INFRASTRUCTURE AS A VEHICLE FOR COMMUNITY BUILDING: AN URBAN DESIGN STRATEGY FOR IZTAPALAPA, MEXICO CITY by George H. Beane MASSACHUSETTS INSTIT(ITF Bachelor of Arts in Architecture Yale University JUN 29 2015 ARC OF TECHNOLOLGY New Haven, Connecticut (2008) Submitted to the Department of Architecture and the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degrees of LIBRARIES & MASTER IN CITY PLANNING MASTER OF SCIENCE IN ARCHITECTURE STUDIES at the MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY June 2015 George H. Beane. All Rights Reserved The author here by grants to MIT the permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of the thesis document in whole or in part in any medium now known or hereafter created. -- Author Signature redacted Department of Urban Studies and Planning Department of Architecture May 21, 2015 Certified by Signature redacted 7 Assistant Professor, Deart Certified by rs Gabriella Carolini and Planning (1T1sis Supervisor Signature redacted \ Rafi Segal Associate Professor, Department of Architecture Thesis Supervisor Signature redacted Accepted by Dennis Frenchman Chair, MCP Committee Department of Urban Studies and Planning Accepted by Takehiko Nagakura Assgiate Professor of Design and Computation Department of Architecture Committee on Graduate Students TITLE Infrastructure as a Vehicle For Community Building: An Urban Design Strategy for Iztapalapa, Mexico City AUTHOR George H. Beane ABSTRACT Mexico City suffers from flooding, water scarcity, pollution, subsidence and enormous financial costs related to water infrastructure. Poor governance contributes to the city's water troubles by creating overlapping political organizations whose interests and administrative purview often conflict. This thesis proposes decentralized water infrastructures implemented at the neighborhood scale, that engage directly with dominant institutional arrangements - namely, the complicated relationship between local government and social organizations representing the needs of informal settlements. The proposal articulates x) a site-specific exploration of design solutions for improving water service in one neighborhood of lztapalapa, 2) a template for coupled social and hydrological development that can be replicated elsewhere in the borough, and 3) a broad argument for multi-performative infrastructure that incorporates, and strengthens, existing reserves of social and political capital. Through these strategies, the thesis addresses the question of how urban designers can use physical infrastructure to not only improve basic service provision but also create new opportunities for community building within and between marginalized urban settlements. Submitted to the Department of Architecture and the Department of Urban Studies and Planning on May 212015 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degrees of Master in City Planning & Master of Science in Architecture Studies. ADVISOR Gabriellia Carolini Assistant Professor Department of Urban Studies & Planning ADVISOR Rafi Segal Associate Professor Department of Architecture iii CONTENTS 1 INTRODUCTION 5 Since the 16th Century, public authorities in Mexico City have managed water resources through centralized water infrastructures. This approach has not resolved recurring problems of scarcity, flooding, and sewage treatment, which disproportionally affected the urban poor concentrated in the eastern regions of the Federal District. The thesis addresses a fundamental problem of water resources management, with a focus on its strategies for informal settlements, and a methodology that combines ethnographic research, mapping, and design. 2 GOVERNANCE 15 Chapter Two describes the existing regulatory structures that oversee water management at the municipal level, and outlines Mexico's experiments with decentralizing water governance. Using examples from other low-income and informal settlements, I argue that social and political capital must be valued in the design of physical infrastructure, and that neglecting to do so risks the long-term sustainabiltiy of that infrastructure. 3 CONTEXT 25 In lztapalapa, one of Mexico City's sixteen boroughs, marginalized communities at the borough's southeastern border suffer greatest from poor water service. In these areas, the predominant institutional forces are 'social organizations' that co-govern along formal government agencies, through a system of political clientelism. Such organizations are so entrenched and so powerful in neighborhoods where they operate, that new models for local-level water infrastructure must engage them in the creation and management of new infrastructures. iv 4 PROPOSAL 5 Chapter Five proposes a nieghborhood-level network of decentralized "nodes" for water collection and retention, and emphasizes the visibility and visual prominence of such infrastructure, and the potential for new urban spaces defined by various forms of water infrastructure. This design is considered in the context of the local institutional bodies necessary for governing, financing and maintaining water infrastructure. It suggests a repIciable strategy for siting infrastructures along a central axis, which supplies needed civic and water-managmeent services to local residents. 5 CONCLUSION 15 The thesis returns to the principle that the design of physical infrastructure can and should be informed by issues of power, politics and relevant local institutions. Conversely, the manipulation of physical form can offer a meaningful tool for institutional reform in local communities. New approaches to water management in Mexico City should deliberatlively align themselves with the realities of local institutional context, engaging with the actual, rather than idealized, landscapes of local governance. Neighborhood models of decentralized infrastructure will employ infrastructure as a multi-performative tool, exhibiting a 'pragmatic idealism' in its ambitions for pragmatic resource management and broad institutional change. V ACKNOWLEDGMENTS With sincere thanks to Gabriella Carolini and Rafi Segal, my co-advisors on this project; to my colleagues in the SmarchS Urbanism program (Wenji, Agu, Gabriel, David, Chaewon, Manos, Kairav, Naichun, Difei, and Ariel) for their support over the past two years; to Lorena Bello Gomez, for her advice and support; for Yolanda Cervantes, Raul Trejo, David Adler, and Raul Gutierrez Calder6n who shared insight and resources that form the basis for this study; and for Susan Szenasy for her encouragement. vi vii CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION The proposal here addresses the need for water and sanitation infrastructure in the neighborhood of Iztapalapa, Mexico City. Implicit in this scheme is an argument for a model of infrastructure in which urban design is grounded in the institutional qualities of a place. The thesis argues that designers should understand infrastructure not just in the context of geographic or landscape considerations, but in light of institutional relationships that can improve the effectiveness, and extend the lives of physical objects. As such, the project attempts to articulate a design process in which infrastructure can both respond to and strengthen complex urban social and political systems. - The choice to situate this argument in the context of Mexico City's faulty water infrastructure is deliberate. The inadequacy of urban water infrastructure is a problem at the global scale, and has particular relevance to informal settlements, where almost a third of the world's population currently lives (UN Habitat 2012, 2). Mexico City offers an ideal case in a number of ways; as a megacity, in which most land production over the past half century has occurred irregularly, the Mexican capital is emblematic of the type of urban growth and the sorts of urban problems - that confront the current generation of urbanists. In practical terms, it is reasonably accessible as a study site, and maintains fairly good data on topics relevant to this thesis. At the same time, the urgency of the water crisis makes water and sanitation (WatSan) infrastructure an ideal vehicle for influencing institutions. Water carries with it a profound intrinsic and emotional value in a way that other infrastructural goods do not. Academic debates over water as an economic good or a human right - which implicitly recognize it as both - sum up its complexity. Water is, simultaneously, a necessary ingredient for human life, an economic commodity, an ecological element, and a religiously charged substance. And, in a way that other physical infrastructure does not, addressing issues of water supply and sanitation has direct bearings on the broader health of urban societies, as demonstrated by discrete epidemics, and perennially high mortality rates associated with diarrhea, the second leading cause of death in children worldwide (WHO 2013). Not surprisingly, then, access to clean water is often a rallying cry for political and social mobilization. In this light, physical infrastructure becomes the manifestation of community demands, as well as a primary tool for improving public health. That infrastructure assumes such varied and complicated meanings, also makes it an ideal topic of investigation within multiple disciplines. Simultaneously, it can be understood as a set of tangible objects whose physicality shapes people's interactions in real space, and the product of rban systems that are influenced by institutions and responsive to particular historical conditions. Ultimately, this thesis investigates both physical and social properties of infrastructure in an attempt to better understand the potential for urban design as a mechanism of community 'upgrading.' 8 INTRODUCTION ; - A ===,sow ~: .~ ~ !11 J7 a I ~ *< ~ i-. 1.1 THE PROBLEM Historically, with the growth of Mexico City, local populations segregated along ethnic and economic lines, and according to physical boundaries demarcated by access to water resources and risk (Legoretta 2008). Accordingly, the western edges of the city, which are less prone to seasonal flooding and closer to water sources, are typically wealthier (and whiter) than the rest of the city. To the east, illegal settlers, attracted by cheap land prices and lax property regulations, have historically settled in flood-prone areas. Citywide, almost one fifth of illegal settlers live in riverbeds, mostly on the eastern edge of the city (WWF 2011, 22). Since the 1960s, a general pattern of illegal land invasion has become the dominant form of land production in the capital: large properties are illegally subdivided and sold to residents seeking to escape the crowded inner city, or drawn to the capital for its abundant economic resources and employment opportunities. The new residents lay out their settlement according to a regular grid pattern, with electric lines laid out, and roads paved. Finally, water lines are extended. Though residents do not possess official deeds to their property, a reasonable expectation of formalization is born out after a few decades. At that point, the settlements are neighborhoods, largely indistinguishable from the rest of the city. The trend of physical municipal expansion - driven in large part by the growth of these informal communities along the capital's eastern fringe - places heavy demands on the city's water infrastructure. In Mexico City, rapid urbanization in the second half of the 20th century led to fast, massive expansion of water infrastructure to keep pace with nascent population demand. Existing water infrastructure, built in the 16th century and continuously updated to manage the enormous growth of city, now services a population of over 22 million people. When water from the valley's 48 rivers proved insufficient, city leadership looked beyond the Valley of Mexico for additional supply. First in the 1940s, and then in the 1970s, government-approved projects to pipe water from the Lerma Valley (62 km away) and the Cutzamala River (130 km) (Legoretta 2008, 74-80). Within the capital, water is distributed through a primary network of 1074 km of pipes, and a secondary network of 12,278 km (Tortajada 2006,360). Pipes also manage the removal of waste outside of the naturally closed water basin, carrying 40 cubic meters / second of sewage north of the city, where it is deposited into the Tula River and eventually carried into the Gulf of Mexico. Only one fourth of the city's sewage is currently treated (Burns 2009, 39). The Atononilco plant, the metropolitan area's largest treatment facility, lies 90 km outside of the city and treats 3.6 million tons of wastewater per day (Acevedo, Bogdan, et al. 2013, 11). The plant is owned and operated by Slim, a private company that retains exclusive rights to wastewater treatment in the metropolitan region (Acevedo, Bogdan, et al. 2013, 12; Acevedo, Bogdan, et al. 2013, 17). Twenty six other plants operate within the Federal District, with a combined actual treatment of 3430 liters per second (or approximately 300,000 gallons per day) (Estadisticas del Agua de la Region Hidrologica 2009,103). Despite the massive investment in cost and energy required to plan, realize and maintain these infrastructural systems, Mexico City today suffers from many of the same problems it confronted in the 17th century. Summer flooding, occurring in increasing frequency over the past half century, is compounded by poor drainage and inadequate sewer infrastructure that leads to sewage backups. Conversely, citywide demand, estimated at 74 cubic meters / second, exceeds system capacity of 64 cubic meters / second (Soto Montes de Oca and Bateman 2006, 4). Seasonal droughts necessitate private delivery of water to municipalities and colonias within the metropolitan region, at great cost to the private citizens and government, which often subsidizes water delivery 11 through delivery of trucked water, called pipas. The quality of the water that arrives in households is low; studies show bacteria contamination rates of approximately 40% for water supply, with higher contamination rates of groundwater sources (Mazari-Hiriart, Lopez-Vidal and Calva 2001, 93) (Mazari-Hiriart et al. 2005, 5131). Notwithstanding the enormous investment in infrastructure needed to pipe water into the city from outside the basin, external water sources accounts for only 31% of the capital's water supply (Tortajada 2006, 360). The rest, drawn from approximately 2,000 wells, between 2oo and 400 meters deep, draw from the city's I Spatial divisions can intensify pronounced differences in quality of service provision. For instance, writing about India, Chaplin finds that segregation of rich and poor reinforced political divides between suburban middle classes and the urban poor, which reduces pressure on government to improve universal conditions (Chaplin 1999, 150). 2 Even these numbers, which rely on data from CONAGUA and SACMEX, may exaggerate water access. Figures for water quantity also ignore the low quality of water resources available in economically marginalized communities (Acevedo et al. 2013, 22). 3 A more recent estimate by the Centro Mario Molina, which includes drainage infrastructure in its final tally, puts the number at $3.1 billion. At the time of writing (anuary 2015) and from this point onwards, I will use the exchange rate of $1 US = $14.7 MX. FILLING WATER BARRELS during dry winter months (photo credit: Rodolpho Angulo). 12 INTRODUCTION 14 underground aquifers. This has led to overexploitation of the city's 14 aquifers, and an annual subsidence rates of between 5 and 40 cm per year (Centro Mario Molino 2012, 391; WWF 2011, 6). Of course, as the city sinks, building foundations shift and pipes crack, increasing the risks of contamination to the system. Additionally, the old gravityfed exit routes for sewage water have sunk too, increasing the energy cost of pumping wastewater out of the basin and into the Tula River. Estimates put energy costs associated with water pumping for water supply and waste removal for Mexico City at o.6% of the country's total electrical energy generated (WWF 2011, 6). The residents of the city's informal neighborhoods are the most heavily impacted by the water problems; flooding is most pronounced in low-lying eastern neighborhoods, and water provision is highly inconsistent. In their comparative study of the delegaciones within the Federal District, Montes de Oca and Batement find lower service rates in poorer neighborhoods of Iztapalapa and Iztacalco, where high percentage of residents reported low water pressure (59%), poor water quality (36%), frequent water shortages (52%), and bottled water consumption (91%). That service deficiencies occur along defined socio-economic boundaries indicates that the populations most affected by water shortages are also those least well-equipped to pay added cost of water delivery (or recover from flood damage in cases of perennial flooding). Similarly, differences in neighborhood consumption rates reflect the deep socio-economic divisions that exist within the city. High rates of household water access (98%) and a citywide aggregated consumption of 297 liters per capita per day mask the deep inequalities of municipal-level water provision (WWF 2011, 6). Minimum daily water intake is typically considered 15- 25 liters per person per day, a consumption rate similar to that experienced in Mexico City's poorer neighborhoods. In contrast, consumption in the city's wealthier, western regions can reach upwards of 6oo liters per person per day (Tortajada 2006,362). 1.2 THE LARGE-SCALE INFRASTRUCTURAL APPROACH Estimates for Mexico City's Cutzamala Water System, the metropolitan area's primary external supply system, indicate aggregated costs of $1.3 billion, or "higher than the national investment in the entire public sector in Mexico, in 1996, in the areas of education ($700 million), health and social security ($300 million), agriculture livestock and rural development ($105 million), tourism ($50 million), and the marine sector ($6o million)" (Tortajada 2006,363). Beyond standard operational expenses, large investments in energy 13 are required to support pumping for water supply, wells, drainage and water treatment. Energy use of 2,113,180,775 annual (kWh) results in $224.1 million spent to provide Mexico City with externally sourced water (Centro Mario Molino 2012, 84). Water provision is frequently defined by dual concerns for equity and financial sustainability, yet those principles are frequently at odds with one another (Moe and Rheingans 2oo6, 51). Full cost recovery, which ensures the financial viability of systems and adequate resources for operational and capital expenditures, often results in increased tariffs for lower income users. Efforts to achieve both long-term financial viability and universal coverage have historically led municipalities to subsidize water and sanitation services, a practice which is fiscally unsustainable and can discourage new projects that seek to expand access or service quality (Olmstead 2003, 33). Montes de Oca and Batement report that in Mexico City, the average tariff of 2 pesos per i cubic meter of water (approximately $0.15 US) falls far below the cost estimate of 9 pesos per cubic meter ($o.67 US). That estimate differs from Tortajada's tariff and cost figures of $0.2 US and $o.214, respectively, but confirms the conclusion that gaps between current supply and treatment costs make the system fiscally unsustainable (Tortajada 2006, 360). The realization of new capital projects will only exaggerate the cost deficit. Including projects at every stage of implementation (review, construction, etc.) at least seven large capital works are projected for the Valley of Mexico between 2014-2018, with an estimated price tag that exceeds $3 billion. Additionally, the omisi6n Nacional del Agua (CONAGUA) proposes extracting water from three new sources, all in neighboring states, at undefined cost (CONAGUA 2014-2018). More generally, the scale of the necessary infrastructure carries with it its own associated problems. Buried distribution systems, aging and invisible, are vulnerable to contamination problems, cracks and high leakage rates. Internationally, water loss in industrialized countries, calculated as a percentage of water supplied, ranges from 8 to 24%, with substantially higher average leakage rates reported in developing countries (Moe and Rheingans 2006,43). 