Contagion and Excess Correlation in Credit Default Swaps Mike Anderson1 May 2010 This paper documents an increase in the correlation of credit default swap (CDS) spread changes during the credit crisis and investigates the source of that increase. One possible explanation is that correlations increased because fundamental values became more correlated during the crisis. Alternatively, correlations may have increased because of contagion, rather than because of an increase in the correlation of fundamental values. I find that fluctuations in fundamental credit risk account for only a small fraction of the increase in correlation. Furthermore, I find no evidence that correlations increased due to liquidity or counterparty risk. Lastly, I show that a systematic re-pricing of credit risk, as evidenced by variations in the default risk premium, amplified correlations during the crisis. 1 Contact information: Department of Finance, Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University, Columbus OH 43210; E-mail: anderson_1345@cob.ohio-state.edu. I am grateful for helpful discussion and suggestions from Jack Bao, Phil Davies, Kewei Hou, Andrew Karolyi, Rose Liao, Bernadette Minton, Taylor Nadauld, Tim Scholl, René Stulz, Jennifer Sustersic, Jérôme Taillard, and Scott Yonker. I thank seminar participants at the Ohio State University. I also thank the Dice Center for research support. 1 1. Introduction A well-documented phenomenon is that asset returns become more correlated in times of crisis. However, there is much debate surrounding the interpretation of this increase in comovement [see Forbes and Rigobon (2002)]. One possible explanation is that comovement increases because fundamental values become more correlated.2 Alternatively, correlations can increase for reasons beyond what can be explained by fundamentals, a condition that Bekaert, Harvey and Ng (2005) refer to as contagion. In this study, I find a significant increase in the comovement of CDS spreads during the credit crisis, which was also observed by market participants. A recent Fitch survey of CDS dealers identified contagion, along with liquidity and counterparty risk, as major factors that facilitated the spread of the subprime turmoil.3 Specifically, they noted the speed at which CDS spreads widened along with amplified correlations as indicators of contagion. The purpose of this paper is to investigate why CDS correlation increased during the credit crisis.4 In particular, I investigate whether the increase in correlation was a function of fundamental values or nonfundamental factors. Figure 1 shows that the average pairwise CDS correlation spiked in July of 2007 and remained high through the first quarter of 2009. I find that only a small fraction of this increase in correlation can be explained by variations in the fundamental factors that determine credit risk. Therefore, I turn to non-credit risk explanations. In particular, I examine whether liquidity risk, counterparty risk, or risk premiums increased correlations during the crisis. Empirical results show no evidence that CDS correlation increased because of liquidity risk or counterparty risk. In contrast, I find convincing evidence that an increase in the variance of the default risk premium amplified CDS correlation during the crisis. In this study, I focus on a sample of 150 corporate investment grade CDS contracts, which are included in one or more rolls of the CDX.NA.IG index 8-12. Collectively, these contracts make up the most liquid sector of the CDS market during the crisis. For each contract, I obtain daily, dealer averaged, mid quotes from July 2005 to March 2009. From these data, I calculate daily CDS spread 2 The definition of fundamentals, in any market, is usually a point of debate. For the purpose of this paper, I define fundamentals as those factors implied by Merton (1974) that determine credit risk. A similar definition is used by Colin-Dufresne Goldstein and Martin (2001) and Ericsson Jacobs and Oviedo (2009). I consider liquidity risk, counterparty risk, and risk premiums to be non-fundamental influences. 3 Global Credit Derivatives Survey: Surprises, Challenges and the Future, Fitch Ratings, August 20, 2009. 4 Throughout this paper I use the term “CDS correlation” to refer to the correlation between daily changes in CDS spreads. 2 changes for each firm in the sample; the correlations between these series are the subject of this paper. As a first step, I document an increase in the comovement of CDS spread changes during the crisis. To do this, I test the average Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlation coefficients as well as the average fraction of firms that move together each week [see Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000)]. Average pairwise Pearson’s correlation increased from 20% prior to the crisis (July 31, 2007) to 44% during the crisis (from July 31, 2007 to March 3, 2009). A similar result holds for average Spearman’s correlation, which more than doubled during the crisis. Finally, the average fraction of firms whose CDS spreads move in the same direction each week increased from 73% to 83% during the crisis. These changes are significant at the 1% level. To better understand why CDS correlation increased, I investigate excess correlation, which is the correlation between CDS spread changes that cannot be explained by changes in the fundamental determinants of credit risk. Estimating excess correlation requires a strong stance on fundamental factors, as well as the form by which these factors determine CDS spreads, which as noted by Bekaert et al. (2005) will always be a point of controversy.5 Therefore, I rely on the extensive credit risk literature to specify the model. I define a linear factor structure to control for changes in the fundamental values of CDS contracts; this model is similar to those employed by Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein and Martin (2001) and Ericsson, Jacobs and Oviedo (2009). Under this framework, I define the excess correlation as the correlation between factor model residuals. Tests for a change in excess correlation show that it increased within the full sample, within industry groups, and across industry portfolios. This confirms that contagion, which I define as an increase in excess correlation, occurred during the crisis. To test for contagion, I begin with a firm level analysis, which shows that the average pairwise correlation of OLS residuals, over the full sample and within industry categories, increased significantly during the crisis. Next, I aggregate to the industry level to examine the excess correlation across six equally weighted industry portfolios of CDS contracts. This allows for a more powerful test of the fundamental credit risk hypothesis. In the reduced dimension of the industry analysis, I am able to estimate the fundamental model and the excess correlation in a system of seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR). I find that controlling for common variations in credit risk, on average, reduces the increase in inter-industry correlation from 5 Bekaert et al. (2005) study contagion in international equity markets. However, their observations regarding the influence of variations in fundamental factors are directly applicable to the CDS market. 3 0.26 to 0.20.6 However, credit risk cannot fully explain the increase in correlations, which is evidenced by a significant contagion effect between 14 of the 15 industry pairs. This provides additional support for the argument that common, non-credit factors amplified correlations during the crisis. After documenting contagion, I investigate why it occurred. Specifically, I examine whether variations in liquidity risk, counterparty risk, or risk premiums were significant channels of contagion during the crisis. Currently, the evidence on liquidity risk in credit default swaps is mixed. Bongaerts, de Jong and Driessen (2009) argue that expected returns on CDS contracts depend on expected transaction costs in the CDS market. Acharya, Schaefer and Zhang (2008) show that heightened liquidity risk in the bond market increased the comovement in CDS returns during the correlation crisis. Tang and Yan (2008) find that CDS spreads covary with liquidity proxies.7 In contrast, authors have argued that CDS contracts are relatively immune to liquidity risk [see Longstaff, Mithal and Neis (2005)]. In this paper, I focus on a set of highly liquid CDS contracts with the purpose of isolating changes in correlations that are unrelated to liquidity premiums. However, given the extreme conditions that persisted during the crisis, liquidity cannot be ignored as a possible source of correlation. To evaluate the role of liquidity risk, I add several liquidity proxies (changes) into the fundamental regressions. The average contract bid-ask spread, over all CDS contracts in the sample, captures changes in transaction costs [see Stoll (1989); Huang and Stoll (1997); Amihud and Mendelson (1986); Amihud (2002)]. To proxy for systematic liquidity premiums [see Pastor and Stambaugh (2003); Acharya and Pedersen (2005)], I include the yield difference between the off and on the run five-year Treasury notes, the spread between the three-month overnight index swap rate and the three-month constant maturity Treasury rate [see Eichengreen, Nedeljkovic, Mody and Sarno (2009)], and the spread between the general collateral repo rate and the three-month constant maturity Treasury rate [see Liu, Longstaff, and Mandell (2006)]. Further, Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009) argue that speculators’ access to external financing is an important determinant of asset 6 It is important to note that some of the factors used to measure credit risk may be subject to non-fundamental effects, which will complicate their interpretation as credit risk proxies. However, these measures will still respond to changes in fundamental values. Therefore, they will still control for changes in credit risk. Unfortunately, to the extent that non-fundamental effects are common across markets, these factors will also capture changes in noncredit risk factors. As long as the commonality of non-fundamentals increases during the crisis, this will bias against finding an increase in excess correlation. In this respect, the increase in excess correlation is a conservative estimate. 7 The correlation crisis refers to the downgrade of Ford and GM in 2005; specifically, the downgrade of Ford on May 5, 2005. 4 liquidity. Therefore, I include an index of hedge fund returns to capture speculators’ funding liquidity. Finally, Pu (2009) shows that CDS and bond liquidity is linked. To measure the effect of bond liquidity, I use TRACE transaction data to calculate liquidity proxies (Amihud, volume, and the number of trades) for bonds issued by firms in the sample. Results from these tests show that liquidity was not a significant source of contagion during the turmoil. Next, I consider counterparty risk contagion. Eichengreen et al. (2009) show that the credit risk of major U.S. and U.K. banks varied drastically during the crisis. These banks are major dealers in the CDS market. Therefore, an increase in the common variation of counterparty risk premiums may have amplified CDS correlation. Counterparty risk has been shown to be a significant determinant of CDS spreads; however, there is controversy on the size of the effect [see Jorion and Zhang (2009); Coval, Jurek and Stafford (2009); Arora, Gandhi and Longstaff (2009)]. To investigate whether variations in counterparty risk increased correlations, I construct four measures of banking sector credit risk. First, the overnight index swap spread (OIS) captures the credit risk component of the TED spread. Second, the asset-backed commercial paper spread proxies for banks’ access to short-term funding.8 Next, the return on a value weighted portfolio of licensed marketmakers (CPstock) in the CDX.NA.IG index measures the financial health of CDS dealers. Finally, I include two measures of dealer risk dispersion. CPDIF is the difference between the maximum and median equity return among licensed market makers in the CDX.NA.IG index and EXCPDIF is equal to CPDIF on days when it is above its 95th percentile. These variables capture potential concentrations in the demand for credit protection from a small group of high quality dealers, which could lead to a reduction in market making services. After controlling for variations in counterparty risk, I reevaluate the change in excess correlation. As with liquidity, I find no evidence that counterparty risk was a significant source of contagion. Finally, I investigate the impact that risk premiums had on CDS correlations. Risk premiums are an important component of the corporate credit spread [see Duffee (1999); Elton, Gruber, Agarwal and Mann (2001); Driessen (2005)] and can vary drastically over time [see Berndt, Douglas, Duffie, Ferguson, and Schranz (2008) – hereafter (“BDDFS”)]. Therefore, an increase in the common variation of risk premiums, which likely occurs as investors adjust their risk appetites, can increase CDS correlation. To measure this effect, I estimate the time varying risk premium following BDDFS. Adding the change in the risk premium back into the fundamental regression, I find that variations in the default risk premium account for approximately 20% of the time series variation in 8 This is taken as the difference between the yield on 90 day asset-backed commercial paper and the three-month constant maturity Treasury yield. 5 CDS spread changes. More importantly, controlling for changes in the risk premium completely explains the increase in inter-industry excess correlation, which suggests that risk premiums were the main source of contagion. This important result shows that a systematic re-pricing of credit risk, rather than changes in market frictions, amplified CDS correlation during the crisis. This paper contributes to three strings of literature. First, several authors have documented a time varying latent component in credit spreads [see Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001); Ericsson et al. (2009); Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein and Helwege (2003); Giesecke (2004); Duffie, Eckner, Horel, and Saita (2009)]. I contribute to this literature by investigating how this latent component affected correlations in CDS spread changes during the credit crisis. Second, credit contagion studies investigate how negative shocks propagate over credit spreads [Giesecke and Weber (2004); Allen and Carletti (2006); Jorion and Zhang (2007); Acharya et al. (2008); Longstaff (2008); Jorion et al. (2009)]. This paper adds to the literature on credit contagion by considering whether shocks were transmitted to investment grade corporate CDS spreads during the 2007-2009 turmoil. Finally, the literature on default correlation seeks to estimate and model the correlations of default probabilities, losses given default, and defaults over time [Zhou (2001); Allen and Saunders (2003); de Servigny and Renault (2004); Das, Duffie, Kapadia and Saita (2007)]. To the extent that CDS spreads reflect compensation for credit risk, this paper documents an increase in the correlation of default probabilities and/or losses given default during the crisis. The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 discusses comovement and tests for contagion. In Section 4, I investigate liquidity risk, counterparty risk and risk premiums as channels of contagion. Finally, Section 5 concludes. 2. Data 2.1 Credit Default Swap Contracts Overview A single-name corporate credit default swap is simply an insurance contract that protects against deteriorations in the credit worthiness of a single reference entity (bond issuer).9 There are two parties to each contract, the protection seller and the protection buyer. The protection buyer agrees to make fixed payments, which are usually quarterly, to the protection seller. These payments are based on the CDS spread or premium, which is quoted as a percent of the notional value of the contract and can be directly interpreted as a credit spread [see Duffie (1999)]. In return, the 9 It should be noted that contract specific issues, such as what legally constitutes a credit event, can greatly complicate this simple explanation. For example, the Bear Stearns merger did not qualify as a credit event while placing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into government conservatorship did. 6 protection seller agrees to make a one-time payment, equal to the difference between the face value of the bond and its recovery value, if a credit event occurs. Credit events are defined in the standard contracts published by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA). Specifically, the 2003 ISDA Credit Derivatives Definitions outline five classes of credit events (failure to pay, default or acceleration, bankruptcy, moratorium/remuneration and restructuring), which are designed to trigger CDS contracts when the credit worthiness of an issuer reaches a critical level. It should be noted that ISDA contracts are flexible and can be used to construct many different types of CDS contracts for a particular reference. Therefore, when comparing CDS premiums, it is important to make sure that all contracts are identically specified. 2.2 Timing the Crisis Most observers agree that the credit crisis began in the summer of 2007. However, an exact date is difficult to define. Fortunately, Figure 2 provides convincing visual evidence of a shift in economic states that occurred at the end of July 2007. Therefore, I define July 31,2007 as the first day of the crisis.10 [INSERT FIGURE 2] The graph is even more specific in identifying the date when credit markets began to recover. On March 9, 2009 there is a sharp drop in the average credit spread. I define this date as the end of the crisis. 2.3 Credit Default Swap Premiums End-of-day CDS premium quotes, on five-year contracts, are obtained from Markit and Credit Market Analysts (CMA). Each of these companies collects quotes from a wide range of contributors who are active in the CDS market. Quotes are first screened and then averaged over dealers to produce the daily mid-quotes used in this study. A comparison of Markit and CMA quotes, on overlapping periods, shows a high degree of consistency between the two sources with a mean and median correlations of .995 and .998 respectively. 10 This date corresponds to the liquidation of Bear Stearns High-Grade Structured Credit Strategies Master Fund and the Bear Stearns High-Grade Structured Credit Strategies Enhanced Leverage Master Fund. I also test different crisis dates and find the results are robust to different specifications in July and June. Finally, further evidence is provided by a Chow test for parameter stability, which rejects the null hypothesis at the 1% level. The test is run using changes or returns of fundamental variables on changes in the equally weighted average of CDS spreads 7 Given the above discussion, it is important to ensure that CDS spreads, for all firms in the sample, are quoted on the same contract specification. Therefore, I choose to focus on five-year contracts, which are widely considered the most liquid, and should convey the most accurate pricing information. Furthermore, I use premiums on contracts that trade under the North American convention, which standardizes many technical issues. Importantly, this convention defines a set of triggering events, which include all the ISDA credit events (mentioned above) except moratorium/remuneration, which is exclusive to sovereign contracts.11 To construct the sample, I begin by obtaining CDS premiums for all contracts included in the CDX.NA.IG index rolls 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12. The CDX.NA.IG is an investment grade CDS index that is “rolled” every six months. Each roll includes 125 CDS contracts that dealer surveys determine to be the most liquid contracts on the market. This criterion yields 159 unique contracts. Furthermore, I require all contracts to remain active throughout the sample period, which eliminates changes in correlation due to contracts entering and exiting the sample. Freddie Mac, Fannie Mae, Washington Mutual and Interactive Corporation are dropped because they stop trading prior to the end of the sample. Embarq, Expedia, ERP, and Time Warner Cable are also dropped because their premiums are not available until after the beginning of the sample period. Finally, I drop Residential Capital Corp because the volatility of its contract premiums is an extreme outlier (it exceeds the 75th percentile by 25 times the interquartile range). This leaves 150 CDS contracts. The sample period begins on July 1, 2005 and ends on March 9, 2009. This period isolates two distinct economic states. The first, which is characterized by low volatility and high economic growth, was a tranquil period in U.S. credit markets. In contrast, the months following August 2007 represent a time of severe economic turmoil. This abrupt shift in economic climate provides an ideal setting to investigate sudden changes in credit correlation.12 This paper is mainly concerned with the correlation between credit default swap spread changes, which is directly linked to the common variation in different components of the CDS spread. Therefore, a brief overview of what credit spreads represent will offer clarity on the economic meaning of these correlations. From a fundamental perspective, in frictionless markets with no arbitrage opportunities credit spreads arise for two reasons: (i) because investors are exposed to default risk and (ii) because, in default, bondholders receive only a fraction of the bond’s face 11 Restructuring was recently removed from the North American Convention. However, this change did not take effect until April 2009, which is after the end of my sample period. O’Kane, Pedersen and Turnbull (2003) and Berndt, Jarrow and Kang (2007) provide detailed discussion of the restructuring clause in CDS contracts. 