, then equilibrium asset prices are Ito integrals is [10]). if information generated by (multidimensional) Brownian motion. The existence of an equilibrium for an economy of one representative agent was demonstrated. machinery developed in Duffie and Huang [12] 10 to show that In this section if the J we use the traded long-lived securities are chosen appropriately, an equilibrium for our economy The proof the equilibrium allocation will be Pareto efficient. sense that a finite number is shown be constructive in the will of long-lived securities are selected, their prices are announced, a trading strategy for each agent allocation Furthermore, exists. is shown to be assigned, markets are Before we carry out this proof, to be Pareto efficient. clear, and the we analyze an analogous Arrow-Debreu economy. An Arrow-Debreu economy 3.1. Suppose that markets for all at time zero not only the spot "state contingent claims" 6 market for the are open in an space and agents are as described in Sections 2.3 and 2.4. Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, defined of an V' : V r — R and v i is and an allocation = {v, t/,-maximal in the set {v functional gives £ also economy whose consumption We will then show the existence as a strictly positive r-continuous linear functional (r,-, a;,-) V, consumption good but 6 ^(v) : Arrow-Debreu equilibrium = 1,2,.. .,/} Vi,i < i'(i>i)}, for each such that « = 1,2,...,/. Here we should note that prices. The if linear L?(P) is dimensional, then an Arrow-Debreu style economy consists of an infinite number infinite of markets at time zero. There zero. (For this point in a finite is no incentive, however, for markets to reopen after time dimensional commodity space, see Arrow Proposition 3.1.1: Let £ = (Vj, the conditions of Sections 2.2 and 2.3. t/,-, 0,-,i = an economy satisfying 1,2, ...,/) be Then there exists [2].) an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium (to')U*). Proof: Given the assumptions of Sections equilibrium follows from Mas-Colell linear functional 6 A $ : V —* state contingent claim Since V is a reflexive is R [30] 7 . A 2.2 and 2.3, quasi-equilibrium and an allocation {t;,- £ Vj-,i the existence of a quasiis a r-continuous positive = 1,2,...,/} such that an element of L?(P). Banach space, the Closeness Hypothesis in Mas-Colell satisfied. 11 [30] is automatically == YL\=i vi H =i t *>i a most surely and l ' > Ui(v) To show that V and strictly positive = {f,-,t V(t') = V'(t',')- form an equilibrium, we must show that 1,2, ...,/} > By the assumption that Y2i=i v(t'i') V>(t>*). ip is and that Ui{v) therefore > Ui(v') implies ^>(v) > By for i'i some implies i>{v) Ui(v]) t' 3> € > ((4) in Section 2.3), {1,2, ...,/}. we know V'(H,- suppose v 6 V+, U{i(v) < continuity of preferences, there exists UP (tjv) > Vi. ip(v') q < 1 > > 0, and t/i»(t/,i), and »'») such that Ui.(v',). Hence, ^M> This implies that ij > V'(t') > that t», > 0, that r, is ^-maximal V'(*',/)- Since U? we know il>(v) >0. Therefore strictly increasing, i> is strictly positive. > Hv i ) for all Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. In an = an obvious contradiction. 1, is i'(vl) i. for all t. Therefore, We ?/,•»( v) V aQ d { v% € K">* = 1)2, ...,/} comprise an | We can therefore freely In particular, the possible. Proposition 3.1.2: Suppose the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium of Proposition as implies can repeat the above arguments to show choose any contingent claim having a positive price as the numeraire. is f/i»(v,-) Then, by the assumption economic equilibrium only relative prices are determined. following characterization > 3.1.1 has T in (fi, 7) numeraire the contingent claim paying one unit of the consumption good at time every state. That is, V'(0, In) = 1. Then there exists a probability measure 12 Q on 8 uniformly absolutely continuous with respect to P, such that WxeL2 (P), 4(0,x)~E\x), E where (•) denotes expectation under Q. Proof: Since $ (a, (3.1.1) ()efiX is a r-continuous strictly positive linear functional on V, there exists L?(P) with a > > and £ ll>(r,x) such that for = ar+ all (r,x) € V z(w)S(u>)P(du), Ja = ar + That T is, <j>{x) <f>(x). gives the equilibrium price at time zero for a claim u, and the price of one unit of consumption good in state is a. which pays x(u) at time By assumption we know that In) V'(0, = / tW)P(du) - 1. Defining Q(A)= [ JA Q is a probability measure on countably additive and Q(Cl) (CI, z(u)P(du), 7) equivalent to P. = E(£) = Q 1; is vie;, It is a probability measure since equivalent to P since £ is it is strictly positive. Therefore, V(o,x) = «£(*)= = Now consider agent 1. We know / ifuKMPfdu/) Jn / x(w)Q(dw ) = £'(*). v, = (r ,x l l ) must solve the following concave programming problem: max Q the is Ut(v) said to be uniformly absolutely continuous with respect to Radon-Nikodym derivative dQ/dP is P if it is bounded above and below away from 13 equivalent to zero. P and ^(w)-^(wi) <0. s.t. Since V,- = V+ and il>(i\) > for all reference for the Slater condition saddle-point theorem that v l only if is (v) t Section 14E of Holmes number - < Ui(v]) have t'j this + t; is Since U\ is - programming problem with v £ V+ i>(v]) We [23].) vG^+ not the case. Take any £ V+. X, 4<(v) (3.1.1) claim that X! > 0. Since F+ we have Ui(v + strictly increasing, then follows from the It [23].) Xi such that for any v (For this point, see Section 14F of Holmes Suppose the Slater condition holds. (A good a solution for the above concave is there exists a nonnegative U we know that i, is v) l strictly positive. is a positive cone, — U\(v\) > 0. we This contradicts (3.1.1). Now we cone, proceed to prove that £ we know that {r l ,x 1 Ux{r\,x\ + + kl A ) k\ A ) - is 6 V+ bounded away from for all < C ri(rJ,ari) A6 7 Since zero. V+ is a positive and k 6 R+- So we have, X,L*(rJ,xJ + k\ A ) - il>{r\,x\) = Xi* J/ f(w )P(du). A Dividing both side of the above equation by k and letting k approach zero, we get, by (2) in Section (2.3) and the Lebesgue convergence theorem: jf ^ mo-;, *;m)p(<m < x, jT e(«)p(du;). (3.1.2) Equivalent ly, + JA (^^)Since (3.1.3) holds for every 0}. For (3.1.3) to hold it A6 7, fy we can take must be that P(A) *i£M > > ui(r\,x\(u))y(d«,) q- = A= 0. (w € That : Xi£(w)- ^- + Ui(r|,xJ(w)) < is, oifr,,*^)) 14 fi (3.1.3) 0. a.«. (3.1.4) By # we know (5) in Section 2.3, Ui(r l ,z l (<*>)) is bounded away from above expression by Xi, we have the desired result that £ Next we want to show that £ ^ 2.3) that J2i *i c/I}. (r*,7* c Then A, € 7 » where c for all -^nglE^- t So is and is bounded away from bounded above. Recall the assumption is a strictly positive constant. Let = fi |J, where ^~ U{(r, y) {w £ ^y CI : Section x^w) > 567, —k J(u,)P(du). and letting it approach zero gives «,(r;,x;H)P(rfu;)>X./^ t(u)P(du) V B € •'B no- |' = ((4) in (3.1.1) implies that Dividing both sides of the above expression by / A,- zero. For any real numbers k G (0,c/7) and A- Vfrlx'i-kl^J-Uiirlx^K-^k [ .'Bfl-4 zero. Dividing the denotes the left hand 7, partial derivative of U{(r, y) with respect to y. This implies that X,'£(w)<— «,-(r,*, x*(u;)) (3.1.5) 5 + <— for almost every u,(''.-,0) w6 A,-, at/ the second inequality of which follows from concavity. By (2) in Section 2.3, K is finite. Since £ < Now if a.«.,the proof let is K = sup,-^complete. (r t-,0)/X,-. | Proposition 3.1.2 states that Arrow-Debreu prices can be normalized so that the price for any claim x Q £ L?(P) at time zero given by E (x), its expected value under a probability uniformly absolutely continuous with respect to P. The uniform absolute continuity of Interpret £ to be societal £ is shadow Q with respect to prices for time T or otherwise, agents can increase their utilities cheaply. utilities for time T l's shadow prices, can be illustrated as follows. consumption. In equilibrium, we know must be greater than or equal to each agent's shadow than or equal to agent P prices for time In particular, £ T must be greater which are constant multiples of consumption. Since agent l's 15 marginal utilities for time consumption, his marginal T consumption are assumed to be bounded away from T hand, by the assumption that time (almost) every state there zero, £ an agent to consume a nontrivial amount shadow price his for consumption By the assumption that £ all bounded away from aggregate endowment at least one agent is is in who is is be no the agents' marginal the other bounded away from zero, in consuming a nontrivial amount. For a particular state, in that state On zero. less utilities it is necessary, roughly, that than the societal shadow are price. bounded above, we then know bounded above. is Some Theorems on 3.2. known well It is the representation of square-integrable martingales that any square-integrable martingale adapted to a Brownian motion can be represented as an filtration Ito integral (Kunita and Watanabe We [28]). will make use of the following result, originally