if m I 5 f ? I ' " - • * o, rr ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT DOUBLING STRATEGIES, LIMITED LIABILITY, AND THE DEFINITION OF CONTINUOUS TIME Mark Latham June 1980 WP 1131-80 1 I ^ lb revised November 1981 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 DOUBLING STRATEGIES, LIMITED LIABILITY, AND THE DEFINITION OF CONTINUOUS TIME Mark Latham June 1980 WP 1131-80. | 98" lb revised November 1981 Support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada and from M.I.T. is gratefully acknowledged. My thanks to Robert C. Merton for suggesting this problem and the approach to solving it, and to Fischer Black, Robert Jarrow, Stewart Myers, and Richard Ruback for helpful suggest ions The principal difference between this and the August 1981 revision is the addition of a convergence proof on page 20. to the middle paragraph of page 23, footnote. Consequent adjustments were made to footnote 8, and to this title page August 1981 DOUBLING STRATEGIES, LIMITED LIABILITY, AND THE DEFINITION OF CONTINUOUS TIME Mark Latham ABSTRACT The assumptions yield many in arbitrage profits to underlies amends used these preserving assumptions "bet-doubling" a Black-Scholes the option to Black-Scholes the continuous-time rule out result. continuous-time corresponding relationship discrete-time approaches zero. models strategy. valuation This or by can seem This doubling, be paper while achieved by requiring that must be the relationship, as the to One such model technique. arbitrage postulating limited liability for investors, valid finance limit time of by any the increment I. Introduction What assumptions mean, we do and continuous-time of should what finance we mean, by models? I standard the basic referring am the to following assumptions: 1. Continuous — time Time is indexed by the real line some (or subinterval thereof), any investor can trade at any point or points in time, and markets clear at all times. 2. — Unrestricted borrowing at the market rate of interest There is no limit on the amount that an investor can borrow, and the rate does not increase with amount borrowed. 3. Stochastic processes for stock prices that have ex ante uncertainty over every subinterval of time, no matter how small. H. Price-takers — Each investor acts as if his actions have no effect on prices. It literally may they 'bet-doubling' arbitrage seem quite imply a strategy, profits. clear what contradiction: using Markets one cannot assumptions those stock Kreps and clear the when mean, shows [1979] riskless there is that arbitrage opportunity, so the standard assumptions above contradict each other are not "internally consistent". This is a serious a yields asset, an taken but — matter, contradictory assumptions tend to produce contradictory implications, they since which can describe possibly not consistency internal economy; actual an is Formal algebraic statement of assumptions and theorems can not imperative. only lessen the ambiguities of statement in English, but may also help the for search proofs internal of rather, taken in this paper; Such consistency. approach an pursue the less ambitious goal of I in not is amending the assumptions to eliminate the arbitrage from doubling strategies. The development of continuous-time enlightening many results that could techniques in finance has led not derived be including Merton [1971] and Black and Scholes [1973]. the claim that the basic assumptions are results of these models are not valid. I discrete in time, One might wonder contradictory implies while eliminating those that not. do In the valid; this paper amends the assumptions so as to preserve the results that reasonable if that believe the results are to seem particular, the Black-Scholes (B-S) model for pricing options is shown to hold under the new assumptions. There are While problem. prohibit Kreps ' possible several imposing either approaches credit arbitrage strategy, I to limits rectifying or discrete doubling the trading would argue that these are unrealistic and would not in general preserve the classical results. Instead, I replace the assumption of unlimited riskless borrowing by an institutional structure in which all loans have a limited liability investors feature: required to repay more than their total assets. In cannot this setting the be Kreps doubling strategy no longer produces arbitrage profits, but the B-S option pricing formula problem lies in still holds. defining a An alternative continuous-time solution economy as to the the doubling limit of a sequence of discrete-time economies, as trading the interval approaches Merton [1975] argues that the only valid continuous-time results zero. those that hold in the limit of discrete time. The doubling strategy while the B-S formula is shown to hold in the limit. this test, are fails Finally, the most sensible solution may be to combine this limiting definition with the limited-liability loan assumption. Section II reviews the Black-Scholes economy and two derivations Section III outlines the Kreps doubling strategy. the B-S formula. Section IV proves the B-S formula in a world of limited-liability demand loans, shows the flaw of doubling in such a world. using (limited-liability) non -demand section section In V. VI, I look is at the discrete-time economies with no limit on formula in such Section VII a analyzed and rejected continuous-time liability; a that the B-S formula also holds proof of the discrete-time economies with limited-liability loans. the in in limit world is presented, and doubling is shown not to shows and feasibility of doubling The loans of of B-S "work". limit of Section VII gives a summary and conclusions. II. the Black-Scholes Economy This section is a brief review, with slight changes, arguments in Black and Scholes [1973] and Merton [1977]. the simplest economy possible for highlight the aspects of special the purposes interest; generalized to more complex economies. no of I this doubt the of the main will work with paper, so results as to can be Let us assume: 1. Capital markets operate (and clear) continuously. 2. Capital markets are perfect — (a) all investors are price-takers; (b) there are no taxes or transaction costs; (c) there are no restrictions on borrowing or selling short; (d) there are no indivisibilities. 