14 INTRODUCTION Mexico City's nonrevenue water rate, exacerbated by dated infrastructure, subsidence and seismic activity, is estimated at 30-40% (Tortajada 2003, 124). 1.3 MEXICO CITY'S COLONIAS POPULARES In informal settlements where property owners lack legal title to their land, high population density, haphazard growth patterns, and limited space reduce options for new infrastructures installed retroactively. Iztapalapa shares some of the qualities that characterize WatSan delivery in informal settlements, including substandard facilities, a lack of government investment in infrastructure and, perhaps most importantly, high rates of poverty at the household level. But in Mexico City and elsewhere, the formal / informal distinction may be more useful in describing historical ambiguities in legal status than as a set of physical qualities that characterize current conditions with any degree of specificity. Some development economists argue that 'informal' assumes multiple meanings in the academic literature, is understood largely in opposition to 'formal' but lacks specificity in its own right (Hernandez, Kellet and Allen 2010; Guha-Khasnobis, Kanbur and Ostrom 2007; Sindzingere 2006). Meanwhile, scholars of land use and property rights are inclined to describe ownership as a "bundle of rights" than as a single right; to discuss ownership as a spectrum between full and zero legality (Payne 200); to admit the co-existence of informal ownership arrangements within formalized property systems (Ensminger 1997); to recognize the legitimacy of informal property rights (Lanjouw and Levy 2002); and to acknowledge the fluidity of land status, which easily passes from formal to informal (e.g. with failure to pay taxes, or disregard of new building codes). Despite its wide currency in depicting a global phenomenon of extra-legal land production, the term informal may flatten nuances of property ownership regimes at a local level, where communities consist of both informal and formal ownership arrangements, and legal status changes easily and often. 4 Typically, lack of legal status discourages government investment in delivery, storage and waste treatment infrastructure, and insecure land tenure can discourage homeowners from investing in necessary water infrastructure (Katukiza et al. 2012, 965). In developed but informal settlements where renting is common, landlords are often reluctant to invest in new infrastructure for the same reasons, and because tenant recourse is limited given their tenuous legal status (lsunju et al. 2011, 370). Even where tenure security is not a barrier to investment, residents may feel that improved sanitation is a human right and should therefore be provided at low or no cost by government (Bolaane and lkgopoleng 2011, 491). Inadequate household investment in delivery, storage and waste treatment infrastructure often leads to water contamination, which can occur both in transmission and during household storage (Mintz et al. 2001, 1567). Because it is often necessary to teach best practices for water treatment, storage, and hygiene practices, slums may suffer when educational resources are scarce. Slum dwellers may also lack the social networks and kinship ties necessary for developing the institutional capacity for shared sanitation facilities, or the political cohesion necessary to make demands of government agencies (lsunju et al. 2011, 370). ATOTONILCO WASTEWATER TREATMENT PLANT In Hidalgo State, Mexico. 15 i6 INTRODUCTION CIUDAD NEZAHUALC6YOTL Ciudad Neza is a municipality with a population over i million, lying within the greater Mexico City Metropolitan Area but outside the Federal District. Planned and developed by real estate interests and citizen organizations, Ciudad Neza was founded on illegally subdivided land. Unsanctioned by local government, public services and land title were only granted retroactively, through decades of protest and political pressure from local activists. The municipality is fully urban and generally indistinguishable from much of adjacent city; here, "informalism" describes a historical condition rather than an ongoing urbanization process. Still, the lack of planned public spaces manifest this history. Historically, in Mexico City, government policy indirectly encouraged the formation of informal settlements, and then muddied the already ambiguous legal status of those settlements. Although various types of informal settlements had existed in the capital since the colonial era, enormous population growth in the 1950s and 196os, combined with rent freezes, bans on low-income housing subdivisions, and protection of communityowned ejido lands, reduced housing options for Mexico City's urban poor (Zanetta 2004, 84). As a result, families turned away from rental housing options in the city center, and towards illegally developed plots on the city's outskirts (Ward 1998, 47). These, and land invasions of private or publicly owned land, produced colonias populares, informal communities settled by organized coalitions of families, or enterprising real estate developers who illegally subdivided ejido land (community property protected from privatization by the 1917 Mexican Constitution) (Ward 1998, 195). Although official government policy banned the acquisition of these lands, at both the federal and municipal level, politicians and bureaucrats often turned a blind eye to informal developments. Since the 1970s, large-scale national efforts have focused on regularizing properties, resulting in the granting of 700,000 titles in Mexico City between 1969 and 1981 (Zanetta 2004,78). Thus, many of the illegal settlements that absorbed Mexico City's growth in the 1960s have since been formalized and regularized. Though the neighborhoods still bear the imprint of their origins, including a lack of basic infrastructure, informal in this context is best used to describe a historical condition. Currently, almost fifty percent of new housing in the capital is produced informally (Yarza 2014). Given the size of this number, and considering government's tacit support of informal housing production and national policies that regularize illegally occupied land almost as soon as it is occupied, informality is both an ambiguous and a short-lived characterization. In this light, while the literature on service provision in informal settlements is a useful reference in some respects, the scholarship often bears little resemblance to the reality of settlements in Mexico City. Moreover, historical precedents influence the relationship between various levels of government, fragmented community interests, local organizations, and individual actors, and the particular blend of interests and influences present in any given settlement. i8 INTRODUCTION 1.4 METHODOLOGY In this research, I rely on three principal sources. First, I reference existing literature on the topic of Mexico City's recurrent water challenges, the experiences of water service provision in informal settlements elsewhere, and theories of social capital in community development, especially those articulated by the scholar Elinor Ostrom. Second, I employ GIS data gathered from three government agencies in Mexico City: Sistema de Aguas de Ciudad de Mexico (SACMEX), Calidad de Vida (PROCDMX), and the Centro de Evaluaci6n de Riesgo Geol6gico (CERG) in Iztapalapa. I used these data to create a series of analytic maps, informing the choice of site and type of intervention. 5 For instance, scholars writing about Africa often highlight lack of accessibility as a limiting factor in WatSan delivery to informal settlements; where informal settlements are founded according to a more "organic" form, narrow and winding streets make it difficult for tankers to access and empty pit latrines (lsunju et al. 2011, 369). Yet in the case of Mexico City, irregular settlements are often laid out according to a grid, with ample space for car access. Additionally, indoor plumbing is common in the capital, and latrines are rare. Third, my analysis relies heavily on qualitative data gathered over the course of two trips to Mexico City, one an extended two-month stay in July 2014, and the second in January 2015. During both trips, I conducted semi-structured interviews of local government officials, residents, and community leaders in Iztapalapa, Mexico City. I identified participants through local contacts in city government and academia, and with the help of a Fulbright Scholar, David Adler, whose own work focused on the political life of social organizations in lztapalapa. I conducted one site visit and one interview in Miravalle, a community along the Sierra de Santa Catarina, and three sets of interviews and site visits to Yuguelito, a small informal settlement near lztapalapa's border with the borough of Tlalpan. The interviews were by no exhaustive, but they introduced and explored some of the larger themes this work addresses - namely, political fragmentation and service provision within the delegacion, and the role of clientelistic politics in determining which communities are provided water service, according to what schedule. This project is both research and design proposal, and as such, the choice of site combines considerations of access -- where I could gather substantive information on local communities - and geo-spatial characteristics - such as the availability of vacant land, topography and water. The result is that the proposal includes areas that fall within Tlahuac, 19 a delegacion that neighbors lztapalapa to its south, and the includes communities whose leadership 1 did not contact. While acknowledging these information gaps, I nonetheless assume the broader system of politics and patterns of land production described in the academic literature and my own interviews in small communities, apply to the more expansive site chosen for this design exercise. 20 INTRODUCTION 1.5 SCOPE OF THESIS The thesis is roughly split into two sections. In Part i, I describe the theoretical, historical and geographic context which my design proposal engages. Chapter One defines the essential problem, briefly describes informal settlements in Mexico City, and argues for water and sanitation infrastructure as an appropriate vehicle for institutional change. Chapter Two outlines the costs associated with Mexico City's centralized WatSan infrastructure, examines the role of governance in exacerbating water provision, and argues for the inclusion of social and political capital as critical components of infrastructural design. Chapter Three discusses theories of institutional change in the context of water struggles in Mexico City. Part 2 outlines the thesis' main design proposal in the context Iztapalapa, a historically founded informal settlement in the east of Mexico City. Chapter Four describes the neighborhood - its physical and institutional landscape, including demographics, local stakeholders, and political and civic organizations. Chapter Five proposes a pilot design that considers the potential for decentralized networks, for public "nodes" oriented towards water service provision (collection, provision, etc.), the visibility and visual prominence of such infrastructure, and the potential for new urban spaces defined by various forms of water infrastructure. This design is considered in the context of the local institutional bodies necessary for governing, financing and maintaining water infrastructure. The design proposal thus traces the potential ripple effect of implementing the new WASH 'skeleton' on the physical and institutional landscape of the community. Finally, in Chapter Six, the thesis returns to its initial argument - namely, that the design of physical infrastructure can and should be informed by issues of power, politics and local institutions and, conversely, that the manipulation of physical form can offer a meaningful tool for institutional reform in local communities. 21 CHAPTER 2: GOVERNANCE The challenges outlined above are directly the result of deficiencies in the physical networks of WatSan delivery, but the provision of water and sanitation services is also inherently tied to issues of governance. Academic scholars and development agencies identify the importance of good governance in ensuring provision of water and sanitation. For instance, USAID, UNDP, the World Bank, the EC, the UN Water and Sanitation Program, and the Global Water Partnership (GWP) all recognize water governance as a key element in improving the lives of urban poor (Harris et al. 2011, 2). In their work on Jakarta, Bakker et al. report that governance failure due to poor pricing strategies, counterproductive land use policies, antipoor service provision business models, etc. was a more important cause of deficient service provision than was natural scarcity. Successful water services thus rely heavily on "clear standards for good governance (such as accountability, transparency, participation, inclusiveness, and the rule of law)" (Bakker 2008, 1899-1900). 2.1 INSTITUTIONS AND WATER GOVERNANCE IN MEXICO Within Mexico, government water agencies operate with overlapping responsibilities on different administrative scales, complicating WatSan service provision at the local level. The existing institutional arrangements of water governance, characterized by unclear boundaries between federal, state and municipal water authorities, are directly tied to Mexico's experiments with political decentralization in the late 1980s and 1990s.7 Following broader trends towards increased local community participation, in 1992 Mexico formally passed the Law of National Waters, which adopts Integrated Water Resource Management (IWRM) as a guiding principle of federal water policy. The Comisi6n Nacional del Agua (CONAGUA), created in 1989 is divided into 13 administrative basin regions, which handle water management at the regional level. The agency is responsible for measuring hydrologic data, water conservation policies for sustainable development, technical and social water control (Mestre, 2009). Beyond this, water management responsibilities are divided into 13 administrative regions, and 102 sub-regions based on political jurisdictions Each of the thirteen regional basins are divided into two groups - a Basin Agency which is responsible for designing and implementing local water policy, and a Basin Council, made up of representatives from local stakeholders, which advises the Agency on decisions (Acevedo, et al. 2013, 6). 22 GOVERNANCE 6 Throughout the paper, I use United Nation's definition of governance as "the exercise of economic, political and administrative authority to manage a country's affairs at all levels...comprises the mechanisms processes and institutions through which citizens and group articulate their interests, exercise their legal rights, meet their obligations and mediate their differences" (UNDP 2006). I use on Elinor Ostrom's definition of institutions: "Broadly defined, institutions are the prescriptions that humans use to organize all forms of repetitive and structured interactions including those within families, neighborhoods, markets, firms, sports leagues, churches, private associations, and governments at all scales" (Ostrom 2009, 3). 