developed by Fujisaki, Kallianpur, and Kunita in the context of non-linear filtering. Lemma 3.2.1: Let there be defined on a complete probability space (Q',7',P') an A -dimensional r [0, [15], process Y. Let the filtration generated by y Assumed that 7 T T\). P'-negligible sets, = and that 7\ 7', that for is almost every t 6 [0, Y be denoted by T] 7\ Suppose that trivial. Y is Fy = augmented by {7\,t all 6 the can be represented by an Ito integral as = r(o)+ Jo/ r(t) where {h(t), W 7y t , y t is 6 [0, T]} is an N- vector F v -adapted •, \h(t)\ \h{t)\ where Epi denotes the expectation under defined on (H', 7',P') adapted to F" can m (t) = m (0) + some h + w*{t), an N-dimensional standard Brownian motion adapted to EP / \ Jo for h( 8 )d 8 l P*. process defined on (fi\ 7', At < oo, Then any 3.1 of Fujisaki, Kallianpur, 16 1 ) and where satisfying square-integrable martingale Vt6 [0,T], satisfying (3.2.1). Proof: See Theorem P , (3.2.1) be represented as / h(8)ldW"{a) Jo lo Fv and Kunita [14]. I m Y The process Lemma of 3.2.1 definition of a generalized diffusion see 3.2.1 states that respect to the Brownian motion \V y The information W defined adapted to Watanabe measure Q F structure Y The next constructed is F Lemma filtration . is generated by an TV-dimensional Brownian proposition shows that if we substitute W for Kunita and (cf. P the probability Proposition 3.1.2, then any square-integrable martingale defined in F can still be represented as an Ito integral with respect to 7 ,Q) adapted (f2, to F. That is, N the multiplicity of the invariant under a substitution of a uniform absolute continuous probability Proposition 3.2.1: There to [29].) T'yP1 ) adapted to the measure. (For a discussion of multiplicity, see Duffie and Huang (H, 7, (For the can be represented as a stochastic integral with F for our economy independent Brownian motions on F (0*, can be represented as an Ito integral with respect to [28]). 7',/"). on (Q,7,P). Therefore, any square-integrable martingale on (H, 7,P) on (Q, 7,Q) adapted to filtration (ft*, Chapter 5 of Liptser and Shiryayev any square-integrable martingale on generated by the generalized diffusion motion a generalized diffusion on is Q) adapted to F exists [13].) an /V-dimensional Brownian motion such that any square-integrable martingale m on (fi, W* defined on 7, Q) adapted can be represented as m(0 = m(0)+ / h{s^dW\a), a.s. Jo where {h(t),7t,t 6 [0, T]} is an TV-vector nonanticipative functional such that E* I \h(t)\ 2 dt < oo. (3.2.2) Jo Remark: We will henceforth denote the set of F- adapted on (H, 7,Q) satisfying measure to P, P H(P) is a. 8., The analogous by H(Q). denoted by H(P). Since Q is set defined processes defined under probability uniformly absolutely continuous with respect = H(Q). Remark: Q— (3.2.2) N- vector Since P and unless a distinction Q is are equivalent, needed. 17 we use a. a. to denote both P— a.s. and Proof: For £ = dQ/dP, let us define £(<) where {£(<)} is = £(£ | 3) as., taken to be a continuous version of {E(( 7 )}. 9 Then t \ there exists p G H(P) such that ^(t) (Kunita and Watanabe ^(t) where = l(0/f(0- 9(f) + 1 / p(8?dW(8) From Proposition [28]). and bounded away from = zero. It follows = exp |^ from 3.1.2 Ito's V (s)ldW(s)- (3.2.3) we know that £ Lemma strictly positive that £(<) can be represented as l -jo is 2 \ V (s)\ ds\, Let W\t) = W(t) - I V (s)d8, t E [0, T\. (3.2.4) jq Girsanov's Fundamental Theorem 1 motion on clear that W (fl, 7 , Q). It is W(t) a generalized diffusion on (H, 7, is It = then follows from on (Cl, Lemma m(t) is that W is an ./V-dimensional Brownian adapted to F. By rearranging the / ti(s)d S Jo + W*(t), t e [0, last expression, T] (3.2.5) Q) and generates F. Furthermore, 3.2.1 that J,Q) can be represented ([17]) states any square-integrable martingale {m(t), T ,t G t [0, T]} as = m(0) + A(«)TdVy*(a), / a.a. •/o This is possible since F is a continuous information structure. 18 For details, see t he prwwes for some h 6 H(Q). This was Remark: to be shown. Relation (3.2.4) defines W | as an Ito process (under P) since T s isrsrW 2 < ^'"i "" °° < 3 2 8> - - implies that [ d< ti(t) I I < rH jf 2 < k(«)| d« oo P— a.«. j by the Cauchy-Scharwz inequality. Remark: Let h 6 H(P). Then m(t) where r?)(0) is a constant, is = m(0) + / A(s)T(/Vy(s) jo a.«., a square-integrable martingale under P. Similarly, for h £ H(Q), m(t) is = m(0)+ / h{a)ldW\8) a.s. Jo a square-integrable martingale under Q. See Chapter 4 of Liptser and Shiryayev 3.3. A [29]. constructive proof of the existence of an equilibrium In this sub-section economy. The proof recast in an is we prove the essentially that given as Proposition 5.1 in Duffie economy with 7 diffusion process information. the tribe if the equilibrium price measure separable, if In that paper it and Huang Q is [13], was shown that an equilibrium in the Arrow-Debreu economy if is existence of an equilibrium for our continuous-trading exists, and uniformly absolutely continuous with respect to P, then the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium can be implemented by continuous trading of at most a countable number of long-lived securities. We show here, however, that in our an equilibrium with a Bnite number of long-lived securities 19 exists. economy Theorem in Section 2 3.3.1: with TV An + equilibrium exists in the continuous-trading economy formulated long-lived securities having payoff structures: 1 «j)J!Li-j[ ht)dw\t) ^n+i where t £ TV [0, + 1 : H X [0, a.s. with T] T] — R NxN £j/ \0(t)\ long-lived securities is 2 = In, any function that < dt) oo. A is nonanticipating, nonsingular for all set of equilibrium price processes for these is Sj(t)=E\dj\T t ) = jf ^(«)rfW'(«) (3.3.1) -y S'.v+ifO for all £ ( [0, respectively, allocation is — T], 0j(s)dW(s) - J a.«. £,(«)»/(«)</*, Proof: Let = 1,2,..., TV, 1« where W and ij are defined Proposition 3.2.1 and equation (3.2.4), and where 0j denotes the j-th row of Pareto j fi. Furthermore, the equilibrium efficient. {(r,-,x,-) 6 V+;i Debreu economy and V De the = 1,2, ...,/} be strictly positive an equilibrium allocation and r-continuous in the Arrow- linear functional on V that gives equilibrium prices as in Proposition 3.1.2: tl)(r,x) where a is = ar + E'(z), the price for time zero consumption, and E (x) gives the equilibrium price at time zero for claims x 6 L2 (P). By the definition of an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium we know that (r i ,x i ) is ^/.-maximal in the set {(r,x)6V+ :V(r,x)<V(r,-,i,)} 20 for every it is i = 1, 2, . . ., By the assumption that /. agents' preferences are strictly increasing, obvious that Equivalent ly, The price for x i — r,-, x\ =a(r' - f.) + E\x] - time zero x\ at - - ^{r'i a{r{ is — it) r,). That consumption good to buy the claim x i units of = ii) — is, 0. (3.3.3) at time zero agent In £,-. what follows i pays (f,- — r, we show that an equilibrium exists in our continuous trading economy with the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium allocation {(r,-,Xi)€ V+ ;i = 1,2,...,/}. well-defined and The proof is completed by the following program: 1. Verify that d 2. Show that 5 3. Allocate an admissible trading strategy to each agent and show that markets is lies in Show there is L?(P). an admissible price system. and the Arrow-Debreu allocation clear 4. is is attained. no incentive for any agent to deviate from his or her allocated trading strategy. Now we Step E*(j 1. proceed exactly as outlined above. We want 2 \ft{t)\ dt) < to oo, show that d which uniform absolute continuity of Q. It follows in is turn implies J P Note that E(f well-defined. |/?(t)| 2 </< < with respect to Q. Thus, d from the second remark after Proposition \P(t)\ 2 < dt) oo implies oo Q-almost surely, by the is well-defined under 3.2.1 that d is P and square-integrable under Q, and therefore square-integrable under P, again by the absolute continuity of P with respect to Q. Step 2. First we show that S is well-defined. the second remark after Proposition 3.2.1 and integral in the third line of (3.3.1) 1. Finally, it follows from (3.2.8) integral in the third line of (3.3.1) is 5 The second is line of (3.3.1) follows well-defined under Q. well-defined under P, since P{J The 2 |/?(<)| <fr from stochastic < oo} = and the Cauchy-Scharwz inequality that the Lebesgue is well-defined. 21 Thus the second and the third lines of (3.3.1) are equal S under P, and Step 3. We W from the definition of is Therefore the second . line is also well-defined an admissible price system. allocate an admissible trading strategy 6 % £ Q[S] to each agent i and show that with the announced price system agents obtain their Arrow-Debreu allocations almost surely and markets clear. Denoting x, — i, by we know from Proposition e,, nonanticipative process {h l (t),t H since, by the fact that £ 6 7]} with h* [0, = E*(ti) + € H(Q) such h\tydW\t) / an TV-vector that a.s., Jo bounded above, is 3.2.1 that there exists e,- £ L2 (Q). For every t £ [0, 7*], and j 1,2,.. .,7V, let —i where 0j denotes the j'-th column of the inverse of 0, and AT *kn(0 = £*(«*) + * We claim that the [0,7] - 0N+i(l) N r(n+i)xn =QV < row vector of £ N+ [0.7], where zeros. First is an admissible trading strategy. Let = 0j(t) V to 0)(t)Sj(t). . t £ [0,7] o.