Draft May 2012 Induced Biased Innovation and Exhaustible Resource Prices John R. Boycea), Daniel V. Gordonb) and Sjak Smuldersc) Abstract: This paper tests a prediction from endogenous growth theory regarding the rate at which commodity prices in exhaustible resource markets grow. The hypothesis we test is that innovation is more likely to occur in large sectors of the economy. This is tested using a panel of 80 mineral commodities annual price growths over the period 19002006. We find support for this hypothesis. Keywords: Endogenous Growth, Resource Prices JEL: Q3, C23, C36 a) Professor of Economics, University of Calgary, 2500 University Drive NW Calgary Canada T2N 1N4 email: boyce@ucalgary.ca b) Professor of Economics, University of Calgary, 2500 University Drive NW Calgary Canada T2N 1N4 email: gdgordon@ucalgary.ca c) Professor of Economics, Tilburg University P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands. Email: j.a.smulders@uvt.nl 1 1. Introduction This paper contributes to our understanding of commodity price formation by empirically examining the relationship between commodity prices for exhaustible resources and induced innovation. The underlying hypothesis we test is quite simple. Induced biased endogenous growth theory (e.g., Kennedy (1964), Acemoglu (2002, 2007), Smulders and de Nooij (2003)) suggests that innovation is more likely to occur in markets in which the gains from innovation are large. Those tend to be markets for which the size of the market is quite large. Thus, if endogenous innovation drives economic growth, and if innovation is of the cost-reducing form, we would expect to see that commodity prices are more likely to decline when the size of the world value product of the commodity is large. Economists have long been interested in natural resource prices. Barnett and Morse (1963) were the first to draw upon a large data set of U.S. mineral prices to analyze resource scarcity. This was updated by Smith (1977). Slade (1982) was the first to examine the connection between innovation and exhaustible resource prices. She focused on the time trend of natural resource prices, regressing the real price of twelve minerals against time and time squared to determine whether or not mineral prices followed a U-shaped price path. Her work was criticized by Mueller and Gorin (1984) for not taking into account specific events concerning market structure and by Perck and Roberts (1986) for not taking account of the time-series properties of her data. This literature was reviewed and Slade's empirical work extended by Krautkraemer (1998). More recently, Kellard and Wohar (2006) examined price trends for twenty-four commodities (some of which are renewable resources) using time series methods, and Gaudet (2007) examines the rate of growth in prices in the context of the Hotelling model. None of these papers investigates the empirical connection between innovation and the rate of growth in prices. 2 This paper is closely related to Popp (2002), who looked at the influence of energy prices on innovation. While Popp was concerned with how natural resource prices affected innovation activities, we indirectly examine the flip side of that question. What we wish to explain is resource commodity price growth rates. Our linkage to innovation is indirect. We expect innovation to be positively related to the size of the commodity in the economy. Thus, commodities that are more important in the economy will attract more innovation. Commodities for which innovation is higher will have higher downward pressure on price growth. In this sense, our work is in a similar spirit to De Cian (2008), which was developed independently of our own paper. De Cian (2008) uses data from fifteen OECD countries over the period 1978-2005 to assess the impact of factor augmenting technical change in three inputs; labor, capital and energy. The methodology utilizes a constant elasticity of substitution aggregate production function with technical change affecting the productivity of each of the inputs. It is not possible to identify factor augmenting technological change from technological change that affects each input, so the assumption is made that all technological change is factor augmenting. She estimates two empirical models. The first assumes that factor augmenting technological change is exogenous, while the second, which is more closely related to this paper, assumes that factor augmenting technological change is endogenous. She postulates that endogenous factor augmenting technological change is driven by R&D expenditures, aggregate imports, imports of machinery, and that labor productivity is affected by education expenditures. Her empirical results on endogenous technological change suggest that R&D expenditures and education expenditures can explain part of the factor augmenting technological change. 3 The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents and reviews the theoretical models on price formation in exhaustible resource models and how the price of an exhaustible resource will grow over time. Section 3 describes the panel data available for price growth analysis for 80 minerals with a time series extending in some cases from 1900-2006. Section 4 describes the econometric modeling and specification of instrumental variables required for empirical estimation. Section 5 concludes. 