3. Investors prefer more to les3. 4. There is riskless asset with a a continuous yield r that is constant through time. 5. There is stock a paying dividends, no whose price S follows the geometric Brownian motion process dS/S where is time, t Z = jjdt + odZ is a standard Wiener process, known and p and 6 are and constant through time. 6. There is a European call option on the stock, maturity date T, option will E, and market price C. Black and Scholes state that the with exercise price depend only on "under the price those assumptions, of the variables that are taken to be known constants." stock (p. and 641) the value of time and They did on not although their derivation of the B-S formula depends prove this assertion, Therefore, on it. also discuss I a proof of the B-S result that does not start by assuming it. In buying the B-S derivation an instantaneously riskless hedge is formed by one call sailing and shares F. stock. of Using stochastic calculus, the rate of change in the hedge's value (in dollars per unit time) is found to be K 1 — with probability one F ss s 2 + F t This must equal the riskless return no uncertainty. F„S)r (F - on investment, 2 giving the partial differential equation: , ^T^S 2 rF S - rF + s F = . fc Solving this subject to the boundary conditions F(S,t) max[0,S-E] = F(0,t) and and a boundedness condition F/S ^ 1 = , as S-*oo , gives the B-S call option valuation formula: F(S.t) = SNCd^ - Ee" r(T_t) N(d 2 ) where N(d) is the cumulative normal distribution function, 2 log(3/E) + (r+|o- )(T-t) d = , and 1 d For 2 = - d 0" v/f^t . 1 future reference, let us denote this particular solution for F (i.e. the B-S formula) by G(S,t). Merton [1977] shows that if C ever differs from G(S,t) then there will This provides be an arbitrage opportunity. a proof of the formula assuming that the only relevant variables are S and If C(0) t. without G(S(0),0), > the arbitrage is achieved by selling one call, pocketing the difference C(0) and investing G(S(0),0) - G(S(0),0), at maturity G(S(0),0) shares with T certainty, in paying thus by continuously borrowing enough stock. of can It shown be that off this maturity it will be worth G(S,T) at the call. He extra money to hold portfolio is always worth G(S,t), even as S and particular, max[0,S-E] such a way as to return strategy t invests G,,(S(t),t) ensures that his change through time. In = max[0,S-E], which must equal the call's market value at maturity, C(T), no matter how wildly it may have been priced in the meantime. that he sold at t The = So he will be able to pay off the 0. Black-Scholes pricing methodology has option fruitful in modern finance theory. valuation of different market these timing skills, extensive call the on the line the the measurement liabilities, analysis of bank resting structures remarkably Among its various applications are types of corporate and proven commitments. Black-Scholes 2/ foundation, of With the underlying assumptions deserve some careful attention. Trouble in Paradise: III. the Problem of Doubling Strategies The strong assumptions of the original Black-Scholes economy sheltered the analysis rates, from many nonexistent rates, and so forth. possible variance unknown variance stochastic interest real-world confusions: rates, jump processes, Then, armed with an understanding of what it takes to subsequent research has tackled these more make the hedging argument work, In this era of expanding frontiers, one general problems with much success. may be surprised to learn that back in the garden where it all began there the bet-doubling strategy outlined by Kreps is still a snake in the grass: pp. UO-41] [1979, shows that the way self-contradictory. He shows a profits, from which we arbitrage impossible. Start any for must section in investor conclude to are above, II, make limitless market-clearing that is Here is a version of his argument: at t = investor An 0. probability one, by the time this, assumptions knowing p, rate of return x o", > r and t = make to $1 a probability with more, or with no investment of his own. first calculates he r, 1, going is q To and > x with probability at least q. given in the Appendix. He then borrows and = proof that such q and t = 1/2, t 4/ 1/2 is at least q. = exist choices. buys enough stock so that by t If his = previous losses and still be up $1 by t = 3/ ) asset he borrows and 3/4, with probability q, he will cover any a Again, dollar. = 1/2, if he wins he shifts to the riskless asset, while if he doesn't win he raises the stakes enough net is investment he invests the profits in the riskless If he is not up a dollar or more at t 1. x at invests enough money in the stock that the chance of yields at least $1 at t (A There will be infinitely many possible being up a dollar or more at until a such that over any time interval of length less than or equal to 1/2, the stock will yield a (continuously compounded) return of least do 7/8 with probability q, once, so the chance of being up $1 by t is certain to be up $1 by t = 1. 5/ and so on. = 1 All he needs - (1/2) n is 1 - (1-q) n is , to and to win he One's first impulse is to look for an incidence of cheating hidden in the above strategy, but it seems to break none of the rules of the game. So we are forced to conclude that, taken literally, the assumptions in II are not mutually consistent. One Solution: IV. section Limited Liability Demand Loans How should we amend the B-S assumptions? Surely we do not want to allow arbitrage profits to be achievable, by doubling or any other strategy. What enables doubling to work in the B-S economy, and why would it not in practise? unrestricted "Continuous time yields the necessary opportunities to bet; short losses." [Kreps, eliminate the p. sales 41] doubling lacking." the necessary earlier paper, yields In an problem but, as Kreps [1979, p. points; work by restricting 43] admits, resources Harrison trading to Kreps and to any cover [1979] discrete time "economic motivation for it Even if we assume that no trading can occur at night when is the organized markets are closed, the continuous opportunity for