The Elephant in the Room: the Impact of Labor Obligations on Credit Risk∗ Jack Favilukis† Xiaoji Lin‡ Xiaofei Zhao§ September 28, 2015 Abstract We study the impact of labor market frictions on credit risk. Our central finding is that labor market variables are the first-order effect in driving both of the aggregate time series and the cross sectional variations of credit risk. Recent studies have highlighted a link between credit risk and macroeconomic/firm-level variables such as investment growth, financial leverage, volatility, etc. We show that labor market variables (wage growth or labor share) can forecast the aggregate credit spread as well as or better than alternative predictors. Furthermore, firm-level labor expense growth rates and labor share can predict Moody-KMV expected default frequency (EDF) in the cross-section across a wide range of countries. A model with wage rigidity and endogenous long-term defaultable debt can explain these links as well as produce large credit spreads despite realistically low default probabilities. This is because pre-committed payments to labor make other committed payments (such as debt) riskier; for this reason variables related to pre-committed labor payments have explanatory power for credit risk. JEL classification: E23, E44, G12 Keywords: Wage rigidity, long-term debt, credit risk, labor market frictions, labor leverage, financial leverage, wage growth, labor share ∗ First draft: November 2013. We thank Frederico Belo, Murillo Campello, Murray Carlson, Sergey Chernenko, Andres Donangelo, Andrea Eisfeldt, Isil Erel, Bob Goldstein, Philippe Mueller, Christopher Polk, René Stulz, Eric Swanson, Sheridan Titman, Andrea Vedolin, Mike Weisbach, and Lu Zhang for helpful comments. All errors are our own. † Finance Division, University of British Columbia, 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC, V6T 1Z2, Canada. Tel: 604-822-9414 and E-mail: jack.favilukis@sauder.ubc.ca ‡ Department of Finance, Ohio State University, 2100 Neil Ave, 846 Fisher Hall, Columbus, OH 43210. Tel: 614-292-4318 and E-mail: lin.1376@osu.edu § Jindal School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, 800 West Campbell Road, SM 31, Richardson, TX 75080. Tel: 972-883-5971 and E-mail: xiaofei.zhao@utdallas.edu 1 1 Introduction We study the impact of labor market frictions on credit risk. Our central finding is that labor market variables are the first-order effect in driving both of the time series and the cross section of variations in credit risk. When wages are rigid, the operating leverage effect caused by smooth wages increases firms’ default risk because precommitted wage payments make debt payment riskier. Consistent with this view, we show that labor market variables (wage growth and labor share) which capture the strength of operating leverage when wages are sticky, significantly forecast the aggregate Baa-Aaa credit spread in the U.S. More specifically, a 1 percentage point increase in the wage growth (labor share) is associated with a decrease (increase) of 15 (11) basis points in credit spread. The predictability of labor market variables is stronger than or comparable to the standard credit risk predictors including market volatility, term spread, financial leverage, etc. For example, the adjusted R2 of wage growth in predicting credit spread is 28%, substantially larger than that of market volatility (22%) and term spread (2%) and is close to that of financial leverage (37%). Furthermore, wage growth drives out the predictability of real variables including investment growth, a key variable used in the recent investment-based models to link credit risk to the real economy. In the cross section, we show that firm-level labor market variables are important predictors of credit risk measured by the Moody-KMV expected default frequency (EDF) across a wide range of countries, including U.S., Canada, and major European and Asian Pacific countries. Controlling for variables that are known to have explanatory power for firmlevel credit risk, labor expense growth rate and labor share remain strong factors in explaining the cross sectional variations of future EDFs. More specifically, firms with higher labor expense growth rates (higher labor share) are associated with lower (higher) future EDFs. These relations are stronger for firms with measures of higher wage rigidity, implying wage rigidity is a key driving force of the result. Taken together, our results suggest the crucial role of labor market variables as the key determinants of both the aggregate and the cross sectional variations of credit risk. To understand the link between labor market and credit risk, we propose a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with heterogeneous firms. Different from the standard models, in our model the labor market is not frictionless, rather wages are rigid. More specifically, wage contracts are staggered, which prevent firms from immediately adjusting their labor expenses in response to new shocks. Sticky wages capture the fact that wages are smoother than output and are imperfectly correlated with output in the data. On the financing side, firms issue longterm debt to finance investment and labor expenses. In particular, firms only issue new debt infrequently before the existing debt matures, making debt payment sticky and hence firms’ cash flow extra risky. In the model, the predictability of labor market variables for the credit spread arises 2 endogenously due to the interaction between operating leverage and financial leverage. In economic downturns, productivity and output fall by more than wages, causing an increase in labor leverage. High expected payments to labor make equity more likely to default in bad times, especially when the wage bill is relatively high. Thus, the model implies that labor share (positively) and wage growth (negatively) are natural predictors of credit risk. More specifically, in the model firms default if the realized firm value is below zero. This occurs if the firm’s idiosyncratic productivity is below a cutoff value, which itself depends on the state of the economy. In economic downturns, profit falls more than output, which makes it harder for firms to pay off precommitted debt payment. This raises the default threshold of idiosyncratic productivity, which in turn increases the default probability and the credit risk premium. Thus the model produces large credit spreads despite realistically low default probabilities, providing a novel explanation for the credit spread puzzle. Furthermore, wage growth negatively whereas labor share positively predicts credit spread because times of low wage growth or high labor share are associated with high operating leverage and hence high credit risk premium. The model endogenously generates time-variations in credit spread. This intuition is consistent with anecdotal evidence. For example, regarding the bankruptcy of American Airlines in 2012, the Wall Street Journal writes “Bankruptcy seems to be helping American do what practically every other bankrupt airline has done – reduce its labor costs to competitive levels. Those costs are ... the highest of any major airline operating in the U.S. today. American spends $600 million more on wages than its peers.” 1 American’s CEO Thomas W. Horton said “Achieving the competitive cost structure we need remains a key imperative in this process, and as one part of that, we plan to initiate further negotiations with all of our unions to reduce our labor costs to competitive levels.” Similarly, regarding the bankruptcy of United in 2002, a UBS analyst said “Excess debt, burdensome labor contracts, expensive pension obligations... are all high on the list of what ails airlines. Bankruptcy can certainly address these other issues.” 2 The model is calibrated to match aggregate-level and firm-level real quantity moments. The model generates a sizable aggregate credit spread and a low aggregate default probability consistent with the data. Most important, the model with wage rigidity and long-term debt successfully replicates the predictability of wage growth and labor share for the credit spread observed in the data. Taken together, our results show that labor market frictions have significant impact for credit risk. In addition to successfully replicating the observed predictability in credit spread, the model also produces a sizable equity premium and equity volatility consistent with the data (the mechanism is similar to Favilukis and Lin 2015a). Thus the model with wage rigidity and corporate debt provides a coherent explanation for the two major asset pricing puzzles in a unified 1 James K. Glassman, Wall Street Journal Op/Ed, October 16, 2012, ”Once It Emerges From Bankruptcy, Let American Airlines Stay American.” 2 Sam Buttrick in interview to CNNMoney, December 9, 2002 ”United hits turbulance of bankruptcy.” 3 framework–the equity premium puzzle and the credit spread puzzle. Related literature: While the macroeconomic literature on wages and labor is quite large (e.g., Pissarides 1979, Calvo 1982, Taylor 1983, Taylor 1999, Shimer 2005, Hall 2006, Gertler and Trigari 2009), there has been little work done relating labor market frictions to credit risk. Notable exceptions include Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (2012) who show credit spread predicts future movement in unemployment rate. We integrate labor market frictions with credit risk. In particular, our paper differs from these macro papers in that we study implications of staggered wage setting on corporate bond pricing, while the models in labor economics fail to match the asset prices observed in the data; this is a problem endemic to most standard models. The literature of structural models on credit risk highlights the roles of financial leverage, asset volatility, and macroeconomic risk as the key determinants of credit spread (e.g., CollinDufresne and Goldstein 2001; Hackbarth, Miao and Morellec 2006; Chen, Collin-Dufresne, and Goldstein 2009; Chen 2010). We are complementary to these work by endogenizing cash flows through firms’ investment, hiring/firing, and financing decisions. More importantly, as is shown in Favilukis and Lin (2015a, b), wage rigidity is crucial to match cash flow dynamics in DSGE models, thus our paper makes structural models of credit risk viable in a production economy. Some recent investment-based models attempt to link credit risk to firms’ real investment decisions. In particular, Gomes and Schmid (2010) explore the propagation mechanism of movements in bond markets into the real economy. Gourio (2013) studies the impact of disaster risk on credit risk in a DSGE model. Kuehn and Schmid (2013) study the interaction between investment and credit spread. Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajsek (2014) study the relations between uncertainty, investment, and credit risk in a DSGE model. Bai (2015) explores the link between unemployment and credit risk. We are different from these papers by explicitly modelling the interactions between staggered wage contract and corporate debt pricing. Our empirical findings relate to the empirical literature on the determinants of credit spread. Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin (2001) show that standard credit spread forecasters have rather limited explanatory power. Elton et al (2001) find that expected default accounts for a small fraction of the credit risk premium. We show that labor market variables, in particular, wage growth, have as strong explanatory power as financial leverage and stock market volatility in predicting the Baa-Aaa spread and the cross sectional variations in firms’ EDFs. Our findings suggest that exploring the link between labor market frictions and credit risk can shed light to the empirical puzzle documented in Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin (2001). Our paper also relates to the recent literature exploring the relations between labor frictions and equity returns. Belo, Lin, and Bazdresch (2013) study the impact of labor frictions on the relationship between hiring rates and the cross section of returns. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2013) explore how search frictions in the style of Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) affect 4 asset pricing in a general equilibrium setting with production. Gomes, Jermann, and Schmid (2013) study the rigidity of nominal debt which creates long term leverage that works in a similar way to our labor leverage. We differ in that we explicitly study credit risk and wage rigidity. 2 Empirical Evidence In this section we explore the explanatory power of labor market variables (wage growth and labor share) for credit risk both in the time series U.S. aggregate data and the firm-level data cross a wide range of countries. 2.1 Time Series Analysis We first describe the data, then the empirical specifications and the results. 2.1.1 Data and Variable Definitions Credit spread We use the Moody’s Baa corporate bond yield in excess of Aaa corporate bond yield from the Federal Reserve. As in Chen, Collin-Dufresne, and Goldstein (2009), the Baa-Aaa spread should be mostly due to credit risk, assuming that the component of the credit spread due to taxes, call/put/conversion options and the lack of liquidity in the corporate bond markets, is of similar magnitude for Aaa and Baa bonds. Wage growth We use the growth rate in the real wages and salaries per full-time equivalent employee from NIPA table 6.6. Labor share Labor share is the ratio of aggregate compensation of employees to GDP. Controls The empirical finance literature has uncovered a list of variables that forecast credit spread. We measure financial leverage as the book value of credit market instruments of nonfinancial business sector divided by the sum of the market value of equity in the nonfinancial corporate business sector and the credit market instruments from the Flow of Funds Accounts. Stock market volatility is the annualized volatility of monthly CRSP stock market returns in excess of riskfree rate. Term spread is the difference between the ten-year Treasury bond yield and the three-month Treasury bill yield from the Federal Reserve. Spot rate is the one-year Treasure bill rate. Our sample is from 1948 to 2014.3 Panel A in Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics for the variables mentioned above. Credit spread has an annual mean of 95 basis points and a volatility of 40 basis points. It has a first3 We start in 1948 because financial leverage from Flow of Funds is available after 1946. We do not start in 1946 to avoid the influence of the WWII on our results. However, the predictability of wage growth for credit spread holds in a longer sample starting from 1929. 