12 I exclude the correlation crisis because it resulted from a liquidity shock to the bond market [see Acharya et al. (2008)] and the focus of this paper is to explain why correlations increased during the credit crisis. 8 value. These risks reduce the value of corporate bonds relative to their risk-free counterparts creating a positive credit spread, which, in theory, equals the CDS spread [see Duffie (1999)]. In addition to fundamental credit risk, CDS spreads may also compensate for non-fundamental risks [see BDDFS; Bongaerts et al. (2009); Arora et al. (2009)], which, if common to all contracts, can alter CDS correlation. The table below provides an initial overview of the behavior of CDS spread changes during the sample period. [INSERT TABLE I] Panel A of Table I describes the time series of daily changes in spreads for seven portfolios of CDS contracts. Statistics for the full sample portfolio, constructed using all 150 CDS contracts, are reported in row one; subsequent rows show descriptive statistics for each of the six industry portfolios. In the construction of industry portfolios, I assume that all contracts have equal notional amounts; that is, they are equally weighted portfolios. Figure 3 shows that CDS spreads for all portfolios increased during the crisis, which is consistent with a heightened concern of default risk. These increases in CDS spreads translate into larger daily changes during the crisis as seen in Panel A of Table I. For example, the premium for the full sample portfolio increased, on average, 0.05% per day prior to the crisis; during the crisis, the average daily change increased by more than a full percentage point to 1.07%, which is a significant change at the 1% level. The industry breakdown shows that, on average, CDS spreads experienced larger movements during the crisis across all industry groups, although the change is insignificant for both the Healthcare and Other industries. This is not surprising for the Healthcare industry given that it is commonly thought of as “recession proof”. However, the Other industry category is mainly composed of homebuilders and entertainment companies, which one would have expected to be among the hardest hit. A closer investigation reveals that entertainment companies, on average, suffered a significant increase in CDS spreads, whereas home builders did not. This result seems counter-intuitive; however, at the beginning of the crisis most homebuilders held large cash reserves, which along with the homebuyers’ tax credit may have helped these companies’ weather the turmoil.13 [INSERT FIGURE 3] The volatility of CDS spread changes increased significantly during the crisis across all portfolios, which is not surprising given the increased uncertainty in the market over this period. The last two sections of Panel A of Table I show that spread changes are positively skewed with fat tails prior to the crisis and approach normality during the turmoil. Again, this result is somewhat counter13 It is important to note that CDS spread levels increased for all industries; however, the average incremental changes were smaller for Healthcare and Other. 9 intuitive because, in times of crisis, one would expect to see a higher probability of tail events (kurtosis). This outcome is more easily understood with a closer investigation of the CDS spread distributions in each period. Prior to the crisis, CDS spread changes are tightly clustered around zero. Therefore, a large idiosyncratic or industry shock could push observations into the tail of the distribution, which is evidenced by the positive pre-crisis skew. If these events occur frequently enough, in the two years preceding the crisis, the distribution would be characterized by high excess kurtosis. In contrast, during the turmoil extreme events became common place, which widened the distribution of credit spread changes, making it more difficult for tail events, in relation to the crisis distribution, to occur. Intuitively, the probability of seeing an event capable of producing outlying observations in the midst of such a turbulent economic climate is very small. Panel B shows the progression in average pairwise correlation within the full sample and within each industry group over the sample period. This shows that the average correlation is low at approximately 0.20 in each half year prior to the second half of 2007 and doubled during the crisis. Importantly, this analysis also reveals that the increase in correlation is not concentrated within any particular sub-period of the turmoil. Lastly, Ljung-Box tests for autocorrelation, in Panel C, show that daily CDS spread changes are significantly autocorrelated for all industries in both periods. 2.4 Sample Characteristics Figure 4 shows the distributions of the market-to-book ratio, cash holdings, profitability, total assets, book leverage, and size, for the full sample (used in this paper) and for the CRSP/Compustat merged universe. These variables, which are important determinants of credit worthiness [see Campbell, Hilscher, and Szilagyi (2008)], are calculated using annual data obtained from the CRSP/Compustat merged data base.14 Distributions of firm characteristics, from 2005 to 2008, are shown in box plots, which provide a convenient visual representation of the sample heterogeneity. For each year and characteristic there are two box plots, one (left) describes the distribution of a firm characteristic for the full sample, the second (right) describes the distribution of the same characteristic for the CRSP/Compustat merged universe. From Figure 4, it is (visually) apparent that these firms are not remarkably levered or profitable, nor do they have extraordinary growth prospects when compared to firms in the CRSP/Compustat merged universe. In contrast, firms in the sample are relatively large cash-rich entities with high total asset values relative to firms in the 14 Book Leverage = ((AT - book equity)/AT) [see Baker and Wurgler (2002)]; book equity = AT – LT – PSTLK + TXDITC + DCVT (or PSTKRV if PSTLK is not available); profitability = (NI/AT); cash holdings = CH; total assets = AT; size = CSHO*PRCC_F; Market-to-book = (CSHO*PRCC_F + AT – book equity)/AT 10 CRSP/Compustat universe. This is apparent from the fact that the mass of each sample distribution occurs in the tail of the corresponding CRSP/Compustat merged distribution for each firm characteristic. [INSERT FIGURE 4] The figure also provides preliminary insight into why correlations increased. For example, firms in the sample maintained large cash reserves and high total asset values throughout the crisis, which may have limited large fluctuations in expected loss. However, there is some evidence of a potential increase in the comovement of fundamentals. In 2008, firms in the sample experienced what appears to be a joint increase in book leverage and decrease in profitability. These movements in fundamentals could translate into higher CDS correlation. However, the full increase in CDS correlation will depend on the increased comovement of non-credit risk components of the CDS spread as well. Finally, Figure 5 shows the distribution of S&P long term issuer credit ratings through time (obtained from Compustat). The mass of these distributions is centered around BBB and BBB+, although observations range from BB- to AAA.15 The distributions remain relatively constant over time, with a slight shift toward speculative grade in 2008 and 2009. This suggests that these companies were relatively high grade issuers and remained so throughout the crisis. [INSERT FIGURE 5] 3. Comovement and Excess Correlation In this section, I document an increase in the comovement of CDS spread changes during the crisis and investigate whether that increase can be explained by variations in the fundamental factors that drive credit risk. The discussion is split into four subsections. First, I formally test for an increase in the comovement of CDS spread changes. Second, I develop a simple factor model approach to decompose the raw correlation into fundamental and excess components. Third, I describe and justify the variable specification of the factor model. Finally, I review the results of the excess correlation analysis, which includes the base test for contagion. 15 Some ratings drop below the investment grade threshold (BBB-), which can occur because the long term issuer rating is a composite rating meant to judge a firm’s long term credit worthiness; whereas, the CDX.NA.IG index is constructed using specific credits. Therefore, firms with speculative long term credit ratings can be included in the sample if they issued investment grade bonds that are included in the CDX.NA.IG index. 11 3.1 Measuring Comovement The first step is to establish that CDS correlation increased during the crisis. To do this, I test for an increase in the average pairwise Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlation coefficients over all firm pairs, as well as an increase in the average fraction of firms that moved together each week during the crisis [see Morck et al. (2000)]. Formally, I test the null hypothesis that the aggregate comovement statistic (Pearson’s correlation, Spearman’s correlation, or the fraction of firms that move together each week), represented by ρ below, prior to the crisis is greater than or equal to the aggregate comovement statistic during the crisis: Ho: ρ pre −crisis ≥ ρ crisis Ha: ρ pre − crisis < ρ crisis The results of these tests are reported in Table II. Columns one and two (respectively) of Panel A show that the average Pearson’s correlation, taken over all 11,175 pairwise combinations, is 0.20 prior to the crisis and increases to 0.44 during the crisis, which is a significant increase of 0.24 (reported in column 3) at the 1% level. To ensure that this result is not driven by a small group of firms that become highly correlated during the turmoil, I repeat the test within each industry group. Average sector correlations range from 0.14 to 0.30 prior to the crisis and increase to between 0.40 and 0.54 during the crisis. The change, for each sector, is significant at the 1% level, indicating that Pearson’s correlation increased uniformly within the sample. However, Pearson’s correlation is subject to distributional assumptions that may influence the outcome of these tests. Therefore, I also include two nonparametric tests. First, the change in the average Spearman’s correlation coefficients (reported in Panel B) yields similar results for the full sample and at the industry level.16 Additional evidence of a uniform increase in Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlation is provided in Figure 6, which shows a shift in the cross-sectional densities of Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlation during the crisis. 16 The sampling distribution of Pearson’s correlation coefficients becomes skewed as the true correlation approaches 1 or -1. Fisher (1921) proposes a simple transformation, which under certain conditions ensures normality (as the number of observations gets large). Moreover, pairwise correlations are measured repeatedly for each firm pair. These conditions satisfy the assumptions of a two sample paired t-test, which is the appropriate test for a change in Pearson’s correlation. The large number of pairwise combinations will mechanically inflate t-statistics. Therefore, I repeat the paired test using the asymptotic distribution implied by the Fisher transformation. Tests based on the Fisher transformation, can be misleading if CDS spread changes do not approximately follow a bivariate normal distribution. Descriptive statistics in Table I show that, prior to the crisis, spread changes were positively skewed with a high degree of excess kurtosis. Spearman’s rank correlation is robust to these distributional assumptions. Further, it can be directly tested using the Friedman statistic [see Friedman (1937)], which is distributed asymptotically Chi squared with T-1 degrees of freedom (as n goes to infinity). 12 [INSERT FIGURE 6] Second, the average fraction of firms whose CDS spreads move in the same direction each week increased from 73% prior to the crisis to 83% during the crisis (columns one and two of Panel C respectively); the increase is statistically significant at the 1% level. The change in the fraction and its corresponding p-value are reported in columns three and four, respectively. The within-sector changes range from 7% to 11% and are all significant at the 1% level. At 73% (83%) the fraction seems relatively high when compared to an average Pearson’s correlation of 0.20 (0.44). This is easily resolved by noting that the Morck et al. (2000) fraction is bounded between 0.50 and 1.00, and therefore will naturally produce larger values. [INSERT TABLE II] 3.2 Measuring Excess Correlation To estimate excess correlation, I build six equally weighted industry portfolios based on the Fama and French five industry classifications. Given the increased attention on the financial sector, I choose to extract financials from the Other industry classification.17 Aggregating to the industry level reduces the noise from firm level CDS spreads and produces a clearer decomposition of CDS correlation. Next, I assume that industry CDS spread changes follow a linear factor structure. Given this framework, and assuming all variables are standardized, the correlation between spread changes can be decomposed as shown below: [ ] [ ] ′ E ∆S∆S ′ = E (β F + ε )(β F + ε ) = β E [FF ′]β ′ + E εε ′ (1) ∆S is an Nx1 vector of CDS spread changes. β is an NxK matrix of factor exposures, F is a Kx1 vector of factors, and ε is an Nx1 vector of model errors. Equation 1 suggests that, all else equal, correlations can increase for three reasons: (i) an increase in the exposure of industry CDS spread changes to a common factor, (ii) an increase in the correlation between factors, (iii) an increase in the correlation of unexplained CDS spread changes (contagion). In the first case, an increase in the exposure of CDS spread changes, for a single industry, to even one common factor, will increase the correlation of that industry’s CDS spread changes with those of all other industries. 17 Although the industry classification is coarse, further refinement reduces the power of the correlation decomposition. This classification may limit the explanatory power of industry variables in the factor model. Further, if refined industry components, that are not capture by industry controls, become more correlated in the crisis, tests may be bias in favor of contagion. However, given the results hold at the firm-level as well (with industry controls-see Appendix A), it is unlikely that this limitation bias the tests of contagion. 13 An important implication of Figure 1 is that correlations remained high throughout the crisis period. Therefore, a onetime shock to factor exposures, factor correlations, or excess correlation, would not explain this observed outcome. A more likely explanation is that a sustained increase in the variance of a common factor increased correlations. An increase in the variance of a common factor, in the context of Equation 1, is counterintuitive. This is because variables are standardized, using GARCH filters that correct for heteroskedasticity, prior to estimating Equation 1. Therefore, the variance of observed common factors is constant over the sample period. Two important observations will help to clarify this contradiction. First, the factor covariance component of the decomposed correlation ( β E [FF ′]β ′ ) can change with changes in the regression coefficient. Hence, an increase in the regression coefficient represents an increase in the variance of an observed common factor. Furthermore, an increase in the variance of common non-credit factors in the CDS spread, which have not been standardized, can also increase the correlation between CDS spread changes by increasing excess correlation. To illustrate, suppose CDS spreads contain a common non-credit premium that is not controlled for by fundamental variables. Because the variation in this premium is common across contracts, it will induce correlation between industry CDS spread changes, which results in excess correlation. Further, since the premium is not standardized, it can experience an increase in variance, which would increase correlations. Hence, excess correlation, and therefore, CDS correlation can increase with the variance of a common non-credit factor. By identifying these factors, I can add them to the factor model in their standardized form, which effectively removes the increase in common variation from the excess correlation matrix. This procedure is employed in Section 4 to study the channels of contagion. The decomposition in Equation 1 requires estimates of all factor exposures for each industry portfolio, which are obtained from a standard feasible generalized least squares (FGLS) estimation of the system of seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR). From this estimation, the excess correlation is calculated as the correlation between factor model residuals [see Kallberg and Pasquariello (2008)].18 After extracting factor model residuals, I perform three tests for a change in excess correlation. First, I test the null hypotheses that the excess correlation matrix and the average excess 18 Equation 1 holds only if all independent variables are the same across equations. If variables differ across equations, then the decomposition should also include the covariance between equation residuals and off-equation specific variables. For example, the covariance of industry i’s residuals with industry j’s stock returns. However, there is no fundamental justification for why the unexplained CDS spread changes of industry i should be correlated with the stock returns of industry j. Therefore, I assume these covariances are non-fundamental and allow them to be absorbed into the residual covariance matrix. 14 correlation remain constant over the full sample period. Statistical significance for these tests is assessed using the Chi-Squared statistics developed by Goetzmann, Li, and Rouwenhorst (2005), which are based on the asymptotic distribution of the correlation matrix.19 The third test is a test of the individual pairwise Pearson’s correlations between unexplained CDS spread changes of industry portfolios. 3.3 Factor Model Specification A disadvantage of the factor model approach is that it requires a strong stance on fundamentals, as well as the form by which fundamentals effect changes in CDS spreads. Fortunately, prior research has uncovered several factors that determine changes in corporate yield spreads. Because CDS spreads are closely related to corporate yield spreads [see Duffie (1999); Blanco, Brennan, and Marsh (2005)], these factors can be used to explain changes in CDS spreads. Therefore, I base the factor model specification on the work of Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001) who investigate the determinants of bond yield spreads using factors implied by Merton (1974).20 In addition, I include several systematic variables designed to capture fluctuations in loss given default, which is largely a function of the state of the economy [see Altman and Kishore (1996); Allen et al. (2003); Schuermann (2004); Altman, Brady, Resti, and Sironi (2005)]. Variable definitions are provided in Table III along with data sources and the expected sign. [INSERT TABLE III] To explain CDS spread changes, I transform all variables that are not returns into first differences, which is consistent with Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001). Results reported in Table I show that the variance of CDS spread changes increased significantly for all industry portfolios during the crisis; unreported results indicate that factor variances increased significantly as well. Therefore, I 19 They base their statistic on the asymptotic distribution of the covariance matrix derived in Browne and Shapiro (1986) and Neudecker and Wesselman (1990): ) ) vec P1 − P2 [ ( )] T 1 1 + Ω n1 n 2 −1 [vec(P) − P) )] → χ [rk (Ω)] d 1 2 2 ) ) where Ω is the covariance matrix defined by Neudecker et al. (1990), and P1 and P2 are estimates of the vectorized correlation matrix. 20 Colin-Dufresne et al. (2001) show that the model does not perform well in explaining changes in bond yield spreads. However, Ericsson et al. (2009) show that a similar model performs well in explaining CDS spread changes. Their specifications include leverage, which is not available daily. Instead, I use daily equity returns to proxy for the overall financial health of the industry. To evaluate the performance of the model, I replicate the Principal Component Analysis used in these papers and find that the common component in factor model residuals is comparable to what Ericsson et al. (2009) find. Prior to (during) the crisis the first PCA explains 19% (37%) of the common variation in factor model residuals. 