Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Does Aggregate Riskiness Predict Future Economic Downturns? Turan G. Bali McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University Nusret Cakici Graduate School of Business, Fordham University Fousseni Chabi-Yo Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University Dice Center WP 2012-9 Fisher College of Business WP 2012-03-009 Original: May 2012 This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2061651 An index to the working papers in the Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series is located at: http://www.ssrn.com/link/Fisher-College-of-Business.html fisher.osu.edu Does Aggregate Riskiness Predict Future Economic Downturns? Turan G. Balia ∗ a McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, D.C.20057 Nusret Cakicib † b Graduate School of Business, Fordham University, New York, NY 10023, USA Fousseni Chabi-Yoc ‡ c Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University, Columbus, OH 43210-1144, USA First draft: January 2011 This draft: March 2012 Abstract Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) introduce riskiness measures based on the physical return distribution of gambles. This paper proposes model-free options’ implied measures of riskiness based on the risk-neutral distribution of financial securities. In addition to introducing the forward-looking measures of riskiness, the paper investigates the significance of aggregate riskiness in predicting future economic downturns. The results indicate strong predictive power of aggregate riskiness even after controlling for the realized volatility of the U.S. equity market, the implied volatility of S&P 500 index options (V IX) proxying for financial market uncertainty, as well as the TED spread proxying for interbank credit risk and the perceived health of the banking system. JEL C LASSIFICATION C ODES : G11, G12, G14, G33 KEY WORDS: Riskiness, economic index of riskiness, operational measure of riskiness, risk-neutral measures, economic downturns. ∗ Tel.: +1-202-687-5388; fax: +1-202-687-4031. E-mail address: tgb27@georgetown.edu 636 6776; fax: +1-212-586-0575. E-mail address: cakici@fordham.edu ‡ Tel.:+1-614-292-8477; fax: +1-614-292-7062. E-mail address: chabi-yo 1@fisher.osu.edu † Tel.:+1-212 Does Aggregate Riskiness Predict Future Economic Downturns? Abstract Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) introduce riskiness measures based on the physical return distribution of gambles. This paper proposes model-free options’ implied measures of riskiness based on the risk-neutral distribution of financial securities. In addition to introducing the forward-looking measures of riskiness, the paper investigates the significance of aggregate riskiness in predicting future economic downturns. The results indicate strong predictive power of aggregate riskiness even after controlling for the realized volatility of the U.S. equity market, the implied volatility of S&P 500 index options (V IX) proxying for financial market uncertainty, as well as the TED spread proxying for interbank credit risk and the perceived health of the banking system. JEL C LASSIFICATION C ODES : G11, G12, G14, G33 KEY WORDS: Riskiness, economic index of riskiness, operational measure of riskiness, risk-neutral measures, economic downturns. 1. Introduction Aumann and Serrano (2008) introduce a measure of riskiness based on investors’ risk tolerance. They define the riskiness of a gamble as the reciprocal of the constant absolute risk aversion of an individual, implying that less-averse individuals accept riskier gambles. Foster and Hart (2009) also develop a riskiness measure that depends only on the gamble and not on the decision maker’s aversion to risk. This alternative measure of riskiness determines the critical wealth level below which it becomes risky to accept the gamble.1 The economic index measure of riskiness pioneered by Aumann and Serrano (2008) looks for the critical utility regardless of wealth, whereas the operational measure of riskiness initiated by Foster and Hart (2009) looks for the critical wealth regardless of utility.2 Bali, Cakici, and Chabi-Yo (2011) introduce a generalized measure of riskiness that nests the original measures proposed by Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009). Risk is a central issue in optimal asset allocation, financial risk management, and derivative pricing. The question is whether the riskiness measures of Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) provide a better characterization of underlying risk than various measures already used by regulators and finance professionals. First, the widely used measures of risk such as standard deviation, variance, and mean absolute deviation determine only “dispersion”, taking little account of the gamble’s actual values. For example, if g and h = g + c are gambles, where c is a positive constant, then any of these standard risk measures rates h precisely as risky as g, in spite of its being sure to yield more than g. One important drawback of these dispersion measures is that they are not monotonic with respect to first-order stochastic dominance, i.e., a better gamble with higher gains and lower losses may well have a higher standard deviation, variance, and mean absolute deviation and thus be wrongly viewed as having a higher riskiness.3 Second, the riskiness measures of Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) do not depend on any ad hoc parameters that need to be specified. The downside risk measure used extensively by commercial banks, investment banks, and insurance companies is Value at Risk (VaR) which depends on a parameter called a confidence level.4 The problem is that an appropriate value of the confidence level is 1 Foster and Hart (2009) show that for every gamble g there exists a unique critical wealth level R(g) such that accepting gambles when the current wealth is below the corresponding R(g) leads to bad outcomes, such as decreasing wealth and even bankruptcy in the long run. 2 As shown in Hart (2011), there is a similarity between the approaches to riskiness and standard decision and consumer theory. Foster and Hart (2011) show that when investors have CRRA utilities, the Aumann and Serrano index can be interpreted as the maximal riskiness, whereas the Foster and Hart measure can be viewed as the minimal riskiness measure. 3 See Hadar and Russell (1969), Hanoch and Levy (1969), Levy (2006, 2008), and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970, 1971). 4 VaR measures market risk by determining how much the value of a portfolio (or a security) could decline over a given probability as a result of changes in market prices or rates. 1 not clear. Also, VaR ignores the gain side of the gamble and even on the loss side, it concentrates only on that loss which hits the confidence level. The losses beyond the VaR threshold are not taken into account when computing the maximum likely loss of a portfolio. Since these traditional measures of dispersion and downside risk do not satisfy the monotonicity and/or duality conditions, the riskiness measures provide more accurate characterization of underlying true risk. Therefore, we think that the recently proposed measures of riskiness deserve further investigation. Both Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) introduce riskiness measures based on the physical return distribution of gambles. This paper contributes to the literature by introducing a model-free options’ implied measure of riskiness based on the risk-neutral return distribution of financial securities. We should note that it is difficult to obtain accurate estimates of riskiness under the physical measure because one has to make a distributional assumption. Aumann and Serrano (2008) assume a Normal distribution and Foster and Hart (2009) assume a Binomial distribution to illustrate the meaning of their riskiness measures. However, there is ample evidence showing significant departures from normality, i.e., the empirical distribution of financial securities is typically skewed, is peaked around the mean (leptokurtic) and has fat tails. Therefore, generating empirical measures of riskiness requires precise estimates of the mean, standard deviation, and higher order moments of the return distribution. However, the literature points out that computing the moments of the return distribution is a difficult task because one has to know the exact return distribution under the physical measure. Since this is not possible, one needs to make a distributional assumption, but then she needs a very long sample to generate reliable estimates of the moments under the assumed distribution. This paper makes an innovative contribution to the literature by providing a distribution-free riskiness measure that can be obtained from actively traded options and does not rely on any particular assumptions about the empirical return distribution. Suppose an investor needs to find a one-month ahead expected riskiness of a financial security. Under the physical measure, riskiness can only be obtained from the past historical data (e.g., daily returns over the past one year) and the investor has to use this historical measure to proxy for future riskiness. However, this physical (or historical) measure does not reflect the market’s expectation of future riskiness because the history does not generally repeat itself. Using options’ implied measures of riskiness solves this problem by making future riskiness observable because option prices incorporate the market’s expectation of future return distribution. Starting with the global financial meltdown, there has been great interest among academics, market