5 order autocorrelation at 0.74, suggesting that credit spread is persistent. Wage growth has mean of 1.5% and a standard deviation of 1.4%. It has a first-order autocorrelation at 0.47, less persistent than credit spread. Labor share has a mean and standard deviation at 0.55 and 1.2%, respectively. Investment growth has a volatility of 6.3%. Turning to financial variables, the mean, volatility and persistence of price-to-earnings ratio, term spread and spot rate are consistent with the estimate in the literature. Financial leverage is persistent with an autocorrelation at 0.88. Panel B in Table 1 presents the correlations of all variables of interest with real GDP growth, and their cross correlations. Credit spread has a correlation with GDP growth at −0.51, suggesting that it is countercyclical. Wage growth and investment growth are procyclical with correlations with GDP growth at 0.41 and 0.76, respectively; both of them negatively correlate with credit spread with correlations at -0.42 and -0.49, respectively. But wage growth is only mildly positively correlated with investment growth at 0.2. This implies that wage growth contains different information than investment growth in explaining credit spread even though all of them negatively correlate with credit spread. Both labor share and financial leverage are negatively correlated with GDP growth with correlations at -0.14 and -0.01, respectively; however labor share and financial leverage themselves are weakly correlated at 0.25, suggesting they contain different information despite both being countercyclical. Consistent with the existing literature, credit spread is positively correlated with financial leverage, market volatility, and the term spread. It is also evident in Figure 1 that credit spread is highly countercyclical and moves in the opposite direction to the wage growth, while labor share somewhat leads credit spread but moves in the same direction as credit spread. 2.1.2 Empirical Specifications and Results In this subsection, we explore the predictability of wage growth and labor share for credit spread in three steps. All regressions are at an annual frequency. First, we run univariate regressions of one year ahead credit spread, CSt+1 , on current wage growth, ∆Wt , labor share, LSt at year t; second, we run horse race regressions of either wage growth or labor share with a control one at a time; thirdly, we conduct a multivariate regression with all the predictors at the right hand side including lagged credit spread which controls for the persistency in credit spread. Univariate regressions Specification 1 in panels A and B in Table 2 reports the univariate regression results. Wage growth negatively forecasts credit spread with a slope coefficient at −15.4 which is more than 4 standard deviations away from zero. Furthermore, the adjusted R2 is 0.28, which is significantly larger than that implied by market volatility (0.22) and slightly smaller than that of financial leverage (0.37), suggesting that the explanatory power of wage growth is as strong as the conventional predictors (Univariate results for other controls are not tabulated but are available upon request). Labor share positively predicts credit spread with the slope coefficient 6 of 10.66 which is more than 2 standard deviations away from zero. 4 Horse race regressions Specifications 2 to 8 in panels A and specifications 2 to 7 of panel B in Table 2 present the horse race regression results of wage growth and labor share with a control one at a time. Wage growth remains statistically significant in predicting credit spread after controlling for all other predictors including financial leverage, market volatility, price-to-earnings, and term premium. Furthermore, investment growth even turns insignificant (specification 3). This is perhaps surprising given that the recent literature has emphasized the role of investment in driving credit spread, however our result shows that wage growth drives out the predictive power of investment growth, thus wage growth is more informative in explaining the movement of credit spread than investment. Similarly, labor share remains significant at 5% significance level with other controls at the right hand side. Multivariate regressions Specification 9 in panel A and specification 8 in panel B present the multivariate kitchen sink regression for wage growth and labor share that includes all controls, respectively. In these regressions, the adjusted R2 is above 0.73; recall that wage growth alone attains an R2 of 0.28. Wage growth remains significant after controlling for all variables; however labor share is no longer significant due to high correlation with lagged credit spread. Given that there are 10 regressors and 66 years of annual observations, this regression may very well be overfitted. 2.2 Cross Sectional Analysis We describe the firm-level international data first, and then the cross-sectional regression results. 2.2.1 Data Our accounting data come from Compustat North America (for U.S. and Canadian firms) and Compustat Global (for firms from other countries) Fundamentals Annual files. Similarly, the security data come from CRSP and Compustat Global Security Daily respectively. We use MoodyKMV’s Expected Default Frequency (EDF) data to measure the default probability for global firms from 1992 to 2011, which is also the sample period for most of our firm-level analysis. In Table 3, we report the number and percentage of annual (firm-year) observations that have non-missing labor expenses (Compustat variable XLR), hiring (Compustat EMP), and EDF for each of the thirty-nine countries. We follow Gao, Parsons, and Shen (2013) to filter out outliers 4 As for the controls in the univariate regressions which are tabulated here, investment growth negatively forecasts credit spread, but the adjusted R2 is only 0.03, far below the adjusted R2 implied by wage growth (it is also smaller than the adjusted R2 implied by labor share at 0.09). Both financial leverage and stock market volatility positively predict credit spread, consistent with Collin-Dufrene, Goldstein, and Martin (2001). However, price-to-earnings ratio, term spread, and spot rate do not significantly predict credit spread. 7 and categorize the countries into seven different regions. First of all, we can see that for the US, only 7% (= 9588/135632) of observations have non-missing labor expenses. If we further require non-missing hiring and EDF data, this percentage drops to 3.5%. Therefore, the sample with labor expenses based on US firms is quite small and it is difficult to make a general conclusion from an exercise based on US only sample. This is the main reason that we expand our scope to global firms for our firm-level analysis. Once we gather data from other countries, we can see a lot of them in fact have decent coverage of labor expenses, especially European countries. Japan is an exception — only 2 annual observations with XLR available — therefore our analysis does not include Japan. Table 4 reports the summary statistics (mean and standard deviation) for our main variables of interest: EDF , ∆XLR, and LS, where ∆XLRt = (XLRt − XLRt−1 )/XLRt−1 is the labor expenses growth rate from year t − 1 to year t and LSt = XLRt /Salet measures the labor share at year t using the ratio of labor expenses to sales. As we can see from Table 4, both ∆XLR and LS show quite a bit of variation across regions. In general, developed countries have higher labor share and lower labor expenses growth whereas developing countries have lower labor share and higher labor expenses growth.5 2.2.2 Empirical Findings Before conducting the empirical analysis, it is worth discussing the measure of labor expenses XLR. According to its definition from WRDS, this item is a supplementary Income Statement item (i.e., not a standardized item) and may include other expenses beyond wages and salaries (such as incentive compensations). Moreover, due to the supplementary nature of this variable, firms could choose to report different components in different years. However, this is the accounting variable that is most closely related to wages and salaries. Therefore, we work with this measure but impose a filter to make sure that we use observations with consistent labor expenses number. More specifically, we identify a firm-year observation as an outlier and exclude it from the crosssectional analysis if the growth rate of labor expenses per employee (XLR/EM P ) is outside the range of (−50%, 300%).6 In other words, if the annual labor expenses per employee growth rate is beyond 300% or less than −50%, it is likely that either the firm has reported a labor expense number with components different from previous year or it may simply be a data error. In this sense, the filter is very similar to the one used by Hou, Karolyi, and Kho (2011) when they filter 5 Both ∆XLR and LS are winsorized at 1% and 99% percentiles. The mean values of un-winsorized variables are much higher — an indication of outliers in labor expenses. 6 The reason we use labor expenses per employee but not total labor expenses for the filtering purpose is because it is much more difficult to judge whether changes in total labor expenses contain an error by just examining its magnitude. However, the labor expenses per employee should be much more stable and a dramatic change is likely to be an outlier. 8 out outliers in monthly stock returns in international data. To understand the impact of labor expenses on default risk, we first conduct firm-level timeseries analysis. This is accomplished by calculating the correlation between ∆XLR and EDF (Corr(∆XLR, EDF )) for each individual company using its time-series observations. Then we present the distribution of this correlation at country and aggregate level in Table 5. The summary statistics reported include mean, standard deviation, number of firms, and t-statistic corresponding to test H0 : Corr(∆XLR, EDF ) = 0. We also calculate the correlation between LS and EDF for each firm and report the corresponding summary statistics on Corr(LS, EDF ) in Table 5. The average value of Corr(∆XLR, EDF ) is -0.19 for all countries (12,280 firms together) with a t-stat of -39.89. This suggests that a decrease in labor expenses is associated with higher default risk. It is quite strong and robust across countries (statistically significant for 30 countries and those insignificant ones have very small number of firms in the sample). The average value of Corr(LS, EDF ) is 0.11 for all countries (12,004 firms together) with a t-stat of 21.29. This indicates that an increase in labor share is associated with higher default risk. The average value of this correlation is also positive and statistically significant for the majority of the countries (though the pattern is weaker than that of Corr(∆XLR, EDF )). These two time-series correlations strongly support that labor obligations are very important determinants of credit risk. Next, we use Fama-MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions to analyze the predictability of labor obligations on credit risk by controlling for a list of well-known determinants of credit and distress risk. We regress default risk measure in year t + 1 on labor expenses growth and labor share in year t, controlling for other firm-characteristics. For example, when we use labor expenses growth (or labor share) as a determinant for default risk, we run the following crosssectional regression EDFi,t+1 = a + b × ∆XLRit (or LSit ) + b1 × Xit + it , (1) where Xit is a vector of determinants for default and distress risk used by previous studies such as Altman (1968), Zmijewski (1984), Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin (2001), Shumway (2001), Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008), among others. Specifically, we control for the following firm characteristics in year t: leverage, stock return volatility, working capital, retained earnings, EBIT, sales, net income, current asset to liability ratio, investments, relative firm size, market capitalization. We also control for individual firm’s stock excess return and the market return for its country in year t. Detailed descriptions of these variable constructions are provided in the appendix. To further understand the impact of labor expense rigidity on the marginal effect of labor expenses growth on default risk, we also create a measure for labor expense rigidity. We calculate the volatility of labor expenses growth rate (V ol(∆XLR)) for each firm using its 9 time-series observations. Then we define a variable Rigid and set Rigid = 1 if V ol(∆XLR) is below its 25% percentile in its country, otherwise we set Rigid = 0. We then interact Rigid with ∆XLR and rerun the above regression with this additional interaction term. The regression results are reported in Table 6. Panel A presents the results based on ∆XLR. The results in columns (1)-(6) are based on all countries; in columns (7)-(8) are based on European countries; in columns (9)-(10) are