Secure Tenure Production: A Land Parais6polis, Sio Dispute Resolution Paulo, Brazil Process for by Alyce M. Russo A.B., Government and Economics Georgetown University (1984) Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degrees of Master of City Planning and Master of Science in Engineering at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology January 1989 © Alyce M. Russo 1989 The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute copies of this thesis document in whole or in part. Signature of Author Alyce M. Russo Department of Urban Studies and Planning January, 1989 Certified by Professor Lawrence Susskind Department of Urban Studies and Planning Thesis Supervisor Accepted by Doniald l. _,w,,- Schon Chair, Master of City Planning Program 7Departpent of Urban Studies and Planning Accepted by Ole S. Madsen Chairman, Committee on Graduate Students Civil Engineering Department MAM U~iTJ i#67f7Uic FEB 2 3 1989 U8MA1 Acknowledgments I would like to thank the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy for funding my Special thanks to Benjamin research trip to Brazil over the summer of 1988. this work would add to the that foresight his for Research, of Director Chinitz, knowledge base of land tenure in developing countries. Many thanks to my thesis advisors, Professor Lawrence Susskind, They have not only Professor James Paddock and Professor William Doebele. introduced me to new ideas but also have exhibited a tremendous amount of patience with my application of these ideas to land tenure. Thanks to Shlomo Angel for introducing me to the idea of Land Sharing through the MIT, SIGUS workshop. Many thanks to the many Brazilian public officials, academics, and private individuals who shared not only information but, more importantly, In particular, I their thoughts and perspectives on a very sensitive issue. would like to thank... Isaura Campana, as she was the first person I met who was directly She received me, both personally and involved with the case study area. Her confidence and enthusiasm in her work maintained my professionally. spirit during the research and is something to be admired. Marcos Gongalves for his time and patience in sharing his experience and knowledge of low-income housing construction in Brazil. Their openness, trust and The residents of the favela of Parais6polis. I hope there are more complete. more hospitality have made this research future. the in avenues for communication Celso and Betty Oliveira for their friendship, discussions, Portuguese practice, and hospitality during the closing moments of the thesis. Mane Alves, my inquisitive MIT colleague, good friend, and housing Thanks to you I have been able to investigate new ideas and seek out explorer. To the never ending search for knowledge and "the innovative projects. housing solution"! To Lucila and Alvaro Borges, my family away from home. If it were not for our meeting 10 years ago I would not have found my way to Brazil (so many times). To my father, whose knowledge of housing, construction and finance has been invaluable, and whose support and encouragement of my ideas has given me confidence to pursue my goals. To Steven Schall, my colleague, my editor, my friend and now my husband, your patience and support to the bitter end is unbelievable. 2 Abstract A Land Secure Tenure Production: Parais6polis, Sio Paulo, Brazil Dispute Resolution Process for by Alyce M. Russo Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in Partial Fulfillment for the Degrees of Master of City Planning and Master of Science in Engineering The problem of insecure land tenure in developing countries merits attention for several reasons. People's lives are disrupted, whether they be squatters facing eviction or land owners unable to assert their right of ownership. Property values, as a result of the insecurity, do not reflect the highest and best use of the land. The judicial system is burdened (as are the litigants) with years of court battles in an effort to prove land ownership. Cities are faced with underinvestment in housing on the part of the land owners and squatters due to insecure tenure. While tenure security alone may not generate development, it is a prerequisite for most housing investment. Thus, improved land tenure security in developing countries is crucial to any overall housing improvement. Some attention has been given to solving land tenure disputes in the developing world. Angel and Boonyabancha have developed and implemented land sharing schemes to resolve disputes over public land in Thailand. In Sio Paulo, Brazil, the municipal government has enacted a law that allows a change zoning to developers who contribute to a fund for the rehousing of favelas. But to date, an outline of the process for resolving land tenure disputes, as well as a financial tool to facilitate the search for a feasible solution, has not been addressed. In this thesis, Secure Tenure Production (STEP) is proposed as a method of resolving land tenure disputes in a case study area in Sio Paulo (privatelyowned land). STEP is most clearly characterized by a negotiation process that utilizes cross-subsidies to produce a win/win consensus resulting in secure tenure. STEP, the process and the physical outcome, draws on the traditional use of land sharing, transfer of development rights, inclusionary zoning, linkage and land readjustment. Building on the land sharing work of Angel and Boonyabancha, and the negotiation theories and achievements of Cruikshank and Susskind, I have formulated STEP to include all the stakeholders and their interests into a fair, efficient, wise, and stable dispute consensus-building process and outcome. The STEP process is integrative bargaining, not distributive, and represents an alternative to a zero-sum game. This thesis will utilize the case study of a disputed, privately-owned parcel of land in the favela of Parais6polis to illustrate the STEP dispute resolution process. The process also integrates a financial model to aid in the search for 3 a feasible win/win solution. In regard to the financial model, I not only argue for the need to integrate one into the process, but also that a specific method of financial evaluation--the Valuation by Components Method (VC). This thesis offers .. solution to a in the favela of Parais6polis in Sdo solution, though, is the contribution the proposed process and financial case study of disputed privately-owned land Paulo. More important than the proposed to the study of land tenure disputes that methodology provide. Thesis Supervisor: Lawrence Susskind Title: Professor of Urban Studies and Planning 4 Table Secure Tenure Production: of Contents A Land Dispute Resolution Process for Parais6polis, Slo Paulo, Brazil CHAPTER ONE: Introduction...................................................................................... 8 Introduction of The Case Study....................................................20 CHAPTER TWO: Sources of Tenure insecurity Existing Solutions to Land Insecurity Institutional Problems of Resolving Tenure The Case Study of Parais6polis BATNA Stakeholders: CHAPTER THREE: Characteristics, BATNAs, Interests and Fears Elements of Secure Tenure Production..................................62 Considerations Criteria for a "Good Outcome" Intermediary Satisfying Interests and Fears Negotiation Tasks--The Case Study of Parais6polis.................92 CHAPTER FOUR: Hypothetical Conflict Prenegotiation Representation Fact Finding and Inventing CHAPTER FIVE: Options The Role of a Financial Model in Packaging a STEP Consensus............................................ A Knowledge-Building and Communication What a Financial Model Needs To Do Options for Securing 109 Tool Tenure Production Defining the Components of the Projects Obtaining the Information Related to Outflows and Inflows Risk Analysis Feasibility Formalizing the Agreement CH APTER SIX : Conclusion............................................................................................166 Advice for Implementation of Elimination of Insecurity General Advice to Each of the Stakeholders Criticisms of Secure Tenure Production Areas for Further Research Applicability to Other Tenure Disputes in Brazil and Other Developing Countries Appendix : Description of the Financial Model and Simulation Results.........178 5 List of Maps and Tables MAPS #1: #2: #3: #4: #5: #6: Greater Sio Paulo Area Municipality of Slo Paulo and Case Study Area Location of Favelas in the Neighborhood of Parais6polis Open Spaces in the City of Slo Paulo Favela of Parais6polis Land Use Tracts in Area of Parais6polis TABLES #1: Annual Growth Rate in Municipal Population and in Favela Population #2: #3: Distribution of Favelas on Private and Public Land Population Growth in the Area of Parais6polis #4: Family Income Distribution: #5: #6: Change in Land Uses (1980-1984) for Parais6polis and Environs Satisfying Stakeholders' Interests and Fears Parais6polis and Greater S~o Paulo, 1983 #7: Net Present Values of Options for Owner, Lender, Favelados, and Government #8: Risks and Who Bears the Risks #9: Net Present Values During the Development Phase #10: #11: #12: #13: #14: Highest Expected Negotiation Value Sensitivity Analysis Land Values in the Area of Parais6polis Effective FAR's (Floor-to-Area Ratio) Apartment Sales Prices in Area of Parais6polis #15: Net Present Value During the Development Phase #16: VC Results of Financing Simulation for Owner/Developer #17: VC Results of Financing Simulation for Owner/Developer #18: #19: Present Value for Lender, Financing Combinations Highest VC for Each Option, Function of Financing 6 7 CHAPTER ONE: Introduction In developing countries, government, insecure about land tenure. invasions. squatters and developers are all Insecurity results from actual or threatened Insecurity is also created when private land owners illegally subdivide their land--without requesting approval--and then sell parcels to unsuspecting individuals. The same plot of land is sometimes sold to several investors, each of whom thinks he is the sole owner. In some instances, the state has permitted land to be settled without the necessary legal agreements. Land tenure insecurity hinders investment. While tenure security, alone, may not generate development, it is a prerequisite for most housing investment. 1 Thus, improved land tenure security in developing countries is crucial to any overall housing improvement. As cities grow, land markets change. As land occupied by non-owners increases in value, land owners want their land back, so they can encourage "higher" uses. Occupants, however, rarely wish to leave. occupants often feel they have a right to remain. Indeed the In some parts of the world, the law may grant the occupants tenure if they have utilized the land for a certain amount of time. Whether the law offers such guarantees or not, changes in land markets cause conflict. 1 Shlomo Angel. "Land Tenure for the Urban Poor." The Human Settlements Division, Asian Institute of Technology. Unpublished paper. (May 1987). 8 In most land tenure conflicts, four outcomes are possible. can intervene and remove people. The government Second, more powerful and wealthier private land owners can evict the occupants, either by buying them off or by Third, legal remedies can be sought, with one side winning and the force. other losing. This involves a substantial expenditure of time and money. Fourth, the government can appropriate the land (with compensation) reassign it. and The first three outcomes imply that land tenure disputes are zero- sum games in which one side must lose when the other wins. The fourth outcome, while not always financially viable, offers an alternative that holds out the prospect of joint gains or integrative bargains. Integrative bargaining provides bargaining. an alternative to zero-sum or distributive All-gain solutions are possible if disputing parties focus on interests, not positions, and devise "packages" that exploit their differences. 2 The goal is to increase the "size of the pie" over which the groups are fighting. When the pie is enlarged before it is divided, each person is better off (or at least no one is worse off) after the division. Bacow defines "better off" in the following way: Better thus can mean more, sooner, or with less risk. It can also mean cheaper (which includes time of participants and the actual money they may spend). 3 2 Roger Fisher and William Ury. Getting to Yes: Negotiating Agreement Without Giving In. (New York: Penguin Books, 1981) 3 Lawrence S. Bacow and Michael Wheeler. Environmental Dispute Resolution. (New York: Plenum Press, 1984), p. 27. 9 In disputes over the disposition of land, integrative bargaining is often possible because parties value things, components, differently. "Land sharing" is an example of an integrative approach to resolving land tenure disputes. Land sharing is a process by which a plot of land occupied by slum dwellers is partitioned into two parts; one part is leased or sold to the slum community to rehouse its members; the other part is returned to the land owner who can develop it to his best possible advantage. 4 Rama IV is an example of a land sharing deal in Thailand. Below is a representation of the occupied area before land sharing. 4 Shlomo Angel and Yap Kioe Sheng. "The Sengki Land-Sharing Project: A Preliminary Evaluation." Report for UNCHS (HABITAT) Nairobi, Kenya (June 1988). 10 Diagram 1 Source: Angel and Boonyabancha. "Land Sharing as an Alternative to Eviction: The Bangkok Experience". Unpublished paper, 1987. After the negotiations the land was split between the owner and the occupants. The owner retained a high-valued commercial portion with frontage along the main roads. The occupants were sold houses, at an affordable below-market price, on the remaining portion of the land. 11 Diagram Source: 2 Angel and Boonyabancha. Land sharing has been traditionally defined in the above manner. I will draw from the land sharing experience in Thailand in order to devise a method of resolving land tenure disputes using a negotiation process that produces a consensus to achieve secure tenure. as well as In this thesis. I shall refer to the process 5 any resulting consensus as Secure Tenure Production (STEP). In negotiating secure tenure, land values of either the developed land or the land for the occupants will always be a function of how much the land will 5 Henceforth, Secure Tenure Production will be referred to as "STEP". 12 contribute to the potential value of any final development; the value will not necessarily reflect only the location and potential buildable area of the land. Therefore, any process and consensus that can subsidize 6 the development of an insecure parcel of land and increase the value of the settlement to all parties can be considered a form of STEP. An integral part of STEP is the use of a change in zoning to help achieve a consensus. STEP, the process and the physical outcome, have drawn on the traditional use of land sharing, transfer of development rights, inclusionary STEP is most clearly characterized zoning linkage and land by a consensus-building utilizes cross-subsidies in order to produce a win/win solution. readjustment. process that A STEP solution can involve sharing the same parcel of land between the occupants owner. and the It can involve relocating the occupants to a site that is more acceptable to the occupants. It can involve utilizing an increase in zoning in the same location along with a transfer of development rights for other parcels. STEP agreements have several advantages over the four alternatives suggested above. The risk First, time and money can be saved by avoiding court battles. of losing everything in court is eliminated. occupants can be avoided. Second, the use of force to remove If all "stakeholders" 7 have participated in the 6 Throughout this thesis a subsidy will be considered any one of the following: cash, guarantees on loans, change in zoning or the contribution of physical assets. 7 This term will be used to refer to all parties which have a stake in the final outcome of any conflict. There are different degrees of stakeholders, as will be outline later. In general, stakeholders will refer to three major groups involved with insecure tenure: the occupants of the property, the owners of the property and the government officials or administrators. This term is 13 settlement and each receives negotiated a portion of the final development, they have an incentive to do that which is necessary to enforce the settlement, including vacating the land. Third, flexible financing is possible, e.g., the government need not provide cash subsidies as it must when land is The fourth advantage of STEP is that tenancy can be secured for appropriated. both owners and occupants. Secure tenure avoids further invasions by the same occupants of other parcels of land and, at the same time, lays the foundation for increased investment in housing. intact and maintains access to jobs. STEP keeps communities Traditional relocation schemes do not, and, as a result, many relocated land occupants have sold their new units in order to seek out more favorable locations. precedent. setting Finally, STEP deals need not set a Each conflict can be settled on its merits without concern about precedents. In this thesis, I will investigate further the concept of land sharing, that was laid out first by Angel and Boonyabancha, adapting its factors to general STEP considerations. I will define the makings of a good consensus-building process and outcome, as defined by negotiation theorists. As my contribution to the field. I will then define the process of STEP by incorporating the consensus-building conflicts. process and tasks for the resolution of land tenure In order to facilitate consensus building. I will also argue not only for the integration of a financial model into the process but also for a specific new method of financial evaluation to be utilized--the Valuation by taken from the writings of Lawrence Susskind and Jeffrey Cruikshank. Breaking The Impasse: Consensual Approaches to Resolving Public Disputes. (New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1987). 14 Components Method (VC). In order to illustrate these ideas I will use a case study in Slo Paulo. Brazil to make proposals as to how a STEP process could be formulated to resolve land tenure disputes on occupied private land. In this particular study the disputed occupied parcel is the parcel desired for further commercial development. 8 The first chapter outlines background on the city of Slo Paulo and the sources and institutional problems of insecure tenure. It also outlines the specific case study which focuses on one occupied private parcel in S~o Paulo for which Ua negotiated settlements have been reached, but which could potentially demonstrate how the STEP process could work in the developing world. Recent legislation in Slo Paulo might expedite the application of STEP for tenure disputes on privately-owned land. In December 1986, the city enacted a law (Lei Desfavelamento) 9 providing incentives to developers removal and rehousing of favelas (squatter settlements). demonstrate how STEP new Brazilian law) privately-owned 8 The to finance the I will try to (which incorporates the incentive structure in the can generate solutions to land tenure disputes on land. process defined in this paper is adaptable to other types of land tenure disputes although I have chosen to focus on occupied private property in which the same parcel is wanted for development. 9 Lei No. 10.209, Dec. 6, 1986. City of Slo Paulo, Brazil. 15 The new law is a tool to remove favelados (squatters) from both public and private land within the city. The law states that a private contractor may request a change in zoning, which consists of a change in the floor-to-arearatio (FAR), change in use and/or change in the side yards, if in exchange he is willing to give the government low-income housing. translated administratively This has been into an across-the-board payment of 50% of the increase in value, due to a change in zoning, back to the government. payment may be made in cash or in kind--infrastructure This and housing. The city can use these funds or facilities to rehouse favelados removed from public lands bound for public works projects, or located on public lands in areas of "physical risk". 1 0 If a private developer wishes to develop his parcel of land occupied by favelados, he must request a large enough change in zoning on that property and/or other properties to permit the rehousing of all the favelados occupying his parcel. responsibility In all cases, the government has the (and therefore the risk) of removing and relocating the favelados; the private developer only pays for the units into which they move. There are several novel aspects of this law. Desfavelamento Unlike most laws, the Lei de is open-ended, allowing room for a negotiation process between the developer and the government. A special team within the mayor's planning office was set up to administer and negotiate the projects with only the developer. board for a variance. 1 0 Interview Each project is treated as a request to the city zoning The zoning board has the power to approve or reject with SEMPLA personnel. 16 negotiated projects. This law also demonstrates that the city is placing a high priority on the clearance and rehousing of favelas. In order to finance this (Other priority, the city is "selling" a change in zoning to the private sector. than permitting a change in zoning for historical preservation, there have been no other like variances since the establishment of zoning laws in 1972). a) Through this approach, the city is assuming a contractual responsibility to: use the funds for no other purpose than rehousing the favelados; and b) physically remove the favelados and pay for the cost of the removal. The law also has many deficiencies, which bias its application in favor of occupied government land and deter its use on occupied private land, that is This bias stems from the desired for further commercial development. distribution of risks and returns between the developer and the government. The law creates no risk for the developer other than increased "market risk" due to the increase in volume of sellable area or change in use; government has the risk of relocation of the favela. favela from public land the government receives of the previously occupied land. whereas the In cases of removal of the housing and additional use In cases of removal from private land the government is obligated to remove the favelas, but receive nothing in return In these cases, the government other than new housing for the favelados. would be signing a contract that it may not be able to fulfill. Without a means for the favelados to enter into the negotiation process, the risks are high. government cannot guarantee property (thus, timely removal defaulting on its contract of the favelados from The private with the private developer) unless force is used--a tactic not in the interest of the government. The structure 17 and application of the law will force the government not to enter into concessionary property. agreements to secure tenure in the cases of occupied private In addition, the law requires that there be a defined legal owner of a parcel before it will enter into negotiations. Thus, the law is structured in such a way that it may not function as a favorable alternative to litigation. It is my position that the incentive of change in zoning, to "sweeten the deal", as part of STEP, should be applicable in the cases of occupied private property in cases where the tenure dispute is between the land owner and the occupants or the tenure dispute is among two or more land owners and the This application is important because 27% of all favelas in Slo occupants. Paulo are located on private land and 35% of them are located on a mixture of public and private land. 1 1 or removal by force. Thus, the law would be an alternative to litigation The only way that an agreement and implementation of a settlement can be reached under these conditions is through a consensusbuilding process, in which all the parties involved in the conflict are included in the process, i.e., the favelados, the government, and the disputing landowners, resulting in a negotiated agreement where each party finishes in a position equal to or better than his initial situation. The thesis will examine the case of Parais6polis, a favela in Slo Paulo. It is a useful an important case study to discuss my proposals because the area of 1 1 Diario Oficial do Municipio, City of Sio Paulo, December 2, 1986, p. 7. 18 Parais6polis has a substantial amount of illegally-occupied, privately-owned land, as a result of squatter invasions and years of litigation. 19 CHAPTER TWO: Introduction of The Case Study This chapter will describe the setting of the case study in S~o Paulo, Brazil. First, the sources of insecure tenure will be identified. Second, the present means of securing tenure and the institutional obstacles to achieving it will illustrate that options are limited and not sufficient to resolve all cases. The second half will be devoted to the description of the case--Parais6polis--an area within the city of S~o Paulo. The physical characteristics and interests of the stakeholders involved will be developed. of the area Through this case study insecure tenure will be seen as a cause of under-investment in housing, lower tax rolls for the city and anxiety for all of the stakeholders. The need for an additional solution--Secure Tenure Production-- in order to establish secure tenure will become apparent. Slo Paulo is a city of 10 million people, in the third largest metropolitan area in the world, after Mexico City and Beijing. Area) (See MAP #1 Greater Slo Paulo It has a serious problem of "illegal squatter-settlements"--favelas. 12 In 1988, there were 818,872 favelados occupying 150,497 dwellings in 1,594 favelas. This represents 7.8% of the total population of the city. decade, the favelado population has increased. was only 71,840. Over the last In 1973, the favela population During the 1973-1983 period, the general population grew at the rate of 59.9%, while the favela population grew at the rate- of nearly 12 For the purposes of this census, a favela is considered a set of households built of brick, tin, cardboard, wood, or corrugated steel. In general, they are built in an unorganized manner on property on which the occupants do not have legal tenure. 20 1,040%.13 The table below illustrates that the increase in growth in the favela population has been ahead of the general population growth. Table 1 Annual Growth Rate in Municipal Population and in Favela Population (in percentage) Years 1973 - 1975 1975 - 1979 1979 - 1985 Favela Population Municipal Popluation 4.44% 3.15% 3.14% 27.75% 22.79% 12.42% Source: Favelas: Fatos e Politicas (p. 81) by Suzana Pasternak Taschner The increasing number of favelas is a function of several factors; two dominate factors are the cost of housing and demolition. risen faster than salaries. Housing costs have At the same time, many of the cortigos (tenement buildings located in the city center) have been demolished. Since people are priced out of the housing market and many well-located tenements have disappeared, favelas, especially those with access to jobs and transportation, have swelled. Unlike the earlier inhabitants of the favelas who were migrant workers from the Northeast of Brazil, many favelados are now low-income 1 wage earners who have lived in the same locale for several years. 4 de Sao Paulo. SEHAB. Censo das Favelas do Municipio de S~o Paulo 1987. (April 1988) 14 Suzana Paternak Taschner. "Favelas: Fatos e Politicas," Espago e Debates. 79-105. pp. Ano.yI, 2, No. 18 (1986), 1 3 Municipio 21 Gru Us PAueo DMiso Sub-RegioaL. 1985 These so-called squatters inhabit both private and public land. available data for these numbers are from 1986. The last Thus any solution to insecure tenure must address both the question of publicly and privately occupied lands. Table 2 Distribution of Favelas on Private and Public Land (City of Sio Paulo) Owner of Area Private Municipal State Federal Mixed (a) Total Favelas (c) Nudeus (b) % of total # dwell ings % of total # dwellings % of total # dwellings 27.7 3 9,607 25.6 32,394 44.9 7,213 37.3 5 3,267 35.7 45,247 49.8 8,020 17 0 0 0 0.1 17 0 8 0 0 0 8 35 4 9,865 38.7 49,023 5.2 842 TOTAL 16,100 100 126,664 100 14 2,764 100 Source: Didrio Oficial do Municlpio, City of SAo Paulo, December 2, 1986, p. 7. Note (a): "Mixed" includes favelas situated on both public and private land Note (b): Nucleus contains 49 dwellings or less Note (c): Favela contains 50 dwellings or more For many of the favelados, the location and the price of their current housing suits their needs, even though the conditions would not be considered acceptable by developed-world standards. The question of official tenure does not appear to be a priority to the favelados as long as they are not threatened by eviction. A federal law does exist (Law of Usocapido)15 by which individuals can obtain tenure through uncontested use of land over 10, 15, or 20 years. 1 6 However, the law has many complexities that confound its 15 Codigo Civil, Federal Lei No. 3.071, 1 January 1916. 16 The three categories are outlined in the Codigo Civil. The first category, Usocapiao Ordindirio , applies to land which has been occupied continuously without opposition as well as having a bona fide purchaser. After 10 years, 23 application. First, it is not easy for occupants, who have been inhabiting land illegally, to produce proof that the cumulated time between them and past occupants meets the specified period of time of occupancy under the law. Second, if occupancy can be established there is the problem of the favelados affording the "hidden costs" in obtaining tenure, even though free lawyer associations are available. The "hidden costs" consist of time spend away from work to start an application process and to go to court plus the cost of surveying the parcel. These costs are often a hindrance in utilizing the law. 1 7 Moreover, the original owner of the land, as well as owners of the surrounding parcels, must pose no opposition to the request for tenure from the favelado; if one of these claimants appears, the favelado risks losing all he has invested. Finally, even without opposition, the approval process may take 6 months, while a court battle may take from 5 to 20 years. The tenure approval process results in long delays, high costs and may carry a high risk of losing. 1 8 the individual (Mr. X) who is the last bona fide purchaser and occupant of land that has been occupied for 10 years without challenge, will receive clear title over a challenge from another apparent bona fide purchaser who lives within the municipality. Mr. X must wait 15 years before he can claim clear title if the challenge comes from another bona fide purchaser who lives outside the municipality. Usocapiao Extraordindrio is the second category of usocapido. Title may be receive with 20 years of continuous use without opposition, independent of title or a bona fide purchaser, i.e., adverse position. A third category, Usocapiao Especial, applies only to rural areas thus it is not discussed. The above explanation was taken from interview with Paulo Guilherme de Almeida. Interview on 25 July 1988. 17A survey of the area should be conducted to establish the correct boundaries that will appear on the title of the owner, i.e. the occupant. 18 de Almeida interview. 24 of Sources Tenure Insecurity Insecurity of tenure has many sources, at least five of which can be readily identified: 19 1) Unclear title: Some parcels of land do not have a registered land owner. Some parcels have several people who hold legitimate deeds yet only one is registered. On the other hand, some parcels have one registered owner, although false deeds may arise and cause court battles. Some parcels have unregistered legitimate deed holders due to the inability of the new owner to pay delinquent taxes that the previous owner never disclosed upon the sale. 2) Squatting: Land with clouded titles, unregistered land, or land purchased years ago for speculation is often the target of squatting. Through the application of the Usocapido law, insecurity can be created or heightened for the land owner or the favelados. 2 0 The land owner or the favelados can be tied up in court for many years with a probability of loosing his land in the end. 3) Invasions: invasions. Land that has clouded title or is unregistered is prime for A traditional invasion is one in which a grillheiro is involved, the goal is for the grillheiro to obtain tenure to the land, the means takes two forms. 2 pay 1 In one case the grillheiro is the instigator of the invasion. individuals to invade a parcel of land. He will They will remain there for some years with the understanding that they are employees of the grillheiro. At 1 9 From interviews, 2 0 See above section research, and professional experience. for complication of application of the law of Usocapido. 21In recent years there have been other reasons for invasions. Some interviewees have stated that the total deficient in housing and poor living conditions have created more invasions for the purpose of obtaining shelter. 25 any point in time when the validity of the ownership of the land is in question, the occupants will claim that the grilleiro is the true owner. Grillheiros also enter into the picture through another means. Grillheiros can also enter areas that already have squatters and claim they are the real owners. titles. The grillheiro will contact the favelados and present fabricated They will ask (order) the favelados to leave the land, or just wait to accumulate as many parcels as they can for future use. When the grillheiros do not want to use the land immediately they make a pact to allow the squatters to remain and guard the land. In return, the squatters often sign a waiver to any right of ownership to the land. In either case, the grillheiro will also use the favelados in order to obtain ownership if he can not obtain it with his false deed. The grilleiro will pay the occupants to invoke the law of If the occupants gain tenure they will turn the property over to Usocapido. the grillheiro. 