Structural GARCH: The Volatility-Leverage Connection Robert Engle1 Emil Siriwardane1,2 1 NYU Stern School of Business 2 U.S. Treasury, Office of Financial Research (OFR) WFA Annual Meeting: 6/16/2014 Introduction 100 2.4 90 2.2 2 80 1.8 70 1.6 60 1.4 1.2 50 1 40 0.8 30 0.6 20 0.4 10 0.2 0 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Dat e 2008 2010 0 2012 De bt t o Eq uit y 1-Mont h R e aliz e d ( Annualiz e d) Volat ility BAC Leverage and Realized Volatility Leverage and Equity Volatility œ Crisis highlighted how leverage and equity volatility are tightly linked œ “Leverage Effect” has been around - e.g. Black (1976), Christie (1982) - but... œ A dynamic volatility model that incorporates leverage directly has remained elusive This Paper œ GARCH-type model where equity volatility is amplified (non-linearly) by leverage as in structural models of credit œ Asset return series from observed equity series œ Assets have time-varying volatility at high frequencies œ Statistical test of how leverage affects volatility œ Two applications: 1. Systemic Risk: SRISK and Precautionary Capital (today) 2. Leverage Effect (in the paper) Theoretical Foundation Structural Models of Credit œ Under relatively weak assumptions on the vol process, structural models say Et = f (At , Dt , æA,t , ø, rt ) œ œ œ œ At = market value of assets Dt = book value of debt æA,t = stochastic asset volatility Generic dynamics for assets and asset variance (allow for jumps later): dAt = µA (t)dt + æA,t dBA (t) At d æ2A,t = µv (t , æA,t )dt + æv (t , æA,t )dBv (t) œ BA (t) and Bv (t) potentially correlated Equity Returns and Equity Volatility Introducing the Leverage Multiplier œ Apply Itò„ Lemma and ignore drift (our model is daily, and daily equity returns º 0): dEt ∫t æv (t , æA,t ) = LMt æA,t dBA (t) + dBv (t) Et Et 2æA,t º LMt £ æA,t £ dBA (t) µ ∂ dEt volt º LMt £ æA,t Et œ œ œ LMt = LM (Et /Dt , 1, æA,t , ø, rt ) is the “leverage multiplier” LMt amplifies asset shocks and volatility Two questions: 1. How much does the higher order term contribute? Not Much 2. What does LMt look like? Robust shape across models The Leverage Multiplier: Three Basic Properties Discrete Time: GARCH Option Pricing 5 4 B SM 3 2 1 0 0 20 40 7 6 5 4 2 1 5 4 H e st on 2 1 0 20 40 D eb t t o E q u i t y 20 40 60 D eb t t o E q u i t y Lev er a g e M u l t i p l i er Lev er a g e M u l t i p l i er D eb t t o E q u i t y 6 3 MJ D 3 0 0 60 15 60 10 8 Lev e r age Mult iplie r Lev er a g e M u l t i p l i er Lev er a g e M u l t i p l i er Popular Continuous Time Option Pricing Models 6 10 5 BSM G ARC H-N G ARC H-t G J R-N G J R-t 6 4 SVJ 2 0 0 20 40 60 0 0 5 10 D eb t t o E q u i t y 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 De bt t o Eq uit y 1. LM(0) = 1. Mechanical, since assets = equity 2. Monotonically increasing. More leverage means more risk 3. Concave. Reducing leverage more powerful than increasing leverage 50 Structural GARCH Our Specification œ The challenge is choosing the right functional form for LMt œ We use simple transformations of Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) functions: ∑ ≥ ¥ D ∏¡ t f BSM BSM f LMt (Dt /Et , æA,t , ø) = 4t £g Et /Dt , 1, æA,t , ø £ Et œ œ g BSM (·) is inverse BSM call function. ¢BSM is BSM delta t ¡ 6= specific option pricing model Our parametrization preserves necessary properties of LM , but still allows us to change its scale The Full Recursive Model Structural GARCH rE ,t = LMt °1 £ rA,t = LMt °1 £ q h A ,t £ " A ,t hA,t ª GJR(!, Æ, ∞, Ø) ∑ ≥ ¥ D ∏¡ t °1 BSM BSM f LMt °1 = 4t °1 £ g Et °1 /Dt °1 , 1, æA,t °1 , ø £ Et °1 s ∑t +ø ∏ X æfA,t °1 = Et °1 h A ,s s =t So parameter set is £ = (!, Æ, ∞, Ø, ¡) Estimation Results Estimation Details œ œ œ Estimate for 82 financials via QMLE; iterate over ø 2 [1, 30] Equity returns and balance sheet information from Bloomberg Dt is exponentially smoothed book value of debt œ œ smoothing parameter = 0.01, so half-life of weights º 70 days We estimate the model using two approaches for æfA,t °1 , then use the highest likelihood: 1. A dynamic forecast for asset volatility over life of the option 2. The unconditional volatility of the asset GJR process Bank of America: Structural GARCH Estimation Annualiz e d Volat ility ¡ = 1.4 (t = 11.4) 3 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 1998 Le ve r age Mult iplie r Asse t s E q u i ty 2.5 2000 2002 2004 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2006 2008 2010 2012 20 15 10 5 0 1998 Dat e Parameter Values Cross-Sectional Summary of Estimated Parameters Parameter ! Æ ∞ Ø ¡ œ œ œ Mean 2.7e-06 0.0458 0.0721 0.9024 0.9834 Mean t-stat 1.70 3.07 2.91 80.08 4.00 % with |t | > 1.64 47.2 86.1 80.6 100 73.6 (!, Æ, ∞, Ø) are standard GJR parameters - for assets, not equity Average ø = 8.34 Leverage matters Application: SRISK SRISK How much would a financial firm need to function normally in another crisis? œ Acharya et. al (2012) and Brownlees and Engle (2012) œ Three steps: 1. GJR-DCC model using firm equity and market index returns 2. Expected firm equity return if market falls by 40% over 6 months ¥ LRMES 3. Combine LRMES with book value of debt to determine capital shortfall in a crisis œ The crisis in this case is a 40% drop in the stock market index over 6 months The Role of Leverage? Thought Experiment with Structural GARCH œ Firm experiences sequence of negative equity (asset) shocks œ Level of leverage goes up rapidly œ Leverage multiplier increases, equity vol amplification higher œ Painfully obvious in the crisis, so build into SRISK Bank of America Capital Shortfall: 2006-2011 Precautionary Capital Defining Precautionary Capital e.g. How much additional equity would a bank need, today, to be 90% sure they won’t need bailout money in a future crisis? œ SRISK: how much capital would a firm need in a financial crisis to return to a equity/asset ratio of k %? œ Precautionary Capital: How much capital do we have to add to the firm today so that we can have a level of certainty, Æ, that the firm meets a capital requirement of k % in a crisis? œ Uses the quantiles of the future return distribution œ We set k = 2% and vary Æ Primary Takeaway in a Nutshell œ Standard volatility models don’t have a channel for leverage, so adding equity to the firm today won’t reduce future risk œ Structural GARCH: reducing leverage today reduces future risk œ œ The effect is further enhanced by the concavity of the LM Engle and Siriwardane (2014) use this idea to suggest a risk-based total leverage capital requirement Precautionary Capital: BAC BAC on 10/1/2008: E0 = 173.9 bn; D0 = 1, 670.1 bn k=0.02 Confidence that Firm Meets Capital Requirement in Crisis (%) 100 90 80 GJR 70 Structural GARCH 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 −200 −100 0 100 200 300 400 Size of Equity Injection (bn) 500 600 700 What’s Next Other Applications œ Endogenous Crisis Probability with Structural GARCH œ Estimation of Distance to Crisis œ Endogenous Capital Structure and Leverage Cycles œ Counter-cyclical Capital Regulation œ Model of CDS Volatility Appendix Ignore Higher Order Terms ∫t æv (t , æA,t ) dEt = LMt æA,t dBA (t) + dBv (t) Et Et 2æA,t How much do the higher order terms contribute? œ Not much. Simple intuition... œ Volatility mean reversion speed ø typical debt maturities, so ... œ œ Back Total volatility over option is effectively constant We verify in paper for variety of option pricing models Dynamic Forecast vs Constant Forecast œ Estimate two types of models: 1. Using a dynamic forecast for asset volatility over life of the option 2. Using unconditional volatility of GJR process œ Then take the model that delivers the highest likelihood œ A few outliers where ¡ hits lower bound (exclude from subsequent analysis): œ SCHW, JNS, LM, BK, BLK, NTRS, CME, CINF, TMK, UNH