23 7 Political power in Mexico has historically been centralized in the presidency. However, beginning in the 1980s, largely because of neoliberal economic policies, the country moved decisively towards political decentralization, with political decisions at the federal level devolved financial responsibilities to thirty one state governments, and the Federal District. Under President Salinas de Gortari (19881994) federal government increased funding of local municipalities through discretionary programs, whose administration became increasingly transparent under the Zedillo presidency (Smoke, Gomez, Peterson 2006, 268). That the largest recipients of funding were traditional supporters of the PRI (Partido Revolucionario Institucional), Mexico's oldest and most dominant political party, hints at political motives for these efforts; increases in funding and transparency may reflect a political hedging, an effort to institutionalize political support of key PRI states in the face of political challenges from rival PAN (Partido Acci6n Nacional) and PRD (Partido de la Revoluci6n DemocrAtica). Greater political competition at the subnational level has led to new political leaders operating outside of the traditional PRI dominated party system, who push for further decentralization (Beer 2004, 191). The effect has been increased decentralization at the state level, though there exist "enormous variation in levels of political competition among the states and between some subnational political environments and the national government" (Beer 2004, 182). Despite federal reforms intended to devolve decisionmaking to the local level, the practical effect of these policies has been mixed. As of 2005, 25 of the 26 planned basin councils were not functional for practical purposes, indicating low stakeholder participation due to lack of technical and managerial experience, reluctance of the authorities to disseminate reliable data, undervaluing of stakeholders participation, and poor economic pricing regimes (Tortajada 2005,125; Scott and Banister 20o8). Basin Council decisions are not legally binding and, in the case of Mexico City, the local Basin Council does not meet regularly or carry out any duties (Acevedo et al. 2013, 13). A lack of enforcement and administrative overlap also stymies effective water governance. For instance, although CONAGUA retains the legal power to sanction those who violate extraction agreements, the agency claims not to have enough inspectors to enforce concessions (despite its staff of 13,406 national employees in 2008) and concession-holders self-report water use. (Acevedo et al. 2013, 15). At the same time, while water management has officially been devolved to local authorities, in practice CONAGUA is responsible for approving concession applications and grants approval to individual users seeking use of local water resources. These concessionary powers make CONAGUA the preeminent water authority in the country. In Mexico City, CONAGUA controls concessions to those users who extract from underground aquifers, an estimated 70% of water users. Additionally, since most local water agencies lack the financial and/ or human resources to build or modernize infrastructure, CONAGUA often defines the agendas of local water institutions (Barkin 2011, 382). Local groups often do not have a formal information system that allows them to share data with counterparts higher up in administrative circles, and oversight over local water agencies is minimal or nonexistent. (Barkin 2011,383). Even within CONAGUA, programs to improve efficiency in water provision lack feedback mechanisms and suffer from "incongruence and ill-defined system boundaries" (CCA 2013, 17). Low cost recovery contributes to failures of local water governance. SACMEX, the Federal District's municipal water provider, prices water according to an increasing 24 GOVERNANCE Block Water Tariffs (IBT) model, which may have unintended adverse effects on poor households that share water connections among many members, and therefore pay higher costs per person (Whittington 1992, 75). Moreover, the tariff does not account for sewerage costs, sanitation costs or depreciation, and is undersupported by federal sources. (Acevedo et al. 2013, 16). Since 1994, in two ten-year contracts, four private companies have been quietly hired to establish a user registry, install meters, repair secondary pipe networks, and collect fees on behalf of SACMEX (Maranon 2004, 178). Because those companies are paid on the number, rather the volume of water connections they collect, they are incentivized to bill individual households. The largest consumers of water - industrial and commercial users - frequently do not pay their full share (Acevedo et al. 2013, 16). Unsustainable revenues mean that federal and municipal authorities often lack the resources to implement proper maintenance. Mexico thus suffers from a crisis of governance, in which "in the absence of an operational and developmental role for the state in Mexico, there exists an 'institutional vacuum' with few civil institutions capable of replacing the roles and functions of the state" (Wilder and Lankao 2006, 1992 citing Dejanvry et al. 1997). Consequently, efforts to strengthen service provision at the grassroots level must address both the physical and institutional challenges described above. The following sections propose decentralized infrastructure as one alternative to the existing system, and suggest broad principles for how decentralized infrastructure might be implemented to strengthen local water governance. 2.2 REALIZING THE PROMISES OF DECENTRALIZED WATER GOVERNANCE Political decentralization is broadly understood as the devolution of authority by central government to independent regional and local governments (Faguet, 2014,4). Proponents of decentralization argue for its positive effect on governance and public sector outputs, by localizing politics and thus increasing public officials' responsiveness to citizens. In theory, decentralized government can reduce abuses of power, grant greater governing authority to minority populations, and increase political competition (Faguet 2014, 2). Empirically, the political-economic literature suggests generally positive results where governments have distributed political and fiscal resources, though, as Bardhan writes, "most of the studies are largely descriptive, not analytical, and often suggest correlations rather than causal processes" (Bardhan 2002, 200). Nonetheless, there is evidence indicating the benefits of decentralization, including strong negative correlations between fiscal decentralization and corruption (Smoke, Gomez, Peterson 2006, 20 citing Fisman and Gatti 2001); "closer" government, which is more likely to respond to local concerns (de Mello 2000, 7); and improved social capital, including greater confidence in government and increased social activity (de Mello 2000, 9). Decentralization has been a formalized and consistently reaffirmed tenet of international water management since 1992, when the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development assumed Integrated Water Resources Management (IWRM) as best practice, and adopted participatory governance as a key feature in national water policies (Rahaman and Varis 2005, 17).' According to a 2012 UN Status Report, 78% of 133 countries polled claimed to have aligned national water policies with an 1WRM model (UN-Water, 2012, 12). Repeatedly, international conferences on development have linked IWRM principles on local water governance to poverty alleviation.9 Simultaneously - though not always linked to national level policies - low-income communities have experimented with decentralized, on-site water and sanitation infrastructure as a way of increasing affordability and service coverage, while ensuring greater community participation and flexibility in service provision. 25 8 The Global Water Partnership (GWP) an international advocate for IWRM promotes participatory action, makes the links between decentralization and community participation explicit: participation is best achieved through "decentralizing decision making to the lowest level" 9 According to Rahaman and Varis (2005) In addition to the Rio Declaration, the Second World Water Forum in 2000, the World Summit on Sustainable development in 2002, the Third World Water Forum in 2003, and the UN Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) reaffirmed support for IWRM principles (Rahaman and Varis 2005, 17) Yet, as seen in Mexico, decentralization at the local level frequently falls short of the aspirations articulated in federal policy. The discrepancy is often due to lack of adequate enforcement at the local level. For instance, while Pakistani law mandates some degree of water cost-recovery, only 7% of rural households countrywide pay for water, largely because local authorities lack of realistic mechanisms for providing water to those unable to pay (Nawab and Nyborg 2009, 588). Insufficient coordination among sectors (i.e. academic and government), levels (i.e. national and local), and bureaucratic agencies may also frustrate attempts to provide water and sanitation services (Nawab and Nyborg 2009, 583; Tsagarakis et al. 2001). For instance, in Haiti, despite national laws supporting decentralized water governance, lack of coordination between government agencies, overlapping laws and unclear parceling of responsibility among federal and state level water agencies has resulted in an inefficient water management regime (Stoa 2014, 36). Where federal law explicitly acknowledges the role of community in creating water policy, as is the case in Pakistan, local governments often still have trouble finding appropriate venues for community participation, attracting truly representative members of local communities, and engaging with women (Nawab and Nyborg 2009,583). More generally, the way decentralization is implemented may have broad, unintended effects on the transparency of local government. If strong, democratic institutions are not already in place at the local level, decentralizing funds and authority may, in fact, increase authoritarianism and decrease government accountability (Oxhorn, Tulchion, Selee 2004); make local government (and federal funds) more vulnerable to capture by local elites (Bardhan 2002, 192); increase local dependency on federal funding sources, with potentially harmful results for national economies (Montero and Samuels, 2004); and lead to problematic spending behavior at the local level, as local governments look for national government for bailouts in exchange for votes (Fauget 2013, 8). Ultimately, as Bardhan writes, "decentralization, to be really effective, has to accompany serious attempts to change the existing structures of power within communities and to improve the opportunities for participation and voice and 26 GOVERNANCE engaging the hitherto disadvantaged or disenfranchised in the political process" (Bardhan 2002, 202). In other words, while decentralized government structures may contribute to good governance, the theorized benefits of decentralization are realized through the work of local institutions, not federal mandate. The successful experience of community WatSan systems, illustrated below in cases from Pakistan and Latin America, suggest lessons for how local institutions might realize physical infrastructure and good governance as mutually reinforcing forces. 2.3 CASE STUDIES In her seminal work on common-pool management institutions, Elinor Ostrom emphasizes the importance of human capital (knowledge and skills) and social capital (interaction among individuals) in complementing physical capital (material resources). She argues that because facilities are not operated or maintained automatically, institutions should encourage the growth of social capital as a necessary quality for development (Ostrom 1994, 20-23). Ostrom writes, "it is a mistake to design irrigation and other development projects on the presumption that physical capital is the most important input factor" (Ostrom 1994, 20). Scholars have since supplemented Ostrom's list of community capital by acknowledging the importance of political capital (influence over resource distribution), natural capital (environmental resources) and cultural capital (community values) (Flora 2004,8). Some of the most successful WatSan programs implemented in poor urban communities have relied on local reserves of social, human and political capital to realize ambitious infrastructures in areas with few apparent resources. The Orangi Pilot Project (OPP) in Karachi, Pakistan is one example of a large, informal, low-income community mobilizing for improved WatSan coverage, in the face of provision deficits from local government.' 0 In a second example, from Brazil, partnerships between local government and users developed "condominial" networks of small pipes, buried shallow in the ground. Extensive networks address the needs of growing water and sanitation needs of populations in the peri-urban surroundings of large Brazilian cities (Melo 2005, 7). Both projects serve as useful models for the Mexico case, to outline some characteristics of successful community implementation and management of WatSan systems. Though the projects exist in very different geographic, political and cultural contexts, there are some basic similarities that recommend them as suitable precedents for community action in the peri-urban neighborhoods of Mexico City. In each case, target populations are urban, informally settled, low-income, and large. The sanitation component of the OPP currently serves around 1oo,ooo households in informal settlements of Karachi, with an additional 5o,ooo households involved in replication projects implemented throughout the country. Similarly, condiminial sewerage programs have been used widely for both sanitation and water provision, including in Brasilia, where 500,000 people benefit from improved sewerage systems (Melo 2005, 7). Orangi has also been studied extensively since the OPP sanitation project was founded in 1988, and condiminial sewerage projects in Brazil date from the 1980s. In both instances, citizen and government groups work together to create practical solutions that addressed both the need for new infrastructure, and the necessity of long-term maintenance of WatSan systems. 27 2.4 SPATIAL ORGANIZATION AS A TOOL FOR COMMUNITY BUILDING The critical innovation of OPP's sanitation project is that of internal-external sanitation provision, which assigns responsibilities for infrastructure along strict spatial borders. Organizational units, which correspond to geographic scales - from household to neighborhood - order construction, maintenance, and financial interactions. According to this model, residents are responsible for household latrines, underground sewers in lanes, and neighborhood collector sewers ("internal" infrastructure) while local government builds and manages trunk sewers and treatment plants ("external" infrastructure) (Hasan 2006, 458). Separating community and government responsibilities allows integration of existing sewage networks into new plans." Responsibility for internal infrastructure is partitioned further according to scalar divisions within the neighborhood. Individual households are responsible for providing sanitary latrines; lanes (20-30 households) create underground sewerage lines and connections; at the neighborhood level, secondary or collector drains (Boyatzis and Khawaja 2014, 295). Households can pay off the cost of lane sewage lines in installments to lane managers, who are elected by households in each lane (Boyatzis and Khawaja 2014, 296; Hasan zoo8, 115). In this way, natural geographic boundaries organize actors into community units that maintain the neighborhood sanitation system. Many of the innovations of the OPP were developed separately in the Brazilian model. There, a division between public and "condiminial" or resident-developed branches, also reduced costs, established clear responsibilities of participants and brought traditional service providers and residents together (Melo 2005, 6). 2.5 EVOLUTION OF COMMUNITY ORGANIZATIONS Ostrom argues that once established, institutions may be used "to accomplish entirely different joint activities at much lower start-up costs" (Ostrom 1994, 20). Supporting that hypothesis, the OPP has diversified into a variety of functions beyond its original purpose of sanitation provision. Currently, the OPP manages community housing and education programs, water supply systems, women's savings programs, research and training, mapping, micro enterprise credit, and health programs (OPPinstitutions.org). The programs are instrumental in their own right, but some, including community credit programs are also tools for building trust in the community and between local community organizations and OPP (Welle zoo6, 22). Where local organizations are most successful, they often invest heavily in human capital. The OPP-RTl (Research and Training Institute) runs training programs that operate along a similar model, teaching residents mapping, surveying, and planning, designing and cost estimating low cost sanitation (OPPinstitutions. org). Similarly, in Honduras, AguaClara, a US-based nonprofit that has co-built eight rural community water systems since 2005, sponsors training programs for local operators in a variety of hard and soft skills including accounting, leadership, teamwork, health, water quality measuring, legal frameworks for water quality, water treatment, technology (M. Gonzalez Rivas et al 2014, 568). Developing such skills within communities are especially important in light of the fact that as much as 30-40% of built water systems is dysfunctional at any moment (Lockwood and Smits 2011 cited in Rivas et al. 2014, 567). Considering that maintenance is a key cause of infrastructural failure, local partners are critical players in ensuring the sustainability of such systems. 2.6 HORIZONTAL LINKS & VERTICAL TIES 28 GOVERNANCE 12 According to Muhammad Yunus, microcredit was pioneered in Khan's earlier work in Comilla, Pakistan, a project that OPP borrowed heavily from, but which predates Opp by approximately two decades. 11 Where the Karachi Water and Sewerage Board (KWSB) has built and funded both internal and external sewage and ignored the in-place informal sewerage systems, new sewer trunk lines remained dry and treatment plants underused, and increased costs have led to loans the KWSB cannot service (Hasan 2006, 473) - Both "bonding" capital, or horizontal links between members of the community, and "bridging" capital, or vertical connections to outsiders, are necessary in successfully leveraging existing social capital; where one is present and the other is not, communities may reject ideas from outsiders, or adopt those ideas indiscriminately (Flora 2004, 9). The founder of OPP, Akhtar Ameed Khan Khan, argued that the OPP model succeeded because a network of relationships allowed leadership to develop at multiple levels of the organization (country, community, village, lane, family), and created tight social groups that strengthened commitment towards realizing projects (Boyatz and Khawaja 2014, 299). Accordingly, the development of community-based organizational units and internal leadership was critical to OPP's success in Karachi. Well-defined community responsibilities - such as managing and collecting money reinforce the autonomy of local, resident-based institutions. Widely used, micro-credit initiatives, which leverage strong social capital for mutual financial gain - used extensively in Orangi today - are actively used to reinforce bonding capital within the settlement (Boyatz 2014, 30o).12 At a national level, a community development network of replication projects employing the OPP model links settlements throughout the country, as partner organizations meet CONDOMINIAL SEWERAGE systems in Brazil and Karachi, Pakistan. regularly to discuss findings (Hasan 2006,460). Condiminial programs in Brasilia "received support from the highest levels of the utility company and local authorities" (Melo 2005, 2). Simultaneously, project leaders worked to garner support from community residents by holding approximately 5,000 meetings within the community, which were attended by 57,000 participants (Melo 2005,17). Similarly, the Orangi Project relied heavily on the coordinated efforts of a variety of community, governmental, nonprofit and academic partners. In both cases, while community participation is critical, project success relies heavily on the strength of links between participants within and outside of the settlement. The experiences in Brazil and Pakistan are borne out elsewhere in the literature. Globally, lack of coordination among actors at different scales (national, local) and sectors (public, private, NGO) negatively affects their ability to provide adequate service provision. In Pakistan, for instance, Nawab and Nyborg's 29 analysis of water provision in rural areas finds that higher level decision-makers often consider local people to be illiterate, disorganized or non-cooperative, while local residents see policy-makers as naive and out of touch (Nawab and Nyborg 2009, 591). In the OPP, well-rehearsed interactions among actors, including between local government and residents, reduced the likelihood of conflict. These vertical links, a form of "bridging" social capital, also connected residents