2. Theoretical Analysis The Hotelling (1931) model of exhaustible resources assumes a fixed stock of the resource, π ! , cost of extraction, πΆ π(π‘) = ππ π‘ , and demand curve, π π‘ = π· π(π‘) , in industry extraction, π(π‘) where π· ! π < 0. When the stock of reserves is fixed, the equation of motion for reserves is (dropping time notation) π ≡ !" !" = −π, π 0 = π ! (1) Alternatively, it will be convenient to work in cumulative extraction, π, where π≡ !" !" = π, π 0 = π! (2) Feasibility requires that π (π‘) ≥ 0 and π₯ π‘ ≤ π! + π ! for all π‘. 2.1 Perfect Competition: Basic results With competitive firms, each owning an infinitesimal share of the stock, and facing an exogenous rate of return to capital of π, Hotelling showed that the equilibrium price path satisfies π =π+π =π+π (3a) (3b) Where π > 0 is the current value of the resource stock in situ, and π < 0 is the marginal value of cumulative extraction. With competitive markets for ownership of the stock, π = −π is the 4 scarcity rental price that would be paid for a unit of the stock in the ground. In order that the rate of return from holding the exhaustible resource asset is equal to the rate of return elsewhere in the economy, the scarcity rental values must rise over time at the rate of interest, π, ! π ≡ ! = π (4a) π ≡ ! = π (4b) ! Therefore, time differentiating (3) and using (4), the Hotelling prediction is that the price grows over time: ! π! ≡ ! = !(!!!) ! > 0. (5) 2.2 Imperfect Competition Exhaustible resource markets often have few firms producing the resource (e.g., Salant (1974), Loury (1986), Polasky (1992)). The effect of imperfect competition can be seen by considering a simple Cournot model of imperfect competition in the extraction industry. Suppose there are π firms, each holding π !! initial reserves and facing costs π. Then the first order condition for the π !! firm is π 1− !! ∈ = π + π! , π = 1, β― , π, where π ! ≡ π! π is firm π′π share of production and ∈ ≡ (6) !" !" β ! ! is the elasticity of demand. Holding π ! and ∈ constant, the rate of change of price in an oligopolistic market is π! = ! ! ! !! ! !! ∈ ! !(!! ! ) (7) ∈ Comparing the growth rate of the competitive market with that of the oligopolistic market at a common starting price, π yields that the competitive market price grows more quickly than the oligopolistic price: 5 0< π 1− π! = π ! ∈ π ! π ! − π < (π − π) 1 − ∈ ∈ π ! −π π(π − π) ∈ < ≡ π! , π ! π π(1 − ) ∈ π π 1− where the second inequality is obtained by adding -1 to each side of the equation, multiplying by π, and adding π(1 − !! ∈ ) to the result; and the second inequality is obtained by dividing each side of the equation by π and then by 1 − !! ∈ . Loury (1986) and Polasky (1992) obtain further results by allowing π ! and ∈ to vary over time. However, for our purposes, the main result is that an increase in market power lowers the rate of growth of prices. 2.3 Effects of Cumulative Extraction The competitive model was extended by Schulze (1974), Solow and Wan (1976), and Slade (1982), who considered models where deposits differ in quality and where marginal costs may be increasing with output. When each deposit is of infinitesimal size and differs by quality, Solow and Wan showed that the reserves will be used in the order of least costs first. This implies that we can model the unit costs of extraction as a function of reserves, π , or, equivalently, of cumulative extraction, π. Letting πΆ(π, π) denote the costs of extraction, then π! ≡ ππΆ ππ > 0 is implied if resources are used in the order of least cost, and πΆ! > 0, πΆ!! ≥ 0, and πΆ!" ≥ 0. If the equilibrium price in this model satisfies π = πΆ! π, π − π (8) The equation of motion for π is π=π+ !! (!,!) ! . (9) 6 From (8), it follows that the price growth path is π = πΆ!" π + πΆ!! π − π ! ! = πΆ!" π + !!! − πππΆ! ! (!) π = 1 − !!! !! !!" !!!! ! ! (!) ! (10) + !(!!!! ) ! , where the second line uses the definition that π = π·(π) to show that π = π π·! π , and uses ! π = π from (2); and the third equality divides each side of the equation by π and by 1 − !!!! . (!) Thus, again the Hotelling effect is the second expression, and this causes prices to rise over time. The effect of cumulative extraction depends upon the sign of the numerator of the first expression, which is πΆ!" π − πΆ! . This expression is equal to π(πΆ! π − πΆ) ππ. The term πΆ! π − πΆ is positive if πΆ!! > 0 and zero if πΆ!! = 0. Thus, in order for there to be an effect on price from cumulative extraction, it must be that the marginal cost of extraction is increasing in π. The sign of πΆ!" π − πΆ! is an empirical question (Farzin, 1992). 2.4 Exogenous Technological Change Stiglitz (1974) and Slade (1982) each considered models in which exogenous technological change occurred. In Slade, the technological change was in regard to the cost of extraction, while in Stiglitz the technological change was a change in the total factor productivity. We focus on the Slade type of exogenous technological change. Let the cost of production be denoted as πΆ(π, π΅), where π΅ is a measure of technology, where πΆ! > 0, πΆ!! ≥ 0, πΆ! < 0 πππ πΆ!" < 0 are assumed. Further, with exogenous technological change, assume that π΅ grows according to ! π΅ ≡ ! = g > 0. (11) Then, the equilibrium equation for the market price is π = πΆ! π, π΅ + π. (12) 7 Differentiating this with respect to time yields ! !! π = 1 − !! (!) !! ! ! !" ! ! + !