4) Political Patronage: When squatters are in place, they often trade their votes with politicians for protection from eviction. The politician usually will stave off eviction but not obtain a permanent solution for secure tenure. Rarely is help offered by the politician in obtaining secure tenure when a threat of eviction is not present, even when occupants might be eligible for ownership. This process sustains insecurity for both the land owners and favelados. 5) Declaration of expropriation: When areas are frozen for expropriation, invasions have occurred. (as will be seen was the case of Parais6polis) expropriation is unable to be fulfilled, due to financial If constraints, tenure becomes insecure for both the land owners and the squatters. 26 Existing Solutions to Land Insecurity: There are several existing solutions to land tenure insecurity in Brazil, although they do not appear to be sufficient for resolving all cases of insecurity. 1) Going to Court: much money. As stated, court battles tend to take many years, and consume In addition, one party wins and the other loses. 2) Expropriation: Expropriation is the traditional method by which land tenure disputes are settled. funds into an escrow account. The government expropriates the land, places the If there is any question as to who the legitimate owners are the parties must fight it out in court. 2 2 Unfortunately, it is not always financially feasible for the government to expropriate the land. Besides, if the land is occupied, the government ends up paying twice: once to the legal owners and once again for the housing or removal of the squatters. 3) "Pay Off" the Favelados: The land owners can either pay the favelados to leave the property now or pay them to sign a contract to leave in the future, waiving any rights to ownership. 4) Abandonment: If the occupied land is not valuable, some owners opt to abandon their land rather than face the hassle and expense of maintaining ownership. 2 3 If favelados are not aware of the abandonment, a better- informed grillheiro will claim title to the land. 2 2 de Almeida. 2 3 Carlos Memolo. Interview. Interview on 3 August 1988. 27 5) Partition of Land without Payment: Sometimes, a small portion of land is given as payment to squatters in order to protect further invasion of the rest 2 of the property; this is often done in the periphery. Institutional Several Problems institutional of Resolving factors contribute 4 Tenure to insecurity and hinder potential solutions in Slo Paulo. First, there appears to be informational roadblocks for the favelados, the government, and the owners. Favelados know that the Usocapiao law exists but often do not understand the applicability of the law, or for that matter where to go to get a process started. Thus, only when they are confronted with eviction do they present their cases to politicians to defend their right to stay or entangle the owner in a court battle. 2 5 At the same time, government officials and land owners do not have the expertise in development and finance to find profitable solutions. In addition, they tend to have a mind set of all or nothing, which the court system promotes. Since the beginning of the democratization of the Brazil governmental electoral system, i.e. direct elections of all officials, it appears that land owners may have less power than 2 4 Celso 2 5 1n N.E. Oliveira. Interview on 12 September 1988. past years, with lower levels of organization within the favelas, people would believe anyone who showed a deed and move out or sign a waiver of Also, from interview with Maria ownership, without verifying the deed. Betania Ferreira Mendonga, 27 July 1988. 28 in the days of military dictatorship; numbers of votes may weigh more to public officials. 2 6 A major institutional source of insecurity is the high standards of subdivisions that result in high costs of creating formal subdivisions. This high cost reduces access to formal subdivisions for the majority of the population in Sao Paulo. The excess demand for housing is supplied by illegal subdivisions which are accompanied by insecure tenure. be overlooked. generate This institutional factor cannot A plan, such as STEP which incorporates cross-subsidies, can alternative financing methods increasing ends of the income scale. the housing stock at both If a plan also includes education of the value of secure tenure and offers the possibility to enter into the formal market, favelados will have less of a probability of entering into another transaction involving insecure tenure. Finally, before the Lei de Desfavelamento, an incentive never existed to negotiate a win/win agreement. support this win/win agreement. Now, occupied land may generate funds to Large privately owned areas that were frozen for future use by the government but never appropriated, require the city council to pass a law unfreezing the entire area for future developed. In some cases, land owners, favelados and involved government agencies can not come to a consensus that represents an equitable solution for all. Thus this 2 6 This is an observation on my part. Both the politicians and land owners may not be aware of this yet, or may not have developed strategies which work under these new conditions. 29 institutional problem creates insecure tenure for all involved, because none of the stakeholders make a decision. The new Lei de Desfavelamento, dismantles this institutional block by overriding the zoning laws, as well as the need to have a law passed for entire areas. The establishment of parcel- to-parcel trades enables all stakeholders to respond to needs of coalitions within larger stakeholder-groups to build a consensus. 2 7 The Case Identifying Study of Parais6polis the Conflict In 1921, the neighborhood of Parais6polis, consisting today of 1,300,000 square meters was the inheritance of Alfonso de Oliveira Santos. 2 8 The property was isolated physically, on the other side of the river Pinheiros (see MAP #2 and MAP #3), at that time the border of the city of Slo Paulo. primarily The land was farming 2 7 Flexibility in the negotiation process might also mitigate the institutional problem of non-registration due to back taxes. All back taxes must be paid in order to register a parcel of land as well as receiving approval for Many times transactions with land are done without a review of development. back taxes. Thus many individuals have not registered their land because they do not have the sufficient cash to pay the taxes. By exempting land owners from this rule as part of a land sharing deal less cash would be needed to register land. 2 8 Cenaviva. Interview. 30 Center Rio Tiete ase- 23-30r o I 1314S Limits de Zona Limit de Distrito 0 Subdistrito 1 24'00 0 _ 5 Ikm MAP #2: Municipality of Sio Paulo and Case Study Area I~0 I,- -CAR ~ R5] A: Area that contains Porto Seguro Favela 11: Area that contains Paraisdpolis FavMa C: Area that contains Jardim Columbo Favela MAP "3: I.ocation of Favelas in the Neighborhood of Parais6polis area and had no infrastructure. By 1929, Mr. Santos decided to liquidate his inheritance by subdividing the land and sell off the small lots. Mr. Santos sold most of the plots to people living in other major Brazilian cities. Several plots were sold multiple times and registration of the titles was difficult to monitor. Since the owners usually lived far from their properties lacking a bird's eye view of their parcel and the increase in value of urban land had not yet reached the area, people who did not have title to the land began to settle it, approximately in the 1950's. Once the Governor's Palace was built in the adjacent neighborhood, Morumbi, and a bridge was built connecting the area to the center of the city, land values and development increased. Many wealthy people wanted to live near this impressive and powerful building and have access to the city. 2 9 This trend signified the creation of the neighborhood of Morumbi, which consists, even today, of large mansions. This area mirrors wealthy suburbs of the United States. As Morumbi grew, so did the settlement of what today is called the Neighborhood of Parais6polis, which contains three separate favelas: Parais6polis, Porto Seguro, and Jardim Columbo (See MAP #3)30. The increase of civil construction and domestic services in the area generated a demand for low-wage workers. The logical place for these workers to live was in a location that shielded the physical unpleasantness of low-income life from the luxury of the mansions. As a result, the favela of Parais6polis was settled in a 2 9 Isolda Paiva Carvalho. Interview on 17 August 1988. that the area of the case study is called Parais6polis as well as one of the favelas which make up the area. The use of Parais6polis will refer to the area, unless identified otherwise in the text. 3 0 Note 33 valley within walking distance of large mansions. Today the favelas of Parais6polis is sandwiched between the low density area of mansions and a high-rise strip of upper-income apartments.(See The owners did not live near their Why was the land in Parais6polis settled? properties and had no use for the land. Map#3) As the value of the area increased, some 30 years later, most of the owners had to overcome several obstacles to regain the use of their land. Many problems over the title of the land began to appear as development tried to take place. Several legitimate owners found that there were other legitimate owners, each unbeknownst to the other at the time of purchase. Favelados had occupied the land, and some owners believed force would have to be used to resolve the conflict, even if legal title could be established. Also, many heirs to the properties were either very old or had no interest (or need for the money) in starting the long confrontation; or there were now many heirs to the same piece of land with each heirs desiring a different outcome. 31 and heirs. There have been many disputes between the occupants The potential value of the resolution of these cases to each heir is usually so small that the fight is not worth pursuing seeing that all proceeds would have to be split between all the heirs. abandoned by their legal owners. Thus, some properties are The confusion of the legal problems and the low value of the land over time was well known as an obstacle to the development of the property, and as such the land was seen as prime for squatting. 3 1 According to Brazilian law, an individual's estate must be divided between the children, half going to the spouse and half to the children. and the spouse 34 Prior to 1968, there was no public intervention on behalf of the squatters or the land owners in Parais6polis. During the next 15 years, several public initiatives are worth noting: 3 2 1968: Decreto (public decree) no. 7.180/68 officially designated areas for playgrounds and public parks. 1971: Decreto no. 9.724/71 declared that the city would expropriate part of the area of Parais6polis to create a green area. 1972: The zoning law for the city was created. Lei no. 7.805/72 stated that as part of the zoning plan, part of the area would have the zoning of Z8-0.29, and the area would be "frozen". Z8-0.29 designates the area for future expropriation as green open space. Owners could build in the area, but such construction would be restricted to a floor-to-area-ratio (FAR) of only 0.29--basically a house. This restriction lowered the value of the land. 1973, 1975, and 1978: the Z8 zone in Parais6polis was enlarged. 1978: Decreto no. 15.556/78 expropriated the land to be a green area and allowed several proposals to develop low-income housing to be considered. As expropriation began, the State decided to service the area with water and electricity. Many complications arose during the expropriation period and in 1980, Decreto no. 16.751/80 revoked the expropriation process. 1981: Lei no. 9.411/81 further expanded the area of the Z8 zoning to bring the area up to today's existing area of 1,300,000 square meters An impasse exists in Parais6polis today: no development rights for the supposed land owners, no ownership rights for the squatters, and inconsistency and inability on the part of the government to deal with one of the most populous and largest favelas in the city of Sio Paulo. 3 2 AIl Squatting the following laws and decrees are from the city of Slo Paulo. information has been outlined in several EMURB reports. The 35 accelerated with the government's announcement that it would expropriate the land for a green area. It should be noted that the early 1970's were a time of depression and hardship in the Brazilian economy, which only fueled the expansion of squatting. In the early 1970's, it was estimated that 60 families were living on approximately half the present area of the favela of Parais6polis. 3 3 By 1983, approximately 3,500 families were in the total area of the favela, 3 4 and it is estimated that 5,000 families are now living in the same area. 3 5 The early 1980's were characterized by a boom in the development of highrise apartment buildings on the other side of the valley in which the favela is situated. The developers capitalized on the name and image of the Morumbi neighborhood and an increasing demand for the security (from crime) that high-rise apartments could offer. the favela was an added attraction. servant. 3 6 The large pool of cheap labor provided by It would be easy to engage a domestic At the same time, the state installed infrastructure in the area of Parais6polis, under a campaign to assist under-serviced areas. increased infrastructure and further development, As a result of the value of the land 3 3 EMURB. "Reurbanizagao Parais6polis." 1984. da Familia e Bem Estar Social - Butantd. "Favela Parais6polis: Relatorio Preliminar." August 1984. 3 5 Antonio Teixeira. Interview on 8 August 1988. Also, from Mendonga interview. The number is only an estimate because the census-takers did not survey Parais6polis. 5,000 families appears to be accepted by all the stakeholders, including the land owners. 3 6 0ne interviewee stated that friends who live in the high rise apartments often call down to the porter and ask him to round up some one to go to the store for them. The porter would then call someone in the favela to do this work. 3 4 Secretaria Municipal 36 occupied by the favelas increased in value. The high-rise development created potential increased value in the surrounding land and may have led to the reversal of the expropriation of the land, because the potential value was the agreed upon expropriation higher than price. During this period, several organs within the government tried to develop land sharing schemes to urbanize the entire area at once. Due to the planned relocation of all the occupants to the southern corner of the area, expropriation was always a component of the projects put forth, yet none were ever accepted. In 1985, a proposal for transferring the development rights to other properties in the area and developing the area as a whole, once again was put forth. Stakeholders, made suggestions, at times, talked with each other, although owners without discussing options with the occupants. There were many problems with the above proposals, in both the process and the substance of the outcome. First, the favelados were consistently offered apartments in an area that is comparable to a small version of the Grand The favelados all said it was dangerous to live in that area because the Canyon. slopes were so steep that a house would not be safe from being washed away during rains. 3 7 the land. Second, the government did not have the funds to expropriate Third, the developers were waiting for a law to enable them to remove the favelados from the area. Finally, a law had to be passed by elected officials in order to implement the projects. 3 7 Alvaro Pereira Santos. The area consisted of 25 to 30 Interview on 1 August 1988. 37 thousand people--too many votes were on the line for politicians to declare removal; the approach was a failure from the start. Beyond this, all the stakeholders, as will be seen, had very different interests and fears--one equal By the end of solution for all the stakeholders would not produce a consensus. 1985, the impending approval of the Lei de Desfavelamento was an incentive for developers to believe that they might have a new way to remove the favelas. Since the adoption of the Lei de Desfavelamento, one project has been proposed in the area of Parais6polis. It asks for the removal of 66 houses in exchange for an increase in FAR on the occupied property as well as another property. As of now, no information relating to the negotiation has been divulged. Thus, this thesis will not compare an optimal negotiation process to the actual, because there has been no actual negotiation to date. Instead, the thesis will propose a negotiation process to build consensus, Secure Tenure Production--STEP, but first an introduction of the area and the stakeholders is necessary. The Physical Characteristics of the Neighborhood of Parais6poliS As of 1988, Parais6polis contains 1,300 hectares. largest open spaces in the city (See MAP #4). under the zoning of Z8-0.29. It is still considered one of the The total area is now frozen The area is serviced by water and electricity. section on the east side of Avenue Gronchi (see MAP #5) The is bordered by large 38 estates of high-income families; high rise apartments are to the west. cemetery lies to the south, and the Avenue borders to the north. A The section on the west side of Giovanni Gronchi is bordered by large higher-income apartment buildings. The topography of the area varies from block to block. In the south and the north, there are very large ravines. 38 the total area is occupied by favelados. Thirty percent of Green areas and substantial amounts of vacant land still exist although interspersed among the favelados (see MAP #5). 3 8 EMURB 1984. SEMPLA interviews. Memo from Arnaldo Paoliello. 39 OS GRAN DES VAZIOSDESAO PAU LO -da *CAANDIRU -Os 400 COO mretros quaudrados pisao tern ludo para se usat ,rciaus. Dever! set cue, sqwiodo urbanistAs, o dtmstino d~a reAno CAMPO DE A4ARTE - Not sm S mil~es de metras qlzadrados pod. surgir um.paqwu. HA mwita genle pensando nisso - fors da Aeronlutica. a quern pertence o term-no. CIIACARAS (IA.CANTAREIRA Maim vazio *urban* de Sjo Fau*M. corn 10 ri~sdomto quadrados dividiuos entre a Saw~a CAsa paulistan e pequens chacareiros insaLuios hM ateao an SANTAN IZONA AAETR6 LESTE rv I ao BNDES. Pool"I CDAOE JAROLM Area 4obre de 300 000 awmoquadra&dos, ent re as avenid.. Cidade Jardirn eluaceino bKubitchck junto a Marginal, popniuldAde de 6rglos f ederais e es'aduass. Autenfico fili no freezer. SANTO AMARO Corredor oe 300 000 Lestce~.-siecdo mctr6. Vai vaoruar -wemutnu pr~xirns arias. rsta con;uu~da. MA TAL&.ZO- No :ocil. antes sede das1 induhtrias, demAr set erjuido urn shovpiag ALTO DE PINPICIROS - Neisa 4rea de I rilhlo de metrios quadrdos ezistem tres proje(os - 25 locrfe$ da C P0. 80 pred.s da faiia Abd~tila e urn paeque corucebido pelo governo do Estado. - .1 AREAS DA LUBECA EDA kVELA PARAIS6POLItS - A pnrneiri, uma extenslo do Momm~bi corn 1,5 milhio de mefros quadrados. twl pt~dios. A oulra tern Ioorafia irrepulaz e S 000 buaracos de favela&s em ma l imnie. Represa de .uarapiranga ~ . KELIOPOUS - 500 000 metro quadxadm emn que eonviem um.& emxme I avela e uinma etaIode tratiamento da Sabesp. Urna are-A conrepLcada. Aur~otomo EINTRLACL, mihe emte tPIRANCA udao - vcpdrd ptir a- Represa Billings "MAP #4: Open Spaces in the City of Sdo Paulo MAP #4 Legend a park can be created. 2.5 million m2, CAMPO DE MARTE: On its idea, aside from the Air Many people are thinking about this Force, to whom this land belongs. the complex can be used in The 400, 000 m2 jail CARADIRU: construction of residential and commercial buildings. According to urban planners, this should be the future destiny of the area. The largest urban open space in CHACARAS DA CANTAREIRA: divided bewteen Santa Casa is Paulo, with 10 million m2, small farmers who have been located in region for years. Sao and ZONA METRO LESTE: A strip of 300,000 m2. Runs parallel with the E-W Metro Line. The value will increase greatly in the next years. an enormous 500, 000 m2, in which sit HELIOPOLIS: water treatment plant. A complicated area. favela and a AUTODROMO DE INTERLAGOS (raceway): Its 3 million m2 are asking to be transformed into a giant recreation area. In this area of 1 million m2 exist 3 projects ALTO DE PINHEIROS: -- 25 hi-rise towers, 80 buildings of the Abdalia family, and a park conceived by the state government. CIDADE JARDIM: A "noble" area of 300,000 m2 between Av.Cidade with the Marginal and Juscelino Kubitschek, along Jardim is like "the agencies. It Owned by federal and state (highway). filet in the freezer." The first is an AREAS DA LUBECA AND PARAISOLPOLIS FAVELA: extension of Morumbi, has 1.5 million m2, and will have dwellings The second has an irregular topography and 5,000 shacks on it. for favelados inside its boundaries. Problematic. In this locale, there was going to be a MATARAZZO: center. The land, hypothetically, belongs to BDNES. shopping PKIINOT ft W 0 s E 90 *115 44 ~~+ - + 414 A AM olo ,, - a, *' MAP#5 Favela of Paraisopolis Favelas - Sistema CartogrAfco Metropowano da Grande SAo Pauo .9 High- and middle-income homes t + FOLHA:SF-23 -Y -C -V Lm- income homes I -2-NO-E -II Apartment buildings lasttutins -' ESCAL-A 1:5000 Paved roads Unpaved roads Qreenare"s GrWad Sao PamSA Stakeholders Analysis of Parais6polis as of 1988 The first step in negotiation is to identify the parties involved in the case, their alternatives to resolving the conflict, their interests and fears. stakeholders are involved in Parais6polis. Many Although one would think that stakeholders on one side of the table would have common concerns, it is inevitable that differences exist among them on specific issues, which creates coalitions within the groups. These tasks of definition, alternatives, interests and fears of the stakeholders will be addressed after a brief discussion of BATNA's. BATNA A BATNA is an acronym for the "Best Alternative to a Negotiated Agreement." As it is traditionally defined by Fisher and Ury, 3 9 a BATNA is the best estimate by a stakeholder of his probability of winning or gaining without negotiation. Without negotiating, the land owner might have a 20% chance of winning in court, while spending "x" amount of money and "y" amount of time. be the best--the most feasible-- alternative to negotiation. This may The process of defining one's own BATNA is only half of the chore; each group should also try to define the BATNAs of its counterparts. 3 9 Fisher and Ury. their book. The ideas in the following BATNAs are not easily section have been adapted from 43 quantifiable, and many BATNAs may appear to be equal. Therefore, the following discussion will not necessarily focus on quantifying the BATNAs, but rather on identifying these alternatives and approximating the best of the lot. The purpose of identifying a BATNA is twofold. First, it is a means by which the stakeholders can evaluate participation in the negotiation process. If any one of the parties feels that a negotiated agreement cannot improve its BATNA, then that party will not have any incentive to come to the negotiation table. Secondly, the BATNA is a means by which each party can evaluate the possible offers that arise during the negotiation process. If, at any point in time, the potential agreement does not better the stakeholder's BATNA, should be rejected. then the deal Entering and evaluating negotiated deals in this manner maintains more flexibility. A stakeholder should not walk away from a deal that does not beat his best alternative, even if it is not exactly that for which he had hoped. In addition, it should be recognized that a negotiation process and agreement do not mean that each stakeholder will better his BATNA by equivalent amounts, but only that each &il In the case of a land dispute, 12. and the group. better his BATNA. dimensions of the BATNA exist: the individual The actors in each group are dependent on each other, just as the groups are dependent upon each other. It is critical to establish this dependence in order to bring people to the table and to turn a win/lose 44 outcome into a win/win outcome. 4 0 Each party has something the other needs in order to realize its own goals; thus, room for trading exists so that all can realize their goals. A comparison of the significance of individual versus group actions may A group L.ct indicate that group actions exercise more leverage and security. effectively take a stand against a proposed plan of action, when it finds itself in a defensive position. cooperative, But if the structure of the relationship is to be a group that declares "we all want one thing" (a one-solution posture) will hinder the actual consensus-building process. In the case of securing land tenure, the goal should be to secure land tenure for all parties involved, i.e., both the favelados and the land owners. The actual physical product of the negotiation needs to satisfy the different needs within the groups of land owners and favelados. Typical one-solution posture associated with group action can reinforce opponents' views that the solution should b& homogeneous (each individual should receive the same thing). A solution based on these perceptions could prevent potential negotiators from even coming to the table because true differences do exist within the stakeholder groups. Thus, group representation and action need to be utilized very cautiously. 40 Roy J. Lewicki and J.A. Litterer. importance book. of dependence (Homewood, IL: among stakeholders Irwin, 1985). The is developed extensively in this 45 BATNAs are not stagnant over time. Events outside of the disputing parties' control, as well as incentives offered by each party, can shift to influence BATNAs. In negotiating a Secure Tenure Production (STEP), for example, there is no guarantee that the housing market will stay the same or improve over time; one owner might offer a large house for each of the favelados yet one year later with market conditions being less optimistic he might only offer a plot of land. At the same time, no accurate forecast of the time needed to resolve the problem in court exists. In addition, judges may change their perspectives over time or laws may shift indicating an advantage to one party over the other. Finally, the local or federal government may change its stance over time, resulting in an advantage for one party or the other. Each disputing party can also produce both incentives and disincentives for other stakeholder by changing, or attempting to change the BATNAs of other stakeholders. The government can offer an incentive to the developer, such as zoning changes or guarantees. On the other hand, the private land owners can bring about disincentives to change the positions of the favelados. latter is more often the case. The The owners will often try to buy out each favelado with a small sum of cash. A land owner might also resort to arson in order to remove people quickly or intimidate occupants. A land owner might hire individuals within the favela to harass "non-compliant favelados" or pay a group of people to thwart the organizational process among the favelados. At the same time, the favelados can use the media, the church and the political parties that are vying for their votes to influence the land owners indirectly. 46 These political groups can bring to the forefront any perceived injustices to the public's and government's attention. BATNAs are not only hard to determine quantitatively at the beginning, but also can be moving targets as time goes on or as negotiations progress. Ury and Fisher notes that each group should never lose sight of its BATNA and should realize when it is better to stop negotiating--if the BATNA appears to be better than a negotiated agreement. Stakeholders: Characteristics, BATNAs, Interests and Fears I. THE LAND OWNERS: General Characteristics A) Size of Holding: Small and Large There are approximately 2,000 lots within the area of Parais6polis. There does not appear to be an accurate count of land owners today, but there are both small and large land holders within the area. B) Occupation of Land Holder: Legitimate Developer, Old Inheritor, Young Inheritor, Grillheiro, High-Income House Owners, and Favelados. There are six identifiable types of land owners: 1) Several developers who have bought parcels with the hope of developing a project. 2) Older individuals who bought the land as an investment or with the hope of giving the land to their heirs to build a house. 3) Young 47 inheritors who no immediate use for the land; they have often abandoned the land since the costs of vacating the land were too high to make holding the land productive. Such inheritors have another profession that brings them income, unlike the developer. 4) A group of owners called grillheiros. They present fabricated titles to the favelados and ask (order) them to leave the land, or just wait to accumulate as many parcels as they can for future use. When the grillheiros do not want to use the land immediately, they will pay the individuals to occupy the land as their employees. This is often done on land that was never registered or on land that has been abandoned. 5) Several high-income house owners who live within the boundaries of the favela. 6) Favelados who have gained title to the land and are living on their property. They often have additional smaller houses or rooms rented out on their property. C) The Status of Title: Clear, Clouded, or At Risk for Loss. Some titles are clear. Others are clouded and in pending court battles. Some titles may be lost if the occupants have been living on the land for more than 20 years without objection. 41 (See the previous section for explanation of the application of the law Usocapiao). 41At the time of writing, the Brazilian Constitution was in the approval process. One of the articles proposes that only 5 years be necessary to gain tenure in urban areas. 48 Land Owners' Alternatives to Resolve the Conflict A land owner's alternatives are to wait for the government to remove all the favelas, to try and buy off the favelados, or to go to court and face either losing title or winning the right to remove the favelados. requires a lot of time and money. Each of the three options For the individual land owner, within the larger neighborhood of Parais6polis, it is evident that any of these alternatives leaves him in an even worse position than if he were to join forces with the rest of the land owners. If he wins a court battle, his land would still not be worth very much if it were surrounded by or adjacent to a favela. The owner can also pressure the government to remove the favela, but he alone cannot bring enough power to bear to effect this outcome. For these reasons, apparently, a group of land owners in Parais6polis has collectively arrived at a more favorable BATNA, which has manifested itself in the "Association of the Friends of the Neighborhood of Parais6polis" (Sociedade dos Amigos do Bairro de Paraisdpolis). It was the increase in value of the land that prompted the group's formation in 1980.42 Land is increasing in value, and evidence may suggest that the developers and land owners market strategy is to build before the market becomes saturated. 43 The Sociedade wants to urbanize area. To this end, it has been trying for 4 2 M~molo interview. 4 3 This pressure has been driven in the last years by the initiation of the tunnel to Morumbi, which will provide greater access between the area and the center of the city. Interviews with various developers and land owners throughout the city of Slo Paulo. 49 several years to remove the favela, to secure control over the use of the land, and to release the land from the con gelamento (freezing of zoning). government, though, can issue a guarantee for the release of the land. Only the The government can also remove the favelados, but it has been unable or unwilling to do so. As a result, only the favelados can guarantee a timely relocation and protect the land from further invasion. owners need the favelados. Paradoxically, the land Only if the land owners reach an agreement with the favelados, can the elimination of a potential court battle be assured. Thus, the BATNA for the land owners is to go to court, and at the same time try to buy off the squatters. LAND OWNERS' INTERESTS: General 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) Interests of the land owner: To To To To To reach a quick solution obtain clear title in cases of dispute have development rights, vacated land re-zone the frozen area decrease risk in implementation,--to have a speedy and secure removal of occupants 6) To minimize forceful confrontation 7) Not to use self-built housing, because it takes a long time and does not support the formal construction industry 8) Not to talk with criminals (e.g., murderers, thieves) among the favelados. Property Owners' A) B) C) D) E) F) G) who want to develop, but have no cash to develop who want to sell the parcel who have an income and want to continue to speculate who want to develop, and need no cash to develop who want to settle a court case who want to expropriate unregistered land who want the favela removed Those Those Those Those Those Those Those Subgroups and Interests: Property Owners' Fears: 1) Government will not live up to its decision 2) Favelados cannot be represented by legitimate individuals; leaders cannot make concessions that the group will recognize. 3) Their property will be devalued because of adjacent low-income housing. 50 4) Political parties and the Church will interfere and delay an agreement 5) A new government will be elected before an agreement can be reached. 6) If a developer has to build low-income housing, and obtain the certificate of occupancy on these low-income units prior to receiving the certificate of occupancy on the market units, he fears that he will have to pay large bribes to obtain the certificate of occupancy on the low-income units. Thus, he would prefer to donate the cash equivalent to the state and have the government build the units. II. THE OCCUPANTS: According to the latest report done by the government, in cooperation with the organization of the favelas in the area of Parais6polis, the following population figures show a growth in the area: 4 Table 3 Population Growth in Area of 4 Parais6polis Source Dwellings People 1980 Census 1,634 7,071 1983 Pro-Luz 2,100 (with electricity) N.A. 1983 Sabe Report 3,500-4,000 15,000 1988 Census 5,000a 25,000a SOURCE: 1980 and 1983 data from Secretaria Municipal da Famflia e Bem Estar Social - Butanti. " Favela Parais6polis: 1988 data from SEHAB Census. aEstimates. Relatorio Preliminar". August 1984.; 44Unless otherwise indicated, information in this section is from Secretaria Municipal da Familia e Bem Estar Social - Butantd, 1984. 