«. for 0j(t) denotes the j-th we want e[] 9)(*)dSj( 8 ) / '0 1-vector process 6 l be such that 0j(t) N - J2 /•( £ let row of 0(t), all j = 1,2,... ,7V, m)dt\ Note that rT / Jo *W£( W) T *W = rT / Jo I Jo i h\tf'0 \t)0(t)0(t)T0 \t)lh (t)dt hHtVkHtot = I Jo Cl X and and where Q denotes an show that {6\tV0(t)0{t : 2 \h\t)\ dt by construction. Because h 6 E Thus, (3.3.4) follows since £ stochastic integral H(Q) we T \L *W/W(') 'W<) < bounded away from is l 6 (t)^dS(t) / have it follows from Next, we want to show that the zero. Memin [31] rT Once we well-defined under probability measure Q, is that the definition of a stochastic integral invariant under an equivalent change of measure. we is Under probability measure Q, rT = *{t)US{t) / Jo (3.3.5) well-defined under probability measure P. is show that the above stochastic integral are done, since oo. / Jo h'Wfi \t)0(t)dW\t) (3.3.6) = which is well-defined, since h / Jo hWdW\t), 6 H(Q). Therefore $' £ Q[S] since by construction it is also self-financing. Finally, by construction and relation (3.3.6), *''(0)TS(0)+ / Jo hWdw'w + / Jo =*}v+i(o) MtydSft) fT =£*(e t ) i + h (t)UW'(t) / = ei a.s. Jo Thus, for an initial trading strategy 0' $' investment of attains thus chosen be agent i's e, E (e,)/o units of consumption good, the admissible units of consumption good at time trading strategy for i = I*' = -£*•• 23 1, 2, ...,/— 1. T almost surely. For agent I, set Let Since 0{S] is 1 a linear space, O admissible. is Markets for long-lived securities then clear by construction. Furthermore, /-I rT / ^(0 T «w(0 + 4v+i(o)--5>-ei v by the fact that, If all in . an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, 5Z,-_i = «i 0, a.e. agents follow these assigned trading strategies, each agent - f, = E'(ei)/a f, - + (r* T agent t at time zero consumes f.) * where the first line follows from (3.3.3). Xi + e,- At time Step 4. Now we want to z,- a.«. Arrow-Debreu his or her consumes = Xi + (x* - ii) = Thus every agent gets i allocation. show that there no incentive for agents to diverge from is their assigned trading strategies. First, let us note that for any h £ H(Q), rt I h(sydw\s) te[o,T] Jo is a square-integrable Proposition 3.2.1). It Q martingale under the second remark after the proof of (cf. then follows from (3.3.5) that, for any / e(s)US(s) = Jo 9{s)ip(6)dW'{s) Jo is also a square-integrable martingale I, and (r,x) 6 V+, with under Q. Next suppose there 6 &[S] such that x I 6 ©[5], - Xf £/,(r,x) = 9N+ i{0) + / > C/,(rJ,a;*) ${t)US(t Jo T = o(r'-r)+ I '0 Jo 24 0(t)lJS(t). and is one agent, say agent Taking expectations with respect to Q, = a(r] - r) + E*U E\x - x]) 9(t)US(t)\ = o(u ~r), the second line follows from the fact that J under Q. But, in 0(s)T(/S(«) an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, a(r'-r) a contradiction. Therefore there is > £/,(r,x) < E\x - is a square-integrable martingale t/,(r,-, x,) implies x*), no incentive for agents to diverge from assigned trading strategies. The equilibrium allocation equilibrium allocations. is Pareto | Given an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium, we can find "support" it in a continuous trading economy. in selecting securities, process and /?. As long satisfies Pareto agents get their Arrow-Debreu since efficient we can as ft(u!,t) 1 long-lived securities which should be clear from the above proof that It our attention to selecting the nonanticipative matrix restrict is N+ nonsingular for all t £ [0, T] and for almost every u £ ft, the given regularity conditions, a continuous trading equilibrium exists with a efficient allocation. Corollary 3.3.1: Under the conditions securities complete markets. That is, of Theorem the price of a claim to x at any time t Let x is E (x 6 L2 (P). Under the chosen \ 7 ), which can t integral. in + 1 long-lived any contingent claim not traded can be replicated by continuously trading on these securities. Proof: See Step 3 3.3.1, the given TV the proof of the Theorem. | 25 price system, be represented as an Ito Properties of equilibrium price system 4. Morgenstern utility functions previous section In the we demonstrated an equilibrium economy and showed that the equilibrium price system in equation (3.3.1) processes. That is, past history of the is any time at t an is € [0, allocation Ito process [4], whose not only an Ito process but / is is The equilibrium generally depend upon the fi some vector I ft(Z(8),a)dW(s)+ s(Z(s), 8 )d3, Jo of unspecified diffusion processes. It is further assumed that (Z,S) We now forms a vector diffusion process, or that (Z,S) has the strong Markov property. show conditions guaranteeing that will Z can be taken to be the "state variable process" Z, implying that the values of nonanticipative processes be written as a (Borel measurable) functions of Z(t) and More diffusion process. for [34], of the form: Jo Z efficient. coefficients are nonanticipative and tj our continuous-trading assumes, however, that the equilibrium price system analogous to 5(0-5(0)+ where Pareto is T], the values of in economy. The Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model of Merton extended by Breeden (3.3.1) when agents have von Neumann- generally, we and t. will exhibit conditions c at any time t € Furthermore, (Z,S) [0, is T] can a vector under which the price process any contingent claim having a certain payoff structure, adjoined to the state variable process, forms a vector diffusion process. From Essay I of Huang [24] the fact that equilibrium prices are Ito integrals is an inherent property of diffusion/Brownian motion information structures. Conditions under which (Z,S) is a vector diffusion process are not as naturally posed. This section flows as follows. In a market equilibrium with a Pareto in which agents have von Neumann-Morgenstern time-additive efficient allocation utility functions, we can construct a representative agent with a von Neumann-Morgenstern time-additive utility function case, who "supports" the equilibrium by consuming aggregate endowments. In that the properties of the equilibrium price for a particular contingent claim will be determined entirely by aggregate endowments. its payoff structure, the representative agent's preferences, and When these "aggregates" have simple structure, so will equilibrium 26 prices. Construction of a representative agent 4.1. In a market equilibrium of either the Arrow-Debreu or Radner design a representative agent endowment who supports point (Kreps [26, 27]). This themselves give a "representative agent". agent takes on content (and has value) When preferences. if [37] type, one can always the equilibrium price system at the aggregate almost vacuous, since the equilibrium prices is The statement that there a representative is one can show that this agent has nicely structured individual agents have preferences given by von Neumann-Morgenstern time- additive utility functions and share given subjective probability assessments over states and when the equilibrium allocation of the world, is Pareto the representative efficient, agent can be chosen to be an expected utility maximizer having a time-additive utility function. Prescott commodity and Mehra [36] assert space, Constantinides that this is We is u, is separable. /?+—>/? such that U{(r,y) i and That = /,(r) + y,(y). U (r,x) (a) /, is, infinite extension of dimensional commodity spaces there exist functions /,• Then Ui can be represented = f (r)+ i I Jn (2) in Section 2.3 implies that for y, The conceptually straightforward but needs to be formalized. assume that Assumption a model with a finite dimensional provides a detailed construction. [8] Const ant inides' construction to economies with (such as ours) so. In : R+ — R and as gi ( X ("))P(du). every t = 1,2, ...,/, are strictly increasing, concave, continuous, and with finite right hand derivatives everywhere. We also (b) /, is assume that strictly for every * = 1,2,...,/, concave and differentiate and y,- is strictly concave, three times continuously differentiable with bounded derivatives, and the second derivative of Q{ is bounded away from zero. 10 The assumption of bounded derivatives can be relaxed by assuming Lipschitz-like conditions on the derivatives. See Theorem 3 on page 293 of Gihman and Skorohod [16]. 27 y,- : For every = i 1,2,...,/, we know (r,- i,- ) , solves the following concave program: max UAr, x) (r,*)€V+ (4.1.1) s.t. By (4) in Section 2.3, ari + a(r > 0(i,-) 0. — f,) + That is, 6 + jn tA*i(»))P(*a) gi{x(Lo))P(du) + + ^iUri - x/a(f, Using the arguments following (3.1.1) From the arguments used - k g[ " r') + = 1/n. From the saddle- such that, for every (r,x) £ jf f(wXi.