15 standardize all variables using autoregressive GARCH filters prior to estimating the fundamental model. In addition, I orthogonalize all market variables (SMB, HML, HB, VIX, and INDRET) to the S&P 500 return since these variables are all highly correlated. Finally, I allow factor exposures to shift during the crisis to avoid biasing the estimated excess correlation; the final model specification is given in equation 2. Following the notation from equation 1, βj and βj,c (j = 1:10) are Nx1 vectors of factor exposures for factor j prior to the crisis and its marginal change during the crisis respectively. ∆S = α + β1 (∆RF 3M ) + β 2 (∆SLOPE) + β 3 (∆VIX ) + β 4 ( SP500) + β 5 ( HB) + β 6 (∆DEF ) + β 7 (SMB) + β 8 ( HML) + β 9 ( INDRET ) + β10 (∆INDVOL) + α c + β1,c (∆RF 3M ) I crisis + β 2,c (∆SLOPE) I crisis (2) + β 3,c (∆VIX ) I crisis + β 4,c ( SP500) I crisis + β 5,c ( HB) I crisis + β 6,c (∆DEF ) I crisis + β 7,c ( SMB) I crisis + β 8,c ( HML) I crisis + β 9,c ( INDRET ) I crisis + β10,c (∆INDVOL) I crisis + ε 3.4 Factor Model Results Before discussing excess correlation, I briefly review results from the factor model estimation. SUR estimates of the pre-crisis factor exposures, for each of the six industry portfolios, are reported in the upper half of Table IV and marginal contributions during the crisis are shown below. Not surprisingly, the S&P500 return is negative and significant, for all industry portfolios. This is consistent with the interpretation of the S&P 500 return as a state variable (as the state of the economy improves, credit risk decreases, and CDS spreads become less sensitive to changes in economic conditions). Estimated pre-crisis coefficients range from -0.11 to -0.36. This suggests that a one standard deviation increase in the S&P 500 return relates to approximately a 0.20 standard deviation decrease in CDS spread changes. Interest rate variables, ∆SLOPE and ∆RF3M, have relatively little explanatory power in the full regression. However, univariate regressions recover the well-known negative relation between the short-term risk-free rate and portfolio credit spread changes.21 Not surprisingly, the change in the default premium (∆DEF) is positive and significant for all industry portfolios. The value premium (HML) is a significant determinant of CDS spread changes for four of the six industry portfolios prior to the crisis. However, the negative sign is inconsistent with its interpretation as a measure of default risk. Vassalou and Xing (2004) find that HML increases with default risk; however, the effect is small for high credit quality firms. Given the large cash reserves and long-term credit ratings of firms in this sample, it is safe to assume that they are at relatively low 21 Longstaff and Schwartz (1995), Duffee (1998), and Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001) all document this relation. 16 risk of default. Therefore, a more plausible explanation is that HML captures systematic risk premiums imbedded in CDS spreads prior to the crisis. Elton et al. (2001) show that a negative exposure is consistent with this interpretation. Interestingly, during the crisis, CDS spreads become less exposed to HML and unreported results show that the absolute exposure is insignificant for all industries. This result provides some evidence that the CDS market detached from the equity market during the crisis. Marginal changes in factor exposures are, for the most part, insignificant with the exception of the marginal change in exposure to the S&P 500 return, which becomes significantly more negative during the crisis for five of the six industry portfolios. This is consistent with the shift in economic conditions observed at the beginning of August 2007. [INSERT TABLE IV] 3.5 Contagion Results Having controlled for credit risk, I now explore whether inter-industry excess correlation increased during the crisis; results of these tests are reported in Table V. First, I test the pairwise excess correlation between industry portfolios individually. These results show that excess correlation between all industry pairs increased significantly. Next, I test the null hypotheses that the excess correlation matrix and average excess correlation remained constant over the full sample period. P-values reported in the lower panel show that these hypotheses are both rejected at the 1% level. The factor model specification is critical to this investigation. Therefore, I repeat the analysis for several different models and find that these results are robust to the model specification.22 For brevity and consistency, I choose to report results for the base model only. The uniform increase in inter-industry excess correlation provides sufficient evidence to conclude that contagion occurred. Moreover, this result supports the argument that a common non-credit component amplified 22 Other variable specifications include non-linear transformations of interest rate variables to control for the effects of convexity. A transformation of equity returns to account for the non-linear relation between equity and debt implied by Merton (1974). I also include different bond indices of various rating categories as well as different riskfree rates of varying maturities. Lagged stock returns up to a five day lag were also explored with no change in the result. From Figure 1, correlation jumped at the Bear Stearns merger and the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. Therefore, I split the crisis into three sub periods: July 31, 2007 – March 15, 2008, March 15, 2008 - September 15, 2008, and September 15, 2008 – March 9, 2009. I allow exposures to change in each period. Regression results show very little variation in factor exposures. Further, excess correlation still increases across industries. Next, I repeat the tests after estimating the factor model once prior to the crisis and once in the crisis. This explicitly allows factor correlations to change. However, there is no change in the main result. Next I re-estimate the model on the crisis sub-periods described above with no change in the main result. The last three tests are performed for each channel of contagion as well, with no notable change in the results. 17 correlations during the crisis. Therefore, I investigate potential channels of contagion in the next section. [INSERT TABLE V] 4. Channels of Contagion The evidence presented in the previous section shows that a large increase in the comovement of daily CDS spread changes, during the crisis, cannot be explained by changes in fundamental credit risk. Furthermore, and of particular interest to this paper, the tests indicate that the excess correlation increased across all industries, which is consistent with the influence of a common non-credit component. In this section, I explore how variations in liquidity risk, counterparty risk, and the default risk premium increase the correlation in CDS spreads. Furthermore, I formally test each channel of contagion to see if it can resolve the increase in excess correlation documented above. These tests allow me to comment on the degree to which each channel increased excess correlation. 4.1 Liquidity Contagion The premise of this argument is that a sustained increase in the variance of common liquidity premiums can increase CDS correlation.23 Liquidity risk in the CDS market can vary for several reasons. First, fluctuations in the supply of or demand for credit protection can lead to variations in transaction costs. This is because market-makers will attempt to hedge their exposure to inventory risk and asymmetric information risk by adjusting the bid-ask spread [see Stoll (1989); Huang et al. (1997)]. During the crisis, investors and dealers likely experienced larger fluctuations in their need to hedge credit risk, which may have increased the common variation in the liquidity related component of the change in CDS spread. Bongaerts et al. (2009) propose a model in which CDS expected (synthetic) returns depend on transaction costs in the CDS market. Moreover, they argue that this effect can be captured in the bid-ask spread. Therefore, I include daily changes in the average bid-ask spread, over all contracts (BIDASK), to measure changes in market-wide CDS liquidity and changes This argument requires some clarification on the relation between bonds and CDS contracts. If bonds are perfectly liquid, an exact arbitrage relation with CDS contracts would prevent liquidity premiums from entering CDS spreads. However, the single name contracts in the study do not specify a particular reference obligation (bond), which makes this an approximate arbitrage. Furthermore, bonds are notoriously illiquid and became more so during the crisis [see Dick-Nielsen, Feldhütter and Lando (2009)]. These limits to the arbitrage relation could allow liquidity premiums to enter CDS spreads. 18 in the average industry bid-ask spreads (IBIDASK) to control for changes in industry specific liquidity.24 The direction of this relation depends on differences in the characteristics of protection buyers and sellers [see Bongaerts et al. (2009)]. Second, the liquidity of CDS contracts may depend on liquidity in the bond market. This is because CDS contracts can be used as a substitute for bonds to trade credit risk. Therefore, when bonds become difficult to trade, the CDS market may experience more variation in the supply of or demand for credit protection [see Acharaya et al. (2008)]. 25 To capture variation in bond liquidity, I obtain transaction prices and volumes, from TRACE, for each firm’s bonds that traded over the sample period (these data are filtered according to Dick-Nielsen (2009)). I then calculate daily Amihud measures for each bond [see Pu (2009); Dick-Nielsen, Feldhütter and Lando (2009)] in the sample and create an aggregate index (AMIHUD).26 AMIHUD increases with illiquidity, which implies a positive relation with CDS spread changes. To measure variation in the ability of investors to trade in the bond market, I use the TRACE data described above to count the number of bond transactions that occurred each day in each industry and average these counts to obtain the variable NTRADES. Using the same procedure, I also calculate the average principal amount (VOLUME) traded each day across industries. These variables control for variations in bond trading activity, which could be either positively or negatively related to CDS spread changes. For example, an increase in volume may suggest that bonds are easier to trade; this could relieve hedging pressure in the CDS market and decrease CDS liquidity premiums. Alternatively an increase in volume could relate to higher expected inventory costs, which could lead dealers to reduce liquidity in both the CDS and bond market. Third, authors have argued that liquidity is a state variable, which suggests that CDS spreads should contain a component that compensates for systematic liquidity risk [see Pastor et al. (2003); Acharya et al. (2005)]. The high level of uncertainty regarding liquidity risk that persisted during the 24 Changes in Industry bid-ask spreads are orthogonalized with respect to changes in the average bid-ask spread BIDASK. 25 This would require dealers to be more willing to trade in the CDS market than in the bond market, which could occur because of differences in transparency. Bond trades require mandatory disclosure but CDS trades do not. Transparency of bond trading reduces transaction costs. Therefore, dealers may be able to charge higher transaction costs in the CDS market than in the bond market, which would make them more willing to trade. 26 Bond level Amihud measures require at least two trades per day; days with one or no trades are replaced with missing values. The index is constructed by building firm level Amihud measures, which are averages of bond-level measures. Next, I aggregate to the industry level by averaging over firms in the industry. The final index is an equally weighted average of industry liquidity measures. This procedure ensures that each industry is equally represented in the final aggregation. I also tested industry level measures but this did not change the result. TRACE variables measure intra-day activity which affects the daily (close-to-close) change and are therefore included as levels. 19 crisis may have increased the volatility of systematic liquidity premiums. Therefore, I include three measures of market-wide liquidity, which are designed to capture fluctuations in aggregate liquidity premiums. The first is the difference between the yield of the off the run and on the run five-year Treasury note (ONOFF), which is calculated using yields on end of day quotes obtained from Datastream [see Fleming (2003)]. A difficulty with this measure is that it may contain “flight-toquality” premiums or be subject to specialness effects that arise from the supply of or demand for the on/off the run five-year Treasury note. Therefore, I include the repo spread (ONREPO), which Liu et al. (2006) argue is less sensitive to these effects. The repo spread is constructed by subtracting the three-month constant maturity Treasury rate (RF3M) from the three-month general collateral repo rate obtained from Bloomberg.27 The third measure is the liquidity component of the TED spread (OISTB), which is the difference between the overnight index swap rate (OIR) and RF3M [see Eichengreen et al. (2009)]. Finally, liquidity in the CDS market can suffer if speculators reduce their trading activity [see Brunnermeier et al. (2009)], which can increase and sustain correlations at a higher level for two reasons. First, speculative trading in the CDS market depends on their access to funding (funding liquidity). This is because CDS contracts commonly contain collateral agreements, which require the exchange of capital at inception.28 Therefore, increased variation in speculators funding liquidity can magnify CDS correlation by increasing the variation in speculators ability to trade.29 Second, collateral agreements provide for incremental payments (collateral calls) throughout the life of the contract, which are contingent on the credit quality of the counterparty and value of the contract. Collateral calls can represent substantial costs to speculators.30 Therefore, trading activity likely varied more during the crisis due to the management of mark-to-market risk. To measure speculators’ ability to transact, I construct an index of hedge fund returns. According to the British Bankers’ Association (BBA) 2006 Credit Derivatives Report, banks and 27 The three-month constant maturity risk-free rate (RF3M), from the Federal Reserve, is constructed from a composite of on-the-run Treasury Bills. Therefore, it can be used as a proxy for the “liquid” risk-free rate. The repo rate is basically the interest rate on a short-term loan collateralized by Treasury bills. Repo rates are usually over collateralized making them effectively a risk-free rate. Moreover, since they are contracts, they are not subject to the same supply and demand issues that result in specialness or flight-to-quality premiums that are present in bonds. 28 The initial payment, which is referred to as the Independent Amount, is outlined in the 2005 ISDA Collateral Guidelines. According to the 2009 ISDA Margin Survey 74% of contracts executed in 2008 were subject to collateral agreements. Further, the dollar value of collateral used increased from approximately 2 trillion to 4 trillion in 2008 29 The increased uncertainty surrounding the value of hedge fund collateral, along with measures taken by the federal government to maintain a liquid market during the crisis could have induced substantial variations in hedge funds’ ability to trade. 30 An example of such a shock to funding liquidity can be found in the downgrade of AIG in September 2008, which triggered collateral calls that exceeded $30 billion by the end of October 20 hedge funds are the largest participants in the CDS market with 59% and 28% (44% and 32%) respectively of buy (sell) side trading activity as of the end of 2006.31 Assuming that banks mainly trade as dealers, hedge funds are clearly the largest speculators in the market, making up approximately 70% (60%) of non-dealer buy (sell) side trading activity. Therefore, I focus on measuring hedge funds’ access to capital, which depends on the performance of their returns [see Boyson, Stahel and Stulz (2008)]. As a direct measure I obtain eight series of daily hedge fund style index returns from Hedge Fund Research (HFR).32 From these data, I calculate an aggregate hedge fund return index (HEDGE) by taking the equally weighted average across all eight return series. Hedge fund returns are lagged one day to limit the influence of hedge fund CDS holdings. As with other potential explanations, I evaluate the role of liquidity in two steps. First, I control for liquidity in the fundamental regression. Second, I reevaluate the correlation of factor model residuals to test whether liquidity was a significant channel of contagion. Results of the test for liquidity contagion are reported in Panel A of Table VI. The main result, for the role of liquidity prior to and during the crisis, is reported in the subpanel labeled PreCrisis/Crisis. These results show that prior to the crisis changes in systematic liquidity as measured by ∆ONOFF, ∆OISTB, and ∆ONREPO do not determine CDS spread changes. Furthermore, bond market liquidity is not a significant determinant of CDS spread changes prior to the crisis, which is evidenced by insignificant estimated regression coefficients for AMIHUD, NTRADES, and VOLUME. The change in the average bid-ask spread is significant, in the pre-crisis period, for four of the six industry portfolios. Moreover, CDS spread changes become significantly more positively related to lagged hedge fund returns during the crisis, which is counter intuitive if hedge funds are liquidity providers (this result is discussed in more detail below). Various industries become more exposed to changes in the bid-ask spread and bond liquidity measures during the crisis. However, these changes are not consistent across industries. For robustness, I repeat these tests on the month following the collapse of Lehman Brothers (Sept. 15, 2008 - Oct. 15, 2008), which is widely thought of as a time when contagion gripped credit markets. The results of these tests are reported in Panel A of Table VI in the subpanel labeled Lehman/Non-Lehman. These results show that liquidity effects, as measured by changes in the bid31 Banks participation is further split into trading activity (39% buy side and 35% sell side) and loan portfolio (20% buy side and 9% sell side), which makes banks market making activity comparable to hedge funds speculating activity. 32 HRF includes over 1,600 funds with no required minimum track record or asset value. Their series are equallyweighted averages of domestic and offshore fund returns. Daily returns are available for eight style indices: Equal Weighted, Equity Hedge, Equity Market Neutral, Event Driven, Global, Macro, Market Directional, Merger Arbitrage, and Relative Value Arbitrage 21 ask spread and HEDGE, are concentrated outside of the Lehman Brothers month. A closer investigation shows that the change in the average bid-ask spread, when run independently of other proxies is positive and significant over the full sample period and becomes more so during the Lehman Brothers month. The hedge fund effect is strongest between August 2007 and May 2008. One possible explanation for this is that bonds were difficult to sell during this period. Therefore, hedge funds may have effectively sold the illiquid bond in the CDS market by purchasing CDS protection, which could lead to a positive return. However, this would also increase the amount of protection demanded in the CDS market, which could increase the liquidity premium. This would explain the positive sign. An asset substitution explanation is supported by a significant negative relation between bond volume and CDS spread changes for four of the six industry portfolios over this period. [INSERT TABLE VI] The above analysis shows that changes in the bid-ask spread and hedge fund returns are significant determinants of CDS spread changes, but systematic liquidity and bond liquidity (with the exception of VOLUME) are not. However, these results must be interpreted relative to liquidity in the equity market. This is because market based proxies for fundamentals, such as the S&P 500 return, can carry liquidity premiums, which could absorb the effect of liquidity in CDS contracts. I now turn to the question of liquidity contagion. To determine whether liquidity risk was a significant source of contagion, I reevaluate the increase in excess correlation using residuals from the fundamental model with liquidity controls. Panel B of Table VI reports results for the tests of excess correlation. The increase in pairwise excess correlation between industry portfolios ranges from 0.09 to 0.33 and is significant for all industry pairs. Furthermore, the tests for a constant excess correlation matrix and for constant average correlation both reject the null hypothesis at the 1% level. These results suggest that liquidity contagion cannot explain the full increase in excess correlation documented above. To investigate the marginal contribution of liquidity, I calculate a difference-indifference matrix by subtracting the matrix in Table V from the matrix in Panel B of Table VI. If there is a significant reduction in correlation after controlling for liquidity, then values in the difference-in-difference matrix will be positive and significant. However, the results show that liquidity controls offer no significant reduction in excess correlation. Additionally, I repeat these tests using residuals from the fundamental model with liquidity contagion parameters estimated in the Lehman Brothers month and several other time intervals. Unreported results are equivalent to those of the previous tests. The important conclusion from the liquidity analysis is that, fluctuations in 22 liquidity premiums (in excess of what may be implied by equity markets) do not significantly increase the correlation in CDS spread changes during the crisis. 