51 According to the figures of the 1988 Census of Favelas, only .94% of the favelas in the city of Slo Paulo have more than 1,000 dwellings thus Parais6polis is one of the largest in the city. 4 5 In Parais6polis, the average family size was estimated to be 4.4 persons per household. 53% of the population was younger than 19 years old, and the majority of the remaining population was in their forties. 44% of the population has an origin in the Northeast of the country and 38% were born in Slo Paulo. According to the report in 1983, 96% of the dwellings were used for residential purposes, with 80% built of wood and 16% of blocks. Although 82% of the dwellings were privately owned and 10% were rented, only 2.2% of the people had ownership of the land, in 1983. 10% of the population owned land out of the area, accordingly, when asked, 90% of the population did not have any other option for housing than their dwellings in Parais6polis. 33% of the families have been residents in the area for 1-5 years and 31% of the families have been there for 5-10 years. Thus it could be assumed that these people were not new comers to the area or migrant labors. Today, in 1988, utilizing the same percentages 33% of the families would have been occupying the land for 5-10 years, and 31% of the population for 10-15 years. 4 5 Municipio 1987. de Sio Paulo. SEHAB. Censo das Favelas do Municipio de Sao Paulo April 1988, p. 19. 52 These figures may be misrepresentation as to the time of occupation of the land. In fact, they only signify the length of stay of the individuals living there not the length of occupancy and use of the land. If an agreement is not reached within five years the possibility of invoking the law of Usocapiao is very real, because the report could be utilized as proof that the land has been occupied for 20 years. both within the neighborhood and in The area is relatively rich in resources the surrounding areas. There is open space; the favelas cover only approximately 30% of the total area; there are two large football fields and open areas through out the favela. pharmacy, There are bars, fresh food stores, a construction material stores and a new health post, although many The area is well serviced of the residents use the hospitals that are close by. by bus lines both outside the favela and inside during the week. public telephones within the favela. There child care services and community support. are several There are churches, which offer The children of the favela have access to both the public and private schools in the neighborhood; the private schools taking the children on for free. Table 4 Family Income Distribution: Gr. S.o Paulo(a) Paraisopolis (b) Parals6polls and Greater Sao Paulo (1983) ---------------------- (In <1 min. salary 1-2 m.s. No income 25.0 11.7 1.4 34.0 9.9 7.4 Percent) 2-5 m.s. 37.0 43.0 ---------------------------> 5 m.s. Unreported 0.9 24.0 2.2 3.5 Source: (a) EMPLASA, Sumdrio de Dados da Grande Sao Paulo 1985 (b)Sabe Report 53 According to the 1983 survey, by comparing the general population family salaries, the favela appears to consist of low to middle income wage earners, 77% of the favelas' families earn between 1 and 5 minimum salaries as compared to 66% of the general population. The difference in income between the general population and that of the favela appears at the extremes. There is a higher percent of unemployed within the favela, 7.4% as compared to 1.4% in general population. And only 3.5% of the favelas have family incomes greater than 5 minimum salaries as compared to 24% in the general population. Sixty percent of the people worked in the neighborhood of Morumbi or adjacent neighborhoods (all of which are mostly rich residential areas); 20% of the population worked directly over the bridge inside the city or south of Morumbi (Jardim, Santo Amaro, Pinherios and Lapa). direct public transportation from the favela. All of these areas have This distribution of work location coincides with the types of jobs that these people hold: 28% of the working force was in domestic services ( women, as maids, cooks, baby sitters; and men as gardeners), 20% of the population worked in civil construction, 16% worked in industry and 18% worked in other occupations (building guard, porter etc.) Although the salaries are low to moderate, the occupants appear to be well integrated into the surrounding economy. Occupants' Alternatives to Resolve the Conflict The BATNA of the favelados reveals the dependence within the group of favelados and upon the other stakeholders. An individual favelado's 54 alternatives can be to receive money to relocate on his own, to react to a court order and risk losing the property, or to wait until the government removes him. 4 6 Staying indefinitely is no longer an option in light of the fact that a conflict exists. On the other hand, the alternatives for the groug of favelados are much stronger. Together, the favelados can: a) trade their collective votes for a delay in the process of removal or receive just compensation for their removal; b) lobby for the government to expropriate the land and sell it to them; or c) go to court to try to secure title to the land. The favelados in Parais6polis have already recognized their strength and have formed an organization called Unido de Moradores da Favela Parais6polis (Union of the Residents of the Parais6polis Favela). By harnessing their communal power, they have been able to achieve installation of telephones, health posts and streets since the establishment of the organization in 1983. In addition, the community has established a school, community center and a day care center. Above all, they have been able to stay in the same location and maintain their social and economic ties. This appears to be the main reason for the formation and interest by the community in the Unido de Moradores da Favela Paraisdpolis. In a survey in 1983, 70% of the population listed the three most important reasons for participating in the organization: 1) not to leave the community, 2) to see where they were going, 3) not to have the favela removed. As of now, however, the favelados have not requested title to the land from the 4 6 Some favelados would have to join together in order to go to court if each one individually did not occupy the legal boundaries of the parcel. 55 government or the land owners, but they have been able to stop further development in the area. For example, the group was able to arrange the free services of a lawyer from one of their elected officials in order to stop the eviction of one plot. 4 7 Given the valuation of the land and the increased probability of efforts to expel them, the favelados need the government/politicians, the judiciary, or the land owners to facilitate their ability to stay in the same location; this the favelados cannot do on their own. Therefore, the BATNA for the favelados is to lobby for permanent services, and hold out to be able to use the Usocapido law to obtain title to the land. If development projects occur, the favelados must go to court and try to stop the project and impending eviction. FAVELADOS' INTERESTS: General Interests: 1) To secure title 2) To maintain community 3) To maintain access to present jobs 4) To maintain affordability 5) To increase jobs in the area Favelados A) Those B) Those C) Those D) Those E) Those Subgroups and Interests: who want to remain in the favela in current situation who want to remain in the same locale, but with improvements who want to build a house on their own outside the favela who want cash to return to another state who want cash to move to another favela Favelados Fears: 1) Developer will not live up to an agreement 4 7 Mendonga interview. 56 2) Government will clear favela and relocate without choice 3) Government will change before agreement is settled III, THE GOVERNMENT The Administration, The Zoning Commission, The Elected Representatives, The Government Housing Company, The Administrative Agencies. Brazil is experiencing a democratization phase that is influencing all of its sectors. The role of popularly-elected officials and the development of political parties have had a strategic effect on the policies and their implementation. a) The Administration has the responsibility of proposing new laws and executing all laws passed by the legislative branch. b) The Zoning Commission proposed projects. has the responsibility of reviewing all It has the right to grant variances as it sees fit. The Commission is appointed, yet it has representatives from both the government and the private sector. Under the new Lei de Desfavelamento, the Commission has the power to negotiate the number of houses for which a developer must pay and the transfer of development rights (TDRs) that will be granted in exchange for the provision of housing. In practice, the Commission does not negotiate, but rather approves or rejects the preprocessed agreements that have been negotiated between a team from the administration and the developer. c) The Elected Representatives have the power to create laws. These representatives also have access to influential people within the administration for the purpose of aiding the favelado or the developer. 57 d) The Government years. Housing Company has been building housing for It formerly received its funds from the now-defunct National Housing Bank to build low-income housing projects on a massive scale. This organ receives funding made available from the Lei de Desfavelamento to continue building large-scale public housing. e) The Administrative Agencies consist of both the planning and implementing agencies. The planning agency, SEMPLA, under the new Lei de Desfavelamento, has the responsibility of negotiating with the developer and processing the agreements that are presented to the planning board, the implementing agencies and those within other secretaries of the administration. The Government's Alternatives to Resolving the Conflict The government is in a very delicate position, as can be seen in its BATNA. Angel states very elegantly the dilemma: Government usually finds itself in the position of arbiter between the conflicting claims of landlords on the one hand, and slum dweller on the other. The general claim of landlord, whether private or public, is that the government must protect their legal rights to the land and assist them in clearing the slums so that they can exercise their right to use the land as they see fit. The position of the slum dwellers is that they have established a claim to the land through prolonged stay, that they have no place to go without losing their means of survival, that the law is unjust if so many people have to suffer so that so few may benefit, and that the government has a social responsibility to house them properly. 4 8 The government's alternatives are: a) to remove the favelas and give them alternative housing or not; b) to let the favelas exist and hope that the parties 4 8 Angel and Boonyabancha. 58 battle out the situation in court; or c) to leave the problem to the next administration. The government's interest to resolve this problem on private property is low because the land and valuation in the land will be returned to individuals and not the State. Therefore, unless the controlling political party can provide secure tenure and keep the votes in the area intact, it will not be interested in any project. Therefore, the government's BATNA is to try to release the area from the zoning freeze, wait for the favelados and owners to sort out their problems, meanwhile only intervening to gain short-term votes. GOVERNMENT INTERESTS General Interests: 1) To maintain urban form 2) To maintain equity and not set a precedent 3) Not to be seen as favoring only the developer or favelados 4) To gain or maintain votes of favelados, and to keep the organized votes intact 5) 6) 7) 8) To Not To To clear the unsightliness of the favela to lay out any cash create some green area remove the freeze from the zoning Government Subgroups and Interests: A) Officials who are corrupt and want to be paid off B) Officials who are ideologically driven, and want the favela either to stay or be removed C) Opposition parties that want to do nothing D) Officials who seek concessions to benefit both sides: to maintain pressure from favelados and developers to keep the law working E) Those who have a preoccupation only with the urban form, and want no concessions on zoning F) Those who want to give temporary and physical goods to the favelados to gain short-term votes, although they do not want to give tenure Government Fears: 1) Developer will try to make an unfair profit off the government 2) Corruption will be all-consuming 3) Favelados do not have the capacity or resources to negotiate 59 4) Political parties and the church will work to hinder negotiations 5) All stakeholders cannot come to an agreement to be realized during the negotiating administration; energy will be wasted IV, THE POLITICAL PARTIES Various political parties are working within the favelas throughout the city. The parties try to produce results for the favelas in order to gain votes. If a party is in power, it tries to provide services; the party not in power promises to deliver services. The level of political party intervention varies depending on the organization of the particular favela. In some cases, the political parties are very active and in others they are not. In the case of the favela of Parais6polis, some political parties are present, but their influence is small relative to their influence in other favelas. V. THE CHURCH The Church also works to deliver services. It is, at times, connected with political parties. within each favela. The Church influence, like that of political parties, varies In the case of the favela of Parais6polis, the Church is present, but it is not accepted as a representative for the favelados. The impasse that exists today causes no further development in the area of Parais6polis. The land owners have no incentive to invest for fear that they will encounter a court battle. The favelados will not invest to their total capacity because they have no guarantee of their presence. The city continues to no be able to fully address the needs of either the favelados or the land owners and continues to have both unpaid taxes and foregone added taxes on land which could be developed. The government is also seen by the 60 surrounding higher income constituency as a failure because it has not been able to provide green open space for the city and it has been unable to remove the "eyesore", the unsightly physical mess of the favela. Through a Secure Tenure Production scheme all the parties can come out winners. The ability for all to gain secure tenure will create development in the area, will increase tax rolls, could possibly create green open space and relieve the anxiety of removal for the favelados resulting in an incentive for increased investment on the part of the favelado. 61 CHAPTER THREE: Elements of Secure Tenure Production--Considerations, Measures of Good Outcomes and the Role of an Intermediary In applying Secure Tenure Production to resolve the problem in Parais6polis, STEP is not necessarily several considerations need to be evaluated. applicable under all circumstances. 4 9 Examples of land sharing in Thailand and Pakistan give a starting point for understanding and expanding the considerations that need to be assessed in applying STEP. Having taken stock of the considerations, the question of a "good outcome" will be addressed. Finally, the complex nature of insecure tenure and the means to resolve it makes the role of an intermediary critical to achieve a good consensus. Accordingly, the final section will define an intermediary and his role. Considerations The following four categories outline STEP considerations developed from land sharing examples in Thailand and Pakistan. different categories: 5 0 Physical/Technical; They appear to fall into four Economic; Functional; and Political. 49"Land sharing is, however, not a panacea for halting slum evictions. It is a tool which can be applied under specific conditions in a limited number of cases." Angel and Sheng, p. 7. 5 0 The following "Considerations" are an expansion of land sharing criteria cited in Angel and Somsook Boonyabancha. "Land Sharing as an Alternative to Eviction: The Bangkok Experience," unpublished paper, May 1987 and in 62 Physical Considerations: o The disputed parcel must have a low enough density to be able to carry an increase in density. parcel is to be shared. An increase in density is needed, particularly if the In the case of Parais6polis, the area is developed with mostly one-story, single-family dwellings. If these same houses were to be two-story dwellings, the same number of families could remain on the same property and half of the land would be vacant for further development. If the property in dispute cannot carry the increase in density, additional parcels of land will be needed in order to share the land. In the case of Parais6polis, some properties that are now very dense could be incorporated with other parcels that are under-utilized or vacant, in order to reach a consensus. o The neighborhood in which the site (or sites) is located must have the capacity to carry increases in density as a result of any specific project. Aside from the physical capacity requirements of the initial site, the larger neighborhood's infrastructure must also be able to respond to future increases in density due to low-income and market development. In Parais6polis, the surrounding area i. capable of handling such increases for the first few Angel and Sheng. The criteria are: 1) LAND CRITERIA, a) development pressure, b) legitimacy of land occupation, c) stage in the eviction process, d) landlord cooperation; 2) SOCIAL CRITERIA, a) community organization, b) outside support, 3) PHYSICAL CRITERIA, a) existing density, b) existing housing values, 4) FINANCIAL CRITERIA, a) affordability, b) cross-subsidies, c) external sources of housing finance. 63 projects; but the roads and sewage system would have to be expanded if the entire neighborhood is to be developed at once. Even though the first project approved in the area may have high amounts of risk due to its innovative nature and untested market, the physical costs/investments for developing increased density in the area will be less for the developer of this initial project. o The site (or a site nearby) must have sufficient room to house the occupants temporarily while reconstruction and increase in density takes place, during the implementation phase. If the development of the site requires that the market portion of the site be vacant, housing must be built or supplied for the occupants prior to developing the market units. This would require that the developer make a large up-front investment before being able to start his development, which increases the risk of the deal. If the site is large enough, both the low-income and the market-rate housing can be developed simultaneously--a means to reduce the time factor, uncertainty, and, thus, the risk. Another option to reduce risk is to incorporate a third site into the deal. The third site can be utilized as temporary shelter for the occupants while both the low-income and market units are being built on the original site. In Parais6polis, all three of these options, physically speaking, have potential. Parais6polis has vacant land to house people during the construction phase. It also presents the potential of combining adjacent properties in order to 64 develop both the low-income and market units simultaneously. (see MAP #5) All three options must be analyzed with a financial model to understand which option is the least costly and gives the highest return, according to the different risks associated with each option. o In order to evaluate and develop these various options, some form of technical assistance must be available during the negotiation process. Economic Considerations: o The location of the site must be one with a return on the commercialized portion sufficient to pay for the cross-subsidization of' the rehousing and infrastructure for the existing occupants. Otherwise, the risk inherent in the project must be reduced to warrant a smaller required profit for the developer. A market that can support the outputs being produced on this parcel (marketrate housing) at the price necessary to cross-subsidize the project must exist as well. In any STEP consensus, the cross-subsidy for the entire project comes from three sources: a) passing on the cost of the low-income development to the market-unit buyers; b) the developer receiving a lower profit, which would be the residual of the low-income project costs that cannot be passed on to the buyer. 5 1 ; and c) any additional concessions from the favelados or the government, e.g., guarantees of loans, smaller units. 51This lower return would be justified if the negotiated project were to have This assertion follows less risk than a non-negotiated hypothetical project. 65 In Parais6polis, there are several indications that development pressure exists. The table below shows that there has been much development, particularly of high-rise apartment buildings in the adjacent area. For example, in tract 227 which contains a large portion of Parais6polis, there was a percentage change of 716% in the number of units in high rise apartment buildings during the period of 1980 to 1984. In a tract adjacent to Parais6polis, tract 228, there was a percentage increase of high rise apartment buildings of 82,300%. from finance theory which states: the greater the risk the higher the return, the lower the risk the lower the return. For further background see Richard Brealey and Stewart Myers. Principles of Corporate Finance. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1984). 66 Table 5: CHANGE IN LAND USES (1980 ---------- 1984) FOR PARAISOPOLIS AND ENVIRONS Percentage change 1980-1984 Bldg Land Units ---------1984 --------Bldg area f units Land area (m2) (m2) 1980 ---------- Sector Use 198 198. 198 Horiz. Apt. Vacant 196 20 513 57,947 1,990 399,675 24,886 5,574 0 248 20 465 67,640 1,990 375,934 32,941 5,574 0 26.5% 0.0% -9.4% 16.7% 0.0% -5.9% 32.4% 0.0% 226 226 226 Horiz. Apt. Vacant 75 20 269 41,307 2,008 21,835 574 0 110 20 228 61,212 2,008 118,246 33,083 574 0 46.7% 0.0% 48.2% 0.0% 14.1% 51.5% 227 Horiz. Apt. Vacant 42 25 742 13.0% 204 131.5% 367.6% 0 738 32,362 9,962 465,494 12,124 2,459 475,909 5,237 6,773 56 227 227 228 228 228 Horiz. Apt. Vacant 65 1 458 27,182 4,770 702,650 7,493 12,942 120 824 41,209 23,146 0 424 243 Horiz. Apt. Vacant 15 7,500 1,040 351 191,250 41 1,063 243 243 144 144 144 Horiz. Apt. Vacant # units Land area (m2) 137,694 Bldg area (m2) -15.2% - 31,672 0 33.3% 716.0% -0.5% 3 05.1% 663,350 28,053 77,184 0 84.6% 82300.0% -7.4% 15 7,500 1,040 0 336 181,500 0 37,356 16,630 61 53,044 708,111 0 977 60,265 28,649 0.0% -2.2% NA 51.6% 274.4% 496.4% 0.0% -5.1% 24,281 48.8% 42.0% 0 -8.1% -91.5% Decreases in vacant land are also attributable to commercial or industrial development NA 385.2% -5.6% -4.3% Source: Cade.stroFiscalde/mobiiario,EMPLASA, 1985. Note: Data are not available for the following tracts-200, 157, 129. 0.0% NA 0.0% P-46.0% NA K ,V I (2) Z00 ""'a (qr 2ZY 4 (q) 22a I I1 (3) 45:F CEMi rER4Am MO'9.M d MAP 0 6 Land Use Tracts 0.0Border of Favela 1 60 227 Area =AvenueGiovaniGrenchi Land Scale U1O OW Use Tract Fear that the area of Morumbi is already over-built is not based on fact. neighborhood city. is one of the last remaining large un-urbanized areas The in the The development of a new tunnel connecting the center of the city to Morumbi presents further development potential for the area. Is there a market for a final sale price for the units that would subsidize the deal? The answer is a function not only of the buyers' capacity but also of the available financing. The financial calculations and estimates in the financial chapter and appendix will show that a market does exist. o At the same time, as Angel has stated, the land cannot be excessively valuable. If it is, the owners will have enough profit to compensate all the parties involved to clear the land. 5 2 From interviews and observations on land prices within the city of Slo Paulo, the land in Parais6polis does not appear to represent the higher priced land in the city. Almost all of the new apartment buildings in the area are selling at prices below the highest prices in the city. 5 3 o The government must be willing to work with the private sector and offer some incentives to all parties involved, e.g., rapid approval of the proposal, change in zoning, or guaranteed financing. In addition, both the land owners and the occupants feel that the government has in some way created the conflict over the parcel of land and, therefore, has a responsibility to help resolve it. 5 2 Angel. In the case of Parais6polis, this bilateral perception of Telephone interview. June 1988. Marcos Mendes. Interviews July and August 1988. 5 3 Gonealves, 69 governmental responsibility is very strong. government's past expropriations more invasions. The land owners feel that the of the land have indirectly encouraged From the point of view of the occupants, the government has the responsibility of providing housing or access to housing for those who have no means to provide it for themselves. The use of government subsidies could be a means to make the deal more profitable for all the stakeholders. o Each group must receive some financial support during the negotiation process, especially the favelados who are without savings, to participate in the project. The support may come from the government, non-governmental organizations, political parties, the developer/land owners or through barter --by exchanging an apartment for the services of development or negotiation professionals. 5 4 o Construction and permanent financing for the project must be obtained. Functional Considerations: o The occupants of the parcel of land must have an organization and a representative. The occupants need both in order to exercise their leverage, to define their interests, to develop alternatives and to participate effectively 54 Rod Hackney. Workshop on Community Architecture, MIT Spring 1988. Hackney has successfully developed low-income housing in England using barter as a method of payment. 70 in the negotiation process. The strongest leverage that the individual occupants have is the power of their numbers, which can be realized only with an organization that stands against receiving anything less than its BATNA. Additionally, it is only within a group that interests can be defined, while maintaining the leverage. The occupants hold information that is crucial in evaluating any project, e.g., what is affordable in terms of housing costs. Effective negotiations require representatives who can convey the needs and fears of the group that they represent; each individual cannot come to the table to negotiate his own agreement. In terms of negotiation, a representative is one who can transmit and aggregate the interests of his stakeholders. In the case of Parais6polis, the Unido de Moradores da Favela Paraisd'polis can be utilized to define the interests of the specific individuals on any parcel within the larger area of Parais6polis. The organization has already formed a network through which information can flow during the negotiation. o The land owners must have a representative organization, parcel is involved. be identified. if more than one In all cases the land owner or disputing land owners must In cases in which court disputes exist between two supposed land owners, while the property is occupied, clear title or resolution of the court battle is not necessary for negotiations to start. As long as both of the disputing parties are also part of the negotiation, the question of ownership may be able to be resolved out of court. 71 o In addition, the occupants and land owners of a specific parcel should have an opportunity to participate in any negotiation with representation therein, if they so wish. The specific occupants and the land owner of the particular parcel in dispute must have direct representation as well. In this way, the larger interests of the neighborhood will not override the specific needs of the individuals whose tenure is in question. Thus, in the case of Parais6polis, the residents on the specific parcels to be considered for STEP should be able to have direct representation, utilizing the larger organizations for support. o There must be some traditional or legal precedent that affirms the occupants' right to remain in the same location. In the case of Sao Paulo, the law of Usocapido serves this purpose, as well as the political atmosphere that dictates no eviction policies. The intensity of this factor will range from site to site, in some cases it will be a stronger advantage for the favelados and in other cases it will give more leverage to the owner. In the case of Parais6polis, the long length of occupancy relative to other favelas in the city seem to give the favelados more legitimacy in the eyes of the public, the politicians, the government and even the land owners. 5 5 5 5 There are no aggregate figures on the age of favelas, although most interviewees assert that it was in fact one of the oldest in the city of Sao Paulo. Many interviewees felt that in comparison to other favelas, this one had much more power due to the size and age. 72 Political Considerations: o The government must lack funds to build replacement houses for the occupants. STEP is an alternative when the government does not have the funds to pay for complete relocation of the occupants. Thus, when a government does not have the funds to relocate, yet would like to see removal of the physical sight of a favela and promote further market development, it will search for ways to subsidize a solution that does not require cash. In Parais6polis, the government does not have the cash to expropriate the area; the government does not have the cash to remove and relocate the favelados. Thus, contributions of change in zoning, guarantee of loans and a rapid approval process are non-cash methods that can subsidize a solution. o The type of State or federal administration, within which STEP is taking place, must be defined. In some societies, a pull exists between the incumbent political party and alternative political parties--a pull that may work to forward STEP. In any event, the goal may not be to isolate the process of STEP from political influence, but to recognize the potential for political exploitation of the situation in order to promote STEP. o The government must be willing to cooperate with both the private sector and the occupants to find a solution. o The potential for a STEP deal, as opposed to removal, also hinges on the actual location, size of the parcel, length of stay of the occupants, and doubt over the 73 legal title of the land. The potential for STEP must be analyzed with regard to the stance of the government. It is often the case that a government will not be absolutely opposed to a STEP deal, but it may nevertheless thwart its progress. When a government is not necessarily in favor of STEP, as is the case Sao Paulo, a remote location of the proposed STEP scheme (Parais6polis is not on a major highway and not seen from the roadside) may have a higher potential for a STEP solution than a more visible location. Criteria for a "Good Outcome" Having reviewed the considerations for a STEP process and consensus, the criteria for a good outcome will be outlined. In cases of disputed land tenure, the process and the agreement reached should be fair, efficient, wise, and stable. It must also satisfy both the stakeholders' interests and fears. These are tests of a good negotiated settlement, according to negotiation theorists and will be consider the criteria for STEP.5 6 Fairness Procedural as well as substantive aspects of fairness need to be addressed. 5 6 Susskind and Cruikshank. 74 The process: What counts most in evaluating the fairness of a negotiated outcome are the perceptions of the participants. The key question is 'Were the people who managed the process responsive to the concerns of those affected by the final decision?' 5 7 If the person managing the process cannot address all the needs of the stakeholders, they, in turn, will perceive it as an unresponsive process. Through the Lei de Desfavelamento, the favelados in Parais6polis do not have any official channel for participation in the process, and, thus, perceive any outcome as unfair. The government is not only trying to manage the process but also represent the favelados at the bargaining table, which often places it in an ambiguous role. In addition, the Slo Paulo municipal planning board, which has final approval over the outcome, tends to focus on a formula to replace process to assure that "fairness" is evident. The planning board wants to prove to the underrepresented parties that, in fact, they were dealt with fairly in the process. Another way to achieve fairness is to produce a set of rules that are applicable in all cases. This can set a dangerous precedent-- some conflicting interests cannot be resolved through the application of rules. If such rules do go into effect, one party will always feel that it is being treated unfairly in the process and may not even want to "play". 5 7 Susskind When rules are considered unfair and Cruikshank, p. 21. 75 the focus turns on disputing the fairness of the process which created the It is more important, as Susskind and Cruikshank state, rules. In a problem-solving context, perceived fairness depends more on the willingness of the parties to accommodate each other's special needs than on the rules not changing. 