professionals, and regulators on the causes, remedies and future of the current financial crisis. There is 2 now a long literature examining the recent economic downturns, high volatility in financial markets, and transmission of tail risk across the world. An important contribution of our paper is to investigate the significance of aggregate riskiness in predicting future economic downturns. The late-2000s financial crisis (often called the Credit Crunch or the Global Financial Crisis) is considered by many economists to be the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s. It resulted in the collapse of large financial institutions, the bailout of banks by national governments, and downturns in stock markets around the world. In many areas, the housing market had also suffered, resulting in numerous evictions, foreclosures and prolonged vacancies. It contributed to the failure of key businesses, declines in consumer wealth estimated in the trillions of U.S. dollars, and a significant decline in economic activity, leading to a severe global economic recession in 2008. The financial crisis was triggered by a liquidity shortfall in the United States banking system in 2008. The collapse of the U.S. housing bubble, which peaked in 2007, caused the values of securities tied to U.S. real estate pricing to plummet, damaging financial institutions globally. Questions regarding bank solvency, declines in credit availability and damaged investor confidence had an impact on global stock markets, where securities suffered large losses during 2008 and early 2009. Economies worldwide slowed during this period, as credit tightened and international trade declined. Governments and central banks responded with unprecedented fiscal stimulus, monetary policy expansion and institutional bailouts. While many causes for the financial crisis have been suggested, with varying weight assigned by experts, the United States Senate Financial Crisis Report indicates that “the crisis was not a natural disaster, but the result of high risk, complex financial products; undisclosed conflicts of interest; and the failure of regulators, the credit rating agencies, and the market itself to rein in the excesses of Wall Street.”5 Critics argued that credit rating agencies and investors failed to accurately price the risk involved with mortgage-related financial products, and that governments did not adjust their regulatory practices to address 21st-century financial markets. In response to the financial crisis, both market-based and regulatory solutions have been implemented or they are under consideration. After introducing the forward-looking options’ implied measures of riskiness, we examine whether these newly proposed measures of riskiness predict future economic activity. We use individual equity options with various strikes and maturities (1 month to 12 months) and estimate expected future riskiness of individual stocks. Then, we define aggregate riskiness of the U.S. equity market as the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average of individual stocks’ riskiness. The results show strong predictive power 5 Senate Financial Crisis Report, 2011: http://hsgac.senate.gov/public/ files/Financial Crisis/FinancialCrisisReport.pdf. 3 of aggregate riskiness even after controlling for the options’ implied volatility (V IX) and the realized volatility of the U.S. equity market as well as the TED spread which is an indicator of interbank credit risk and the perceived health of the banking system. We also compare the options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness with the options’ implied volatility of the S&P 500 index (V IX) in terms of their power to forecast future economic activity.6 The results indicate that aggregate riskiness provides much more accurate predictions of future downturns than the V IX index, implying significant contribution of higher-order moments and tails of the risk-neutral distribution in predicting declines in economic growth. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides the original, physical measures of riskiness developed by earlier studies. Section 3 presents the newly proposed options’ implied measures of riskiness. Section 4 describes the data and variables. Section 5 presents the empirical results. Section 6 concludes the paper. 2. Physical Measures of Riskiness This section describes and compares the original, physical measures of riskiness developed by Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009). 2.1. Aumann and Serrano’s Economic Index Measure of Riskiness Aumann and Serrano (2008) assume a von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function for money which is strictly monotonic, strictly concave, and twice continuously differentiable, and defined over the entire real line. A gamble g is a random variable with real values - interpreted as dollar amounts - some of which are negative, and that has positive expectation. That is, an individual with utility function u accepts a gamble g at wealth w if E (u [w + g]) > u [w], where E stands for “expectation”. Aumann and Serrano (2008)’s measure of riskiness is based on a “duality” axiom between riskiness and risk aversion and positive homogeneity of degree one: DUALITY: Roughly duality says that less risk-averse decision makers accept riskier gambles. Define an index Q as a positive real-valued function on gambles and assume that gamble g is riskier than gamble h, i.e., Q [g] > Q [h]. If an individual i is more risk-averse than individual j, then whenever i accepts g at 6V IX is the Chicago Board Options Exchange’s (CBOE) market volatility index and it is a popular measure of the implied volatility of the aggregate stock market portfolio. Often referred to as the fear index or the fear gauge, it represents a measure of the market’s expectation of stock market volatility over the next 30-day period. 4 some wealth w, and Q [g] > Q [h], then j accepts h at w. POSITIVE HOMOGENEITY: Positive homogeneity represents the cardinal nature of riskiness, i.e., Q [ng] > nQ [g] for all positive numbers n. If g is a gamble, positive homogeneity implies that 2g is “twice as” risky as g, not just “more” risky. Aumann and Serrano (2008) show that for each gamble g, there is a unique positive number R [g] with ( ( −g E exp R [g] )) −1 = 0 (1) The index of riskiness denoted in (1) satisfies duality and positive homogeneity. Aumann and Serrano (2008) consider an agent with constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) coefficient α, who is indifferent between accepting and rejecting g. Applying (1) to the CARA utility function, u [x] = − exp (−αx), gives R [g] = α1 . That is, the riskiness of a gamble is the reciprocal of the CARA of an individual who is indifferent between taking and not taking that gamble. 2.2. Foster and Hart’s Operational Measure of Riskiness Foster and Hart (2009) shows that for every gamble g, there exists a unique real number R [g] > 0 such that a simple strategy with critical-wealth function Q guarantees no-bankruptcy if and only if Q [g] ≥ R [g] for every gamble g. R[g] is uniquely determined by the equation: ( ( g E log 1 + R [g] )) =0 (2) The condition Q [g] ≥ R [g] says that the minimal wealth level Q [g] at which g is accepted must be R [g] or higher, and so g is for sure rejected at all wealth levels below R [g], that is, at all w < R [g]. Thus, the riskiness measure of Foster and Hart (2009) is the minimal wealth level at which g may be accepted. R [g] in (2) may also be viewed as a sort of minimal “reserve” needed for g. Comparing the two physical measures of riskiness yields the following distinctions: (a) The riskiness measure of Aumann and Serrano (2008), RAS [g], is an index of riskiness based on comparing the gambles in terms of their riskiness, whereas the riskiness measure of Foster and Hart (2009), RFH [g] , is defined for each gamble separately. (b) RAS [g] is based on risk-averse expected-utility decision makers, whereas RFH [g] does not require utility functions and risk aversion, and just compares two situations: bankruptcy versus 5 no-bankruptcy or loss versus no-loss. (c) RAS [g] is based on the critical level of risk aversion, whereas RFH [g] is based on the critical level of wealth. The comparison between decision makers in Aumann and Serrano (2008) being more or less risk-averse - must hold at all wealth levels. In other words, RAS [g] looks for the critical risk aversion coefficient regardless of wealth, whereas RFH [g] looks for the critical wealth regardless of risk aversion. We further refer RFH to as the Foster and Hart (2009) measure of riskiness and RAS to as the Aumann and Serrano (2008) measure of riskiness. 3. Risk-Neutral Options Implied Measures of Riskiness This paper contributes to the existing literature by introducing the risk-neutral options’ implied measures of riskiness based on the Bakshi and Madan (2000) spanning formula. They show that any function of the form H(S) with E[H(S)] < ∞ can be spanned by as a collection of call and put options: [ ] ( ) [ ] ∫ H [S] = H S + S − S Hs S + S ∞ HSS [K] (S − K)+ dK + ∫ S 0 HSS [K] (K − S)+ dK (3) where HS (.) and HSS (.) represent the first and second derivative of H with respect to S. We denote gt+τ = Si (t, τ) − Si (t) Si (t) (4) the return on the risky asset i with an investment horizon τ. Si (t, τ) is the price of the individual security at time t + τ, and Si (t) is the price of the individual security at time t. In Propositions (1) and (2), we derive a model-free measure of riskiness from option prices.7 Proposition 1 Let RAS i,t be the riskiness measure of the risky asset with return-payoff gt+τ . Let C (Si (t) , K, τ) be the price at time t of the call option with strike price K, maturity τ. Let P (Si (t) , K, τ) be the price at time t of the put option with strike price K, maturity τ. Denote 1 + r f (t, τ) the return on the risk-free security. 