trading from 10 a.m. to 4 p.m. is enough to permit arbitrage by doubling. Think of a gambler playing on red and doubling if he loses). a doubling strategy at roulette (betting $1 Aside from discrete time, one problem he will face is that the house will limit the size of his bet. The parallel to this in capital markets might be that if a doubler doubles too many times, his position would be so large that the "price-taker" assumption would questionable. This approach will not be pursued here. gambler wants to finance his bets by borrowing. In But now suppose practise, be our prospective lenders will ask what the money is to be used for, and will turn him down if Doubling looks fine, even for lenders, except for that he tells them. chance of one string of losses long enough that the money to double again a is not forthcoming. This suggests another possible amendment: borrowing. credit Doubling would no longer 'work', but choosing some level for the would limit option prices. leverage. putting an upper limit on be somewhat arbitrary, If the constraint is binding, Finally, such a and it may affect equilibrium investors may use options limit would not be realistic: we do not for find that investors can borrow at r up to a ceiling on borrowing, but rather that the interest rate charged depends on the term of the loan, wealth, and what he plans to assumptions often prove useful, limit that is do I with the money. the Although investor's unrealistic shall propose an alternative to the credit both more realistic and more appealing in its analysis and results. Append the following to the assumptions of section II: 7. Each economic agent's wealth is always nonnegative and finite, so that no contract can require that an agent pay more than his total assets under any possible circumstances. 8. All loans, short sales, and options are negotiated on a demand basis either party may redeem the contract at any time without penalty. the case of options (American or European), this is intended to that the option buyer can give the option back to the seller in In mean return 10 for sum equal a to default risk (for example, a covered call would have no default risk). made be You may well ask how a contradictory set of assumptions can consistent adding more assumptions. by Well, 1 believe that field had be that some researchers in this so that it in mind is merely being made explicit an Or it may assumption implicit here. fact in #7 replaces an implicit assumption that negative wealth was allowed. like #7, no similar option that has the market price of a But in any case, the great appeal of this assumption is that negative wealth in fact has no realistic meaning. You also may limited-liability world all else fails, whether ask — riskless a asset wouldn't every loan have a exist can risk of default? delivery of $B cash that is secured by $B of cash sitting in sources of riskless assets. a Consider a But If future the riskless asset can be defined as a contract for similarity to government debt should be apparent.) this in vault. a are there (A other demand loan owed by an investor with portfolio of stock and option positions, where the portfolio has a market Since stock prices (and therefore put and value greater than the loan owed. call prices) have continuous sample paths with probability one, there is no risk of default on the loan, because if the portfolio value drops close to the amount owed, the loan can be called in. instantaneously called; so the dropping below the amount proceeds dominated by of owed riskless rate will be charged. would lend to an investor with zero wealth the There is no chance of the value hi3 investment), investing directly in because whatever before the loan Also notice that can no-one (unless he agreed to repay such the a proposition borrower was be would all be planning to 11 invest in. the new framework of assumptions In through 1 8, doubling the strategy does not earn arbitrage profits, but the B-S option formula holds. First economy, it I will prove Black-Scholes the formula. In will make a greater difference to the force and this still amended form of proof whether or not one starts by assuming that the call price is the known a function of only S and t. Given this assumption, original the B-S carries proof Unless the Black-Scholes partial differential unchanged. over almost equation holds, any investor with positive wealth can make excess returns on the of portfolio hedge stock, call option, riskless and standard More asset. specifically, denoting the call price function by F(S,t), if rF S - rF + s i^S 2 + F 5 b then the investor can buy n calls, sell short nF difference the in riskless asset, chosen as large as he likes). (unborrowed) wealth, > make and shares of stock, put s $nb In other words, must time (n can the be This is in addition to any returns on his own this is an The opposite investment strategy is followed if b equation unit per which he needed as collateral with no default risk. differential , fc Also hold. the < in order to arbitrage 0. short-sell opportunity. So the B-S boundary partial conditions are unchanged, and thus the B-S formula is valid in this economy. If the call price is not assumed to be a function of only S and t, proof is more difficult. price by C(t), and an investor's C(0) < G(S(0),0), buys n calls, Denote and sells W(0) > short 0. the B-S formula by G(S(t),t), (market-valued) wealth by W(t). The call nF„(S(0),0) is undervalued, shares of stock, so the and the the call Suppose investor puts the 12 (including W(0)) remainder continuously position As stock. in Merton the in he that so [1977], asset. riskless always is short This is not more undervalued? a but here there is a what is to prevent its becoming But in for some t before maturity, my investor will no longer < his position to maturity — be he would be out of the game. This puts a limit on n, I my maintain able to borrow (or sell short or sell calls), and thus could not take. even investor problem for Merton, because his can hold out until maturity, when he is sure he will be ahead. case, if W(t) of investor this is designed to ensure that the If a call can be undervalued, short shares nF (S(t),t) can pay off the calls