(!!!! ! . (13) While the second expression is the Hotelling effect from scarcity, which is positive, the first term is the effect of technological change. This expression is negative, since πΆ!" < 0. By observing that innovation is most valuable when reserves are large, Slade (1982) argued that the innovation effect should dominate early in the extraction cycle and that the Hotelling scarcity effect should dominate later in the extraction cycle. Thus, she predicted U-shaped price paths. 2.5 Endogenous Technological Change Smulders and de Nooij (2003) consider a model in which endogenous technological change occurs. In their model, the rate of innovation depends upon the size of the economy. Let π ≡ !" ! , where π is gross world GDP, denote the share of a mineral resource in the economy. Then Smulders and de Nooij (2003) postulated that the rate of technological improvement, π΅ is an increasing function of the size of the sector in the economy: π΅ = β(π£) (14) where β! π > 0. Thus, in their model, the growth in the price of an exhaustible resource is given by ! π = 1 − !!!! (!) !! ! !!(!) !(!!! !" ! ! ! . (15) Since πΆ!" < 0 and β! π > 0, it follows that an increase in π causes the price growth rate to decrease. The key empirical difference between the endogenous and exogenous technological change models is that in the exogenous technological change model, β π = π, which is independent of π. Hence, the key empirical test whether the rate of growth of prices is inversely correlated with the size of the sector in the economy. 8 3 Data Definitions and Summary Statistics The focus of the empirical work is to empirical test the hypothesis predicting a negative relationship between the growth rate in mineral price and endogenous technical change as measured by world value product. The data for analysis includes 80 minerals covering the period 1900-2006. While price and quantity data are available for only 27 of the 80 minerals for more than 100 years, data are available for 26 years or longer for all 80 minerals. The data consist of a main database covering all 80 minerals and includes the growth rate in mineral price, world value product, cumulative production, world population and the U.S. real bond rate. The secondary data set includes only a subset of the defined minerals and a much-shortened time series but augments the variables in the main database with proxy measures of monopoly power on both the demand and supply side of the market. The primary source for the data is Kelly and Matos (2007), which is an electronic database maintained by the United States Geological Survey (USGS). This database contains price and production data for some 90 minerals. We use all minerals for which both price and quantity data are available. Prices are U.S. prices per tonne. This yielded data for 76 minerals. This data was supplemented with data for four additional mineral resources: petroleum, coal, natural gas and uranium. That data comes from a variety of sources. The oil price data is from the BP Statistical Review of Energy 2008. The natural gas, uranium, and coal price data are from the United States Energy Information Agency's (EIA) Annual Energy Review. Coal quantity data is from two sources; from 1965 forward, coal production data is contained in the BP Statistical Review of Energy 2008, and world coal production data is available back to 1932 from the USGS publication Minerals Yearbook (various years). World petroleum production data is from World Oil's Annual Forecast and Review Issue. Uranium consumption data is complied by using 9 the quantities of fuel injected into reactors in the United States, published in the EIA's Annual Energy Review, and combining this with the electricity production by nuclear energy sources published in the BP Statistical Review of Energy 2008. Using the U.S. average consumption rates, world production1 rates were then estimated. For the π !! mineral in the π‘ !! period, the growth in mineral price is defined as π!"# = ln ( π!" π!"!! ) (1) where π!" is real price of the π !! mineral in the π‘ !! period. Prices are in 2000 U.S. dollars per tonne. Table 1 reports for each mineral in the data set the mineral id number, time period available, average price and average growth rate in price. Prices vary dramatically, with gemstones reaching almost 2 billion dollars per tonne down to $17 per tonne for industrial gravel.2 On average, mineral prices were declining at rate -0.008 per year in an un-weighted average over all minerals and years, and almost 3/4 of the minerals experienced declining prices on average. While 15 mineral prices declined by more than 2% per annum, only two (quartzcrystals and thallium) experience growth rates of more than 2%. Thus, Barnett and Morse (1963), Slade (1982), Krautkraemer (1998), Kellard and Wohar (2006) and Gaudet (2007), inter alia, have observed, the preponderance of evidence is that mineral prices have declined in the twentieth century. The time series structure of individual prices requires that we investigate the stochastic properties of each. Undoubtedly individual prices are nonstationary3 implying that the moments of the distribution are changing over time, but the transformation to the growth in prices is a form of first differences and likely a transformation to stationary stochastic properties. We test for stationarity using a standard Dickey-Fuller statistic and report the results in column 5 of 1 These exclude uranium used in nuclear weapons and other non-energy uses. Natural gas averaged approximately $2 per million cubic feet and uranium averaged about $21 per pound. 