<«) jf fl^XM") - - *.-M)/w) V+ (4.1.2) z(u))P(c/a;)\ proof for Proposition 3.1.2, we know £ fl«X«Kw) " *!(«)VW = X,- > 0. B (r'.z* j,-. Let < Xt€(«) Bn /~ B f ] (4.1.4) for some we , H : a;*(w) > £}, let A strictly positive scalar k, 6 /, with get f(a/)P(«M, X,- = {u6n: z,*(w) > 0} = (J^ Bn *'/4 (4.1.3) o.«., be the set {u 6 - fcl^n^J G V+ ^M)P(rfw) > 0. we have the argument used to obtain (3.1.5) /n Since + r) to derive (3.1.4), denotes the derivative of finally let (r,x) < X,- + r,*) in the ?'(*,V)) and By the Slater condition holds. (4.1.2) implies that «(r; where 0. Jq gAx'^mdu) + b(a(u -r') + jn Zi^i^u) - x\(u))P(du)\ >MU) + jf Then < 6 R+, Mr*) + >fi{r) ii) number point theorem there exists a nonnegative real and every — <j>(x n = l,2,... . we have tt)W>^/ «M rt [IB 28 flw)P(<M V>ie7. (4.1.5) Let fl + - Bf\{u> e n ftzfa)) > X .£( w )} and : Applying the argument used to obtain 0. That is, for those w£fi is = ^DW e B+ (4.1.4) to the sets > such that z'^uj) and ft : rffoV)) < X t fl«)}. = B~ we get P{B + \J B~} 0, — *.£(<") l5(*J(«)) It B~ o.«. (4.1.6) from the calculus that clear — X,o /J(rJ) > if r- if r* = 0, and (4.1.7) < fi(r]) Therefore and (4.1.3), (4.1.4), (4.1.6), X,o 0. (4.1.7) are necessary conditions for (r*,x*) 6 V+ to be a solution to (4.1.1). Now define F #+ : — i? and —# G #+ : F(r) by £r ' = max 1 /,{j,,) / £y,<r, st. (4.1.8) and ' G(r)— max s-t. 1 5^7-0i(y,) £y,<r. ( 41 9 - ) t'=l One can easily verify that the following Lemma F() and G() lemma shows are strictly increasing that F(-) and G{) and strictly concave. Furthermore, are differentiate. 4.1.1: F(-) and G'() are differentiable. In addition, F'(R) =o (4.1.10) G'(X(u)) where /? s J3,-_, f, and where X = X\=i *»'• 29 £(u>) a.«., Proof: Consider F() Let first. r of (4.1.8) be any strictly positive real number and be the solution of the concave program of let (y,)f=I {1,2,...,/} such that yj > 0. F(r since giving the "extra (4.1.8). + k)- F(r) > f (ffa + *) - amount" k to agent j is D + F(r) > D + F(r) and > r k get F at r, which exists since F is concave we have lies in (0,j/,), F(r Dividing both sides of ^fjiVj), denotes the right hand derivative of When 0. 6 ffy,j)), certainly feasible. we there must exist j Then Let k be any positive real number. the above expression by k and letting k approach zero, where Then -k)- F(r) > Uf } ( yj —k and Dividing both sides of the above expression by IT F[r) < -k)- ffa)). letting k approach zero, we get J-fjivj), A; where D~F(r) denotes the left hand derivative of F at r. A; Ay = Therefore D + F(r) = on Suppose the right hand derivative of F{) (0, oo). Thus, D~F(r) £fj{yj), and so F'(r) exists. Thus, F() at zero does not exist. is differentiate Then, by strict concavity of F(-), there exists a sequence of strictly positive real numbers {k n }, with kn such that F(k n )-F(0) ; Now it follows from monotonicity > Vn n, and concavity of ,<!M5<f ' ; 30 = l,2,... /,• /W that Vn = l,2 J 0, which contradicts the fact that /$(0) zero. Identical arguments show that G(-) Next we show that F'(R) we know = (r, )' , is =a for is finite is r - E f# A some j £ {1,2,...,/} with > r- 0. - = £(u>) a.s. By strict concavity of /,-, «>- » i-yjfrj) Substituting from (4.1.7) gives = F'(R) Similar arguments show G'(X(u>)) The concavity and bounded. differentiable at 0, F'(R) for is the unique set of positive real numbers such that t=l R > Therefore F(-) also differentiable. and that G'(X(ui)) ft*) Since all t. Now we — £(a>) a.s. differentiability of Proposition 4.1.1: (R,X) is Proof: This assertion follows F() and G(-) also imply that F'() and G'(-) are results of this subsection: the unique solution of the following program: max s.t. | main are ready to prove the a. F(r)+ / G(x(oj))P(du) ar + <f>(x) directly <ak + 4>(X). from (4.1.10). | Proposition 4.1.1 implies that the equilibrium established in the previous section can be supported by a representative agent whose preferences are represented by the functional V(r,i) = F(r) + fQ G(x(u>))P(duj), and whose consumption is constrained by aggregate endowments. If if each agent's time T equilibrium consumption is in the quasi-interior 11 L\{P) and of time aggregate endowments satisfy a regularity condition, we can say a bit more. 11 L,\(P) has an empty interior. The quasi-interior of 31 L+(P) is the set {x 6 L+(P) x : > 0}. Proposition 4.1.2: Suppose P{X > s] = then G'() = 1,2,...,/, such that t = i Let c 1,2, ...,/. three times continuously differentiable on is C2 Furthermore, there exist derivatives. R+, 1, for every 2> a:, z,-(u;) Proof: By the assumptions x,- (c, = ess inf X. oo) with bounded functions with bounded derivatives = c,(X(w)) for almost every € Q. » V 6 {1,2, ...,/} and P{X > If c,- : (c, oo) — u> i e} = 1, we know the solution of I lies in = X: R+ the interior of on a if r > c, for otherwise there exists a measure. set of strictly positive probability i' 6 Suppose {1,2,...,/} such that r > c Necessary and above program are: sufficient conditions for (y,)f=1 to solve the /_1 1 x for i = 1,2,...,/- 1. Now ;ff'(j/.)= . t rV/(»--X!y.) X, let /_1 for »== ]/j is 1,2, ...,/— Since each y, is is / first non-trivial implicit function = x, x7 — 1 arguments. from the theorem It is fact that each (see, for ^i(r). That y,- is (c. 00) strictly concave. example, Hestenes c,- : (c, 00) [22], — It p. 172) /?+, 1 = then follows from the that there exist / 1, 2, ...,/— 1 — 1 such that is, X, : Let J be the Jacobian of (]/,)[=' with . easy but tedious to check that the determinant z-g'i (c i (r))=^g'I Define cj £j three times continuously differentiable on /?+, each twice continuously differentiable functions J/» 1 -1 twice continuously differentiable on /? + respect to the of J 1. 1 —» R+ by cj(r) X, = r — ^Zi=\ (r-^2c £- c »'( r )> 32 i (r)). (4.1.11) clearly twice continuously differentiable. For 6 r we have (c, oo), = £ ^,(c,(r)). G(r) We on want to show that (c, oo). G is three time9 continuously differentiable with bounded derivatives From Proposition 4.1.1, G() is differentiable on (c, oo) and A* i=i (4I12) -f **»!>) = ^;(c,(r)). The second and that J2l=\ c 'i( r ) the third lines of the above expression follow from (4.1.6) and the fact — 1) respectively. Equation (4.1.12) reconfirms (4.1.10) "envelope condition". Now from the thrice continuous of on c, differentiability of j,- on R+ G on and twice continuous has bounded derivatives on we want to show that we only have to show the boundedness has bounded first for the so called (c, oo) follows differentiability £'_, Therefore c'- is G" and G m bounded since {1,2,...,/}. (Recall that g"{ < it If Given Proposition we can show that each for all i.) bounded above away from zero. fact that the price oo) (4.1.11), from (4.1.13) that 1 > cj- > for all i € Differentiating (4.1.11) with respect to r again, g'", g^, g", and the fact that g" is | system As should be (c, c,- »5(<v(r))/»JMr)) clear is From the boundedness of e" follows from the boundedness of terization possible. . (e, oo). and second derivatives, then the boundedness of G" and G'" on follows from the chain rule for differentiation. The G is (r, oo). Next, 4.1.1, the thrice continuous differentiability of and (3.1.1) clear completes markets makes the above charac- from Section 33 3, every complete markets equilibrium in our continuous trading economy corresponds to an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. In an Arrow-Debreu economy, equilibrium prices are determined by agents' preferences and (the distribution of) endowments. Thus, equilibrium prices in the continuous trading economy should depend only upon the distribution of endowments and not on the distribution of wealth over time. on agents, ^, In the construction of the representative agent, (4.1.8), = i 1,2,...,/, are constants reflecting the distribution of the weights endowments. the distribution of wealth over time were important, then these weights would be and the representative agent's variables, The prices can be linked directly to aggregate is making assumptions about X. This asset price 4.2. apparent from (4.1.10). endowments. aggregate endowments are exogenously specified. of £ by in random function would be state dependent. utility usefulness of a representative agent If We shadow Societal In our pure exchange economy, can therefore derive useful properties turn allows us to deduce conclusions about behavior and optimal portfolio choice. Equilibrium price processes and "state variable process" form a vector diffusion process In this subsection we show a set of conditions ensuring that the price process for a contingent claim, adjoined to the vector of state variable processes, forms a vector diffusion process. We adopt the notation: 0Oi+O 2 +...+O„ QO, ^"tfp" for positive integers a,, is denoted by Dyg a2 , . . or by g y . ., dy?...dy°»> an The If . g : l«l=«i+°2 + R N X [0, T] —R is C following assumptions are 1 , ... + a„ the vector (dg/dt/i, made throughout . ., dg/dy n this subsec- tion. Assumption P{X > c} = 1, 4.2.1: In equilibrium, x] where we Assumption recall c from 4.2.2: There exists a derivatives, such that > for every »' = 1,2, ...,/. Furthermore, (4) of Section 2.3. C2 function X = L(Z(T)) a.8. 