5 8 Thus, it is more important that parties perceive that they are being treated fairly in a process that can be adapted to the needs of the groups involved, than to have a system of inflexible rules that supposedly convey the concept of fairness. In order to achieve perceived fairness, it is suggested: If each stakeholding group [is] given some responsibility for making a solution work (as well as part of the credit for devising a set of good ideas), they probably all would have viewed the process as fair. 5 9 This should be the goal in order to achieve fairness--it can be accomplished only through the direct interaction of all parties involved. The substance: Focusing on the substance (content) of a negotiated agreement is a second dimension by which to evaluate fairness. Susskind's conclusion from field work: . . . avoid ironclad determinations of 'fairness'. . . in a public dispute, a good process produces a good outcome; and a better process, a better 5 8 ihid., p. 22. and Cruikshank, p. 23. 5 9 Susskind 76 outcome. A process is fair if it is perceived as fair by the disputants and the community at large. 6 0 Thus, perception is a critical factor in evaluating fairness, for if the process and the substance are perceived as fair, involved parties will be more willing to work to implement the agreement. Efficiency Efficiency is defined by Susskind and Cruikshank in relative terms: If it takes much longer to produce an outcome that is only slightly fairer than what might have been achieved in the absence of consensus, then the process is inefficient, and probably not worth the trouble. Our contention is that a better process produces a more efficient as well as a fairer outcome. A better process is one that first creates a climate in which side-by-side problem solving is possible. Such a climate is a prerequisite if the participants are ever to trust each other enough to divulge their true priorities. And unless they reveal their underlying interest it is almost impossible to invent the most efficient agreement. 6 1 Under the Lei de Desfavelamento, a side-by-side problem-solving does not exist. relationship In the case of Parais6polis, the government has become a broker between two fighting factions: the land owners and the favelados. Thus, neither the favelados nor the land owners want to reveal their true interests because each believes it is fighting the other for all or nothing, which precludes finding a solution to insecure land tenure. This creates inefficiencies because the government is placed in the position of proposing solutions that are not necessarily going to satisfy the interests of all the stakeholders. 6 0 ibid., p. 24. 61ihid., p. 26. 77 Another source of inefficiencies in negotiation is unclear definition of stakeholders' interests. In the case of a parcel of land with many land owners, the owners may refuse to reveal their true interests and, thus, be unable to work together to achieve the highest value in a STEP deal. Therefore, instead of concentrating on the negotiation, a more efficient solution would be to concentrate on the organization of land owners so they could participate in a more efficient manner and act as a united front. At the same time, many land owners appear to be threatened by the high level of organization among the favelados, when, in fact, in the negotiation process, a strong and legitimate organization allows negotiations to proceed more efficiently for all involved. When disputes arise negotiations can take place or unilateral action can occur. The unilateral move, prompted often by a political concern, appears efficient because a solution is arrived at quickly. Susskind argues that such an approach is only a short-term gain and may be costly later. He has observed that in the United States, The public official who acts unilaterally in a public dispute 'trades several months of negotiation for roughly twice as many months or years in court. In the public disputes, it is often necessary to "go slow to go fast." 6 2 In the case of land disputes in Brazil, this same rule is often applicable. Unilateral deals are often made with the favelados in order to gain votes by a particular party in power, or in order to deny votes to a particular party in power. In the case of Parais6polis, one of the opposition parties will provide 6 2 Susskind and Cruikshank, p. 27. 78 lawyers to defend any favelado in court if expulsion is pending. But the intervening party will not help the favelados find a solution to gain tenure to the land in the absence of a conflict. battles with the land owners. Unfortunately, this only prolongs court More often, the government will reach a quick agreement with a land owner, counting on easy removal of the favelados. Yet as in the case above, an opposing party may be willing to defend the side of the favelados, or the favelados may be willing to use the power of the media and their numbers to protest any removal effort. Thus, unilateral decisions often do appear to be easy and efficient, yet the consequences may lead to long-term delays. On the other hand, Susskind and Cruikshank highlight the trade-off between efficiency and fairness, "It may well be possible for an informed observer to invent quickly a set of policies identical to those developed by a group of Such a brilliant individual negotiators working over a long period of time. effort would undoubtedly be more" 6 3 efficient than a group process. This trade-off is being played out under the new Lei de Desfavelamento and other ad hoc pay-off agreements with the favelados. The government is acting as a proxy for the favelados in negotiating with the developer. the favelados only after a decision has been made. As such, it informs The government team feels that it is the capable technical group and can formulate an accord more rapidly than one negotiated with all parties. Yet this lack of participation by the favelados induces them to try to undermine the land owner/government 79 negotiated agreement. It is not that the favelados do not like the agreement but they feel they should have a voice in determining their future dwellings. 6 4 The favelados, though, are not part of the negotiation process. As Susskind and Cruikshank state: "Our experience suggests, however, that perceived fairness depends on participation. Those who participate feel that they 'own' the agreement, and are therefore more likely to support its implementation." 65 Wisdom 6 "The key to wisdom is what has been called 'prospective hindsight'." 6 Sometimes relevant experiences can be used to identify the potential problems and solutions; but all solutions contain some element of novelty and risk. Many novelties are incorporated in a STEP consensus. The introduction of changes in zoning alter the value of land, as well as the potential profit of the At the same time, a change in the final product or an increase in project. square footage also increases or alters risks. These risks and value changes are difficult to estimate for there is no real active market in real estate and each parcel is unique. This [novelty and uncertainty] often leads to the dismal process of 'advocacy science,' in which disputing parties use hired experts to undercut each other's claims. As a result, useful information is Instead of being examined and resolved, legitimate scientific obscured. 6 and technical differences are exaggerated. 7 6 4 Santos 65 and Mendonea interviews. ii. 66 ihid., p. 28. 67ihid., p. 29. 80 In the case of Parais6polis, the government, the developer, and several experts have tried to define these values, each claiming that their numbers are correct. Focusing on a set formula to define these numbers, with no regard to the viability of the total project, leads each side to develop a number or value that is more advantageous to that side's position. For every desired number (e.g., maximum number of houses for the government; minimum number of houses for the developer) one can construct and defend a formula to produce that number. Instead of defining a formula, "The answer lies in cooperation: both sides must participate in an effort to minimize the the risk of being wrong. They must develop a working approach that accommodates the best possible technical 6 evidence--no matter which 'side' that evidence supports." 8 This thesis will develop a model that can serve to help identify tradable components to reduce the risk for all involved in land tenure dispute in order to create a successful project. The model will not give one answer, but it will help stakeholders define and understand their costs and benefits. Stability The final element necessary for a good negotiated agreement is stability. Negotiation theorists cite several sources of instability. unrealistic expectations--feasibility 6 8 Susskind The first source is of a project is the key. If stakeholders and Cruikshank, p. 30. 81 have unrealistic expectations and act on them, the consensus will only fall apart during implementation causing all the stakeholders to lose. In cross- subsidized projects, unrealistic market sales prices will only cause the developer to default on the project, forfeiting the source of funding for the Second, "feasibility rests on realistic timetables". low-income units. A STEP consensus is very sensitive to time which directly effects the costs and benefits of the project: the market may move away from the owner causing a down turn in sale prices, the low-income housing units might take longer to build than expected, the favelados might take longer to be transfer to their new dwellings, and the government might take longer to approve certificate of occupancies. projections. Thus, realistic time table must be factored into any Moreover, everything should be done before hand to minimize the negative effects of delays. The third element related to stability is the Each party should only commitments that each party makes to the other. commit itself and request of others that which it can honestly deliver, if not stability will be sacrificed at the point of delivery. It will help none of the stakeholders to force one party to agree to something under pressure which they can not fulfill. In a STEP consensus there is a high degree of interdependency, such that if one party fails all of the others will also loose. One way to enhance stability, suggested by negotiation theorists, is to leave room in the contract to renegotiate the agreement, especially under changing circumstances. One option is to outline the circumstances under which the contract is renegotiable. Another is to identify under what circumstances specific parts of the contract are renegotiable. This may be particularly 82 important in developing STEP because larger projects last over long time periods, as such are more susceptible to outside influences. In the case of Brazil, the inflation factor can make previously agreed to quantities or quality of units for either party (developer or city) difficult to achieve. At the same time, the sale price agreed to by the favelados may not be feasible one year later, when the new units are completed. Timetables for construction may also be altered due to changing prices or market conditions for resale of the market units. Finally, Susskind and Cruikshank state that stability within agreements depends on relationships. If all parties still feel that they have something worthwhile within the contract and are able to renegotiate, they can overcome an impasse easily. In traditional methods of win/lose agreements, As a result, confrontational encounters...create hostility and ill will. the slightest flaw in an agreement imposed by such methods will be seized upon by a disgruntled disputant and used to scuttle the entire New information and unexpected turns of events pose agreement. Any wedge that a loser can grave threats to nonconsensusual solutions. 6 9 agreement. the topple to used be find will Unlike traditional agreements, win/win agreements have built-in incentives for each party to try and over come any problems. 69 Susskind and Cruikshank, p. 32. 83 Intermediary 7 0 The integration of the function of an intermediary who can bring the stakeholder together can facilitate arriving at a STEP consensus. Tenure conflicts are representative of what Susskind and Cruikshank describe as public, distributional disputes that require assisted negotiation: Most public dispute are highly complex, for example, and the affected Disputing parties groups are hard to identify and difficult to represent. often have great difficulty initiating and pursuing discussions. Emotional, psychological, or financial stakes may be so high that the disputants are unable to sustain the collaborative aspects of unassisted Finally, power imbalances may preclude direct and negotiation. unassisted dealing among disputants. 7 1 In the case of Parais6polis, it is questionable as to who the correct representatives are for land owners, favelados and the government. Even on a particular plot, the actual number of separate families may be unclear; and as soon as tenure is awarded, more families will appear. disputes, false proposals, misunderstanding, Because of past and unclear outcomes of alternative actions, it is hard to begin negotiations, let alone sustain them. There are strong emotional, psychological and financial stakes. very valuable to both the land owners and the favelados. The land is The developer feels that his land has been invaded and that the government has never lived up to its bargain of expropriation when the zoning was frozen. At the same time, the favelados are very poor and they are in the position of losing not only 7 0 The ideas in this section are derived from Susskind and Cruikshank. 71ihid.., p. 136. 84 their homes but the support of their community and access to their jobs. Finally, an imbalance of power exists between the land owners and the favelados. The land owner often has money and knowledge of the legal and financial system, yet he lacks the "power in numbers" to exercise political influence in an election process. power of information On the other hand, the favelados lack the and financial resources. to be perceived as aiding one side or the other. conditions, an intermediary The government does not want Under these complex is necessary. An intermediary may be called on by one of the stakeholders, may be indicated by an outsider, or be a disinterested observer who may offer his assistance. The role of an intermediary can be filled by one individual or a team. major concerns of the stakeholders regarding intermediary are control, negotiation theorists. Three the introduction of an neutrality and competence, as outlined by In an ideal world, an intermediary should be one who has no control over the final outcome, has interest only in finding a solution agreeable to all, and is competent enough to produce the best possible solution. The role of and concerns regarding an intermediary have possibly hindered the appearance of an intermediary in Parais6polis in the past. If the developer or the favelados were to propose an intermediary, the other side would believe that the intermediary has the interest of only the proposing party at heart. The government i& in a position to inject an intermediary into the dispute, but within the government there a the other. those who favor one side or In addition, government officials usually do not have the 85 negotiation or financial evaluation skills needed to evaluate the proposed options. Within the larger community, some individuals are seen as neutral with no direct control over the outcome of the case. number. These individuals exist in small Their integrity and personal relationships with the stakeholders present them as potential intermediaries. In the last year, an economics professor and former politician, who was known to each of the stakeholders, acted as an intermediary for one meeting between the favelados and the land owners. In general, in Brazil today, it appears that personal integrity and acquaintance with the stakeholder is also a concern in identifying an intermediary. 72 No matter who the intermediary is, as long as each stakeholder has the power to veto the decision, the intermediary could be acceptable to all. Extent of Involvement of an Intermediary In traditional negotiation theory, three levels of intermediaries facilitator; mediator; and non-binding arbitrator. are identified: These three types of intermediaries are separated by the level of involvement in the process of the negotiation. 7 2 Ceniviva interview. 86 Facilitation: "facilitation is the simplest form of assisted negotiation,...the facilitator restricts himself or herself to procedural questions". 7 3 Mediation: "Mediation intensifies the substantive involvement of the neutral without removing control over the outcome from the parties. It also involves the helper in a great deal more confidential interaction with the parties ...In essence, the mediator plays a transforming role--helping the parties out of a zero-sum mind-set into an integrative bargaining role". 7 4 Nonbinding arbitration: "a process whereby a private judge or panel listens to the arguments of all sides, and then suggests an appropriate solution that the parties can either accept or reject". 7 5 In STEP a mediator is necessary. In the case of Parais6polis, a mediator is needed not only to facilitate discussions but also to meet privately with each side to discover interests that are tradable-- interests that would be difficult to discuss in front of the other stakeholders. For example, a favelado would not say that some individuals in his group would be willing to relocate to another site outside of the neighborhood for fear that he would jeopardize the ability of the rest of his group to receive housing on the same site. A developer would not want to disclose to the government his real cost of construction of lowincome units, for fear that he will be seen as not spending enough on the 7 3 ibid., 7 4 ibid., p. 161. p. 162. 75ihid. p. 175. 87 project to receive a change in zoning. Thus, the need to have private meetings in order to develop potential proposals as well as transmit hypothetical proposals to stakeholders is critical in obtaining a consensus--it is just as important as face-to-face negotiations. Finally, the use of an intermediary helps all the parties appear "tough" in public. For example, one land owner may not want other land owners to know that he is willing to talk with the favelados. If an intermediary is present he may be able to conceal identities as well as information. Alternatives to an Independent Mediator Government as Mediator: with and without separate orientator for occupants. An alternative to an independent mediator is to utilize the government as a stakeholder anAd mediator. Even though the government does have a stake in the outcome, in some ways it can be seen as not having a predisposed bias towards one side or the other in the terms of the outcome of the negotiated agreement. Thus, it has an incentive to resolve the conflict, but may not have an interest in any particular outcome. In this option, the government would perform the chores of the mediator in the above scenario. If it did not have the expertise to develop a feasibility study, it could hire an independent technician. In terms of representation, the government could represent the favelados or the favelados could obtain their own orientator to help them define their interests. 88 First, it is entirely possible that the Such a process has several deficiencies. government would have a specific solution in mind. Second, the government, once it is seen as the mediator and driving force behind the agreement, will be more conservative so as not to set a precedent for future deals. When the government assumes the position of negotiator on behalf of the favelados, the government may very well, once again, make decisions for this group of occupants who, it often feels, has no ability to comprehend the issues at stake. Thus, the government will reduce the decision-making role and, therefore, the responsibility of the occupants--an implementation of any agreement. approach that might later hinder the Third, the government often maintains stances that are contradictory to the goals of not only the developer but also the favelados, e.g., the government would like to see more open space by moving the favelados to another site instead of development. Thus, if the government were the mediator, it would be worthwhile for the favelados to have an independent orientator to maintain their ability to participate on a more knowledgeable and active level with the other stakeholders. Occupant and Land Owner Negotiate A third option would be to have negotiations proceed with a mediator between the occupants and the land owner. These two groups could develop various options and choose the most feasible one. Then, the two groups could go to the 89 government to request the approval of their joint project, which would include the necessary participation of the government. This process would place enormous pressure on the government to approve the proposed project. Nevertheless, the late entry of the government into the process might alienate the government into not agreeing to participate in the manner necessary to make the agreement profitable. As will be seen in the last Chapter, the participation of the government is critical to make a STEP consensus feasible. The government should be treated as a stakeholder, i.e., it must be brought into the negotiation process from the start. Satisfying Interests and Fears Beyond the considerations for Secure Tenure Production and the criteria outlined above for a good outcome and the need for an intermediary, interests and fears of the stakeholders must also be satisfied. This can be done through a combination of the negotiation process and the substance of the final agreement. For example, the fear that a favelado's interests will not be heard can be satisfied through face-to-face participation in the negotiation process. But, merely participating in the process will not address his interest in receiving a plot of land or a new dwelling--only the substance of a final agreement can guarantee that interest. Thus, I will develop several negotiation processes for the case of Parais6polis and offer several possible outcomes. These processes and outcomes will be 90 evaluated by the four criteria of a good negotiation process and agreement as outlined by theoreticians--fairness, efficiency, wisdom, and stability--as well as how they address the interests and fears of the stakeholders. I will show that ont solution cannot respond to the specific characteristics of each negotiated case. Every solution has its benefits and costs and must be adjusted to meet the varied interests of the stakeholders. 91 CHAPTER FOUR: Negotiation Tasks--The Case Study of Parais6polis Hypothetical Conflict Under the new Lei de Desfavelamento, a land owner from within the area of Parais6polis presents a development project for his parcel of land to the government. He asks for an increase in the FAR in order to build an apartment building. Currently, 30 families live on his plot--they have occupied the land for 15 years. The developer has agreed to build housing for and give land tenure to the occupants on another parcel of land 5 kilometers away from the present site. The government has agreed to relocate the favelados and award the change in zoning. the relocation plan to the favelados. The government then announces The favelados respond that they do not want to be relocated and that they have the potential to go to court to invoke the Usocapiao law to stop all proceedings. At this point, the government does not force the proposal for fear of a public clash. sought by all stakeholders. negotiation An alternative solution is They decide they would like to try a STEP process. Several procedural and substantive tasks need to be accomplished in order to start a STEP negotiation and see it through to a successful consensus-based agreement: 1) Prenegotiation, 2) Representation, 3) Fact Finding and Inventing Options, and 4) Packaging and Formalization. This Chapter will address the first four task categories; the final task of packaging and 92 formalizing an agreement will be addressed in the following Chapter, utilizing a financial model. intermediary--an It will be assumed that these tasks will be facilitated by an independent mediator--in the case study of Parais6polis, although the direct identity of the mediator will not be determined. 93 Prenegotiation In the case of Parais6polis, an Prenegotiation is the first critical stage. independent mediator comes forth either voluntarily, appointed by a court, designated by one of the stakeholders. stakeholders, privately. The first task is to talk with each of the He helps the groups define their true interests, fears and BATNAs (as listed in Chapter 2). The mediator devotes a great deal of time helping the government group and the favelado internally, making or their respective interests. group develop and define, An important part of this process is each party aware of its BATNAs and defining the different interests that exist among the stakeholders. Generally, each group is accustomed to playing a defensive role in any conflict. As a result, all of the stakeholders' current mind-sets, as well as envisioned solutions, tend to focus on what they can do to thwart the opposing party--not on how they can help themselves Put achieve their own interests by utilizing the resources of the other parties. simply, most factions see the conflict as a zero-sum game; the intermediary needs to turn this into a non-zero sum game or at least show the potential to arrive at a non-zero sum game. One obstacle in turning the game around is convincing the stakeholders that it is possible and better to define the divergent interests within their group. When organizations are in a defensive mode they need to stand together. result, individuals within the group divergent interests. more often conform than express As a their For example, some favelados in Parais6polis say they want a house for all the favelados, or they will not move. In fact, some would prefer to have money to build a house on land they own somewhere else. The former 94 posture suits process a defensive action, but does not necessarily work in a negotiation where the differences and the different values each stakeholder places on items are the elements that can be traded to bring about a consensus. Government also tends to define interests and solutions in this same manner, based on a need to simplify implementation and demonstrate fairness and equality for all involved; while internally each faction ends up compromising their interests. Thus, a mediator for Parais6polis must reorient the stakeholders to divulge their sorted interests and to understand that other groups also have these same variations. recognize Meanwhile, the mediator needs to some reorganization of the present internal structure or coalitions may need to be addressed. Disaggregating interests does not imply dilution of the organization, existing power structures or group representation, which is usually assumed to be the case. A well-organized group of individuals with defined interests can be just The need as powerful as one that seeks an equal outcome for all its individuals. for group action is very strong, especially for those stakeholders who lack financial resources or feel powerless in a negotiation process, as is the case for the favelados. In fact, it benefits the government and the land owner to deal with the favelados as a group. A united front of favelados can guarantee a smaller probability that one favela will hold out and impede a deal, an advantage for the owner. The government can also benefit from a well- organized group of favelados. with the favelados, By placing the decision-making the government can redirect its energies responsibility from enforcing imposed decisions to negotiating a better solution for themselves. Through 95 such an approach, the government can avoid being seen as taking one side or the other. Representation: Who can participate, who sits at the table? The second operational task is to identify any unrepresented stakeholders, to choose spokespersons or team leaders for all the stakeholders, and to devise All parties that are directly strategies for dealing with diffuse interests. affected by the outcome of implementing a STEP consensus should be In the case of the land tenure dispute in Parais6polis, the first represented. difficult task is to identify the number of families directly affected in the occupied plot. It would be nice to have an independent source to verify the number of families, but this is impossible. the number of houses on the parcel. The next best thing is to identify At this point criteria needs to be established as to who can participate in the negotiations. efficiency, For reasons of the favelados and an independent source--either the mediator, government representative or land owner--should take stock of the population. It is important to identify the stakeholders immediately, particularly the favelados. It is probable that over the course of the negotiation more houses will be erected or more families will show up. Either the favelados should agree to limit further entry or a rule must be established as to how new comers will be factored into any solution. For example, all of the existing 96 favelados would be willing to give up one square meter for every new family who enters the parcel during the negotiation period. Setting the number of total participants needs to be done at the outset with all the stakeholders. Later, the criterion for the exact distribution of benefits from any solution should be determined. Some criteria might be size of family, level of income, level of participation in community, length of stay in the community, size of existing plot or dwelling. This is best left to the internal discretion of the occupants. 7 6 It is sometimes easier to create new more efficient organizations in order to give more control to outsiders or other stakeholders. Disputing parties' confidence in such new structures may be very low. Thus, working with existing organizations is critical, especially in reference to the favelados. Parais6polis, a favela organization already exists. In It should be included in order to tap a network of communication and trust that is already established. The exclusion of the favelados would give them grounds to be suspicious of any outsider who was trying to dismantle the existing power structure. One owner of land in Parais6polis has tried to negotiate with the favelados. priority was to determine the number of houses in the area. people on each block and asked them to count the houses. they did not want to do this. His He talked with The favelados said From the owner's point of view the favelados did 7 6 This was the case in the projects in Osasco, a municipality adjacent to Sao Paulo where occupied municipal land was being regularized. The city delineated plots and the distribution was left to the favelados. Interview with Ione Marisa K. Cornejo, 18 August 1988. 97 not want to talk because they were lazy. From the favelados' point of view, a stranger to their community was coming into count how many favelados had to be removed. Why had the owner not contacted the existing "mayor" of Parais6polis, who had all the necessary information? 7 7 In negotiating one parcel within the favelas of Parais6polis, the larger favela organization as well as the people directly located on the disputed parcel need to be included in any negotiations. Those on the parcel will need to define their interests, while the larger favela organization can be seen as a resource. In the case of Parais6polis, the Uniao de Moradores da Favela Paraispolis might be able to bring future guarantees of no entry by additional families into the area. The group might be able to pressure smaller dissenting factions on the plot to agree with the majority. The larger organization may be able to offer other useful components to close an agreement. For example, an individual on the disputing parcel might no want to take part in the negotiation. The larger favela organization might be able to find another family within the favela who would be willing to trade houses with this family in order to part take and benefit in the negotiation. At the same time, the land owner and designated governmental agencies should be directly included in the negotiations. Likewise, the larger owners' association should be involved, although perhaps not directly, because the owners, too, can bring added resources to the table: 7 7 Santos and offer the incorporation of M6melo interviews. 98 other land owners and their parcels and/or alternative land parcels within or outside the area. The same holds true for the government. SEMPLA (the planning office) should negotiate, but it should be able to utilize its contacts and access to available resources within other governmental institutions to the table, e.g., state banks, tax offices. Finally, any other non-profit organization in the community should be given a chance to participate in the negotiations along with the favelados, although the final decision on any agreement form the favelados point of view should remain with the occupants themselves. Once stakeholders have been determined, spokespersons need to be chosen to represent the groups at the bargaining table. A spokesperson, unlike a representative, can speak only for the group and is not vested with authority to make decisions for the group. The role of spokesperson for the favelados at least appears to be a familiar one within their organization of dwellers. When the president of the favela organization was asked if her community would like a "hypothetical solution X or solution Y", she responded that she did not know and would be willing to go back and ask her community what they thought of the idea. 7 8 would be efficient. To work with the present structure in Parais6polis A role of spokesperson, similar to that of the favela president, would help create a more stable solution in the end because each individual would feel that he would have contributed to the decision-making process. 7 8 Mendonga interview. 