and still have money left over, hitch: adjusts his He the size of the position that he may need to show that this limit is positive, i.e. safely that there is positive position that the investor could take and make excess profits a for certain. Lemma: -E ^ G(S(t),t) - C(t) ^ E for all t until maturity. Proof: (a) S(t)-E ^ C(t) ^ S(t) investors could collateral for limit, sell the the call, call, for all buy If t. the stock, C(t) and making arbitrage gains. broke the upper limit, put If it up the broke stock the lower investors could sell the stock short, buy the call, and put up call and $E as collateral for the short sale. as the ] 13 (b) S(t)-E < G(S(t),t) ^ S(t) for all This t. is a well-known property of the B-S formula. (o) The lemma follows easily from (a) moving interval of length E, and (b). and so can never be more than E apart. If n < W(0)/{E-[G(S(0),0)-C(0) Theorem: F and C are trapped in ] } then W(t) , for all > t until maturity. The constraint on n implies that Proof: < W(0) - En + n[G(3(0),0)-C(0)] « W(0) n[G(S(0),0)-C(0)] - n[G(S(t) ,t)-C(t) « (W(0) + n[G(S(0) t 0)-C(0)]}e = rt (by the Lemma) ] - n[G(3(t) ,t)-C(t) W(t) (For the last line of the proof, recall that the investor starts with W(0), skims off G(S(0),0)-C(0) immediately for every call he buys, is long n calls thenceforth, portfolio, and short ensures by continuous hedging that in stock and long riskless the the asset, remainder always of his has value -nG(S(t),t).) The proof is similar for the case of an overvalued call, in which limit on n would be W(0)/{E-[C(0)-G(S(0) ,0) ] the }. Therefore any deviation from the B-S formula allows excess profits to be made, and so the B-S formula must hold. of position an investor can take, the Because of the limit on the size above is more in the spirit of a 14 dominance argument than an arbitrage argument. If C(t) > G(S(t),t) then all investors with positive wealth would be wanting to write the call; G(S(t),t) they would all want to buy the call. only clear if C(t) = C(t) if So the call market could G(S(t),t) for all t. There remains the question of whether the Kreps doubling strategy can produce sure gains in world a doubler starts with wealth W(0) of > limited liability. Suppose would-be a He may borrow as much as he wants, but 0. if ever his net market position W(t) becomes the loan will be called, will not be able to borrow any more, and so he will have lost permanently. The trouble is that no matter how small an amount he borrows at t put in the stock until t = there 1/2, stock will drop enough to make W(t) disaster doesn't strike him, is a if he has to t < 'double' 1/2. And even if several times in the stake will have risen so as to increase the risk of hitting zero before the next double. to = positive probability that for some = he the that a row wealth So arbitrage profits can not be made this way. But that does not prove that there is no way to make excess profits by some other type of doubling strategy. The next section looks at some of these. V. Doubling With Non-Demand Loans The doubler who is only allowed complain that this is an unfair handicap is such that if only he weren't to — borrow using demand that the nature of his interrupted when his loans may strategy wealth drops < 15 temporarily below zero, he would in the end pay off all his debts with some money left term loans lines and section of outline I conclude The over. introduction of such real-world contracts credit an permit yet institutional doubling that may still successful structure fails. All with effort doubling. these is not as In this features, but wasted though, because the rules drawn up for this economy will be useful in sections VI and VII. Replace assumption 8 of section IV by the following: All kinds of financial contracts are allowed, provided that 8. (a) they satisfy the limited-liability assumption, (b) they specify how each borrower will invest his assets (loans plus wealth) until contract the expires, problems in pricing contracts; (c) //7; so as avoid to hazard moral and all loans and lines of credit are of finite size. The idea short-seller or is that option if there writer) will is a not chance have that enough the borrower (or make the wealth to prescribed payment, it is understood at the outset that he will only pay much as he has; and the contract is priced with that in mind. total evolve in wealth. a This relatively institutional unregulated setting seems marketplace. like In one fact, as Furthermore, contracts may be written in which the borrower pledges an amount less his own that the than could limited 16 explicit liability feature is borrowing through corporations), contracts many in and is implicit that others all in observe we (e.g. because bankruptcy is allowed and slavery is not. Notice that the proofs of the Black-Scholes formula given in section apply here also, IV They required the existence of fortiori. a 'demand' securities, not the nonexistence of nondemand securities. Suppose maturity equal t : t = can doubler a to his stock planned holding period the he borrows on financed promise to repay at positions for the term by is not up = 1/2. If he 1/2, he borrows on a promise to pay at t = 3/^; and so on. not be put out of game the period, but there is still hitting by That stock. t a zero wealth loans of is, at $1 at This way he during a holding chance that at the end of any holding period he a will have to pay all his assets to his creditor. In such a will case he have zero wealth, and be unable to recoup his losses since no-one would then lend to him. Therefore riskless excess profits can not be made this way. Suppose instead he negotiates whole period from t to = t = 1 , a single line of credit of $B for paying the riskless rate on any amounts borrowed. with the aim of making that he may suffer $1 a fee of $f up front, He then arranges his plus $f plus any interest paid. the paying and 'doubling' Here the catch is enough losses that the amount he needs to invest would After that he can not increase his stock involve borrowing more than $B. holdings for more 'doubles', and so can not guarantee to be ahead by t = 1. 