to outside constituencies such as government and nonprofit groups. While community involvement is fundamental to planning and financing the community sanitation system, the OPP has also consistently provided technical assistance and managerial guidance. In fact, the financial viability of the Orangi project is premised on technological innovations, developed in coordination with the OPP and its partners that simplified the materials and sizing of pipes (Boyatzis and Khawaja 2014, 295). Government, which finances and constructs large trunk sewer lines and wastewater treatment plants, are equal partners in the internalexternal sanitation model. Students from local universities helped survey the Orangi settlement early in the history of the project (Hasan 2006,460). In Brasilia, government funding and technical support helped plan and implement new condiminial lines. The case of AguaClara, shows how vertical linkages between actors can help village communities access financial and technical support unavailable locally. Although decentralized water management is a basic principle of Honduras' national water policy, local political capital is necessary for villages to claim resources made available by regional and national government (Gonzalez Rivas et al. 2014, 573). As with OPP, community participation is critical to success, but outside guidance provided by APP "helps build bridging ties to access external technical expertise and financial resources" (Gonzalez Rivas et al. 2014, 572). In Honduras, Brazil and Pakistan local mobilizations for improved water services were most effective when they combined top-down support with bottom-up activism, belying the conceptual dichotomy that maintains a clear distinction between the two. In other words, even where movements explicitly root themselves in community support, as in the case of OPP, complex social projects entail hybrid system of institutions 30 GOVERNANCE that combine public, private and nonprofit actors operating at multiple scales. In the next section, 1propose this hybrid system - simultaneously bottom-up and top-down, centralized and decentralized - in the social and institutional context of Mexico City. 2.6 CONCLUSIONS In this light, any new WatSan infrastructures should consider not only physical capital, but also the various forms of social, political and human capital described above. The referenced cases suggest that participatory approaches can create sustainable physical infrastructures, by leveraging latent sources of finance and labor. At the same time, infrastructure can reinforce local institutions in nonphysical ways by developing inter and intra-community ties, encouraging opportunities for learning and knowledge creation, and creating new organizational vehicles for wealth generation and political mobilization. This basic principle of complementarity - that an understanding of local institutions should inform the design of physical infrastructure, and that infrastructure should in turn reinforce local institutions - describes the philosophical logic behind the proposal offered in Part 2 of this thesis. That section begins by examining lztapalapa in greater detail as a way of better understanding what types of infrastructure might be most appropriate for the neighborhood, and what forms of local governance can contribute to implementation and long term sustainability of new water infrastructures there. 31 CHAPTER 3: CONTEXT If the preceding examples illustrate some of the general social characteristics for successful urban water and sanitation projects, this chapter explores the specific physical and social landscape of Iztapalapa. Rather than speculate on the possibility for community led mobilization in the delegacion, the intention here is to better understand ways to integrate new water infrastructure within the local institutional context. As the cases described earlier suggest, successful projects inevitably exploit multiple forms of latent capital (social, cultural, technological, financial, etc.), realized through a network of actors that include local residents and community leaders, government, and civil society. Identifying the resources and partners present in the site heavily influences choices regarding the form and placement of design interventions that promote effective water management at the local level. 3.1 GROWTH lztapalapa is the most populous of Mexico City's delegaciones, the most densely settled, and the third largest by land area (INEGI). The borough lies along the eastern edge of the Federal district, bounded to the east and north by the municipalities of Ciudad Nezahualcoyotl and La Paz, both within Mexico State. Among residents of the Federal District, the delegacion carries a reputation for crime, perhaps because it consistently ranks at the top of city rates in absolute numbers, although the per capita rates are in fact almost identical to citywide averages (372.8 "high impact" crimes per 100,000 people, versus an average of 373.3 in 2014 for the entire Distrito Federal) (calculations based on Informe Estadistico Delectivo en el Distrito Federal, 2014). Commerce and Industry represent the two largest economic sectors within Iztapalapa, accounting for 38.0% and 27.5% of gross product, respectively (Delegacion Iztapalapa, Secretaria de Desarollo Economico). Most male residents work as artesans or manual laborers, while women are most commonly merchants or clerks (Delegacion Iztapalapa: Perfil Sociodemografico, 34).13 Despite employment rates roughly equal with the Federal District, half of lztapalapa's population earns less than two times the minimum monthly wage, and almost three quarters earn less than three times the minimum monthly wage (Delegacion lztapalapa, Secretaria de Desarollo Economico, 22; Delegacion lztapalapa: Perfil Sociodemografico, 34).14 These numbers compare unfavorably with the greater Federal District, where only 42% of the population makes less than two times the minimum monthly wage (Programa Delegacional de Desarrollo Urbano en lztapalapa, 18). Most residents live in freestanding houses, though almost a quarter inhabit apartments, and 13% live in vecindades, a type of apartment building with shared central patios, often designed for low-income residents (El Universal, 2009). Historically, the area has grown at a faster rate than the rest of the Federal District, though this rate has declined significantly since 1990 as the delegacion fully urbanized (Delegacion Iztapalapa: Perfil Sociodemografico, 6). As early as the 16th century, lztapalapa consisted of io,ooo residents (wikipedia - delegacion original source), though the number 32 CONTEXT 0 _____ Ylp .4 ~MjXCLVAT -1- -J~ ~ 'J L~ 'I 13 -I Data regarding business size for the delegacion is not publically available but if lztapalapa accords with trends at the city level, the vast majority of residents (approximately 94%) work in microempresas of less than io people (Mondragon and Mondragon 2008, 51). 14 This metric is commonly in Mexico used to describe earning potential, and to evaluate household eligibility for subsidies, among other things. In 2014, the minimum monthly salary was 67.29 pesos per day, which translates to roughly 2020 pesos per month or $136 USD (CONSAMI 2014). 33 URBAN FABRICS Recent settlement in lztapalapa tends to concentrate along the district's eastern edge, in the area bordering the Sierra Catalina mountain ranges and Mexico State, farthest removed from the city center. The distinction between the more recently founded urban areas, and those established in the 1940s and earlier, can be read in the physical fabric of these communities, which become increasing dense along a west-to-east gradient. The neighborhood social organizations that agitate and protest on behalf of the urban poor, typically command more local support in these eastern regions. 34 CONTEXT 0 UUPS V Al. a-Wil 41 PIZ1 9 plinia tflA i'"' UU~intAX N K { {Li~ ~ ;.ThE7LpC w / tj~1 N-. ;jJ-i-4.4 ~' (p / / '~-N. N-'' -p A / 1-. N- ff1! -J N I- Nt 35 dropped considerably during early colonial times, and only fully recovered in the early 2oth century. By 1903 the municipal population had grown to 10,0440 residents (lztapalapa, 6/132), with most inhabitants concentrated predominantly in neighborhoods north of the Cerro de la Estrella, and around what is the modern day Central de Abastos - the commercial heart of the region, and the single most important foodstuff entrepot for the greater metropolitan area (Enciclopedia de los Municipios y Delegaciones de Mexico: lztapalapa). In 1928, when lztapalapa was made a delegacion within the Federal District the area population still hovered around io,ooo. In 1940, the population was 24,272. By 1960, however, the population had grown to 254,355 with 37% of the demographic growth due to rural migration spurred by economic opportunities in Mexico City (Bravo M., 55). By the end of the 1970s, the delegacion was almost fully urbanized, its economy shifted from agricultural to industrial and commercial production, and fueled by heady population growth. Throughout the Federal District, public authorities propogated a new housing type, the modernist apartment block called unidades habitacioneles, built to meet the housing needs of migrants with limited economic means. As industry made agricultural land uses obsolete, the lacustrine landscape disappeared, and by 1950 almost all navigable canals were buried under asphalt or paved for new roads (lztapalapa Delegacion website; Enciclopedia de los Municipios y Delegaciones de Mexico: lztapalapa). The pace of growth continued through the 198os, then slowed dramatically; population growth exceeded zoo% each decade between 1940 and 1960, dropped to between ioo% and 140% in the decades from 1960 to 1980, and then plunged to below 20% after 1990, with negative growth in the five year period between 2005 and 2010 (calculations from INEGL; Delegacion lztapalapa Diagnostico; Bravo M. 54,55). Despite the slow-down, migration still accounts for a sizeable and stable portion of lztapalapa's gradual densification. Both the 20oo and 2010, the census documents that approximately 20% of the area's population was born outside of the delegacion. 3.2 GEOGRAPHY AND MARGINALIZATION While lztapalapa's historical settlement initially concentrated around its center and the flat plains of the drained Texcoco Lake, recent growth concentrates in the less hospitable geographies around the delegation's eastern edges, where the Sierra de Santa Catalina separates Lztapalapa from the delegacion of Tlahuac. The mountains are the site of prominent land invasions since the 1960s, and new informal settlements that advanced along the mountain slopes. Nor surprisingly, the colonias along Santa Catalina are home to the youngest, most illiterate and most densely settled populations, the largest numbers of recently immigrated groups, and feature the longest commute times from downtown Mexico City (Delegacion lztapalapa: Perfil Sociodemografico). Natural physical barriers to adequate service provision compound social vulnerabilities inherent to the urban poor, who often lack the time, financial resources and political clout to redress these problems. The supply of water, which flows through secondary piping networks along the flat expanses at the center of the delegacion, often does not reach the upper levels of the mountain slope. Water service is therefore rationed, with service in some communities limited to several hours, and extended as infrequently as once per week (interviews). Throughout much of the delegacion, but especially in water poor sierran communities, service is supplemented by delivery of pipas, water tankers subsidized by government but for which residents still pay am unofficial delivery fee (interviews). Because neither piped nor trucked water is potable without treatment, families buy 20 liter water jugs from local suppliers who tour the community regularly, selling each for approximately $8 MX, though prices vary between colonias (interview with Jorge Carbajal). 36 CONTEXT The Sierra Catalina terminates in several large inactive volcanoes, the most prominent of which - Cerro de la Estrella - was Pre-Colombian ceremonial site and is now a protected ecological region. To the east, the volcano Yuhualixqui is owned by mining interests that produce gravel from the mountain's volcanic rock. Even further east lies Xaltepec, another volcano and protected ecological site. With the exception of Yuhualixqui, these landforms are administered jointly by the city and national level environmental agencies, though the delegacion struggles with the challenge of encroaching urbanization on the slopes of the sierra (interview with Juan Pablo Espejel). A lack of adequate water service is one unifying concern for the settlements along the Sierra Catalina, but there also exist deficiencies in the quality of urban spaces within the region. Settlements here were often founded with the singular purpose of supplying additional housing and, consequently, many of the colonias in the sierra lack purposely built public spaces, including plazas, parks and playing fields. These characteristics exacerbate problems associated with flooding - the dearth of green surfaces contribute to poor drainage and increased surface runoff - but they also imply an impact on quality of life. Communal public spaces are opportunistic and often improvised, established where space and demand exist to justify their presence. In satellite photos, one identifies the presence of urban shared spaces not through large expanses of green - as in the city's center and western neighborhoods - but through the colorful mosaic of market stalls that indicate tianguis, outdoor street markets. These markets represent the most ubiquitous forms of public space throughout much of lztapalapa, and they display an immediate logic corresponding to local demand but even here the lack of planning externalizes higher levels of traffic, congestion and pollution. In this way, the geography of the sierra abstracts common demographic characteristics of social risk and marginalization. Roughly speaking, the severity of these conditions diminishes as the mountain range breaks from a continuous range to an archipelago of volcanic features, along the southeastern border of the delegacion. The colonias touching these mountainous areas share common household characteristics related to access to amenities and services, are farther removed from the center of the Federal District, and benefit less from municipal infrastructure. The conditions related to their historical founding - inward looking planning regimes concerned almost exclusively with housing production - promotes urban density without the relief or luxury of shard civic spaces and parkland. 38 CONTEXT -- - 2MMA -- -- - - . - - 3.3 CLIENTELISM AND PARTY POLITICS In previous sections, I describe how recent experiments in political decentralization have contributed to a failure of federal and regional-level water governance, blurring the relationship between agencies charged with the same mission but operating in overlapping administrative levels and physical geographies. At the local level - that is, how local communities actually receive water services from the delegacion - the institutional processes involved are no less problematic, but in fact have a longer history and are thus in many ways more entrenched. Within Iztapalapa, provision of basic services such as water, drainage, electricity, and housing is largely accounted for within systems of clientelistic politics, with social organizations representing the interests of urban poor. Clientelism describes an institutionalized politics in which "the distribution of resources (or promise of) by political office holders or political candidates in exchange for political support, primarily - although not exclusively - in the form of the vote" (Gay 1990 quoted in Auyero 199,297). It has a long history in Mexico, where a single political party, the Partido Revolucionario Institucional (PRI) dominated Mexican politics from the late 1920S until the 1988 presidential election. VULNERABILITY & MARGINALIZATION According to various household indicators of of social marginalization, the eastern edges of the borough are the most marginalized. Not surprisingly, these areas are the farthest removed from downtown Mexico City, the most recently settled, and the most vulnerable to water shortages. The first map derives from studies made by the borough's Centro de Evaluacion de Riesgo (CERG), which employs federal standards, accounting for level of education, health, houshold characteristic, etc. All other maps are derived from Mexican census data Source: INEGI). 40 CONTEXT Beginning in the late 1960s, social organizations fought for increasing autonomy in their relations with the state, while never breaking fully with the patronage model. Local organizations cultivated strong links with the PRI, but were largely confined to operating as social welfare groups rather than political groups (Fox 1994,160). Beginning in the 198os, however, several events accelerated the creation of an increasingly pluralistic political landscape, and a move away from traditional clientelism. First, the adoption of neoliberal economic policies in the wake of the 1980s debt crisis limited the resources available for clientelistic rewards (Fox 1994, 165). Second, after the 1985 earthquake, effective responses from citizen groups contrasted sharply with government incompetency, affirming the value of these organizations in popular imagination (and especially in Mexico City) (Fox and Hernandez 1002, 166). Third, as a result of ideological disagreements within the PRI, several charismatic political leaders emerged as alternative candidates to the ruling party. In 1988, running under the Frente Democratico Nacional party, RATE OF SOCIAL MARGINALIZATION COMPUTER IN HOUSEHOLD 100% HIGH I 0% LOW POPULATION UNDER 14 YEARS BORN IN IZTAPALAPA 66% 0% 200% I I YEARS OF SCHOOLING 0% POPULATION DENSITY So,ooo / sq. km 17 01 I 0 41 Cuauhtemoc Cardenas lost the Mexican presidency by a slim electoral margin, which was widely believed to be the result of electoral fraud. The following year, Cardenas and other leftleaning former prifstas formed the Partido de la Revolucion Democritico (PRD). Throughout the Federal District, leaders of city government had been appointed by the federal government until 1997, when the city won the right to elect its own leaders (Hilgers 2005, io). Beginning in the late 199os, however, residents of the Federal District were free to elect their own officials, making the left-leaning PRD an increasingly potent political force within the city, and especially in the poorer delegaciones along its eastern edge. 15 In an interview with Rebelion, Enrique Reinosos, a leader of the movement, says the origin date is 1988. Emergent social organizations allied with newly established political parties for mutual advantage. By the early 198os an explosion of urban social organizations responded to budget cuts that limited funding for basic services in neighborhoods. In turn, movements like the Coordinadora Nacional de Movimientos Urbanos Populares (CONAMUP) coordinated disparate neighborhood-based local movements that made explicit demands on the PRI leadership (Davis 1994, 252). In the face of the PRI's waning ability to address local concerns, social organizations sought and found greater political autonomy, "working with new technocrats in in government that recognized social movements as legitimate representatives of the poor" (Fox 16o). Since 2000, when elections were first initiated in individual delegaciones, PRD leaders have won every local political election in Iztapalapa, thereby creating a new political space and traction for local social organizations aligned with their leftist political views. 