99 Once spokespersons are chosen, the question then becomes one of whether or not this spokesperson is legitimate. Government and owners are often wary of believing in the legitimacy of any favelado. This can be dealt with through procedure, having elections observed by the mediator. In reality, it is often clear whether or not the representative is truly a respected leader, by the way individuals listen to this person and whether or not the person is well known. Remember the spokesperson does not have any authority to take decisions for the group thus the legitimacy question may be considered of secondary importance in this framework. The legitimacy of the land owner concerns the government and the favelados, particularly when a lawyer is used as a representative. A solution to this problem is for the owner to show his clear title or for the lawyer to show his contract with the land owner. When the title is in question or a lawyer or other party represents owners who are in court the fear of dealing with a non-legitimate owner is heightened. Again, if two land owners are in court, the potential for an agreement out of court with both of them and the favelados may be enough incentive to resolve the two problems at once. Therefore, it is not necessary that there be only one owner or that there be clear title in order to start a negotiation. Once spokespersons are chosen, agenda-setting becomes the next task. First acknowledgement of common issues of concern should be recorded. In the hypothetical case, time is a common concern. It appears contradictory that time would be of the essence for the favelados, but they too have said that they do not want to waste their time negotiating and having nothing come of their 100 investment. Accordingly, it is important for all stakeholders time table. In the case of Parais6polis, I suggest a one-year negotiation period. to agree on a In fact, by setting a time table the developer is exposed to less risk of market movement--he faces a lower probability that the market will move away from him. The developer desires a time table not only during the negotiation phase but also during the approval process of the project. A shorter approval time is of great value to the developer yet it is no extra cost for the government. The time table is a perfect example of tradable item, it should be factored as a benefit for the developer. The second item of the agenda is the fear of how each party will live up to its part of the agreement. solution. This can be addressed by a procedural and substantive By allowing each party to participate and negotiate, each stakeholder will have more of a responsibility to fulfill the outcome. On the substantive side, the parties, with the help of the mediator, can draw up contracts to enforce the agreements. Also, in structuring the agreement, each party should be required to fulfill an action equal to its rewards; thus no one party will feel that it is being taken advantage of. The third item is to designate meeting times and locations. For the sake fo efficiency the time should be convenient and the location accessible. For the sake of perceived fairness, meetings should take place on neutral ground. the sake of efficient and perceived fairness. for This item is very important for the favelados, for they usually work all day and do not have the freedom to attend meetings during regular business hours. One of the land owners who 101 said he was willing to talk with the favelados called the president of the favela and scheduled a meeting downtown at 3:00 p.m. president never showed up. He later said the favelado The president was a receptionist for a state agency, and it was impossible for her to attend the meeting. Yet, her absence was construed as unwillingness to discuss options. 7 9 This example illustrates the problem of timing and location of meetings. Downtown is not the most convenient location for the favelados. In the case of Parais6polis, meetings with all the stakeholders should be held every other Sunday evening. The meetings should take place, alternately, at the church in Parais6polis and the land owner's office, as long as the latter location is In addition a public office on the site accessible by public transportation. should be designated in order to facilitate communications. Internally, both the favelados and government must designate meetings to inform their constituencies. Fact Finding and Inventing Options The next task is to designate a fact-finding group. Fact-finding, feasibility analysis and packaging of agreements must be done simultaneously and are to be coordinated by the mediator. The resulting data from fact finding must be analyzed, then packaged to produce different alternative solutions. 7 9 Memelo Generally, interview. 102 a joint fact-finding mission and feasibility study would be completed by outside independent experts, so as to produce unbiased information. In the case of STEP, most of the information needed to develop packaging options is not accessible to outside experts; the experts happen to be the stakeholders themselves. For example, it is the occupants who know how much they are willing and able to spend on serving new housing expenditures. It is the developer who knows what his cost of capital is, and it is the government who knows how much of a change in zoning it is willing to allow. Next, the mediator needs to outline what each group needs and from whom it is able to receive these components. On the following three pages a summary table (table 6) outlines these needs and shows how they can be satisfied. 103 Satisfying Stakeholders' interests and Fears Parties Needed to Achieve Satisfaction InterFAVELADOS Govern't Owner Lendei mediary General Interests X X title secure 1) X 2) maintain community X 3) maintain job access X X X 4) maintain affordability X 5) increase jobs in area Table 6: Means to Achieve Satisfaction Agree to give title to the favelados Agree to keep people together, favela should act as a group Agree to maintain people in close proximity to jobs and/or transport Sale price should be according to affordability, provide financing Agree to location with access to jobs, if in area agree to hire workers from within the occupants for construction Sub-group___nterests_ Sub-group Interests a) those who want to remain X in favela in current situation b) .... to remain in same locale X but with improvements c) ....to build a house outside the favela d) ....cash to return to another state e) ....cash to move to another X favela _____________________________________ Fears X 1) Developer will not live up to agreement 2) Goverment will clear favele X and reloacte w/out choice 3) Government will change X before agreement is settled C0 X X X X Agree to relocate in the same area, make new units affordable, need to use favela group pressure Agree to relocate in the same area, also make new units affordable Cash equivalent of construction costs to build unit off-site if occupant has clear title to another parcel Ticket to return to another state X X X X Agree to no resale restriction, occupant can sell unit and move later X X X X X For all: a financially feasible agreement A Signed agreement, with built-in renegotiation clause, and a process in which all stakeholders participate Utilize political pressure with favela group action and a process in which all stakeholders participate Time-specific agreement with all stakeholders to reach agreement; intermediary can provide continuity over administrations LAND OWNERS General Interests Govern't Favela Lendel 1) reach quick solution X X 2) obtain clear title X X X 3) have development rights X 4) re-zone the frozen area X 5) speedy and secure removal 7) not use self-built housing ____________Owner 8) not deal with criminals X X X X _____________________ X must build or contract affordable conventional housing a) Those who want to develop, X but have no cash Agreement to exclude occupants with past police records, and/'or agr ement within favelados to take responsibility for all occupants ____X ________ _______ Part of the overall agreement outlining tenure Part of overall agreement Conditional agreement, fulfillment of low-income units Agreement on specific time of removal,work with favela as a group Process of neotiation that includes all stakeholders ____ ___ X Interests A "time agreement" with all stakeholders ____X _____X 6) minimize confrontation Sub-group In t e r mediary all: change zoning and favelados consent to secure tenure and ___For _ increase land values __________thus X X Find a partner with cash (individual or institution) and land as equity contribution _______use b)..to sell the parcel c) ....to develop, and need no cashXXX X X X X Find other person within area to sell to, as part of a STEP option Organize an acireement with stakeholders d) ....to settle court case X X Structure an agreement to include disputing parties x x X Signed agreement by all stakeholders, renegotiation clause 2) Favelados can't be represented X X X 3) Property will be devalued b/c of adjacent low-income housing 4) Political parties & church interfere and cause delay 5) New gov't will be elected before agreement reached 6) Will have to pay bribes for certificate of occupancy X X Agree on a representation structureuse intermediary to verify, find funds to incorporate an oientator for favelados X X X X X X Fears _ 1) Gov't will not live up to its decision _____________________ X X __________ _______intermediary _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Design and construction of units must be approved by all stakeholders _______________________________ Agreement on means of representation and definition of stakeholders, use of an intermediary Agreement with time specification; intermediary can give continuity over administrations Agreement for inspection and defined means to resolve any dispute, especially outlining time to resolve disputes; can oversee implementation -I Inte r- GOVERNMENT General Interests 1) maintain urban form 2) maintain equity 3) not favor one side or other 4) gain votes of favelados 5) clear favela 6) not lay out any cash 7) create some green area 8) remove zoning freeze Sub-aroup interests a) ....are ideologically driven Fears 1) Developer will make unfair profit 2) Corruption will abound 3) Favelados don't have capacity or resources to negotiate 4) Political parties & church will hinder negotiations 5) Will take too much time C Favela X X Owner Lende X X mediary X X X X X X X X X X X X X X Develop area, remove the physical appearance of favela not people X Reach agreement to develop area Utilize a financial model, change zoning to enable cross-subsidy X Aareement on the goal of secure tenure, not housing X Utilize a financial model to measure fair return to risk X X X X Define guidelines for urban form Define equity in terms of process and utilize financial model Use independent intermediary Achieve secure tenure through an agreement X _ X X Use intermediary, barter,i.e., avoid exchange of cash Utilize an intermediary, and find a means to fund technical assistance X Agreement on means of representation and definition of stakeholders, use of an intermediary X greement for a time to reach an agreement The mediator can help establish a joint fact-finding mission, made up of representatives from the stakeholders and technical experts. find out the facts. The goal is to In some cases, a joint mission might be impossible if each party does not want to divulge its true positions. In these cases, the mediator can be a "holding bank" for the information needed to develop a feasibility study. In developing STEP agreements, this is probably one of the most important roles of a mediator. 8 0 take place. Simultaneously, inventing of options should Negotiation theorists suggest role playing and brain storming for good methods for inventing options. Role playing is a particularly helpful method for stakeholders to understand the needs and fears of their counterparts. These exercises can be run as a group activity with all the stakeholders by the mediator, or they can be done within each stakeholding group with the mediator. Once the facts are in, the task of packaging the options are at hand. Packaging is the process of first finding elements that are valued differently by each party and trying to trade these items to reach a win/win consensus. In addition, packaging entails finding the way to structure a consensus that will reduce the overall risk and, it is hoped, make the project feasible for all stakeholders. This process will be described in the following Chapter along with the formalization of a STEP consensus. A summary diagram that illustrates the STEP tasks and process described in this chapter follows. 8 0 0n the other hand, an outside expert could be hired to develop these This option will be reasserted alternatives and hold the sensitive information. mediator. outside is no which there in in the following options 107 Diagram 3 Prene otiatio Favela Organization Intermediary Occupants f Site Owner's Organization Gove nment P Intermediary Intermediary I Adm inistrative Agency Site Owner Representation S okesperson (G) Spokesperson (F I (0) -Spokesperson Intermediary r act Findin I ntermediary Fact Finding Group PackMj Itnventing Options CO., ei Spokesperson (G)----- Spokesperson (F)- Intermediary--Spokesperson (0) Develop' Proposals I % \' SIP Tender Outstanding Needs Consensus I Formalizing Agree t Administrative Agency Consensus Site Owner(s) Occupants Zoning Board 108 CHAPTER FIVE: The Role of a Financial Model in Packaging a STEP Consensus This Chapter will discuss the role that a financial model can play in a STEP process and consensus. The valuation and financial structure (packaging) of the deal is what the financial model addresses and helps to accomplish. It assists greatly in conducting feasibility analyses and in eliciting options for secure tenure production. It incorporates the cash flows and risks, and permits the users and observers of the model to assess a project's impact on each of the different stakeholders. below are: Accordingly, the topics to be discussed a) The Financial Model as a Knowledge-Building and Communication Tool; b) What a Financial Model Needs to Do: Feasibility Analysis and Negotiation; c) Options for Securing Tenure Production; d) Defining the Components of the Projects; e) Obtaining Information Related to Outflows and Inflows; f) Risk Analysis and Its Impact on Each of the Stakeholders; g) Feasibility; and h) Formalizing the Agreement. In addition, some results of simulations for the Parais6polis case study will be presented and the implication of their values on a negotiated solution will be discussed. The actual simulations and explanation of the financial model is presented in more detail in Appendix. Many potential STEP negotiations are unable to reach consensus because of problems in knowledge, communication and feasibility, even though the stakeholders are willing to try to build a consensus. The outcome of STEP is a complex real estate deal based on project finance. Both the physical and non- 109 physical components of the deal must be valued and analyzed. value the various options, the cash flows must be identified. In order to These cash flows must be communicated to and understood by the negotiating parties for them to reach an agreement. An educational process for all stakeholders is critical. The elements of the cash flows (risks and returns) must be packaged in a way that the final consensus is feasible to all parties involved. integrated into a consensus-building process, can help A financial model, overcome the communication, knowledge and feasibility obstacles in packaging a deal that is agreeable to all--or at least a deal which is better for all than would have been reached without a financial model. The particular method of financial evaluation called Valuation by Components (VC) can facilitate the process. What exactly is and is not a financial model? defining, structuring and evaluating and their alternative financing options. A financial model is a means of different alternative physical projects A financial model incorporates the specific risks of each venture and the ability of each party to bear the potential risks. A financial model differs from project to project and from stakeholder to stakeholder. It is a tool both to educate and clarify the implications of alternative options, as well as to be useful as a decision-making tool. A financial model is go a formula which will produce a single answer to a problem once all the data is input. It often is not an objective tool which can necessarily be used repeatedly without being adapted from one option to 110 another, or from case to case. 8 1 A financial model is not a black box to replace human reason or individual responsibility for taking a decision. A financial model i. a tool or instrument to help all parties involved in a complex decisionmaking problem arrive at a more rational decision based on their knowledge of the conditions and assessment of the risks and expected rewards. 81In land sharing deals the location of each project and the type of project, i.e. commercial or residential, may change the value of different options as well as the components which make up the valuation process. For example, the value of a parcel of land will be worth one value if there is a commercial project developed and may be worth another value if a residential project is developed. 111 A Knowledge-Building and Communication Tool When each individual begins to search for a house(s), he has an ideal house in mind--usually the size or the location is beyond the price the individual is willing or able to pay. After a period of searching for this dream house, the individual realizes that his dream house does not exist or it is out of his reach at the moment. He then has two options: to wait until he can afford or find his dream house, or he can change his vision of his dream house. knowledge-building process is crucial in understanding This search or the realistic available options. The search process can be expanded to a knowledge-building process through practical investigation, resulting in clear comprehension of the values of the variables in any package of options. All stakeholders must undergo the knowledge-building process in a systematic manner. The search for the data needed to build a financial model is a method by which knowledge-building can take place in a systematic and efficient manner. Each group must be given the responsibility and direction to research and gather the necessary information to devise a financial model. The process of data gathering serves to inform stakeholders of the available options as a function of the market, the individuals in their groups and the other stakeholders. The knowledge-building process can help individuals understand what their trade-offs feasibly could be, as in the above example of the buyer searching for his ideal home. This process serves to shift positions 112 on issues which might make the options or the positions of stakeholders more feasible or realistic. The knowledge-building process is an important task for the favelados, the land owner/developer 8 2 and the government to undertake. For example, the favelados in Parais6polis do realize that they are situated on valuable property, although they do not know how valuable. The favelados think that a proposal for a new house on another site of 30 square meters is too small, but they have no idea how much a square meter costs. The favelados believe that no one will develop a project in the area of Parais6polis because all of the previous projects required large trucks to move earth within the area. The favelados understand that such hauling involves a substantial amount of money, yet they have no idea how much money. The favelados do not know how or where the money would come from to finance their dwellings. 8 3 It is also very typical for individuals and governmental bodies who receive payment for moving, not to, comprehend or acknowledge the resale value of the unit that the individuals are receiving. The developer is often seen, by both the state and the favelados, as one who is receiving an extraordinary profit; but he is never credited for creating wealth for the favelado. 8 4 The favelado, upon receipt of the house, can sell the house on the open market for much more than he received for it; he will now have the right to sell it because he has 8 2 Throughout chapter Five and in Appendix the land owner will be referred to with the title "developer" or "owner". 8 3 Interviews with Mendonga, Alvaro Pereria Santos, and other residents. 8 4 The wealth creation depends on who will receive the proceeds from the sale price of the favelados' low-income units. If the state holds mortgages on these units it may be the recipient of this wealth instead of the favelado. 113 clear title to it. Thus, the gap between what the stakeholders perceive and what the numbers actually indicate is crucial in defining a package. Stakeholders inaccurately perceive their potential gains not only because of ignorance of the numbers, but also because they tend to focus on the tangible, and not the intangible, elements of a project. elements o o o Some examples of tangible are: construction costs sales revenues interest payments o size of units o location of units One can often consult official sources of information to determine these elements: in Slo Paulo, there are monthly published tables of construction costs in A Construggo (a trade journal), and estimates of sales prices of apartments can be assembled by perusing the weekly newspapers. Land prices can even be determined by assessors and conducting market comparisons. Because these factors are "tangible"--that is, easily identifiable, and often easily measured by a meter stick or bank account--they are often the focus of attention during negotiations. On the other hand, the "intangible" elements are often just as critical defining an agreeable package of options, yet are so often overlooked because they are difficult for parties to comprehend and determine. elements Examples of "intangible" are: o a tax shield received by the developer (construction interest is really a cost, thus reducing the final taxes paid on the profit) o the total value of the investment, which includes the cash equivalent of the land value 114 o the resale value of the low-income units and the question of who receives the money from the resale o the different risks which are associated with different cash flows within the project o the impact of timing factors in the worth of the subsidies within the project It is precisely because these factors are intangible that they are hard to convey to the various stakeholders in the project. Furthermore, some of these factors are the most difficult to estimate from an independent source. In some cases there is no active market to estimate the values; this is the case with the resale value of the low-income units. On the other hand, some of these values are also a function of individual expectations; this is the case with the risk associated with different cash flows. It is hard to find two projects which carry same risk and two companies which have the same perception of this risk. Even though complications exist, there is no reason to disregard the all- important intangible factors. Benchmark estimates of the intangibles can be utilized as a means of accounting for their existence. One way to decrease the gap between reality and perception is for an outside expert to define the numbers. If this route is chosen, the expert must be agreed upon by and have the confidence of all the stakeholders, favelados. including the An outside expert may give more credence to the numbers, but the stakeholders still may not understand the magnitude and weight of the numbers. In order to overcome this problem, the expert should incorporate the help of the stakeholders in gathering the information necessary to build the financial model. Many representatives of government and land owners say that the favelados do not have the educational expertise necessary to carry out this task--even though the favelados search the market place and devise 115 income allocations every day. The favelados require a technical orientation as to what data is necessary and the sources of that data; but they are surely able to retrieve the information. Accordingly, the expert would be needed both to define the financial model and incorporate all stakeholders into the datagathering process. Such a method would enable all the stakeholders, in particular the favelados, to participate in the decision-making In Mexico, an innovative architectural partnership worked with process. a cooperative of low-income people in such a manner to design and erect a new apartment building. The architects defined the necessary data to develop the project and they supplied direction for the individuals to obtain the needed information. On their own, the residents searched for alternative sites to buy and priced the land. During this process, the residents realized the relationship between the price of the land and the location of the property. When the units were being designed, the architects gave the opportunity to residents to price different building materials. The group initially wanted to use high-priced tiles; after the search, they realized they could afford only a cheaper tile or a smaller amount of the expensive tile. The group initially wanted to build the units themselves, until the architect instructed them to go out and get a bid on the construction from a contractor. Afterwards, the group realized they could afford to contract the project out to a builder; in fact, it was not as expensive as they had thought. 8 5 8 5 Jorge Andrade, Visiting Prof. of Architecture, MIT, IAP Seminar: "Participatory Design: Aims and Limits". Cambridge, MA, January 1988. 116 The above project example shows that if assistance is given in defining the necessary data and interpreting that data, the stakeholders can obtain the information on their own and make decisions based on their findings. Users more readily believe in self-collected information and, as a result, can assume responsibility for a decision. As a result, the process of gathering the data for the financial model has just as much meaning as the outcome of the numbers of the model itself. All of the above is applicable for the developer and the government, as well. Each party needs to have a method of comprehending the costs, returns and risks of their cohorts. Therefore, the A financial analysis of any option can accomplish this. knowledge-building among the stakeholders. process can improve the communication Having educated stakeholders is important, so that each party can understand how it can alter components within a deal to achieve its own interests. approach to Communication is a prerequisite for such an work. What a Financial Model Needs To Do:. and Negotiation Feasibility Analysis Any negotiated consensus must be financially feasible to all parties, especially for the developer. Without any direct cash subsidies from the state, a STEP deal hinges on a valuable parcel of land and its development. This parcel of land and the developed project must be valuable enough to subsidize the lowincome units and still maintain a profit for the developer. If not, there needs 117 to be additional subsidies, such as utilizing transfer of development rights or government subsidies. As a result, a critical goal in the negotiation process is to assess whether or not a consensus option is feasible, profitable, for each of the stakeholders. If the option is not feasible, the financial analysis should be able to identify the potential changes which would turn the project into a profitable venture. This task is referred to as "packaging" a STEP consensus. A financial model is needed to facilitate the packaging of any consensus and to assess the feasibility of any proposed package. The following list describes the demands of a financial model in STEP: o Incorporate the economic value of the project to each of the stakeholders, i.e., the costs and benefits o Incorporate the impact of each component of a project to the total value of the project, yet calculating each separately so that the weight of the components can be seen in the overall value of the project easily and quickly o Incorporate explicitly the different risks involved in each alternative o Incorporate explicitly the different risks for each of the stakeholders o Incorporate explicitly the financial risk and the operating risk o Incorporate the added value of the financing structure and intangible items, such as subsidies, to the total value of the project o Incorporate the time value of money o Incorporate the probability of negotiating the deal o Follow a consistent decision criteria 118 o Facilitate the stakeholder in achieving the criteria of a good negotiated agreement Traditional cash flow methods cannot achieve many of these goals. 86 A traditional cash flow analysis generates a present value (PV) or an internal rate of return (IRR) which dictate whether or not a project is feasible. (A traditional model is defined as estimating the expected cash flows for each year and discounting the total periodic cash flows back to the present value, using the average weighted cost of capital to determine the hurdle rate or discount rate). First, the IRR method does not give a consistent decision rule, Thus the stakeholders may i.e. unambiguous information as to the best option. be making choices based on incorrect information generated from a traditional model. The second problem with the traditional model is its In a negotiation, the inability to disaggregate the cash flow components. ability to disaggregate the cash flow components, understand their weights and how shifts in risk can alter their values is critical. This inflexibility makes it difficult to see exactly what each party can negotiate, and why. In addition, it is difficult to assign different discount rates to different cash flows within a traditional model. final agreement. In negotiation this can cause inefficiencies in the If the risks are not correctly accounted for stakeholders may be making decisions based on incorrect information. Furthermore if the risks are not distributed to the parties whom are best able to "bear" these risks then a better agreement may have been passed over. Finally, functionally the 8 6 See Appendix for a more detailed description of the problems with the traditional method. 119 traditional model is often difficult to manipulate. In a negotiation the ability to test many different scenarios is paramount, especially to show all the parties various options. negotiating Thus, the traditional model has limited value in a setting. A financial model for negotiation purposes needs to be more flexible and more transparent than the traditional methods. The Valuation by Components (VC) method can achieve this: VC is a simple approach which takes advantage of the fact that present values are additive. The VC of a project is the sum of the present values of the basic project cash flows, each discounted with an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. . . The VC method is more powerful than a NPV because it explicitly identifies and evaluates financial contributions to the value of a project separately, something very useful for the appraisal of different risk elements and for the contract negotiation process itself, when special concessions may be granted which increase the value of the project to the company. 8 7 The VC method solves the problems of the traditional methods of project evaluation by separating out the project's important cash flows", such as: investment expenditures, operating costs revenues, financing costs and benefits, and taxes. expected cash flows is calculated, rate for each component. "component expected The present value of each of these using an appropriate (different) discount Then, the present values of the respective components are added together to obtain the total adjusted net present value for the project. 8 7 Charles Blitzer, P.E. Cavoulacos and J.L. Paddock. "Risk Bearing and Contract Design: Are Stable Contracts Feasible?" in K. Khan, ed. Petroleum Resources and Development: Economic. Legal and Policy Issues for Developing Countries, (London: Belhaven Press, 1988), p. 175. 120 Assessing the VC method against the criteria of illustrating the time value of money, explicit incorporation of risk analysis and a consistent decision rule, the VC method meets all of these criteria and is more useful for negotiation. The VC method uses discounting for the component cash flows, and can even incorporate a different discount rate for different time periods. The VC method incorporates risk explicitly for respective cash flow components through the disaggregation of cash flow and the use of specific discount rates The decision rule is not ambiguous--the for each corresponding cash flow. project and financial structure with the largest positive VC or Net Present The value of the project for resale purposes is Value (NPV) should be accepted. the value of the NPV. If the VC is negative it would indicate the present value by which the project would need to be subsidized in order for that project to be feasible for that party. Accordingly, the only measure of feasibility in VC method is the NPV of the project. Three additional advantages make the VC more useful for negotiation. the VC method is more transparent. First, The users can see directly which components of a specific project have dominant or more critical effects on the project value and success. Second, the VC is the easiest method for which to conduct sensitivity analysis, due to its format. Third, a VC analysis is meant to be conducted from each stakeholder's perspective, not from an economic costbenefit analysis of the project. By using the VC analysis, it is possible that an individual stakeholder's value of the project might be greater than the actual value of the entire project, if stakeholders' abilities to carry risk are incorporated. This unique character of the VC method, which identifies 121 values in increments to be valued differently by different parties, can enable an intermediary to turn a zero-sum game into a non-zero sum game. A VC analysis requires no more information than the traditional methods of project evaluation, yet it is much more flexible and useful for negotiations. 8 8 In addition any financial model must enable the stakeholders to achieve the goals of a good negotiated agreement in financing terms. The criteria for a good negotiated agreement, as outlined in the previous Chapter, will be invoked once again only in slightly different terms in order to measure the most effective contractual and fiscal framework of various STEP solutions utilizing a financial model. following sections. 