based on other countries. As expected, the coefficient associated with ∆XLR is negative and highly statistically significant. For example, in column (6) when we include all control variables, the coefficient estimate for ∆XLR is -0.85 with a t-stat of -12.87. This is consistent with the conclusion from our time-series analysis in Table 5: a decrease in labor expenses predicts a higher default risk, and this effect is beyond the traditional firm characteristics in existing literature. In the same column, the coefficient estimate associated with Rigid × ∆XLR is -1.24 with a t-stat of -3.99. This suggests that firms with rigid labor expense would experience a much larger increase in default risk for the same percentage decrease in labor expenses, all else being equal. The results are robust and qualitatively similar for European and non-European countries. Panel B presents the results based on LS. To capture a sudden change in labor share (in particular sudden increases in labor share due to drops in sales), we create a dummy variable LSIncrease for each firm-year observation. It is set to equal to 1 if it is above the 75th percentile of labor share changes in its country year, and 0 otherwise. We then interact the labor share with this dummy variable in our analysis. As we can see from Panel B, the coefficient estimates for LS and LSIncrease × LS are both positive when there are no control variables or when we control for leverage and stock return volatility, suggesting an increase in labor share predicts higher default risk and this increase is much bigger for firms with sudden rapid increase in labor share. However, when we control for all the other variables, the LS becomes insignificant, potentially because the control variables absorb the profitability shocks that affect labor share. However, the coefficient on LSIncrease × LS still remains positive and statistically significant, reflecting the effects of wage rigidity and labor adjustments costs that are not absorbed by the other control variables. The impact of labor obligations on credit risk is likely to be higher when a firm is experiencing distress and needs to cut down labor expenses. To test whether labor expense cut plays an important role in the relation between labor obligations and default risk, we create a variable XLRCut which takes the value of 1 if the firm’s ∆XLR is below the 25% percentile of ∆XLR in its country, and 0 otherwise. Then we interact XLRCut with ∆XLR and LS and rerun the crosssectional predictive regressions as in Table 6. The results are reported in Table 7. From column (2) of the table we can see that the coefficient estimate associated with XLRCut × ∆XLR is -3.51 with a t-stat of -7.77, suggesting that the impact of labor expenses growth on default risk is highly asymmetric — labor expense cut plays a main role in the negative relation between ∆XLR 10 and default risk. If we move to column (4), we can see the coefficient estimate associated with XLRCut × LS is 2.12 with a t-stat of 14.7. This again suggests that the impact of labor share on default risk is mainly from labor expenses cutting. 3 Model In this section, we present a dynamic general equilibrium model with heterogenous firms to understand the economic mechanism that drives the empirical links between labor market variables and firms’ credit risk. We begin with the household’s problem. We then outline the firm’s problem, the economy’s key frictions are described there. Finally we define equilibrium. In the model financial markets are complete, therefore we consider one representative household who receives labor income and financial income, chooses between consumption and saving, and maximizes utility as in Epstein and Zin (1989). 11 1− 1 1 1− ψ 1− ψ ψ 1−θ 1−θ + βEt [Ut+1 ] Ut = max (1 − β)Ct (2) where Ct is average consumption and β is subjective discount factor. For simplicity, we assume that aggregate labor supply is inelastic: Nt = 1. Risk aversion is given by θ and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution by ψ. 3.1 Firms The interesting frictions in the model are on the firm’s side. We assume a large number of firms (indexed by i and differing in idiosyncratic productivity) choose investment, labor, and debt to maximize the present value of future dividend payments where the dividend payments are equal to the firm’s after-tax profit (output net of wage bills, operating costs, and debt payment) net of investment plus new issuance of debt. Output is produced from labor and capital. Firms hold beliefs about the discount factor Mt+1 , which is determined in equilibrium. 3.1.1 Technology Firm i’s output is given by Yti = Zti α(Kti )η + (1 − α)(Xt Nti )ηρ 11 η1 . (3) Output is produced with CES technology from capital (Kti ) and labor (Nti ) where Xt is labor augmenting aggregate productivity, Zti is the firm’s idiosyncratic productivity, ρ determines the 1 degree of return to scale (constant return to scale if ρ = 1), 1−η is the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor (Cobb-Douglas production if η = 0), and (1 − α)ρ is labor share in production. The process for Xt is non-stationary but its growth rate is stationary, this is in the spirit of the exogenous shock process in long run risk models of Bansal and Yaron (2004), Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (2010), and Croce (2014). We specify the growth rate of aggregate productivity (∆ log Xt+1 ) to be the following ∆ log Xt+1 = (1 − ρX ) µX + ρX ∆ log Xt + X t+1 , (4) which is consistent with long run risk. ∆ is the first-difference operator, X t+1 is an independently and identically distributed (i.i.d.) standard normal shock, and µX and ρX are the average growth rate and autocorrelation of the growth rate of aggregate productivity, respectively. Idiosyncratic productivity log Zti follow an AR(1) process i log Zt+1 = ρZ log Zti + Zt+1 , (5) where Zt+1 is an i.i.d. standard normal shock that is uncorrelated across all firms in the economy and independent of X t+1 , and ρZ is the autocorrelation of idiosyncratic productivity. 3.1.2 The Wage Contract The wage contract here builds on Favilukis and Lin (2015a). In standard production models wages are reset each period and employees receive the marginal product of labor. We assume that any employee’s wage will be reset this period with probability 1 − µ.7 When µ = 0 our model is identical to models without rigidity: all wages are reset each period, each firm can freely choose the number of its employees, and each firm chooses Nti such that its marginal product of labor is equal to the wage. When µ > 0 we must differentiate between the spot wage (wt ) which is paid to all employees resetting wages this year, the economy’s average wage (wt ), and the firm’s average wage (wit ). The firm’s choice of employees may no longer make the marginal product equal to either average or spot wages because firms will also take into account the effect of today’s labor choice and today’s wage on future obligations. 7 Note that this is independent of length of employment. This allows us to keep track of only the number of employees and the average wage as state variables, as opposed to keeping track of the number of employees and the wage of each tenure. This way of modeling wage rigidity is similar in spirit to Gertler and Trigari (2009), but for tractability reasons, we do not model search and match frictions. 12 When a firm hires a new employee in a year with spot wage wt , with probability µ it must pay this employee the same wage next year; on average this employee will keep the same wage for 1 1−µ years. All resetting employees come to the same labor market and the spot wage is selected to clear markets. The firm chooses its total labor force Nti each period. These conditions lead to a natural formulation of the firm’s average wage as the weighted average of the previous average wage and the spot wage: i i ) + wit−1 µNt−1 wit Nti = wt (Nti − µNt−1 (6) i i Here Nti − µNt−1 is the number of new employees the firm hires at the spot wage and µNt−1 is the number of tenured employees with average wage wit−1 .8 Note that the rigidity in our model is a real wage rigidity, although our channel could in principle work through nominal rigidities as well. There is evidence for the importance of both real and nominal rigidities. Micro-level studies of panel data sets comparing actual and notional wage distributions show that nominal wage changes cluster both at zero and at the current inflation rate, with sharp decreases in the density to the left of the two mass points. Barwell and Schweitzer (2007), Devicenti, Maida and Sestito (2007), and Bauer, Goette and Sunde (2007) find that downward real wage rigidity is substantial in Great Britain, Germany, and Italy, and that the fraction of real wage cuts prevented by downward real wage rigidity is more than five times greater than the fraction prevented by downward nominal wage rigidity. In a recent international wage flexibility study, Dickens, Goette, and Groshen (2007) find that the relative importance of downward real wage rigidity and downward nominal wage rigidity varies greatly across countries while the incidences of both types of wage rigidity are about the same. 3.1.3 The debt contract The firm uses long-term defaultable debt to finance investment and wage bills. More specifically, in each period the firm chooses to issue a level of new coupon payment κit+1 for next period. The firm may only issue κit+1 if it is currently debt free, i.e., κit = 0. If the firm currently has outstanding debt, i.e., the current coupon κit is above zero, then the firm will not change its coupon payment (κit =κit+1 ), in other words the firm will not issue new debt, unless one of the following two conditions occur: i) Debt randomly expires between t and t+1, which happens with probability pexp , ii) The firm chooses to default at the start of t+1. A firm’s debt cannot expire before it has paid its first coupon payment. The probability of debt expiration also determines 8 i i cannot be interpreted as tenured employees. In this case It is possible that Nti < µNt−1 , in which case µNt−1 we would interpret the total wage bill as including payments to prematurely laid-off employees. Note that the wage i bill can be rewritten as wit Nti = wit−1 Nti + (µNt−1 − Nti )(wit − wt ), here the first term on the right is the wage paid to current employees and the second term represents the payments to prematurely laid off employees. An earlier i version of the paper included the constraint Nti ≥ µNt−1 , the results were largely similar. 13 the expected maturity of the debt, i.e., the average length of the debt contract is 1 . pexp The firm defaults at t if its cum-dividend market value Vt+1 is below 0. Additionally, if there is a positive amount of debt outstanding, the firm’s dividend cannot be so high so that the firm’s ex-dividend value is less than or equal to zero, consistent with the covenants that limit the dividends firms may pay. In the event of bankruptcy, creditors inherit a debt free firm, of which the firm’s cum-dividend 0 . The market price of bond is determined in equilibrium and depends value is denoted by Vt+1 on the aggregate state (discount rate) and the firm’s individual state (probability of default). In particular, the bond pricing follows the equation below, 0 Ψit = Et Mt+1 1{exp} × 0 + 1{Vt+1 <0} × Vt+1 + 1 − 1{exp} − 1{Vt+1 <0} κit+1 + Ψit+1 , (7) where Ψit is the price of debt with coupon payment κit+1 , 1{exp} is an indicator function that takes the value of one when the debt expires and zero otherwise, and 1{Vt+1 <0} is an indicator function that takes the value of one when the firm is insolvent and zero otherwise. 3.1.4 Accounting The equation for after-tax profit is Π(Kti ) = (1 − τ ) Yti − wit Nti − zt − κit + τ δKti (8) Π(Kti ) is after-tax profit, which is output less labor, operating costs, and coupon payment, plus tax shield on capital depreciation. Operating costs are defined as zt = f ∗ Kt ; they depend on aggregate (but not firm specific) capital.9 Labor costs are wit Nti . Capital adjustment costs are convex given by Φ(Iti , Kti ) =υ Iti Kti 2 Kti , where υ > 0. The total dividend paid by the firm is Dti = Π(Kti ) − Iti − Φ(Iti , Kti ) + Ψit 1{Issue} , 9 (9) Because productivity is non-stationary, all model quantities are non-stationary and we cannot allow for a constant operating cost as it would grow infinitely large or infinitely small relative to other quantities. All quantities in the model must be scaled by something that is co-integrated with the productivity level, such as aggregate capital. We have also experimented with using the spot wage (wt ) or aggregate productivity (Xt ) and the results appear insensitive to this. 14 which is after-tax profit less investment, capital adjustment costs plus the cash from newly issued debt where 1{Issue} is an indicator function that takes the value of one when the firm issues new coupon and zero otherwise. 3.1.5 The Firm’s Problem We now formally write down firm i’s problem. The firm maximizes the present discounted value of future dividends ( Vti = max ) max i i ,κi It+j ,Nt+j t+j+1 Et [ X i Mt+j Dt+j ], 0 , (10) j=0,∞ subject to the standard capital accumulation equation i Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kti + Iti , (11) as well as equations (3), (6), (8), and (9). 3.1.6 Credit Spread We define the credit spread CSt in the model as the difference between the yield ζ B t on the defaultable debt and the yield of a comparable bond without default risk, ζ t , i.e., CSt = ζ B t − ζ t, with ζ B t = 3.2 κit+1 Ψit and ζ t = κit+1 Ψit (saf e) (12) where Ψit (saf e) is the price of the bond without default risk. Equilibrium We assume that there exists some underlying set of state variables St which is sufficient for this problem. Each firm’s individual state variables are given by the vector Sti . Because the household is a representative agent, we are able to avoid explicitly solving the household’s maximization problem and simply use the first order conditions to find Mt+1 as an analytic function of consumption or expectations of future consumption. For instance, with CRRA utility, ψ1 −θ −θ − ψ1 Ct+1 Ct+1 Ut+1 Mt+1 = β Ct while for Epstein-Zin utility Mt+1 = β Ct .10 1 1−θ Et [Ut+1 ] 1−θ 10 Given a process for Ct we can recursively solve for all the necessary expectations to calculate Mt+1 . The appendix provides more details. 