17 If a doubler could arrange an infinite line of credit, he could arbitrage profits with Kreps make strategy while only borrowing finite amounts, ' but he can set no sure upper limit in advance on his borrowing, and infinite credit lines are eliminated assumption. by would It be interesting to analyse what happens in the limit as B approaches infinity. VI. Limit of Discrete Time, No Limit on Liability Quite a different approach to resolving the question of doubling is to only allow as valid continuous-time economies those that have the property of being the limit of a interval h approaches zero. lines. This preserving turns out See Merton [1975] for a discussion along these doubling while eliminate to result, Black-Scholes the benefits the thus of identifying phenomenon as a singularity of the continuous-time extreme. we do not assume that wealth is nonnegative. a trading sequence of discrete-time economies, as the the doubling In this section Although it is hard to imagine meaning for negative wealth, we assume that investors have derived utility of wealth functions defined on the entire real line. We will set up a sequence of discrete-time economies with the aim finding the price of a European call in the continuous-time limit. we want to price it at t and it matures at t = from the set {1,2,4,8,16,...} 1. , = T >0. Suppose Where n is . . . where h = drawn define economy n by the assumptions: Capital markets operate (and clear) only at the dicrete time points 0,h,2h,3h, of T/n. It is to be understood in what t = follows 18 that for a given n the variable t takes on only these discrete values. 2. Capital markets are perfect. 3. Investors prefer more to less, and are risk-averse, throughout the range of their utility functions. 4. There is a riskless asset that returns $(1+rh) on an investment of $1 for time interval h. 5. There is a stock paying no dividends, stock price whose follows S Markov process such that given S(t), the mean of S(t+h) is a S(t)[1+jih], 2 2 and the variance of S(t+h) is a [3(t)] h. 6. There is a European call option on the stock, maturity date Merton T, with exercise price E, and market price C(t). [forthcoming] provides assumptions of set a security about price dynamics in discrete time that are sufficient to make prices follow an It6 process in the continuous-time Here limit. I make a similar but stronger set of assumptions to give the continuous-limit process dS/S This is geometric Black-Scholes, and = ;jdt + adZ Brownian motion with constant drift . constant rate /J. simplicity, though the results do not require it. jj variance is held rate 2 o* , constant as in for 19 To the above six assumptions economy on add n, the following cross-economy assumptions: C1. The parameters r, Let e(t) [Notation: /j, = a, and T are the same in all economies. E, S(t) - E (S(t) } . ] 1 C2. The distribution of e(t) and M < CO , both is discrete, and independent of n and t, there exist numbers m such that each t for < CO the 2 number of possible outcomes for e(t) is ^ m, and e (t) ^ M for certain. Merton invokes these to simplify the mathematics without imposing any significant economic restrictions. Choose some time t in economy n. probabilities p., j = 1,2,3, ... ,m. 7/ Then e(t) may take on values d. with For a fixed t and j, and increasing d. and p. can be thought of as functions of h, with h approaching zero n, from above. Define the notation f(h)~h 3 to mean that lim f(h)/h 3 is a nonzero h-*0 real number. Now assume: C3. For all t and j, d. and p. are sufficiently "well-behaved" functions of that there exist numbers r. and q. such that d J J . J ~h J and d j ~h J * : . ; ; 20 CM. For all and t such that q. + 2r j J purpose main this of Merton shows that assumptions, q is + 2r . that and rule to < . if q assume that r. 1, (The 1/2. = J processes jump out limit. the in is impossible as it would violate prior 1 + 2r . = . J . > for 1 possible outcomes some j, then those outcomes contribute nothing to the limiting continuous-time stock price process.) do not attempt to derive I formula for the price of the call option, a Rather, C(0), in any of the discrete-time economies. it must converge this sequence of prices is, value, G(S(0),0), as —* n oo and h ->• To simplify notation, 0. stand for any function f(h) with the property S(k) = stock price at C(k) = option price at N(k) = G G(k) = G(S(k),k) H(k) = value of hedge position at (S(k),k) = = kh = t = , for k lc(0) - G(S(0),0)| > £ in ; kh t = kh B-S formula call value at for = 0,1,2,...,n; = B-S hedge ratio at that such > formula let —— lim h-»0 t = t = kh any N economy n. and ; kh Then there exists Suppose C(0) does not converge to G(S(0),0). £ whatever argue that the Black-Scholes to o(h) t I there an is For that £, n > N some such that consider the following two sequences: :- {all n such that C(0) - G(S(0),0) > £. in economy n} Sequence 2 :- {all n such that C(0) - G(S(0),0) < £ in economy n} Sequence 1 At least one of these two squences must be infinite. infinite. Suppose sequence Then applying the following argument to economies with from sequence large enough n 1 n shows that arbitrage profits can be made in an economy 1 is drawn with ] 21 At t invest G(0) and pocket the difference sell one call for C(0), = in of N(0) composed portfolio stock levered a stock and riskless borrowing of $[N(0)S(0)-G(0) ] C(0) - G(0), shares of to make up the difference. So the portfolio's initial value H(0) will equal the B-S formula call value G(0), but will be less than the call's market price C(0). Let D(t) = H(t) - G(t), the difference between the hedge value and the So D(0) B-S formula value. that D(t) by construction. = The next goal is to show for all t in the continuous-time limit. = The change in the hedge value from t H(1) - H(0) = = to t = h will be N(0)[S(1)-S(0)] - rh[N(0)S(0)-H(0)]. At each stage (t=(k-1)h for k=2, 3, . . . ,n) , the hedge is revised so as to hold N(k-1) shares of stock, financed by borrowing as necessary. The change in the hedge value from t=(k-1)h to t=kh will be H(k) -H(k-1) Meanwhile the B-S = N(k-1)[S(k)-S(k-1)] - rh[N(k-1 )S(k-1 )-H(k-1 value call formula also changes. Its (1) )]. change can be rewritten following the Taylor series argument in Merton [forthcoming]: G(k)-G(k-1) = (k-1 )[S(k)-S(k-1 G (k-1)[S(k)-S(k-1)]+ G (k-1)h + ^G ss s t 2 ) +o(h) ....