7 Aumann and Serrano (2008) develop their physical measure of riskiness R relative to a gamble g interpreted as a random dollar amount, whereas we introduce options implied measures of riskiness by applying R to returns on g, not to dollar amounts. We should note that our newly proposed measure of riskiness retains the properties of R shown by Aumann and Serrano. 6 RAS i,t is the fixed point solution to (5) r f (t, τ) 1 = 1 + r f (t, τ) RAS i,t ∫ ∞ Si (t) [K]C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK + fRAS i,t ∫ Si (t) 0 where fRAS [K] = ( i,t − 1 )2 e RAS S (t) i i,t [K] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK fRAS i,t (5) (K−Si (t)) 1 RAS i,t Si (t) . (6) Proof: See Appendix A. Proposition 2 Let RFH i,t be the riskiness measure of the risky asset with return-payoff gt+τ . Let C (Si (t) , K, τ) be the price at time t of the call option with strike price K, maturity τ. Let P (Si (t) , K, τ) be the price at time t of the put option with strike price K, maturity τ. Denote 1 + r f (t, τ) the return on the risk-free security. RFH i,t is the fixed point solution to (7) r f (t, τ) 1 = FH 1 + r f (t, τ) Ri,t ∫ ∞ Si (t) fRFH [K]C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK + i,t ∫ Si (t) 0 fRFH [K] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK i,t (7) where fRFH [K] = ( i,t 1 1 )2 ( )2 . 1 K−Si (t) FH Ri,t Si (t) 1 + RFH Si (t) (8) i,t Proof: See Appendix A. The advantage of the option implied measures (5) and (7) is that they can be computed using option prices at any time, and they are not model-dependent. We also provide in Appendix B, the Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) option implied measures of riskiness when the return on the underlying assets are defined in terms of log returns.8 4. Data and Variable Definitions In this section we first describe the individual equity options data used to estimate the options’ implied measures of riskiness for individual stocks. Second, we introduce generalized physical measures of riskiness accounting for higher-order moments of the empirical return distribution. Third, we present aggregate 8 The results indicate that there is no significant empirical difference between the riskiness measures when simple or log returns are used. 7 riskiness of the U.S. equity market based on the physical and risk-neutral measures of individual stocks’ riskiness. Finally, we describe the TED spread proxying for default risk and the V IX index proxying for financial market uncertainty. 4.1. Equity Options Data The daily data on call and put option prices, and the corresponding strikes, maturities, and volatilities are from OptionMetrics. The OptionMetrics Volatility Surface computes the interpolated implied volatility surface separately for puts and calls using a kernel smoothing algorithm using options with various strikes and maturities. The volatility surface data contain prices and implied volatilities for a list of standardized options for constant maturities and deltas. A standardized option is only included if there exists enough underlying option price data on that date to accurately compute an interpolated value. The interpolations are done each day so that no forward-looking information is used in computing the volatility surface. One advantage of using the Volatility Surface is that it avoids having to make potentially arbitrary decisions on which strikes or maturities to include when computing options’ implied measures of riskiness based on the Bakshi and Madan (2000) spanning formula for each stock. In our empirical analyses, we use out-of-themoney call and put option prices with expirations of 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to estimate options’ implied measures of riskiness. In Volatility Surface, at-the-money call (put) options have a delta of 0.50 (-0.50). Out-of-the-money call options have delta of 0.20 to 0.50 and out-of-the-money put options have delta of -0.20 to -0.50. We use the longest sample available from January 1996 to October 2010. 4.2. Generalized Physical Measures of Riskiness In Section 2, we present the original measures of riskiness developed by Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009). As discussed earlier, Aumann and Serrano (2008) assume a Normal distribution and Foster and Hart (2009) assume a Binomial distribution to illustrate the meaning of their riskiness measures. In this section, we use a Taylor series expansion to introduce more generalized physical measures of riskiness that take into account higher-order moments of the empirical return distribution. Under the physical measure, the Aumann and Serrano (2008) riskiness measure RAS,P is solution to i,t ( ( Et exp − )) gt+1 RAS,P i,t 8 = 1. (9) ) ( t+1 − gAS,P Ri,t The Taylor expansion series of exp ) ( exp − ( gt+1 ≃ exp − RAS,P i,t 1 + ( 2! 1 − ( 3! around the expected value produces Et (gt+1 ) ) RAS,P i,t 1 ( 1 − RAS,P i,t (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 )) exp − ( 2 RAS,P i,t 1 )2 (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 )) exp − ( 3 RAS,P i,t )3 (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 )) exp − Et (gt+1 ) ) Et (gt+1 ) ) (10) RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t Et (gt+1 ) RAS,P i,t ) . We apply the expected value to (10) and deduce ( 1 − exp Et (gt+1 ) RAS,P i,t ) ( + 1 2! RAS,P i,t )2 Var [gt+1 ] − 3 1 ( )3 (Var [gt+1 ]) 2 SKEW [gt+1 ] = 0, AS,P 3! Ri,t (11) where Var [gt+1 ] and SKEW [gt+1 ] represent the variance and skewness of asset i return. The Aumann and Serrano measure of riskiness RAS,P is solution to (11). i,t Under the physical measure, the Foster and Hart (2009) riskiness measure RFH,P is solution to (12): i,t ( EtP ( log 1 + ) gt+1 RFH,P i,t ( ≃ log 1 + )) log 1 + gt+1 = 0. RFH,P i,t (12) ) Taylor expansion series of log 1 + ( ( gt+1 RFH,P i,t Et (gt+1 ) RFH,P i,t around Et (gt+1 ) is ) + (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 )) ( 1 FH,P Ri,t (13) t+1 ) 1 + Et (g FH,P Ri,t )2 ( )3 1 − 1 (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 ))2 ( 2! RFH,P i,t 1+ 9 Et (gt+1 ) RFH,P i,t 1 )2 + 2 (gt+1 − Et (gt+1 ))3 ( 3! FH,P Ri,t 1+ Et (gt+1 ) FH,P Ri,t )3 . The expected value of (13) can be simplified as ( log 1 + Et (gt+1 ) ( ) RFH,P i,t 1 − Var [gt+1 ] ( 2! )2 ( )3 1 1 FH,P Ri,t RFH,P i,t 1+ 3 2 )2 + (Var [gt+1 ]) 2 SKEW [gt+1 ] ( 3! Et (gt+1 ) RFH,P i,t 1+ )3 = 0. Et (gt+1 ) RFH,P i,t (14) The Foster and Hart riskiness measure is solution to (14). To generate the physical measures of riskiness for each month from January 1996 to October 2010, we first compute the mean, standard deviation, and skewness of daily returns over the past 1, 3, 6, and 12 months and then numerically back out the physical measure of riskiness from equation (11) for Aumann and Serrano (2008) and equation (14) for Foster and Hart (2009). The physical measures of riskiness are estimated for each optionable stock in OptionMetrics. We should note that optionable stocks are generally liquid and big in terms of market capitalization, hence they do not carry significant size or liquidity premium. 4.3. Aggregate Measures of Riskiness Figures 1 and 2 show the options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness (Foster-Hart and AumannSerrano), computed as the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. Figures 3 and 4 display the physical measures of aggregate riskiness (Foster-Hart and Aumann-Serrano), computed as the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average of firm-level physical measures of riskiness obtained from daily stock returns over the past 1, 3, 6, and 12 months. The figures present significant time-series variation in both the risk-neutral and the physical measures of aggregate riskiness. Although there is no specific pattern in the physical measures of riskiness, the forward-looking measures of aggregate riskiness seem to track lower economic activity. Notably, the options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness exhibit extremely high values during large falls of the market corresponding to financial crisis period (2007 - 2010). 4.4. TED Spread The TED spread is the difference between the interest rates on interbank loans and short-term U.S. government debt (T-bills). TED is an acronym formed from T-Bill and ED, the ticker symbol for the 10 Eurodollar futures contract.9 The size of the spread is usually denominated in basis points (bps). For example, if the T-bill rate is 5.10% and ED trades at 5.50%, the TED spread is 40 bps. The TED spread fluctuates over time but generally has remained within the range of 10 and 50 bps (0.1% and 0.5%) except in times of financial crisis. A rising TED spread often presages a downturn in the U.S. stock market, as it indicates that liquidity is being withdrawn. The TED spread is an indicator of perceived credit risk in the general economy. This is because T-bills are considered risk-free while LIBOR reflects the credit risk of lending to commercial banks. When the TED spread increases, that is a sign that lenders believe the risk of default on interbank loans (also known as counterparty risk) is increasing. Interbank lenders therefore demand a higher rate of interest, or accept lower returns on safe investments such as T-bills. When the risk of bank defaults is considered to be decreasing, the TED spread decreases. Figure 5 plots the TED spread for each month from January 1996 to October 2010. Excluding the Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) and post-LTCM periods (1998-2000) and the recent financial crisis period (2007-2010), the