3 Dickey-Fuller statistics for individual prices confirms this property. 2 10 Table 1. For each mineral the Dickey-Fuller statistic is significantly important and we can reject the null hypothesis of non-stationary in the growth in prices. In other words, the transformation to the growth in prices is in fact a stationary transformation. This is important information for econometric specification and will allow reduced form modelling with a stationary (i.e., integrated of order zero) dependent variable. Table 2 records for each mineral world production in tonnes, average value of world value product and cumulative production. To calculate world value product by mineral, we used data on world GDP compiled by Angus Maddison.4 That data contains both population and GDP information by country through 2003, with the GDP data in 1990 U.S. dollars. We extended Maddison's GDP series with data from the World Bank's World Development Indicators data. As there is no reliable world GDP data existing prior to 1950, we use the Maddison data that existed for the thirty countries for which data is continuously available back to 1900. Those countries include the twenty original members of the OECD5, plus seven Latin American countries not original members of the OECD (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Columbia, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela), and three Asian countries not original members of the OECD (India, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka). We call this the ‘Group of Thirty’ countries and their combined GDP30 is used in calculating our measure of world GDP. For the π !! mineral in the π‘ !! period, world value product is defined as π!" = ln ( π!"β π!" πΊπ·π!!" ) (2) where π!" is world production. From Table 2, the share of minerals in world GDP is quite small. Petroleum is the largest (accounting for just less than 1/2 of the world value product of the 4 5 Downloaded from http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/. These are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States. 11 minerals we consider), but even here it only accounts for 2.12% of world GDP. Coal is second in share accounting for 1.1%. All other minerals are less than 1% of world GDP: cement (0.47%), iron-ore (0.27%), aluminum (0.15%), nitrogen (0.10%), copper (0.22%) and gold (0.23%) are the only minerals accounting for more than 1/10th of world GDP. At the other end of the spectrum, thallium accounted for only 5/1000th of a percent of world GDP. The average share of all minerals was about 0.08% of world GDP, and the total for all minerals was 5.63% of world GDP.6 Cumulative production is calculated from annual world production since 1900. As we wish to have a measure that varies across time and since cumulative production varies most dramatically across minerals, we use as our measure of cumulative production the ratio of current production to cumulative past consumption. This measure is without units, and varies between zero and one in value, declining as time progresses. For the π !! mineral in the π‘ !! period, cumulative production is defined as π!"# = ln ( π!" π!" ) (3) where π!" is cumulative production. For completeness we report average values of cumulative production for each mineral in column 4 of Table 2. Again, we want to characterize the stochastic structure of the individual time series for both world value product and cumulative production. We report in Table 3 standard DickeyFuller time series statistics for each mineral for the variables of interest. The table tells and interesting story; for world value product only 16 of the 80 minerals show stationarity in the defined variable at less than the 5% p-value and this increases to only 22 out of 80 at less than the 10% p-value. This is fairly strong statistical evidence that for the vast majority of minerals 6 Our group of minerals accounted for 4.63% of total world GDP. 12 the world value product variable in a strictly time series setting is non-stationary and thus integrated of order one. However, for cumulative production we observe the opposite and here the vast majority of minerals (73 of 80) are statistically stationary (at less than 5% p-value) and, consistent with the price growth variable, integrated of order zero. Econometrically the Dickey-Fuller results for the three main variables of interest cause serious concern. In a time series perspective, it is in general not