(2) Let u(k) in the n-»co, E k_1 3ense = e(k) TV7i? ;/h — —=r, This standardizes the driving random variable • ot>(.k-i that outcomes the (u(k)} = whereas of the u(k) and E _ (u 2 (k)} k 1 S(k) - S(k-1) outcomes not, do = 1 by of e(k) become assumption for all n. So = /iS(k-1)h + e(k) = /jS(k-1)h + dS(k-1)u(k)/h C4 infinitesimal above. In as fact, 22 Then [S(k)-S(k-1 2 a S (k-1 = )] and equation (k)h + o(h), )u can be (2) rewritten as G(k) - G(k-1) = G s (k-1)[S(k)-S(k-1)] + G (k-1 )h + ^G Into D(k) - 2 2 2 (k-1)o- S (k-1)u (k-1)h + o(h) ss D(k-D - H(k-1) H(k) = - 9/ - G(k-1)] [G(k) ....(3) substitute (1) and (3) to give D(k) - D(k-1) G s N(k-1)[S(k)-S(k-1)] - rh[N(k-1)S(k-1)-H(k-1)] - = (k-1)[S(k)-S(k-1)] - G (k-1)h t But recall N(k-1) that = 2 2 ^ ss (k-1 )o S G (k-1 ) , (k-1 )u that and Black-Scholes partial differential equation so that 2 (k)h + o(h) (4) satisfies G rG S+G =rG - irS the G Substituting these into (4) gives D(k) - D(k-1) = rh[H(k-1)-G(k-1)] - ^G 3S 2 2 2 (k-1)o- S (k-1)[u (k)-1]h + o(h) (5) Defining y(k) = ^G ss (k-1 )cj 2 2 2 S (k-1 )[u (k)-1 ], we have from the law of n large numbers martingales for lim hV'y(k) that n-»oo =D(0) + £ [D(k) ^ k= where 1 Consider the difference D(t) for some time D(t) K = nt/T . Substituting from probability ', k= one. with = /— t between and T: (k-1 }] 1 (5) taking and the continuous-time limit, this becomes K D(t) = D(0) + K limV n "°°k = 1 rh[H(k-1)-G(k-1)] - K limVy(k)h n ^~k = 1 + lim5o(h) n — k= 1 ' 25 K limV n -»<».*— ,00 + = k= rhD(k-l) 1 t rD (s)ds / s=0 Solutions D(0) = this to integral this means that 0, D(t) equation for = satisfy D(t) from to all t = D(0)e and T, value H(t) will always equal the B-S formula call value G(t). at t = T, = will be the hedge when the investor has to make good on the call he sold, he will max[0,S(T)-E] just so sufficient but the Black-Scholes formula has the H(T) = to pay arbitrage portfolio. So is C(0) t achieved must max[0 S(T )-E , off the on also ] call — were 'free' = — at property the hedge portfolio maturity. Thus the arbitrage. if sequence 2 were infinite instead of sequence By a similar argument, then Since finally profits that were pocketed at 1, . And have to pay max[0,S(T)-E]; G(T) rt by buying the call converge to G(S(0),0): and the shorting B-S hedge the formula is the limit of the call's market price, as the trading interval approaches zero. an As example of why doubling fails in the imagine a doubler betting red on .5), all in a his a limit of discrete time, fair roulette wheel (probability of win discrete-time world where negative wealth is allowed. bets with riskless borrowing. To make each bet a = He finances fairly priced security, let us say that its outcome is independent of everything else, the riskless rate is zero, and bets pay off at to bet between t=0 and t=1, 2 to 1 . He has n opportunities wants to be up $1 by t=1, and so he first $1 and keeps doubling until he wins once. $1 with probability 1-(1/2) n , or $(1-2 n ) His net payoff as of t=1 will with probability (1/2) n . bets be 24 Now the parallel to Kreps infinite, so that payoff the ' doubling argument would be to next let is $1 with probability — 1 disastrous the string of losses gets swept under the rug of zero probability, for doubling is large. noise any to n be and demand But for any economy n, the doubling payoff only adds portfolio's return, and so would not undertaken be by any risk-averse investor [Rothschild and Stiglitz, 1970]. So in the sequence of discrete-time demand for economies as n increases, the such doubling a strategy is identically zero, and hence is zero in the limit. Limit of Discrete Time, With Limit on Liability VII. Defining continuous time in terms of the limit of discrete time is very appealing in the way it seems to preserve results that make sense while rejecting those that requiring wealth to imagine methods a don't. be At the nonnegative is same time, desirable realistic meaning for negative wealth. in what may be the most the other because it approach of hard to is This section combines both reasonable way to resolve the questions addressed here. To the six assumptions defining economy n in section VI, append the following: 7. Each economic agent's wealth is always nonnegative and finite, no contract can require that an agent pay more than his under any possible circumstances. total so that assets 25 All kinds of financial contracts are allowed, provided that 8. they specify how each borrower will (a) invest his assets until the contract expires; (b) all loans and lines of credit are of finite size; (c) transactions occur only at the time points t = and 0,h,2h,... The cross-economy assumptions C1, C2, C3, and C4 are also retained. In this setting, a riskless asset is much harder to come by. discrete time interval, any loan on a portfolio with finite pledged In wealth and some stock-price risk will have a positive probability of default. that in option-stock an hedge portfolio cases, the contracts will stock-price Furthermore, completely hedged away in discrete time. stock or writing of options will the have default risk be priced to risk Note cannot be any short sale of also. all In take account of the default these risk. Define the default premium to be the difference between the prices today a a given promise to pay with and without the default risk. of The price without default risk can be imagined as the limit of the price as the pledged wealth (collateral) approaches infinity or, better still, no-default securities can be invented. The price for a short sale is not a problem the stock price if there is no default risk. A call not to default by putting up the stock as collateral. riskless if backed by enough cash; to borrow on such terms, the — it should equal writer can guarantee And a loan can although no private investor would government existence of riskless government debt. might, so let us assume be want the 26 The pursuit of doubling strategy in this world would suffer from all a the handicaps of sections V and VI above, so it will not generate arbitrage The remainder of this section is devoted to profits here either. showing that in spite of default problems