sample average of the TED spread is about 35 basis points with a maximum of 73 bps. During 2007, the subprime mortgage crisis increased the TED spread to a region of 150-200 bps. For the crisis period in 2007 (July 2007-December 2007), the average TED spread is about 140 basis points with a maximum of 202 bps. On September 17, 2008, the TED spread exceeded 300 bps, breaking the previous record set after the Black Monday crash of 1987. Some higher readings for the spread were due to inability to obtain accurate LIBOR rates in the absence of a liquid unsecured lending market. On October 10, 2008, the TED spread reached another new high of 457 basis points (after the collapse of Lehman Brothers). Figure 5 shows that during 2008 the monthly difference between the 3-month LIBOR and T-bills is averaged at 160 bps with a maximum of 365 bps. In the first half of 2009, the monthly TED spread remained high in the range of 73 to 89 bps with an average of 84 bps. In 2010, the TED spread has returned slowly to its long-term average of 30 basis points, hitting a low of 11 basis points in March, as confidence returned. But as the Greek debt crisis escalated into widespread fears about the health of the Eurozone, the TED spread started to rise again, moving above 45 basis points by mid-June. 9 Initially, the TED spread was the difference between the interest rates for three-month U.S. Treasuries contracts and the three-month Eurodollars contract as represented by the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR). However, since the Chicago Mercantile Exchange dropped T-bill futures, the TED spread is now calculated as the difference between the three-month T-bill interest rate and three-month LIBOR. 11 4.5. VIX Index V IX is the ticker symbol for the Chicago Board Options Exchange Market Volatility Index, a popular measure of the implied volatility of S&P 500 index options. The V IX is the square-root of the risk neutral expectation of the S&P 500 variance over the next 30 calendar days. The V IX is quoted as an annualized standard deviation. Although the V IX is often called the “fear index”, a high V IX is not necessarily bearish for stocks. Instead, the V IX is a measure of market perceived volatility in either direction, including to the upside. In practical terms, when investors anticipate large upside volatility, they are unwilling to sell upside call stock options unless they receive a large premium. Option buyers will be willing to pay such high premiums only if similarly anticipating a large upside move. The resulting aggregate of increases in upside stock option call prices raises the V IX just as does the aggregate growth in downside stock put option premiums that occurs when option buyers and sellers anticipate a likely sharp move to the downside. Hence high V IX readings mean investors see significant risk that the market will move sharply, whether downward or upward. The highest V IX readings occur when investors anticipate that huge moves in either direction are likely. Only when investors perceive neither significant downside risk nor significant upside potential will the V IX be low. Figure 6 plots the end-of-month V IX index from January 1996 to October 2010. Between 1996 and 2010, the average value of monthly V IX is about 22% per annum with a maximum of 60%. During 2007, the subprime mortgage crisis increased the V IX to a region of 20% to 25%. In 2008, the V IX index is averaged at 32% with a maximum of 60% in October 2008. In the first half of 2009, the monthly V IX index remained high in the range of 20% to 45% with an average of 32% per annum. In 2010, similar to the TED spread, the V IX index has returned slowly to 24% per annum hitting a low of 18% in March, as confidence returned. But as the Greek debt crisis increased financial market uncertainty across the world, the V IX index started to rise again, moving to 35% per annum in June 2010.10 5. Empirical Results The recent subprime mortgage crisis is an ongoing real estate and financial crisis triggered by a dramatic rise in mortgage delinquencies and foreclosures in the United States, with major adverse consequences for banks and financial markets around the globe. Between June 2007 and November 2008, Americans lost 10 Over the sample period January 2, 1996 to October 29, 2010, the daily V IX index reached its highest value (80.86% per annum) on November 28, 2008. The daily VIX is in the range of 60% to 80% in most of October and November of 2008. 12 more than a quarter of their net worth. By early November 2008, a broad U.S. stock index, the S&P 500, was down 45% from its 2007 high. Housing prices had dropped 20% from their 2006 peak, with futures markets signaling a 30-35% potential drop. Total home equity in the United States, which was valued at $13 trillion at its peak in 2006, had dropped to $8.8 trillion by mid-2008 and was still falling in late 2008. Total retirement assets, Americans’ second-largest household asset, dropped by 22%, from $10.3 trillion in 2006 to $8 trillion in mid-2008. During the same period, savings and investment assets (apart from retirement savings) lost $1.2 trillion and pension assets lost $1.3 trillion. Taken together, these losses total a staggering $8.3 trillion.11 During 2008, three of the largest U.S. investment banks either went bankrupt (Lehman Brothers) or were sold at fire sale prices to other banks (Bear Stearns and Merrill Lynch). These failures augmented the instability in the global financial system. The significant declines and uncertainty in financial markets, low economic growth, and high unemployment rate continued until mid-2009. Falling prices also resulted in 23% of U.S. homes worth less than the mortgage loan by September 2010, providing a financial incentive for borrowers to enter foreclosure. Although there have been aftershocks, the financial crisis itself ended sometime between late-2008 and mid-2009. A relevant question is whether the time-varying riskiness of financial markets contains significant information about future macroeconomic activity. In other words, can we use information in the stock and options markets to predict future economic downturns and financial crisis? The newly proposed forwardlooking measures of riskiness well capture lower economic activity and the recent financial crisis. As shown in Figures 1 and 2, between July 2007 and October 2010 (end of our sample), there is a significant upward trend as well as jump in the options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness that track instability in the global financial system. In this section, we investigate whether the aggregate measures of riskiness can predict real economic activity. As discussed earlier, the riskiness measure of Foster and Hart (2009) is a combination of the statistical moments such as the mean, volatility, skewness, kurtosis, and tails of a physical return distribution. The options’ implied riskiness measure of Foster and Hart introduced in the paper can be viewed as a combination of the first, second and higher-order moments as well as the tails of a risk-neutral distribution. Since the options’ implied risk-neutral distributions incorporate the market’s forecast of future return distributions and they take into account downturns in financial markets, we think that when measured at the aggregate level, riskiness of the U.S. equity market may potentially predict future declines in economic activity. 11 These figures are taken from the 2009 speeches of the Federal Reserve Bank (FRB) Chairman Ben Bernanke: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/2009speech.htm. 13 Aumann and Serrano (2008) propose a measure of riskiness based on investors’ risk tolerance. Risk tolerance is one of the most important factors influencing asset allocation because it takes into account investors’ ability to take risks. A conservative or risk averse investor would favor investments in which her capital is preserved, whereas an aggressive investor can risk losing her investment to generate higher profits. According to Aumann and Serrano (2008), aggregate riskiness is related to aggregate risk aversion of market investors. Since aggregate risk aversion affects investors’ investment and consumption decisions, aggregate riskiness may potentially affect future economic activity. The options’ implied riskiness measure of Aumann and Serrano introduced in the paper takes into account time-series variation in aggregate risk aversion and may potentially be linked to business cycle fluctuations. We determine increases and decreases in real economic activity by relying on the Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI index), which is a monthly index designed to assess production, consumption, employment, and related inflationary pressure. The CFNAI is a weighted average of 85 existing monthly indicators of national economic activity. It is constructed to have an average value of zero and a standard deviation of one.12 Since economic activity tends toward trend growth rate over time, a positive index reading corresponds to growth above trend and a negative index reading corresponds to growth below trend. Since the underlying monthly macroeconomic data series are volatile, the monthly CFNAI index is also quite volatile. The Chicago Fed generates the three-month moving average of the CFNAI index (CFNAI MA3 index) to reduce the month-to-month volatility. In our empirical analyses, we use both the CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 indices. We also compare the options’ implied and physical measures of aggregate riskiness with the options’ implied volatility of the S&P 500 index. We use the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE)’s V IX implied