36 Hilgers describes a 2004 meeting of the PRD National Council this way: "the objective appears to be seeing and being seen, as well as meeting and making deals with associates, rather than engaging in the formal business of the meeting at hand, since it is well know that matters of importance have already been resolved (or postponed) by those present in the private room." (Hilgers 2005, 20) 17 For example, in Yuguelito, the six subcommittees are security, which includes access to the community and safety within its borders; and press, responsible for creating and disseminating literature and publications advancing the FPVI mission. 42 CONTEXT Thus, by the 1990s community-based community organizations exercised a real influence on local level politics, dramatically altering the urban political landscape of Mexico City. In lztapalapa, since the 1980s the single most important organization has been the Frente Popular Francisco Villa (FPFV), which espouses a Marxist-Leninist political philosophy, and retains close ties to the Partido de la Revoluci6n Democritico (PRD). FPFV was founded in 1983 in Mexico City. From the start it pursued a strategy of claiming abandoned land at the outskirts of the city, and a focus on providing housing to its constituents (Guerra Blanco 2013, 8o). 5 The FPFV actively pursued alliances with like-minded social groups, participating in alliances through pan-organizational bodies such as CONAMUP, as well as directing its own 43 internal assemblies for local chapters. The FPFV's political ideology has always been intrinsic to the organization, yet the group only became explicitly political - engaged in the day-to-day of local politics - in 1997, in exchange for a seat on the city assembly. That decision, which reified an implicit ideological alliance with the PRD, exacerbated divisions within the organization and quickly led to fracture (Guerra Blanco 2013, 85; Hilgers 2005, 17). One faction, of particular relevance here because of its local political influence in parts of the Sierra de Santa Catarina, is the Frente Popular Francisco Villa Independientes (FPFVI), an offshoot that engages with local politics to secure services for its members, but keeps no longstanding affiliation with any local party. Still, FPFV carries its own set of political allegiances, including a partnership with UNOPIL (Unidad Nacional de Organizaciones Populares de Izuierda Independiente), an umbrella group that includes the FPFV and the Organizacion Campesina Emiliano Zapata (OCEZ) (unopii.org). The complicated mix of alliances and conflict hints at the complex structure and competing motivations shared by local organizations. Within the established party, the dispersed nature of the group means that individual factions must compete for influence in the national Congress.' Consequently, it is not easy to chart the specifics of the institutional relationship between and among political groups in lztapalapa, where social organizations within the borough are as frequently engaged with internal political feuds as they are winning concessions from higher levels of government. Much decision-making is devolved to the local affiliates, who establish local committees that govern the quotidian matters of security, maintenance, and community finances. The specific governance operations of these bodies, including term lengths for committee members, vary between communities (Lao y Flavia Rebelion 2009,4). '7 The basic function, however, remains consistent across groups; in exchange for participation in protest and marches, party members receive benefits, foremost access to property and housing. Where organizations are explicitly political, as is the FPFV (with the exception of the "independent" faction) members are also required to vote for the affiliated political party, which in lztapalapa, means the PRD. In both cases, where local government is not receptive to community demands, organizations join with groups to protest for basic services through the use of strikes, protest, denuncias and roadblocks. Represented through its local community leaders, the social organization initiates land invasions, secures government services and housing subsidies, and retroactively negotiates title deeds with the delegacion. Residents pay fees and labor directly to the organization for maintenance and new capital projects, such as installing electric transformers for electricity (interviews with Raul Trujo; Hilger 17). They bear the cost of housing construction individually, though materials are often offset by subsidies from the Instituto de Vivienda del Distrito Federal (INVI), which are negotiated by the FPFV. 3.4 YUGUELITO The case of Yuguelito, in southeastern lztapalapa, illustrates the clientelistic model of service provision, and the role of water in the mobilizations of certain marginalized communities. Yuguelito is the youngest of several organized communities in the area founded by social organizations. It is home to around 5,000 people, housed on 20,000 square meters. Prior to its settlement, the site had been used as a trash dump, which allowed its unconstrained (but illegal) expansion until the community grew to the boundaries of active gravel site to the north, and older settlements to the east. The settlement is divided into 50 square meter family-owned lots, distributed over 21 blocks. A local architect worked with community leaders to draft the initial masterplan for the community, and subsequent development has followed that original layout somewhat faithfully. Because 44 CONTEXT FPFVI DEMONSTRATIONS FPFVI rally in downtown Mexico City, in 2014. (photo credit: Raul Trejo) 45 ,4 MI4 _ _ _ _ j \ TT - e 47 financial means vary between households, and some families have been present in Yuguelito longer than others, houses in the community differ somewhat in their degree of furnishing, building materials and number of stories. Still, a typical home costs somewhere around $300,000 MX, including the cost of materials - subsidized by loans from the Instituto de Vivienda del Distrito Federal (lNVl), negotiated by the community leaders - and of labor, which is often drawn from workers living within the community. In Yuguelito's infancy, however, early settlers often lived in makeshift houses built with whatever materials were available, including cardboard and salvaged plastic. New arrivals sometimes build temporary structures until they secure enough capital for more permanent homes, and almost all houses are planned in anticipation of future expansion (interview with Raul Trejo). The community is currently run by the Ruben Jaramillo faction of the FPFVI. However, the original settlement consisted of a larger parcel, established by a unified FPFVI group before a political split between Yuguelito and its neighbor, another FPFVI faction that now occupies a slightly larger footprint on an adjacent plot. The two groups sometimes clash, though their leadership remains on amicable terms. In part, the friendly relationship is built of necessity and political convenience. The need for shared water infrastructure has proven significant enough that the two factions have forged a working relationship over the construction and management of shared water pipelines. The two groups perform maintenance jointly, with the understanding that shared infrastructure is critical to the health of both communities. Although group leaders communicate with one another when necessary, no shared community group exists to administer water. Although the new infrastructure will alleviate demand, it is not enough to meet all of the needs of the community. Yuguelito receives 6-7 pipas per day for its population of approximately 5,000 people. The supply from secondary networks is insufficient, so families buy jugs from private vendors for consumption. Unlike in overtly politicized settlements, Yuguelito residents are not required to vote for any particular political 48 CONTEXT candidate. They are, however, expected to partake in organized protests such as marches or strikes, to pay for necessary infrastructure, and to participate in community governance. Three citizen committees, each comprised of twenty local residents elected every six months, are responsible for local security, community health, and press (in charge of community newspapers and flyers). Additionally, block coordinators gather regular payments from citizens, including fees for guards (who patrol the settlement and watch major entrances) and water. Specifically, each family pays $6.50 MX per week for the cost of water, which affords them three barrels per week, although families often pay an added "tip" of 70 or 8o pesos directly to the piperos (6:oo). Families pay an initial downpayment of $500 MX (approximately $35 US) and are expected to contribute to large infrastructural projects such as drainage, walls, electricity, and legal fees, as those projects come up. In exchange for their participation, residents receive titles to their lots once the parcel is regularized, as a result of legal negotiations between community lawyers and government officials (person interview with Yolanda Cervantes). Residents also pay a fee to support the salary of community leaders and administrative overhead. In Yuguelito, the two community leaders - Yolanda and Raul - are cofounders and residents of the settlement, and organizers for several nearby settlements affiliated with the Ruben Jaramillo FPFVI faction. Unlike other administrative positions within the community, community leaders are not elected. They resolve disputes, organize protests and negotiate with political officials and bureaucrats to win services for the community. Yolanda and Raul have also developed relationships with some civil society groups, including Rotary International and Isla Urbana, a small nonprofit that advocates for rainwater catchment in Mexico City. The Ruben Jaramillo faction collaborates with like-minded organizations periodically. However, Raul describes a similar process of service provision even in non-organized settlements, with politicians promising services street by street in exchange for service provision. 50 CONTEXT 4 7 V . ;:5-f -- TT- -177 MIRAVALLE, IZTAPALAPA Like Yuguelito, the settlement of Miravalle sits along lztapalapa's eastern edge. Founded through land invasions in the early 198os, Miravalle still struggles with deficient water service. 51 52 CONTEXT We arrived here June 28, seven years ago. We came because one of the [social groups] sold us io,ooo square meters. However, our organization grew in two direction, until it had in its possession around 50,000 square meters. That were divided into two territories, one part of land for the group Patria y Libertad, and the group Ruben Jaramillo...With the compatriots from Patria y Libertad, we had to have meetings because of water. Precisely for water. Here, on the street you walk on [to get here] we put in an 8 inch water. So, for that we had to talk with each other and come to an agreement. And we put in a joint water connection." Raul Trejo Yuguelito, lztapalapa 53 3.5 MIRAVALLE In contrast, Miravalle - a colonia near Iztapalapa's border with Mexico State, northeast from Yuguelito along the sierra - has increasingly relied on apolitical strategies to secure new services. Unlike Yuguelito, Miravalle has a long history as a regularized informal settlement, dating to the early 1980s when the community was founded by migrants from the Mexican interior. Since then, the colonia has grown to approximately 13,000 inhabitants, housed in 69 blocks that climb upwards from the foothills of the Mexico Valley (Asamblea Comunitaria Miravalle website; interview with Jorge Carbajal). Initial settlements were founded through land invasions of ejido land, and local community groups fought for additional services from local government, who eventually provided paving, electricity and water, although more recent informal enclaves still lack basic services. Miravalle has been connected to the municipal water network since approximately 20IO. Yet water service remains sporadic, and residents receive water only one or two days a week, for two to three hours per day, and typically reserve those times for the bulk of their weekly clothes and dishwashing. The newer settlements, also the product of land invasions, are entirely unconnected to the existing network (interview with Jorge Carbajal). Because of inadequate piped supply, the community is serviced by publicly subsidized pipas. As in Yuguelito pipa delivery is purportedly free, but drivers often demand additional payments from residents, fill up large barrels for washing and cleaning purposes. Three businesses in the area sell zo liter jugs of potable from the back of trucks which circulate through the community. Unlike in Yuguelito, the activist residents of Miravalle have adopted a strategy to second-generation service provision that relies on multiple sources and toggles between government and civil society organizations for support. Although the community has benefited from basic service provision from both the PRI and, to a lesser extent the PRD, the community has a long history of politically unaffiliated community organizing. Through the Coordinadora Comunitaria de Miravalle (COCOMl), local school teachers, students and family heads, developed community 54 CONTEXT committees in health, education, ecology and provisions. But the fact that COCOMI remained largely apolitical eventually threatened PRI leaders who resented the increased power of the community group, and continues to threaten political groups. In other words, the asamblea derives its authority from its apolitical nature; the fact that it is unaffiliated makes it less effective in some respects and encounters significant political opposition from local political parties, but it also means that its demands cannot be dismissed, redirected or subverted. In this way, the community has staked out politically independent territory. COCOMI has since been largely subsumed within another community organization, the asamblea comunitaria of approximately 8o people from the community, unelected by widely representative of the community and not beholden to any single political party. The strategy of the asamblea, is to rely on multiple sources of support, seeking funding from nonprofits and charitable organizations, and relying primarily on Federal District for support, but triangulating efforts between the municipal, city, and federal levels of government. The assembly relies on Federal District funds from the Programa Comunitario de Mejoramiento Barrial, which gives money to committees. The community won a $MX 1,200,ooo grant from Deutsche Bank to fund a complex surrounding the school building, that includes a skate park, music pavilion and running track. As Carabajal says, "more taxes, less services.. .the first [cause] is corruption. Here in Mexico, to be a politician implies indirect benefits and direct benefits, negotiations with providers." Consequently, the community has had to find creative alternatives to working with local government through traditional measure. (43:40). In addition to Deutsche Bank - which provided a $1,200,ooo MX grant to fund a complex surrounding the school building, that includes a skate park, music pavilion and running track - the asamblea comunitaria has received assistance from local universities. Similarly, from moneys from the Federal District's Programa Comunitario de Mejoramiento Barrial the assembly received $5,000,000 MX the community to build a library, childcare center, community cafeteria, theater, bandstand, and community center (27:00). Despite their differences, both Yuguelito and Miravalle are typical of the ways communities leverage existing resources for basic services, and the somewhat oppositional relationship between local communities and local government. However, both Yuguelito and Miravalle are also decidedly atypical in their overt rejection of political means for securing services. As suggested earlier, social groups in lztapalapa are often explicitly affiliated with the PRD, and trade votes for land, water, electricity and other services. In this system, leaders of social groups reap the political rewards of acting as go-betweens, translating the political will of local communities to higher-ups in delegation government. Despite differences in tactics and political ideologies, neither of the two cases discussed above follow this mold of explicit politicization. Leadership has chosen, instead to remain strategically unaligned, picking their partners as needed, and availing themselves of multiple streams of revenue and political support. 3.6 CONCLUSIONS In lztapalapa, a long tradition of clientelistic politics creates a set of powerful interests described only partially by the borough's formal democratic political system. Interactions between government and citizen groups, and between codified and informal practices, is clouded if not entirely opaque. In this arrangement, representatives of social organizations marshal votes to secure services from government leaders, so that the urban poor primarily derive their rights not as citizens but as members of groups. At their worst, social organization lack transparency, embody coercive and authoritarian political tactics, and dampen free democratic expression. 