4.2 Counterparty Risk Contagion The risk that counterparties will not be able to uphold contractual obligations can systematically affect CDS spreads for at least three reasons. First, an increase in the credit risk of a CDS protection seller decreases the value of the insurance guarantee they can provide [see Arora et al. (2009)] and, therefore, reduces the CDS premium they are able to charge. Hence, a common increase in the variation of credit risk among CDS dealers can increase the comovement of CDS spreads. I refer to this effect as the insurance value mechanism. Second, an increase in counterparty risk can reduce market participants’ willingness to trade with each other;33 a condition that Brunnermeier (2009) refers to as “Gridlock”. Gridlock is a side effect of CDS market structure (overthe-counter), which transfers credit risk from the seller to the final bearer of the risk through a series of offsetting transactions. This creates a complex and fragile network of interdependence among dealers.34 In Gridlock, dealers’ refusal to trade with each other causes this network to breakdown, making contracts more difficult to offset and increasing liquidity premiums. Both the Gridlock and the insurance value mechanisms suggest that variations in dealers’ credit risk can increase excess correlation. Eichengreen et al. (2009) argue that the credit risk of large investment banks, who are major dealers in the CDS market, varied substantially more throughout the crisis. To test if an increase in the variation of counterparty risk amplified correlations during the crisis, I relate CDS spread changes to four measures of bank sector credit risk. First, I include the credit risk component of the TED spread, which is calculated using the overnight index swap rate (OIR) [see Eichengreen et al. (2009)]. In this decomposition, TED = (LIBOR – OIR) + (OIR – TBILL), the first term (the overnight index swap spread (OIS)) measures banking sector credit risk and the second term measures liquidity risk. Banks’ access to short-term funding is also an important determinant of dealers’ credit risk. Prior to 2007 banks took on large positions in long-term structured finance products, such as residential mortgage backed securities (RMBS), which they financed using short-term asset backed commercial paper. This maturity mismatch caused banks to rely heavily on the asset backed 33 Some evidence that dealers became more reluctant to trade with each other during the crisis can be found in Global Credit Derivatives Survey: Surprises, Challenges and the Future, Fitch Ratings, August 20, 2009. 34 Some evidence is provided in the March 10, 2009 testimony of Robert Pickel, CEO of ISDA, to Congress that 86% of the Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (DTCC) trades were dealer to dealer trades. 23 commercial paper market to meet short-term funding requirement [see Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2009); Brunnermeier (2009); Acharya and Richardson (2009)]. Therefore, to capture changes in the cost of short-term funding, I construct a second measure, the asset-backed commercial paper spread (ABCP), which is the spread between the yield on 90 day asset-backed commercial paper obtained from Bloomberg and RF3M. Third, I construct a measure of dealers’ financial health, which is a value weighted index of dealers’ stock returns (CPstock). I define dealers as the sixteen banks that are licensed, by the index administrator (Markit), to make the market in the CDX.NA.IG index. The data used to construct the dealer stock return index is obtained from Datastream for each dealer as long as equity returns are available.35 Finally, CDS correlation can increase if credit risk increased inconsistently across dealers. In the extreme, this would produce a group of high-quality dealers and a group of low-quality dealers. In this case, the demand for protection from participants seeking to enter new positions will be concentrated with high-quality dealers. This is because, even with collateral agreements, protection buyers can experience losses from the failure of a CDS counterparty.36 Hence, they have incentives to deal with low-risk dealers. Moreover, protection buyers who hold existing contracts with high-risk counterparties may choose to novate (transfer) these contracts to a more stable dealer. This would further increase the quantity of protection demanded from a small group of high-quality marketmakers. The additional strain would likely cause dealers to reduce the extent of their market making services. Therefore, an increase in the time variation of dealer risk dispersion may have increased CDS correlation during the crisis.37 In this case, CDS spread changes would become more related to the degree of risk dispersion among dealers. To capture the cross-sectional variation in dealers’ credit risk, I create a measure of risk dispersion among CDS market-makers. I use individual equity return series for the sixteen dealers defined above (for as long as equity returns are available) to measure the credit risk of each dealer. 35 The counterparty risk variables are mainly designed to capture changes in liquidity brought on by changes in dealers’ credit risk. It is likely that this form of liquidity will not be captured by changes in the bid-ask spread because it stems from dealers refusal to trade with each other. This would manifest as a symmetric increase in the bid-ask spread, in which case, changes in the mid price would not become more correlated with changes in the bid ask spread. 36 Losses can occur for two reasons. First, the protection buyer may have to pay to reestablish a comparable contract with another dealer. In this case, if the value of the collateral posted does not fully cover these costs, the protection buyer must seek compensation from the bankruptcy estate. Second, if the contract triggers at the same time the protection seller defaults, then additional costs (over the value of collateral posted) must be claimed from the bankruptcy estate. 37 Some evidence of the time variation in risk dispersion can be seen in the Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers events. Also variation in the timing an degree to which various banks accepted government aid provides additional evidence of an increase in the time variation of dealer risk dispersion. 24 Next, I calculate the degree of risk dispersion (CPDIF) by subtracting the maximum return from the median return on each day. The median return measures the “normal” credit risk in the pool and the maximum return measures the risk of the highest quality dealer.38 The effect of dealer risk dispersion will be most severe on days when risk dispersion is large. Hence, I include an interaction dummy variable (EXCPDIF) that is equal to CPDIF on days when the difference between the median and maximum return is above its 95th percentile. [INSERT TABLE VII] Regression coefficients for counterparty risk variables, which are added to the fundamental model, are reported in Panel A of Table VII. They show that changes in counterparty risk are not significant determinants of CDS spread changes prior to the crisis. Furthermore, the marginal change in the exposure of CDS spread changes to counterparty risk is insignificant for all proxies. This result suggests that counterparty risk is not a significant determinant of CDS spread changes, which is consistent with the findings of Arora et al. (2009).39 Having controlled for counterparty risk, I now turn to the question of contagion. The results of these tests are reported in Panel B of Table VII. Tests of pairwise excess correlation between industry portfolios show that controlling for counterparty risk does not explain the increase in excess correlation. Further, the null hypotheses of constant average excess correlation and a constant correlation matrix are both rejected at the 1% level. Moreover, the difference-in-difference matrix, reported in Panel B, shows that counterparty risk proxies do not provide any significant improvement, over the fundamental model alone, in explaining the increase in excess correlation. As with the liquidity analysis, I repeat these tests on the month following the Lehman Brothers Bankruptcy with no notable change in the results. These results suggest that counterparty risk contagion did not significantly affect CDS spread changes during the crisis. 4.3 Liquidity and Counterparty Risk Robustness Before investigating risk premiums, I explore the robustness of the above results. Although proxies are designed to measure changes in liquidity and counterparty risk, one could argue that they do not adequately capture the desired effect during periods of turmoil or that the microstructure noise 38 To correct for the large skewness of this variable I take the natural log of dealer risk dispersion, which is the final measure. 39 They find evidence of statistically significant counterparty risk in the cross section of dealer quotes; however, the effect only appears in quotes from U.S. issuers and is not economically large. Therefore, counterparty risk is not likely to be present in the dealer averages. 25 present in high frequency data obscures their power. To address these concerns, I simplify the approach and focus on events that occurred during the crisis which could have constrained liquidity or amplified counterparty risk. At this point, I do not attempt to separate these two effects as both are susceptible to sudden short-lived spikes. This is distinctly different from risk premiums, which likely changed gradually over this period as investors adjusted their risk appetites. For shocks to liquidity risk or counterparty risk to produce a sustained increase in correlations, multiple events would need to be spaced throughout the crisis period. From appendix A it is apparent that this requirement was sufficiently satisfied. If shocks to liquidity/counterparty risk significantly affected CDS correlation during the crisis, then spread changes, across all portfolios, should respond to liquidity/counterparty risk enhancing and deteriorating events. To test this, I begin by collecting a list of 85 events that occurred during the crisis. I then split these into distress events, which constrain liquidity or increase counterparty risk, and recovery events with the opposite effect. This list is included as Appendix B. I then implement a calendar time event study by including two dummy variables DISTRESS and RECOVERY in the fundamental regressions. Each dummy variable equals one on a window around the distress or recovery date and zero elsewhere. For distress or recovery events, a positive coefficient suggests that CDS spreads increased, which is consistent with an increase in liquidity risk or a decrease in counterparty risk. The opposite is true for a negative coefficient. [INSERT TABLE VIII] Table VIII reports the estimated shift in the constant around the specified event dates. Because each fundamental regression already contains a crisis dummy, this marginal change is relative to the crisis fixed effect.40 In Panel A, the distress and recovery indicators are set equal to one on all event dates listed in Appendix B and zero elsewhere.41 Using the event date only eliminates overlapping windows. Results show that, on average, CDS spread changes do not increase significantly on distress event dates, nor do they decrease significantly on recovery event dates. This result could arise if a number of insignificant events, included in this first pass, obscure the larger effect, which is concentrated on more severe event dates. Therefore, Panel B reports the estimated recovery and distress indicator variable coefficients for more severe events, which are labeled 2 and 3 in the Severity column of Appendix B. This adjustment does not change the above result. Finally, I 40 To ensure that these effects are not subsumed by the crisis fixed effect, I repeat the estimation without a crisis dummy. The results do not change. 41 Most events are obtained from the St. Luis Federal Reserve timeline. If events fall on a weekend, I define the next available trading date as the event date. 26 investigate only the most severe distress events, which include the Bear Stearns merger, the collapse of Lehman Brothers, and the closure of Washington Mutual. I define a four-day observation window around each of these events (one day prior and two days after).42 Again, I find that the reaction in CDS spread changes around these events is insignificant.43 Controlling for extreme events cannot explain the increase in excess correlation. After including the distress and recovery indicators in the fundamental regression, I repeat the tests for a change in inter-industry excess correlation. These results, which are left unreported, show that the correlation between model residuals still increases significantly for most industry pairs. Taken together, the results of the examination to this point provide convincing evidence that CDS correlation increased for reasons other than liquidity or counterparty risk. 4.4 Risk Premium Contagion In this subsection I investigate whether variations in default risk premiums amplified CDS correlation. Prior work has shown that the default risk premium is an important component of corporate credit spreads [see Duffee (1999); Elton et al. (2001); Driessen (2005)] and can vary drastically over time [see BDDFS]. Therefore, a sustained increase in the common variation of risk premiums may have increased CDS correlation over the crisis period. This could occur if investors continually adjusted their risk appetites, perhaps in response to large mark-to-market losses, over the crisis period. Hence, an increase in the common variation of risk premiums is a likely explanation for the higher level of correlation. Some evidence that default risk premiums varied more in the crisis can be found in the December 2008 Financial Stability Review issued by the European Central Bank (ECB). According to the ECB, the market price of default risk was low (at approximately 5 basis points) and remained relatively constant prior to the crisis. In August 2007 there is a notable change in the behavior of risk premiums, which increased drastically up to the Bear Stearns merger and continued to vary through the end of 2008. An increase in the common variation of default risk premiums alone is not sufficient to explain the observed increase in excess correlation. Additionally, risk premiums in the CDS market must vary independently from those in the equity market, which may be captured by the fundamental 42 Several different windows were specified the 1 and 2 day combination was chosen because it performed best in the regression. 43 It is important to remember that these dummy variables are estimated relative to fundamental factors. Therefore, CDS spreads may have reacted to these events, but these results suggest that the reaction was not remarkably different from what occurred in other markets. 27 model. There are at least two reasons why risk premiums in the CDS market can differ from those in the equity market. First, if the CDS market is segmented or became segmented during the crisis, then risk premiums in the CDS market would be determined independently from risk premiums in other markets. Second, CDS spreads contain a jump-to-default risk premium that is not present in equity returns.44 Recent investigations of the credit crisis suggest that risk premiums may play a role in amplifying correlations in credit derivatives. For example, Longstaff (2008) shows that contagion spread from the subprime market, represented by the ABX index, to different asset classes such as stocks, corporate bonds and Treasuries during the credit crisis. In a related paper, Kim, Loretan and Remolona (2009) use Moody’s EDF and principal components (extracted from various CDS indices) to argue that changes in risk premiums were responsible for a general widening of CDS spreads in Asian credit markets (38 foreign references) between 2007 and 2009. The default risk premium compensates investors for bearing exposure to two basic sources of risk. The first is diffusion or systematic risk [see Duffie (1999)], which is the risk associated with non-diversifiable variations in macroeconomic conditions. This component of the default risk premium is closely related to the premiums demanded by investors in the equity market [see Elton et al. (2001)]. Second, investors require a premium for bearing exposure to the default event itself (the jump-to-default risk premium) [see Jarrow, Lando and Yu (2005); Driessen (2005); BDDFS (2008)].45 This is measured as the ratio of the risk neutral to the physical probability of default and is exclusive to defaultable securities. A ratio in excess of one indicates that investors require a positive premium for exposure to event risk. This can be justified in two ways. First, if the default event is specific to a particular firm, the associated risk can be priced if event risk is not fully diversifiable [see Jarrow et al. (2005)]. Alternatively, the jump-to-default risk premium can compensate investors for exposure to systemic or contagious events [see Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Helwege (2010)]. In either case, common variations in this premium are capable of amplifying correlations. To investigate whether variations in the jump-to-default risk premium increased CDS correlation, it is necessary to obtain a time varying measure of this risk premium. To do this, I follow BDDFS who use Moody’s Expected Default Frequency (EDF) to measure the physical 44 The default spread used in the fundamental model may also capture some of the influence from risk premiums. However, this does not preclude changes in risk premiums from increasing excess correlation because, as previously discussed, the arbitrage relation between CDS contracts and bonds is approximate. 45 I am aware that recovery risk will also command a premium. However, research has shown that recovery is closely associated with macroeconomic conditions. Therefore, these premiums are likely captured by the systematic component of the default risk premium. 28 probability of default. 46 Moody’s KMV provides EDF, which are firm-level estimates of conditional default probabilities, for most publicly traded companies over several horizons. I use the five-year horizon to match the CDS maturities. Crosbie and Bohn (2002) and Kealhofer (2003) provide more details on the KMV model and fitting procedure for the EDF. Daily EDF data is available beginning on June 1, 2006. Therefore, I adjust the pre-crisis period, for the risk premium analysis, to begin on this date. I then reevaluate the change in excess correlation using the adjusted sample periods. Unreported results show that pairwise correlations still increase significantly for all industry pairs. Following BDDFS, I estimate the panel regression model shown in Equation 3. I modify the original estimation slightly by adding firm fixed effects, which offer stronger controls for crosssectional variations in expected loss given default. 47 Consistent with their specification, Dt is a time fixed effect, which is equal to one on day t. This yields estimates γ for each day j; the inverse log of these parameters e is an estimate of the proportional risk premium (RP). That is, e is the ratio of the fitted CDS spread for a firm on day j to that of the average firm on June 1, 2006 (the reference time period). ln ln γ D z (3) The object of this estimation is to obtain an accurate measure of the jump-to-default risk premium in CDS spreads. Intuitively, one can think of this as the premium associated with a systemic event that is capable of increasing default probabilities for a substantial number of firms. In this case, the risk associated with such an event would be priced. Hence, the estimated jump-to-default risk premium can be interpreted as the ratio of the risk neutral to the physical probability that a systemic event occurs. 