volatility that provides the market’s forecast of aggregate volatility by using real-time S&P 500 index option prices. Since V IX is known as the fear index and captures financial market uncertainty, it may potentially predict future economic downturns as well. We investigate the relative performance of aggregate riskiness and aggregate implied volatility in predicting future economic activity. Panel A of Table 1 reports the correlation matrix for the value-weighted average options’ implied measures of riskiness, the V IX implied volatility, the CFNAI and CFNAI MA3 economic activity indices for the sample period January 1996 - October 2010. As reported in Panel A, the correlations between the 12 The 85 economic indicators that are included in the CFNAI are drawn from four broad categories of data: production and income; employment, unemployment, and hours; personal consumption and housing; and sales, orders, and inventories. Each of these data series measures some aspect of overall macroeconomic activity. The derived index provides a single, summary measure of a factor common to these national economic data. 14 V IX and the CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 indices are about the same as the correlations between aggregate riskiness measures and the CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 indices. Hence we rely on multivariate regressions to determine whether the V IX or aggregate riskiness measures have a stronger link with macroeconomic activity index. A notable point in Panel A is that the correlations between the options’ implied measures of aggregate volatility and aggregate riskiness are in the range of 0.46 to 0.53. This relatively low correlation at the aggregate level indicates significant contribution of other moments (such as skewness, kurtosis, and tails) to the aggregate measure of riskiness. Panel B of Table 1 reports the correlation matrix for the equal-weighted average options’ implied measures of riskiness, the V IX implied volatility, the CFNAI and CFNAI MA3 economic activity indices and the qualitative results are very similar to those reported in Panel A. Panels C and D of Table 1 show lower association between the physical measures of aggregate riskiness and the CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 indices. At an earlier stage of the study, we investigate the predictive power of aggregate measures of physical riskiness and find that the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average measures of physical riskiness do not predict future economic downturns. The regressions results with the physical measures and the control variables are available upon request. We now examine the relative performance of aggregate riskiness and V IX in predicting future economic downturns after controlling for the T ED spread proxying for default risk of the financial sector. Specifically, we estimate the time-series regressions of one-month ahead CFNAI MA3 index on the valueweighted average options’ implied measures of riskiness, the V IX index, and the T ED spread: CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1 RFH,VW + λ2V IXt + λ3 T EDt + εt+1 i,t (15) CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1 RAS,VW + λ2V IXt + λ3 T EDt + εt+1 i,t (16) where CFNAI MA3t+1 is the 3-month moving average of the CFNAI index in month t + 1, RFH,VW denotes i,t the value-weighted average options’ implied measure of Foster-Hart riskiness in month t, RAS,VW denotes i,t the value-weighted average options’ implied measure of Aumann-Serrano riskiness in month t, V IXt is the annualized implied volatility of the S&P 500 index options in month t, and T EDt is the T ED spread in month t. Table 2 presents the predictive regression results for the period January 1996 - October 2010. The Newey and West (1987) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. The last column shows the adjusted R2 values. The first four regressions in the top panel of Table 2 report significantly negative slopes on RFH,VW i,t with the Newey-West t-statistics ranging from -2.38 to -3.42, indicating that higher levels of aggregate riskiness predict lower macroeconomic activity. This result is robust across all measures of the value15 weighted average riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The options’ implied measure of riskiness, RFH,VW , is a combination of the mean, volatility, and higheri,t order moments as well as the tails of a risk-neutral distribution. Since RFH,VW captures not only the average i,t fluctuations, but also the extreme fluctuations of the risk-neutral distribution, it accounts for downturns in predicts future declines in economic growth. financial markets. Hence, RFH,VW i,t The first four regressions in Table 2 also exhibit significantly negative slopes on the T ED spread with the t-statistics ranging from -3.41 to -3.76, indicating that an increase in the spread between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rate predicts lower economic activity. This makes economic sense because as the T ED spread increases, the default risk is considered to be increasing. Since, the risk of a bank defaulting is slightly higher than that of the U.S. government defaulting, the T ED spread measures the estimated risks that banks pose on each other. The higher the perceived risk that one or several banks may have liquidity or solvency problems, the higher the rate you will ask from your loans to other banks (LIBOR) compared to your loans to the government (T-bill rate). Consequently, the T ED spread is a great indicator of interbank credit risk and the perceived health of the banking system. The significantly negative slope on the T ED spread indicates that an increase in interbank credit risk (or decrease in the stability of the financial system) predicts future economic downturns.13 The first four regressions in Table 2 provide no evidence for a robust, significant link between the V IX index and the CFNAI MA3 macroeconomic activity index. Although the slopes on the V IX index are estimated to be negative, they are not statistically significant at conventional levels. These results suggest that aggregate riskiness provides much more accurate predictions of future economic downturns than the V IX index, implying significant contribution of higher-order moments and tails of the risk-neutral distribution in predicting declines in economic growth. In addition to the risk-neutral measure of market volatility (V IX), we now control for the physical measure of aggregate volatility (realized volatility) in predicting future economic downturns. Specifically, we estimate the time-series regressions of one-month ahead CFNAI MA3 index on the options’ implied aggregate riskiness, the V IX index, the T ED spread, and the realized volatility of the S&P 500 index: CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1 RFH,VW + λ2V IXt + λ3 T EDt + λ4 RVt + εt+1 i,t (17) CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1 RAS,VW + λ2V IXt + λ3 T EDt + λ4 RVt + εt+1 i,t (18) 13 When there is a downturn in the economy, banks suspect that some banks may encounter problems. However, they do not know which banks, so they restrict interbank lending, resulting in higher TED spreads and lower liquidity in the interbank market, which ultimately produces lower credit availability for consumers and corporates. 16 where RVt is the annualized realized volatility of the U.S. equity market in month t.14 The last four regressions in Table 2 show that after controlling for the realized volatility of the stock market portfolio, the negative link between RFH,VW and CFNAI MA3 remains significant. The Newey-West t-statistics of the i,t slopes on RFH,VW are in the range of -2.55 to -3.52. Similar to our earlier findings, this result is robust i,t across all measures of the value-weighted average riskiness. After including the realized volatility of the S&P500 index, the economic and statistical significance of the T ED spread reduced, but the slopes on TED are still negative and significant with the t-statistics ranging from -2.11 to -2.35. The slopes on the realized volatility are estimated to be negative and significant with the t-statistics between -2.18 and -2.60, implying that an increase in stock market volatility predicts declines in future economic activity. A notable point in the last four regressions is that the slopes on the V IX index are almost zero and they are statistically insignificant with the t-statistics ranging from 0.13 to 0.80. Overall, these results show that after controlling for the T ED spread and the realized volatility of the U.S. equity market, the options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness successfully predict future economic activity, whereas the options’ implied measure of aggregate volatility (V IX) has no significant association with future economic downturns. As shown in the bottom panel of Table 2, the results from the value-weighted average options’ implied measure of Aumann-Serrano riskiness, RAS,VW , are very similar to those obtained from RFH,VW . We find a i,t i,t and the CFNAI MA3 index. The significantly negative negative and highly significant link between RAS,VW i,t relation between the T ED spread, the realized volatility, and the CFNAI MA3 index remains intact. Another notable in Table 2 is the large R2 values. The adjusted R2 ’s reported in the last column of Table 2 are between 48% and 56% without the realized volatility and between 51% and 59% with the realized volatility of the market. To clarify the marginal contribution of RFH,VW and RAS,VW in forecasting future i,t i,t economic downturns, we estimate the predictive regressions with the T ED spread and the V IX index only: CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1V IXt + λ2 T EDt + εt+1 (19) The adjusted R2 from this regression is about 39%. Adding RFH,VW or RAS,VW to equation (19) increases the i,t i,t adjusted R2 to the range of 48%-56% when we use the options’ implied measures of riskiness. Improvement in the adjusted R2 values provides clear evidence for the strong predictive power of riskiness. 