15 Equilibrium consists of: • Beliefs about the transition function of the state variable and the shocks: St+1 = f (St , Xt+1 ). • Beliefs about the realized stochastic discount factor as a function of the state variable and realized shocks: M (St , Xt+1 ). • Beliefs about the aggregate spot wage as a function of the state variable: w(St ). • Beliefs about the price of debt, as a function of the state today and the firm’s choice of coupon next period: Ψit St , Sti , κit+1 • Firm policy functions (which depend on St and Sti ) for labor demand Nti , investment Iti and coupon κit . It must also be the case that given the above policy functions all markets clear and the beliefs turn out to be rational: • The firm’s policy functions maximize the firm’s problem given beliefs about the wages, the discount factor, and the state variable. • The labor market clears: P Nti = 1 • The goods market clears: Ct = P (Yti − Iti ) = P Πit + wit Nti + zt + Φit − Iti + Tt . Note that here we are assuming that all costs are paid by firms to individuals and are therefore consumed, the results look very similar if all costs are instead wasted. • The beliefs about Mt+1 are consistent with goods market clearing through the household’s Euler Equation.11 • Beliefs about the transition of the state variables are correct. For instance if aggregate P capital is part of the aggregate state vector, then it must be that Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + Iti . 4 Model Solution We solve the model at a quarterly frequency using a variation of the Krusell and Smith (1998) algorithm, we discuss the solution method in the appendix. The model requires us to choose the preference parameters: β (time discount factor), θ (risk aversion), ψ (intertemporal elasticity of substitution); the technology parameters: α and ρ (jointly determine labor share in output 11 For example, with CRRA Mt+1 = β P Dt+1,i P +wt Nt+1,i +Φt+1,i +Ξt+1,i +Ψt+1,i Dt,i +wt Nt,i +Φt,i +Ξt,i +Ψt,i 16 −θ and degree of return to scale), 1 1−η (elasticity of substitution between labor and capital), δ (depreciation), f (operating cost); the adjustment cost parameters: ν (capital adjustment cost), and the debt contract parameter: pexp (debt expiration probability). Finally we must choose our key parameter µ which determines the frequency of wage resetting. Below we justify our choices of these parameters. Table 8 presents parameters of the benchmark calibration. Preferences We set β = 0.98 to match the level of the risk free rate. We set θ = 8 to get a reasonably high Sharpe Ratio, while keeping risk aversion within the range recommended by Mehra and Prescott (1985). The intertemporal elasticity of substitution ψ also helps with the Sharpe Ratio, it is set to 2 close to that in Bansal and Yaron (2004), who show that values above 1 are required for the long run risk channel to match asset pricing moments as this ensures that the compensation for long-run expected growth risk is positive. Technology The technology parameters are fairly standard and we use numbers consistent with prior literature. We jointly choose α = 0.45 and ρ = 0.77 so that labor share and profit share are consistent with empirical estimates.12 Similarly we set η = −1 to match empirical estimates of the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. The elasticity of substitution between 1 labor and capital is 1−η = 0.5. In a survey article based on a multitude of studies, Chirinko (2008) argues this elasticity is between 0.4 and 0.6.13 We set δ = 0.025 to match annual depreciation. Operating cost zt = f ∗Kt is a fixed cost from the perspective of the firm, however it depends on the aggregate state of the economy, in particular aggregate capital. We choose f = 0.019 to match the average market-to-book ratio in the economy, which we estimate to be 1.33 (details of this estimation are in Favilukis and Lin 2015a). While we think it is realistic for this cost to increase when aggregate capital is higher (during expansions), the results are not sensitive to this assumption. The results look very similar when zt is simply growing at the same rate as the economy.14 Note that fixed costs in the production process also effectively constitute a form of operating leverage. However, its quantitative effect on credit spread is minimal. Capital adjustment costs We choose the capital adjustment costs ν = 5 to match the volatility of aggregate investment. Higher adjustment costs always help increase equity 12 Labor share is (1 − α)ρ = 0.42. Profit share is (1 − α)(1 − ρ) = 0.13 implying returns to scale of 0.87. Gomes (2001) uses 0.95 citing estimates of just under 1 by Burnside (1996). Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995) estimate it to be between 0.8 and 0.9. Khan and Thomas (2008) use 0.896, justifying it by matching the capital to output ratio. Bachmann, Caballero and Engel (2013) use 0.82, justifying it by matching the revenue elasticity of capital. 13 One concern may be that the estimate of η would itself be affected by frictions, such as the one in our paper. However, several of the studies cited by Chirinko (2008) are done with micro-level data specifically to account for frictions, therefore η is the exact model analog of their estimate. Furthermore, we have repeated the exercise in Caballero (2004) to estimate η from aggregate quantities in our model by regressing log(Y /K) on the cost of 1 is 0.5 if the cost of capital is defined as the return on capital, and 0.41 if it is the capital. The estimate of 1−η interest rate plus the log of Tobin’s Q. 14 Recall that the model is non-stationary, therefore zt cannot be a constant and must be scaled by something that is cointegrated with the size of the economy. 17 volatility but they decrease aggregate investment volatility. This restriction on matching aggregate investment limits how much work capital adjustment costs can do in helping to match financial moments. Debt contract We calibrate the debt expiration probability pexp = 0.025, which implies that the maturity of the debt contract is 40 quarters, close to the average estimate in Guedes and Opler (1996). Corporate tax rate τ is set to 0.3 close to that in Jermann and Quadrini (2012). Productivity shocks In order for the long run risk channel to produce high Sharpe ratios, aggregate productivity must be non-stationary with a stationary growth rate. We specify the growth rate of aggregate productivity (∆ log Xt ) to be a symmetric 3-state Markov process with autocorrelation 0.27, unconditional mean of 0.02, and unconditional standard deviation of 0.055. We choose these numbers to roughly match the autocorrelation, growth rate, and standard deviation of output. Aggregate productivity is then log(Xt+1 ) = log(Xt ) + ∆ log Xt+1 which is consistent with long run risk.15 The volatility of idiosyncratic productivity shocks log Zti depends on the model’s scale, that is which real world production unit (firm, plant) is analogous to the model’s production unit. There is no consensus on the right scale to use, for example the annual autocorrelation and unconditional standard deviation are 0.69 and 0.40 in Zhang (2005), 0.62 and 0.19 in Gomes (2001), 0.86 and 0.04 in Khan and Thomas (2008), while Pastor and Veronesi (2003) estimate that the volatility of firm-level profitability rose from 10% per year in the early 1960s to 45% in the late 1990s. We have experimented with various idiosyncratic shocks and find that our aggregate results are not significantly affected by the size of these shocks. In our model, log Zti is a 3-state Markov process with autocorrelation and unconditional standard deviation of 0.75 and 0.23 respectively. We believe these shocks make our production units closest to real world firms because, as will be discussed below, these shocks allow us to match various firm moments, such as the cross-sectional variation of investment rate and stock returns. Frequency of wage resetting In standard models wages are reset once per period and employees receive the marginal product of labor as compensation. This corresponds to the µ = 0 case. However, wages are far too volatile in these models relative to the data. We choose the frequency of resetting to roughly match the volatility of wages in the data. This results in µ = 0.90 or an average resetting frequency of ten quarters. We also believe that this number is realistic, for example Rich and Tracy (2004) estimate that a majority of labor contracts last between two and five years with a mean of three years, they cite several major renewals (United Auto Workers, United Steel Workers) which are at the top of the range. Anecdotal evidence suggests that assistant professors, investment bankers, and corporate 15 Our process for TFP growth is analogous to a discretized AR(1) process, Bansal and Yaron (2004) use a slightly more complicated formulation where consumption growth is ARMA(1,1). When the short-run and long-run shocks in Bansal and Yaron (2004) are perfectly correlated, their process becomes identical to ours. 18 lawyers all wait approximately this long to be promoted. Even if explicit contracts are written for a shorter period than our calibration (or not written at all), we believe that four years is a reasonable estimate of how long the real wage of many employees stays unchanged. Campbell and Kamlani (1997) conducted a survey of 184 firms and find that implicit contracts are an important explanation for wage rigidity of U.S. manufacturing workers, especially of blue-collar workers. For example, if the costs of replacing employees (for employers) and the costs of finding a new job (for employees) are high, the status quo will remain, keeping wages the same without an explicit contract. Another example are workers who receive small raises every year, keeping their real wage constant or growing slowly; indeed, Barwell and Schweitzer (2007) show that this type of rigidity is quite common. Such workers do not experience major changes to their income until they are promoted, or let go, or move to another job. Hall (1982) estimates an average job duration of eight years for American workers, Abraham and Farber (1987) estimate similar numbers just for non-unionized workers (presumably unionized workers have even longer durations). Given the importance of this parameter for our model, it is useful to note the difference between job length and the separation rate. As mentioned above, average job length is around eight years for American workers. A separation rate is the probability of a worker separating from her job in any particular period. Estimates of separation rates for the US range from 1.1%/month by Hobijn and Sahin (2009), to 3.4%/month by Shimer (2005), with most being around 3%/month. If separations were equally likely for all workers, this would imply an average job length of around 2.8 years - far shorter than our calibrated contract length or job length in the data. This apparent difference is due to a small number of workers who frequently transition between jobs, while a majority of workers stay in their jobs for a long time. For example, Hall (2005) writes “Separation rates are sensitive to the accounting period because a small fraction of jobs but a large fraction of separations come from jobs lasting as little as a day.” Hobijn and Sahin (2009) show that 15% of jobs have a tenure below 6 months; Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger (2006) show that if one estimates separations based on workers who have held their job for a full quarter (as opposed to all separations), the quarterly separation rate falls from 24% to 10.7%. On the other hand, as mentioned above, estimates of average job length are around 8 years for U.S. workers. Since, for computational reasons, in our model separation is equally likely for all workers, we can either relate µ to estimated separation rates which will imply that model job length is too low relative to the data, or to estimated job and contract lengths, which will imply that model separation rates are too low relative to the data. We believe that the latter is more relevant for our model. Note that workers who separate frequently are likely to be low paid, temporary or part time workers who do not significantly contribute to the firm’s wage bill. The majority of the firm’s wage bill is likely paid to high skilled and long-tenured workers and the obligations to these workers are likely to be quite sticky. 19 5 Model Results In this section, we study the model implications for both equity volatility and credit spread predictability. 