possible to form an equilibrium relationship with variables integrated of different order (Enders, 1994), which is exactly the case at hand with price growth and cumulative production integrated of order zero and world value added integrated of order one. However, there is one possibility that may allow us to proceed with the statistical model. The Dickey-Fuller statistics presented above are a purely time series evaluation and thus ignore the stochastic panel properties of our data. It is possible that all variables are stationary in a panel sense. Here we evaluate the stationary prospects of our panel using two statistics for testing unit root hypotheses in un-balanced panels. Im, Pesearan and Shan (2003), hereafter the IPS test, develop a transformation of the standard Dickey-Fuller procedure for testing the null hypothesis that all panels have unit root against an alternative that at least some panels are stationary. The test allows for trend, demeaning the data and accounting for autocorrelation structures. Under the assumption that π βΆ ∞ and NβΆ ∞ the test statistic is asymptotically standard normal. The second test is a Fisher-type test where the individual Dickey-Fuller statistics obtained above (Table 1 and 2) are combined using meta-analysis to generate a powerful test for stationary in the panels. The null and alternative hypotheses are as defined for the IPS test. Choi (2001) shows that if the time dimension is large and the number of panels finite (less than 100) the test statistic 13 follows an inverse normal. Choi defines the test statistics as a ‘Z-statistic’ and suggests it use based on power and size. For the three panel data variables of interest we report in Table 4 both the IPS and Fishertype test statistics. Now we observe for each variable and for each statistical test that the null hypothesis of unit root in each panel can be rejected. This provides statistical evidence that within the panel data framework all important variables have stochastic properties amenable to equilibrium evaluation. The equilibrium relationship can be further evaluated after estimation by testing the predicted errors for properties of stationarity. We augment the panel variables above with strictly time series variables that control for demand and supply shifters that may affect the equilibrium. We include two types of shifters. On the supply side, we use as a proxy the real U.S. bond rate (Reference, year), which is constant across commodities but varies by time. In Figure 1, we graphically represent the variation in this variable overtime- 1900-2006. Notice the relative stability in the bond rate prior to the 1940s but gradually increasing after this point to reach a maximum of over 12 points in 1981 before declining to 4.8 points in 2006. The demand side shifter is world population defined as the combined population of our group of thirty countries. All else equal, we expect an increase in the population to increase the demand for the commodity.7 This variable is shown in Figure 2 for the period 1900-2006. Both the demand and supply shift variables are constant across the different minerals but vary over time. Figure 1 and 2 suggest trends in each series and standard Dickey-Fuller statistics 7 This variable is used in lieu of world per capita income as the numerator of per capita income is world GDP, which is used in the denominator of the world value product for each mineral. 14 show that a null hypothesis of non-stationarity cannot be rejected.8 Standard first-differences techniques transform both series to stationary processes.9 Our secondary data set includes all of the variables defined above for a reduced number of minerals over the period 1990-2004.10 The minerals and time period are dictated by the availability of indices of market power.11 The market power variables are based on data published in the Minerals Yearbook on 49 minerals for which data on the country of production exits. This data is available from 1990-2004. From this data, we calculate the Herfindahl index, π»!"! = ! !!!(100 β π !" )! where π !" is the share of world production of the π !! mineral for the π!! country π = 1 β― πΆ. We use this data to measure market power among suppliers. This is an imperfect measure of supplier market power, as it is country based rather than firm based. However, it is the only measure that is widely available. In addition, Kelly and Matos (2007) report data for 56 commodities from the United States on which industries consume the commodity. For example, titanium is used primarily in the aerospace industry. From this data, we are able to construct a Herfindahl index of the demander's of the resource, π»!"! = ! !!!(100 β π !" )! where π !" is the share of the π !! mineral consumed by the π!! company π = 1 β― πΎ. This is our measure of market power on the demand side of the market. Our Herfindahl demand index cannot measure the number of firms in a sector, but it does measure the number of sectors that are buying the commodity. We list the minerals available for the market power variables and both the Herfindahl demand and supply index in Table 5. 