1) Risk/Return These elements will be considered in detail in Three elements define the criteria: Effiienc 89: The structure of a STEP consensus should take advantage of comparative ability to bear different categories of risks. the influences are information asymmetries, Some of controllability of factors affecting respective risks, and different capital market bases for pricing risks. For example, the potential risk for a land owner/developer of the final sale price of a market unit can be lowered by negotiating committed retail financing through the national housing finance system. The bank along with the guarantee of the national housing finance system is better able to bear the risk of the market than the developer. aforementioned 8 8 Donald This element is akin to the efficiency criteria. Lessard, E. Flood, Jr, and J.L. Paddock. class notes. 8 9 Paddock, . (1986), To be published. 122 2) Efficiency Incentive 9 0 : management. The government Ensure consistent and efficient project and the favelados want the owner to build low- income units with quality, yet all the stakeholders do not want great cost overruns that would jeopardize the feasibility of the project. Therefore, the project should be structured so that both quality and cost-efficiency maintained. will be One way to accomplish this is to locate the low-income units close to the market units. at least aesthetically, The developer will have an incentive to maintain quality, so that the physical presence of the low-income units will not detract from the value of the high-income units. As long as the full value of the land and the realistic resale price of the low-income units are calculated and the developer is compensated for these costs, expenditures be kept to a minimum. the contract. will Such a structure builds an efficiency incentive into This element is akin to the aforementioned fairness and wisdom criteria. 3) Omni-Enforceabilitv 9 1: across all outcomes. Designing a contract to be more self-enforcing Since housing prices are very sensitive to mortgage availability and interest rates, a contract which gives the owner an option to develop his market units based on an index of these two factors would create more stability over time. This element is akin to the aforementioned stability criteria. 9 0 Paddock, class notes. 91This is a criteria set-up by the author. of Paddock's, Cross-Border Enforceability: self-enforcing across It has its origins in the third criteria Designing a contract to be more different legal/political jurisdictions. Omni-Enforceability self-enforcing across all outcomes the structure of the solution to economic factors. In the case of refers to sensitive of 123 Options for Securing Tenure Production I have developed four separate packages for a parcel of occupied land in Parais6polis. stakeholders: The analysis will be done from the point of view of each of the the land owner, lender, government and favelados. Due to restriction of time and information, during the research, sufficient data on the taxes of the properties were not gathered, thus the government's VC will be estimated conceptually and not numerically. 9 2 Likewise, some of the favelados' values will be determined numerically and some will be determined conceptually. Only the results will be presented in this chapter, the detailed analysis is in Appendix. 1) The traditional relocation solution: both held by private investors. be further away. Two pieces of land will be developed, One will be in Parais6polis and the other will The piece of property off site will house thirty favelados on it and the other will contain an apartment building for sale at market rates. The object is to build housing off site and then build the market rate units in Parais6polis. 2) Land Sharing Scheme: One occupied parcel of land in Parais6polis will be shared between the market units and thirty low-income units. 3) Two pieces of land are to be developed: One will house thirty favelados on it and the other will contain an apartment building for sale at market rates. The present land situation is that, one parcel has a low market land value because 9 2 1n developing a project, taxes are not a significant cash flow factor. Gongalves interview. 124 it is poorly located and vacant; the other parcel has a higher potential market value because it has a good location, yet has thirty favelados on it. The object is to build apartments for the favelados on the low market value land and then construct market rate units on the higher valued land. 4) Three pieces of land are to be utilized. all within Paraisdpolis: two are vacant and one is occupied. The highest potential market value property is occupied, and the two vacant parcels are poorly located. The goal is to relocate the favelados temporarily on the one poorly located property and build the low-income units on the other poorly located parcel and the market units on the well located parcel simultaneously. The following Present Values of component cash flows result from an in-depth VC analysis. The methodology of the VC analysis will discussed in detail below. However, the reader should be made aware that the Present Values across options for each stakeholder (in the table below) represent the best possible deal for each stakeholder, considering finance, risk, costs and revenues. ,The NPV, considering the equity investment, shows the net value added to each of the stakeholders as a result of the total investment. As well, these figures represent the optimum structure of an agreement for all the stakeholders. The best option is the present value with the highest value for each stakeholder, although every value which is above zero is a viable project for that stakeholder. A minimum increase in one Floor-to-Area Ratio (FAR) has been offered as the subsidy. For a detailed version of the financial model and estimation procedures, refer to Appendix., 125 Table 7: Net Present Values of Options for Owner, and Government (all values stated in OTN 9 3 ) Relocation out of Area LAND OWNER $ 8,996 LENDER $17,664 Land Sharing Same Parcel $2,905 $13,920 Lender, Relocation within Area Favelados Three Parcels $25,455 $ 9,423 $17,664 $21,320 FAVELADOS: It is assumed that they will pay full taxes and full charges for services plus a This will be considered as a slight increase in their costs, but small mortgage. it will be common to all options. Relocation out of Area Land Same Low $500 OTN High $1,000 OTN High $1,000 OTN Costs Community High Disruption Low Moderate Moderate Mortgage $145 OTN $145 OTN $145 OTN $145 OTN $4,400 OTN $2,220 OTN $6,660 OTN $4,290 OTN Benefits Resale Value (per unit) (per Relocation within Area Three Parcels High $1,000 OTN unit) NPV for Favelados (30 Sharing Parcel units) 9 3 0TN stands for Obrigagio Tesoro Nacional. treasury bill. It is the equivalent of a US OTN is the most widely used Brazilian index to factor inflation in prices. 126 GOVERNMENT: Costs and benefits are common for all options, and therefore are not considered to be factors. o no infrastructure costs 9 4 o service of small mortgage and income from mortgage repayment, i f the government were to hold them. Relocation out of Area Land Sharing Same Parcel Relocation within Area Three Parcels One Time One Time One Time Two Times Shelter Tax High Low Moderate Moderate Revenues Votes Lowest Highest High Moderate Costs Removal/ Transfer Benefits The option which produces the maximum joint benefits is the use of two parcels within the area ("relocation within area"). All of the stakeholders gain, all of the VC are positive, although not every stakeholder achieves his most preferred option. the developer. This consensus produces by far the highest NPV for It produces the second highest NPV for the lender. government it has a moderate income from taxes. For the Relatively speaking, it brings a high degree of satisfaction to voters because it keeps the group intact, an added benefit for maintaining voting patterns. The two-parcel option has only a one-time relocation cost for the government. For the favelados, this option maintains their access to the larger favela community and jobs, although it does require relocation to another site but within the area. The option also allows for one of the highest resale potentials. A rough 9 4 This value can be accounted for with the addition of a new cost component in the analysis. In this analysis, for simplicity, it is assumed to be minimal, or at least similar for each option. Any infrastructure costs can be estimated and then added to the analysis. 127 estimate of the value of the project from the favelados' point of view is approximately 6,700 OTN. These NPV's and the choice of the relocation within the area option represent a series of decisions to achieve the optimal joint structure for all the First, the VC is used to estimate the value stakeholders (i.e., the highest NPV). to each stakeholder of the four different options. defining the best financing structure. risk involved Then, the VC is utilized in Later, the VC is used to incorporate the in negotiating the agreement. Throughout this process, each of the components which contribute to the value of the project is analyzed. more important point is that the value of the project for all the positive, illustrating a feasible project. The stakeholders is Moreover, all the participants have been able to satisfy their interests, and have perceived that the process and outcome is fair. The process has been outlined previously, but the method, and obstacles, for arriving at the numbers to package the consensus needs to be defined. Defining the Components of the Projects For all of the stakeholders, defining the components to be studied is the first step in financial analysis. The components--costs, benefits and probability of achieving the option--will be defined in general for each of the stakeholders, where the costs are the outflows and the benefits are the inflows. Not only do these individual components need to be calculated, but the corresponding risk 128 of each of these components needs to be analyzed. discussed below.) (The risk analysis will be By incorporating the components and the risk, I will provide a simple example of the analysis of a potential STEP consensus. In the last section, I will propose multiple options to show how the best possible option can be reached. The Outflows (costs) and Inflows (benefits) for each stakeholder follow: From Owner's point of View Outflows: o Equity/Investment Short fall in cash for development of the project Value of the land for both market and low-income units, when the property is occupied Increase in value of the vacant land on the market unit portion or parcel o Debt repayment at the end of the project o Other costs associated with debt: points, interest, insurance o Kicker to debt: points charged to the developer, by the lender, on the difference o o o o o o o o between the total amount of the construction financing and the total amount of the permanent financing Architectural, legal and construction administration fees Low-income unit construction costs Market-unit construction costs Infrastructure costs, if needed and if paid by developer Sales commission on the market units Taxes on the profit from operation Property taxes during development Loss in the market value of the low-income units 9 5 Inflows: o Debt for the project o o o o Increase in value of the vacant land on the market unit portion or parcel Sale price of the market units Sale price of the low-income units, if charged Interest Tax Shield, the amount of taxes not paid because interest financing is calculated as a cost o Kicker Tax Shield, the amount of taxes not paid because the kicker paid to lender is also considered a cost 9 5 Difference between the market value and the sale price received as income for the low-income units. 129 o Any property tax exemptions, if given Favelados' Point of View: Outflows: o The monthly payment for utilities, above that which they are paying now o Up-front costs, such as downpayments, if a mortgage exists o The monthly service for a mortgage, if there is one o The repayment of the mortgage at the time the resale value of the units is calculated ( if a mortgage is held) o The forgone sale price of their present dwelling, exclusive of the land because they do not own the land o Additional property taxes Inflows: o The resale price of the new unit. This price should reflect secure tenure o Mortgage, if given o Any property tax exemptions, if given Lender's Point of View Outflows: o The invest of the loan amount o The taxes paid on the income Inflows: o The income o The income o The income o The income from from from from the up-front points insurance the interest on the construction loan the kicker Government's Point of View Outflows: o The cost of increased density or development of the area o Infrastructure costs, if needed and if paid for by government o Loss of property tax revenue due to tax exemptions, if any are given o The cost of transferring the favelados Inflows: o The increase in property taxes from the market and low-income developed properties 130 Obtaining the Information Related to Outflows and Inflows For Most of the necessary information can be obtained from unbiased sources. example, the cost of construction for various quality levels is published monthly in A Construcao. Other information (e.g., the corporate and property tax rates) is based on government regulations which change infrequently. Financing charges can also be estimated, particularly if the national housing finance system is used, which has little fluctuation in the interest rates and in the points charged. Once the financing is decided upon and the potential market is targeted, the price of the market units can also be forecasted through market surveys. 9 6 The only significant problem in defining the sale price is that it is highly dependent upon the proximity of the low-income units; the closer they are to the market units the lower the resale value will be. Division of the same parcel, i.e., land sharing, is the closest the low- income units could be. If the location of the units were in the neighborhood of Parais6polis, the market value will mirror that of the existing luxury apartments in very close proximity to the favela. The value of these apartments can be assessed in order to define the market more clearly. The resale value of the new low-income housing can also be estimated by examining the market. 9 7 The value of the favelados' present units can also be estimated by a quick survey of the transfer price of the dwellings in the 9 6 Final housing prices are very sensitive to available Brazilian officials have argued that in fact there On the other hand, there market for a low-income unit. evidence that there is a market, for there is a line for housing in the periphery of the city. 9 7 Some financing. would be no resale does appear to be government subsidized 131 favela. Since this number is not recorded in any official document, it will be difficult to find the figure without the cooperation of the favelados. Three issues that are particularly difficult to estimate are 1)cost of increase in density, 2) land values, and 3) the value, the sale price and the beneficiary of the increase in value of the low-income unit. Some may argue that the question as to who retains the benefit of the low-income units is strictly a policy issue. I will try to examine the issue as a question of feasibility, to be dictated on a case-by-case basis. In some cases, there is The cost of increased density will vary from site to site. very little increase in costs, where neither infrastructure, extra road systems, nor an increase in open space is needed. costs occur. In other cases there are very large These costs must be calculated and the costs must be paid by either the government or the developer must pay the costs. Who bears the burden is again a question of the ability to pay and the capability of the market to bear some of the costs. In this case study it is assumed to be minimal because water and electricity exist in the area, in any event it is also assumed that the costs would be approximately the same for any one of the options. The next difficult estimation is the value of the land used in the development of the low-income and market units. The opportunity cost of land should be that for which the developer could sell the property considering the location and the zoning, assuming an approved STEP consensus. Actually, two different values of land are involved in STEP consensus, whether the favelados are to be 132 relocated or they share the land: the value of the low-income property and the value of the market-unit property. These values must be calculated in order to account for the developer's land investment. There are three stages, or elements, in the process of estimating land costs: 1) the value of the market portion of the land while it is occupied; 2) the value of the market portion of the land when it has been vacated; and 3) the value of the low-income developed land. will reflect its occupied status. The occupied land has a market value which Once the land is vacated and has a change in zoning, it will have a higher market value. made by assessors. Estimates of these figures can be Newspapers and trade magazines also contain reasonable estimates of land values but admittedly they are only prices at which land is offered for sale and not the final sale value. 9 8 The value of the low-income land must also be estimated. Whether the low- income land is owibd by one owner (if the land is shared) or another parcel of land is used to relocate occupants, two price influences can be identified to arrive at the value of the low-income land or at least a range in which the value will lie. First is what I term as the "added project value premium", a premium which (when added to the market price of the low-income parcel of land) defines an upper limit for the value of the low-income property. The premium will be based on the added value that the low-income parcel enables the high-income income parcel to achieve due to the development plan. This 9 8 See Appendix : estimation of components, under equity for the values estimated for the case study. 133 premium indicates that the low-income land will be worth at least something above its prevailing market value but no more than the total value it adds to the high-income land. It defines the ceiling for the low-income land value. The second premium, which I have termed the "attractiveness premium", determines the degree to which the value of the low-income parcel will approach the ceiling price. This premium is based on the attractiveness of the alternative parcel to the occupants. If the occupants will settle for only the portion of land which they now occupy, the entire added value will be calculated. If there are several alternative sites which would suit the occupants, the full added value will not be reached because the owner will be able to negotiate the price of the premium down among the alternative sites. The applicability of the above two premiums is best illustrated through a hypothetical example. An owner has a parcel of occupied land, the market value of which is 5 OTN/m 2 . If the owner shares the land, he could receive 7 OTN/m 2 for the high-income portion. OTN/m 2, indicating a ceiling of 7 OTN/m 2 for the value of the low-income property. The added project value premium is 2 If the only land acceptable to the occupants were a portion of the presently occupied land, the maximum attractiveness premium of 2 OTN/m 2 (7 OTN-5 OTN) would be applied, increasing the value of the low-income land to 7 OTN/m 2 . If the owner could. relocate the occupants, given the same parcel of land with a value of 5 OTN/m 2 , the market value of his land might be 15 OTN/m 2 . The added project value premium would then be 10 OTN/m 2 (15 OTN-5 OTN). If the 134 market value of the parcels to which the occupants could be relocated were 4 OTN/m 2 (due to a less desirable location), the upper limit for the value of the low-income property would be 14 OTN/m 2 . Assuming several acceptable alternate sites, the attractiveness premium would be lower than 10 OTN/m 2 , possibly 5 OTN/m 2 , resulting in a value of 9 OTN/m 2 (4 OTN+5 OTN) for the lowincome property. If the developer were to pay cash to the government to take on the responsibility of locating the low-income parcel, the same calculations would be necessary. In this case the cost of the low-income land and construction would be seen as an outflow for the government. be the same and this amount should The value of the land would be charged to the developer if the government were to obtain the land. Even if the government were to utilize some of its own land an opportunity cost needs to be factor for that contribution. The above method is a means for calculating this value. The next difficult decisions are the estimation of the market value of the lowincome units, the sale price of the low-income units and who will retain the increase in value of these units. The market value of the low-income units must be calculated to factor in the benefit created by the developer to the favelados, as well as the forgone benefit to the developer. low-income property can be estimated by assessors. The value of the This amount, net the sale price, is then considered to be a loss of revenue to the developer. 9 9 For the 9 9 This value has been calculated in the VC analysis for the developer, under the title value loss due to low-income units in Appendix. In effect it is the market value of the units minus the sale price to the favelados. 135 favelados the benefit is the difference between the sale price (inclusive of equity and mortgage) and the market value. The goal is not to reward the developer for the exact amount which he has created or lost, rather it is to create an agreement which takes into consideration these costs and benefits and shares these values with all the stakeholders in order to achieve positive VCs for each of them. In order to complete the calculations above for both the developer and the favelados, the sale price of the units must be determined. based on affordability for the favelados.1 0 0 one of two ways: This price must be Affordability can be achieved in either the sale price must be low or mortgage financing must be available. If financing is available, then the holder of the mortgage must be identified. Finally, the beneficiary of the resale profit, due to valuation, must be identified. 10 1 If the favelados were to sell the units, with financing from the government, upon resale they would have to repay the mortgage. Thus, they would rea'Iize a net gain of only the difference between the mortgage, any equity and the resale price. If the developer were to give the units to favelados, without any mortgage, the favelado would be receiving the total value of the property upon resale. These factors are often not calculated, they are the "intangible costs" referred to in the beginning of this chapter. 100 See 101The incurred payment Appendix resale profit upon resale would be a for affordability calculations. is the difference between the resale price, any costs A mortgage principal and any equity or downpayment. resale cost. 136 After defining the market value and the sale price for the low-income units, if the developer's VC is not positive there are four alternative means to alter the The four alternative agreement to regain a positive VC to the developer. sources for further solutions follow: an increase in the sale price of the units with a larger "silent" mortgage, direct outlay of funds by the government, pass-through to high income buyers resulting in higher sale price, larger change in zoning or lower profits to the developer by trading or reducing risks. A "silent" second mortgage is a second mortgage on the property which It reflects the true market value of the unit and not the subsidized sale price. is given in addition to a smaller affordable mortgage, which is serviced by the low-income family. This mortgage is "silent" because it is payable only upon resale of the unit, with deferred interest. It can be held by a bank, in which case the developer would receive more funds up front. It could also be held by the developer as an investment, in which case it would be calculated as a future income in his VC. The down-side of this solution is that a silent mortgage would reduce the benefit to the favelados. The government could also pay the developer a sum to bring his project up to a positive VC, although as stated in an earlier chapter the government is utilizing a STEP process due to lack of funds. The government could also give a larger increase in zoning to offset the deficit for the developer. Finally, a means of reducing the risk for the developer would turn his VC positive. 10 2 This will be addressed in the following section, although one example is the guarantee of permanent financing of the market units. This reduces the risk of the resale value of the units for the developer, thus increasing his VC without increased cash outlays. 10 2 This will be elaborated upon in the following section. 137 Thus this question is not necessarily a simple policy question but is dependent on the impact on feasibility of the specific project. The resulting benefits can vary from case to case, indicating a flexible case by case solution. In some cases, the expected resale value may be far above the cost of the units, resulting in a potentially large benefit for the favelados even if a cost for the unit was originally charged to the favelados. In other cases, the favelados may be able and willing to pay more for their housing, in which case a cost for the unit could be charged. Still, in other cases, the resale value might be equal to or less than the construction costs, thus a cost charged for the unit equal to the value of the construction costs would result in a smaller profit margin for the favelados. Thus it is seen that the arrangement depends on the situation. In Parais6polis, it the estimated market price of the units will be only slightly above the cost of the units. 10 3 amount for the units. The developer will charge an affordable Mortgages are assumed to be committed via one of the Brazilian finance systems at 145 OTN per unit, along with permanent refinancing. 10 4 The favelado will be able to afford this added mortgage expense and pay their property taxes and full utility charges. 10 5 The structure of such a deal permits each of the parties to feel that it is the 10 3 See Appendix : under estimation of components for cost of low-income construction estimates. 10 4 See Appendix -: under estimation of components of low-income revenue for estimate of affordable sale prices for low-income units. 105At present the favelados are only paying a minimum service charge for the use of public utilities. ' 138 legitimate owner. Neither the government nor the land owner wants to feel like it is giving something to the favelados. In addition, the favelados say they are willing and would like to pay for a secure housing situation, as long as it is affordable. 10 6 Resale restrictions are another decision which enters into the question of the value of the low-income units. Many subsidized housing schemes have resale restrictions and/or "silent" mortgages with the intent of discouraging quick resale of units, or the intent of recapturing the subsidy in order for it to remain with the unit or revenue for the state. housing projects. consensus. This may be a goal in subsidized Such a strategy is not advisable in trying to attain a STEP In a STEP project all stakeholders are asserting that both the land owner and the occupants have rights to the land, in this sense each should be allowed to receive the benefits of the land, even the benefit of resale of their units. Secondly, the goal of STEP is to create and maintain secure tenure. Accordingly, any barriers which might induce people to sell their property 10 6 Unfortunately, this structure may not be the most financially feasible, although I do not have the necessary information to discern this. It may be that the cost of servicing these small mortgages may not make it a profitable venture. If a mortgage is used it may be worthwhile to have a cooperative mortgage on the whole building. On the other hand, the small amount of income to the developer resulting from the sale price charge to the favelados may be better traded back to the favelados. They would value this component more. If this were the case, the government would not have to guarantee any additional debt and it would not have to service more loans. The issue of responsible ownership can be fulfilled by having each favelados pay full taxes and full service charges no utilities. More investigation needs to be done on the feasibility of low-income mortgages. Alternative types of co-operative ownership should also be examined. It is beyond the scope of this thesis to address this issue. Even though it is not discussed this does not imply that co-operative ownership may not be a viable alternative. 139 under the table, i.e. without registration, must be removed. In the face of resale restrictions or mortgages, the individual who wants to sell his property will find a way to sell it, illegally or non-legally. Thus, an apartment may be sold but never registered, which would point to a failure of STEP since legal tenure has not been secured. Third, by increasing resale restrictions through mortgages or restricted sale prices the VC of the favelados is reduced, thus creating disincentive for them to enter into an agreement. In this light, it is suggested that resale restrictions should not be encouraged. Actually, an offer of resale financing should be established as an incentive for continued legal transfer of property, as has been stated above. Beyond estimating the values of the components, the risks which affect these components must be identified and incorporated into the financial model. Then, the probability of reaching an agreement must also be factored to arrive at the value of the options and to understand the movement possible to achieve a consensus. Risk Analysis and Defining the Best Agreement Often, projects have different risks according to their phases and, as such, should be analyzed differently to incorporate the proper discount rates associated with each phase. project need to be addressed: In the case of STEP, two distinct phases of the a negotiation phase and a development phase. The development phase consists of analyzing the value of the project as if the 140 negotiation were completed. The project itself is not necessarily anything other than a cross-subsidized project of low- and high-income apartments and, as such, is dependent on the risk associated with such projects. Once this value is known, the second analysis can begin, the negotiation phase. This phase consists of analyzing the probability of negotiating an option over an expected time period. It is a conditional value, since some of the risk during this phase are a function of the market and some depend on the ability to negotiate the deal. To incorporate these changes into the risk, an expected VC is calculated, by estimating the probability of succeeding or failing to negotiate the project. Then, the resulting value is discounted at the proper risk-adjusted discount rate, reflecting the systematic negotiation stages. risk during the With this new value and by incorporating the costs of negotiation, it can be estimated if the value of the subsidy through zoning will make the project worthwhile, i.e. the net present value of the project is greater than zero. If the project is deemed to be worthwhile, the most feasible project, i.e. the project with the highest net present value, can be highlighted. If the projects are unfeasible, the analysis can show how much additional subsidies would be required to make the project feasible. beginning of the chapter feasibility As stated at the is a multi-dimensional question. Feasibility is not only tested by a positive NPV but also by analyzing an agreement according omni-enforceability. to risk/return efficiency, efficiency incentives and This will be addressed in the following section. 141 Identifying the Risks During the Development Phase In general, several risks impact on the inputs and outputs of any construction project of apartments in Brazil. In defining the financing and structuring of a STEP deal, some additional risks exists. In either case the goal is to assign the risk to the party with a comparative advantage in managing the risk, according to the definition of efficiency. The first section will outline and discuss the risks involved in self-financing of a construction project in general, highlighting additional risk due to the cross-subsidy specific to a STEP project. The second section will present a table assigning the risk to the party best able to manage to these risks, as well as potential means of mitigating some of the risks. The method by which these risks are incorporated into the financial model will be described in Appendix, the determination of the discount rate. under From these calculations a table will follow illustrating the first set of VC evaluations for each of the options and financing possibilities. This will show the best option for financing based on an optimal risk management scheme. General Risks o cost risks due to inflation, miss match of currency of inflows and outflows and presold units o price risk due to uncertainty of market sale price and indexation o interest rate risk STEP Risks o o o o inflow risk due timing of sale cost risks due to timing and approval interest rate risk risk of resale value of low-income units 142 o risk that the project's value will not be enough to guarantee loan amount o risk that the project will default o Cost risks due to inflation, mis-match of currency of inflows and outflows: Many costs The problem of inflation is all-encompassing in Brazil's economy. risks are heightened by increasing month to month inflation. These are normally hedged by the use of an indexed currency OTN, although risks still remain. The use of pricing in OTN shields the developer from inflation through inflation unfortunately adjusted monthly payments from the buyers, but construction costs rise faster than the general index of the OTN. This phenomenon has been calculated in the model by adding a minimum construction inflation rate of 12%.107 Beyond this there are further complications due to the use of an OTN index. Although the index is readjusted monthly, the inflows and outflows are not matched. Most costs are paid out in cruzados at various times during the month while the inflows are calculated on indexed cruzados readjusted only the first day of each month. Thus any inflation during the month must be made up by the developer, yielding a 1 potential loss even though there is indexation. 