34 L : R N — R+ with bounded partial ) Assumption there exist constants Ko and K\ D°p(yj) | Assumption D y fi(y,t) and D y (r(y, t) exist and are continuous 4.2.3: 4.2.3 is aggregate endowment is | | K (l+ y \ K >), Assumption a regularity condition. The path-independent: | path-independence is The needed. value of time is the positive orthant of half of Assumption agents' consumption Assumption 4.2.1 T Assumptions shadow aggregate endowment the positive orthant of lies in and A more V imply that 4.2.2 together T useful result Proposition 4.2.1: There bounded differential equation Assumption This latter Section 4.3), but 4.2.1 fact that each agent's is the least consumption In the first not binding. is The second half of a technical assumption. 4.2.1 are continuous and (cf. to establish the existence of an equilibrium. prices at time zero for time function of Z(T). half of T however, we assume that in the equilibrium, the constraint that 4.2.1, is V first we used the satisfactory part of this essay. In Section 3, set and 4.2.2 says that the time assumption can be relaxed to some extent by enlarging the state space sort of 2, \<*\<2. depends only upon the value of the state variable process at that time. some a |< such that + D ay a(y,t) \< | for in consumption, is t; which we interpret to be is societal path-independent and a smooth actually possible: exists a function 6 y and £, bt exists; : RN X and [0, T] —* R such f>(y,t) satisfies that 8 y and Dy6 the following partial and boundary condition: 6lfi + 6t + -tr(J yy <T<rT) = o, (4.2.1) \jm6(y,t) = G'(L(y)). In addition, £(*) (where {£(<). t £ [0, T]} is = 6{z(t),t) the martingale defined in the proof of Proposition 3.2.1.). Finally, 35 Z(t) can be represented flf) where = expU t](y,l) is as: 1 rt(Z{8),s)UW{8)- continuous in y and t, -^ r,(Z(s),e) \ 2 dsla.s. \ satisfying the Lipschitz Vte[0,T], and growth conditions: \v(y,t)-*l(v,t)\<K\y-y\, (4.2.2) 2 2 2 h(lM)| <A- (l+|j,| ) for some K, and positive constant * (z(<) '' ) Proof: From (4.1.10), 6 y (Z(t),t)MZ(t),t) = Assumptions a twice continuously differentiable function such that, redefining £ on a null set, Z(u}) It follows from Skorohod and t; hi [16] Assumption 4.2.3 : RN — and Proposition /? > , Dyh 4.1.2, there exists with bounded partial derivatives = 9(Z{u,T)) and Theorem vw 9.4 in ea (4.2.4) Chapter that there exists a function h(y,t) such that h y exists; h y also follows § 4.2.2, we have , 2 of Part Dyh II of Gihman and are are continuous in y are bounded; and t(t) It and 4.2.1 (423) • mtu) from Theorem 8.4 in = 6{Z(t),t). Chapter 2 of Part II of Gihman and Skorohod [16] that £(0 can be represented as £(t) = h(Z(t),t)=l+ I p(Z(a),8YdW(8) a.8., Jo where P (Z(t),ty = h y (z(t),ty<7(z(t),t), 36 (4.2.5) and where S(y,t) satisfies (4.2.1). clear that It is 'T El < i \p{Z(t),t)\ dt oo Jo 'o since £ is square-integrable. Ito's fl<) = ex P n Lemma then yields l -jo r,(Z(s),syd\V(s)- \r,(Z{s), 8 )\ 2 ds\ a.8. Vt6 [0, T], whcT6 ri(z(t),ty=p(z(t),t)y6(z(t),t) b {Z(t),t)ta(Z(t),t) y 6(Z(t),t) The fact that tj(y,t) and cr(y,t). is continuous in y and Finally, (4.2.2) follows t follows from the continuity of 6(y, from the fact that away from zero, the fact that a(y,t) satisfies (2.1.1a) Sy{Z{t),t). | If we interpret £(<) as the societal shadow £(t) and is then Proposition 4.2.1 shows that the shadow prices for time path-independent. It 6 y {y,t), bounded above and below (2.1.1b), prices at time t), and the boundedness of for time t T T consumption, consumption over time is follows that the payoff structure of a claim determines whether or not the equilibrium price process forms, with the state variable processes, a vector diffusion process. Proposition 4.2.2: For any contingent claim x £ L?(P) x = E*(x) + I K(Z(t),t)ldW*(t) satisfying a.s., (4.2.6) Jo where it(y,t) : RN X [0,7] — RN is such that E(j T \n(Z(t), t)\ 2 dt) < oo, the equilibrium price process for a claim to x, denoted {ar(<)}> can be represented as x(t) = E'(x)+ I k{Z(s), eydW'( 8 Jo = £*(*)" / ) K(Z(s),8)^(Z(s),s)d8+ Jo I k{Z(s),8)UW(s) 0.8. Jo (4.2.7) 37 Furthermore, suppose that K(y,t) is continuous in y and Then K(y,t) r v(y<t) satisfy Lipschitz and growth conditions. and that both n(y,t) and {(Z(t),x(t)),t G T]} [0, is a under P. diffusion process Proof: t, First we note that by uniform absolute continuity E'lJo \K(Z(t),t)\~dt) < oo. It of P with respect to Q, then follows from the corollary after Theorem 3.3.1, the second remark after the proof of Proposition 3.2.1, and Proposition 4.2.1 that the equilibrium price for x at time E\x 7 t I ) is t - E\x) + Elj «(Z(«),«)W(«) 7 t | o = E'(x)+ J I K(Z(s),8)ldw\s) Jo = E\x)- I Jo Now suppose that Arnold 6.2.2 in [l] k(j/, t) and K(Z(s), S yri{Z{s),8)ds+ I K(Z(s), 8 ydW(s) a.s. Jo k(j/, t^tjd/, t) satisfy ensures that {(Z(t),x(t)),t € Lipschitz and growth conditions. [0, T]} of stochastic differential (integral) equations (2.1.2) /i(i/,/), (r{y,t), ti(y, t), [0,T]} is and K(y,t), Theorem 9.3.1 of and is Theorem the unique solution for the system (4.2.7). Finally, Arnold [1] by the continuity of ensures that {(Z(t),x(t)),t G a vector diffusion process under P. | As an immediate consequence, we have: Corollary 4.2.2: as 0(Z(lj,1), <), if Hy< the If { ) ' s random matrix 0(u>,t) (cf. continuous in y and t, and if Theorem 3.3.1) can be written 0{y,t) and fl(y,t) J il(y,t) satisfy Lipschitz and growth conditions, then the equilibrium price system for long-lived securities, S, can be represented as 5(<) = 5(0)+ / 0(Z{s),a)dW(a)- / p{Z{a), e)t){Z{8), e)ds Jo Jo and forms, with the state variable process, a vector N + 1-th row of fl(t) is diffusion process. a.s., (Recall that the a vector of zeros.) Proposition 4.2.2 states that if the payoff structure of a claim librium price has a nice representation. (Here we use 38 nice to mean is nice, then its equi- of the forms (4.2.6) and On (4.2.7), respectively). the other hand, the fact that the equilibrium price process of a claim has a nice representation does not necessarily imply that adjoining to that proces the state variable processes forms a vector diffusion process, unless conditions are satisfied. is nice little whenever its One natural question to follow some Lipschitz and growth whether a claim's payoff structure is The price proces has a nice representation. following proposition is a stronger than the converse of Proposition 4.2.2. Proposition 4.2.3: Suppose the equilibrium 6 L2 (P) can be price for a claim to x represented as x{t) where f is = x(0) + J s(a)d8 x K (Z(8),sydW(e) t 6 = E*(x)+ oo. [0, J Jo Then a.*., RN X : (4.2.8) T] [0, —» R N Borel is can be written as $(Z(w,t), ?(u>,<) T] and almost every K(Z(t),t)UW*(t) w£H , in and a.s. ( f («) + K{Z(8),a)tdW'(a) K(Z(«),«)TirtZ(«), «))</«+ / a.s. (4.2.9) Jo Step 2 of the proof of Theorem 3.3.1 show that the above expression defined under Q. By Corollary 3.3.1 is a square-integrable martingale. E (J 2 \K(Z(t),l)\ dt) < we know that, under probability Next note that E(f oo by the fact that £ is \n(Z(t), 2 <)| bounded above. It measure Q, < ^0 is well- {x(t)} oo implies that then follows from the second remark after the proof of Proposition 3.2.1 that the stochastic integral of (4.2.9) a square-integrable martingale under Q. integrable martingale under continuous. variation or have c(u;,e) t) First let us rewrite (4.2.8) as = x{0) + Jq/ Arguments < 2 \it(Z(t),t)\ dt) (Borel measurable) for almost every x{t) J a nonanticipative process, and where n(y,t) measurable with E(f Proof: + Now is = Q as well. note the following: a constant throughout -k(Z(u>, t), Thus the Lebesgue integral in (4.2.9) Furthermore, as a function of Any continuous martingale (cf. Dellacherie and tyt](Z(uj,t), t) for almost 39 all t Meyer € [0, is [12]). t, it is is either of is a square- absolutely unbounded Therefore, we must T] and almost every w 6 f2. Substituting into (4.2.9) we have z(t) = z(0) + n(Z(e), / aydW"{e) a.a. Jo =x Finally note that x(T) = E*(x). a.a., so x(0) | Propositions 4.2.2 and 4.2.3 together imply that for the equilibrium price of a claim to have a nice representation Note t also that, in the may depend upon representation. The structure of a claim it is necessary and sufficient that payoff structure its is nice. above characterization, the equilibrium price of a claim at any time the past realizations of the state variable process, even if it following proposition formalizes the intuitive notion that is path-independent, then its if has a nice the payoff equilibrium price process must also be path-independent. Proposition 4.2.4: The equilibrium claim whose payoff is price, at each time t £ [0,T], of a consumption a Borel measurable function of Z(T), can be written as a Borel measurable function of Z(t). Proof: The