in the discrete-time economies, the market price of call will approach the B-S formula value in the a continuous-time My plan is to adapt the discrete portfolio adjustment argument limit. section VI, and to show that in a time interval of length h, each probability is o(h), each default premium must be o(h), so that as cumulative effect of these probabilities Just as in section disappears. IV, premia and there will be a position that an investor may take to make money on since all from default h —* the to = t t limit on the size a mispriced call, investors would be wanting to transact on the call in of the = T of but same direction, dominance would prevent the market from clearing until the price is right. Let us take care some in defining what just discrete-hedging investor is going to invest in. or bonds, or debt (the stock is not a of contracts our When he buys stock, calls, let him do so no a no-default-risk basis: government sort problem). by buying covered calls When he sells short, writes calls, or borrows, there will be no way to avoid some default risk on his part, means of but the let the following risk be confined to one time unit per contract arrangement. Each of his liabilities is to resettled after each time unit h (in the style of futures contracts). is nothing unusual stock) — in this for borrowing and these are to be repaid next period. option with some distant maturity date T, I short in I be There (borrowings of have him write an sales But when by fact will mean for him contract to pay, at time h from now, the market price that that option to will 27 then command if it has no default risk from then on (e.g. of a continuous-time demand-basis assumption #8 on page options on portfolio any stock, that price This is the next best thing in discrete time to covered call). Consider the market and of short bonds, and/or 9, long section IV. positions in with positive pledged wealth In order for default to occur on any of the short positions, ~h stock, a (positive market value), where all short positions are to be resettled each must move by an amount the period. the stock price in a time interval of length h. By assumption CM the probability of such an outcome is o(h). Now the default premium can be thought of a3 the market value of o(h), probability the guarantor will only have to pay off with loan guarantee; in an amount that is bounded of such a liability were larger than o(h). 3uch claims would give, as h-»0, — payoff of probability zero Suppose the market in magnitude. a Then rolling over arbitrage. value sequence a value greater than summed a of zero for So the default premium must a be o(h). The hedge strategy to be followed is the same as that in section except that there is sold, a VI, limit on the number of calls that can be bought or for the same reason as in section IV. Here, the change in the hedge value from time k-1 to time k, conditional on default not occurring, is H(k) - H(k-1) where the o(h) = N(k-1)[S(k)-S(k-D] - rh[N(k-1 )S(k-1 )-H(k-1 term includes any default premium. With before, we again get K D(t) = n limY]rhD(k-1) -°°kTl t = f rD(s)ds J s =0 )] D(t) + o(h) defined as 28 conditional on there being no default between time probability of such a default bounded is and time t. But the by something of the above form K which approaches zero as h 2_,o(h), —»0. So we have D(t) D(0)e = with k=1 probability one, the call position can be closed at maturity using only from proceeds completes the the hedge dominance portfolio, argument and riskless are Black-Scholes the for gains the This made. formula this in setting. Conclusions VIII. Kreps The doubling strategy raised doubts about internal the consistency of the standard assumptions in continuous-time finance Two ways of resolving the doubling problem were presented: one was to explicit the natural requirement that wealth is never negative; was define to a economy continuous-time as the limit of models. a make other the sequence discrete-time economies, as the trading interval approaches zero. These two more methods were combined in the last section, to form what seems to be a reasonable model of the world. fails to produce In arbitrage gains, argument still obtains. It the three sets) will provide is a all three cases, while the the doubling of strategy pricing Black-Scholes option hoped that the amended assumptions (any general partition of results that make of sense from those that do not. Furthermore, an explicit limited-liability requirement may prove to be a useful tool for applications well beyond those of the present paper, example p. 1122]. in such general equilibrium existence proofs as in Green for [1973, = 29 FOOTNOTES 1. Subscripts to functions denote partial derivatives, e.g. 2. See Black Scholes and Merton [19733, F Henriksson [1981], = 3F/dS Merton and [1981], and Hawkins [1982]. 3. statement that "there is some positive probability q that over Kreps* any time interval the second security [stock] will strictly outperform the a [riskless asset]" first < r then for any q [1979, there exists > a not quite accurate. is **0] p. time enough interval T large that the probability of the stock beating the riskless asset If is less But this is not a problem for his doubler, who can put an upper than q. bound on the lengths of his holding periods. 