8 55 km ; a' Here the political issue is clientelism, including with the left. Here in the colonia there are three parties of the PRD and one of the PRI, which is the minority. But they do these political games playing with services ... The government's fear is to have politically conscious citizens. Because the moment we wake up, we won't let them [the government] to continue to do these ridiculous things. We'll start demanding, pressuring. They can't tell us no when we start to mobilize, because it's a right. We have a right to this. If they delay or they tell us they don't have money, we can tell them it's not true and it's not legal. They can't deny us." Jorge Carbajal Miravalle, lztapalapa 57 Yet, in the face of government indifference to the needs of the urban poor, social organizations have consistently demonstrated their ability to win basic rights to water, sanitation, housing, transportation, etc. Moreover, as clientelistic relationships depend upon the patron's ability to win real victories for the political client, leaders are ultimately beholden to their constituents for support (Auyero , 326). The philosophical merits of social organizations notwithstanding, there are several problems associated with the unplanned and inherently political method of community building described above. First, this form of land production - through illegal and unplanned appropriation - often neglects consideration of "second-order" amenities such as public space or parks. Second, because social organizations are primarily concerned with housing production, both leadership and members appear to lose interest in collective civic improvements once those primary goals have been achieved. For example, as indicated in relatively low numbers of community schools within the Sierra de Santa Catarina, neighborhood schools rank comparatively low on the priority list of social organization leadership, who tend to focus on more pressing needs such as shelter, roads, and electricity. Nor does government prioritize this agenda of "second order" amenities. Instances of low-income community mobilizations promoting community centers, health clinics, parks, recreation programs, etc. are rare, and- as in the case of Miravalle - often the result of efforts by unusually active but non-political community groups. To some extent at least, the nature of social organizations - which mix elements of collective idealism, narrow political ideology, and realpolitiks - frustrate institutional transparency and true democracy. The existence of such groups is thus a double-edged sword, instrumental in realizing short-term needs but harmful to long-term prospects of citizen empowerment. In the same way that Mexico City's traditional approach to water supply offers a reasonable (if expensive) short-term solution to scarcity while sacrificing the system's long-term health, so too do local clientelistic politics pose as many new long-term problems as they resolve. The link between water and politics is not simply rhetorical. In fact, improved water infrastructure can serve as a vehicle for addressing some of the critical urban problems described above. Within Iztapalapa, residents and government leadership view the issue with some urgency, while over-withdrawal from aquifers in the Valley of Mexico threatens the entire Federal District and adjacent municipalities within the State of Mexico. The challenge thus unifies disparate political interests, and presents opportunities for cooperation and resource sharing between governments at several levels. If linked to a fuller agenda of urban reform that includes demands for adequate urban space, schools, medical facilities, daycare, parks etc. - the amenities afforded to residents of the formally planned city - improved water infrastructure subsumes the needs of the urban poor within a broader agenda able to garner support from non-local interests. In theory, at least, Mexico City's water crisis represents an opportunity for collaborative action that can improve urban conditions for the urban poor. In practice, political leadership has been tepid, reluctant to invest the human and financial capital necessary for system-wide reform. The key question becomes, in the absence of committed political leadership, how can local actors leverage existing resources to realize the agenda of combined urban / water improvement described above. 58 CONTEXT 59 CHAPTER 4: PROPOSAL As successive levels of public leadership shirk responsibility for Mexico City's water crisis, the impact of the crisis continues to fall on city residents. Local resident groups are both most likely to mobilize in response to this crisis, and best equipped to fill the administrative management vacuum. In the management of local water resources, which transcend local geographies, neighborhood groups may find a focal point for broadbased activism that transcends hyper-local political divisions. Urban infrastructures are physical objects. That these objects must be designed and built, suggests a role for architecture in creating new types of urban space, inserting new complementary functions and, finally, developing to new models of local governance. In those capacities, new water infrastructure may help address the problems associated with the model of urbanization described earlier, which result in incomplete neighborhoods that lack essential civic programs and public space. This proposal attempts to justify the high costs of urban infrastructure by coupling water infrastructure with new social programs and public space. It suggests a model for one network - based on models of network decentralization, and implemented in the area around RAIN CATCHMENT SYSTEMS are used in a limited capacity throughout the city, installed by groups like Isla Urbana, a nonprofit organization based in Coyoacan, Mexico City. Isla Urbana teaches local residents to install and maintain household catchment systems. These household systems are limited by the cost and space requirements associated with storage, which could take place off-site. 6o PROPOSAL 41AIM - 7, . *04 r Yuguelito, lztapalapa - that can be replicated broadly throughout the borough. Using local networks of water transmission and storage as a skeleton, the plan inserts new public spaces and civic functions into the dense urban fabrics, thereby completing the unfinished processes of informal urbanization described in Chapter 4. Broadly, the proposal addresses the entire volcanic archipelago, the socially marginalized region of lztapalapa that suffers from the greatest problems with water supply. Specifically, the project focuses on a series of neighborhoods at the southern edge of the archipelago, in an area adjacent to Yuhualixqui. The area includes the settlement of Yuguelito the study of my fieldwork. My knowledge of local conditions influenced the decision to locate the design intervention here, where 1could best apply the methodology described in the following section. DECENTRALIZED WATER INFRASTRUCTURE In the context of Mexico City's recurrent water problems, and its historical reliance on highly centralized infrastructure systems, I propose a decentralized water network as one alternative to the current method of service delivery. Many of the same qualities that recommend decentralization in a political economic context - namely, more efficient resource allocation and improved governance (see Chapter i) - are also key tenets of decentralized water management. Decentralized infrastructure occurs locally, at the household or neighborhood level. Such strategies - which often include 'soft' or 'green' infrastructures that treat water on-site - purport to address 'wicked' problems more effectively than centralized regimes, while localizing the ecological, ecological and urbanistic benefits of these strategies. Proponents argue that local level community actors are more aware of ecological processes and more likely to adopt regulations in accordance with local realities, and that their regulations have additional legitimacy if imposed at the local level (Stoa 2014, 34). Reusing water at the neighborhood scale reduces financial and ecological costs associated with piping water (in) and wastewater (out) (Nelson, 12). Generally, such systems are lower in cost, require less energy, and are more finely attuned to community needs. Simultaneously, soft infrastructure offers opportunities to improve the spatial and urbanistic quality of neighborhoods by introducing ecological diversity and creating new public spaces. Such systems may yield significant cost savings too, and in cases of absent or insufficient technical and financial assistance they may be the only option available to communities (M.A. Massoud et al. 2009, 654).'9 In a second sense, decentralization refers to a non-hierarchical network, in which there is no single central server, and each node is connected to multiple other nodes. As the number of nodes grows, the risk of failure to the entire system is reduced, and reliance on a single central node decreases (Baran 1962, 3). Decentralized networks are not the opposite of centralized networks (Paul Baran refers to such networks as "distributed" networks); rather decentralized networks are similar to centralized networks in the "zoomed-in" scale, where they focus around a small number of centralizing nodes. In a decentralized network, each grouping of nodes and links forms a sort of module, however, connected to the next decentralized network. While the individual parts of the broad network may be centralized, the network in the aggregate is non-hierarchical, making the system resilient in the face of any single failure. 62 PROPOSAL -Link Stollar CENTRALIZED I A A DECENTRALIZED fal DISTRIBUTED fri Centralized, Decentralized, Distributed Networks. (Baran 1964, i) 19 Comparisons of centralized and decentralized infrastructure costs typically look at peri-urban and rural, as opposed to urban settings, however. An EPA study concludes that total costs for alternative and centralized water systems are between 1/4th and 1/7th of the cost of a centralized system, including capital, operation and maintenance fees. 63 SITE STRATEGY This proposal illustrates one module within a decentralized network, offering a series of vignettes describing module and outlining the rules for connecting such modules into a unified network. The parts of the system here are the nodes, individual infrastructural "assets," and connectors, the pipes that link each node in the system. The intention is to address three concerns articulated in earlier descriptions of the area. First, the design manages the need for improved water service by capturing, transmitting and storing rainwater for domestic use. Second, the project introduces new civic programs and open spaces to the neighborhood in an effort to correct for a historical shortage of these basic civic amenities. Third, the proposal attempts to reduce the severity of neighborhood divisions that factionalize relationships in the area, and create physical barriers that divide the neighborhood. The project creates a single axis, located along existing seams of political division (and considering land availability and local needs; this process is described in a subsequent section on methodology). Along this axis, the proposal introduces a combination of civic infrastructure - small parks, larger recreation spaces, schools and medical facilities -- and hydraulic infrastructure - a mix of pipes, water storage tanks water. The axis, which runs along existing rights of way, recreates the street as a new center of civic life for the area, unifying segregated and inward-looking settlements into a cohesive new neighborhood. 64 PROPOSAL Fl- + 4 DESIGN STRATEGY The project identifies boundaries or areas of division (1), locates an axis along those seams (2), and introduces a mix of social and hydraulic infrastructures (3), to create common spaces and integrate isolated settlements (4). 65 BOUNDARIES The process of informal urbanization often results in inward-facing communities of self-interested groups looking to maximize their own access to finite resources. These divisions are clearly read where territory is delineated through walls, and political affiliations are advertised prominently. The result is neighborhoods that are divided physically, with long stretches of dead streetscape, deadening urban life and frustrates pedestrian mobility (photo credit: Paulina Reyes.) 66 PROPOSAL 67 & BOUNDARIES DIVISIONS KERNEL DENSITY BOUNDARIES SITE SELECTION & DESIGN METHODOLOGY: The proposal introduces a site-selection methodology that uses GIS-based mapping to identify areas most suitable for new design interventions. Suitability analysis considers proximity to certain 'desirable' characteristics, then calculates the rate of occurrence of these characteristics and assigns each square meter a score indicating low or high suitability. In this case, I map four discrete characteristics including, first, the existence of political boundaries and divisions; second, the frequency of recent flooding events; third, the regularity of water service; and fourth the presence of unused or underused parcels. Proximity to each condition suggests either a need for new infrastructure - as in the first three cases - or an opportunity for minimizing disruptive impact on the neighborhood - as in the fourth case. The selection criteria can be expanded and customized when applied elsewhere. For instance, a more detailed suitability analysis might include distance to relevant civic infrastructure (schools, hospitals, etc.), access to existing transportation networks, or demographic characteristics like income or household size, as a measure of which neighborhoods demonstrate most need for new interventions. Consequently, the method is can increase or reduce the number of characteristics considered when defining site 'suitability' Similarly, the meth- 68 PROPOSAL VACANT PARCELS KERNEL DENSITY VACANT FLOODING WATER RATIONED COLONIAS KERNEL DENSITY KERNEL DENSITY FLOODING WATER RATIONED SUITABILITY (COMPOSITE) SITE IDENTIFICATION 69 odology can be implemented at a variety of scales. In this case, 1used the approach to "zoom-in" on a pre-chosen site area - the neighborhood that surrounds Yuguelito where much of my previous research focuses. However, the same method could have been applied to a much larger site, with similar results. There are significant caveats to this process, both in its specific application to Yuguelito, and its broad use as a replicable process used throughout the borough. First, the availability, specificity, and currentness of information may influence the results in unintended ways by favoring data-rich areas. For example, because of its newness and informal status, Yuguelito, appears on some official maps but not others. Without correcting for this data gap, suitability analyses will under-represent the demand for infrastructures within the community. Second, despite their apparent objectivity, decisions made through GIS-based software are inherently subjective, reflecting map makers' determinations about which information to include, how to visualize that data, and - in this case - how to weight each individual criteria in the final composite analysis.20 Although there is no "correct" weighting method, all assumptions should be made apparent and justified. Third, because these methods rely on information gathered from field interviews and site visits, the data itself is subject to biases, faulty memory and deliberate misrepresentation. Nevertheless, the use of GIS-based tools provides a valuable baseline for decision-making processes, helping guide choices about where to locate specific interventions within a larger site. Despite its inherent limitations, the method offers a useful way to locate longitudinal axes and nodes within large areas. 70 PROPOSAL 20 In this case, each of the four criteria (land use, borders, regular supply, and flooding) are weighted equally. The data is sourced from a variety of places: Calidad de Vida, a city government agency provided building footprints, blocks and street shapefiles. Sistemas de Agua de Ciudad de Mexico (SACMEX) provided flooding data. I based political boundaries on site interviews, site visits, and online maps made available by the Instituto Electoral del Distrito Federal (IEDF). I determined vacant parcels based on satellite imagery. I also note that footprints on GIS shape files do not always align with the most current satellite photos which, in turn do not necessarily correlate with on-site observations. 71 URBAN ARMATURE The site, which includes the rectangular area along both sides of a 500 meter axis, running just southwest of Yuguelito. The axis coincides with an existing street - Calle Salto de Agua - that begins at a vacant parcel on one end, and terminates at secondary school at the other. Within this site, the proposal connects storage systems at four different levels - the household, street, block and neighborhood level. At each level, tanks store water for a predefined geographic area. Storage is mixed between aboveground and underground tanks. Smaller pipes, buried at shallow depths beneath streets, connect household systems to larger neighborhood tanks. Where one street fails, it does not affect the rest of the system, but where the central line fails, it can cripple service to nodes farther down the system. The impact of such a break is limited to the quantities of water lost during the period of the pipe break, however, with overall storage within each tank largely unaffected. A mix of open spaces and new civic buildings punctuate the axis at the site of formerly vacant parcels. The axis provides a proof-of-concept to describe the rules governing how and where such a strategy can be implemented within densely settled areas. It represents a single component within a larger network deployed throughout the borough. That larger network can be described as decentralized when taken in the aggregate, and yet the module itself relies on a single central transmission axis, making it prone to systemic failure in the case of leakage along the central water main. Still, because each axis functions independently from the next, taken as a whole, the entire network becomes immune to single shocks. 72 PROPOSAL UNDERGROUND WATER STORAGE ABOVEGROUND WATER TORAGE I. K HYDRAULIC INFRASTRUCTURE 1 1 AXIS 1>1. 41 SITE CONTEXT 73 CIVIC PROGRAMS Civic programs housed in mid-sized buildings, accommodate small community libraries, daycare centers, schools, health clinics. While the type of program varies according to community needs, the buildings themselves are built using locally available materials, according to construction techniques already employed by local laborers. Rather than making water infrastructure invisible by burying it, fencing it off, or removing it from the city entirely, the proposal highlights those assets. 