8 The DF statistics are -0.79 (0.966) and -1.66 (0.769) for population and real bond rate, respectively. (p-value in parentheses) 9 The DF statistics are -5.12 (0.000) and -7.74 (0.000) for population and real bond rate, respectively. (p-value in parentheses) 10 The mineral mercury is included in this data set for the period 1990-2003. 11 Boyce (2009), John we need some reference to your building the Herfindahl indices. 15 The Herfindahl market power variables have short time periods but we can evaluate the stochastic property of each variable within the panel stationary testing procedures. We rely on the IPS t-bar statistic that allows for both the number of cross-sections and time periods fixed. These statistics are reported at the bottom of Table 5 and, again, provides statistical support that in a panel setting both Herfindahl indices can be considered stationary. In summing up, the main data set available for econometric analysis is an unbalanced panel on three cross section variables (mineral price growth, world value product and cumulative production) and two time series variables (population and real U.S. bond rate). The main data set has 80 panels with individual time periods ranging from 22 to 107 years for a total sample of 6064. A secondary data set augments the variables with proxy measures of market power on both the demand and supply side of the market. This data set has 22 panels with time periods of 14 or 15 years for a total sample of 307 observations. 4 Econometric Specification and Results The econometric search is to model the data generating process describing the growth in mineral prices. Theory suggests a number of variables that impact the moments of this distribution and our efforts will be to attempt to statistically identify the importance of endogenous technical change within this stochastic process. We start by specifying a general reduced form equation including all variables as: ln( Pit Pq q ) = β v ln( it it30 ) + β x ln( it ) + β n ln Popt30 + β Rb Rbt + β d ln H itd + β s ln H its + ηi + ε it Pit −1 X it GDPt 4) 16 where ln( Pq Pit ) is annual rate of growth in the real price of mineral i in year t; ln( it it30 ) is Pit −1 GDPt world value product of mineral i in year t; ln( qit ) is the ratio of world production to cumulative X it production of mineral i in year t; ln Popt30 is world population in year t; Rbt is the U.S. real bond rate in year t; ln H itd is Herfindahl index of demand sources for mineral i in year t; ln H its is Herfindahl index of supply sources for mineral i in year t; ηi is unobserved heterogeneity of mineral i and ε it is idiosyncratic error term. Several econometric issues present themselves in equation 4): First, all variables defined in equation 4) are integrated of order zero except population and bond rate, which are integrated of order one. In estimation, the log of the first differences of both population and bond rate are used. This allows us to define equation 4) as an equilibrium expression. Second, we must decide on an appropriate estimator to account for the unobserved heterogeneity within the panels. And finally, both world value product and cumulative production are endogenous in the sense that they are correlated with the idiosyncratic error term. World value product includes the current price of mineral i, which is in fact part of the endogenous variable that we are trying to explain. Whereas cumulative production includes current quantity of mineral i, which is a choice variable to the economic agents we are modelling. For the second issue, we will rely on a standard fixed effect model using the within estimator. In general, this will account for the unobserved heterogeneity within the panels and can generate consistent estimates of the parameter coefficients in our reduced form model. For the third issue, we account for the endogenous problem using an instrumental variable (IV) procedure that relies on the time series properties of the variables (hereafter called lagged IV). To make the econometrics tractable and test the 17 robustness of the lagged IV estimator combinations of lags up to four periods will be used. In addition, we attempt an alternative IV procedure relying on the physical properties of the minerals investigated. We obtain information on the abundance of each mineral within the earth’s crust, the minerals are ranked based on abundance and for each mineral we arbitrarily pick the price of the immediate more abundant and less abundant mineral for use as instrumental variables (hereafter called Earth IV). Table 6 shows a ranked list of our minerals that are amenable to the Earth IV estimator. We list mineral id as defined in Table 1 and the id of the mineral immediate more abundant and less abundant. The table lists 46 minerals with the most abundant in the earth’s crust being silicon and aluminum and the least abundant being gold and rhenium. Each of our minerals is associated with two price instruments except silicon and rhenium which because of end point restrictions receive one price instrument each. Table 7 shows some results for equation 4) applied to our main data set using the Fixed Effect estimator and lagged IV. To start the results we estimate the simple two-variable regression of price growth on world value product using a