14 Following a series of papers by Andersen, Bollerslev, and Diebold et al. (2001, 2003), daily realized volatility of the U.S. equity market is computed as the sum of squared 5-minute returns on the S&P 500 index. We then annualize the daily realized volatility assuming 252 trading days in a year. 17 To provide further evidence for the weak performance of the V IX index in forecasting future economic downturns, we run the following regression with the 1-month options’ implied measure of riskiness, RFH,VW , and the T ED spread: i,t CFNAI MA3t+1 = λ0 + λ1 RFH,VW + λ2 T EDt + εt+1 i,t (20) The adjusted R2 from equation (20) is 54.27%. As shown in the last column of Table 2, adding the V IX index to equation (20) increases the adjusted R2 to 55.84%. This small improvement in the adjusted R2 (only 1.57%) provides another evidence for the weak predictive power of the V IX index. Table 3 replicates the main predictive regressions using the equal-weighted average options’ implied measures of riskiness (RFH,EW and RFH,EW ), the V IX index, the T ED spread, and the realized volatility of i,t i,t the U.S. equity market. Similar to our earlier results in Table 2, we find a strongly negative link between aggregate riskiness and the CFNAI MA3 index. The significantly negative relation between the T ED spread, the realized volatility, and the CFNAI MA3 index remains intact as well. However, the V IX index has no forecasting power for future declines in economic activity. Table 4 provides further robustness checks by presenting evidence for the CFNAI index. Panel A (Panel B) shows that the value-weighted (equal-weighted) average options’ implied measures of riskiness strongly predict the one-month ahead CFNAI index, whereas the V IX index remains a poor determinant of future economic activity. At an earlier stage of the study, we replicate our main findings by excluding the recent crisis period 2008-2010. Specifically, we estimate equations (17)-(18) for the sample period January 1996 - December 2007 and find that the predictive power of aggregate riskiness remains economically and statistically significant. 6. Conclusion Aumann and Serrano (2008) introduce an economic index measure of riskiness that looks for the critical utility regardless of wealth. Foster and Hart (2009) develop an operational measure of riskiness that looks for the critical wealth regardless of utility. Both measures of riskiness are originated based on the physical return distribution of risky assets. In this paper, we introduce generalized physical measures of riskiness that take into account higher-order moments of the empirical return distribution. More importantly, we develop new measures of riskiness based on the risk-neutral return distribution of underlying 18 assets. Riskiness of an underlying financial security (e.g., equity) is derived from the prices of derivative securities written on the underlying asset (i.e., prices of call and put options on equity). The newly proposed forward-looking measures of riskiness condense options’ implied risk-neutral probability distribution to a scalar and satisfy the monotonicity and duality conditions. We also introduce the aggregate measures of riskiness for the U.S. equity market and investigate their predictive power for future economic downturns. Although there is no specific pattern in the physical measures of aggregate riskiness, the forward-looking options’ implied measures of aggregate riskiness successfully track lower economic activity. Finally, we examine the relative performance of aggregate riskiness and aggregate volatility (V IX) in forecasting declines in economic growth. The results indicate that aggregate riskiness provides accurate predictions of future economic downturns, whereas the V IX implied volatility does not add significant, marginal predictive power for real economic activity. The strong predictive power of aggregate riskiness remains intact even after controlling for the realized volatility of the U.S. equity market, the V IX index proxying for financial market uncertainty, and the T ED spread proxying for interbank credit risk and the perceived health of the banking system. Our findings suggest significant contribution of the higher-order moments and the tails of the riskneutral distribution in forecasting declines in economic growth. Hence, regulators can utilize readily available information in the options market to predict downturns in financial markets and macroeconomic activity. Our aggregate measure of riskiness can be viewed as a complement to bank systemic risk measures (e.g., CoVaR and Marginal Expected Shortfall), and can be used to calibrate systemic risk premiums set by bank regulators. 19 References Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F. X., Ebens, H., 1969. The distribution of realized stock return volatility. Journal of Financial Economics 61, 43–76. Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F. X., Labys, P., 2003. Modeling and forecasting realized volatility. Econometrica 71, 25–34. Aumann, R. J., Serrano, R., 2008. An economic index of riskiness. Journal of Political Economy 116, 810–836. Bakshi, G., Madan, D., 2000. Spanning and derivative-security valuation. Journal of Financial Economics 55, 205–238. Bali, T. G., Cakici, N., Chabi-Yo, F., 2011. A generalized measure of riskiness. Management Science 57, 1406–1423. Foster, D. P., Hart, S., 2009. An operational measure of riskiness. Journal of Political Economy 117, 785– 814. Foster, D. P., Hart, S., 2011. A wealth-requirement axiomatization of riskiness. Working paper. Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Center for Rationality. Hadar, J., Russell, W., 1969. Rules for ordering uncertain prospects. American Economic Review 59, 25– 34. Hanoch, G., Levy, H., 1969. The efficiency analysis of choices involving risk. Review of Economic Studies 36, 335–46. Hart, S., 2011. Comparing risks by acceptance and rejection. Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming). Levy, H., 2006. Decision Making Under Uncertainty: Stochastic Dominance. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York, NY. Levy, H., 2008. First degree stochastic dominance violations: Decision weights and bounded rationality. Economic Journal 118, 759–774. Newey, W. K., West, K. D., 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 703–708. Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J., 1970. Increasing risk I: A definition. Journal of Economic Theory 2, 225–243. Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J., 1971. Increasing risk: II. its economic consequences. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 66–84. 20 Appendix A: Recovering the Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) riskiness measures from option prices: The case of simple returns We use simple returns, and derive the Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) riskiness measures from option prices. Aumann and Serrano (2008) Theorem A in Aumann and Serrano (2008) show that for each gamble gt+τ , there is a unique positive number Rt [gt+τ ] such that ( Et e ) gt+τ t [gt+τ ] −R − 1 = 0. (A1) UNDER THE RISK NEUTRAL MEASURE, (A1) can be expressed as Et∗ ( gt+τ t [gt+τ ] −R e ) −1 = 0 (A2) where gt+τ = Si (t, τ) − Si (t) Si (t) (A3) represents the return on the risky asset i with an investment horizon τ. Notice that, under the risk neutral measure Et∗ (gt+τ ) = r f (t, τ) . (A4) ) ( g − t+τ where r f (t, τ) represents the risk-free rate for the time period [t,t + τ]. Since Et∗ e Rt [gt+τ ] − 1 is finite, we can use the Bakshi and Madan (2000) spanning formula: [ ] ( ) [ ] ∫ H [S] = H S + S − S Hs S + S ∞ + HSS [K] (S − K) dK + ∫ S 0 HSS [K] (K − S)+ dK. (A5) We use the return’s definition (A3) and apply the Bakshi and Madan (2000) formula (A5) to gt+τ t [gt+τ ] −R H [S (t, τ)] = e 21 − 1. (A6) with S = Si (t). We obtain e gt+τ t [gt+τ ] −R ( ) 1 − 1 = (Si (t, τ) − Si (t)) − Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) ∫ ∞ (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 + e i t [ t+τ ] (Si (t, τ) − K)+ dK 2 2 Si (t) Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) ∫ Si (t) (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 [ ] + e i t t+τ (K − Si (t, τ))+ dK. Si2 (t) Rt2 [gt+τ ] 0 (A7) Now, we apply the expectation operator to (A7) and get 1 r f (t, τ) Rt [gt+τ ] ) (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 = e i t [ t+τ ] Et∗ (Si (t, τ) − K)+ dK 2 2 Si (t) Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) ∫ Si (t) (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 + e i t [ t+τ ] Et∗ (K − Si (t, τ))+ dK. 2 2 Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] 0 ∫ ∞ ( (A8) Notice that the prices of the call and put options are: 1 E ∗ (Si (t, τ) − K)+ = C (Si (t) , K, τ) , (1 + r f (t, τ)) t 1 E ∗ (K − Si (t, τ))+ = P (Si (t) , K, τ) . (1 + r f (t, τ)) t Hence (A8) can be written as r f (t, τ) 1 (1 + r f (t, τ)) Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 = e i t [ t+τ ] C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK 2 2 Si (t) Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) ∫ Si (t) (K−S (t)) − S (t)R ig 1 + e i t [ t+τ ] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK. Si2 (t) Rt2 [gt+τ ] 0 ∫ ∞ (A9) The riskiness measure Rt [gt+τ ] is, therefore, solution to (A9). Foster and Hart (2009) Theorem 1 in Foster and