48 The most direct method to obtain this premium is to estimate Equation 3 using all contracts in the sample. However, this assumes that all CDS spreads are unaffected by other noncredit risk factors. If this is not the case, then these factors could bias the estimation. For example, 46 This can also be achieved using equity returns [see Elkamhi and Ericsson (2007)]. However, I focus on the jumpto-default risk premium, which is inherently difficult to measure using equity returns. Moreover, if markets became segmented during the crisis this technique would not be appropriate. BDDFS, to my knowledge provides the only time varying estimate of the jump-to-default risk premium. 47 This justification for fixed effects is valid to the extent that expected loss given default has a component that varies over industries or firms and is constant over time. An f-test of the fixed effects and a Hausman for fixed vs. random effects confirms that this is the appropriate model. 48 This interpretation violates the conditional independence assumption of Jarrow, Lando, and Yu (2005) by linking firms’ default intensities to a single unpredictable event. Therefore, it is closely related to the counterparty risk pricing model of Jarrow and Yu (2001) where many firms share a single counterparty. Alternatively, one can think of this as a contagion premium where firm’s default intensities are linked. This is modeled by Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein Helwege (2010). 29 suppose contracts in a particular industry carry a liquidity premium that is not common across industries. Although variations in this premium would not affect correlations, its presence in the CDS spread could bias estimates of the jump-to-default risk premium. Alternatively, one could estimate the jump-to-default risk premium using a subset of contracts. This is because only a priced event is capable of producing premiums that can alter correlations. Therefore, if contagion occurred because of an increase in the variance of the jump-todefault risk premium, then, by definition, this premium would be present in the CDS spreads of all contracts. Following this intuition, I choose the set of firms that have the lowest volatility in their contract premiums over the sample period. The basic reasoning behind this choice is that contracts with relatively low CDS spread volatility are not likely to be heavily exposed to other non-credit risk factors such as liquidity or counterparty risk. Further, if event risk is priced then the CDS spreads of these firms, which I refer to as well-behaved firms, should vary with variations in the jump-to-default risk premium. Therefore, focusing on well-behaved firms may offer the most precise estimate of the risk premium. Additionally, Moody’s EDF likely performed best during the crisis for firms that did not experience large variations in credit risk, which, by definition, would include well-behaved firms. This will also add precision to the estimated risk premium. Specifically, I define well-behaved firms using a double sort. First, I sort CDS contracts by the volatility of their contract spreads prior to the crisis and eliminate all firms with pre-crisis volatilities that fall above the median. Second, I repeat the sort using the volatility of their contract spreads during the crisis. This ensures that contract premiums have low volatility in both periods. Finally, I take the 10 firms with the lowest crisis CDS spread volatility as my base subsample of well-behaved firms.49 After estimating the risk premium using well-behaved firms, I return to the question of excess correlation. This requires a control for the influence of risk premiums on CDS spread changes. To remain consistent with prior explanations, I add the change in the estimated risk premium ∆e back into the fundamental regression, which achieves the desired control. To see this, note that Equation 3 implies a proportional relation between the fitted CDS spread and both the EDF and risk 49 I chose 10 firms to avoid a hardwired result. As more firms are added to the set, there is higher likelihood that the risk premium measure is significant because it captures residual variations from firms that are also in the industry portfolios. To address this issue I also construct risk premium estimates using the 20 most well-behaved firms that are not included in each of industry. 30 % $ premium ,! " # ,! &'! (. Therefore, by holding the EDF constant over time, I can isolate the relation between the CDS spread and the risk premium. In this setting, a change in the risk premium is clearly proportional to a change in the CDS spread ∆,! )∆&'! over time, which still holds after CDS spreads are aggregated to the industry level. Results of the fundamental regression with risk premium controls, estimated using the subsample of 10 well-behaved firms, are reported in panel A of Table IX. As with other tests, I allow the exposures to vary during the crisis. A significant increase in the exposure across industries indicates that a larger portion of the common variation in CDS spread changes can be attributed to variation in the default risk premium. The first row of table IX reports the exposures of CDS spread changes to changes in the risk premium. Not surprisingly, I find that risk premiums are both statistically and economically important determinants of CDS spread changes prior to and during the crisis. The estimated regression coefficients imply that, after controlling for factors that determine expected loss and holding all else constant, on average 40% of the change in CDS spreads can be explained by changes in risk premiums. This number increases slightly during the crisis to approximately 60%, which is consistent with an increase in excess correlation. R-squared for each regression shows a strong improvement in the model fit increasing by approximately 0.30 relative to the fundamental regression. This suggests that approximately 30% of the time series variation in CDS spread changes can be explained by changes in the risk premium.50 Panel C of Table IX shows the results of the test for risk premium contagion. Strikingly, the increase in pairwise inter-industry excess correlation is almost entirely explained by controlling for changes in the default risk premium. This result suggests that risk premiums were the main source of contagion during the crisis. The one notable exception is the healthcare industry, which still shows a significant increase in excess correlation with the other and financial sectors. This could result from a noisy estimate of the risk premium given that only 10 firms are used to construct this measure. Therefore, I repeat the test using estimates of the risk premium constructed from 20 firms. To avoid a hardwired result, each industry’s risk premium proxy is estimated using the 20 most well-behaved firms that are not members of that particular industry. The results of the factor model estimation using the modified risk premium are reported in Panel B of table IX and show similar results to those 50 Adding the estimated risk premium back into the fundamental model means that the SUR regression suffers from errors in variables. This is done to remain consistent with other tests. To alleviate such econometric concerns, I also extract additive errors from equation 3 and repeat the tests for a change in excess correlation. These results are consistent with what is reported in Table IX 31 in panel A. The tests for contagion are reported in Panel D and show that increasing the precision of the risk premium estimate explains any residual increase in excess correlation. The results of the default risk premium analysis are compelling. However, estimates of the risk premium obtained from Equation 3 may also capture liquidity premiums, which previous tests have shown to be important determinants of CDS spread changes. Therefore, it is plausible that the risk premium control is in fact a more powerful estimate of the liquidity premium. To address this concern, I re-estimate the risk premium using the 20 most well-behaved non-industry firms and control for liquidity using bid-ask spreads for each firm.51 Results of the risk premium robustness tests are reported in Table X. They show that controlling for transaction costs in the estimation of the jump-to-default risk premium reduces its explanatory power in the fundamental regression. This is evidenced by a reduction of approximately 0.08 in r-squared relative to the results reported in Table IX. Therefore, variations in the risk premium explain approximately 20% rather than 30% of the time series variation in CDS spread changes. The remaining 10% is likely due to variations in the liquidity premium. With respect to risk premium contagion, Panel B shows that the results of risk premium contagion are not driven by variations in liquidity risk. 5. Conclusion This paper investigates contagion and excess correlation in daily CDS spread changes during the 2007-2009 credit crisis. I construct a sample of liquid corporate single-name credit default swap contracts, which includes constituents of the CDX.NA.IG index roles 8-12. Using simple measures of association, I show that the comovement of CDS spread changes increases significantly after July 2007. Having established that correlations increased, I turn to the question of contagion. CDS correlation can increase simply because of an increase in the variance of common factors that drive credit risk. Alternatively, correlations can increase because of an increase in the influence of noncredit risk factors. To test whether common variations in credit risk increased correlations, I build six equally weighted industry portfolios based on the Fama and French five industry classifications (the six is Financials which is extracted from Other). In the spirit of Bekaert et al. (2005), I decompose the raw inter-industry CDS correlation into fundamental and excess correlation using a factor model. Finally, I test for contagion by evaluating whether the correlations of factor model residuals 51 Specifically, I add the natural of the bid-ask spread for each firm into the panel regression in Equation 3. The bidask spread was show to be the most significant determinant of CDS liquidity in Section 4.1 32 increased during the crisis. I find strong evidence that common variations in credit risk were not fully responsible for the higher correlations observed during the crisis, which establishes that contagion occurred. Next, I investigate whether an increase in the variance of liquidity premiums, counterparty risk premiums, or the jump-to-default risk premium can explain the increase in excess correlation. First, I investigate liquidity risk. To do this, I add several liquidity proxies, which control for variations in transaction costs, funding liquidity, systematic liquidity, and bond market liquidity, into the fundamental model and repeat the test for contagion. The results of these tests show that liquidity risk was not a significant channel of contagion during the crisis. Therefore, I turn to counterparty risk. To control for variations in counterparty risk, I add several proxies of aggregate dealer credit risk into the factor model. However, as with liquidity, controlling for variations in counterparty risk offers no significant improvement over the fundamental model alone. Therefore, I conclude that counterparty risk was not a significant source of contagion during the crisis. Finally, I evaluate whether variations in risk premiums increased the excess correlation. To do this, I estimate the jump-to-default risk premium from a sample of well-behaved firms using Moody’s EDF and the panel regression procedure developed in BDDFS. Adding the change in this measure into the factor model, I find that changes in the risk premium account for approximately 30% of the time series variation in CDS spread changes. Furthermore, controlling for changes in the risk premium completely explains the increase in excess correlation, which suggests that an increase in the variance of the risk premium was the main channel for contagion. This important result shows that a systematic re-pricing of credit risk, rather than increased variations from market frictions, amplified CDS correlation during the credit crisis. 33 References Acharya, V. and L. H. Pedersen (2005). Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk. Journal of Financial Economics 77, 375–410. Acharya, V. V. and M. Richardson (2009). Causes of the Financial Crisis. Critial Review 21(2-3). Acharya, V. V., S. M. Schaefer, and Y. Zhang (2008). Liquidity Risk and Correlation Risk: A Clinical Study of the General Motors and Ford Downgrade of May 2005. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper Series. Allen, F. and E. Carletti (2006). Credit Risk Transfer and Contagion. Journal of Monetary Economics 53(1), 89–111. Allen, L. and A. Saunders (2003). A Survey of Cyclical Effects in Credit Risk Measurement Models. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper Series. Altman, E. I., B. Brady, A. Resti, and A. Sironi (2005). The Link Between Default and Recovery Rates: Theory, Empirical Evidence, and Implications. The Journal of Business 78(6), 22032227. Altman, E. I. and V. M. Kishore (1996). Almost Everything You Wanted to Know About Recoveries on Defaulted Bonds. Financial Analysts Journal 52(6), 57–64. Amihud, Y. (2002). Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects. Journal of Financial Markets 5(1), 31–56. Amihud, Y. and H. Mendelson (1986). Asset Pricing and the Bid-Ask Spread. Journal of Financial Economics 17(2), 223–249. Arora, N., P. Gandhi, and F. A. Longstaff (2009). Counterparty Credit Risk and the Credit Default Swap Market. Working Paper, UCLA. Working paper. Baker, M. and J. Wurgler (2002). Market Timing and Capital Structure. Journal of finance 57(1), 1– 32. Bekaert, G., C. R. Harvey, and A. Ng (2005). Market Integration and Contagion. The Journal of Business 78(1), 39–69. Berndt, A., R. Douglas, D. Duffie, M. Ferguson, and D. Schranz (2008). Measuring Default Risk Premia From Default Swap Rates and EDFs. Working Paper. Berndt, A., R. A. Jarrow, and C. Kang (2007). Restructuring Risk in Credit Default Swaps: An Empirical Analysis. Stochastic Processes and their Applications 117(11), 1724–1749. Blanco, R., S. Brennan, and I. w. Marsh (2005). An Empirical Analysis of the Dynamic Relation Between Investment-Grade Bonds and Credit Default Swaps. The Journal of Finance 60(5), 2255–2281. Bongaerts, D., F. D. Jong, and J. Driessen (2009). Derivative Pricing with Liquidity Risk: Theory and Evidence From the Credit Default Swap Market. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper Series. Boyer, B. H., M. S. Gibson, and M. Loretan (1997). Pitfalls in Tests for Changes in Correlations. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.). International Finance Discussion Papers. Boyson, N. M., C. W. Stahel, and R. M. Stulz (2008). Hedge Fund Contagion and Liquidity. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper Series. Browne, M. W. and A. Shapiro (1986). The Asymptotic Covariance Matrix of Sample Correlation Coefficients Under General Conditions. Linear Algebra and Its Applications 82, 169–76. Brunnermeier, M. K. (2009). Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1), 77. Brunnermeier, M. K. and L. H. Pedersen (2009). Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 22(6), 2201–2238. Buhler, W., and M. Trapp. (2008) Time-varying credit risk and liquidity premia in bond and CDS Markets. Working Paper. 34 Campbell, J. Y., J. Hilscher, and J. Szilagyi (2008). In Search of Distress Risk. The Journal of Finance 63(6), 2899–2939. Chen, L., D. A. Lesmond, and J. Wei (2007). Corporate Yield Spreads and Bond Liquidity. Journal of Finance 62, 119–149. Collin-Dufresne, P., R. Goldstein, and J. Helwege (2003). Is Credit Event Risk Priced? Modeling Contagion Via the Updating of Beliefs. Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley. Collin-Dufresne, P., R. S. Goldstein, and J. S. Martin (2001). The Determinants of Credit Spread Changes. The Journal of Finance 56(6), 2177–2207. Corsetti, G., M. Pericoli, and M. Sbracia (2005). “Some Contagion, Some Interdependence”: More Pitfalls in Tests of Financial Contagion. Journal of International Money and Finance 24(8), 1177–1199. Coval, J. D., J. W. Jurek, and E. Stafford (2009). The Pricing of Investment Grade Credit Risk During the Financial Crisis. Working Paper. Crosbie, P. and J. R. Bohn (2003). Modeling Default Risk. Moody’s KMV. Das, S. R., D. Duffie, N. Kapadia, and L. Saita (2007). Common Failings: How Corporate Defaults Are Correlated. The Journal of Finance 62(1), 93–117. de Servigny, A. and O. Renault (2002). Default Correlation: Empirical Evidence, working paper, Standard and Poor’s. Dick-Nielsen, Jens. (2009). Liquidity biases in TRACE. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper. Dick-Nielsen, J., P. Feldhutter, and D. Lando (2009). Corporate Bond Liquidity Before and After the Onset of the Subprime Crisis. Working paper. Driessen, J. (2005). Is Default Event Risk Priced in Corporate Bonds? Review of Financial Studies 18(1), 165–195. Duffee, G. R. (1998). The Relation Between Treasury Yields and Corporate Bond Yield Spreads. Journal of Finance 53, 2225–2241. Duffee, G. R. (1999). Estimating the Price of Default Risk Review of Financial Studies, 12, 197-226. Duffie, D. (1999). Credit Swap Valuation. Financial Analysts Journal 55(1), 73. Duffie, D., A. Eckner, G. Horel, and L. Saita (2009). Frailty Correlated Default. The Journal of Finance 64(5), 2089–2123. Eichengreen, B. J., M. Nedeljkovic, A. Mody, and L. Sarno (2009). How the Subprime Crisis Went Global: Evidence From Bank Credit Default Swap Spreads. SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper. Elton, Gruber, Agrawal and Mann (2001). Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds. Journal of Finance 56, 247–277. Ericsson, J., K. Jacobs, and R. Oviedo (2009). The Determinants of Credit Default Swap Premia. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 44(1), 109–132. Fisher, R. A. (1921). On the "Probable Error" of a Coefficient of Correlation Deduced From a Small Sample. Metron 1, 1–32. Fleming, M. J. (2003). Measuring Treasury Market Liquidity. Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Forbes, K. J. and R. Rigobon (2002). No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market Comovements. The Journal of Finance 57(5), 2223–2261. Friedman, M. (1937). The Use of Ranks to Avoid the Assumption of Normality Implicit in the Analysis of Variance. Journal of the American Statistical Association 32(200), 675–701. Froot, K. A. and P. G. J. O’Connell (1999). The Pricing of U.S. Catastrophe Reinsurance. The Financing of Catastrophe Risk, 195–232. Giesecke, K. (2004). Correlated Default with Incomplete Information. Journal of Banking and Finance 28(7), 1521–1545. Giesecke, K. and S. Weber (2004). Cyclical Correlations, Credit Contagion, and Portfolio Losses. Journal of Banking and Finance 28(12), 3009–3036. 35 Goetzmann, W., L. Li, and K. G. Rouwenhorst (2005). Long-Term Global Market Correlations. The Journal of Business 78(1), 1–38. Huang, R. D. and H. R. Stoll (1997). The Components of the Bid-Ask Spread: A General Approach. Review of Financial Studies 10(4), 995–1034. Jarrow, R. A., D. Lando, and F. Yu (2005). Default Risk and Diversification: Theory and Applications. Mathematical Finance 15(1), 1 – 26. Jorion, P. and G. Zhang (2007). Good and Bad Credit Contagion: Evidence From C`redit Default Swaps. Journal of Financial Economics 84(3), 860–883. Jorion, P. and G. Zhang (2009). Credit Contagion From Counterparty Risk. The Journal of Finance 64(5), 2053–2087. Kallberg, J. and P. Pasquariello (2008). Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Excess Comovement in Stock Indexes. Journal of Empirical Finance 15(3), 481–502. Kashyap, A. K., R. G. Rajan, and J. C. Stein (2009). Rethinking capital regulation in federal reserve bank of kansas city symposium. Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System, 431– 471. Working paper. Kealhofer, S. (2003). Quantifying Credit Risk I: Default Prediction. Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 59, No. 1, January/February 2003 59, 30–44. Kim, D. H., M. Loretan, and E. M. Remolona (2009). Contagion and Risk Premia in the Amplification of Crisis: Evidence From Asian Names in the Global CDS Market. Journal of Asian Economics In Press, Corrected Proof. Litterman, Robert, and J. Scheinkman. (1991). Common factors affecting bond returns. Journal of Fixed Income 1, (1): 54-61. Liu, J., F. A. Longstaff, and R. E. Mandell (2006). The Market Price of Risk in Interest Rate Swaps: the Roles of Default and Liquidity Risks. Journal of Business 79,(5), 2337–2359. Longstaff, F. A. (2008). The Subprime Credit Crisis and Contagion in Financial Markets. Working Paper, UCLA. Working paper. Longstaff, F. A., S. Mithal, and E. Neis (2005). Corporate Yield Spreads: Default Risk or Liquidity? New Evidence From the Credit Default Swap Market. The Journal of Finance 60(5), 2213– 2253. Longstaff, F. A., J. Pan, L. H. Pedersen, and K. J. Singleton (2007). How Sovereign Is Sovereign Credit Risk? SSRN eLibrary. Working Paper Series. Longstaff, F. A. and E. S. Schwartz (1995). A Simple Approach to Valuing Risky Fixed and Floating Rate Debt. The Journal of Finance 50(6-8), 789–819. Merton, R. C. (1974). On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates. The Journal of Finance 29(2), 449-470 Morck, R., B. Yeung, and W. Yu (2000). The Information Content of Stock Markets: Why Do Emerging Markets Have Synchronous Stock Price Movements? Journal of Financial Economics 58(1-2), 215–260. Neudecker, H. and A. Wesselman (1990). The Asymptotic Covariance of Sample Correlation Matrix. Linear Algebra and its Applications 127, 589–99. O’Kane, D., C. M. Pedersen, and S. M. Turnbull (2003). The Restructuring Clause in Credit Default Swap Contracts. Lehman Brothers. Pastor, L. and R. F. Stambaugh (2003). Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns. The Journal of Political Economy 111(3), 642–685. Pu, Xiaoling. (2009). Liquidity commonality across the bond and CDS markets. Journal of Fixed Income 19, (1): 26-39. Rigobon, R. (2003). Contagion: How to Measure It? Working Paper 8118, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Schuermann, T. (2004). What Do We Know About Loss Given Default? Working paper, Federal 36 Reserve Bank of New York. Stoll, H. R. (1989). Inferring the Components of the Bid-Ask Spread: Theory and Empirical Tests. The Journal of Finance 44(1), 115–134. Subrahmanyam, M. G., A. J. Nashikkar, and S. Mahanti. (2009). Limited arbitrage and liquidity in the market for credit risk. SSRN eLibrary Tang, D. Y. and H. Yan (2008). Liquidity and Credit Default Swap Spreads. Working paper, SSRN eLibrary. Vassalou, M. and Y. Xing (2004). Default Risk in Equity Returns. The Journal of Finance 59(2), 831–868. Zhou, C. (2001). An Analysis of Default Correlations and Multiple Defaults. The Review of Financial Studies 14(2), 555–576. 37 Appendix A Firm-by-Firm Excess Correlation Testing for excess correlation proceeds in two steps, first I control for changes in credit risk using firm-level OLS estimations of the factor model. Independent variables include firm specific equity returns and equity volatility (when equity data is available). Systematic and industry variables are defined in Table III (firm-level factor models do not include industry equity volatility). For robustness, I estimate three additional models. The time varying model allows for time variation in factor exposures.52 The Acharya and Johnson (2007) (A&J) model controls for the non-linear relation between equity returns and CDS returns [see Acharya and Johnson (2007)],53 The time varying Acharya and Johnson model allows for time varying parameters in the A&J model. This produces 150 series of regression residuals for each model. After controlling for credit risk I implement three tests for an increase in excess correlation. The first is a principal component analysis of the model residuals, which is similar to that of Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001). In this analysis, a decrease in the number of principal components required to explain a certain level of common variation indicates an increase in comovement [see Kaminsky et al. (2002)]. Additionally, I include tests of average Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlations, which are identical to those carried out on raw CDS spread changes. The results of these tests are reported in Table A1. Panel A shows the factor exposures of the average firm; the percent of firms for which the factor is significant at the 10% level is reported in square brackets. Panel B shows that the number of principal components required to explain 37% of the common variation in residuals, for the base model, decreased from twelve prior to the crisis to one during the crisis. This result is consistent across all model specifications. Furthermore, the average Pearson’s and Spearman’s correlations increased significantly during the crisis for all model residuals and within each industry. These results support the argument that correlations increased due to the heightened influence of a common non-credit component. 52 This is achieved, using OLS, by estimating interaction terms for each factor along with a constant dummy variable for sixty day intervals, which is the same as running OLS on 60 day windows throughout the sample period. The 60 day window is arbitrary and reduces the precision of OLS estimates. Therefore, I also use 90 and 120 day windows, which do not change the results. 53 Acharya et al. (2007) exploit the approximate linear elasticity between CDS returns and equity returns to capture the non- linear relation implied by Merton (1974). Their model relates CDS returns, which are different from spread changes, to stock returns. However, CDS returns, as defined by Longstaff, Pan, Pedersen and Singleton (2007), on average have a correlation of -.94 with spread changes. 38 Table A1 Equation – by – equation excess correlation: This table reports the results from the firm-by-firm analysis of excess correlation. In the fundamental model, shown below, β i is a vector of coefficients on economic variables for firm i and γ i is a vector of marginal changes during the crisis, Dcrisis is an indicator variable equal to one during the crisis. Finally, F is the vector of economic factors listed in Table III with the addition of firm specific equity returns (FRET) and equity GARCH volatility (FVOL) for each firm with available equity prices. Ri = β i F + γ i FDcrisis + ε i The average regression coefficients from the equation-by-equation OLS estimation are reported in Panel A. The column labeled β contains the average regression coefficient for each fundamental variable and the panel labeled γ contains the average marginal change during the crisis. In square braces is the percent of times the variable is significant at the 10% level, significance is determined using the Huber/White/sandwich robust variance estimator. Market variables ∆VIX, HML SMB and HB are orthogonalized to the S&P 500 returns. Panel B reports the cumulative explained variation for components 1 through 4 and 12 of the principal components analysis of OLS residuals. Columns 1 and 2 show the pre-crisis and crisis principal components for the base model, time varying factor exposure model, the Acharya and Johnson Model and the time varying Acharya and Johnson Model. Panel C shows the results of the test for a change in the average correlations (Pearson’s and Spearman’s) of OLS residuals from each of the four different models. The first column gives the number of firms in each group. Column two reports the average difference in Pearson’s correlation from the pre-crisis to the crisis period. The tstatistic is for a paired two sample t-test of Fisher transformed correlation coefficients, the z-statistic is calculated from the asymptotic variance of the difference in transformed correlations (assuming independence). Columns five and six report results of the test for a change in average Spearman’s Rho. Significance of the change is assessed using an F-test based on the ratio of Friedman (1937) statistics in the pre-crisis and crisis periods. Correlations are tested using one sided tests for an increase. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10% 5% and 1% levels respectively. Panel A: Firm Regression Coefficient Summary β -0.24 SP500 0.00 ∆VIX -0.03 ∆RF3M -0.01 ∆SLOPE -1.19 HB 0.07 ∆DEF 0.04 SMB -0.26 HML -0.07 FVOL 0.00 FRET 0.01 INDRET 0.19 R Squared Panel B: Principal Components Base Model Pre-Crisis Crisis Component 1 0.19 0.37 Component 2 0.22 0.41 Component 3 0.24 0.43 Component 4 0.26 0.45 Component 12 0.37 0.58 γ [0.44] [0.27] [0.18] [0.30] [0.14] [0.49] [0.11] [0.31] [0.19] [0.19] [0.15] -0.86 -0.04 0.01 0.10 0.78 0.17 0.17 0.39 -4.36 -0.18 -0.08 [0.27] [0.43] [0.19] [0.09] [0.07] [0.22] [0.03] [0.20] [0.17] [0.25] [0.11] Time Varying Pre-Crisis Crisis 0.18 0.36 0.21 0.40 0.23 0.42 0.25 0.44 A&J Pre-Crisis Crisis 0.20 0.37 0.23 0.40 0.25 0.43 0.27 0.45 Time Varying AJ Pre-Crisis Crisis 0.15 0.33 0.18 0.37 0.20 0.39 0.22 0.41 0.37 0.57 0.38 0.57 0.34 0.53 39 Time Varying AJ A&J Time Varying Base Model Panel C: Excess Correlation Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials N 150 36 43 20 7 18 26 150 36 43 20 7 18 26 150 36 43 20 7 18 26 150 36 43 20 7 18 26 pre 0.17 0.18 0.19 0.21 0.13 0.27 0.18 0.17 0.17 0.18 0.19 0.12 0.26 0.16 0.17 0.19 0.20 0.22 0.13 0.28 0.19 0.17 0.15 0.15 0.18 0.12 0.22 0.10 Pearson’s Correlation crisis Diff t-stat 0.36 0.18*** 154.81 0.40 0.22*** 42.54 0.37 0.19*** 47.15 0.44 0.23*** 23.45 0.42 0.29*** 17.57 0.44 0.17*** 10.24 0.31 0.13** 16.46 0.36 0.18*** 154.81 0.40 0.22*** 44.17 0.37 0.19*** 47.77 0.44 0.25*** 26.64 0.38 0.26*** 15.88 0.44 0.18*** 11.94 0.31 0.15*** 17.24 0.36 0.18*** 154.81 0.41 0.22*** 45.15 0.37 0.17*** 43.10 0.44 0.21*** 20.92 0.41 0.28*** 20.17 0.43 0.15*** 10.06 0.30 0.11** 14.40 0.36 0.18*** 154.81 0.37 0.22*** 47.12 0.34 0.18*** 49.73 0.40 0.23*** 25.62 0.35 0.23*** 13.86 0.39 0.17*** 13.70 0.26 0.16*** 23.48 z stat 3.02 3.67 3.16 3.98 4.72 2.79 2.18 3.02 3.72 3.16 4.20 4.17 2.97 2.51 3.02 3.74 2.89 3.69 4.67 2.47 1.87 3.02 3.61 3.01 3.78 3.67 2.73 2.53 pre 0.16 0.18 0.18 0.21 0.11 0.26 0.16 0.16 0.15 0.16 0.18 0.10 0.24 0.13 0.16 0.17 0.17 0.21 0.11 0.25 0.15 0.16 0.13 0.14 0.16 0.08 0.20 0.10 Spearman’s Rho crisis Ratio 0.37 1.70*** 0.41 1.65*** 0.40 1.60*** 0.43 1.42*** 0.41 1.59*** 0.43 1.20** 0.33 1.46*** 0.37 1.70*** 0.38 1.70*** 0.38 1.72*** 0.40 1.49*** 0.36 1.50*** 0.41 1.21** 0.31 1.58*** 0.37 1.70*** 0.41 1.71*** 0.38 1.57*** 0.41 1.37*** 0.40 1.61*** 0.42 1.21** 0.31 1.37*** 0.37 1.70*** 0.34 1.74*** 0.32 1.64*** 0.34 1.44*** 0.33 1.53*** 0.36 1.26*** 0.26 1.61*** p-val 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 40 Appendix B List of Events: This table shows a list of significant distress and recovery events that occurred during the crisis. The event number is listed in the left most column, the date it occurred is in column two. Column three contains the type of event, which is defined as follows: D = distress event, F = action by the Federal Reserve, R = the rescue of a distressed company or companies, P = a government implemented policy to aid the economy, CI = a capital infusion where the government purchased stock via the Capital Purchase Program. Panel B lists interest rate reduction events (IR) and Panel C lists dates that are omitted due to two or more confounding events that took place on a single day. Finally, Swap identifies days when swap lines with other countries were established or increased. I also classify the events into three categories by the severity of the event. These classifications, 1-3, are reported in the column labeled Severity. In determining severity of an event both the timing and significance of the event are taken into account. For example Capital Infusions during the most severe part of the crisis (Sept. 2008 to Dec. 2008) are classified as 2; after Dec. they are classified as 1. Date Type Severity Event 1 7/31/2007 D 2 2 3 8/6/2007 8/9/2007 D D 2 1 4 8/16/2007 D 1 5 1/11/2008 D 2 6 1/18/2008 D 1 7 8 9 10 11 2/17/2008 3/5/2008 3/14/2008 6/5/2008 7/11/2008 D D D D D 2 1 3 1 2 12 7/15/2008 D 1 13 9/7/2008 D 2 14 9/15/2008 D 3 15 16 9/25/2008 10/24/2008 D D 3 2 17 11/17/2008 D 1 18 1/13/2009 D 1 19 8/10/2007 F 1 Distress Events Bear Stearns Liquidates two hedge funds that specialize in subprime securitizations. American Home Mortgage announces inability to fund lending obligations American Home Mortgage Investment Corporation files for bankruptcy. BNP Paribas halts redemptions on three investment funds. Fitch Ratings downgrades Countrywide Financial Corporation to BBB+. Countrywide borrows the entire $11.5 billion available in its credit lines with other banks. Bank of America announces that it will purchase Countrywide Financial for approximately $4 billion. Fitch Ratings downgrades Ambac Financial Group’s insurance financial strength rating to AA, Credit Watch Negative. Standard and Poor’s place Ambac’s AAA rating on CreditWatch Negative. Northern Rock is taken over by the Treasury of the United Kingdom. Carlyle Capital Corporation begins receiving default notices after failing to meet margin calls on mortgage securities. JPMorgan Chase announces the purchase of Bear Stearns Standard and Poor’s downgrades monoline bond insurers AMBAC and MBIA from AAA to AA. The Office of Thrift Supervision closes IndyMac Bank The Securities Exchange Commission (SEC) temporarily prohibits naked short selling in the securities of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and primary dealers at commercial and investment banks. The Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) places Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in government conservatorship. The U.S. Treasury Department announces three additional measures to provide additional support to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Lehman Brothers Holdings Incorporated files for bankruptcy. Bank of America announces its intent to purchase Merrill Lynch & Co. for $50 billion. The Office of Thrift Supervision closes Washington Mutual Bank and JPMorgan Chase acquires its banking operations. PNC Financial Services Group Inc. purchases National City Corporation Three large U.S. life insurance companies seek TARP funding: Lincoln National, Hartford Financial Services Group, and Genworth Financial. The Federal Home Loan Bank of Seattle reports a risk-based capital deficiency and suspend its dividend because of a decline in the market value of its mortgage-backed securities portfolio. Royal Bank of Scotland forced to reveal that it had leant 3.47 billion dollars to bankrupt Lyondell Chemical Recovery Events The Federal Reserve Board announces that it “will provide reserves as necessary…to promote trading in the federal funds market at rates 41 20 21 9/14/2007 10/15/2007 R R 2 2 22 12/12/2007 F 2 23 2/13/2008 P 2 24 3/7/2008 F 1 25 3/11/2008 F 2 26 3/16/2008 F 3 27 5/2/2008 F 1 28 7/13/2008 F 1 29 7/30/2008 F/P 1 30 31 9/14/2008 9/16/2008 F R 1 3 32 9/19/2008 F 2 33 10/3/2008 P 3 34 10/7/2008 F 2 35 10/8/2008 R 1 36 10/14/2008 F/P 1 37 10/21/2008 F 2 38 10/28/2008 CI 2 close to the FOMC’s target rate of 5.25 percent.” The Chancellor of the Exchequer authorizes the Bank of England to provide liquidity support for Northern Rock. Citigroup, Bank of America, and JPMorgan Chase announce plans for an $80 billion Master Liquidity Enhancement Conduit. The Federal Reserve Board announces the creation of the Term Auction Facility (TAF) in which fixed amounts of term funds will be auctioned to depository institutions. The FOMC authorizes temporary swap lines with the European Central Bank (ECB) and the Swiss National Bank (SNB). President Bush signs the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 (Public Law 110-185) into law. The Federal Reserve Board announces $50 billion TAF auctions on March 10 and March 24 and extends TAF for at least 6 months. The Board also initiates a series of term repurchase transactions, expected to cumulate to $100 billion, conducted as 28-day term repurchase agreements with primary dealers. The Federal Reserve Board announces the creation of the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF). The FOMC increases its swap lines with the ECB by $10 billion and the Swiss National Bank by $2 billion. The Federal Reserve Board establishes the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF), which extends credit to primary dealers at the primary credit rate (against investment grade securities). The Federal Reserve Board reduces the primary credit rate 25 basis points to 3.25 percent. The FOMC expands the list of eligible collateral for Schedule 2 TSLF auctions. The FOMC also increases existing swap lines with the ECB and with the Swiss National Bank by $6 billion. The Federal Reserve Board expands TAF auctions from $50 billion to $75 billion. The Federal Reserve Board authorizes the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lend to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, should such lending prove necessary. The U.S. Treasury Department announces a temporary increase in the credit lines of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and a temporary authorization for the Treasury to purchase equity in either GSE if needed. The Federal Reserve Board extends the TSLF and PDCF. It also introduces auctions of options on $50 billion of draws on the TSLF, and introduces 84-day TAF loans. The FOMC increases its swap line with the ECB to $55 billion. President Bush signs into law the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 (Public Law 110-289). The Federal Reserve Board expands the list of eligible collateral for the PDCF and TSLF. The NY Fed is authorized to lend up to $85 billion to American International Group (AIG). The Federal Reserve Board announces the creation of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF) facilitating the purchase of high-quality asset-backed commercial paper from money market mutual funds. The Federal Reserve Board also announces plans to purchase federal agency discount notes from primary dealers. The U.S. Treasury Department makes $50 billion available, which will guarantee investments in participating money market mutual funds. Congress passes and President Bush signs into law the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 (Public Law 110-343), which establishes the $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP). The Federal Reserve Board announces the creation of the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF) providing liquidity backstops to U.S. issuers of commercial paper. The FDIC announces an increase in deposit insurance coverage to $250,000 per depositor. NY Fed is authorized to borrow up to $37.8 billion in investment-grade, fixed-income securities from American International Group (AIG) in return for cash collateral. The FOMC increases its swap line with the Bank of Japan. The FDIC creates a new Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program to guarantee the senior debt of all FDIC-insured institutions and their holding companies, as well as deposits in non-interest-bearing deposit transactions through June 30, 2009. U.S. Treasury Department announces that TARP funds will be used to purchase equity in financial institutions under the authority of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008. The Federal Reserve Board announces creation of the Money Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF). The facility provides senior secured funding to special purpose vehicles for the purchase of U.S. dollar-denominated certificates of deposit and commercial paper, issued by highly rated financial institutions, with a maturity of 90 days or less. The U.S. Treasury Department purchases $125 billion in preferred stock in nine U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program). The FOMC and 42 Reserve Bank of New Zealand establish a $15 billion swap line. Federal Reserve adds $21 billion to loans for AIG Restructuring of AIG financial support. Treasury purchased 40 billion in AIG preferred stock under TARP. AIG will use 25 billion to 40 11/10/2008 CI 1 pay down Federal Reserve Board Loans leaving $15 billion in new support to AIG. Also NY Fed establishes new lending facility with AIG 41 11/14/2008 CI 2 Treasury purchase $33.5 billion in preferred stock of 21 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) 42 11/21/2008 CI 2 Treasury purchase $3 billion in preferred stock of 23 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) The U.S. Treasury Department, Federal Reserve Board, and FDIC jointly announce an agreement provide Citigroup with protection 43 11/23/2008 R 1 against losses on commercial residential securities. In exchange Citigroup will issue preferred shares to the Treasury and FDIC. The Federal Reserve Board announces the creation of the Term Asset-Backed Securities Lending Facility (TALF). The Federal Reserve 44 11/25/2008 F 2 Board announces a new program to purchase direct obligations of GSEs — Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and Federal Home Loan Banks. Up to $100 billion in GSE direct obligations and $500 billion in MBS. 45 12/2/2008 F 2 The Federal Reserve Board announces that it will extend three liquidity facilities, PDCF, AMLF, TSLF through April 30, 2009. 46 12/5/2008 CI 2 Treasury purchase $4 billion in preferred stock of 35 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) Treasury purchase $27.9 billion in preferred stock of 49 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) The U.S. Treasury Department 47 12/19/2008 CI 2 authorizes loans of up to $13.4 billion for General Motors and $4.0 billion for Chrysler from the TARP. 48 12/23/2008 CI 2 Treasury purchase $15.1 billion in preferred stock of 43 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) The U.S. Treasury Department announces that it will purchase $5 billion in equity from GMAC and agrees to lend up to $1 billion to 49 12/29/2008 R 2 GM. 50 12/31/2008 CI 2 Treasury purchase $1.91 billion in preferred stock of 7 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) 51 1/9/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $4.8 billion in preferred stock of 43 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) Treasury purchase $1.4 billion in preferred stock of 39 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program). The U.S. Treasury Department, Federal 52 1/16/2009 CI 1 Reserve, and FDIC announce a support package for Bank of America including a loss-sharing arrangement ($118 billion), in exchange for preferred stock. The U.S. Treasury Department announces that it will lend $1.5 billion from the TARP to Chrysler Financial. 