08 The next section will describe the reason for presold units, but I will address the cost problem associated with this system. Once units are presold the risk of increase in costs rests totally with the developer. Any unanticipated real increase in costs of the project will be picked up by the developer. 1 0 7 Rocha Lima. Interview on 5 August 1988. Lima has said that this can be as high as 25% a month. Unfortunately, this has not been calculated into the model because no ibid. concrete information has been found. 1 0 8 Rocha 143 o Price risk due to uncertainty of market sale price and indexation: Normally, 90% of the units in a construction project are presold, to secure occupancy after construction and the reduce the risk of price uncertainty. national housing finance system both construction and Under the permanent financing can be obtained at the same time in order to reduce the uncertainty in the probability of selling the units and at a specific price. Thus, the downpayment for the units is paid to the developer over the construction period, and is paid in indexed cruzados, OTN. Although this indexation shields the developer from inflation on the inflows side, it also adds some risk. Most individuals receive their pay or interest on their savings in cruzados yet they must make monthly payments in OTN. Unfortunately, some individuals do not have the means to keep up with the monthly OTN payments. As a result, a great risk exists that pre-sold units will not close at the end of construction. valuation occurs as a project progresses. On the other hand, So, the land owner may be better off 10 9 taking back the unit in the end and reselling it for a higher price. Thus, the risks of cost of construction and loss of buyers, due to indexation, must be incorporated. o Interest rate risk: Interest rate risk exists on both the construction loan and permanent financing. Traditionally, these are passed to the national housing system (SFH) by utilizing subsidized credit. Both construction and cost-plus-construction sale price to the buyer would shield the developer from increases in construction costs. This is typical with very expensive units, in the case of Parais6polis all of the sale prices are too low, indicating a target market which could not bear this cost risk, thus is must stay with the owner. 109 A 144 permanent financing are committed if the units are sold within the sale price limits set out by the bank. This system can be used for the market units but additional financing must be sought for the low-income units. This can come from other funds within the government which loan for low-income housing or possibly through SFH itself 1 1O. Thus interest rate risk is placed with the national housing finance system, through up-front commitments. not come for free. construction These do The bank will charge a commitment fee for both the finance and the permanent financing. STEP Project Risks o Inflow risk due to timing of sale: A STEP project is more complicated and has increased risk than a normal project due to the miss match in the timing of the inflows and outflows. If the occupied parcel of land is to be utilized for the If, market unit development then the low-income units need to be built first. as traditional practice has it, the downpayment of the market units is only received upon the commencement of construction then the low-income must either be financed by additional debt or equity. units In addition, if the market units can not be presold, i.e., a commitment from the future buyers, until the site is cleared there is greater uncertainty in the market price at which the units could be sold. 110 Time constraints did not allow for investigation of the possibility of SFH finance for the low-income units. If SFH cannot provide the permanent financing, other sources do exist for low-income financing, although they will not be explicitly outlined in this thesis. For simplicity, I have assumed that SFH would provide the construction financing on the low-income units and another unspecified source would provide the permanent financing. 145 The time delay due to the construction of the low-income units increases the possibility of selling the market units at a lower price than anticipated. This risk is present if the STEP deal does not afford the owner the option of delaying development of the property, or the sale of the property. option is not given to the owner, the risk is high. If the One additional method of reducing the sale price risk is to build the low-income and market units simultaneously, thus reducing the time over which the market units are sold (a three parcel scheme). the There is less time for the market to move away from developer/owner. o Cost risks due to timing and approval: Because the low-income units must be built first, there is a long time horizon to the entire project. This exacerbates the problem of estimating costs and calculating inflation, thus increasing the cost risks. A second factor concerning the risks of construction cost is the final approval of the completed construction project, i.e., receipt of the certificate of occupancy. In a normal project, the potential delays in obtaining inspectors during construction and at project completion often lead developers to pay extra money or make extraordinary changes to obtain the final approval. A STEP project has the additional risk that costs will increase during the approval process with the added approval of the low-income project. One way to mitigate this type of risk is to have an agreement as to the exact specifications of the low-income projects, as well as a process designed to settle any disputes. It would also be worthwhile to have the government 146 commit to making inspectors available upon request or within a short period of time of a request. o Interest rate risk: Once again, the fact that a STEP project takes longer to build, the interest rate risk is extended over a longer period of time. If the commitment from the lender to fund both the construction and permanent financing is done at the beginning of the project, the lender is exposed to a longer period of time during which he has funds committed than in a normal construction project. If the commitment is not made, then the owner/developer is assuming some of the interest rate risk, unlike a traditional project. o Risk of resale value of low-income units: The inflow in the VC of the favelado is based on the value of the new low-income unit, with secure tenure, which he is receiving in return for vacating the insecure parcel of land. There is risk in the resale value of the low-income unit, especially if resale financing is not available, or if the lending institution recognizes only the subsidized sale value of the unit, rather than the market value. mitigated by a commitment of resale financing at a base level. This can be Another means of reducing this risk is to have the owner/developer give an option to the favelados to purchase the units back within a specified period of time at a set price. The owner could also place a sum of money for each unit in an escrow account for a determined period of time. The owner would make-up the difference for any of the individuals who do not receive at least the valued price for their unit. Such a guarantee could also ensure a higher quality level 147 of the low-income units, if the owner knew he stood to make additional money on the resale of the market units at some future date. o Risk that the project's value will not be enough to guarantee total loan amount: The risk that the project will not be able to guarantee the loan amount is a normal risk in any development project. It is usually satisfied by the collateral of the land and a portion of equity investment. In the case of a STEP project this traditional method becomes more complicated. The total project loan amount, inclusive of the low-income loan amount, is actually only being collateralized by the value of the high-income, market units and the land for these units. This collateral can be put forth only after the low- income units are built and turned over to the favelados, and title for all the land is cleared. 1 11 Thus, there is an added risk that the collateral may not be enough to guarantee the loan amount. Even if the developer were to use his own funds, i.e. make an equity investment, for the initial low-income units in order to clear title to use the land as collateral, he would have to bear the risk that the future market units would cover the costs of the initial investment. Therefore, the risk cannot be mitigated, but it must be accounted for and held by the party best able to bear it. o Risk that the project will default: The risk that the project will default, or that payment of the interest will be delayed, relates directly to many of the above risks. The fact that there is a delay in the income from the low-income 111Theoretically, the title would be defined and agreed upon at the signing of the agreement, although the actual transfer of the parcels and titles would not take place until the completion of the low-income units. 148 units shows that the potential for default or delay of payment is all too real. This delay would indicate that an investor with "deep pockets" would be necessary or an institution furnishing the debt should be prepared to participate in the profits if more cash or delayed payments occur. conditional A agreement might be arranged to accommodate these short-falls in equity or in delayed repayment, in order to cover this very real risk. 1 12 1 1 2 1n order to incorporate the risk due to default, one would conduct an analysis to define an interest rate which is adjusted for the probability of default (i.e., the expected interest rate equal to the promised interest rate). I have not carried out such an analysis due to a lack of information on loan pricing methods within the SFH system. Thus, an interest rate of 13% and a kicker of 7.5% have been assumed. It appears that the presence of any kicker indicates that the interest rate is not a sufficient return to cover the risk of a normal SFH project. In a STEP project, the interest might be higher and/or a larger kicker might be needed (if interest rates are capped) in order to cover additional risk; in which case, the VC to the developer would be reduced. More research needs to be done in the area of pricing of SFH loans. 149 Table 8: Risks and Who Bears the Risks Risk Manager and Method OWNEROEVELOPER RISKS FAVELADO GOVT LENDER General Risks Cost, due to inflation, mis- Use of OTN index; match of currency inflows cost risk due to inflation; &outflows and presold units presell units Price, due to uncertainty of market sale price and indexation Commit to permanent financing risk of drop out of presold units Take commitment fee for both construction and permanent finance Interest rate risk STEP Risks inflow risk due to timing of sale Provide financing for low-income units,with provision that 80% of market units sold prior to takedown Risk remains w/developer reduced by guarantee of inspection from gov't Cost risk, due to timing and approval Interest-rate risk Developer could guarantee value of low-income units for 2 years Risk of resale value of low-income units Risk of project's ability guarantee loan amount Risk that project will default Guarantee for inspection Risk remains with lender; return based on additional fees and a participation Refinance Refinance Guarantee Guarantee to Participation, if delay In payments 150 Table 9: OTN) 1 13 Net Present Values During the Development Land out of Area Same Parcel within 150,227 10,780 141,699 100,517 Lender 17,664 13,290 17,664 21,320 Favelados 12,150 24,420 24,450 23,610 (30 Relocation (in Relocation Owner Sharing Phase Three Area Parcels Units) One of the goals in packaging is to provide win/win solutions. achieved by examining the value each party places components with regard to risk. This can be on the different "[If] any party has a comparative advantage in [holding that risk], for that party will assign a lower cost of holding that risk than the other party and thus will have to be compensated less for holding it."'114 In essence, values will be traded but not at equal costs and benefits, clearing the way for a win/win outcome. trade risks, there are ways to mitigate general In addition to trying to risks. From the table above, the highest VC for the owner is the relocation outside of the area, although not far behind is the relocation within the area option. The major difference between these two options is due to the small difference in the land values for the low-income units. The best scenario for financing, according to the owner's point of view, is to finance the low-income units with equity 1 13 1 14 and utilize a combination of debt and buyer downpayments as See Appendix A: effects of financing combinations. Blitzer, Cavoulacos, and Paddock, p.174. 151 financing for the market units. These results illustrate the fact that the major risk during the development of the low-income units is the cost risk. The owner is best able to bear this risk, thus he will charge the least for holding it. In the case of the market units the resale value risk is predominant. lender and buyer are better able to bear these risks, therefore The the owner will have a higher VC with debt and buyer financing. The highest VC for the lender is the three parcel option. lower discount rate and a shorter built-out period. This is due to the While the second best option is to finance only the market units for either the relocation within or outside the area. Both of these values are higher than the land sharing scheme due to the kicker component--the higher in the relocation scheme. line with the other preferences sale value of the market units is In order to bring the option of the lender in of the stakeholders, an increase in the interest rate or an increase in the participation rate would have to be arranged. For the favelados, all the options are very close in value, except for the relocation outside option, if the project were to be developed. The major difference between these options is a lower resale price in the relocation outside of the area. These values are only half of the picture. The other half is the incorporation of the risks during the negotiation phase and the probability of achieving an 152 agreement for each of the options. the best option. Expected This will give a more accurate definition of The following section addresses these issues. Negotiation Value During the negotiation phase there are different systematic risks which effect the expected values for each of the options and stakeholders. In addition, there are different probabilities associated with reaching any one of the four options put forth in the beginning of this Chapter. been incorporated in the cash flow estimates above. These factors have not First the present values have to be adjusted by the probability of the stakeholders accepting. probability is considered a non-systematic risk. This The basis of accepting or rejecting a proposal is based on the total agreement and is not necessarily dependent on any systematic economic conditions, as such it must be incorporated by tht use of a probability analysis. Once the probability has been incorporated the new values have to be discounted over the time period needed to complete the negotiation process. The discount rate used will reflect the systematic risk during this period. time period has been assumed to be one year. The These risks and probabilities will be outlined below. 1 15 115 For further discussion see Appendix. 153 Owner's/Developer's Risks: the developer. Three main risks can be identified that impact on The strongest risk is the time it will take to negotiate any deal with the government, other land owners, and the favelados. the developer. Time is money to The risk that the next elected government might not want to continue negotiations or offer the same incentives is very real. The second risk, which is again a function of the time it takes to negotiate, is that the market in which the developer had planned to sell his units will move away from him by the time the negotiations have ended and the favelados have vacated his property. This is extremely critical. If the market moves too far away, the project may no longer be profitable or the type of project may no longer be suited for the market. Third, if too much time lapses, costs might not be valid any longer and the project will not be profitable. The ranking of options according to risk follow, with their corresponding probabilities: o Relocation out of the area: This has the highest risk for the developer because the negotiation process would tend to be the longest and most difficult. The probability of achieving this option, based on the consensus of the favelados and government is estimated at 10%.116 o Relocation within the area: This is a less risky prospect. This alternative would reduce the time necessary to negotiate the deal, yet the time lapse between the building of the market units until after completion of the low-income units places risk on the project. The probability of achieving this option, based on the consensus of the favelados and government, is estimated at 30%. o Sharing the same parcel: This has equal amount of risk as the above project. The probability of achieving this option, based on the consensus of the favelados and government is estimated at 45%. o Relocation within area with three parcels: This is probably the least risky venture because negotiation would move rapidly and the time span to build out the projects would be shorter, or at least simultaneous. 116These are the author's estimates based on the acceptability of the option to the other stakeholders. 154 The probability of achieving this option, based on the consensus of the favelados and government, is estimated at 15%. The government's risk: The first risk to the government is to allocate time and money and find an agreement can not be reached. The second risk is trying to keep intact the votes of the occupants in Parais6polis, this is a function of the final destination of the favelados, they should all be kept together. According to these risks the three alternative solution can be ranked according to the risk premium which would be necessary for the government 1 to enter into this solution: 17 o Relocation out of the area: This is probably the most risk project for the government, for the time to negotiate would be long and the possibility that the occupants would not be together would lower the probability of keeping votes in tack. o Relocation within area with three parcels: This is a less risky option. Votes would be intact but the there is a longer time period of negotiation due to multiple parcels. o Sharing the same parcel: This option carries less risk because only It also keeps votes intact. one land owner is involved in the negotiation. flexibility in terms of little It is not the least risky because it has very options. o Relocation within the area: This is the least risky of all the options. It keeps the votes intact. It has flexibility by utilizing another parcel in Relatively, it requires the least amount of negotiation time. the area. The favelados' risk: The favelados have two main risks. First that they will end up in a location which will not be as favorable as the present one. they will put out energy and time and no agreement will come about. Second, Third, 1 1 7 Due to lack of data, specifically the value of real estate taxes, the government's VC will not be defined numerically, thus no probabilities have been calculated. 155 they will be moved before they receive their new dwelling. According to these risks the three alternative solution can be ranked according to the risk premium which would be necessary for the favelados to enter into this solution: o Relocation out of the area: The has a high risk that the resale value will be low. The units will be built prior to movement. The probability of reaching a consensus from the government and the developer is estimated at 40%. The risk of moving before o Relocation within area with three parcels: low risk that the resale is There high. is built are dwellings the new value will be low. The probability of reaching a consensus from the government and the developer is estimated at 20%. o Sharing the same parcel: This option is the least risky: the resale price will be high, the dwellings will be built prior to movement. The probability of reaching a consensus from the government and the developer is estimated at 10%. o Relocation within the area: This option is equal to the above proposal. The probability of reaching a consensus from the government and the developer is estimated at 30%. The effect of the probability analysis on the VCs of all the stakeholders will have strong implications for the ranking of the options. favelados Originally, the were indifferent between the land sharing, relocation within the area and the three parcel options, all of which produced a VC of approximately 24,000 OTN. Now there will be a clear ranking of the choices, the relocation within the area will be by far the the highest VC. 156 It could be argued that various desired ordering of the options for each stakeholder could be formulate utilizing different probabilities. The purpose of only the numbers are the criteria for the best outcome. describing process of dispute resolution, an elaborate This is true, if as well as an inquiry into all the risks that influence the values, is to provide a means to arrive at numbers as well as probabilities that reflect the reality of the situation, not to choose numbers to create any one desired reality. On means of testing the probabilities assigned to the various options is to do a sensitivity analysis of probabilities. these 1 1 8 Feasibility: Table 10: Highest Expected Relocation out of Area Land Sharing Same Parcel (in OTN) 1 19 Relocation within Area Three Parcels 25,455 9,423 17,664 13,920 17,664 21,320 4,400 2,220 6,660 4,290 8,996 LENDER (30 Value 2,905 Owner Favelados Negotiation units) 118This has not been done for the case study. It should also be remembered that probabilities will often change during the course of a negotiation Therefore, it is important "update" the calculations of the process. stakeholders' VCs periodically. 1 1 9 The government's PV has been outlined in the beginning of the chapter. These figures do not include the cost of negotiation, i.e., the cost of an This cost would have to be subtracted from these present values. intermediary. Depending on the distribution of the expected negotiation costs between various stakeholders, some stakeholders' present values could result in negative the values. 157 From the table above it can be seen that all of the highest NPVs for each stakeholder is positive. This would indicate that all the projects are feasible for each of the stakeholders, although each stakeholder individually would prefer his own highest NPV. parcel option. proportion. Jointly, a win/win solution would be the two Each party is gaining, yet not necessarily by the same The goal of the analysis is not to make each person gain an equal amount, but is to make sure that each stakeholder gains, the result--a non-zero sum outcome. 12 0 With a win/win solution, each of the stakeholders will have the incentive to see the project through to its completion. If the NPVs were not positive several alternatives could be investigated to produce a positive VC. If any of the stakeholders VC's were negative, risks could be traded, as was defined in the previous section. Perhaps there is a more optimal means to manage the risks within the options. If the owner's VC were negative, an additional increase in zoning could be offered to the owner on the parcel in dispute or on another parcel. (transfer of development rights) A new use of the parcels might have to be investigated, in order to obtain a higher sale price on the market units. to be arranged from the favelados. 12 1 A larger sale price might have If the favelados' VC was negative, a lower sale price might have to be arranged, or a higher resale price for their units would have to be guaranteed. If the lender's VC were negative it might have to charge a larger interest rate, or participate at a higher rate. Since the 120As was stated in the section on "criteria for a good outcome", each party should gain but not necessarily by the same amount. 1 2 1 Cost reduction could also be investigated, although quality should not be sacrificed. 158 components which make up each of the stakeholders' VC are already separated, the VC can help when a reassessment of the alternatives are necessary. Even though all of the options in this case study generate positive NPVs, each option, should be reviewed against the three sets of criteria outlined in the beginning of this chapter: risk/return efficiency, efficiency incentives and omni-enforceability. Risk/return efficiency: This is taking advantage of comparative ability to bear different categories of risks. All of the options fill this criteria. The construction cost risk is allocated to the developer, he is the one stakeholder who has knowledge in this area, yet the risk due to inflation is hedged by the use of an indexed currency. The problem in all cases is that a land owner is not and may not be a developer. 1 2 2 contracted by the land owner. In this case a developer/builder will be He will either be able to participate as an equity partner, and thus bear the cost risk or the owner will have to incur this risk. All of the options have reduced the risk of the sale price of the units, to the developer, with the contract for retail financing. The bank along with the developer has guaranteed resale financing for the favelados. Finally, by utilizing the VC method which incorporates the risks explicitly having positive present values illustrates that risks and returns are matched. 1 2 2 Although through out this thesis I have referred to the owner also as a developer, in some cases. 159 Efficiency This criteria refers to Incentive: consistent and efficient project management. an agreement which encourages In the case of STEP agreements it would refer to quality and cost efficiency, as well as meeting time schedules. All of the options appear to have these qualities as long as inspection guarantees are developed and designs are specified before hand (with input form all the stakeholders). Both the land sharing and relocation within the same area have an added efficiency with respect to time and quality. If the location and physical appears of the low-income units have an impact on the sale price of the high income units then the closer the low-income units are to the high-income units then more care needs to be taken to ensure aethetics and quality of the low-income units. Also, if part of resale financing has been guaranteed by the developer and the lender for the low-income units, it is an incentive for the developer to make sure that these low-income units will be worth at least the guaranteed amount. With all of the relocation options, inside or outside the area, the pressure to build the low-income units on time is increased; the market units can only begin construction upon the rehousing of the favelados. "efficiency Thus the relocation within the area meets the highest incentive" Omni-enforceability: all outcomes. criteria. The ability of an agreement to be self-enforcing across One of the best means of testing this criteria is to test each option with respect to sensitivity analysis. positive over various The option which can remain different outcomes would be considered omni-efficient. The highest VC within each option, for each of the stakeholders has been tested with respect to the following changes: 1)increase in interest rates, 160 2)increase in participation rates, 3)decrease in sales price, 4)increase in construction costs and 5)decrease in the sale value for the low-income units. 161 7 Table 11: Original Values Relocation Sensitivity Analysis (in OTN) Variables 2% Increase in Double 20% Decrease Interest Rate Participation Rate Mkt Sales Price within 20% Increase Const Costs 20% Decr in Sale Price Low-Income Area Owner $25,455 $23,697 $25,066 $17,424 $21,729 $26,017 Lender $17,664 $18,488 $18,225 $17,664 $17,664 $17,664 Favelados $24,450 $24,450 $24,450 $24,450 $24,450 $5,340 Relocation outside the Area Owner $8,996 $8,409 $8,866 $6,319 $7,754 $9,089 Lender $17,664 $18,488 $18,225 $17,664 $17,664 $17,664 Favelados $12,150 $12,150 $12,150 $12,150 $12,150 $3,510 ($1,603) ($1,170) $3,747 Land Sharing Owner $2,905 $1,942 $2,450 Lender $13,920 $14,402 $13,779 $13,920 $13,920 $13,920 $24,420 $24,420 $24,420 $24,420 $24,420 $1,770 $9,200 $4,111 $6,374 $9,681 Favelados Three Parcels Owner $9,423 $8,790 Lender $21,320 $22,191 $21,817 $21,320 $21,320 $21,320 Favelados $23,610 $23,610 $23,610 $23,610 $23,610 $3,420 162 From the table above, the relocation within the area, as well as relocation outside of the area, exhibits the least amount of sensitivity to the changes The decrease in sale price and the increase in construction cost tested. produce the largest changes in the VC of the owner. For the two relocation options, percentage decrease in the VC due to the decrease in sale price and the increase in construction costs are 30% and 40%, respectively; whereas the decrease due to these factors in the land sharing option are 150% and 140%; and for the three parcel option 56% options are less sensitive changing and 30%. and therefore Thus both of the relocation will be more enforceable under conditions. For the favelados the only change in their VC is due to a decrease in the resale price of the low-income unit. 1 2 3 the decrease of their VC. economic changes. The decrease in resale price is mirrored in The stability in their VCs reflects a small exposure to For the lender, there is no one option which is more sensitive than another with respect to the variables tested above. 1 2 3 1t is assumed that the interest rate will not change for the favelados. 163 Based on the omni-enforceability criteria either of the relocation options is the least sensitive to the changes tested above. If there were miscalculations due to the model or any changes in the economy the agreement will not automatically be unfeasible if either of these options are chosen. Between the two relocation options, the relocation within the area should be chosen due to Based on the criteria laid out in this section the most feasible a higher VC. option is the relocation within the area. Formalizing the Agreement 2 4 Once a consensus has been reached, there are two steps in formalizing it. First, the consensus must be approved by the Zoning Board. Even though a spokesperson from the government has participated in the STEP process, that person was never vested with the authority to make final decisions for the Zoning Board. His role, rather, has been to enable the other parties to reach a 1 2 4 The formalization of the agreement might be considered an additional risk, in which case an additional probability would need to be worked out as to whether or not the proposal would be accepted by the zoning board. Since, there is practically no experience available on which to base this probability, it is not considered an additional risk. It is assumed, if all of the stakeholders agree on the project and they have all participated during the negotiation process that the zoning board would accept the proposal. It is also assumed that the government office negotiating would receive informal feedback from the zoning board during the negotiation, thus the options would not become totally unacceptable after a consensus was reached. this nature have been tried, a probability After several projects of of acceptance and rejection might need to be added to the analysis. 