5.1 Aggregate Quantities Here we discuss our benchmark model, which combines long-run risk, infrequent wage renegotiation, long-term defaultable debt, and a calibrated CES production function. Quarterly variables are aggregated to annual frequency to be consistent with the data. Table 9 presents the real aggregate quantities in the data and the model. The benchmark model does a good job at matching many macroeconomic moments. For example, it produces smooth consumption and volatile investment. In the data, consumption is about half as volatile as GDP, and investment is three times more volatile than GDP both in HP filtered levels and in growth rates. The model implied consumption volatility is slightly higher than the data and investment volatility is fairly close to the data. In addition, the persistence of consumption (consumption growth) and investment (investment growth) are reasonably close to the data moments as well. Turning to wage volatility, recall that in standard models where wages are reset every period, as is shown in Favilukis and Lin (2015a), the volatility of hourly compensation is twice as high as in the data and its correlation with output is far too high. Because labor income comprises such a large fraction of output, this flaw is very significant quantitatively and is responsible for many of this model’s failures at matching financial data.16 While in our benchmark model with wage rigidity, because wages are negotiated infrequently, the average wage is no longer equal to the marginal product of labor but rather a weighted average of past spot wages, this results in average wages being much smoother than the marginal product of labor. The model implied wage volatility relative to that of GDP is 0.49, close to the data moment at 0.44. Moreover wages are imperfectly correlated with GDP; the correlation of HP filtered wage (wage growth) with GDP (GDP growth) is 0.82 (0.85), somewhat higher than the data 0.60 (0.61), but represents a big improvement relative to the standard models where this correlation is perfect at one. We believe that almost any model in which average wages are smoother than the marginal product of labor 16 Unlike the first generation of RBC models, which did a very poor job matching financial moments (the well known Equity Premium Puzzle), this model can produce a high Sharpe Ratio through the long run risk channel. First proposed by Bansal and Yaron (2004) in an endowment economy and later incorporated into a production economy by Croce (2014) and Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (2010), the long run risk channel makes the economy appear risky to households because (i) a high intertemporal elasticity of substitution makes households care not only about instantaneous shocks to consumption growth but also shocks to expectations of future consumption growth, (ii) shocks to the growth rate (as opposed to the level in standard models) of productivity are persistent causing expectations of future consumption growth to vary over time. But because the volatility of equity is so low, the equity premium (which is the Sharpe Ratio multiplied by the volatility of equity) is also quite low. 20 will have results qualitatively similar to those discussed below. We view infrequent renegotiation as simply one of multiple mechanisms responsible for the relatively smooth wages in the data. 5.2 Equity Volatility Profits are approximately equal to output minus wages. In a standard model wages are highly volatile and highly pro-cyclical (the marginal product of labor is perfectly correlated with output). This results in profits being too smooth. Dividends are approximately equal to profits minus investment. Because profits are relatively small in magnitude while investment is pro-cyclical, dividends in a standard model are counter-cyclical and highly volatile, exactly the opposite of what we observe in the data. Because profits are smooth and dividends are counter-cyclical, the firm’s equity is also very smooth in standard models. In other words, pro-cyclical wages act as a hedge for the firm’s shareholders, making equity seem very safe. When wages become smoother than the marginal product of labor, profits become more volatile and more pro-cyclical relative to the standard model. Volatile and pro-cyclical profits lead to procyclical dividends. With smoother wages no longer being as strong of a hedge, equity volatility looks closer to the data as well. Table 10 presents the unconditional asset pricing moments of the wage rigidity model. The rigidity model, combining infrequent renegotiation and CES production function, has an equity volatility of 8.9% representing a significant improvement over the standard models despite somewhat below the 19.89% in the data.17 A common problem of production models that were able to produce high equity volatilities is that they also resulted in highly volatile risk free rates (for example Jermann (1998) and Boldrin, Christiano and Fisher (2001) . Note that risk free rates in our models are all sufficiently smooth. Furthermore, due to the high volatility of equity, our model is not only able to match the high Sharpe Ratio (like Croce (2014) and Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (2010)) but also gets close to the actual equity premium; the model combining infrequent renegotiation and CES production function has an equity premium of 4.5%, close to the data. 5.3 Credit Spread As in Favilukis and Lin (2015a), our benchmark model fixes or greatly reduces all of the problems with the standard model in matching wage volatility, and equity volatility. In the following, we will also focus on the novel empirical predictions of the model on the forecastability of credit spread. 17 The model implied equity volatility is short of magnitude because both labor and debt are frictionlessly adjusted. Adding adjustment costs on these margins will make equity volatility even closer to the data. 21 Because wages are set infrequently, the average wage is no longer equal to the marginal product of labor but rather a weighted average of past spot wages, this results in average wages being much smoother than the marginal product of labor. Smoother wages imply volatile profit which in turn increases the default probability and credit risk premium. Table 10 presents the credit risk moments implied by the model. The model implied financial leverage is 0.31, close to the data moment at 0.44. The credit spread is 2.9%, within the historical range of the credit spread while lies on the upper part of the distribution. The average default probability is 1.3%, close to the mean estimate at 1.5% in the data, which also falls within the historical estimates reported in Giesecke et al (2011). Turning to the predictability of the credit spread, Panel B in Table 11 presents the predictive regression results. In the model, wage growth negatively forecasts credit spread with the slope at -11.03, which is fairly close to the data counterpart at -15.4. Similarly, labor share positively forecasts credit spread with the slope coefficient at 10.20, which is also close to the data slope of 10.66. Taken together, the model does a reasonably good job generating a sizable credit spread despite low default probability, thus providing a novel explanation for the credit spread puzzle. Furthermore, the benchmark model also quantitatively generates time-variations in credit spread that is consistent with data. 5.4 Intuition To gain some intuition for why wage rigidity matters for credit risk premium and its predictability, we will compare the default decision in the frictionless model to the model with wage rigidities. The firm defaults if its realized firm value Vt is below zero. This occurs if all else being equal, the firm’s idiosyncratic productivity Z is below a cutoff value Z ∗ , which itself depends on the state of the economy including the aggregate the firm-specific state variables. Mathematically, the cutoff value Z ∗ is a function of states, which can be characterized as i Z ∗ St , Kti , Nt−1 , κit ; wit = arg min [Vt (St , Sti ) > 0] Z = arg min (1 − τ ) Yti − wit Nti − Ψit − κit + τ δKti − Iti − Φ(Iti , Kti ) + Ψit 1{Issue} + Et Mt+1 Vt+1 > 0 Z (13) The default decision can be described as follows Z ≥ Z ∗ stay Z < Z ∗ default 22 (14) All else equal, the model with rigidity implies a higher default probability than the frictionless model. When a negative aggregate productivity shock hits the economy, gross profit Yti − wit Nti in the model without wage rigidity will fall roughly proportional to output, whereas the gross profit will fall by more than output in the wage rigidity model. This implies that all else being equal, the cutoff value of idiosyncratic productivity for default in the frictionless model is lower than that of wage rigidity model, i.e., ∗ Zf∗rictionless < Zrigidity (15) Equation (15) implies that the default region in idiosyncratic productivity for the frictionless model is smaller than the wage rigidity model, which is described in equation (16), ∗ −∞, Zf∗rictionless ⊂ −∞, Zrigidity . (16) This relationship will directly translate into a higher default probability for the firm in the wage rigidity model, which in turn results in higher credit risk premium since aggregate productivity shocks carry a positive price of risk. This economic channel leads to a sizable credit spread in the wage rigidity model. Furthermore, the operating leverage effect caused by wage rigidities is not constant over time. Times of low wage growth or high labor share are associated with high labor leverage and hence are associated with high credit risk premium. This happens because during bad (good) times, wages fall (rise) by less than output leading to an increase (decrease) in operating leverage, thus wage growth negatively whereas labor share positively predicts future credit spread in the model. 6 Conclusion Labor market variables have significant impact in driving the credit spread fluctuations. We show that wage growth and labor share strongly forecast credit risk as well as or better than the standard predictors including financial leverage and market volatility both in the time series and the cross section of firms across a wide range of countries. We build a DSGE model with wage rigidities and long-term defaultable debt that can explain this link. This is because pre-committed payments to labor make other committed payments (such as debt) riskier; for this reason variables related to pre-committed labor payments forecast credit risk. Our results have implications for asset pricing, labor economics, and macroeconomics literature. Our findings suggest that labor market frictions, in particular, wage rigidity can have a significant impact on corporate bond prices. Credit market variables, which are typically ignored in the labor economics literature, can thus be a useful source of information for quantifying frictions in labor 23 markets. Our results suggest that incorporating time-varying credit risk in current DSGE models can be important for an accurate understanding of labor market dynamics over the business cycle. 24 References Abraham, Katherine, and Henry Farber, 1987, Job duration, seniority, and earnings, American Economic Review 77, 278–297. Altman, Edward I., 1968, Financial ratios, discriminant analysis, and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy, Journal of Finance 23, 589–609. Bachmann, Ruediger., and Ricardo J. Caballero, Eduardo M.R.A. Engel, 2013, Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Investment: New Evidence and a DSGE Model, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(4): 29-67 Bai, Hang, 2015, Unemployment and Credit Risk, Working paper, Ohio State University Bansal, Ravi, and Amir Yaron, 2004, Risks for the long run: A potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles, Journal of Finance 59, 1481–1509. Barwell, Richard, and Mark Schweitzer, 2007, The incidence of nominal and real wage rigidities in Great Britain: 1978-98, Economic Journal 117, 553–569. Bauer, Thomas, Lorenz Goette, and Uwe Sunde, 2007, Wage rigidity: Measurement, causes and consequences, Economic Journal 117, 499–507. Belo, Frederico., Xiaoji Lin, and Santiago Bazdresch, 2013, Labor hiring, investment and stock return predictability in the cross section, Forthcoming, Journal of Political Economy. Boldrin, M., L. Christiano, and J. Fisher, 1999, Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 99-14. Boldrin, M., L. Christinano and J. Fisher. 2001. Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle, American Economic Review 91 (1), 149–166. Burnside, Craig, 1996, Production function regressions, returns to scale, and externalities, Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 177–201. Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo, 1995, Capital utilization and returns to scale, NBER Macroeconomics Annual 10, 67–110. Caballero, R., 1994, Small sample bias and adjustment costs, The Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 52–58. Campbell, John Y., and Robert Shiller, 1988, Stock prices, earnings and expected dividends, Journal of Finance 43, 661–676. Campbell, John Y., Jens Hilscher, and Jan Szilagyi, 2008, In search of distress risk, Journal of Finance 63, 2899–2939. Calvo, Guillermo A, 1982, Staggered contracts and exchange rate policy, In: J.A. Frankel, ed., Exchange Rates and International Macroeconomics (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL). 25 Chen, Hui, 2010, Macroeconomic conditions and the puzzles of credit spreads and capital structure, Journal of Finance 65, 2171–2212. Chen, Long, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein, 2009, On the relation between credit spread puzzles and the equity premium puzzle, Review of Financial Studies 22, 33673409. Collin-Dufresne, Pierre, Robert Goldstein, and J. Spencer Martin, 2001, The determinants of credit spread changes, Journal of Finance 56, 2177-2207. Collin-Dufresne, Pierre, and Robert S. Goldstein, 2001, Do credit spreads reflect stationary leverage ratios? Journal of Finance 56, 1929-1957. Chirinko, Robert, 2008, [sigma]: The long and short of it, Journal of Macroeconomics 30, 671– 686. Croce, Marano Massimilliano, 2014, Long-run productivity risk: A new hope for productionbased asset pricing? Journal of Monetary Economics 66: 13–31 Davis, Steven, Jason Faberman, and John Haltiwanger, 2006, The flow approach to labor markets: New data sources and micro-macro links, Journal of Economic Perspectives 20, 3–26. Devicenti, Francesco, Agata Maida, and Paolo Sestito, 2007, Downward wage rigidity in Italy: Micro-based measures and implications, Economic Journal 117, 530–552. Dickens, William, Lorenz Goette, Erica Groshen, Steinar Holden, Julian Messina, Mark Schweitzer, Jarkko Turunen, and Melanie Ward, 2007, How wages change: Micro evidence from the international wage flexibility project, Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, 195– 214. Elton, Edwin J., Martin J. Gruber, Deepak Agrawal, and Christopher Mann. 2001. Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds. Journal of Finance 56(1), 247-277. Epstein, L., and S. Zin. 1989. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework, Econometrica 57, 937–969. Favilukis, Jack, and Xiaoji Lin, 2015a, Wage rigidity: a quantitative solution to several asset pricing puzzles, Forthcoming, Review of Financial Studies. Favilukis, Jack, and Xiaoji Lin, 2015b, Does Wage Rigidity Make Firms Riskier? Evidence from Long-Horizon Return Predictability. Working paper, University of British Columbia and Ohio State University Gertler, Mark and Antonella Trigari, 2009, Unemployment Dynamics with Staggered Nash Wage Bargaining, Journal of Political Economy, 117 (1), 38-86. Giesecke, Kay; Francis A. Longstaff, Stephen Schaefer, and Ilya Strebulaev, 2011, Journal of Financial Economics 102: 233–250 26 Gilchrist, Simon., and Egon Zakrajsek, 2012, Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations, American Economic Review, 102(4): 1692–1720 Gilchrist, Simon., Jae Sim and Egon Zakrajsek, 2014, Uncertainty, Financial Frictions and Investment Dynamics, Working paper, Boston University Gomes, Joao, 2001, Financing investment, American Economic Review 91, 1263–1285. Gomes, Joao, and Lukas Schmid, 2010, Equilibrium Credit Spreads and the Macroeconomy, Working paper. Gomes, Joao, Urban Jermann, and Lukas Schmid, 2013, Sticky leverage, Working Paper. Guedes, Jose., and Tim Opler, 1996, The Determinants of the Maturity of Corporate Debt Issues, Journal of Finance 51: 1809-1833 Gourio, Francois, 2013, Credit risk and Disaster risk, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(3):1-34, 2013 Hackbarth, Dirk, Jianjun Miao, and Erwan Morellec, 2006, Capital structure, credit risk and macroeconomic conditions, Journal of Financial Economics 82, 519-550. Hall, Robert, 2005, Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness, American Economic Review, 95(1), 50-65. Hamermesh, Daniel, and Gerard Pfann, 1996, Adjustment costs in factor demand, Journal of Economic Literature XXXIV, 1264–1292. Hobijn, Bart, and Aysegul Sahin, 2009, Job-finding and separation rates in the oecd, Economic Letters 104, 107–111. Hou, Kewei, Andrew Karolyi, and Bon-Chan Kho, 2011, What Factors Drive Global Stock Returns?, Review of Financial Studies, 24(8), 2527–2574. Jermann, Urban, and Vicenzo Quadrini, 2012, Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks, American Economic Review, 238-71. Kaltenbrunner, Georg, and Lars Lochstoer, 2010, Long-run risk through consumption smoothing, Review of Financial Studies. Khan, Aubhik., and Julia Thomas, 2008, Idiosyncratic Shocks and the Role of Nonconvexities in Plant and Aggregate Investment Dynamics, Econometrica 76 (2): 395 - 436 Krusell, P and Smith, A.A. 1998, Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy, Journal of Political Economy, 106(5): 867-896. Kuehn, Lars-Alexander, and Lukas Schmid, 2013, Investment-Based Corporate Bond Pricing, Working Paper. Kuehn, Lars-Alexander, Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau, and Lu Zhang, 2013, An equilibrium asset pricing model with labor markets search, Working Paper. 27 Mehra, Rajnish, and Edward Prescott, 1985, The equity premium: A puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 145–161. Modigliani, F., and M. Miller, 1958, The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment, American Economic Review 48, 261–297. Mortensen, Dale, and Christopher Pissarides, 1994, Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment, Review of Economic Studies 61, 397–415. Newey, Whitney, and Kenneth West, 1987, A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica 55, 703–708. Pastor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi, 2003, Stock valuation and learning about profitability, Journal of Finance 58, 1749–1789. Pissarides, Christopher, 1979, Job matchings with state employment agencies and random search, Economic Journal 89, 818–833. Pissarides, Christopher, 2009, The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: Is Wage Stickiness the Answer? Econometrica: 1339-1369 Shimer, Robert, 2005, The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies, The American Economic Review. 95 (1), 25-49. Shumway, Tyler, 2001, Forecasting bankruptcy more accurately: A simple hazard model, Journal of Business 74, 101–124. Sweeney, Richard, Arthur Warga, and Drew Winters, 1997, The market value of debt, market versus book value of debt, and returns to assets, Financial Management 26, 5–21. Taylor, J.B., 1983, Union wage settlements during a disinflation, American Economic Review 73, 981–993. Taylor, J.B., 1999, Staggered price and wage setting in macroeconomics, In: John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford (Eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics, North-Holland, Elsevier, 1, Part 2 pp. 1009–1050. Zhang, Lu, 2005, The value premium, Journal of Finance 60 (1), 67–103. Zmijewski, Mark E., 1984, Methodological issues related to the estimation of financial distress prediction models, Journal of Accounting Research 22, 59–82. 28 A A.1 Numerical Solution Making the Model Stationary Note that the model is not stationary. In order to solve it numerically, we must rewrite it in terms of stationary quantities. We will show that a normalizing all non-stationary variables by Ztρ implies a stationary competitive equilibrium. We will do this in two steps. First we will show that if the firm believes that the stochastic discount factor is stationary and that aggregate quantities (in particular the spot wage) normalized by Ztρ are stationary than the firm’s policy functions normalized by Ztρ will also be stationary. Second we show that these policy functions imply that these aggregate quantities are indeed stationary when normalized by Ztρ . The firm’s problem is: i i , κit , W t−1 ; Zt , Kt , St , W t−1 ) = maxIti ,Nti ,κit+1 (1 − τ ) Yti − wit Nti − zt − κit + τ δKti V (Zti , Kti , Nt−1 i i i , Nti , κit+1 , W t ; Zt+1 , Kt+1 , St+1 , W t )] , Kt+1 +Et [Mt+1 V (Zt+1 (17) i i i Where Zt is the idiosyncratic productivity, Kt is the firm’s individual capital, Nt−1 is the firm’s i employment last period, κit is the current coupon payment paid, W t−1 is the firm’s average wage last period, Zt is aggregate productivity, W t−1 is the aggregate average wage from last period, and Wt is the spot wage this period. Following Krusell and Smith (1998) the state space potentially contains all information about the joint distribution of capital and productivity. Kt and St summarize this distribution. We explicitly write its first moment Kt as an aggregate state variable and let St be a vector of any other relevant moments normalized by the mean (i.e. the normalized second moment is E[(Kti − Kt )2 ]/Kt2 ). Households have beliefs about the evolution of the aggregate quantities Mt+1 , Kt , and St and about the spot wage as a function of the aggregate state. Aggregate wage evolves as W t = µW t−1 + (1 − µ)Wt . The individual state variables evolve as: i Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kti + Iti i Wt = Ki (18) i i i W t−1 Nt−1 µ+(Nti −Nt−1 µ)Wt i Nt Ii κi i t Let us define kti = Z ρt , kt = ZKρt , iit = Ztρ , κ̂it = Ztρ ,wt = W , wit = ZWρ t , and wt = ZWρ t (not that Ztρ t t t t t+1 t+1 the timing of wit and wt differs from the others). We will now show by induction that the value function is linear in Ztρ . Suppose this is true at t+1: i ρ i i i i V (Zt+1 , Kt+1 , Nti , κit , W t ; Zt+1 , Kt+1 , St+1 , W t ) = Zt+1 V (Zt+1 , kt+1 , Nti , κit+1 , wit ; 1, kt+1 , St+1 , wt ) 29 Than we can rewrite the firm’s problem as: i V (Zti , kti , Nt−1 , κ̂it , wit−1 ; 1, kt , St , wt−1 ) = maxiit ,Nti ,κit+1 (1 − τ ) Yti − wit Nti − zt − κit + τ δKti ρ i i +Et [ ZZt+1 Mt+1 V (Zt+1 , kt+1 , Nti , κ̂it+1 , wit ; 1, kt+1 , St+1 , wt )] t (19) −ρ Zt+1 and the individual state where the aggregate wage evolves as wt = (µwt−1 + (1 − µ)wt ) Zt variables evolve as: −ρ i kt+1 = ((1 − δ)kti + iit ) ZZt+1 t i i −ρ (20) i −N i w N µ+(N µ)w t Zt+1 t t−1 t−1 t−1 wit = i Zt Nt ρ As long as ZZt+1 , Mt+1 , kt+1 , and wt+1 are stationary this is a well defined stationary problem t i where the firm’s optimal policy (iit and Nti ) will also be stationary. But this implies that kt+1 and P i kt+1 = kt+1 are stationary as well, confirming the firm’s beliefs. It is similarly straight forward to show that the stochastic discount factor is stationary. First of all note that Mt+1 is related to the growth rate of consumption, so it should be stationary. More formally: 11 1− 1 1 1− ψ 1− ψ ψ 1−θ 1−θ + βEt [Ut+1 ] U t = Ct (21) 1 −θ 1 ψ Ut+1 Mt+1 = β Ct+1 Ct 1 1−θ 1−θ Et [Ut+1 ] −ψ Define ct = ZCρt and ut = ZUρt and note that the firm’s optimal policy implies that ct is stationary. t t Now we can rewrite the above equations as: ut = 1− 1 ct ψ + βEt [ Z Mt+1 = β t+1 Zt Et [ Z t+1 Zt Zt+1 Zt ρ ρ ρ ut+1 1− 1 ψ 1−θ 1−θ ut+1 ] ! ψ1 −θ 1 1−θ u1−θ t+1 ] 1 1− 1 ψ ct+1 ct − ψ1 Zt+1 Zt − ψρ (22) which are stationary as long as ct is stationary. Next, we must show that the spot wage is stationary. The firm’s first order condition for labor implies: wt = Zti α(kti )η + (1 − α)(Nti )ρη 1−η η (1 − α)ρ(Nti )ρη−1 ρ Zt+1 ∂Vt+1 + Et [ Mt+1 ] Zt ∂Nti (23) For every firm, the right hand side is well defined and stationary, therefore the wage is too. To jointly find the wage and each firm’s choice of Nti one must solve a system of N equations. N-1 equations where the right hand side of the first order condition for firm 1 is set equal to firm i 30 P i (i=2,N), and the labor market clearing equation Nt = 1. There remains one last complication, is St stationary? This is related to a more general problem of the validity and accuracy of the Krusell and Smith (1998) algorithm. We cannot give an explicit answer as it is not clear what exactly St must contain. Krusell and Smith (1998) argue that St should contain higher order moments of the distribution since they fully describe the distribution. Since we define St to be normalized by its first moment, it is likely that these normalized higher moments are stationary. We have also checked the behavior of several simulated higher order moments and they appear stationary. In practice our numerical algorithm (described in the next section) only considers the first moment so St is an empty set, which is stationary by definition. A.2 Numerical Algorithm We will now describe the numerical algorithm used to solve the stationary problem above. We will first describe the algorithm used to solve a model with CRRA utility and then the extension necessary to solve the recursive utility version. The algorithm is a variation of the algorithm in Krusell and Smith (1998). The aggregate state space is potentially infinite because it contains the full distribution of capital across firms. We follow Krusell and Smith (1998) and summarize it by the average aggregate capital kt and the state of aggregate productivity ∆Zt ; because past wages matter, we augment the aggregate state space with the previous period’s average wage wt−1 . Each of these is put on a grid, with the grid sizes of 20 for capital, 9 for past wage, and 13 for coupon. Productivity is a 3-state Markov process. We also discretize the firm’s individual state space with grid sizes of 25 i ), and 5 for last period’s average wage for individual capital (kti ), 11 for last period’s labor (Nt−1 (wit−1 ). Individual productivity is a 2-state Markov process. We chose these grid sizes after careful experimentation to determine which grid sizes had the most effect on Euler equation errors and predictive R2 . For each point in the aggregate state space (kt , wt−1 , ∆Zt ) we start out with an initial belief about consumption, spot wages, and investment (ct , wt , and it ); note that this non-parametric approach is different from Krusell and Smith (1998).18 From these we can solve for aggregate −ρ capital next period kt+1 = ((1 − δ)kt + it ) ZZt+1 for each realization of the shock. Combining t kt+1 with beliefs about consumption as a function of capital we can also solve for the stochastic 18 The standard Krusell and Smith (1998) algorithm instead assumes a functional form for the transition, such as log(k t+1 ) = A(Zt ) + B(Zt )log(kt ) and forms beliefs only about the coefficients A(Zt ) and B(Zt ) however we find that this approach does not converge in many cases due to incorrect beliefs about off-equilibrium situations and that our approach works better. Without heterogeneity and infrequent resetting we would not need beliefs about wt because it would just be the marginal product of aggregate capital. Similarly, we would not need beliefs about ct as we could solve for it from yt = ct + it where yt is aggregate output, however aggregate output is no longer a simple analytic function of aggregate capital. 