4. To calculate the amount that our "bet-doubler" should borrow and invest in the stock each time, n = the let number of consecutive losses he has suffered so far; W = his net winnings up to that time (may be negative); T = (1/2) n+ and the length of his next holding period. = holding To be up $1 with probability at least q at the end of the next — - W e - e 1 period, he borrows and invests $ =• Then if y(T) . > x, his net position will be W + —xT= 1 e 5. A simpler W - e , =-(e yT J rT bet-doubling - e rT. ) . > ,. W + —xT- 1 e strategy, which W . xT =-(e - e rT can be - e rT. . = ) defined without reference to a specific stochastic process, is 1 and . analyzed found by making 30 U3 of short sales. e short sell a large enough nolding-period return exceeds q = 1/4, r if and to median the stock holding-period both quartiles equal r, 6. than r, the go median of long when equals r. median the Instead, a return. set This works unless possibility which can be safely ignored. This sequence (powers of 2) is chosen for n so that any time capital stock the go short an amount calculated with reference to the quarcile of the lower less fails whenever amount to 1/2, = q go long when the upper quartile exceeds r, and in the case when does not exceed it is this but r; almost works (but not quite) to set It markets are open in economy n, will have the for which t property that capital markets are open at cnat time in all economies of higher n. 7. Merton is not explicit about m and M being independent of (a) and n t, but clearly intends it that way. (o) En the following discussion, if any e(t) possible has less than m outcomes, imagine augmenting the number of outcomes until it equals m by adding outcomes of zero probability. d. I thank Robert Jarrow for emphasizing to me the importance of proving rather than just assuming convergence and proving that C(0) converges, that it must converge to G(3(0),0). on Merton [1977 J, [197dJ, The argument that follows is and [forthcoming]. The preceding assumptions correspond to those in Merton [forthcoming] as follows: l:; more E.5, than and E.6. enough to guarantee My Cj is his E.4. Merton' s based assumptions My assumption 5 E.1, E.2, My C4 is his "Type I" partition. E. i, 31 9. Remember statement that o(h) the + notation o(h) o(h) = o(h) refers to means that a the class of functions. class is closed addition. 10. See the argument in Merton [forthcoming] leading to equation (j2). The under ) 32 APPENDIX Theorem Given the stock price process : dS/S + adZ = jjdt and the (constant) riskless rate of return r, there exist q and > length rate of return a T 4 stock the 1/2, probability at least x r > will such that over yield rate a any of probability a time at interval least (All rates of return are meant as q. of with x continuously compounded. Proof: Let y denote the (random variable) rate of return on the stock time T. in S(0), the Then S(T) lognormal = S(0)e = /j - variance 2 o- /2 = o" 2 x of = £log[s(T)/S(0)] S(T) implies that log S(0) + aT and variance = For . given log S(T) = 2 cr is where T, = a and /T. and q a = and y Therefore y is distributed normally with mean . Case Choose , distribution distributed normally with mean a yT = >y — a r > Then clearly for any T (including T ^ 1/2) 1/2. probability that y 1 x is 1/2 (^q), because x is the mean of y's the normal distribution. Case 2 Choose x r r + 0.001 and q = — a Prob{y > 4 x r for T = 1/2}. condition on q holds by the definition of q. For (Clearly q > T = 1/2 the 0.) For (Appendix cont'd) 33 smaller T, it is intuitively obvious that since and (a) the mean of y is unchanged, (b) the variance of y is increased, (c) x is greater than the mean of y, must be true that Pr{y it >y x} increases, and so is > q. Here is formal proof: q = Pr{ y(1/2) - Pr( x >, y(1/2)-a } X^a : } >x Note that both have the standard normal distribution, = Pr{l y v. < Pr{ } ^vt"f ;»^-=-^ o-yr ^7=7 Pr{ y(T) } for all T, } for any T including T < 1/2 ; / >, >, x jLZ-£ } . < 1/2 , since X "a - x ~a a 34 REFERENCES Black, F., and M. Scholes [1973], "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities", Journal of Political Economy Green, J. [19733, R. "Temporary General vol. 81, Equilibrium in , Trading Model With Spot and Futures Transactions", vol. Harrison, 11, J., and D. Kreps Securities vol. 381-408. Hawkins, G. pp. [1982], D. R. D. , and Markets", Journal C. Investment Performance. , Merton II. vol. D. III, [1979], no. 10, "On [1981], Sequential Econometrica , of Arbitrage Economic in Theory , Agreements", 1. Market Timing and Statistical Procedures for Evaluating Forecasting Skills", Journal of Business Kreps, and Analysis of Revolving Credit "An R. "Martingales [1979], Journal of Financial Economics Henriksson, a 1103-1123. pp. Multiperiod 20, 637-659. pp. , vol. 54, October. "Three Essays on Capital Markets" (especially essay "Continuous Time Models"), Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social University. Sciences (IMSS3), Technical Report No. 261, Stanford 35 Merton, Continuous-Time Model", Journal vol. Portfolio and Theory Economic of Rules , in a vol. 3, of from Finance Perspective the of Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis Time", , 659-674. 10, pp. C. [1977], R. "Theory [1975], C. R. Continuous Merton, Consumption 373-413. pp. Merton, "Optimum [1971], C. R. "On the Pricing Theorem", Modigliani-Miller Contingent of Journal of Claims Financial the and Economics , vol. 5, pp. 241-249. [1978], Seminar notes for "On the Mathematics and Economic Merton, R. C. Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models", unpublished manuscript. Merton, I. R. [1981], C. An "On Market Timing Investment and Performance. Equilibrium Theory of Value for Market Forecasts", Journal of Busines s, vol. 54, pp. 363-406. Merton, R. C [forthcoming], Assumptions Essays in of "On the Mathematics Continuous-Time Models", Paul Cootner Honor of in , and Economic Financial Economics: W. F. Sharpe (ed.), Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey. Rothschild, M., and J. E. Stiglitz [1970], "Increasing Definition", Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 2, pp. Risk: 225-243. I. A DDM 524 22b TDfl D 3 HD28.M414 no.1129- 80A Stephe/Taking the burdens Barley. : DOl TIE b4 TOflQ HD28.M414 no.1129- 80B Edwar/Cntical Roberts, functions D*BK§ 739558 mi ill inn mini i DOl TTb 203 TOflO 3 : 00132550 H028.M414 no.1130- 80 Schmalensee, R/Economies of scale and D*BKS 00 1^264F 739574 001 TTb lbl TOflO 3 HD28.M414 no.1130- 80A Sterman, John /The effect of D*BKS 739856 001 115 72b TOflO 3 energy de 0Q132S25 HD28.M414 no.1131- 80 Latham, Mark. /Doubling strategies, D*BKS 739564 h 013 001 5jj 002 2bl bMT TOflO 3 HD28.M414 no.1131- 80 1981 Latham, Mark. /Doubling TOflO 3 nun H028.M414 Keen. Peter 740317 .. h 001526"" 257 bl3 00c? 1 1 oa 3 strategies, D*BKS 743102 1 III II G. 1 132- I III III I III SEM 2M2 M no. III 80 /Building a decision D.xBKS _"_ .0013649.4 TOflO sup . 002 041 7A5 HD28.M414 no. 1 132- 80A Wong, M. Antho/An itho/An empirical empirn study 73957C 00152666 .P.*BKS..... of . III 3 TOflO 002 257 b3^ t o \ ctZ\b