two-lagged IV variable for world value product within the Fixed Effect estimator. Of course, within our reduced form specification the simple regression model is subject to omitted variable bias but does set a reference point for comparison with more complete models. In the simple regression, we see a statistically significant negative relationship from world value product to mineral price growth. In fact, a literal interpretation would indicate a 1% change in current world value product resulting, on average, in a -0.053% decline in mineral price growth. Moving to the full-reduced form specification in regression 2 (again using a two lagged IV for both world value product and cumulative production) we observe that the negative relationship is maintained between world 18 value product and price growth and not substantially impacted by the introduction of the other variables. Now, we also observe a positive impact, as expected a prior, of cumulative production, population and U.S bond rate on price growth. Note, however, the bond rate is not statistically significant. The positive elasticity result for cumulative production is in agreement with the observation by Slade (1982) that prices were likely to decline in the early part of the data than in the later part i.e., prices follow a U-shaped path. It is important to evaluate how robust our main estimated prediction is on the relationship between world value product and price growth to the definition of the lagged IV variable for world value product. In Table 7a we show only the estimated coefficient and p-value for world value product for four alternative definitions of lagged IV.12 The conclusion is clear and indicates that actual number of lags defining the lagged IV is not the determining factor in setting the sign of the coefficient. Parsimony and short time series on some minerals pushes us to define a two period lag for the lagged IV estimator for further estimation. We test further the results obtained for the two period lagged IV reported in regression 2 Table 7 by testing the estimated residuals for stable stochastic properties. Our reduced form model is an equilibrium model so there is no notion of cointegration but rather if the model is statistically specified correctly the predicted residuals must be stable or stationary. We test predicted residuals for each mineral and the full panel data set and we find solid evidence of stable stochastic properties. Returning to Table 7 columns 4 and 5 re-estimate the reduced form equation using different truncations of the main data set. Column 4 shows results for regression 3 that uses only data on minerals each with 107 years of observations. There are 20 minerals in this category for a total of 2099 observations. Column 5 shows results for regression 4 that uses only data on 12 Other coefficients in the reduced form are not substantially impacted by changes in the lagged IV. 19 minerals with less than 107 years of observations. There are 60 minerals in this category for a total of 3766 observations. In both regressions, we still predict on average a negative and statistically important elasticity for our main hypothesis between world value product and mineral price growth, albeit regression 3 under predicts the magnitude of the effect whereas regression 4 over predicts. Also, note that in regression 3 world value product is the only variable statistically significant. Table 7 certainly provides statistical support of our main hypothesis of endogenous technical change negatively impacting the growth in prices but does not provide an empirical measure of the lagged impact13 of innovation on prices. Perhaps one way of looking at this problem is to approach estimation of the reduced form not with an IV estimator but rather the use of lagged proxy variables. We do this by re-estimating regression 2 in Table 7 using sequentially, lags one to six of world value product as proxy for current value of world value product.14 The results for the coefficients on world value product are displayed figuratively in Figure 3. Upper and lower confidence limits accompany predicted coefficients. The first five lags result in statistically significant negative coefficients increasing in value towards zero. The lag six proxy variable is statistically zero. We interpret this result to indicate that the impact of innovation on price growth is time dependent but declining in statistical importance over time. For our data set we observe a statistical window of five years of innovation impacting current mineral price growth. Finally, Table 8 shows some alternative regression results with respect to world value product and price growth. Column 2 shows a re-estimation of our main regression model adding in dummy variables to account for four major shocks that occurred in the 20th century; First 13 Theory does not provide a prediction about how long before the effect of innovation is seen in prices. We maintain an IV estimator for cumulative production. 