31 ct+1 ct −θ Zt+1 Zt −θρ . This is enough information to solve discount factor next period: Mt+1 = β the stationary problem described in the previous section. We solve the problem by value function iteration with the output being policies and market values of each firm for each point in the state space. The next step is to use the policy functions to simulate the economy. We simulate the economy for 5500 periods (we throw away the initial 500 periods). In addition to the long simulation, we start off the model in each point of the aggregate state space. We must do this because unlike Krusell and Smith (1998), the beliefs in our algorithm are non-parametric and during the model’s typical behavior it does not visit every possible point in the state space. From the simulation we form simulation implied beliefs about ct , wt , and it at each point in the aggregate state space by averaging over all periods in which the economy was sufficiently close to that point in the state space. Our updated beliefs are a weighted average of the old beliefs and the new simulation implied beliefs.19 With these updated beliefs we again solve the firm’s dynamic program; we continue doing this until convergence. In order to solve this model with recursive preferences an additional step is required. Knowing ct and kt+1 as functions of the aggregate state is not alone enough to know Mt+1 because in addition to consumption growth, it depends on the household’s value function next period: ψ1 −θ − ψ1 Ut+1 Ct+1 . However this problem is not difficult to overcome. After Mt+1 = β Ct 1 1−θ Et [Ut+1 ] 1−θ each simulation step we use beliefs about ct and kt+1 to recursively solve for the household’s value function at each point in the state space. This is again done through value function iteration, however as there are no choice variables this recursion is very quick. We perform the standard checks proposed by Krusell and Smith (1998) to make sure we have found the equilibrium. Although our beliefs are non-parametric, we can still compute an R2 analogous to a regression; all of the R2 are above 0.999. We have also checked that an additional state variable (either the cross-sectional standard deviation of capital or lagged capital) does not alter the results. A.3 Variable Construction Our firm-level control variables are constructed as follows: • W CT A: Working capital is the ratio of Compustat item WCAP to total assets (Compustat item AT). 19 The weight on the old belief is often required to be very high in order for the algorithm to converge. This is because while rational equilibria exist, they are only weakly stable in the sense described by Marcet and Sargent (1989). However, we find that this is only a problem when capital adjustment costs are very close to zero. 32 • RET A: Retained earnings is the ratio of Compustat item RE to total assets. • EBIT T A: EBIT is the ratio of Compustat item EBIT to total assets. • Leverage: Financial leverage is defined as (DLT T + DLC)/AT , where DLT T and DLC are Compustat items for long-term and short-term debt respectively. We also calculate an alternative measure using (DLT T + DLC)/(DLT T + DLC + AT + T XDIT C − P ST K − LT ) but find that empirically the correlation between these two measures is high (95% correlation). Therefore we only report the results based on our main definition of financial leverage. • ST A: Sales is the ratio of Compustat item SALE to total assets. • N IT A: Net income is the ratio of Compustat item NI (for North America) and NICON (for Global) to total assets. • CACL: Current ratio is the ratio of Compustat item ACT (current assets) to LCT (current liabilities). • σ: Stock return volatility is the standard deviation of monthly returns. For US firms, stock returns are retried from CRSP. For firms in other countries, we use data from Compustat Global Security Daily to calculate stock return in month t as RETt = P RCCDt /AJEXDIt × T RF Dt − P RCCDt−1 /AJEXDIt−1 × T RF Dt−1 P RCCDt−1 /AJEXDIt−1 × T RF Dt−1 where P RCCDt is the closing price at month end, AJEXDIt and T RF Dt are the corresponding share and return adjustment factors. • Invest: Investment ratio is defined as the ratio of Compustat item CAPX to lagged PPENT (Property, Plant and Equipment). • M CAP : The market capitalization of a firm at year for is defined as the logarithm of the product of year end closing price (PRCCD) and shares outstanding (CSHOC). • RSIZE: Relative size is defined as the logarithm of the ratio of company’s market capitalization to the total market capitalization in its country at the year end. In other words, it is a company’s weight in its country’s value-weighted market portfolio. • Rm : The return on the value-weighted market portfolio for each country at annual frequency. • Rexcess : The excess return of a firm’s stock is defined as the difference between firm’s raw return (RET ) and the value-weighted market portfolio return (Rm ). 33 4 Credit Spread ∆W LS 3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −3 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure 1: Labor Market Variables and Credit Spread This figure plots the Baa-Aaa credit spread, wage growth (∆W ) and labor share (LS). Wage growth is the growth rate of real wages & salaries per employee; labor share is the total compensation scaled by GDP, and credit spread is the Moody’s Baa-Aaa corporate bond yield. Sample is from 1948 to 2014. The grey bars are the NBER recessions. All variables are standardized to allow for an easy comparison in one plot. 34 Table 1 Descriptive Statistics Panel A reports the descriptive statistics of the variables of interests. Panel B reports the cross correlations of the variables. Credit spread (CS) is the Moody’s Baa-Aaa corporate bond yield. Wage growth (∆W ) is the growth rate of real wages & salaries per employee; labor share (LS) is the aggregate compensation divided by GDP; investment growth (InvGr) is the growth rate of real private nonresidential fixed investment; P/E is the equity price to earnings ratio from Shiller; term spread (TS) is the long-term government bond yield (10 year) minus the short-term government bond yield (1 year); financial leverage (FinLev) is book value of nonfinancial credit instruments divided by the sum of the market value of equities and credit instruments of nonfinancial corporate sector. Market volatility (MktVol) is the annual volatility of CRSP value-weighted market premium; spot rate (SoptRate) is the real 1 year government bond yield from Shiller’s webpage. GDP growth (GDPGr) is the real GDP growth from NIPA. Wage growth, labor share, investment growth, term spread, credit spread, and spot rate are in percentage terms. Sample is from 1948 to 2014. Panel A Summary Statistics ∆W LS InvGr P/E TS FinLev MktVol SpotRate CS Mean s.d AC 1.5 55.29 4.46 16.58 1.37 0.44 0.14 1.57 0.95 1.42 1.23 6.31 16.16 1.28 0.09 0.05 2.73 0.4 0.47 0.86 0.2 0.82 0.44 0.88 0.33 0.56 0.74 Panel B Cross Correlations GDPGr ∆W LS ∆W LS InvGr P/E TS FinLev MktVol SpotRate 0.41 -0.14 -0.1 InvGr 0.76 0.2 -0.06 P/E 0.07 0.2 0.21 0.06 TS -0.16 0.01 -0.21 -0.29 -0.07 FinLev -0.01 -0.54 0.25 -0.15 -0.18 0.09 MktVol -0.32 -0.2 0.32 -0.32 0.11 -0.02 0.38 SpotRate -0.12 0.16 0.3 -0.07 0.12 0.02 0.19 0.08 CS -0.51 -0.42 0.22 -0.49 -0.08 0.25 0.62 0.45 35 0.3 Table 2 Labor Market Variables and Credit Spread This table reports the predictive regression of variables of interests for credit spread. Credit spread (CS) is the Moody’s Baa-Aaa corporate bond yield. Wage growth (∆W ) is the growth rate of real wages & salaries per employee; labor share (LS) is the aggregate compensation divided by GDP; investment growth (InvGr) is the growth rate of real private nonresidential fixed investment; P/E is the equity price to earnings ratio from Shiller; term spread (TS) is the long-term government bond yield (10 year) minus the short-term government bond yield (1 year); financial leverage (FinLev) is book value of nonfinancial credit instruments divided by the sum of the market value of equities and credit instruments of nonfinancial corporate sector. Market volatility (MktVol) is the annual volatility of CRSP value-weighted market premium; spot rate (SR) is the real 1 year government bond yield from Shiller’s webpage. GDP growth (GDPGr) is the real GDP growth from NIPA. [t] are heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent t-statistics (Newey-West). Sample is from 1948 to 2014. Panel A Wage growth ∆W [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] -15.4 -14.47 -14.82 -8.08 -13.04 -14.86 -15.29 -16.67 -4.29 -4.15 -4.41 -3.75 -2.86 -4.32 -4.92 -4.9 -3.68 -3.4 LS 8.52 0.14 3.13 0.08 InvGr -0.63 0.53 -1.24 1.43 FinLev 2.17 1.12 4.77 2.26 MktVol 2.84 0.56 6.35 1.29 P/E 0 0.01 -0.49 1.55 TS -5.36 -10.61 -1.62 -4.06 SpotRate 4.63 0.26 2.61 0.41 lag CS 0.67 7.74 2 R 0.28 0.34 0.28 0.42 36 0.41 0.28 0.3 0.37 0.74 Labor Market Variables and Credit Spread (Contd) Panel B Labor Share LS [1] 10.66 2.15 InvGr [2] 10.33 2.09 -1.2 -2.45 FinLev [3] 6.33 1.46 [4] 6.33 1.45 [5] 11.14 2.04 [6] 9.83 2.19 [7] 9.28 1.83 2.71 5.73 MktVol 3.14 4.68 P/E -0.01 -1.06 TS -3.79 -0.71 SpotRate 2.24 0.98 lag CS R2 0.09 0.11 0.4 0.24 37 0.13 0.09 0.10 [8] 0.08 0.24 0.34 0.76 1.67 3.2 0.32 0.75 0.01 2.11 -11.53 -3.93 -0.46 -0.95 0.7 8.1 0.73 Table 3: No. of annual observations with non-missing labor expenses, hiring, and EDF This table reports the number of annual (firm-year) observations for each individual country. In particular, the number of annual observations with non-missing labor expenses (Compustat variable XLR), hiring (Compustat variable EMP), and the EDF is reported in the column titled “# Obs w XLR/EMP/EDF”. The percentage of observations with non-missing labor expenses, hiring, and EDF is reported for each country (column titled “Within country % of obs w XLR/EMP/EDF”). The last column titled “For all countries % of obs w XLR/EMP/EDF” presents the percentage of observations with non-missing labor expenses, hiring, and EDF contributed by each country to the final sample of all observations with non-missing labor expenses, hiring, and EDF (total # of obs = 63274). Start Year End Year All Obs # Obs w XLR Country Region: Europe Austria 1992 2011 1425 1318 Belgium 1992 2011 1769 1597 Denmark 1992 2011 2244 2048 Finland 1992 2011 1995 1897 France 1992 2011 10855 10055 Germany 1992 2011 11151 10005 Greece 1994 2011 2443 1443 Italy 1992 2011 3631 3425 Netherlands 1992 2011 2756 2492 Norway 1992 2011 3021 2607 Poland 1994 2011 3722 2699 Portugal 1992 2011 857 771 Spain 1992 2011 2216 2149 Sweden 1992 2011 5712 4798 Switzerland 1992 2011 3485 3176 United Kingdom 1992 2011 26546 21034 Region: North America Canada 1992 2011 23575 3228 United States 1992 2011 135632 9588 Region: Japan Japan 1992 2011 50011 2 Region: Asia Pacific (ex. Japan) Australia 1992 2011 19885 11285 China 1992 2011 27448 1210 Hong Kong 1992 2011 3468 2363 India 1992 2011 29938 26949 Indonesia 1992 2011 4017 2705 Malaysia 1992 2011 12457 7986 New Zealand 1992 2011 1633 563 Philippines 1992 2011 2198 1296 Singapore 1992 2011 7903 5210 S. Korea 1993 2011 8701 75 Taiwan 1992 2011 14520 214 Thailand 1992 2011 5749 3171 Region: Other America (ex. Canada and U.S.) Argentina 1992 2011 934 352 Brazil 1992 2011 4558 2039 Chile 1992 2011 2171 346 Mexico 1992 2011 1674 282 Region: Middle East Israel 1992 2011 2975 2058 Pakistan 1994 2011 2814 2033 Turkey 1992 2011 1905 854 Region: Africa South Africa 1992 2011 3761 1893 Total 451755 157216 Within For all # Obs w EMP # Obs w EDF # Obs w XLR/EMP/EDF Country % of obs w XLR/EMP/EDF Countries % of obs w XLR/EMP/EDF 1152 1348 1844 1716 7122 7884 1073 2261 2414 2189 304 495 1580 3296 2721 20157 981 1224 1457 1544 8105 7200 1724 2584 2085 1900 1457 643 1674 3041 2378 18954 796 932 1216 1342 5393 5053 498 1631 1800 1436 135 403 1273 2045 1867 15372 55.86 52.69 54.19 67.27 49.68 45.31 20.38 44.92 65.31 47.53 3.63 47.02 57.45 35.80 53.57 57.91 1.26 1.47 1.92 2.12 8.52 7.99 0.79 2.58 2.84 2.27 0.21 0.64 2.01 3.23 2.95 24.29 10989 115652 11908 69610 975 4747 4.14 3.50 1.54 7.50 33883 42403 0 0.00 0.00 4515 1031 1969 5927 2440 4267 337 1191 2425 62 213 2071 12018 10755 1812 6603 2377 9084 1029 995 5211 5916 10868 3240 2385 486 1019 2786 1169 3024 147 551 1591 32 20 908 11.99 1.77 29.38 9.31 29.10 24.28 9.00 25.07 20.13 0.37 0.14 15.79 3.77 0.77 1.61 4.40 1.85 4.78 0.23 0.87 2.51 0.05 0.03 1.44 79 956 381 646 667 671 1303 993 36 115 49 63 3.85 2.52 2.26 3.76 0.06 0.18 0.08 0.10 711 524 906 1008 993 1443 362 242 481 12.17 8.60 25.25 0.57 0.38 0.76 1700 2330 894 23.77 1.41 250431 260188 63274 38 Table 4: Summary statistics on labor expenses and EDF This table reports the summary statistics on EDF, labor expenses growth, and labor share. We define labor expenses growth as ∆XLR = (XLRt − XLRt−1 )/XLRt−1 and labor share as LSt = XLRt /Salet for year t. We report the mean and standard deviation of these variables within each country; we also report the same summary statistics for all countries in the last row “Total”. EDF ∆XLR LS Country Mean St.D. Mean St.D. Mean St.D. Region: Europe Austria 1.57 3.90 0.01 0.35 0.26 0.12 Belgium 1.25 3.14 0.06 0.46 0.22 0.15 Denmark 1.36 3.49 0.11 0.38 0.27 0.17 Finland 1.03 2.81 0.04 0.36 0.27 0.16 France 1.94 4.15 0.04 0.35 0.28 0.18 Germany 2.47 5.45 0.07 0.39 0.27 0.17 Greece 3.72 6.10 0.05 0.42 0.17 0.13 Italy 1.38 3.21 0.01 0.39 0.20 0.12 Netherlands 1.30 3.71 0.06 0.36 0.26 0.17 Norway 2.50 5.50 0.17 0.41 0.26 0.17 Poland 2.40 4.80 0.19 0.37 0.18 0.13 Portugal 2.27 4.52 0.00 0.32 0.19 0.14 Spain 0.85 2.38 0.03 0.31 0.21 0.13 Sweden 1.74 4.22 0.15 0.39 0.32 0.21 Switzerland 0.82 2.74 0.06 0.27 0.26 0.13 United Kingdom 2.07 4.50 0.20 0.53 0.23 0.18 Region: North America Canada 4.13 7.59 0.18 0.51 0.26 0.20 United States 2.78 6.13 0.10 0.25 0.30 0.18 Region: Japan Japan 2.31 4.23 0.07 NA 0.27 0.01 Region: Asia Pacific (ex. Japan) Australia 2.50 5.16 0.56 1.20 0.26 0.24 China 0.87 1.74 0.24 0.35 0.09 0.08 Hong Kong 1.79 3.73 0.31 0.67 0.13 0.13 India 4.03 6.34 0.23 0.54 0.10 0.11 Indonesia 6.70 9.50 0.28 0.71 0.08 0.08 Malaysia 2.98 5.44 0.09 0.31 0.12 0.09 New Zealand 1.62 4.23 0.12 0.42 0.21 0.16 Philippines 5.69 9.01 0.18 0.63 0.13 0.14 Singapore 2.59 4.41 0.15 0.47 0.15 0.12 S. Korea 4.15 6.51 0.24 0.80 0.07 0.09 Taiwan 1.74 3.29 0.27 0.51 0.10 0.12 Thailand 3.52 6.76 0.08 0.25 0.13 0.10 Region: Other America (ex. Canada and U.S.) Argentina 4.38 7.18 0.29 0.46 0.13 0.09 Brazil 3.68 7.06 0.23 0.58 0.11 0.12 Chile 1.55 4.17 0.16 0.38 0.11 0.10 Mexico 2.91 6.12 0.45 1.21 0.04 0.08 Region: Middle East Israel 1.92 4.13 0.28 0.79 0.15 0.16 Pakistan 5.82 8.92 0.22 0.53 0.07 0.06 Turkey 1.68 2.81 0.23 0.58 0.08 0.08 Region: Africa South Africa 3.60 6.98 0.30 0.73 0.17 0.12 Total 2.57 5.3939 0.18 0.56 0.19 0.17 Table 5: Time-series correlation between labor expenses and EDF This table reports the distribution