74 PROPOSAL UNDERGROUND WATER STORAGE ABOVEGROUND WATER TORAGE ii I HYDRAUUC INFRASTRUCTURE AXIS A SITE CONTEXT 75 RAINWATER HARVESTING & STORAGE The technology involved with water harvesting from roofs is proven, simple and cheap. Within Mexico City, organizations such as the nonprofit Isla Urbana have installed various rainwater harvesting systems at a household level, often for central community buildings in socially marginalized areas of the capital. Isla Urbana officially counts 1700 systems installed over the past six years, and estimates complete capital costs of approximately $350 for most household systems (Isla Urbana website; interview with Enrique Lomnitz). Applied at the urban scale, the principal limitation to the harvesting systems is the system's capacity for storage, which varies according to the household cistern size but typically stores up to 5,ooo liters. However, space is limited in dense urban areas, and there are significant economies of scale associated with centralizing storage capacity in a limited number of large tanks, which is what this plan proposes. The proposal estimates the amount of rainwater that can be harvested in a given catchment area over the course of any given year, based on the type and size of roof, and estimates for annual precipitation.2 The catchment area here encompasses a zone of one square kilometer, along both sides of the central axis. The proposal assumes various scenarios for this area, according to the number of households channeling water into the new system's storage tanks. As more roofs are introduced to the catchment area, and new parcels are identified for development, the necessary storage capacity grows to accommodate ioo% of volume stored by these roofs. Storing, treating and reusing this water would yield a total of 47,000,000 liters of water annually, accommodating the needs of 866 people per day, or - if saved for exclusive use during three, summer dry months, accommodating 3474 people per day. 76 PROPOSAL 21 These calculations use the equation S = R x A x Cr, where S = total rain volume, R = annual precipitation, A = surface catchment area and Cr = a runoff coefficient describing material properties of the roof surface (in this case, I use a runoff coefficient of 0.85 for sheet-metal roofs). The numbers reflect back-of-the-envelope calculations that do not account for water stored and consumed at the individual household level. Accounting for this consumption will 22 reduce the total amount of rainwater available to the entire system, which in turn reduces the total number of residents that the system can serve. At the same time, this will mean that each storage tank does not need to cover ioo% of the volume captured annually - with the assumption that some small percentage of runoff is stored by individual households. RAIN VOLUME & CATCHMENT The size of the catchment area determines the total volume of rain captured, and the number of local residents supported by the system. At 100%, so% and s% of roofs used to capture run- off, the total volume varies up to 40,000,000 liters. AREA: 91, 731 SQ METERS VOLUME: 47,422,474 LITERS ~~a~ :t MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMAMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM 11MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM AREA: 45,865 SQ METERS VOLUME: 23,711,000 LITERS noonooOono MOMMEMEMEMEMS= M OME:======= H - 0 OMU.... AREA: 4,586 SQ METERS VOLUME: 2,371,000 LITERS 0 U....MMMMM=MMMM=MH MMEMMMMMMMMMM=M=MM MESON 77 CALLE SALTO DEL AGUA / STREET SECTION If the full system functions as an integrated mechanism for storing rainwater, the central axis moves water between individual nodes within that network. From household roofs, where it is captured and undergoes a 'first flush' to remove sediment, rainwater is piped along streets into a large main running beneath Salto del Agua, the major street axis for the network.13 Pipes carry water to underground and aboveground tanks along the axis, terminating in the largest tanks of the network. Along the street, native vegetation captures and filters storm water, which percolates into the subsurface and reduces street flooding. The strip runs along the eastern side of the existing street and, where it widens into small plazas, introduces new spaces for seating and street furniture. At its terminus, treated water is trucked back to individual households by private water vendors and public pipas, where it is delivered at no cost or sold back to residents at heavily subsidized prices. 23 The system borrows heavily from the simplified sewerage systems discussed in the context of brazil and Pakistan. In both cases, pipes are laid by citizen groups operating at the block or street level. Pipes themselves are placed at shallow depths beneath the street, to minimize costs. STREET SECTION A Household Connection B Connection to Street C Transmission Line to Storage D Existing Water Main 78 PROPOSAL A B D A MOT& B C D 79 .... ......... .............. .. = : - -- - . . . * f"Www4wimpow LIBRARY The community library serves as a flexible learning space, managed by local users and employed as a flexible space for community programs. The ground floor is open to a large plaza, below which a cistern gathers rainwater piped from surrounding communities. The open lobby connects the interior communities to the major development axis, linking fragmented neighborhoods through a series of related programs. The central square becomes a meeting place for various groups, an outdoor weekend market, and a space for protest and demonstration. 80 PROPOSAL 41 I -- -- 1111- - I - - I. . . . -. II I 81 MARKET A public market mediates between the street and interior recreation space, which also functions as a retention basin during heavy rains and flooding. On the street-side, commercial activities link the avenue to the interior parts of the neighborhood. Recreation rooms, meeting spaces, and community halls on the inside of the building serve surrounding communities. Water is stored in underground cisterns, the surface of which forms a stepped plaza overlooking soccer fields. These fields flood during periods of high storm runoff. 82 PROPOSAL -.- IL 1 - - El. ., 7 83 84 PROPOSAL 85 86 PROPOSAL 87 WATER STORAGE Large aboveground storage tanks collect and store rainwater from neighboring blocks. When these tanks reach full capacity, shutoff valves located inside the tanks bypass water flows along the water main towards the next cluster of tanks along the line. Water stored in each cistern is treated with chlorine on site, then transferred into mid-sized water tankers, and trucked to households. Unlike most existing water infrastructure, which is typically removed from sight, these structures remain visible and prominent, a reminder of water's centrality to the healthy functioning of the neighborhood, and of government's standing obligation to provide these basic services. The tanks become local neighborhood landmarks, contributing to a shared civic identity. By opening the street wall, they introduce new civic spaces, adding variety to the existing grid, and providing new areas for meeting and gathering, socializing and small-scale commerce. As a recurring modular unit, these infrastructures can be built according to standardized plans, exploiting the knowledge and labor of local residents, with financial support from governmental and nongovernmental bodies at the borough, city, and national level. 88 PROPOSAL 89 STRATEGIES FOR COMMUNITY ENGAGEMENT Activist organizations like FPFVI have become increasingly creative in their search for outside financial support for community projects. These groups often pair their significant organizing skills and members' capacity for semi-skilled manual labor with financial backing from sympathetic organizations; in Miravalle, for instance, Jorge Carabajal has fundraised from Deutsche Bank, among other private 24 foundations, nonprofits and government agencies. The same approach could be used to develop the series of small civic and water storage projects that make up the axis water system, with its connected storage tanks, civic buildings, and open spaces. Where local user groups provide much of the sweat equity involved in construction and maintenance needs, outside funders - including government agencies from the municipal to federal levels - could contribute to the capital and operating expenses associated with building and maintaining those assets. 90 PROPOSAL COMMUNITY 'USE SHARES' + + CONSTRUCTION MAINTENANCE USE USER COMMITTEES I COMMUNITY REPRESENTATIVES OUTSIDE CIVIL -- GOVERNMENT SOCIETY 91 Although each asset is available for broad public use, local user committees make decisions regarding how to maintain and program each asset. Membership in these boards reflects each group's level of participation in construction and maintenance, measured by communities' financial donations and sweat equity. For each asset, user committees consist of representatives from each sponsoring organization, with the size of each committee varying with the type and cost of the infrastructural asset. A large civic building, for example, might necessitate a larger board, whose membership includes representatives from government and civil society, as well representatives from neighborhood groups. This type of community governance is not new to the area. For many local groups, there already exists a culture of neighborhood committees charged with performing basic administrative functions within their self-contained settlements. Within the FPFV1 in Yuguelito, for instance, user committees organize efforts behind laying pipes, paving and electric lines for the settlement. Other committees maintain communal spaces, perform security, collect funds, and organize social events. 92 PROPOSAL F A B CD A B C D E F G A B C D E F G E USE / MANAGEMENT CONSTRUCTION MAINTENANCE A B C D E F La Polvorilla Neighborhood G H Francisco Villa indepeiente Santa Cruz Residential Block J K L M N 0 Pancho Villa Patria y Libertad Francisco Villa Indepediente Santa Cruz Residential Block Las Arboledas Neighborhood Santa Ana Residential Block Las Arboledas Neighborhood Santa Ana Residential Block Minas Polvorilla Neighborhood Isla Urbana SACMEX (CDMX) Secretaria de Desarollo Econornico (CDMX) 93 a4jpjl%!W! , , t4wrim - Rain Event __ - __ Household Collection --- .- ., Off-Site Storage Household Use - JCL" off-Site Treatment Trucked De- livery 4.4 OPPORTUNITIES FOR PROJECT SPONSORSHIP Beyond individual grants, there exist recurrent opportunities for government sponsorship, according to extant government programs. One potential source of small project funding exists in the form of Programa Comunitario de Mejoramiento Barrial (PCMB), a program initiated in 2007 through the Secretaria de Desarollo Social of the Federal District (Ziccardi 2013, 13). PCMB targets neighborhoods defined as having very high, high and medium levels of marginalization. Its goal is to create and improve public spaces in marginalized communities, and it funds new parks, community centers, playgrounds etc. in response to projects presented to them by community groups. Broadly, the initiative represents an effort to devolve the design and implementation of these projects to the local level, and the program relies local Asamblea Vecinales to officially endorse projects before they receive municipal funding. Projects are supported directly by funds from the Federal District, and budgets are reviewed Technical Committee comprised of members of the Secretaria de Desarollo Social, the Federal District government, and civil society. Project budgets are decided on an annual budget, with a maximum timeframe of five years, with up to $5oo,ooo MX for new projects and up to $i,ooo,ooo MX for continuing projects (Gaceta Oficial 94 PROPOSAL POTENTIAL SPONSORS Organizations like FPFVI have become increasingly creative in their search for funds, and found a variety of public and private sponsors for projects. These groups operate in lztapalapa and nearby, and could be tapped as potential sponsors for new infrastructural assets. 24 Government sponsors could include Delegaci6n de lztapalapa, Sistemas de Aguas de Ciudad de Mexico (SACMEX), Secretara de Desarrollo Urbano y Vivienda, Secretaria de Medio Ambiente, Secretaria de Obras y Servicios, Secretaria de Desarrollo Social, Secretarfa de Salud, Secretaria de Educaci6n, and the Comisi6n Nacional de Agua (CONAGUA). LOCAL GOVERNMENT AGENCIES POTENTIAL SPONSORS MeGAC" FEDERAL GOVERNMENT IZTAPALAPA CIVIL SOCIETY K!) INTERNATIONAL COMMUNITY ORGANIZATIONS 95 del Distrito Federal 2014, 144). Despite friction between local assemblies and local politicians, the nature of the funding process allows project funding to remain somewhat beyond the reach of local politicians, and therefore insulated from the traditional clientelistic relationship. This, in effect, allows a certain amount of autonomy for local projects. Although the projects have one-year budgets, amounts can be significant: projects between 2007 and 2009 typically varied between $i,ooo,ooo - $5,ooo,ooo MX (Ziccardi 2013, 13). The program's budget in 2014 was $108,750,000 MX, down from $117,000,000 MX in 2012 (El Universal 2014; Torres Marquez 2014, 12). In fact, current budgetary procedures may actually bias local politicians towards the types of small-scale urban projects offered here. lztapalapa, like the other boroughs within the Federal District, does not collect its own taxes, relying instead on the city to recover and redistribute money to boroughs based on need and size. Accordingly, lztapalapa - the city's largest delegaci6n - receives the greatest share of collected taxes. In 2014, only 16% of the budget was apportioned directly to boroughs, with the rest of funds directed towards various citywide funds (El Universal 2013). Of the $3.4B MX allocated to Lztapalapa, approximately one third of that amount is distributed equally among the 290 colonias within the borough ($353,000 MX per entity or approximately $24,000 US), administered by citizen committees and councils. Additionally, $63M MX is allotted to "special programs" decided on by the council members (El Universal, December 22, 2013).26 To justify its expenses, each delegaci6n must submit annual budgets that describe operational and capital costs. The one-year cycle discourages long term project planning because, even when longer-term projects are described in annual phases, the added difficulty imposed by this bureaucratic process makes it harder and more expensive to realize multi-year initiatives (interview with Mar Tomas Cascall6, Equipo de Proyectos Especiales, Delegaci6n lztapalapa,). One interviewer also suggested that the short timeline of each project dissuaded real community participation, since there was simply not enough time to engage with communities in any meaningful way (interview with Mar Tomas Cascall6, Equipo de Proyectos Especiales, Delegaci6n lztapalapa). At the same time, delegados, the elected heads of each borough, are limited to a single three-year term. Moreover, the tendency for sitting politicians to plan their next move in advance of their term's conclusion often shortens their tenure even further. For instance, in January of 2015 fourteen of the sixteen elected delegados resigned their positions. All fourteen were members of the PRD, and thirteen resigned in anticipation of running for other office.28 The three-year election cycle for active delegados, combined with the one-year municipal budgetary cycle, means that small-scale infrastructure projects may be both fiscally and politically attractive to sitting politicians working at the borough level. 96 PROPOSAL 25 The relative size of budgets within the DF are only partially accounted for by size. In 2014, the top three budgets were awarded to lztapalapa , which received 3,417 million pesos; Gustavo A. Madero, which received 2,914 million pesos; and Cuauhtemoc, which received 2,277 million pesos. However, the differences in per capita funding 1882 pesos / person versus 2457 pesos / person versus 4281 pesos / person, respectively, suggests funding considers other priorities (budget calculations from CNN 2013). 26 The total DF budget came to $156.8B MX of which $25.4 MX was allocated to boroughs. The rest of the budget included $67B MX for various city-wide secretariats, such as the Secretary of Tourism, Secretary of Economic Development, etc. Of these, the Secretary of Public Security ($13B MX), SACMEX ($ilB MX), the Secretary of Social Development ($8B MX), and Secretary of Works and Services ($7B MX) received the largest shares of the $67B MX budget allocated to all groups. Forty other city entities, such as the city Metro system, the city Housing Authority (INVI) and various educational agencies received the combined next largest budgetary share. ("Administraci6n P6blica del Distrito Federal: Decreto de Presupuesto de Egresos del Distrito Federal para el Ejercicio Fiscal 2014," Gaceta Oficial del Distrito Federal, December 2013. 27 Beginning in 2018, delegados will be eligible for a second term (Diaz 2014). 28 The single delegado not running for office was Jesus Valencia of lztapalapa, who resigned to resolve accusations of corruption, stemming from a car accident the month before, in which Valencia crashed a truck owned by Protexer, a private company that had received almost $3M MX in fees for services to cultural programs within the delegaci6n (Milenio, December 22 2014). 97 98 CONCLUSION CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSION In her investigation of institutions ("what they are, how and why they are crafted and sustained, and what consequences they generate"), Elinor Ostrom coins the term "action situation" to describe "the social space1s] where participants with diverse preferences interact, exchange goods and services, solve problems, dominate one another or fight" (Ostrom 2009, 14) - in other words, spaces of ideological conflict and resolution. The proposal here literalizes those social spaces by tying them to physical networks of pipes, plazas, and buildings. The final chapter in this thesis reiterates the link between social and institutional space in order to reframe water infrastructure as a potential agent for institutional change. MULTI-PERFORMATIVE INFRASTRUCTURE Where an active local civil society exists, and local residents meet and discuss issues of concern with their elected officials, interactions between citizens, government and civil society will occur naturally. Where these relationships are absent - because, for instance, the legal status of residents remains in doubt, or civic amenities do not exist - other venues for meaningful interaction must stand in. The network of infrastructural objects performs this function. In this way the governance strategies described earlier seek to introduce multiple opportunities and incentives for collective organizing around shared interests. These strategies borrow directly from existing models of informal governance, but service of a broad social agenda that transcends the hyper-local interests of individual communities. Co-constructed and locally managed, each infrastructural asset facilitates new horizontal ties between isolated community organizations, and creates vertical links between residents, government and civil society. At the same time, the creation of user committees introduces new local governing bodies, may challenge the entrenched system of political clientelism by making it harder for local politicians to 'divide and conquer' with promises of resources awarded to individual communities in exchange for votes. The proposal offers a new paradigm for urban infrastructure that justifies its costs by combining essential functional benefits (e.g. water service) with social, cultural, ecological and institutional concerns. The design thus catalyzes community development by exploiting and then building upon latent community strengths. In this sense, it embraces a multi-performative infrastructure that makes explicit claims on altering social and political, as well as physical landscapes. 