14 20 World War (DWWI-1914-1917), Second World War (DWWII-1939-1945), a world depression (Ddep-1929-1935) and a major world recession (Dres-1980-1986). From the results displayed, these shocks although perhaps important in their own right have little or no impact on marginal effects of interest to this research and are not considered further. Regressions 2 and 3 in columns 3 and 4 of Table 8 show the reduced form results using the Earth IV. Regression 2 uses all minerals available for the Earth IV including the end points, whereas, regression 3 repeats the exercise but drops the end point observations. In general both sets of regression results confirm our earlier findings on an important negative elasticity between innovation and price growth but note the comparatively large standard errors on the estimated world value coefficients in Table 8 compared to regression 2 in Table 7. This might suggest that the Earth IV is not as statistically efficient as the standard lagged IV. It does however show robustness in our main result. Finally, the last regression reported in column 5 augments the main regression specification by including proxy variables for market power on both the demand and supply side of the market. Lagged IV procedures for both world value product and cumulative production are used in combination with the Fixed Effect estimator in estimation. By introducing the power proxies we suffer a serious reduction in sample size and number of minerals used in the regression but we do obtain a more complete variable specification of our reduced form model. Interestingly the Herfindahl specification results in much higher elasticity of world value product (by almost an order of magnitude) compared to the main reduced form equations. In any case the Herfindahl specification shows both demand and supply power proxies unimportant in estimation. 21 Overall the statistical results obtained using many different regression specifications are consistent in the findings of our main theoretical hypothesis of endogenous innovation impacting the growth in mineral prices. 5 Conclusions References Acemoglu, Daron, “Directed Technical Change” Review of Economic Studies, 2002, 69 (October), 781-810. -- “Equilibrium Bias of Technology” Econometrica, 2007, 75 (September),1371-1409. Barnett, Harold J. and Chandler Morse, Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of Natural Resource Availability, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University, University Press, 1963. Choi, I. 2001. “Unit root tests for panel data,” Journal of International Money and Finance 20: 249–272. De Cian, Enrica, “Factor-Augmenting Technical Change: An Empirical Analysis,” Resource and Energy Economics, 2008, (forthcoming). Enders, W. 2010, Applied Econometric Time Series Wiley. Farzin, Y. H., “The Time Path of Scarcity Rent in the Theory of Exhaustible Resources,” The Economic Journal, 1992, (July), 813-830. Gaudet, Gerard, Canadian Journal of Economic, 2007, (November). Hotelling, Harold, “The Economics of Exhaustible Resources,” Journal of Political Economy, 1931, (April), 137-175. Im, K. S., M. H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin. 2003. “Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels,” Journal of Econometrics 115: 53-74. Kellard, Neil and Marc A. Wohar, “On the Prevalence of Trends of Primary Commodities,” Journal of Development Economics, 2006, 79, 146-167, 12 Kelly, T.D. and G. R. Matos, “Historical statistics for mineral and material commodities in the United States,” U.S. Geological Survey Data Series 140 (http://pubs.usgs.gov/ds/2005/140/), 2007. 22 Kennedy, Charles, “Induced Bias in Innovation and the Theory of Distribution,” The Economic Journal, 1964, 74 (September), 541-547. Krautkraemer, Je_rey A., “Nonrenewable Resource Scarcity," Journal of Economic Literature, 1998, 36, 2065-2107. Loury, Glenn C., “A Theory of 'Oil'igopoly: Cournot Equilibrium in Exhaustible Resource Markets with Fixed Supplies,” International Economic Review, 1986, 27, 285-301. Mueller and Gorin, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1984. Perck, Peter and Roberts, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1986. Polasky, Stephen, “Do Oil Producers Act as 'Oil'igopolists?,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1992, 22. Popp, David, “Induced Innovation and Energy Prices,” American Economic Review, 2002, 92, 160-180. Salant, Stephen W., “Exhaustible Resources and Industrial Structure: A Nash-Cournot Approach to the World Oil Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 1974, 84 (October), 1079-1093. Schulze, William, “The Optimal Use of Non-Renewable Resources: The Theory of Extraction,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1974, 1, 53-73. Slade, Margaret M., “Trends in Natural-Resource Commodity Prices: An Analysis of the Time Domain,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1982, 9, 122-137. Smith, V. Kerry, Scarcity and Growth Revisited 1977. Smulders, Sjak and Michiel de Nooij, “The Impact of Energy Conservation on Technology and Economic Growth,” Resource and Energy Economics, 2003, 25, 59-79. Solow, Robert M. and Henry F. Wan, “Extraction Costs in the Theory of Exhaustible Resources,” Bell Journal of Economics, 1976, pp. 359-370. Stiglitz, Joseph E., \Growth with Exhaustible Natural Resources: Efficient and Optimal Growth Paths” Review of Economic Studies, 1974, 41, 123-137. 23