of the firm-level time-series correlation between labor expenses growth and EDF (Corr(∆XLR, EDF )), and the correlation between labor share and EDF (Corr(LS, EDF )). For every firm, we calculate Corr(∆XLR, EDF ) and Corr(LS, EDF ) using its time-series observations. Then we report the mean and standard deviation of these two correlations within each country; we also report the same summary statistics for all countries in the last row “Total”. The t-stat is for testing whether Corr(∆XLR, EDF ) = 0 or Corr(LS, EDF ) = 0. Corr(∆XLR, EDF ) Country Mean St.D. No of firms t-stat Region: Europe Austria -0.34 0.48 102 -7.08 Belgium -0.15 0.50 121 -3.20 Denmark -0.23 0.45 137 -6.02 Finland -0.21 0.38 139 -6.45 France -0.21 0.46 822 -12.73 Germany -0.25 0.45 723 -14.68 Greece -0.16 0.61 152 -3.24 Italy -0.13 0.50 272 -4.46 Netherlands -0.18 0.50 189 -5.07 Norway -0.26 0.55 212 -6.91 Poland -0.27 0.60 195 -6.24 Portugal -0.17 0.46 60 -2.83 Spain -0.15 0.45 155 -4.07 Sweden -0.24 0.54 311 -7.94 Switzerland -0.22 0.44 212 -7.26 United Kingdom -0.23 0.51 1917 -19.84 Region: North America Canada -0.17 0.67 268 -4.07 United States -0.17 0.64 712 -6.96 Region: Japan Japan Region: Asia Pacific (ex. Japan) Australia -0.19 0.53 1265 -12.78 China -0.14 0.57 87 -2.35 Hong Kong -0.16 0.51 170 -4.03 India -0.20 0.54 1279 -13.31 Indonesia -0.11 0.51 214 -3.01 Malaysia -0.16 0.51 885 -9.70 New Zealand -0.26 0.60 92 -4.22 Philippines -0.03 0.49 87 -0.61 Singapore -0.16 0.52 519 -6.77 S. Korea 0.23 0.75 9 0.92 Taiwan 0.97 1 Thailand -0.10 0.58 289 -2.95 Region: Other America (ex. Canada and U.S.) Argentina -0.03 0.56 38 -0.34 Brazil -0.11 0.65 78 -1.45 Chile 0.05 0.95 39 0.31 Mexico -0.04 0.82 22 -0.21 Region: Middle East Israel -0.19 0.52 107 -3.83 Pakistan -0.02 0.53 103 -0.38 Turkey -0.17 0.58 105 -2.97 Region: Africa South Africa -0.20 0.59 192 -4.67 40 Total -0.19 0.53 12280 -39.89 Corr(LS, EDF ) St.D. No of firms t-stat 0.09 0.02 0.08 0.20 0.16 0.16 0.19 0.17 0.11 0.13 0.10 0.09 0.27 0.21 0.11 0.15 0.54 0.58 0.51 0.44 0.53 0.53 0.59 0.53 0.52 0.55 0.59 0.49 0.49 0.55 0.50 0.58 103 121 135 139 827 721 165 272 191 209 198 60 158 309 209 1895 1.71 0.30 1.87 5.41 8.46 7.94 4.15 5.31 2.86 3.28 2.34 1.48 6.79 6.53 3.26 10.89 0.05 0.09 0.74 0.68 117 692 0.77 3.63 0.05 0.12 0.16 0.13 -0.07 0.06 -0.02 0.01 0.09 0.00 0.74 0.04 0.66 0.61 0.54 0.57 0.55 0.54 0.60 0.56 0.52 0.85 0.70 0.55 1004 88 175 1277 223 908 91 89 530 14 7 300 2.53 1.92 3.85 8.06 -2.02 3.28 -0.24 0.19 3.96 0.00 2.79 1.30 0.21 0.16 0.01 0.38 0.54 0.63 0.87 0.74 42 79 77 37 2.48 2.32 0.06 3.16 0.05 -0.04 0.07 0.56 0.51 0.61 109 104 118 0.92 -0.75 1.26 0.14 0.60 211 3.40 0.11 0.58 12004 21.29 Mean Table 6: Labor expenses and default risk This table reports the results of cross-sectional regressions using labor expenses to predict default risk. Panel A reports the results based on labor expenses growth (∆XLR). We regress the default risk (EDF ) in year t+1 on labor expenses growth and other control variables in year t. We also interact the labor expenses with a labor expense rigidity measure Rigid. To calculate Rigid, we first calculate the time series volatility of labor expenses growth for each individual firm. Then we define a firm’s labor expenses as rigid if its labor expense volatility is below 25% percentile in its country (i.e., Rigid = 1), otherwise we set Rigid = 0. The other variables include leverage (Leverage), stock volatility (σ), working capital (W CT A), retained earnings (RET A), EBIT (EBIT T A), sales (ST A), net income (N IT A), current asset to liability (CACL), investment (Invest), stock excess return (Rexcess ), relative size (RSIZE), market return (Rm ), market capitalization (M CAP ). Panel B reports the results based on labor share (LS). We also interact the labor share with a indicator variable for rapid increase in labor share LSIncrease . To calculate LSIncrease , we first calculate the change in labor share for each firm-year observations. Then we define a labor share as experiencing rapid increase if its change is above below 75% percentile in its country for that year (i.e., LSIncrease = 1), otherwise we set LSIncrease = 0. All the other variables are the same as in Panel A. The details of the variable constructions can be found in the appendix. All the results are estimated using Fama-MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions. The t-statistics reported in the parentheses below each coefficient estimate are heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent t-statistics (Newey-West). Statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10% are indicated with ***, **, and * respectively. Panel A: (1) ∆XLR (2) All countries (3) (4) -1.10*** -0.95*** -1.08*** (-7.84) (-7.22) (-11.25) Rigid × ∆XLR -2.65*** (-6.67) Control variables: Leverage σ W CT A RET A EBIT T A ST A N IT A CACL Invest Continued on Next Page. . . (5) (6) European countries (7) (8) Other countries (9) (10) -1.00*** -0.91*** -0.85*** -1.01*** -0.94*** -0.81*** (-11.03) (-14.08) (-12.87) (-10.81) (-9.94) (-3.11) -1.44*** -1.24*** -1.04** (-3.72) (-3.99) (-2.42) 5.45*** 5.45*** 4.74*** 4.72*** (4.75) (4.73) (4.10) (4.07) 5.96*** 5.94*** 4.75*** 4.73*** (18.66) (18.62) (13.41) (13.36) -1.74*** -1.74*** (-7.15) (-7.12) 0.02 0.02 (0.28) (0.27) -2.18** -2.16** (-2.18) (-2.14) 0.41*** 0.41*** (7.52) (7.68) -0.88** -0.89** (-2.82) (-2.82) -0.05*** -0.05*** (-7.93) (-8.01) 0.04 0.04 41 3.65*** (4.00) 4.18*** (8.70) -1.71*** (-4.44) 0.01 (0.06) -2.28 (-1.39) 0.39*** (6.91) -2.04** (-2.30) -0.05*** (-6.80) 0.05 3.65*** (3.97) 4.16*** (8.79) -1.70*** (-4.51) 0.01 (0.06) -2.25 (-1.35) 0.40*** (7.17) -2.04** (-2.27) -0.06*** (-6.15) 0.05 6.19*** (4.49) 5.82*** (4.57) -1.64*** (-11.13) -0.47 (-1.19) -1.77* (-2.09) 0.41*** (18.03) -0.37** (-2.25) -0.21** (-2.11) -0.13** -0.77*** (-2.98) -2.21*** (-4.33) 6.14*** (4.40) 5.78*** (4.56) -1.64*** (-10.85) -0.46 (-1.18) -1.77* (-2.05) 0.42*** (19.26) -0.38** (-2.18) -0.21** (-2.12) -0.13** Table 6 – Continued Rexcess RSIZE Rm M CAP Obs Avg. R2 45588 0.007 45588 0.010 (1) (2) Panel B: LS LSIncrease × LS 1.43** (2.09) 45385 0.196 45385 0.197 All countries (3) (4) (1.22) -3.60*** (-16.23) -0.23*** (-3.81) -2.01** (-2.49) -0.09 (-1.41) (1.20) -3.59*** (-16.21) -0.23*** (-3.81) -1.96** (-2.39) -0.09 (-1.37) 45385 0.301 45385 0.302 (5) (6) (1.15) (1.16) (-2.16) -2.90*** -2.88*** -2.49 (-11.98) (-12.12) (-1.40) -0.11** -0.12** -0.30*** (-2.24) (-2.28) (-7.36) -2.60*** -2.53*** 3.92 (-6.51) (-6.47) (0.95) -0.26** -0.25** -0.11*** (-2.59) (-2.56) (-4.34) 31061 0.316 31061 0.318 European countries (7) (8) 14324 0.362 (-2.23) -2.47 (-1.37) -0.30*** (-6.84) 4.45 (1.09) -0.11*** (-4.32) 14324 0.363 Other countries (9) (10) 0.22 1.32*** 0.61*** -0.40 -0.72 -0.45 (0.32) (7.00) (3.24) (-0.60) (-1.01) (-0.99) 2.81*** 1.69*** 0.81*** (9.92) (11.43) (10.44) -0.61 (-1.22) 0.43*** (3.36) -0.46 (-0.56) -1.32 (-1.68) 2.34*** (3.22) 5.26*** 5.27*** 4.14*** 4.15*** (5.05) (5.10) (4.36) (4.38) 6.08*** 6.01*** 4.66*** 4.64*** (14.47) (14.39) (11.60) (11.64) -1.52*** -1.53*** (-7.49) (-7.46) -0.09 -0.09 (-0.87) (-0.92) -4.92*** -4.80*** (-4.29) (-4.22) 0.41*** 0.41*** (7.73) (7.88) -1.74** -1.72** (-2.34) (-2.33) -0.04*** -0.04*** (-3.91) (-4.24) -0.01 -0.01 (-0.27) (-0.44) -3.60*** -3.57*** (-10.51) (-10.44) -0.22*** -0.22*** 3.22*** (3.88) 4.16*** (7.80) -1.48*** (-4.63) -0.10 (-0.50) -4.40*** (-3.26) 0.39*** (7.54) -2.48** (-2.26) -0.03*** (-4.06) -0.05 (-1.23) -2.93*** (-10.74) -0.10** 5.12*** (3.98) 5.67*** (4.23) -1.42*** (-11.20) -0.41 (-1.43) -6.86*** (-4.49) 0.45*** (12.52) -1.85** (-2.11) -0.28* (-2.05) -0.07 (-0.65) -2.02 (-0.94) -0.30*** 5.20*** (3.97) 5.63*** (4.13) -1.41*** (-10.42) -0.41 (-1.44) -6.46*** (-4.41) 0.50*** (10.31) -1.87** (-2.11) -0.30** (-2.10) -0.08 (-0.78) -1.88 (-0.86) -0.31*** Control variables: Leverage σ W CT A RET A EBIT T A ST A N IT A CACL Invest Rexcess RSIZE Continued on Next Page. . . 42 3.21*** (3.91) 4.16*** (7.77) -1.48*** (-4.56) -0.10 (-0.50) -4.50*** (-3.40) 0.39*** (7.33) -2.48** (-2.24) -0.03*** (-4.07) -0.05 (-1.22) -2.93*** (-10.73) -0.10** Table 6 – Continued Rm M CAP Obs Avg. R2 43470 0.007 43470 0.014 43338 0.192 43338 0.196 (-4.14) -2.37*** (-4.55) -0.08 (-1.49) (-4.17) -2.42*** (-4.84) -0.08 (-1.48) 43338 0.312 43338 0.313 43 (-2.34) (-2.37) -2.80*** -2.88*** (-5.95) (-5.82) -0.25** -0.25** (-2.63) (-2.64) 29867 0.327 29867 0.327 (-6.08) 4.17 (0.81) -0.06 (-1.71) (-7.01) 3.72 (0.80) -0.05 (-1.22) 13471 0.379 13471 0.386 Table 7: Impact of labor expenses cutting and default risk This table reports the results of analyzing whether labor expenses cutting in year t affects the impact of labor expenses on default risk in year t + 1. We interact labor expenses growth (∆XLR) and labor share (LS) with a labor firing measure XLRCut and test whether the interaction term has any impact on the predictability of default risk (EDF ) in year t + 1. We set XLRCut= 1 if the labor expenses growth is below 25% percentile of its distribution in each country (this percentile is negative for most countries with an average of -4% and a median of -4.4%), and set XLRCut= 0 otherwise. The regressions are similar to those in Table 6. The control variables are the same as in Table 6. All the results are estimated using Fama-MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions. The t-statistics reported in the parentheses below each coefficient estimate are heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent t-statistics (Newey-West). Statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10% are indicated with ***, **, and * respectively. ∆XLR XLRCut × ∆XLR (1) -0.32*** (-3.85) -4.32*** (-7.43) LS XLRCut × LS Control variables: Leverage σ 5.51*** (4.72) 5.71*** (18.11) W CT A RET A EBIT T A ST A N IT A CACL Invest Rexcess RSIZE Rm M CAP Obs Avg. R2 45385 0.204 All countries (2) (3) -0.29** (-2.42) -3.51*** (-7.77) 0.48* (1.76) 3.37*** (11.84) 4.74*** (4.06) 4.59*** (12.84) -1.73*** (-6.99) 0.03 (0.35) -2.08** (-2.11) 0.43*** (7.94) -0.87*** (-2.97) -0.05*** (-9.67) 0.03 (0.75) -3.58*** (-17.14) -0.23*** (-3.80) -1.99** (-2.37) -0.08 (-1.30) 45385 0.307 5.19*** (4.90) 5.93*** (14.64) 43338 0.201 -0.89 (-1.26) 2.12*** (14.70) European countries (5) (6) -0.37*** (-4.03) -2.98*** (-7.26) -0.82* (-1.75) 1.88*** (13.24) Other countries (7) (8) 0.12 (0.31) -6.16*** (-3.50) -0.95 (-1.27) 2.28*** (4.35) 4.11*** (4.25) 4.59*** (11.65) -1.54*** (-7.65) -0.08 (-0.83) -4.72*** (-4.25) 0.41*** (8.02) -1.70** (-2.36) -0.04*** (-4.13) 0.02 (0.60) -3.61*** (-11.14) -0.22*** (-4.11) -2.40*** (-4.48) -0.08 (-1.47) 43338 0.316 3.65*** (3.96) 4.05*** (8.74) -1.66*** (-4.45) 0.03 (0.14) -2.16 (-1.31) 0.41*** (7.36) -2.06** (-2.31) -0.06*** (-6.90) 0.03 (0.75) -2.91*** (-11.75) -0.11** (-2.13) -2.58*** (-6.57) -0.25** (-2.54) 31061 0.322 6.09*** (4.20) 5.61*** (4.46) -1.61*** (-10.25) -0.42 (-1.16) -1.79** (-2.17) 0.48*** (13.32) -0.40** (-2.56) -0.22** (-2.15) -0.23** (-2.76) -3.18** (-2.43) -0.30*** (-6.99) 4.81 (1.03) -0.11*** (-4.08) 14324 0.371 (4) 44 3.28*** (3.92) 4.13*** (7.76) -1.65*** (-4.28) -0.11 (-0.54) -3.93*** (-3.18) 0.39*** (7.03) -2.26** (-2.34) -0.03*** (-3.16) -0.02 (-0.34) -2.95*** (-11.80) -0.10** (-2.27) -2.72*** (-5.80) -0.25** (-2.64) 29867 0.329 5.08*** (3.96) 5.64*** (4.26) -1.42*** (-11.34) -0.42 (-1.42) -6.72*** (-4.36) 0.44*** (13.05) -1.80** (-2.10) -0.28* (-2.08) -0.00 (-0.02) -2.02 (-0.94) -0.30*** (-6.43) 3.83 (0.76) -0.06 (-1.60) 13471 0.384 Table 8 Calibration The benchmark model parameters are listed in this table. Parameter Description Benchmark Preferences β θ ψ Time Preference 0.98 Risk Aversion 8 IES 2 Production (1 − α)ρ α + ρ − αρ Labor Share 0.42 Returns to Scale 0.87 1 1−η Labor Capital Elasticity 0.50 δ υ f µ τ pexp Depreciation 0.025 Capital Adj. Cost 5 Operating Cost 0.019 Probability No Resetting 0.90 Corporate tax rate 0.3 Debt expiration probability 0.025 45 Table 9 Aggregate Macroeconomic Moments This table compares macroeconomic moments from the data to the model. All reported correlations are with HP filtered GDP (y) except for growth rates of variables, in these cases correlations are reported with the growth rate of GDP. In the data, y is real GDP, c is consumption, i is private non-residential fixed investment plus durables, and w is compensation per hour. The 1 = 0.5), model in Panels B has a calibrated elasticity of substitution between labor and capital ( 1−η exp wage rigidity (µ = 0.9) and long-term debt (p = 0.025). Note that the table reports the volatility of quantities relative to GDP volatility. The volatility of HP filtered GDP in the data is 3.55%, the model is calibrated to match this number. Panel A: Data x σ(x) σ(y) ρ(x, y) AC(x) σ(∆x) σ(∆y) ρ(∆x, ∆y) AC(∆x) y c i w 1.00 0.51 3.04 0.44 1.00 0.72 0.07 0.60 0.57 0.53 0.55 0.36 1.00 0.53 2.84 0.49 1.00 0.79 0.27 0.61 0.54 0.50 0.39 0.32 x σ(x) σ(y) ρ(x, y) AC(x) σ(∆x) σ(∆y) ρ(∆x, ∆y) AC(∆x) y c i w 1 0.74 3.17 0.49 1 0.87 0.83 0.82 0.6 0.6 0.51 0.71 1 0.82 2.84 0.66 1 0.89 0.77 0.85 0.67 0.72 0.38 0.88 Panel B: Model Table 10 Unconditional Financial Moments This table presents the unconditional financial moments of the data and the model. Rf is the riskfree rate, Rexc is the market excess return, SR is the sharpe ratio, Lev is the aggregate financial leverage, CS is credit spread in percentage term with the range of estimate in the data. DefProb is the percentage default probability from Giesecke et al (2011). Data Model E[Rf ] σ(Rf ) E[Rexc ] σ(Rexc ) 0.69 3.81 6.84 19.89 2.88 2.11 4.49 8.85 46 SR Lev 0.34 0.44 0.51 0.31 CS DefProb 0.38-4.19 0.3-3.99 2.91 1.27 Table 11 Simulated Labor Market Variables and Credit Spread This table reports the predictive regression of variables of interests for credit spread in the mode. [t] are heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent t-statistics (Newey-West). ∆W [t] LS [t] Adj. R2 Panel A Data -15.4 -4.15 10.66 2.15 0.28 0.09 47 Panel B Model -11.03 -5.07 10.19 4.50 0.36 0.24