arbitrage value By the for a claim x definition of conditional expectation E\x\7t) £ L2 (P) class argument (see Chapter 2 of = E{xi\7t)IZ{t) E(xi\7 t since by Assumptions from the Lemma c^ 4.2.1 and [19].) Markov property Chung ) [6] If (see = E{xi\Z{t)) [6] t is E (x \ It) almost surely. a.a. x depends only on Z(T), Chung or see Williams 4.2.2, £ also on page 299 of Chung time we have (For the above fact see, for example, Harrison follows from the definition of the at [7], [38], p. p. 2-3.) it then and a monotone 122) that a.a., depends only upon Z{T). Finally, it follows that there exist two Borel measurable functions and f such that E{xl\Z(t)) = 40 <t>(Z{t)) a.a. and S(t) Thus the is = <p(Z(t)) O.8. assertion follows from the fact that the ratio of two Borel measurable functions Borel measurable, and the fact that £(t) is strictly positive. | Special cases of the above proposition are (multiple contingency) options written on The equilibrium the final values of the state variable process. at each time t prices of these call options are Borel measurable functions of the value of the state variable process at that time. Remark: If the payoff structure of a claim with bounded partial derivatives, then this In this subsection system S is not only path-independent but is C2 is a special case of Proposition 4.2.2. we have shown that under some conditions the equilibrium Z together with the "state variable process" continuous trading models of financial markets it price forms a vector diffusion process. In has always been assumed that the equi- librium price system together with certain unspecified processes, which may be endogenous, forms a vector diffusion process. Here, however, we have provided a set of conditions under which those unspecified processes are identified as the vector exogenously specified "state variable processes" Z. The 4.2.3. results of this subsection As mentioned earlier, depend crucially upon Assumptions Assumption 4.2.2 sumption. same are not path-independent neither are societal In that case, the equilibrium price of a structure will not have a nice representation. stated in Propositions 4.2.2 and 4.2.3. aggregate endowment is and can be relaxed to some extent while main- taining characterizations of equilibrium prices of the endowments 4.2.1, 4.2.2, flavor. When shadow time T aggregate prices for time T con- consumption claim with a nice payoff Here we still use nice to In the next subsection, mean of the forms we show that if time T not path-independent but can be represented in a certain form, then, by enlarging the state space, we can make everything 41 nice again. An augmented 4.3. Let us system suppose that the aggregate endowment first X=X where t, | ft(y, t) RN X : 2 D°fty,t) A'o, A'o, and a(y, t) X(T) = A' | + | D ay a(y,t) : J &(Z(t),t)lJW(t) RN X [0, T] -* D°&(y, t), |< A' (l+ A'i are positive constants. = A'(0) + X(«) Thus, and + RN a.s., (4.3.1) are continuous in y and exist t) of the form: is and are continuous if with | where —R T] [0, fi(Z(t),t)dt J and growth conditions, Dyii{y, satisfy Lipschitz q |< + X at time T a.s. Now ii(Z{s), s)ds / + Kl \ ), \ a |< 2, is [0, T}} by (4.3.2) the unique solution for the system and We € &{Z(s), 8 )dW(s). I of stochastic differential (integral) equations (2.1.2) [l]). y define the process {X{t),t Then Ux(t), Z(t)\te [0,T}\ process (Theorem 6.2.2 and 9.3.1 of Arnold | (4.3.2), and is a vector diffusion have the following result, analogous to Proposition 4.2.2. Proposition 4.3.1: For any contingent claim x £ L2 (P) of the form: = E(x)+ ;*(x)+ x / / K(Z(t),X(t),tydW »c (t) a.8., Jo where K (y,t) : A N+1 X [0, T) RN - satisfies E(J T \ K (Z(t), X(t),t)\ 2 dt) < oo, if in equi- librium the assumptions of Section 4.2 hold, then the equilibrium price process of a claim to x, {x(()}, can be represented as x{t) = E\x)+ I s{Z(s),X(8),8)ds+ Jo where f(y,0 : fl satisfy Lipschitz N+1 X [0, T] I k(Z(s),X(8),8)UW(s) — R is Borel measurable. and growth conditions, then {Z(t), X(t), Proof: The proof is a.s., Jo If, in addition, ?(j/,*) x(t)} is a vector diffusion process. similar to those for Propositions 4.2.1 and 4.2.2, so 42 and n(y,t) we omit it. I The above proposition once again signifies that, with complete markets (or equilibrium allocation is Pareto efficient), it is when the the nature of aggregate endowments that determines the properties of societal shadow prices, which in turn, together with the payoff structure of consumption claims, determine the properties of equilibrium prices. The characterization 5. of optimal portfolio rules In intertemporal portfolio theory, where price processes are taken as primitives, agents' optimal trading strategies are typically computed using stochastic dynamic programming (cf. Merton [32,33]). Merton [34] and Breeden behavior in an equilibrium context by their dynamic programs. representation argument. See, for example, Harrison Cox [4,5] characterized agents' optimal portfolio summing up agents' first order conditions from recently proposed an alternative using a martingale [9] (This method and Kreps is vaguely foreshadowed in the earlier literature. Section [20, 3] and Kreps [26].) We will illustrate, in our equilibrium setting, a technique similar to that proposed by Cox. Properties of agents' optimal trading strategies which are be established. We difficult to come by using dynamic programming will contend, and hope herein to demonstrate, that the technique using martingale representation is not just an alternative to the dynamic programming; it is a better technology. In establishing the existence of picked TV + 1 long-lived securities, nonsingular matrix process, /?, an equilibrium in TV of which could be characterized by an TV satisfying certain regularity conditions (Section 3.3). mentioned that any such process would do the job. we analyze a (The (TV + our continuous-trading economy, we 3.3.1 that the equilibrium price Sj(t) is still system = Wj(t)- I = Vj (s)d8 1 43 a.s. We In) It to be the identity matrix. then follows from Theorem is '0 Jo SN+1 {t) a claim to TV For this section, to simplify things, particular version of the equilibrium by choosing l)-th long-lived security X y = l,2,...,TV, for all 6 t a claim to x Once again the above T\. [0, € L2 (P) has Some prelimenary set of long-lived securities completes markets, a value at time t E of P Let [13].) almost surely. in order. Let They m m and be two square- are square-integrable semimartingales P by the uniform absolute continuity of and Duffie and Huang It) \ and remarks are definitions integrable F-adapted martingales under Q. under (x and with respect to Q. (m,m) denote the unique F-adapted Meyer (See [35] process of bounded variation vanishing at time zero which satisfies te m(t)m(t)-(Tn,rh)t is an F-adapted square-integrable martingale under Q. (See Dellacherie and Meyer The joint variation process [m,rh] (Meyer (cf. known is Since [35]). continuous It [0,T\, is equivalent to (m,fn) We will therefore that the joint variation process (Memin is time T Theorem 3.3.1 exchange for the portfolio zero in zero Arrow-Debreu allocation T]}, which in state u in is m and m. e,- = xi #'(0), pays i where a is By at that time. E In the proof of m are continuous for the portfolio he Theorem 3.3.1, is is i,-. the joint variation process That is, e,- We know (ei)/a units of the difference is from the same consumption at time the unit price of time zero consumption, following the trading strategy {0'(<),< budget feasible throughout, he gets exchange — is equilibrium allocation and endowment. proof that, given the price system S, agent (0, and always use [m,m] to denote [m,rn). Therefore, under P, [m,rh] [31]). Recall the notation from t's m invariant under a substitution of an equivalent two square-integrable semimartingales between agent when a continuous information structure, any F-adapted martingale the previous essay). probability measure for the F is [12].) e,-(u;) units of consumption holding at that time and consume we demonstrated / optimal trading at time € T z,-(w). strategies, one for each agent. They were chosen from a set of "admissible trading strategies" which forms a linear space. The primary tool used is martingale representation (Proposition 3.2.1). Using the theory of optimal control, however, sufficient conditions for the existence of optimal trading strategies usually involve compactness of the admissible set of controls [3], Chapter IV). 44 (cf. Bismut Now define a continuous process c'(t) This is the value process for agent defined F-adapted process The almost surely. € {e,'(t)> ?t,t t's = E\ ei T time [®>T]} by \T ) a.s. t optimal net trade. It is Q a square-integrable martingale under is clear that the above = and tht e,(T) c,- following proposition shows that the optimal trading strategies have hedging properties. Proposition 5.1: For any agent in the economy, say agent i, we have for all t E [0, T], #}(«)« 4&wJ]i/<ft (5.1) = d\elWj] t j=l,2,...,N, /dt and N W0==«. (0-£'}(0S/(0! Proof: The them and Shiryayev in Liptser from the fact Theorems of (5.1) follows from first line [29]. In fact, it defines 6j. is W the proof of Since from the construction is we have taken Theorem measure (Memin [31]), i | l to be the identity matrix, (0 j)ji=1 = h* for all = 1 local joint variability of is, d[e it i in 3.3.1. for all £ ( [0, 7*]. The number optimally chooses to hold at time with Wj (that is and the for the j-th (j < N) long-lived locally perfectly corrected with the j-th underlying source of uncertainty, since d[VV-, Wj] t /dt that agent line in (5.1) follows in Section 3.3. Roughly speaking, we could say that the price process security The second . (5.2) follows Remark: and the note after zero throughout, the fact that the joint variation process invariant under a substitution of an equivalent probability Equation and 5.5 5.4 that the joint variation process of a continuous process and a continuous bounded variation process definition of (5.2) e,- and Wj Wj]/dt < 0, t at that time. is If of shares of the j-th (j < N) security equal to, again roughly speaking, the at time t, which means, roughly, that 45 Wj, e, if is negatively correlated Wj goes up in the next instant, ceteris paribus agent agent i we perfectly, N first of security /, call and vice versa. them hedging securities. The (N+l)-th The above be termed the numeraire security. will the value of his optimal net trade to go down) like long-lived securities can hedge against the underlying uncertainty henceforth will would amount holds a negative Since the i long-lived security analysis then implies that agents hold hedging securities purely for hedging motives and use the numeraire security to transfer wealth across time. If we define the market portfolio to be the aggregate value of the market portfolio long-lived securities, then the value of the Our that long-lived securities are in zero net supply. zero throughout by the fact is results are thus largely consistent with previous characterizations of agents' optimal trading strategies stochastic dynamic programming: Agents, [34], Breeden may not be applicable. [4, 5]). In our present setting, can be applied in Even if Markovian stochastic dynamic programming our present setting, the number of hedging portfolios (securities) held may be substantially larger than TV. point will soon be clarified. In the above analysis we have characterized hedging properties of agents' optimal made trading strategies without the assumptions Assumptions 4.2.1, 4.2.2, as a function of Z{t) for agents' not, Merton Markovian stochastic dynamic programming by agents as characterized by dynamic programming If (cf. Neverthless, Proposition 5.1 illustrates the hedging properties of agents' optimal trading strategies. t portfolio, the Markov dynamic program agents' wealth, are sufficient statistics for agents' last market in equilibrium, hold the and portfolios most highly correlated with the variables which together with riskless asset, This made with Markovian and 4.2.3 We in Section 4.2. and ask the following question: Can and S(t)? (Equivalently, dynamic choice problems?) If is this now re-adopt will % $ (t) be written (Z(t), S(t)) a sufficient statistic at is true, what is the functional relation? what additional assumptions are required to develop such a relationship? proceeding, we take note is Before of the following fact. Proposition 5.2: Given Assumptions matrix, (Z,S) time 4.2.1, 4.2.2, and 4.2.3, and equals the identity a vector diffusion process. Proof: Since the identity matrix is certainly continuous 46 and satisfies Lipschitz and growth conditions, the assertion follows from the fact that rj{y, t) is Lipschilz and growth conditions, and from Proposition 4.2.2. Note that agent value at time t i's of e,(f). vector diffusion process. The T optimal net trade at time If e It i a contingent claim, with a meets the conditions of Proposition may then follow that $*(t) satisfies | itself is continuous and 4.2.4, then (Z,e*) is a a function of Z(t) and S(t) alone. is following proposition formalizes this. Proposition 5.3: Suppose there partial derivatives such that = £,-(u/) exists a 7r,(Z(u;, C2 T)) function a.s.. 7r,- : RN — R with bounded Then (W)H -(WM))H (5.3) uy (Z{t), t)l<7(Z(t), t) v (Z(t), t)6 y (Z(t), satisfies (4.2.1); v{y,t) are continuous in y and t; t/< RN X : exists; t) 6 2 (Z(t),t) 6(Z(t),t) where S(y,t) t)MZ(t), [0,T] and v(y,t) —R such that is satisfies D\v and D y v exist and the following partial differential equation and boundary condition: v\\i + Vi + -tr(i/ yj ,<7<7 T ) = 0, (5.4) lim i'(y,t) = (c (L{y))-ni(y))g(y), l t\T where as in Proposition 4.1.2, c s is L as in Assumption 4.2.2, and § As for ar,(w) is a C2 as in (4.2.4). the numeraire security, Proof: From Proposition function of X(w) with bounded almost surely a that ii(uj) is that = x^u))— e,(cj) C2 i,-(u;) is 4.1.2 we know that derivatives. for almost every Assumption u6[), 4.2.2 together with the assumption function of Z(u>, T) with bounded partial derivatives implies almost surely a C2 47 function of Z(ui,T) with bounded partial derivatives. Ignoring a null set we can write ti where jr, RN — R : C2 is = k{Z{T)), with bounded partial derivatives. By the definition of conditional expectation and arguments similar to those in Proposition 4.2.1, we have t\{i)=E\ti\7t ) = E(tji\7t) m v{Z(t),t) (5-5) . 6(Z(t),T) _ E(Cii) + /q v l where 6(y,t) y and t, v t satisfies (4.2.2), and v(y,t) exists, are diffusion processes. By + y (Z(s), 8)l(T(Z(8),s)dW(s) Ji6 y (Z(s),s)^(Z(s),s)dW(s) and v{y,t) is such that Lemma we D^is exist and are continuous in The numerator and satisfies (5.4). Ito's D y v, the denominator of (5.5) have: V "«*£**,) d#- ^dw- ^fdw^ 0' 0* dt _ «*l°f*,) dL i (56) b Substituting (4.2.5) into (5.6) yields where we recall that W is T , It is r't »-i f ( an F-adapted TV-dimensional Brownian motion under Q. Equivalently, »y(Z(t),tV<?(Z(t),t) now obvious that the row vector , (6 At)W_ 1 (v y (z(t),t)wz(t),t) „(Z(t),t)6 y (Z(t),tMZ(t),t) \„ ir ,,^ can be chosen to be i>(z(t),t)6 y (z(t),tMZ(t),ty 6 2 (Z(t),t) HZ(t),t) 48 ') or (5.3). 12 The characterization of follows from Step 3 in the proof of 6% +i Theorem 3.3.1. I Proposition 5.3 states that if agent then under the assumptions of Section dynamic choice problem only Z(t), S(t), and (This follows since When the t'-th depend on the That process. t, E at time t. 4.2, | T t ) is agent's time T endowment i's Z is A how this endowment, minimum x\, equals the over the interval [0, T]. positive may minimum of Z\.) {Z,S) forms a first T time T T endowments. One agent's time some state variable, say Z\, endowment equal agent's time above two statements are the conditions: (ii) not render past not destroy the Markovian nature of of value attained by The second agent has time and nonzerod, and may might come about. Imagine an economy with between some smooth function of Z(T) and the implicit in the $*(t) will, in general, Conversely, the fact that agents have two agents identical except that they have different time T be a function of (Z, S) forms a vector diffusion a vector diffusion process portfolio decisions. simple example illustrates will sufficient for his (cf. (5.5)).) S even when path-dependent optimal dynamic decision rules (Z,S). t not path-independent, is or t is statistic for the value of his net trade. a function of Z(t) and the fact that (Z,S) history irrelevant for agent path-independent and smooth, knowledge of (Z(t),S(t)) with Z(t) being a sufficient (e,- is His "indirect utility function" at historical realizations of is, endowment t's (i) to the difference T endowment. The minimum (Note that value of Z\ is aggregate endowments are strictly greater than the Thus the aggregate endowment at time T is path-independent, implying diffusion process (provided certain regularity conditions are satisfied). But, T in equilibrium, each agent must hedge against his or her time which varies ways that depend upon the entire path of Z\. Each consumes an amount in that depends on In our Z(T) only, but their net trades are endowment realization much more complex. exchange economy, aggregate endowments at time T are the essential deter- minants of asset price dynamics, rather than properties of agents' optimal portfolio Agents in the economy may all have path-dependent decision rules, but so long as Assumptions The dt X dP over this rules. / optimal trading strategies, (#')'_,, one for each agent, are unique over the measure (Chapter 5 of Liptser and Shiryayev [29]). But elements of a particular equivalence class measure may not be indistinguishable processes. 49 4.2.1, 4.2.2, and (Z,S) obeys the strong Markov property. 