99 PRAGMATIC IDEALISM Even replicated widely, the proposed network supplies only a portion of the catchment area's total water needs. At best, the proposal represents a partial fix to the large-scale water management issues described in Chapter i. A full solution to Mexico City's water challenges would require widespread societal commitment to reducing water use; enormous public expenditures to maintain existing infrastructure; investment in new technologies capable of treating and recycling grey and black water; enforcement of existing regulations, including bans on pumping from aquifers and vigilant policing of corporate pollution; and broad limits on urban expansion, especially where development encroaches on protected ecological zones. Given the political risk associated with each of those options, and considering the countervailing historical inertia, none of these reforms is likely. The intention here is neither to fully resolve those chronic and large-scale challenges, nor to absolve government of its core responsibilities to citizens. Instead, the proposal aspires to a realizable, medium-term solution that alleviates the most crippling impacts of the water crisis on local communities, while laying the groundwork for long-term institutional change. In both its geographic and temporal aspirations, the proposal advocates a meso-scale solution, operating at the level of the neighborhood and scalable to larger geographic areas. By engaging the "action situation" at the level of the neighborhood, the project mitigates the impact of flooding and water shortages. Although it offers a limited solution to entrenched socio-hydrological challenges, the proposal can be piloted and scaled up over the course of 5-20 years, with immediate benefits. In this light, the approach reflects a philosophy of pragmatic idealism that recognizes the need to operate within existing political and physical landscapes, despite the inherent power imbalances that define those landscapes. It exploits the ability of social organizations to negotiate with governmental authorities while ultimately reducing the need for such practices. To borrow again from Ostrom, new coalitions for neighborhood-level water management will manifest the 100 CONCLUSION - 2r phenomenon of "level shifting," wherein an actor is made aware of "the opportunities and constraints that might be available at a different level for solving some of the problems occurring at a current level" (Ostrom 2009, 62).) By creating avenues for regular, substantive, and unmediated interaction between different sponsors, the project translates local needs into new urban policy. It situates both the diagnosis and response to Mexico City's water management problems at the neighborhood scale. CONCLUSION - Throughout this thesis, I have tried to forefront the role of designer as advocate for marginalized communities. Generally speaking, urban planners are explicit about their professional responsibilities to the public, and to disadvantaged classes, in particular. This stance stems from an acute awareness of the discipline's mixed historical legacy specifically its complicity in large-scale displacement of the urban poor in the middle of the 20th century - and the topic remains an important and recurrent theme in planning literature and its curriculum. By contrast, the question of ethics plays a much more subdued role in the urban design discourse. Although designers are often concerned with physical space as a means for improving quality of life, and increasingly focus on the discipline's environmental responsibilities, the same issues of equity and social activism rarely express themselves in discussion about the role and responsibilities of the urban designer.29 An explicit social mission underlies this work. The proposal recommends designers as advocates for the urban poor. It argues that they can affect widespread change in the physical expression of neighborhoods and how their inhabitants live, shop, move and play in those spaces. Moreover, it asserts that designers impact the ways residents exercise control over those spaces and, by extension, how they negotiate their role within hierarchies of power. These questions imply ethical stances on the part of the designer that should be prominent in discussions about the role infrastructure and its impact on the city. 102 CONCLUSION 29 Many of the canonical urban planning texts from the last century (Jacobs 1961, Davidoff 1965, Arnstein 1969, Richard Klosterman 1985, Scott 1998) acknowledge the discipline's record as a tool of the powerful, imposed upon the powerless. While some authors in the field of urban design address this same question, the topic is much less resonant within the academic literature of that field. As an illustration of this fact, the official code of ethics for the American Institute of Certified Planners (AICP) includes the following mandates: "We shall always be conscious of the rights of others; we shall give people the opportunity to have a meaningful impact on the development of plans and programs that may affect them; we shall seek social justice by working to expand choice and opportunity for all persons; we shall educate the public about planning issues and their relevance to our everyday lives" (AICP website). Although the Code of Ethics for the American Institute of Architects (AIA) exhorts members to "uphold human rights in all their professional endeavors," the document overwhelmingly emphasizes professional obligations to clients and colleagues, to "care and competence," to "standards of aesthetic excellence," and to embracing the "spirit and letter of the law governing their professional affairs" (AIA website). 103 BIBLIOGRAPHY: CHAPTER 1 Bolaane, B., and H. Ikgopoleng. "Towards Improved Sanitation: Constraints and Opportuni ties in Accessing Waterborne Sewerage in Major Villages of Botswana." Habitat Interna tional 35.3. 2011. Big Cities. Big Water. Big Challenges: Water in an Urbanizing World. WWF Germany. 20H. Burns, Elena. "Repensar la cuenca: la gesti6n de ciclos del agua en el Valle de Mexico." UAMCENTL, Mexico. 2009. Centro Mario Molino "Evaluaci6n Energdtica de los Actuales Sistemas de Aguas Urbanas y Propuestas de Manejo de los Recursos Hidricos en la Ciudad de Mexico." 2012. CONAGUA, "Strategic Projects: Drinking Water, Sewerage, Sanitation. Programa Nacional de Infraestructura 2014-2018. Chaplin, Susan E. "Cities, Sewers and Poverty: India's Politics of Sanitation." Environment and Urbanization ii.1. 199. Daigger, Glen T., and George V. Crawford. "Enhancing Water System Security and Sustain ability by Incorporating Centralized and Decentralized Water Reclamation and Reuse into Urban Water Management Systems." Journal of Environmental Engineering and Management 17, no. 1. 2007. Ensminger, Jean. "Changing Property Rights: Reconciling Formal and Informal Rights to Land in Africa." The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics. 1997. Guha-Khasnobis, Basudeb, Ravi Kanbur, and Elinor Ostrom. "Linking the Formal and Informal economy: Concepts and Policies." Oxford University Press. 2007. Hern~indez, Felipe, Peter Kellett, and Lea Knudsen Allen. "Rethinking the informal city." Critical Perspectives from Latin America. 2009. Isunju, J. B., et al. "Socio-economic Aspects of Improved Sanitation in Slums: A review." Public Health 125.6. 2011. Katukiza, A. Y., et al. "Sustainable Sanitation Technology Options for Urban Slums." Biotechnology Advances 30.5. 2012. Lanjouw, Jean 0., and Philip 1. Levy. "Untitled: A Study of Formal and Informal Property Rights in Urban Ecuador*." The Economic Journal 112, no. 482. 2002. Legorreta, Jorge. "El Agua y la Ciudad de Mexico." Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana Azcapotzalco. 2008. Massoud, May A., Akram Tarhini, and Joumana A. Nasr. "Decentralized Approaches to Wastewater Treatment and Management: Applicability in Developing Countries." Journal of Environmental Management go, no. i. January 2009. Mazari-Hiriart, Marisa, et al. "Longitudinal Study of Microbial Diversity and Seasonality in the Mexico City Metropolitan Area Water Supply System." Applied and Environ mental Microbiology 71.9. 2005. Mazari-Hiriart, M., Y. Lopez-Vidal, and J. Calva. "Helicobacter pylori in water systems for human use in Mexico City." Water Science & Technology 43.12. 2001. Mintz, Eric, et al. "Not just a drop in the bucket: expanding access to point-of-use water treatment systems." American Journal of Public Health 91.10. 2001. 104 CONCLUSION Moe, Christine L., and Richard D. Rheingans. "Global challenges in water, sanitation and health." Journal of Water and Health 4. 2006. Olmstead, Sheila M. "Water Supply and Poor Communities: What's Price Got to Do with It?." Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development 45, no. 10. 2003. Ostrom, Elinor. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton university press, 2009. Payne, Geoffrey. "Urban land tenure policy options: Titles or rights?." Habitat Interna tional 25, no. 3. 2001. Sindzingre, Alice. "The Relevance of the Concepts of Formality and Informality: A Theoretical Appraisal." Linking the Formal and Informal Economy: Concepts and Policies, Oxford University Press, Oxford. 2006. Tortajada, Cecilia. "Water Management in Mexico City Metropolitan Area." Water Resources Development 22.2. 2006. Tortajada, Cecilia, and Enrique Castelin. "Water management for a Megacity: Mexico City Metropolitan Area." AMBIO: A journal of the Human Environment 32. 2003. UN Habitat "Making Slums History - A Global Challenge for 2020." Morrocco. November 2012.. Ward, Peter M. Mexico City. J. Wiley, England. 1998. Ward, Peter. "'A Patrimony for the Children': Low-Income Homeownership and Housing (lm)mobility in Latin American Cities." Annals of the Association of American Geographers 102 (6). 2012. Whittington, Dale. "Possible Adverse Effects of Increasing Block Water Tariffs in Developing Countries." Economic Development and Cultural Change. 1992. World Health Organization. "Diarrhoeal Disease: Fact Sheet No 330." April 2013. http:// www.who.int/mediacentre/factsheets/fs33o/en/ Yarza, Jorge. "Housing in Mexico: Structural Opportunities, Short Term Challenges." Housing Finance International. 2014. Zanetta, Cecilia. The Influence of the World Bank on National Housing and Urban Policies. Ashgate, Wiltshire, UK. 2004. 105 BIBLIOGRAPHY: CHAPTER 2 Acevedo, Brielle, et al. "The Institutional Structure of Water Policy in the Mexico City Metro politan Area." 2013. Aldama, Alvaro A. "Water Management in Mexico." Cech TV. Principles of Water Resources. & History, Development, Management, and Policy. 2nd edition. New York: John Wiley Sons. 2005. Bardhan, Pranab. "Decentralization of Governance and Development." Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2002. Barkin, David. "The Governance Crisis in Urban Water Management in Mexico." In Water Resources in Mexico, pp. 379-393. Springer Berlin Heidelberg. 20H. Bakker, Karen, Michelle Kooy, Nur Endah Shofiani, and Ernst-Jan Martijn. "Governance Failure: Rethinking the Institutional Dimensions of Urban Water Supply to Poor Hous holds." World Development 36, no. 10. 2008. Big Cities. Big Water. Big Challenges: Water in an Urbanizing World. WWF Germany. 2011. Boyatzis, Richard E., and Masud Khawaja. "How Dr. Akhtar Hameed Khan Led a Change Process That Started a Movement." The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science. 2014. Beer, Caroline. "Electoral competition and fiscal decentralization in Mexico." 2004. Burns, Elena. "Repensar la Cuenca: la Gesti6n de Ciclos del Agua en el Valle de Mexico." UAM-CENTLl, Mexico. 2009. Cameron, John, Joseph S. Tulchin, Philip Oxhorn, and Andrew D. Selee. "Decentralization, Democratic Governance, and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and Latin America." Canadian Journal of Development Studies. 2005. CONAGUA, "Strategic Projects: Drinking water, sewerage, sanitation. Programa Nacional de Infraestructura 2014-2018. Daigger, Glen T., and George V. Crawford. "Enhancing Water System Security and Sustainability by Incorporating Centralized and Decentralized Water Reclamation and Reuse into Urban Water Management Systems." Journal of Environmental Engineering and Management 17, no. 1. 2007. Faguet, Jean-Paul. "Decentralization and Governance." World Development 53. January 2014. Flora, Cornelia Butler. "Social aspects of small water systems." Journal of Contemporary Water Research & Education 128, no. 1. 2004. GonzAlez Rivas, Marcela, Karim Beers, Mildred E. Warner, and Monroe Weber-Shirk. "Analyzing the Potential of Community Water Systems: The Case of AguaClara." Water 16, no. 3. June 2014. Harris, Daniel, L. Jones, and M. Kooy. Analysing the governance and political economy of water and sanitation service delivery. ODI Working Paper 334. London: Overseas Policy Development Institute. 2011. Hasan, Arif. "Orangi Pilot Project: The expansion of Work beyond Orangi and the Mapping of Informal Settlements and Infrastructure." Environment and Urbanization 18, no. 2. 2006. Legorreta, Jorge. "El agua y la Ciudad de Mexico." (2008) Universidad Autonoma Metropotana-Azcapotzalco. io6 CONCLUSION Massoud, May A., Akram Tarhini, and Joumana A. Nasr. "Decentralized Approaches to Wastewater Treatment and Management: Applicability in Developing Countries." Journal of Environmental Management 90, no. i. January 2009. Mazari-Hiriart, Marisa, et al. "Longitudinal Study of Microbial Diversity and Seasonality in the Mexico City Metropolitan Area Water Supply System." Applied and Environ mental Microbiology 71.9. 2005. Mazari-Hiriart, M., Y. Lopez-Vidal, and J. Calva. "Helicobacter Pylori in Water Systems for Human Use in Mexico City." Water Science &Technology 43.12. 2001. Melo, Jose Carlos. "The experience of condominial water and sewerage systems in Brazil." Case studies from Brasdia, Salvador and Parauapebas. Lima: Water and Sanitation Program Latin America. 2005. Moe, Christine L., and Richard D. Rheingans. "Global Challenges in Water, Sanitation and Health." Journal of Water and Health 4. 20o6. Montero, Alfred, et al. Decentralization and Democracy in Latin America. Indiana: University of Notre Dame Press. 2004. Nawab, Bahadar, and 1. Nyborg. "Institutional Challenges in Water Supply and Sanitation in Pakistan: Revealing the Gap between National Policy and Local Experience." Water Policy 11.5. 2009. Nelson, Valerie 1. "New Approaches in Decentralized Water Infrastructure." Gloucester. MA. USA: Coalition for Alternative Wastewater Treatment, 2008. Olmstead, Sheila M. "Water Supply and Poor Communities: What's Price Got to Do with it?." Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development 45, no. 10. 2003. Ostrom, Elinor. Neither market nor state: Governance of common-pool resources in the twenty-first century. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 1994. Rahaman, Muhammad Mizanur, and Olli Varis. "Integrated water resources management: evolution, prospects and future challenges." Sustainability: Science, Practice & Policy 1.1. 2005. Smoke, Paul J., Eduardo J. G6mez, and George E. Peterson, eds. Decentralization in Asia and Latin America: Towards a Comparative Interdisciplinary Perspective. Edward Elgar Publishing, 20o6. Tortajada, "River Basin Management. Approaches in Mexico." 2005. UN-Water, "Status Report on the Application of Integrated Approaches to Water Resources Management." 2012. UNDP "Beyond Scarcity: Power, poverty and the global water crisis." Human Develop ment Report (2006). Welle, Katharina. "WaterAid Learning for Advocacy and Good Practice." Water and Sanitation Mapping in Ghana and Nigeria. Based on field visits to Ghana and Nigeria. 2006. Wilder, Margaret, and Patricia Romero Lankao. "Paradoxes of Decentralization: Water Reform and Social Implications in Mexico." World Development 34, no. ii. November 2006. 107 BIBLIOGRAPHY: CHAPTER 3 El Universal: lztapalapa: Sus Habitants, Viviendas, Problemas. 2009. http:// www.eluniversal.com.mx/notas/645276.html Aduna Mondrag6n, Alma Patricia. "La influencia de la Cultura y del Estilo de Gesti6n Sobre el Clima Organizacional. Estudio de Caso de la Mediana Empresa en la Delegaci6n lztapalapa." Estudios gerenciales 24, no. 1o6 (2008): 47-64. Auyero, Javier. ""From The Client's Point (S) Of View": How Poor People Perceive And Evaluate Political Clientelism." Theory And Society 28, No. 2 (1999): 297-334. Blanco, Edgar Everardo Guerra. "Observing Protest Organizations As Social Systems: The Popular Front Francisco Villa's Media Diffusion and its Press and Propaganda Strategy." Contention: The Multidisciplinary Journal Of Social Protest Volume i Issue i. October 2013. Bravo, Carlos. "Poblacidn Indigena Urbana. El Caso de lztapalapa." Iztapalapa Ritual Cultural y Cambio Social. Revista de Ciencias Sociales y Humandades 25. 2005. Castillo, Elia and Valdez, lich. Valencia Utiliza Otra Caminoeta'Prestada' Milenio, December 22 2014. CNN Expansion. DF Tendra Presupuesto De 156,837 Mdp. December 2013. Davis, Diane. Urban Leviathan: Mexico City in the Twentieth Century. Temple University Press. 2010. Diaz, Omar. "Delegados Y Diputados Locales Podrain Reelegirse a Partir de 2018." Mas Df. June 2014. Enciclopedia de los Municipios Y Delegaciones De Mexico: lztapalapa, INAFED (Instituto Nacional Para El Federalismo Y El Disarrollo Municipal). http:www.inafed.gob.mx/work/enciclopedia/EMMogDF delegaciones/o9007a.htmI Gay, Robert. "Community Organization and Clientelist Politics in Contemporary Brazil: a case study from suburban Rio de Janeiro." International journal of Urban and Regional Research 14, no. 4.1990. Hilgers, Tina. "The Nature of Clientelism in Mexico City." Canadian Political Science. 2005. i08 CONCLUSION BIBLIOGRAPHY: CHAPTER 4 "Publican Presupuesto de Egresos y Ley de Ingresos 2014 para el DF" El Milenio. December 2013 "Los 14 delegados del PRD en el DF piden licencia; 13 van por una candidature." Animal Politico.com. January 2015. Robles, Johana "GDF publica presupuesto 2014 en la gaceta official del DF" El Universal. December 2013. "Lztapalapa tendra de Nuevo presupuesto historico" El Universal. December 2013. Ziccardi, Alicia. "Espacio pdblico y nuevas formas de participaci6n ciudadana. El caso del Programa Comunitario de Mejoramiento de Barrios de la Ciudad de Mexico." Organo del Gobierno del Distrito Federal. "Gaceta Oficial del Distrito Federal." AVISO. 2014. "Modifican presupuesto para programas sociales del DF" El Universal. November 2014. BIBLIOGRAPHY: CHAPTER 5 Arnstein, Sherry R. "A ladder of Citizen Participation." Journal of the American Institute of planners 35, no. 4. 1969. Davidoff, Paul. "Advocacy and Pluralism in Planning." Journal of the American Institute of Planners 31, no. 4. 1965. Jacobs, Jane. The Death and Life of Great American Cities. Vintage. 1961. Klosterman, Richard E. "Arguments for and Against Planning." Town Planning Review 56, no. 1. 1985Ostrom, Elinor. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton University Press. Scott, James C. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition have Failed. Yale University Press. 1998. 2009. 109