53 1/23/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $326 million in preferred stock of 23 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) The National Credit Union Administration (NCUA) Board announces that the NCUA will guarantee uninsured shares at all corporate 54 1/28/2009 CI 1 credit. The Board also approves a $1 billion capital purchase in U.S. Central Corporate Federal Credit Unions. 55 1/30/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $1.15 billion in preferred stock of 23 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) 56 2/3/2009 F 1 The Federal Reserve announces the extension of existing liquidity programs. 57 2/6/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $238.5 million in preferred stock of 28 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) The Federal Reserve Board announces that it is prepared to expand the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF). U.S. 58 2/10/2009 F 1 Treasury announces a Financial Stability Plan involving purchases of preferred stock in eligible banks. Expansion of the Federal Reserve’s TALF. 59 2/13/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $429 million in preferred stock of 29 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) Treasury purchase $365.4 million in preferred stock of 23 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) 60 2/24/2009 CI 1 President Obama signs into law the "American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009", which includes a variety of spending measures 61 2/17/2009 P 1 and tax cuts intended to promote economic recovery. Treasury purchase $394.9 million in preferred stock of 28 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) 62 2/27/2009 CI 1 The U.S. Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve Board announce the launch of the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility 63 3/3/2009 F 1 (TALF). 64 3/6/2009 CI 1 Treasury purchase $284.7 million in preferred stock of 22 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) Panel B: Interest Rate Reductions and Swap Agreements 39 10/30/2008 R 1 43 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 8/17/2007 9/18/2007 10/31/2007 12/11/2007 1/22/2008 1/30/2008 3/18/2008 4/30/2008 10/8/2008 IR IR IR IR IR IR IR IR IR 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 73 12/16/2008 IR 1 73 9/18/2008 Swap 1 74 9/24/2008 Swap 1 75 9/26/2008 Swap 1 76 10/13/2008 Swap 1 77 10/29/2008 Swap 1 Panel C: Multiple Event Dates 78 12/21/2007 D 79 12/21/2007 F 80 9/17/2008 D 81 9/17/2008 P 82 9/29/2008 F 83 9/29/2008 D 84 85 12/12/2008 12/12/2008 CI D The Federal Reserve Board reduces the primary credit rate 50 basis points to 5.75 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 50 basis points to 4.75 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate50 basis points to 5.25 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 25 basis points to 4.50 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate25 basis points to 5.00 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 25 basis points to 4.25 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate25 basis points to 4.75 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 75 basis points to 3.5 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate75 basis points to 4 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 50 basis points to 3 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate50 basis points to 3.5 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 75 basis points to 2.25 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate75 basis points to 2.50 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 25 basis points to 2 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate25 basis points to 2.25 percent. FMOC reduces target federal funds rate 50 basis points to 1.50 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate50 basis points to 1.75 percent. The FOMC votes to establish a target range for the effective federal funds rate of 0 to 0.25 percent. Fed reduces primary credit rate75 basis points to 0.50 percent. The FOMC expands existing swap lines by $180 billion and authorizes new swap lines with the Bank of Japan, Bank of England, and Bank of Canada. The FOMC establishes new swap lines with the Reserve Bank of Australia, the Sveriges Riksbank, the Danmarks National bank and the Norges Bank. The FOMC increases existing swap lines with the ECB by $10 billion and the Swiss National Bank by $3 billion. The FOMC increases existing swap lines with foreign central banks. The Bank of England, European Central Bank, and Swiss National Bank announce that they will conduct tenders of U.S. dollar funding at 7-, 28-, and 84-day maturities at fixed interest rates. The FOMC also establishes swap lines with the Banco Central do Brasil, Banco de Mexico, Bank of Korea and the Monetary Authority of Singapore for up to $30 billion. The FOMC reduces its target for the federal funds rate 50 basis points to 1.00 percent. The Federal Reserve Board reduces the primary credit rate 50 basis points to 1.25 percent. Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, and Bank of America abandon plans for the Master Liquidity Enhancement Conduit. The Federal Reserve Board announces that TAF auctions will be conducted every two weeks as long as financial market conditions warrant. The SEC bans short selling of stock for all companies in the financial sector. The U.S. Treasury Department announces a Supplementary Financing Program consisting of a series of Treasury bill issues that will provide cash for use in Federal Reserve initiatives. The FOMC authorizes a $330 billion expansion of swap lines with Bank of Canada, Bank of England, Bank of Japan, Danmarks Nationalbank, ECB, Norges Bank, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sveriges Riksbank, and Swiss National Bank. The Federal Reserve Board expands the TAF. The FDIC announces that Citigroup will purchase the banking operations of Wachovia Corporation. The FDIC agrees to a loss-sharing arrangement with Citigroup. In return, Citigroup would grant the FDIC $12 billion in preferred stock and warrants. The U.S. House of Representatives rejects legislation submitted by the Treasury Department requesting authority to purchase troubled assets from financial institutions. Treasury purchase $6.25 billion in preferred stock of 28 U.S. banks (Capital Purchase Program) Bernard Madoff arrested for over alleged Ponzi scheme 44 The Average CDS spread is an equally weighted average over all 150 firms in the sample. To get the average correlation for a particular day, I calculate pairwise correlations for each of the 11,175 possible firm pairs using 60 days of trailing data. I then take an equ equally ally weighted average over all pairwise correlations. This calculation is rolled daily ily to obtain the correlations graphed above. 45 Figure 2 Average CDS Spread & Sample Per Periods The graph shows the daily equally weighted average CDS spread for all 150 firms between July 5, 2005 and March 9, 2009. Numbers on the graph represent significant events that occurred during the crisis aand correspond to event numbers in Appendix A.. The time period between the two vertical bars (labeled crisis period) defines the crisis period. To the left of the left-most vertical bar is the pre-crisis crisis period. 46 Figure 3 S&P Long Term Issuer Ratings Over Time Industry groups are defined using the Fama and French 5 industry classifications with the sixth industry, Financials, extract extracted from Other. Each industry CDS spread represents the CDS premium on an equally weighted portfolio of contracts. 47 Figure 4 Sample Characteristics Box plots show the distributions of firms’ characteristics through time (2005-2008) for the sample of the full sample of firms used in this study against the CRSP/Compustat universe. Book Leverage = ((AT - (AT – LT – PSTLK + TXDITC + DCVT))/AT), Profitability = NI/AT, Market–To– Book = (CSHO*PRCC_F + AT - (AT – LT – PSTLK + TXDITC + DCVT))/AT, Cash = CH, Total Assets = AT, and Market Capitalization = CSHO * PRCC_F. The book leverage and book value of equity are calculated as in Baker and Wurgler (2002).The Box plots omit outliers. 48 Figure 5 S&P Long Term Issuer Ratings Over Time The graph above shows the number of firms in the sample with S& S&P long-term term issuer ratings in a given category by year from 2005 to 2009. The investment grade threshold for S&P ratings is BBB BBB- and several firms in the CDX.NA.IG fall below that. This is because the long term issuer rating is an aggregate measure of the firm’s ability to meet all debt obligations. In contrast, the CDX.NA.IG index is constructed using investment grade bonds. Monthly S&P long term issuer ratings are obtained from Compustat and yearly ratings are constructed using the rating on the first ava available month of the year. 49 Figure 6 Pairwise Correlations of CDS Spread Changes Pairwise correlations for all 11,175 possible firm pairs are calculated prior to and during the crisis and are shown above. In red is the cross-sectional density of pairwise correlation during the crisis and in blue is the crosssectional density of pairwise correlation prior to the crisis. 50 Table I Descriptive statistics for the sample of CDS spread changes prior to and during the crisis are reported below. The pre-crisis period begins on July 5, 2005 and ends on July 30 2007; the crisis period begins on July 31, 2007 and ends on March 9, 2009. Each panel describes the changes in raw CDS premiums for seven equally weighted portfolios of CDS contracts. The Full Sample portfolio is constructed using daily premiums for all CDS contracts in the sample. Similarly, industry portfolios are constructed using daily spreads for industry groups defined using the Fama and French five industry portfolio classifications. The sixth industry, Financials, is extracted from the Other industry classification, which yields the following industry groups. Consumer: Consumer Durables and Non-Durables, Wholesale, Retail, and Laundry and Repair shop services. Manufacturing: Manufacturing, Energy and Utilities. HiTech: Business Equipment and Telephone & Television Transmission. Other: Mining, Construction, Building Materials, Transportation, Hotels, Business Services, and Entertainment. In Panel A, the first two columns give portfolio labels and the number of firms in each portfolio. Columns labeled Pre-Crisis report statistics calculated prior to the crisis and columns labeled Crisis report statistics calculated during the crisis. Statistics include the mean, standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis of CDS spread changes. The difference in the average spread change and standard deviations are reported in columns labeled Diff and Ratio respectively. The column labeled Ratio reports the ratio of the variance in spread changes during the crisis to that prior to the crisis. Panel B shows the average Pearson’s correlations for the full sample and within each industry over different sub periods. Column one reports the average correlations over the full sample period. Columns two and three give correlations for the pre-crisis and crisis periods respectively. The remaining columns show the average correlation calculated on half year intervals where H1 and H2 indicate the first and second half of each year. Significance of correlation coefficients is assessed using a standard t-test. Panel C reports results for the tests of autocorrelation using the standard Ljung Box test with five lags. Bold statistics represent significance at the 5% level. Panel A: Descriptive Statistics Mean Spread Changes Standard Deviations Skewness Excess Kurtosis Pre-Crisis Crisis Diff Pre-Crisis Crisis Ratio Pre-Crisis Crisis Pre-Crisis Crisis Full Sample 150 0.05% 0.01 0.08 4.45 0.39 40.95 4.79 1.07% 1.02% 146.08 Consumer 36 0.02% 0.01 0.09 3.09 -0.07 21.46 5.47 1.00% 0.98% 153.13 Manufacturing 43 0.01% 0.01 0.06 3.34 0.78 25.88 4.62 0.88% 0.86% 113.54 HiTech 20 0.07% 0.01 0.07 3.14 0.17 20.73 5.09 0.69% 0.62% 57.96 Health 7 0.11% 0.04% 0.01 0.03 5.91 0.01 62.13 2.53 0.07% 13.95 Other 18 0.56% 0.45% 0.01 0.07 3.81 0.04 32.38 2.37 0.11% 31.64 Financials 26 0.01 0.22 4.51 0.32 42.36 10.09 0.07% 2.38% 2.30% 763.98 Panel B: Pre-Crisis and Crisis Correlations N Full Period Pre-Crisis Crisis 2005 H2 2006 H1 2006 H2 2007 H1 2007 H2 2008 H1 2008 H2 2009 H1 Full Sample 150 0.22 0.16 0.22 0.12 0.20 0.41 0.43 0.41 0.52 0.47 0.42 Consumer 36 0.20 0.14 0.22 0.11 0.21 0.47 0.50 0.45 0.53 0.56 0.44 Manufacturing 43 0.22 0.23 0.14 0.21 0.42 0.24 0.43 0.45 0.58 0.46 0.44 HiTech 20 0.27 0.20 0.27 0.15 0.26 0.47 0.51 0.49 0.52 0.53 0.55 Health 7 0.13 0.04 0.09 0.07 0.13 0.33 0.40 0.41 0.44 0.53 0.54 Other 18 0.32 0.28 0.32 0.22 0.31 0.52 0.54 0.51 0.59 0.58 0.58 Financials 26 0.26 0.20 0.22 0.12 0.21 0.34 0.36 0.37 0.37 0.47 0.43 Panel C: Autocorrelation Pre-Crisis Crisis Full Full Sample Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Financials Sample Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Financials Ljung-Box Test (1-5) 205.88 122.26 158.33 114.80 159.55 148.37 246.39 37.49 36.40 72.54 52.18 37.84 60.81 11.34 p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 N 51 Table II Changes in comovement are reported below. The table shows three measures of aggregate comovement in CDS spread changes prior to and during the crisis. It also includes the results of tests for an increase in each of these measures. Spread changes have all been filtered for autocorrelation. The pre-crisis and crisis periods are defined in Table I. Industries are the Fama and French five industry classifications with the sixth industry, Financials, extracted from Other; category details are given in Table I. In each panel the column labeled Pre-Crisis shows the aggregate association statistic calculated prior to the crisis and the column labeled Crisis shows the aggregate association statistic during the crisis. Aggregate association statistics include the average pairwise Pearson’s correlation, the average pairwise Spearman’s correlations and the average fraction of firms that move together each week reported in panels A,B and C respectively. Panel A: the t-statistic for a two sample paired t-test of Fisher transformed Pearson’s correlations (z = ½ ln[(1+ρ)/ (1-ρ)]) is reported in the column labeled t-statistic. The column labeled z-statistic reports the z-statistic for the paired two sample test based on the asymptotic distribution implied by the Fisher transformation. Panel B: The average change in Rho is tested using the ratio of Friedman statistics (FR = (T-1)[(N-1) ρ +1]) ~ χ2(T-1)), which are shown in column labeled Ratio. P-values for these ratios, taken from the F distribution, are reported in column labeled P-Value. Panel C The fraction of firms that move together each week is calculated from Morck et al. (2000) up t Their proposed asymptotic variance ( f t (1 − f t ) /(n down t +n ( ) f t = max ntup , ntdown ntup + ntdown . ) ) is used to assess the statistical significance of the increase in this fraction (assuming independence over time). The change in this fraction is reported in the column labeled Difference and the associated p-values for the change are reported in the column labeled P-Value. All tests are one sided for an increase in comovement. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10% 5% and 1% levels respectively. Panel A: Average Pearson’s Correlation Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Pre-Crisis 0.20 0.21 0.22 0.24 0.14 0.30 0.21 Crisis 0.44 0.50 0.45 0.51 0.46 0.54 0.40 Diff 0.24*** 0.29*** 0.23*** 0.27*** 0.32*** 0.23*** 0.19*** t-statistic 194.75 56.64 53.04 27.39 22.87 14.60 22.33 z-statistic 4.16 5.20 4.07 4.90 5.42 4.12 3.32 Panel B: Average Spearman Correlation Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Pre-Crisis 0.18 0.19 0.19 0.22 0.12 0.27 0.16 Crisis 0.46 0.51 0.47 0.50 0.47 0.54 0.43 Ratio 1.96*** 1.88*** 1.77*** 1.56*** 1.72*** 1.40*** 1.80*** P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Difference 0.10*** 0.11*** 0.11*** 0.08*** 0.08*** 0.08*** 0.07*** P-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Panel C: Fraction of Common Co-movement Full Sample Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Pre-Crisis 0.73 0.73 0.74 0.76 0.76 0.77 0.75 Crisis 0.83 0.85 0.85 0.84 0.83 0.85 0.82 52 Table III Variable Definitions for the fundamental model are shown below. The specification is based on Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001) who base their intuition on Merton (1974). The upper panel labeled Default Probabilities lists variables that are included to capture changes in default probabilities. The lower panel labeled Loss Given Default lists systematic variables, which capture changes in loss given default. The column labeled “Source” gives the data source which are: The Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), The Federal Reserve (FED), and The Chicago Board of Exchange (CBOE). Name Variable Description Default Probabilities INDRET The equally weighted industry equity return. It proxies for leverage or the overall financial health of firms in the industry Source Ex-Sign CRSP - INDVOL The GARCH equity return volatility. It measures the aggregate risk of firms in each industry CRSP + RF3M The three-month constant maturity treasury rate (CMT). Measures the risk neutral drift of the firm value process. Increases in the risk free rate decrease default probabilities. FED - SLOPE The spread between the three-month and 5 year CMT rates. The slope of the yield curve contains information about the expected future short rate [Litterman and Scheinkman (1991)], which may affect the short term risk free rate. FED - VIX The S&P 500 option implied volatility. Measures expected future volatility CBOE + SMB & HML Fama and French small cap and value premiums. Vassalou and Xing (2004) argue that they contain default risk information French Data Library + CRSP - Loss Given Default SP500 The daily return on the S&P 500 index. Measures the economic state. Higher returns are associated with good economic states and lower CDS spreads HB Value weighted return index of major U.S. homebuilders (SIC code of 1521). The index excludes homebuilders in the sample. This variable measures variations in the real estate market. Datastream - DEF Yield spread between Baa and Aaa Moody's bond indices. DEF measures the general state of credit markets. FED + 53 Table IV SUR parameter estimates of the fundamental model are reported in this table. The dependant variable in each regression is the daily change in CDS spreads for each of the six industry portfolios (for industry group classifications and sub-period definitions, see the caption in Table I). Independent variables are defined in Table III. Regression estimates of factor exposures, for the pre-crisis period, are reported in the section of the table labeled Pre-Crisis. Their marginal changes, during the crisis period, are reported in the section of the table labeled “Marginal Change in the Crisis”. ∆ indicates that the variable is first differenced; all other variables are percent changes. All variables are corrected for serial correlation and standardized using autoregressive GARCH filters. Changes in volatilities are winsorized at 99%. ∆VIX, HB, SMB, HML, INDRET are all orthogonalized to SP500. Constants were estimated, though not reported, for the pre-crisis and crisis periods. The z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 912 observations for each industry and *,**,*** represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels respectively. Pre-Crisis SP500 ∆RF3M ∆SLOPE ∆VIX HB ∆DEF SMB HML INDRET ∆INDVOL Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Financials -0.21*** (-5.26) 0.01 (0.14) -0.01 (-0.14) 0.05 (0.77) -0.07 (-1.37) 0.14*** (3.49) -0.02 (-0.55) -0.15*** (-3.82) 0.01 (0.27) -0.03 (-1.29) -0.20*** (-5.05) -0.04 (-0.95) -0.05 (-1.25) -0.02 (-0.28) -0.02 (-0.31) 0.12*** (3.12) -0.03 (-0.59) -0.09* (-2.07) 0.00 (0.00) -0.05 (-1.95) -0.14*** (-3.57) -0.06 (-1.49) -0.05 (-1.16) 0.05 (0.80) -0.09 (-1.81) 0.14*** (3.54) -0.01 (-0.14) -0.05 (-1.40) 0.07 (1.38) -0.06* (-2.27) -0.11** (-2.49) 0.05 (1.18) 0.01 (0.13) -0.03 (-0.46) 0.07 (1.24) 0.10** (2.39) 0.02 (0.43) -0.07 (-1.71) -0.10* (-1.97) 0.02 (0.65) -0.36*** (-9.35) -0.05 (-1.26) -0.12*** (-3.11) 0.06 (0.86) -0.24*** (-4.28) 0.08* (2.23) 0.04 (0.98) -0.10*** (-2.66) 0.05 (0.86) 0.00 (0.20) -0.19*** (-4.79) -0.10** (-2.51) -0.07 (-1.75) 0.03 (0.47) -0.10* (-1.98) 0.10*** (2.61) 0.02 (0.46) -0.19*** (-4.82) -0.13* (-2.12) 0.05 (1.59) -0.23*** (-3.40) -0.09 (-1.31) -0.02 (-0.25) 0.18 (1.60) -0.01 (-0.16) -0.05 (-0.79) 0.03 (0.45) 0.12 (1.89) 0.04 (0.41) 0.06 (1.54) 0.1684 -0.32*** (-4.72) -0.11 (-1.64) -0.01 (-0.21) 0.08 (0.74) 0.07 (0.77) -0.07 (-1.17) -0.04 (-0.60) 0.09 (1.43) -0.09 (-1.07) 0.04 (0.90) 0.1781 -0.19*** (-2.67) -0.18** (-2.50) -0.07 (-0.99) 0.19 (1.58) -0.10 (-1.04) -0.12 (-1.88) -0.01 (-0.19) 0.14* (2.05) 0.02 (0.23) -0.04 (-0.89) 0.0913 -0.11 (-1.72) -0.17** (-2.50) -0.01 (-0.11) 0.01 (0.11) 0.20* (2.04) -0.06 (-1.14) -0.01 (-0.15) 0.13* (2.14) -0.32*** (-3.21) 0.04 (1.07) 0.2822 -0.24*** (-3.51) 0.00 (0.05) 0.05 (0.67) 0.10 (0.92) 0.10 (1.18) -0.03 (-0.44) 0.01 (0.10) 0.24*** (3.83) -0.17 (-1.74) -0.05 (-1.03) 0.1974 Marginal change during the crisis SP500 -0.29*** (-4.27) ∆RF3M -0.15* (-2.13) ∆SLOPE -0.05 (-0.69) ∆VIX 0.08 (0.76) HB 0.09 (0.98) ∆DEF -0.06 (-1.01) SMB -0.02 (-0.23) HML 0.14* (2.29) INDRET -0.11 (-1.28) ∆INDVOL 0.03 (0.74) R Squared 0.2084 54 Table V Change in excess correlation: Reported below are estimates of the increase in excess correlation between industry portfolios. After estimating the SUR system shown in Table IV, I extract regression residuals for the pre-crisis and crisis periods (defined din the caption of Table I). Using these residuals, I implement three tests for a change in excess correlation. The first two, test for a change in the correlation matrix and a change in the average pairwise correlation using the χ2 statistics developed by Goetzmann et al. (2005); p-values for these tests are reported in Panel B. In Panel A I report the results of the test for a change in pairwise correlations ρ crisis − ρ pre −crisis the significance of the change is determined using z-scores from the fisher transformation. Outliers are eliminated prior to calculating correlations. *,**,*** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level respectively. Panel A: Pairwise Excess Correlation Difference Matrix Consumer Manuf. HiTech Consumer 0.00 Manufacturing 0.09** 0.00 HiTech 0.17*** 0.21*** 0.00 Health 0.22*** 0.30*** 0.36*** Other 0.12*** 0.18*** 0.15*** Financials 0.08 0.19*** 0.14*** Panel B: Correlation Matrix & Average Correlation Statistic P-Value Matrix Test 0.00 Average Correlation 0. 