4.2.3 hold, Given Proposition 4.3.1, the following Proposition 5.4: Suppose that agent is t's easy to prove. time + iii(Z(t),t)dt+ ii { (Z(t),t)dt '0 Jo where M,(lM) and t; KN X : satisfy Lipschitz continuous for | a |< | where is x,(0), A'o, D Qy and -R [O.rj 2, £,• satisfies the Ito integral: rT rT x, = i,(0)+/ T endowment &i(Z(t),t)TdW(t), J Jo JO and a { {y,t) RN X : [0,T] -* and growth conditions; and D^fi^y, t) a.8., RN (5.7) are continuous in y and Dy&{(y,t) exist and are with ii t{y,t) | + | Day &i(y,t) K |< (l+ | y Kl | ). I « l< 2, Furthermore, suppose the process A'j are positive constants. (i,(<), t G defined by = i,(0) + £,-(*) Then ! [0,T]} (f) is / Jo fi i (Z(8),s)da+ I bi(Z(8),8)UW{s) a.s. can be written as a function of Z{t), S(t), and £,(*), and {(Z(t),S(t),Xi(t)),t When agent t's time to those of Propositions 4.3.1 T endowment is decision rule can be revived by augmenting that case, agent t's j's and (Z,S) with the process defined is a function of Z(t), S(t), and dynamic choice at that time. is important | in the price in (5.8). In which &i(t), Using the traditional characterization of equilibrium asset prices and optimal portfolio rules, concluded that the x^t) 5.3. well-behaved, the path-independence of his indirect utility for net trade are sufficient statistics for agent 1 E a diffusion process. Proof: The arguments are similar N+ (5.8) Jo we would have formation process, and that agent i faces sources of uncertainty to hedge against. In this section, we have characterized properties of agents' optimal portfolio rules in an equilibrium setting, primarily using martingale representation techniques. Some results have been derived in an environment where Markovian dynamic programming cannot be 50 [0, T}} applied. Even when Markovian dynamic programming order optimality conditions first Kreps [26], may "is management problem". The martingale connection theorists. makes [20] applicable, not give the right answer. that the stochastic control machinery by Harrison and Kreps is We summing up agents' contend, along with not really necessary in the portfolio of equilibrium asset prices developed available a rich theory of martingales to financial The martingale representation technique demonstrated an alternative to stochastic control, as suggested by Cox [9], in this section is not only but also a more powerful one, especially in an equilibrium setting. Concluding remarks 6. This paper addresses three in issues: First, can we prove the existence of an equilibrium a Merton/Breeden-like continuous-trading economy? Second, under what conditions do the vector price process and the vector state variable process together form a vector diffusion process? Third, is dynamic programming an appropriate agents' optimal portfolio rules in an equilibrium setting? two questions. With respect to the third one, it is tool in characterizing Answers are provided for the first argued that martingale representation techniques might be more powerful. Dynamic programming has not yet been shown to yield a consistent characterization of heterogeneous-agent equilibrium asset prices. our work that dynamic programming The economy considered in this is seems from It indeed an inappropriate tool for this problem. paper agents consume only at two time points. is a continuous time Radner economy in which Questions related to the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model, such as whether agents would optimally choose their consumption rates to be Ito integrals addressed here. asset prices When is When totally when information there is is generated by diffusion process, cannot be no intermediate consumption, the behavior of equilibrium determined by the arrival of information agents are allowed to consume continuously, it (cf. ourprev by how agents choose to consume over time and by the way information This ongoing research of the authors. 51 om c»ay ). seems that prices would be determined jointly is i is revealed. References 1. L. ARNOLD, Stochastic Differential & Sons, New York, 1974. 2. K. ARROW, The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk-bearing, Economic Studies 31 3. J. BlSMUT, "Theorie Probabiliste du Control des Diffusions," Volume 4, Number 167. Society, In , , Memoirs of The 1976. BREEDEN, An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities, Journal of Financial Economics 7 (1979), 265-296. D. "Futures markets and commodity options: Hedging and optimality incomplete markets," forthcoming in Journal of Economic Theory, 1983. 5. 6. Review of (1964), 91-96. American Mathematical 4. Equations: Theory and Applications, John Wiley , CHUNG, A K. Course in Probability Academic Theory, 2nd ed. New Press, in York, 1974. New -, Lectures From Markov Processes to Brownian Motion, Springer- Verlag: York, Heidelberg, Berlin, 1982. 8. G. CONSTANTINIDES, 9. J. COX, "Optimal consumption and Intertemporal asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers and without demand aggregation, Journal of Business 55 (1982), 253-267. diffusion process," University, 10. J. COX, J. May when portfolio policies Working Paper 658, Graduate School asset returns follow of Business, a Stanford 1983. INGERSOLL, AND S. Ross, "A rational anticipations intertemporal asset pricing theory," forthcoming in Econometrica, 1983. 11. G. DEBREU, Theory of Value, Cowles Foundation Monograph New Haven and London, 1959. 17, Yale University Press, 12. C. DELLACHERIE AND P. MEYER, Probabilities North-Holland Publishing Company, 13. D. New and Potential B: Theory of Martingales, York, 1982. DUFFIE AND C. HUANG, "Implementing Arrow-Debreu equilibria by continuous trading of few long lived securities," Working Paper Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, February 1983. , 14. A. FRIEDMAN, Stochastic Differential Equations and New Yoik, San Francisco, London, 1975. Press: 52 Applications, Vol I, Academic 15. M. FUJISAKI, G. KALL1ANPUR for the 16. I. non GlHMAN AND New AND SKOROHOD, A. H. KUNITA, Stochastic differential equations Osaka Journal of Mathematics linear filtering problem, (1972), 19-40. Stochastic Differential Equations, Springer- Verlag: York, Heidelberg, Berlin, 1972. 17. I. GlRSANOV, On 18. S. GROSSMAN AND transforming a certain class of stochastic processes by absolutely continuous substitution of measures, Theory of Probability and Its Applications 5 (1960), 285-301. R. SHILLER, Consumption correlated ness and risk measurement economies with non-traded assets and heterogeneous information, Journal of Financial Economics 10 (1982), 195-210. in 19. J. HARRISON, "Stochastic calculus and its applications," Lecture Notes, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, 1982. 20. J. 21. J. HARRISON AND D. KREPS, Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets, Journal of Economic Theory 20 (1979), 381-408. HARRISON AND S. PLISKA, Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory and Their Applications 11 (1981), 215— of continuous trading, Stochastic Processes 260. 22. M. HESTENES, Optimization Theory: The Finite Dimensional Case, John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1975. 23. R. HOLMES, Geometric New York, 1975. 24. C. HUANG, Essays of Financial Economics, Stanford University, 1983. 25. D. KREPS, "Three Functional Analysis and PhD Its Applications, Springer- Verlag, Thesis, Graduate School of Business, essays on capital markets," Technical Report 298, Institute for Mathematical Studies in The Social Sciences, Stanford University, Arbitrage and equilibrium in economies with infinitely Journal of Mathematical Economics 8 (1981), 15-35. 26. , 27. , 1979. many commodities, "Multiperiod securities and the efficient allocation of risk: a comment on the Black-Scholes option pricing model," In J. McCall, The Economics of Uncertainty and Information. University of Chicago Press, 1982. 28. H. KUNITA AND S. WATANABE, On square-integrable martingales, Nagoya Mathematics Journal 30(1967), 209-245. 29. R. LlPTSER AND A. SHIRYAYEV, Statistics of Random Processes Springer-Verlag, New York, 1977. 53 I: General Theory, MAS-COLELL, "The price equilibrium existence problem Harvard University (mimeo), 1983. 30. A. 31. JEAN MEMIN, R. MERTON, case, Banach Lattices," Espaces de semi-martingale et changement de probabilite, Zeitschrift fur Wahrscheialichkeitstheorie 32. in 52 (1980), 9-39. Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous time Statistics 51 (1969), 247-257. Review of Economics and 33. , Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous time model, Journal of Economic Theory 3 (1971), 373-413. 34. , An intertemporal capital asset pricing model, Econometrica 41 (1973), 867-888. 35. P. MEYER, Probability and Potentials, Blaisdell Publishing Company, Waltham, Mass.., 1966. 36. E. PRESCOTT AND R. MEHRA, Recursive competitive equilibrium: (1980), 1365-1979. The case of homogeneous households, Econometrica 48 37. R. 38. D. RADNER, Existence of equilibrium of plans, prices and price expectations in a sequence of markets, Econometrica 40 (1972), 289-303. WILLIAMS, Diffusions, Markov Processes and Martingales, York, 1979. 54 Vol. 1, Wiley, New I* 2 2 I • - 3 TDflO DOM 462 32b Date Due L Lib-26-t;'; '****, <§0K Co^ '% (V «r