Hart (2009) show that there exists a critical wealth level Rt [gt+τ ] such as ( Et ( gt+τ log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] )) = 0. UNDER THE RISK NEUTRAL MEASURE, (A10) can be expressed as 22 (A10) Et∗ ( ( gt+τ log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] )) = 0. (A11) where gt+τ is defined in (A3). Notice that, under the risk neutral measure, Et∗ (gt+τ ) = r f (t, τ) . (A12) ( ( )) where r f (t, τ) represents the risk-free rate for the time period [t,t + τ]. Since Et∗ log 1 + Rtg[gt+τ is t+τ ] finite, we can use the Bakshi and Madan (2000) spanning formula (A5). Now, we consider ( gt+τ H [Si (t, τ)] = log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] ) (A13) with S = Si (t) and apply (A5) to (A13) gives ( gt+τ log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] ) ( = log (1) + (Si (t, τ) − Si (t)) − − ∫ ∞ 1 Rt [gt+τ ]Si (t) Si (t) ∫ Si (t) 1+ 1 Rt [gt+τ ] K Si (t) 1 Rt [gt+τ ]Si (t) 0 ( 1+ 1 Rt [gt+τ ] ( 1 ) Rt [gt+τ ] Si (t) 2 (A14) ) (Si (t, τ) − K)+ dK −1 2 K Si (t) −1 ) (K − Si (t, τ))+ dK. Therefore, (A14) can be simplified to ( gt+τ log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] ) ) Si (t, τ) − Si (t) = Si (t) ∫ ∞ 1 1 + − ( )2 (Si (t, τ) − K) dK 2 Si (t) Si (t) K Rt [gt+τ ] + Si (t) − 1 1 Rt [gt+τ ] − 1 2 Si (t) ( ∫ Si (t) 0 (A15) 1 + ( )2 (K − Si (t, τ)) dK. K Rt [gt+τ ] + Si (t) − 1 We apply the expectation operator under the risk neutral measure to (A15): 1 r f (t, τ) Rt [gt+τ ] = 1 2 Si (t) + ∫ ∞ 1 + ∗ ( )2 Et (Si (t, τ) − K) dK Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] + SiK(t) − 1 1 Rt [gt+τ ] ∫ Si (t) 0 1 1 ( Si2 (t) Rt [gt+τ ] + SiK(t) 23 + ∗ )2 Et (K − Si (t, τ)) dK −1 (A16) We recall that the prices of the call and put options with strike K and maturity τ are given by (A17) and (A18) respectively 1 Et∗ (Si (t, τ) − K)+ = C (Si (t) , K, τ) (1 + r f (t, τ)) 1 E ∗ (K − Si (t, τ))+ = P (Si (t) , K, τ) (1 + r f (t, τ)) t (A17) (A18) where (1 + r f (t, τ)) represents the risk-free return for the time period [t,t + τ]. Hence, (A16) reduces to r f (t, τ) 1 1 + r f (t, τ) Rt [gt+τ ] 1 Si2 (t) = ∫ ∞ 1 ( )2 C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK Si (t) K Rt [gt+τ ] + Si (t) − 1 ∫ Si (t) + 0 1 1 ( Si2 (t) Rt [gt+τ ] + SiK(t) (A19) )2 P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK −1 which simplifies to r f (t, τ) 1 = 1 + r f (t, τ) Rt [gt+τ ] ∫ ∞ Si (t) fR [K]C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK + ∫ Si (t) 0 fR [K] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK (A20) with fR [K] = 1 1 ( Si2 (t) Rt2 [gt+τ ] 1+ 1 K 1 Rt [gt+τ ] ( Si (t) )2 − 1) (A21) Equation (A20) can be numerically solved to deduce the Foster and Hart (2009) critical wealth level Rt [gt+τ ] (solve for the fixed point f (x) = x). We further denote RtFH = Rt [gt+τ ]. 24 Appendix B: Recovering the Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) riskiness measures from option prices: The case of log returns We use log returns, and derive the Aumann and Serrano (2008) and Foster and Hart (2009) riskiness , measures from option prices. We denote the log return: gt+τ = log SSi (t,τ) i (t) Aumann and Serrano (2008) UNDER THE RISK NEUTRAL MEASURE, the riskiness measure in Theorem A of Aumann and Serrano (2008) is ( ) Et∗ e−gt+τ /Rt [gt+τ ] − 1 = 0. (B1) We apply Bakshi and Madan (2000) formula (A5) to H [Si (t, τ)] = e−gt+τ /Rt [gt+τ ] − 1 (B2) with S = Si (t). We obtain e −gt+τ /Rt [gt+τ ] ( ) 1 − 1 = (Si (t, τ) − Si (t)) − (B3) Rt [gt+τ ] Si (t) ) (( ) ∫ ∞ − R g1 log S K(t) 1 1 [ ] i e t t+τ + + (Si (t, τ) − K)+ dK Rt [gt+τ ] K 2 [Rt [gt+τ ] K]2 Si (t) (( ) ) ∫ Si (t) − R g1 log S K(t) 1 1 i + + e t [ t+τ ] (K − Si (t, τ))+ dK. 2 2 R [g ] K 0 t t+τ [Rt [gt+τ ] K] Now, we apply the expectation operator to (B3) and get 1 r f (t, τ) Rt [gt+τ ] ∫ ∞ (( ) 1 = Si (t) ∫ Si (t) Rt [gt+τ (( + ] K2 + 1 Rt [gt+τ ] K 2 0 1 2 [Rt [gt+τ ] K] + −R 1 t [gt+τ ] e 1 [Rt [gt+τ ] K]2 ) log S K(t) Et∗ (Si (t, τ) − K)+ dK (B4) i −R e ) 1 t [gt+τ ] log S K(t) ) i Et∗ (K − Si (t, τ))+ dK. Hence, (B4) can be written as r f (t, τ) 1 (1 + r f (t, τ)) Rt [gt+τ ] ∫ ∞ = (( ) 1 1 −R 1 t [gt+τ ] log S K(t) ) i C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK(B5) + e Rt [gt+τ ] K 2 [Rt [gt+τ ] K]2 ) ) (( ∫ Si (t) − R g1 log S K(t) 1 1 i e t [ t+τ ] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK. + + Rt [gt+τ ] K 2 [Rt [gt+τ ] K]2 0 Si (t) 25 Therefore, Rt [gt+τ ] is the fixed-point solution to (B5). Foster and Hart (2009) UNDER THE RISK NEUTRAL MEASURE, Et∗ ( ( gt+τ log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] )) =0 (B6) We then apply the Bakshi and Madan (2000) formula (A5) to ( gt+τ H [Si (t, τ)] = log 1 + Rt [gt+τ ] ) (B7) with S = Si (t). We obtain ( log 1 + gt+τ Rt [gt+τ ] ) ( ) 1 = log (1) + (Si (t, τ) − Si (t)) Rt [gt+τ ] Si (t) ( ) K ∫ ∞ 1 Rt [gt+τ ] + log Si (t) + 1 + − 2 ( ( ))2 (Si (t, τ) − K) dK K Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] + log SiK(t) ( ) ∫ Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] + log K + 1 Si (t) 1 + − 2 ( ( ))2 (K − Si (t, τ)) dK K 0 K Rt [gt+τ ] + log Si (t) (B8) Applying the expectation operator under the risk neutral measure to (B8) gives: r f (t, τ) 1 = (1 + r f (t, τ)) Rt [gt+τ ] ∫ ∞ Si (t) fR [K]C (Si (t) , K, τ) dK + ∫ Si (t) 0 fR [K] P (Si (t) , K, τ) dK ( ) 1 K 1 1 + log + Rt [gt+τ ] Si (t) Rt [gt+τ ] 1 1 fR [K] = 2 ( ( ))2 . K Rt [gt+τ ] 1 + Rt [g1t+τ ] log SiK(t) (B9) Equation (B9) can be solved numerically to recover Rt [gt+τ ] (solve for the fixed point f (x) = x). 26 (B10) Table 1: Correlation Matrix This table presents the correlation matrix for the options’ implied and the physical measures of aggregate riskiness (Foster-Hart and Aumann-Serrano), the V IX implied volatility, the CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 indices for the sample period January 1996 - October 2010. The aggregate options’ implied measures of riskiness are computed as the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The aggregate physical measures of riskiness are computed as the value-weighted and the equal-weighted average of firm-level physical measures of riskiness obtained from daily stock returns over the past 1, 3, 6, and 12 months. The V IX implied volatility is obtained from the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) that provides the market’s forecast of aggregate volatility by using real-time S&P 500 index option prices. The CFNAI and the CFNAI MA3 economic activity indices are obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Panel A. Correlations with the Value-Weighted Average Options’ Implied Measures of Riskiness Foster-Hart Aumann-Serrano 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month V IX CFNAI RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t -0.5301 -0.5453 -0.4136 -0.4249 -0.4554 -0.5453 -0.4138 -0.4251 -0.4558 CFNAI MA3 -0.5947 -0.6406 -0.4981 -0.5087 -0.5363 -0.6406 -0.4983 -0.5089 -0.5368 V IX 1.0000 0.5277 0.4595 0.4700 0.4978 0.5278 0.4596 0.4701 0.4981 Panel B. Correlations with the Equal-Weighted Average Options’ Implied Measures of Riskiness Foster-Hart Aumann-Serrano 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month V IX CFNAI RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RFH,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t RAS,Q i,t -0.5301 -0.4777 -0.3512 -0.3644 -0.3945 -0.4777 -0.3514 -0.3643 -0.3943 CFNAI MA3 -0.5947 -0.5710 -0.4326 -0.4465 -0.4755 -0.5710 -0.4328 -0.4463 -0.4752 V IX 1.0000 0.4517 0.3790 0.3924 0.4251 27 0.4517 0.3793 0.3923 0.4250 Table 1 (continued) Panel C. Correlations with the Value-Weighted Average Physical Measures of Riskiness Foster-Hart Aumann-Serrano 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month V IX CFNAI RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t -0.5301 -0.0763 -0.3478 -0.3191 -0.3338 -0.0765 -0.3477 -0.3185 -0.3331 CFNAI MA3 -0.5947 -0.0444 -0.3186 -0.3228 -0.3754 -0.0444 -0.3186 -0.3222 -0.3746 V IX 1.0000 0.0394 0.4223 0.3117 0.4243 0.0393 0.4220 0.3113 0.4239 Panel D. Correlations with the Equal-Weighted Average Physical Measures of Riskiness Foster-Hart Aumann-Serrano 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month 1-month 3-month 6-month 12-month V IX CFNAI RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RFH,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t RAS,P i,t -0.5301 -0.2464 -0.2359 -0.2487 -0.2587 -0.2466 -0.2360 -0.2481 -0.2573 CFNAI MA3 -0.5947 -0.2637 -0.1892 -0.3033 -0.3001 -0.2639 -0.1894 -0.3028 -0.2987 V IX 1.0000 0.3259 0.3890 0.3830 0.2834 28 0.3258 0.3890 0.3827 0.2826 29 1-month Intercept RFH,VW i,t 0.7622 -0.0472 (4.82) (-3.42) 0.9495 (4.15) 0.9485 (4.18) 0.9367 (4.36) 0.5977 -0.0460 (3.84) (-3.52) 0.7814 (3.33) 0.7862 (3.36) 0.7827 (3.52) 0.7622 (4.82) 0.9495 (4.15) 0.9483 (4.18) 0.9364 (4.36) 0.5977 (3.84) 0.7813 (3.33) 0.7860 (3.36) 0.7824 (3.52) -0.0530 (-2.55) -0.0554 (-2.38) 3-month RFH,VW i,t -0.0666 (-2.67) -0.0700 (-2.52) 6-month RFH,VW i,t -0.0975 (-2.69) -0.1026 (-2.61) 12-month RFH,VW i,t -0.0460 (-3.52) -0.0472 (-3.42) 1-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0530 (-2.55) -0.0554 (-2.38) 3-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0667 (-2.68) -0.0701 (-2.52) 6-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0978 (-2.70) -0.1028 (-2.62) 12-month AS,VW Ri,t VIX -0.0184 (-1.48) -0.0286 (-1.96) -0.0269 (-1.85) -0.0232 (-1.62) 0.0126 (0.80) 0.0026 (0.13) 0.0032 (0.16) 0.0053 (0.29) -0.0184 (-1.48) -0.0286 (-1.96) -0.0269 (-1.85) -0.0231 (-1.62) 0.0126 (0.80) 0.0026 (0.13) 0.0032 (0.16) 0.0054 (0.29) TED -0.6266 (-3.41) -0.6092 (-3.56) -0.6256 (-3.66) -0.6520 (-3.76) -0.4443 (-2.20) -0.4212 (-2.11) -0.4407 (-2.21) -0.4728 (-2.35) -0.6266 (-3.41) -0.6093 (-3.56) -0.6258 (-3.66) -0.6524 (-3.76) -0.4444 (-2.20) -0.4213 (-2.11) -0.4409 (-2.21) -0.4732 (-2.35) -0.0393 (-2.57) -0.0398 (-2.20) -0.0386 (-2.18) -0.0369 (-2.18) -0.0393 (-2.60) -0.0398 (-2.20) -0.0386 (-2.18) -0.0369 (-2.18) RV This table presents the parameter estimates from the predictive regressions of one-month ahead CFNAI MA3 index on aggregate riskiness (RFH,VW , i,t AS,VW Ri,t ), the annualized implied volatility of the S&P 500 index options (V IX), the T ED spread defined as the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rate, and the annualized realized volatility (RV ) of the S&P 500 index. The aggregate measures of riskiness are computed as the value-weighted average of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The results are reported for the sample period January 1996-October 2010. Newey and West (1987) t-statistics are given in parentheses. The last column presents the adjusted R2 values. Table 2: Predicting CFNAI 3MA with the Value-Weighted Average Riskiness, Credit Risk, and Market Uncertainty 53.09% 51.59% 50.98% 58.60% 50.74% 48.98% 48.20% 55.84% 53.07% 51.57% 50.97% 58.60% 50.72% 48.97% 48.19% 55.84% R2 30 Intercept 0.7102 (3.89) 0.8395 (3.30) 0.8454 (3.35) 0.8532 (3.50) 0.7102 (3.89) 0.8394 (3.30) 0.8455 (3.35) 0.8532 (3.50) 1-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0173 (-3.00) -0.0202 (-2.58) 3-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0274 (-2.66) 6-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0458 (-2.64) 12-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0173 (-3.00) 1-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0202 (-2.58) 3-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0274 (-2.66) 6-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0457 (-2.63) 12-month RAS,EW i,t VIX 0.0065 (0.38) 0.0009 (0.04) 0.0001 (0.01) 0.0016 (0.08) 0.0065 (0.38) 0.0009 (0.04) 0.0001 (0.01) 0.0015 (0.08) TED -0.4353 (-2.17) -0.3986 (-2.02) -0.4219 (-2.13) -0.4581 (-2.28) -0.4353 (-2.17) -0.3988 (-2.02) -0.4219 (-2.13) -0.4578 (-2.28) RV -0.0401 (-2.45) -0.0413 (-2.24) -0.0403 (-2.22) -0.0385 (-2.19) -0.0401 (-2.45) -0.0413 (-2.24) -0.0403 (-2.22) -0.0385 (-2.19) This table presents the parameter estimates from the predictive regressions of one-month ahead CFNAI MA3 index on aggregate riskiness (RFH,EW , i,t AS,EW ), the annualized implied volatility of the S&P 500 index options (V IX), the T ED spread defined as the difference between the 3-month LIBOR Ri,t and the 3-month T-bill rate, and the annualized realized volatility (RV ) of the S&P 500 index. The aggregate measures of riskiness are computed as the equal-weighted average of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The results are reported for the sample period January 1996-October 2010. Newey and West (1987) t-statistics are given in parentheses. The last column presents the adjusted R2 values. Table 3: Predicting CFNAI 3MA with Equal-Weighted Average Riskiness, Credit Risk, and Market Uncertainty 51.37% 50.20% 49.57% 55.59% 51.38% 50.21% 49.57% 55.60% R2 31 1-month Intercept RFH,VW i,t 0.6760 -0.0375 (4.11) (-3.28) 0.8214 (3.79) 0.8241 (3.83) 0.8203 (4.00) 0.6759 (4.11) 0.8214 (3.79) 0.8241 (3.83) 0.8203 (4.00) -0.0449 (-2.44) 3-month RFH,VW i,t -0.0572 (-2.56) 6-month RFH,VW i,t Panel A. Value-Weighted Average Riskiness -0.0844 (-2.67) 12-month RFH,VW i,t -0.0375 (-3.28) 1-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0449 (-2.44) 3-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0572 (-2.56) 6-month AS,VW Ri,t -0.0845 (-2.67) 12-month AS,VW Ri,t VIX 0.0131 (0.81) 0.0055 (0.29) 0.0062 (0.33) 0.0082 (0.47) 0.0131 (0.81) 0.0055 (0.29) 0.0062 (0.33) 0.0082 (0.47) TED -0.4850 (-2.35) -0.4738 (-2.30) -0.4933 (-2.38) -0.5230 (-2.50) -0.4850 (-2.35) -0.4739 (-2.30) -0.4933 (-2.38) -0.5230 (-2.50) RV -0.0462 (-2.95) -0.0464 (-2.60) -0.0454 (-2.58) -0.0439 (-2.58) -0.0462 (-2.95) -0.0464 (-2.60) -0.0454 (-2.58) -0.0439 (-2.58) This table presents the parameter estimates from the predictive regressions of one-month ahead CFNAI index on aggregate riskiness, the annualized implied volatility of the S&P 500 index options (V IX), the T ED spread defined as the difference between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rate, and the annualized realized volatility (RV ) of the S&P 500 index. The aggregate measures of riskiness are computed as the value-weighted (Panel A) and the equal-weighted (Panel B) average of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The results are reported for the sample period January 1996-October 2010. Newey and West (1987) t-statistics are given in parentheses. The last column presents the adjusted R2 values. Table 4: Predicting CFNAI with Aggregate Riskiness, Credit Risk, and Market Uncertainty 47.10% 46.08% 45.59% 49.42% 47.10% 46.08% 45.58% 49.42% R2 32 Intercept 0.7683 (4.22) 0.8714 (3.77) 0.8758 (3.82) 0.8822 (3.97) 0.7683 (4.22) 0.8713 (3.77) 0.8759 (3.82) 0.8823 (3.97) 1-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0141 (-2.82) -0.0169 (-2.44) 3-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0232 (-2.53) 6-month RFH,EW i,t Panel B. Equal-Weighted Average Riskiness Table 4 (continued) -0.0388 (-2.58) 12-month RFH,EW i,t -0.0141 (-2.82) 1-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0169 (-2.44) 3-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0231 (-2.53) 6-month RAS,EW i,t -0.0388 (-2.58) 12-month RAS,EW i,t VIX 0.0088 (0.47) 0.0024 (0.12) 0.0031 (0.16) 0.0046 (0.25) 0.0080 (0.47) 0.0024 (0.12) 0.0031 (0.16) 0.0046 (0.25) TED -0.4767 (-2.31) -0.4526 (-2.23) -0.4741 (-2.32) -0.5053 (-2.42) -0.4766 (-2.31) -0.4527 (-2.23) -0.4740 (-2.32) -0.5051 (-2.42) RV -0.0469 (-2.84) -0.0478 (-2.62) -0.0469 (-2.61) -0.0454 (-2.58) -0.0469 (-2.84) -0.0478 (-2.62) -0.0469 (-2.61) -0.0454 (-2.58) 45.83% 45.11% 44.66% 47.71% 45.84% 45.11% 44.66% 47.71% R2 Aggregate Options’ Implied Foster−Hart Riskiness Measure (Value−Weighted) 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Aggregate Options’ Implied Foster−Hart Riskiness Measure (Equal−Weighted) 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Figure 1. Options’ Implied Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Foster-Hart) This figure presents the aggregate options’ implied measures of riskiness (Foster-Hart), computed as the value-weighted average (top panel) and the equal-weighted average (bottom panel) of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 33 Aggregate Options’ Implied Aumann−Serrano Riskiness Measure (Value−Weighted) 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Aggregate Options’ Implied Aumann−Serrano Riskiness Measure (Equal−Weighted) 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Figure 2. Options’ Implied Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Aumann-Serrano) This figure presents the aggregate options’ implied measures of riskiness (Aumann-Serrano), computed as the value-weighted average (top panel) and the equal-weighted average (bottom panel) of firm-level options’ implied measures of riskiness obtained from individual equity options with 1, 3, 6, and 12 months to maturity. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 34 Foster and Hart Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Value−Weighted) 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Foster and Hart Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Equal−Weighted) 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Figure 3. Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Foster-Hart) This figure presents the aggregate physical measures of riskiness (Foster-Hart), computed as the valueweighted average (top panel) and the equal-weighted average (bottom panel) of firm-level physical measures of riskiness obtained from daily returns over the past 1, 3, 6, and 12 months. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 35 Aumann and Serrano Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Value−Weighted) 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Aumann and Serrano Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Equal−Weighted) 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 1−month Aug−02 Apr−04 3−month Dec−05 6−month Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 12−month Figure 4. Physical Measures of Aggregate Riskiness (Aumann-Serrano) This figure presents the aggregate physical measures of riskiness (Aumann-Serrano), computed as the value-weighted average (top panel) and the equal-weighted average (bottom panel) of firm-level physical measures of riskiness obtained from daily returns over the past 1, 3, 6, and 12 months. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 36 4 TED Spread 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 Aug−02 Apr−04 Dec−05 Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 Figure 5. TED Spread This figure plots the TED spread defined as the difference between the 3-month LIBOR (an average of interest rates offered in the London interbank market for 3-month dollar-denominated loans) and the 3month Treasury bill rate. The size of this gap reflects interbank credit risk or liquidity premium. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 37 0.6 VIX 0.55 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 Jan 96 Aug−97 Apr−99 Dec−00 Aug−02 Apr−04 Dec−05 Aug−07 Apr−09 Dec−10 Figure 6. VIX Index This figure plots the end-of-month V IX index, a popular measure of the implied volatility of S&P 500 index options with 30 days to maturity. The V IX is the square-root of the risk neutral expectation of the S&P 500 variance over the next 30 calendar days. The V IX is quoted as an annualized standard deviation. The V IX is calculated and disseminated in real-time by the Chicago Board Options Exchange. The sample period is January 1996-October 2010. 38