1963*** 0.00 Health Other Financials 0.00 0.27*** 0.32*** 0.00 0.14*** 0.00 55 Table VI Liquidity contagion parameter estimates are reported below. Panel A shows the estimated liquidity parameters along with their marginal changes during the crisis, which are estimated by adding liquidity proxies back into the fundamental model. The specification below contains all fundamental variables defined in Table III (∆S = βiF+γiFDcrisis), and liquidity proxies (L). ∆S i = β i F + γ i FDcrisis + δ i L + δ ic LDcrisis + ε i Liquidity proxies include the yield spread between the on-the-run and off-the-run five-year treasury note (ONOFF). The spread between the three-month overnight index swap rate and RF3M (OISTB). The average bid-ask spread over all contracts in the sample (BIDASK) and by industry (IBIDASK); the industry bid-ask spreads are orthogonalized to the average bid-ask spread. The difference between the general collateral repo rate and RF3M (ONREPO) and the hedge fund index (HEDGE), which is the equally weighted average of hedge fund style returns. Bond market liquidity proxies include the daily average Amidhud measure (AMIHUD), the average industry principal amount traded each day (VOLUME), and the average number of trades per industry each day (NTRADE). All bond market proxies are constructed using TRACE transaction prices for all firms’ bonds that traded over the sample period. HEDGE is orthogonalized to the S&P 500 return. I re-estimate the marginal changes in liquidity parameters on the month following the collapse of Lehman Brothers (9/15/2008-10/15/2008) these results are reported in the panel labeled Non-Lehman/ Lehman. Panel B reports the results of the tests for an increase in excess correlation. The subpanel labeled “Change in Excess Correlation” shows the results of the tests for a change in the correlation matrix and a change in the average correlation (lower panel); p-values are calculated using the χ2 statistics developed by Goetzmann et al. (2005). ∆ indicates that the variable is first differenced; all other variables are percent changes. All variables are corrected for serial correlation and standardized using autoregressive GARCH filters. The upper half of the panel shows the increase in correlation between industry pairs; significance is assessed using Fisher transformed correlations. Finally, the subpanel labeled “Excess Correlation Diff-in-Diff” shows the marginal reduction in excess correlation relative to the fundamental model without liquidity controls. Positive values indicate a reduction in excess correlation. z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 899 observations for each industry and *,**,*** indicates significance at 10% 5% and 1% respectively. 56 Panel A: Liquidity Factor Exposures Pre-Crisis/Crisis Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Pre-Crisis ∆ONOFF -0.01 -0.03 0.00 0.00 (-0.35) (-0.69) (0.11) (0.05) ∆OISTB -0.01 -0.04 -0.02 0.04 (-0.13) (-0.60) (-0.26) (0.45) ∆ONREPO -0.06 0.01 -0.02 0.01 (-1.13) (0.25) (-0.40) (0.26) ∆BIDASK 0.10* 0.08 0.10** 0.09* (2.21) (1.83) (2.54) (2.02) ∆IBIDASK 0.02 -0.01 -0.07* 0.13*** (0.64) (-0.29) (-2.30) (3.65) HEDGE 0.16* 0.08 0.08 0.00 (2.06) (1.02) (1.05) (-0.05) AMIHUD 0.01 -0.04 -0.01 -0.02 (0.16) (-1.04) (-0.26) (-0.53) NTRADES -0.02 0.02 -0.01 -0.02 (-0.36) (0.42) (-0.29) (-0.35) VOLUME 0.00 -0.07 0.00 0.06 (0.04) (-1.45) (-0.04) (1.15) Marginal Crisis Effects ∆ONOFF 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.08 (1.10) (0.93) (0.67) (1.29) ∆OISTB 0.04 0.12 0.07 -0.01 (0.36) (1.12) (0.64) (-0.09) ∆ONREPO 0.11 -0.09 -0.04 -0.01 (1.36) (-1.14) (-0.48) (-0.15) ∆BIDASK -0.03 0.07 0.08 0.07 (-0.45) (1.06) (1.23) (1.01) ∆IBIDASK 0.04 0.14*** 0.12** -0.10 (0.77) (2.65) (2.45) (-1.68) HEDGE 0.07 0.23* 0.28*** 0.30** (0.62) (2.03) (2.62) (2.49) AMIHUD -0.10 -0.07 -0.09 -0.04 (-1.65) (-1.25) (-1.56) (-0.70) NTRADES 0.11 -0.01 -0.01 0.08 (1.47) (-0.11) (-0.10) (0.99) VOLUME -0.18** -0.07 -0.09 -0.21*** (-2.47) (-0.94) (-1.24) (-2.69) R-Squared 0.2366 0.2184 0.2216 0.1371 Other Financials 0.02 (0.54) 0.03 (0.50) -0.03 (-0.66) 0.01 (0.25) 0.05 (1.77) 0.07 (0.94) 0.00 (-0.10) -0.07 (-1.42) -0.05 (-1.16) 0.02 (0.48) 0.01 (0.10) -0.02 (-0.45) 0.09* (2.28) 0.06 (1.63) 0.06 (0.82) 0.02 (0.55) -0.07 (-1.47) -0.02 (-0.47) 0.03 (0.50) -0.01 (-0.13) 0.00 (-0.04) 0.14* (2.25) 0.03 (0.66) 0.22* (2.13) -0.08 (-1.47) 0.10 (1.36) -0.09 (-1.27) 0.3178 -0.01 (-0.24) 0.03 (0.30) 0.01 (0.10) -0.03 (-0.50) 0.10 (1.74) 0.20 (1.88) -0.17*** (-2.87) 0.02 (0.25) -0.07 (-0.96) 0.2642 Consumer Manuf. Non-Lehman 0.01 -0.01 (0.43) (-0.18) 0.02 0.01 (0.45) (0.11) -0.03 -0.03 (-0.65) (-0.84) 0.08* 0.11*** (2.28) (3.18) 0.04 0.03 (1.54) (1.26) 0.19*** 0.19*** (3.44) (3.35) -0.04 -0.08*** (-1.42) (-2.72) 0.02 0.02 (0.53) (0.41) -0.07* -0.10*** (-2.00) (-2.74) Marginal Lehman Effects 0.25 0.21 (0.90) (0.78) 0.04 -0.03 (0.14) (-0.09) 0.18 0.10 (0.96) (0.54) 0.30 0.25 (0.84) (0.63) 0.58 1.14 (0.90) (1.79) 0.43 0.04 (0.96) (0.09) 0.55 0.10 (0.88) (0.15) -0.37 -0.09 (-0.47) (-0.11) 0.02 0.19 (0.07) (0.76) 0.2346 0.2118 Non-Lehman/Lehman HiTech Health Other Financials 0.02 (0.73) 0.01 (0.22) -0.04 (-0.95) 0.13*** (4.20) -0.02 (-1.02) 0.22*** (3.99) -0.05 (-1.74) -0.01 (-0.39) -0.04 (-1.15) 0.04 (1.36) 0.04 (0.62) 0.01 (0.13) 0.11*** (3.38) 0.09*** (3.35) 0.15** (2.56) -0.05 (-1.49) 0.01 (0.17) -0.02 (-0.64) 0.04 (1.28) 0.03 (0.64) -0.05 (-1.39) 0.07* (2.25) 0.05* (2.21) 0.18*** (3.41) -0.05 (-1.76) -0.02 (-0.64) -0.09** (-2.57) 0.02 (0.58) 0.02 (0.39) -0.04 (-1.10) 0.09*** (2.61) 0.09*** (3.23) 0.17*** (3.14) -0.07* (-2.31) -0.06 (-1.78) -0.05 (-1.55) 0.47 (1.66) 0.02 (0.06) 0.04 (0.20) 0.26 (0.69) 1.21 (1.90) 0.22 (0.53) -0.40 (-0.68) -0.03 (-0.03) -0.23 (-0.95) 0.2183 0.12 (0.42) -0.03 (-0.09) 0.03 (0.12) 0.23 (0.63) 0.13 (0.15) 0.08 (0.12) 0.21 (0.33) -0.19 (-0.21) 0.20 (0.33) 0.1209 0.15 (0.56) -0.09 (-0.30) 0.24 (0.94) 0.25 (0.76) 0.84 (1.26) 0.37 (0.60) 0.28 (0.43) -0.40 (-0.36) 0.21 (0.64) 0.3178 0.34 (1.29) -0.36 (-1.19) 0.25 (1.32) 0.58 (1.57) 0.40 (0.66) 0.64 (1.62) 0.69 (1.09) 0.20 (0.25) 0.46 (1.21) 0.2631 57 Panel B: Liquidity Contagion Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Matrix Test Average Correlation Consumer 0.00 0.11*** 0.15*** 0.18*** 0.12*** 0.09* Statistic 0. 1680*** Change in Excess Correlation Manuf. HiTech Health Other 0.00 0.21*** 0.22*** 0.16*** 0.17*** P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.33*** 0.14*** 0.10* 0.00 0.21*** 0.23*** 0.00 0.10** Financials 0.00 Consumer 0.00 -0.03 -0.05 0.00 -0.05 -0.06 Excess Correlation Diff-in-Diff Manuf. HiTech Health Other 0.00 -0.05 0.12 0.04 -0.03 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.06 -0.01 0.00 0.03 Financials 0.00 58 Table VII Counterparty risk contagion parameter estimates are reported below. Panel A shows the regression coefficients for counterparty risk proxies prior to the crisis and their marginal changes during the crisis. The specification below contains all fundamental variables defined in Table III (∆S = βiF+γiFDcrisis),along with counterparty risk proxies (CP). ∆S i = β i F + γ i FDcrisis + ϑCPi + ϑic CPi Dcrisis + ε i Counterparty risk variables include the spread between the three-month overnight index swap rate and three-month LIBOR (OIS). The spread between the yield on three-month asset-backed commercial paper and RF3M (ABCP). The change in ABCP is orthogonalized to the change in RF3M. The return on the value weighted portfolio of 16 licensed market-makers in the CDX index (CPstock). CPstock is orthogonalized to SP500. Finally, CPDIF measures risk dispersion between counterparties. The interaction variable EXCPDIF equals CPDIF on days when risk dispersion is above its 95th percentile. I also include the dummy variable corresponding to EXCPDIF but do not report it because it is always insignificant. I re-estimate the marginal changes on the month following the collapse of Lehman Brothers (9/15/2008-10/15/2008) these results are reported in the panel labeled Non-Lehman/ Lehman. Panel B reports the results of the tests for an increase in excess correlation after controlling for counterparty risk. The subpanel labeled “Change in Excess Correlation” shows the results of the test for a change in the correlation matrix and the average correlation (lower panel) p-values are calculated using the χ2 statistics developed by Goetzmann et al. (2005). The upper half of the panel shows the increase in correlation between industry pairs; significance is assessed using Fisher transformed correlations. Finally, the subpanel labeled “Excess Correlation Diff-in-Diff” shows the marginal reduction (positive values) in excess correlation relative to the fundamental model without counterparty risk controls. ∆ indicates that the variable is first differenced; all other variables are percent changes. All variables are corrected for serial correlation and standardized using autoregressive GARCH filters. z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 905 observations for each industry and *,**,*** indicates significance at 10% 5% and 1% respectively. Panel A: Counterparty Risk Factor Exposures Pre-Crisis/Crisis Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Pre-Crisis ∆OIS -0.03 0.06 0.05 0.02 (-0.62) (1.34) (1.24) (0.42) ∆ABCP -0.07 -0.14 -0.03 -0.06 (-0.81) (-1.74) (-0.41) (-0.75) CPstock -0.06 -0.02 0.01 -0.03 (-0.85) (-0.29) (0.14) (-0.37) CPDIF 0.01 -0.03 -0.03 -0.02 (0.18) (-1.06) (-0.89) (-0.50) Marginal Crisis Effects ∆OIS 0.09 -0.06 0.00 0.05 (1.47) (-0.86) (0.04) (0.71) ∆ABCP 0.09 0.17 -0.02 0.04 (0.83) (1.63) (-0.21) (0.34) CPstock -0.10 -0.10 -0.13 -0.12 (-0.80) (-0.76) (-1.08) (-0.91) EXCPDIF -0.06 -0.03 0.05 -0.12 (-0.40) (-0.18) (0.36) (-0.75) R-Squared 0.2150 0.1761 0.1869 0.1016 Other Financials 0.02 (0.41) -0.13 (-1.60) -0.06 (-0.81) -0.02 (-0.63) 0.00 (0.07) -0.01 (-0.13) -0.03 (-0.44) -0.01 (-0.29) 0.00 (-0.01) 0.11 (1.14) 0.01 (0.08) 0.02 (0.13) 0.2883 0.03 (0.52) -0.03 (-0.31) 0.07 (0.53) 0.14 (0.87) 0.2011 Consumer Manuf. Non-Lehman 0.01 0.04 (0.27) (1.23) -0.01 -0.05 (-0.26) (-0.92) -0.10 -0.05 (-1.62) (-0.81) 0.01 -0.04 (0.22) (-1.08) Marginal Lehman Effects 0.22 -0.32 (1.11) (-1.61) 0.42 0.26 (0.67) (0.42) -0.12 -0.82 (-0.23) (-1.57) -0.08 -0.08 (-0.48) (-0.50) 0.2153 0.1764 Non-Lehman/Lehman HiTech Health Other Financials 0.05 (1.65) -0.05 (-1.06) -0.03 (-0.54) -0.03 (-0.91) 0.04 (1.31) -0.05 (-0.96) -0.07 (-1.10) -0.02 (-0.52) 0.02 (0.50) -0.05 (-1.14) -0.05 (-0.94) -0.02 (-0.61) 0.02 (0.72) -0.03 (-0.63) -0.01 (-0.16) -0.01 (-0.29) -0.10 (-0.53) 0.18 (0.29) -0.59 (-1.16) 0.02 (0.12) 0.1880 -0.35 (-1.69) 0.85 (1.32) -0.83 (-1.55) -0.18 (-1.07) 0.1082 0.01 (0.05) -0.17 (-0.28) -0.29 (-0.59) 0.00 (-0.01) 0.2879 -0.40* (-2.08) 0.19 (0.30) -0.77 (-1.52) 0.08 (0.52) 0.2045 59 Panel B: Counterparty Risk Contagion Consumer Manufacturing HiTech Health Other Financials Matrix Test Average Correlation Consumer 0.00 0.12*** 0.20*** 0.26*** 0.15*** 0.10** Statistic 0.2151*** Excess Correlation Difference Matrix Manuf. HiTech Health Other 0.00 0.23*** 0.32*** 0.20*** 0.17*** P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.39*** 0.16*** 0.12*** 0.00 0.31*** 0.26*** 0.00 0.14*** Panel C: Liquidity & Counterparty Risk Excess Correlation Excess Correlation Difference Matrix Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Consumer 0.00 Manufacturing 0.10*** 0.00 HiTech 0.13*** 0.19*** 0.00 Health 0.16*** 0.22*** 0.28*** 0.00 Other 0.10*** 0.17*** 0.11*** 0.18*** 0.00 Financials 0.08 0.16*** 0.08 0.24*** 0.10* Statistic P-Value Matrix Test 0.00 Average Correlation 0.1544*** 0.00 Financials 0.00 Financials 0.00 Consumer 0.00 -0.04 -0.10 -0.08 -0.08 -0.08 Consumer 0.00 -0.03 -0.03 0.02 -0.03 -0.06 Excess Correlation Diff-in-Diff Manuf. HiTech Health Other 0.00 -0.06 0.02 0.00 -0.04 0.00 -0.07 0.02 0.00 0.00 -0.04 -0.05 0.00 -0.01 Excess Correlation Diff-in-Diff Manuf. HiTech Health Other 0.00 -0.03 0.12 0.02 -0.03 0.00 0.04 0.07 0.04 0.00 0.08 -0.03 Financials 0.00 Financials 0.00 0.03 0.00 60 Table VIII Liquidity & Counterparty Risk Shocks: This table reports the results of the tests for liquidity/counterparty risk shocks during the crisis. The dependant variables are CDS spread changes for industry portfolios listed in the column headers. The independent variables include all the controls for fundamental credit risk defined in the caption of Table V and two indicator variables DISTRESS and RECOVERY, which equal one on the day of, or surrounding, events listed in Appendix B and zero everywhere else. ∆S i = β i F + γ i FDcrisis + λ R DRECOVERY + λ D DDISTRESS + ε i Panel A shows the results using all events. In this case, the indicator variables DISTRESS and RECOVERY equal one on the event date only. Panel B reports results for the level 2 and 3 severity events only. Again these events are listed in the table in Appendix B. They include all dates corresponding to events with 2 or 3 listed in the column labeled Severity. For this regression, I define a three “calendar” day window which includes the event date and one day pre and post. Panel C includes the results of the most severe distress events, which include the Bear Stearns merger (3/14/2008), the collapse of Lehman Brothers (9/15/2008), and the closure of Washington Mutual (9/25/2008). I define the window around these events to be 1 observation prior to the event and 2 observations after. As with other tests, these regressions are estimated using SUR. z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 912 observations for each industry portfolio and *,**,*** indicate statistical significance at the 10% 5% and 1% level respectively. Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Financials Panel A: All Distress and Recovery Events (event date only) DISTRESS RECOVERY R-Squared -0.01 -0.06 -0.21 0.25 -0.13 -0.07 (-0.04) (-0.19) (-0.63) (0.72) (-0.43) (-0.22) -0.16 0.05 -0.07 0.15 -0.17 0.01 (-0.78) (0.26) (-0.34) (0.69) (-0.88) (0.05) 0.2111 0.1855 0.1869 0.1009 0.2760 0.1939 Panel B: Level 2 and 3 Distress and Recovery Events (1 calendar day around the event) DISTRESS RECOVERY R-Squared -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 0.17 -0.07 0.01 (-0.36) (-0.34) (-0.37) (0.81) (-0.39) (0.07) 0.04 -0.08 -0.18 -0.02 -0.04 -0.10 (0.29) (-0.57) (-1.32) (-0.13) (-0.28) (-0.75) 0.2107 0.1859 0.1881 0.1006 0.2755 0.1945 Panel C: Distress and Recovery Events (1 - 2 observations prior to and after the event) DISTRESS R-Squared 0.66* 0.53 0.58 0.57 0.42 0.58 (2.20) (1.72) (1.89) (1.76) (1.43) (1.87) 0.2147 0.1881 0.1896 0.1031 0.2769 0.1970 61 Table IX Risk Premium Contagion: Reported in Panel A below are the regression results for the risk premium analysis. The dependent variable for each regression is the change in industry CDS spreads; industries are defined in the caption of Table I and are listed in column headers. The risk premium (RP) is estimated from the 10 most well-behaved firms using the panel regression approach outlined by BDDFS. Changes in the estimated risk premium are then included in the fundamental regression (defined in the caption of Table IV) as explanatory variables. Coefficients of the fundamental controls are omitted for brevity. The row labeled ∆RP shows the pre-crisis risk premium regression coefficient for each industry. The row labeled ∆RPC shows the marginal change in that coefficient during the crisis. Panel B shows the coefficients from the factor model estimation using the risk premium estimated from the 20 most well-behaved (non-industry) firms. Due to EDF data limitations, the pre-crisis period was shortened to 3/1/2006 – 7/30/2007. Panel C shows the change in excess correlation after controlling for the risk premium. Panel D shows the change in excess correlation after controlling for the risk premium (estimated using the 20 most well-behaved (non-industry) firms). Tests of pairwise correlation are based on the Fisher transformed correlation coefficients. Tests of the average correlation and correlation matrix are based on the asymptotic Chi Squared tests derived in Goetzmann et al. (2005). Tests of pairwise correlations are one sided. z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 747 observations for each industry portfolio and *,**,*** indicate statistical significance at the 10% 5% and 1% level respectively. Panel A: Risk Premium Using the 10 Most Well-behaved Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Pre-Crisis ∆RP 0.47*** 0.53*** 0.37*** (10.60) (13.10) (8.83) Health Other Financials 0.45*** (9.19) 0.40*** (9.47) 0.34*** (7.23) Marginal Crisis Effects ∆RPC 0.10 (1.63) 0.20*** (3.69) 0.27*** (4.74) 0.16** (2.50) 0.14** (2.56) 0.14* (2.26) R-Squared 0.4698 0.5477 0.4729 0.3475 0.5158 0.3718 Panel B: Risk Premium Using the 20 Most Well-behaved Non-Industry Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Pre-Crisis ∆RP 0.30*** 0.41*** 0.26*** 0.30*** (7.49) (11.28) (7.04) (6.15) Other Financials 0.29*** (7.89) 0.28*** (6.42) Marginal Crisis Effects ∆RPC 0.15*** (2.76) 0.20*** (4.12) 0.30*** (5.97) 0.25*** (3.95) 0.16*** (3.12) 0.12* (2.11) R-Squared 0.4606 0.5519 0.4995 0.3280 0.5340 0.3906 Panel C: Risk Premium Contagion: 10 Most Well-behaved Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Consumer 0.00 Manufacturing -0.09 0.00 HiTech -0.05 0.03 0.00 Health 0.10 0.07 0.11 0.00 Other -0.02 0.03 -0.01 0.16** Financials -0.10 -0.02 -0.03 0.13* Statistic P-Value Matrix Test 0.00 Average Correlation 0.0170*** 0.00 Panel D: Risk Premium Contagion: 20 Most Well-behaved Firms Non-Industry Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Consumer 0.00 Manufacturing -0.11 0.00 HiTech -0.10 -0.03 0.00 Health 0.02 0.04 0.10 0.00 Other -0.05 0.08 -0.05 0.09 Financials -0.17 0.07 -0.07 0.09 Statistic P-Value Matrix Test 0.00 Average Correlation -0.008*** 0.00 Other Financials 0.00 -0.03 0.00 Other Financials 0.00 -0.04 0.00 62 Table X Risk Premium Contagion Robustness: Reported in Panel A reports the results of the risk premium controls in the fundamental model. The standard set of fundamentals is included in the regression but coefficients for not reported. In this case, the risk premium is estimated with controls for transaction costs. That is, I add the bid-ask spread into Equation 3 and re-estimate the risk premium. The risk premium is estimated from the CDS spreads of the 20 most well-behaved non-industry firms. The estimated risk premium is then included in the fundamental regression to control for potential contamination from transaction costs in the estimation of the risk premium. The row labeled ∆RP shows the pre-crisis risk premium regression coefficient for each industry. The row labeled ∆RPC shows the marginal change in that coefficient during the crisis. Due to EDF data limitations, the pre-crisis period was shortened to 3/1/2006 – 7/30/2007. Panel B reports the change in excess correlation after controlling for variations in the fundamental factors that drive credit risk and the liquidity adjusted risk premium. Tests of pairwise correlation are based on the Fisher transformed correlation coefficients. Tests of the average correlation and correlation matrix are based on the asymptotic Chi Squared tests derived in Goetzmann et al. (2005). Tests of pairwise correlations are one sided. z-statistics are reported in parentheses. There are 747 observations for each industry portfolio and *,**,*** indicate statistical significance at the 10% 5% and 1% level respectively. Panel A: Liquidity Adjusted Risk Premium Controls Using the 20 Most Well-behaved Non-industry Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Other Financials Pre-Crisis ∆RP 0.12*** 0.20*** 0.14*** 0.15*** 0.16*** 0.16*** (3.12) (5.25) (3.62) (3.02) (4.22) (3.58) Marginal Crisis Effects ∆RPC 0.21*** (3.93) 0.26*** (5.09) 0.30*** (5.77) 0.32*** (4.96) 0.17*** (3.36) 0.17*** (2.83) R-Squared 0.3723 0.4207 0.4017 0.2795 0.4576 0.3388 Panel B: Risk Premium Contagion: 20 Most Well-behaved Non-Industry Firms Consumer Manuf. HiTech Health Consumer 0.00 Manufacturing -0.06 0.00 HiTech -0.01 0.00 0.00 Health 0.03 -0.05 0.03 0.00 Other 0.04 0.08 0.00 0.05 Financials -0.07 0.06 -0.08 0.09 Statistic Matrix Test Average Correlation 0.0074*** Other Financials 0.00 0.03 0.00 P-Value 0.00 0.00 63