164 consensus. Second, the consensus must be put in writing and signed by all the stakeholders. If all parties are in consensus and can illustrate that to the Zoning Board through an explanation of the process, a written agreement, and their united physical presence, the Board should have no problem approving the agreement. As stated above, the Board will have difficulty approving a proposal if they perceive any of the following: each party is not represented; the parties are not in agreement; the Board's action will set a precedent. Through a STEP process and consensus, these potential obstacles can be overcome. If all parties still perceive the risks to be high--that the Zoning Board will say "no"--then preliminary approvals from or informational sessions with the Zoning Board can be arranged to avoid any unpredictable outcomes. In the worst case, any disagreement can be negotiated as long as each stakeholder has something to gain. 165 CHAPTER SIX: CONCLUSION By utilizing the STEP process, that incorporates a change in zoning as an incentive to all the stakeholders within a negotiation process, insecurity of tenure for all the stakeholders can be resolved in an efficient manner in Sao Paulo, Brazil. This thesis has utilized the case study area of Parais6polis, a favela in Sio Paulo, to illustrate a land tenure dispute resolution process. a useful case study because: incentive law; It is a) the city has already enacted some type of and b) the Parais6polis favela has a substantial amount of illegally-occupied privately-owned land, as a result of squatter invasions and years of litigation. STEP asserts: It has been shown that STEP is an alternative to litigation. the only way that an agreement and implementation of a settlement can be reached is through a consensus-building process, resulting in a negotiated agreement in which all the parties involved in the conflict are included in the process, i.e., the favelados, the government, and the disputing landowners. The case of Parais6polis presents some peculiarities--high level of favelado organization, long length of tenure, confusion of ownership, high development pressure, remote location, and larger, yet less dense, than most favelas. These factors may make the case less generalizable, although it has been one of the most difficult cases in the city to resolve. Therefore, if an agreement could be accomplished in Parais6polis, a simpler case situation could utilize this solution more easily. The effects of these variables will have to be developed in the future, preferably after several negotiations have taken 166 place to understand their true impact. I have illustrated the potential and logical impact of these factors in the section of elements of STEP. Suggestions for Eliminating Insecurity In general, all of the stakeholders need to keep several things in mind in initiating and achieving a successful agreement. on interests and not on positions. All parties must try to focus The goal should be to address their own interests and fears, as well as those of their counterparts. In addition, all stakeholders should search for someone to fulfill the function of an intermediary as outlined in contribution. Chapter 3, and value his or her potential Finally, each party should develop the skills and purchase the expertise necessary to incorporate the tool of a financial model, in order not only to understand the values and tradeable elements but also to incorporate systematically the intangible factors in any negotiation. At the same time, each of the stakeholders should not preoccupy himself with searching for the exact values or numbers, to the extent that any financial model becomes the focus of the negotiation instead of a tool to reach an agreement. Mistrust abounds and shareholders feel insecure. Thus, each party needs to pay attention even to the details which may be important for other stakeholders, but insignificant for themselves--for example proper meeting times and accessible locations--that will help to build trust and support among all of the stakeholders. Each party must never forget that it is dependent on 167 the other to reach and carry out a successful agreement. Finally, in utilizing the idea of dispute resolution, the conflicts and goals must be clear. I have asserted that the problem is not that each person should "get a house", but that each person should have secure tenure. This work is not a solution to the housing problem, and it is not designed to stop the creation of new favelas. General Advice to Each of the Stakeholders Government: Flexibility is the key. The government should not assume that to achieve fairness and enforce equality, the same solution will hold for each case. The solutions lie in the differences. If flexibility is the key, and case by The case analysis is the goal, the problem of precedent-setting will be avoided. government, as much as any one party, must acquire the expertise needed to evaluate each of the aspects of any project, including not only the urban and architectural qualities, but also the feasibility of the project and its value to the government, i.e. the costs and benefits. The creation of minimum levels of payment for changes in zoning will not suffice, because each case will, in reality, be different. The government should be open to deal even with disputing land owners, in order to make the process truly an alternative to a court proceeding. Occupants: position, The occupants should organize themselves for a proactive and know their and others' varied interests. solutions, look for intermediaries, They should initiate and search for funds from non- 168 governmental organizations to support full-time spokespersons or The favelados should take their fate in their own hands, not wait researchers. for the government or anyone else to offer a solution. The favelados are all capable of learning and gathering the information necessary to "play ball." Land Owners: The land owners need to be more cooperative and show more flexibility in the solutions that are put forth and in the manner in which they are put forth. They need to estimate the values of the various alternatives and value all the subsidies which they are receiving. The land owners must be willing to deal with the favelados as a group, if an efficient process and outcome are desired. The land owner should utilize the strength and control of the entire group of favelados and their resources. The land owner should not be put in the position to pay X to 29 favelados and have to pay 100 X to the 30th favelado on the last day. The land owner should not make unilateral deals with only the government for removal of the occupants. The government will either not agree to this or will agree but not be able to carry out the task. In addition, any unilateral agreement will only make the implementation of vacating the land more difficult, thus jeopardizing the stability of a contract on which the land owner worked hard to achieve, and in some cases may have paid dearly for. approval. return. The land owner should not be hostage to governmental He should not trade something unless he is getting something in Most of all, the land owner should force the group to keep track of the tally, in writing. 169 Finally, the land owner should remember that the other stakeholders are capable citizens like himself or other home owners/buyers. If they are not supplied with the correct information to make a decision, they will not make a decision. Thus it is in the land owner's interest that each of the parties understands the information necessary to make a decision, just as a home buyer needs to understand the financing in order to decide whether or not he will buy one of the land owner's apartments. time and effort The land owner should put the in to transmitting the information stakeholders to arrive at a rational decision. necessary to enable It is not necessarily an advantage for the land owner if the other negotiating stakeholders do not possess adequate information. 1 25 Criticisms of Secure Tenure Production In the course of researching and developing the ideas in this thesis, many criticisms have arisen. Some are legitimate and some are not well-founded. First, some have criticized the use of financial models because the value of land, along with some other values, is very hard to predict. exact numbers need not be a prerequisite model. This is true, but for incorporation of a financial Benchmark figures are acceptable if a financial model is used only to understand where there is movement in the process of packaging, as has been 12 5 Susskind and Cruikshank also point out the importance of these concepts. 170 suggested in this thesis. Disagreement about the validity of values should not jeopardize the efficiency of incorporating a financial model. Second, some critics have asked, "Why should society sacrifice density in order to resolve the problem of insecure tenure?". sacrifice of green open space. are occupied parcels. There U. a sacrifice, but it is not a All of the parcels which I have tried to address The reality is that people do inhabit supposed green areas, even if the areas are legally non-existent. will not take away open green space. Thus, densifying the area On the contrary, by densifying the area, some green open space may be created. The problem of insecure The sacrifice is development and increased density. tenure was brought about by many city wide problems; therefore, the city If the city does not have somehow needs to defray the costs of this problem. the resources to alter laws to create lower standards of subdivision, or build housing or infrastructure (including transport), it must look to other resources which it does have to resolve the problem. This may not be the best alternative, but it does reflect reality. Third, some argue with the premise that STEP will not solve the problem of insecure tenure for the favelados, that it is only a ploy to pay people off. The argument asserts that the favelados will sell the new piece of land or dwelling and take the money and return to another favela. This may be the case with some of the favelados, but at least they will leave with their pockets full, full enough to possibly enter into a new living situation which ha. secure tenure. 171 Remember, an educational process has taken place during negotiations, one which will hopefully help in the favelados' next purchase of a residence. the other hand, dispute resolution is a long process and intense one. On It has been found in Thailand that some people will not move for any price after devoting a great deal of energy, time and money in achieving a secure tenure agreement. 126 It must also be remembered that the favelados will have input into where they would like to be located. As a result, the probability that they will want to move will be lower. The fourth criticism asserts that as a consequence of STEP, invasions will be encouraged as a means to receive a house or money. The purpose of STEP is to help find solutions to existing situations of insecure land tenure. It is on. of many options designed to find solutions to existing situations of insecure land tenure. It has never been stated in this thesis that a STEP process would stop invasions; but, it certainly will not be the sole reason for increased invasions. Given that a STEP consensus takes more than two days to negotiate (it may take years), the time and commitment needed to achieve a STEP consensus can act as a deterrent to quick invasions for quick gains. One technical way of avoiding the potential problem of continued invasions is to define, on the day the law goes into effect, those areas that are eligible for STEP. This was done in the case of the Lei Desfavelamento; only favelas recorded in the 1980 census are eligible. Predetermining eligible favelas based on length of existence has two disadvantages, though. 12 6 Angel and First, some Boonyabancha. 172 recently occupied areas may be experiencing more development pressure than older areas. Denying a subsidy to these areas may hinder an agreement where a market incentive exists. Second, the problem of defining the stakeholders is complicated by the need to determine the exact number of occupants who can participate before negotiations begin. Undoubtedly, there will be a different number of occupants at the time of negotiation than was recorded in prior years: missing what do the stakeholders do with the additional or occupants? The fifth criticism of the STEP process is the potential added cost of the intermediary. Who will pay for this person and how much should he be paid? It is a well-founded concern, but both costs and benefits will result from the decision to use and pay for an intermediary. The intermediary will need to spend a considerable amount of time laying the groundwork for a negotiation process (e.g., bringing the stakeholders to the table). As Susskind and Cruikshank posit, the intermediary will need to make an up-front investment of his own time in order to sell his services, much in the same way that a contractor bids for a project. Once the possibility of negotiating a consensus is apparent and the stakeholders are convinced that the intermediary can help achieve it, arrangement for payment must be addressed. All stakeholders should contribute to the payment of the intermediary, although not necessarily in the same proportion or in the same manner. The value of the intermediary should be viewed in a manner similar to that of the additional parcel of land premium, outlined in Chapter Five. The intermediary 173 should be paid the equivalent of his added value to the project. An estimation of the contribution of the intermediary could be made utilizing the VC analysis. If the STEP project could not have occurred without the intermediary, then the intermediary's value would be equal to the VC each of the parties. If a lower value project could have been achieved without the intermediary, then the added value due to a STEP project with the intermediary's help would be an estimation of his value. The VC of each of the stakeholders can also give an indication as to the proportion each stakeholder should contribute to the payment of the intermediary. If the developer's VC is two times that of the favelado, then he should contribute twice as much as the favelados to pay the intermediary. Affordability also needs to be factored in for each of the stakeholders, as it is a function of the means of payment as well as the timing. The intermediary might have to accept an apartment as payment from the favelados, in lieu of cash. The developer may not be able to pay the negotiator until he has an approved agreement. Thus, the negotiator would work on a contingency basis. In the interim, some form of payment may need to be agreed upon, whether in barter or as a salary from the government or an NGO. In any case, the value of the intermediary should not be underestimated. The last criticism is one which i. well-founded, although not without faults. The argument proceeds as follows: in creating parcel-to-parcel cross- subsidies, the price of the market units have to be inflated in order to carry the cost of the low-income units. As a result, the cost of housing is inflated. 174 This is partially true. The market units will be inflated, but only to the point to which the market can bear the increase. Any costs from the low-income units which cannot be passed on to the market will represent a reduction in profits for the developer. Such a reduction will supposedly be subsidized by the increase in the number of units which the owner can sell, and any reduction in the risk of the project. The resulting prices should reflect only an increase which the market can bear. Areas for Further Research There are many areas which can be identified for further research as a result of my experience. First, perceptions as well as real risks of all the stakeholders need to be studied. Further research relating to the transformation of an owner of a parcel of land into a developer; that is to say does an inhertiant also develop land their own land, and what are the necessary incentives to bring the land into development. Second, change in land values due to change in zoning should be studied, as well as the impact that low-income units have on land values in close proximity to different types of market developments. The impact of low-income residential units near a shopping mall might be different than the effect of low-income units near a high-income residential project. For example, in the Parais6polis case study, the reason that the land sharing option (one of the four examined) may not have been the most favorable is that another type of market project (e.g., a shopping center) was not included in the deal. Third, more information needs 175 to be compiled as to the beta's of different types of construction projects. Fourth, analysis of past projects should be conducted with the Valuation by Components method in order to show how its use would have helped resolve the conflict. Fifth, research on the impact of inflation on construction costs and means for mitigating its influence would be valuable. Also, methods for estimating and incorporating inflation into a financial model should be developed. Finally, alternative types of financing structures for the low- income units should be researched (e.g., co-operatives, as well as alternative sources of financing). As was stated in the introductory paragraph of this chapter, research on the impact of following variables in negotiating an agreement merits attention: the level of favelado organization, length of tenure, confusion of ownership, development pressure, location of parcel, size of parcel and density of parcel. Applicability to Other Tenure Disputes in Brazil and Other Developing Countries The assumptions about the role of the stakeholders in this thesis have been considerably "conservative". This thesis has tried to set-out a process for resolving land tenure conflicts. The situation need not be between only two land owners and one group of favelados. The same process could be utilized in a situation where the land owner with an occupied parcel could find another parcel, also occupied, and define an option for occupants from both parcels to move to one parcel. There could be a parcel which is owned by a group of favelados without enough funds to develop housing. The favelado group could 176 approach another land owner, whose parcel is occupied, and create an option for all the occupants to move to one parcel. Thus, this thesis has attempted to convey that a flexible negotiation process is the most prudent approach to resolving land tenure disputes. STEP has potential in other developing countries and in other cases of tenure disputes. If all of the political, economic, social and financial considerations presented in Chapter Two are analyzed, it will become apparent that there are economic as well as political and social bases for its application. The process may need to be adapted but the basic considerations should hold beyond Sio Paulo's borders. Although the thesis has focused on the application of STEP and dispute resolution for the case of occupied private land, most of the ideas represent a synthesis of policies of affordable housing, linkage, and transfer of development rights outlined in developed countries for both private and public lands, 1 2 7 as well as the extensive work of Shlomo Angel on land sharing on public property in Thailand. In the most basic sense, the key for the application of STEP and a STEP consensus on public land lies in the correct analysis of who holds the risks. 127Urban Land Institute. "Downtown Linkages", presented at Education Forum, (New York: 11 April 1985), outlines the definitions and experiences in the developed world. 177 Appendix: Description of the Financial Model and Simulation Results This Appendix will discuss in detail the VC method and develop the VC utilized in the thesis case study. Most of the detail will focus on the developer's and lender's VC due to the complex nature of these parties' roles in a STEP solution. A discussion of the results has been presented in Chapter five in the text, thus this Appendix will focus on the mechanics and estimation used to simulate the result. The VC Method: Traditional cash flow methods of analysis generate a present value (PV) or an internal rate of return (IRR) which dictate whether or not a project is feasible. (A traditional model is defined as estimating the expected cash flows for each year and discounting the total periodic cash flows back to the present value, using the average weighted cost of capital to determine the discount rate.) 12 8 Once a traditional model is devised, it is difficult to disaggregate the 12 8 From James Paddock, class notes "Construction Finance", MIT, Spring 1988. 1) representation The three criteria used in assessing a financial model are: of the time value of money, 2) explicit incorporation of risk and 3) a clear and The traditional methods have problems in consistent analysis for a decision. meeting these criteria. The IRR Method calculates the discount rate which sets the present value of the expected net operating cash flows equal to the present value of the investment expenditures: 1) the IRR applies discounting, but assumes a constant interest rate, 2) it incorporates risk explicitly in the use of a riskadjusted hurdle rate and the expected net operating cash flows, 3) decision rule--compare the project IRR to the hurdle rate and accept project if IRR is larger, reject if smaller. However, the IRR can give ambiguous results due to: a) some projects' cash flow sequences can return multiple roots, thus multiple IRRs; b) the IRR implicitly assumes a reinvestment rate of all profits at the 178 cash flow components within the project to understand their weights, and how shifts in risk can alter their values. On the other hand, the Valuation by Components method is more flexible, transparent, and the only theoretically correct method. VC is a simple approach which takes advantage of the fact that present values are additive. The VC of a project is the sum of the present values of the basic project cash flows, each discounted with an appropriate risk-adjusted rate. . . The VC method is more powerful than a NPV because it explicitly identifies and evaluates financial contributions to the value of a project separately, something very useful for the appraisal of different risk elements and for the contract negotiation process itself, when special concessions may be granted which increase the value of the project to the company. 1 29 constant rate of the IRR in order to realize the IRR itself; this may not be possible; c) depending on the sequence of the cash flows, the IRR can be the same for two different projects, thus making it impossible to decide between two projects; and d) the risk-adjusted hurdle rate is constant over the life of the project. This may not be the case, particularly on the construction and operation of a project. The Net Present Value (NPV) calculated with the average weighted cost of capital (WACC): calculate the present discounted value of the investment expenditure and net operating cash flows using a pre-selected risk-adjusted discount rate (WACC). Where the WACC= [Proportion of equity][cost of levered equity]+ [proportion of debt][after-tax cost of debt] The NPV/WACC: 1) does incorporate discounting, but usually assumes a constant discount rate. 2) The NPV/WACC incorporates risk explicitly in the risk-adjusted discount rate(WACC) and by using the expected net operating cash flow. 3) decision rule--if the NPV is positive, accept the project, if negative reject the project. However, the use of the WACC can give ambiguous results: a) cash flows of new projects may not be of the same risk class as the firm's average risk. All of the estimates of cash flows need to be either all real or all nominal. All the cash flows must have the same (perpetual) time horizon. b) The debt related to new projects must be assumed to be issued in perpetuity. The new project may not have the same capacity as the firm's average project or may not be constant overtime. c) The new project may not be tax deductible at the same (constant) tax rate, which is implicit. 12 9 Charles Blitzer, P.E. Cavoulacos and J.L. Paddock. "Risk Bearing and Contract Design: Are Stable Contracts Feasible?" in K. Khan, ed. Petroleum 179 Below is an equation defining the major components of a VC analysis for a land sharing deal. By separating cash flows, VC allows different means for estimating the cash flows. It is necessary to identify the three separate means of estimating components: 1 30 1) debt equivalents 2) equity equivalents 3) options In the following application to land sharing, in the case of Parais6polis, the first two methods have been utilized. 1 3 1 Resources and Development: Economic. Legal and Policy Issues for Developing Countries. (London: Belhaven Press, 1988), p. 175. 130 Donald Lessard, E. Flood, Jr, and J.L. Paddock. . (1986), To be published. 131The option theory can be utilized to determine the option value of the land. It has not been used in this analysis due to lack of information. 180 VC = expected expected 12 investment revenues -- expenditures expected expected income taxes operating - 1costs T (1+A)T T (1+B)T Interest debt principal payments inflow T (1+D)T T (1 +C)T T Debt -- rincipal on operations -- (1+C)T Interest + repayment T (1+D)T T (1+D)T T (1+D)T In the equation above each of the components is expected, i.e., the mean of its probability distribution, thus accounting for both the unsystematic and systematic risk of each flow. The second step in defining a VC is to distinguish the contractual cash flows from the non-contractual cash flows--that is, flows fixed by a contract versus those that are not. Typically, all equity positions are non-contractual and most debt positions are contractual. In the case of a real estate venture, such as land sharing, the pre-sale of market units would also be considered a contractual flow and the costs of construction would be considered a noncontractual. The need to define these different categories of flows is linked to 181 the risk and, thus, affects the discount rates, which will be explained in after the definition of the components. 1 32 Estimation of the Components I have adapted the VC method to produce a financial model for the case of Parais6polis. Many assumptions have been set out in order to construct the financial model and to define and estimate the necessary data. These assumptions will be defined with the final goal of estimating the cash flows and present value of four alternative projects. The analysis will be done from the point of view of each of the stakeholders: the land owner, lender, government and favelados. Particular attention is devoted to the developer's point of view, for if the project is not feasible it will not be undertaken. 1 33 Due to restriction of time during my research, sufficient data on the taxes of the properties were not gathered, thus the government's and favelados' VC will be estimated conceptually and not numerically. The four scenarios to be tested are presented first. the stakeholders is then developed. The cash flows for each of The developer and lender's perspective will be shown by an example of a completed VC. The following section will define the tested financing schemes which appear in the example and discuss their effects. As well the definition and explanation of the discount rates and 13 2 Paddock, class notes. to lack of time, information was not gathered on real estate taxes. According to interviews with developers, taxes are not a significant cash flow factor for the developer, thus lack of this information should not invalidate Gonealves interview. findings. 13 3 Due 182 incorporation of the risk analysis will be addressed in the following section, but first the four possible STEP agreements and the cash flow components. In the case of Parais6polis four scenarios will be tested along with four different financing schemes: 1) The traditional relocation solution: both held privately. away. Two pieces of land will be developed, One will be in Parais6polis and the other will be further The piece of property off site will house thirty favelados on it and the other will contain an apartment building for sale at market rates. The object is to build housing off site and then build the market rate units in Parais6polis. 2) Land Sharing Scheme: One occupied parcel of land in Parais6polis will be shared between the market units and thirty low-income units. 3) Two pieces of land are to be developed: One will house thirty favelados on it The and the other will contain an apartment building for sale at market rates. present land situation, one parcel has a low market land value because it is poorly located within Parais6polis yet it is vacant; the other parcel has a higher potential market value because it has a good location, yet has thirty favelados on it. The object is to build apartments for the favelados on the low market value land and then construct market rate units on the higher valued land. 4) Three pieces of land are to be utilized. all within Parais6polis: two are vacant and one is occupied. The highest potential market value property is occupied, and the two vacant parcels are poorly located. The goal is to relocate the favelados temporarily on the one poorly located property and build the 183 low-income units on the other poorly located parcel and the market units on the well located parcel simultaneously. The Cash Flow Components: Assumptions: From Owner's point of View (see Exhibit I) Equity--Column 1&2 Depending on the financing option equity is based on two factors-1) Paying out of pocket the cost of the low-income units, or if financed-through debt or with the purchaser's credit--paying the difference in the cash flows between the debt and the income from the project. 2) Equity is also the value of the land used to build both projects. This has been calculated by defining first the size of the two parcels: Low-Income Parcel size 441m 2 Market Parcel size 2000m 2 In the case of land sharing, the market parcel is net of the low-income parcel. Next, the value of the two parcels was estimated. By developing the property, the owner is investing the cash amount of the sale value of each parcel: as the project progresses these values change. The methodology used for estimation of the property values have been outlined in the text, in chapter five. The benchmark land values were taken from the following survey of land prices in the area of Parais6polis. 184 Table 12: Land Values in the Area of Parais6polis Land Values In Area of Paralsopolls 1981, 1984, 1988 Year Location 1981 very good good bad bad 1984 good bad 1988 very good OTNs/m2 (Potential value) a 14.35 9.56 4.68 3.52 2.4 1.4 4.2 - 4.9 2.1 - 2.8 17.5 Source: 1981: Estado de Sao Paulo 1984: IMURB 1988: Estado de Sao Paulo Notes: (a) potential value is the potential market value estimated by the state Land Values Used in STEP Options: Relocation within the Area: The high income parcel, which is well located yet occupied, was calculated to be worth 7 OTN/m 2 before an agreement. The low-income parcel was calculated to be worth 7 OTN/m 2 also before the agreement, it is assumed to be poorly located and vacant. After the agreement the high-income parcel was assumed to have a value of 15 OTN/m 2 . Thus the value added premium is 9/m 2 . The attractiveness premium is then assumed to be 6 OTN/m 2 , based on the fact that there are several vacant parcels within the area that the would be 185 acceptable to the favelados. Thus the low-income land is calculated to be 13 OTN/m 2 . Three Parcel Option: The same values were used as the above relocation option. The third parcel for holding purposes was calculated to be worth 7 OTN/m 2 . Relocation out of Area: Again the high-income parcel was calculated to be worth 7 OTN/m 2 before the agreement and 15 OTN/m 2 after, yielding a valued added premium of 9 OTN/m 2 . The low-income parcel is estimated to be worth 7 OTN/m 2 . The attractiveness premium was determined to be only 4 OTN/m 2 due to the acceptability of several alternative sights outside the area. Thus the final price for the low- income property is 11 OTN/m 2 . Land Sharing: Assuming that the presence of the low-income units on the same parcel of the low-income units, will reduce the potential sales price of the high-income units, land values are adjusted. OTN/m 2 It is assumed that the parcels now are worth 7 . It is assumed that the high-income parcel will be worth 10 OTN/m 2 after an agreement. Thus the value added premium is 3 OTN/m 2 . The attractiveness premium is the full value of the value added premium, 3 OTN/m 2 , due to the fact that the favelados will not accept any other parcel except that which is they presently occupy. Thus the value of the low-income property is 10 OTN/m 2 also. 186 These two values not only reflect the location and the occupation factors, but also the fact that these two parcels are zoned with a floor to area ratio (FAR) of (this indicates only a house is permitted) only 0.29. Once the favelados are moved and the FAR is increased to 2.0, the value of the market property increase to 15 OTN/m 2 . When the low-income units are completed, the developer will have made an added investment of the increase in value of his land. Technical Note onEquity and Land Values: column in Exhibit 1. Equity is only an accounting It includes the land value for the investment, as well as the cash needed for the investment. The result of a VC is a =1_t1 present value. The cash investment (part of the equity component) is not subtracted as a separate component; it is accounted for by the cash shortfall in all of the other components. Thus, the equity column illustrates only the value the owner is contributing to the project. (The equity column(1) minus the land value column(2)). On the other hand, the investment of the land values and the increase in land values are not cash outlays and cash incomes. If they are not added/subtracted as separate cost and income components, they will not be accounted for. This is the reason for making " investment land value" and "increase in land value" separate components summed in the final VC. 187 Exhibit 1: Example of Owner's VC under relocation within area (in OTN) 1 Discount RateE year Present Value Equity (1)+(2) 0 $50,050 Totals Monthly Costs I." 00 00 2 67% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 $65,118 $22,354 $2,817 $4,226 $4,226 $5,634 $4,226 $2,817 $1,409 $704 $704 $0 $16,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 3 67% Investments Increase in Vacant Land Value on Land Values Comm and Low Commercial Prop $27,026 $8,336 4 $35,733 $19,733 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $16,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $16,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $16,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 5 13% 67% Debt _ $112,458 $140,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4,200 $11,200 $7,000 $7,000 $8,400 $9,800 $11,200 $11,200 $9,800 $9,800 $9,800 $9,800 $12,600 $14,000 $4,200 $0 13% Arqu, Legal, & Construction Admin Costs $40,860 $49,007 $1,396 $367 $551 $551 $735 $551 $367 $184 $92 $92 $0 $0 $11,935 $2,893 $1,808 $1,447 $1,808 $2,531 $2,531 $2,531 $2,170 $2,531 $2,170 $2,531 $2,893 $3,255 $1,085 $0 6 7 67% 67% ow Income Cons Market Const Costs Costs $19,022 000 $24,498 $1,225 $2,450 $3,675 $3,675 $4,900 $3,675 $2,450 $1,225 $612 $612 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $84,685 $241,087 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $26,520 $19,287 $12,054 $9,643 $12,054 $16,876 $16,876 $16,876 $14,465 $16,876 $14,465 $16,876 $19,287 $21,698 $7,233 $0 8 11 10 9 13% 13% 13% NCI Expected Low Commission Expected -(5)-(6)-(7) Market Revenue Income Revenue Market Units Price +(S)+(9)-(10) _7%*Sale __________ $222,044 $28,155 $3,954 $390,811 _ $500,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $49,118 $48,655 $11,089 $7,260 $4,669 $6,222 $10,584 $9,437 $9,727 $8,643 $11,669 $9,150 $12,175 $12,401 $14,099 $7,626 $267,477 $4,500 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4,500 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $35,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $17,500 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $17,500 13 67% 13% Loss in Value Tax of Oper Low-Inc Units sum (9)*IT $154,908 ($2,621) ($2,817) ($4,226) ($4,226) ($5,634) ($4,226) ($2,817) ($1,409) ($704) ($704) $0 $53,618 ($7,300) ($11,092) ($6,602) ($6,421) ($7,641) ($8,824) ($9,970) ($9,681) ($7,992) ($7,739) ($7,485) ($7,232) ($9,779) ($10,854) ($692) $249,977 12 (9)-LowSale $40,097 ($13,286) $54,218 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $54,218 ($25,500) $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 ($25,500) $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Monthly Loan Balance 0) 13% Interest+ Insurance + Points $22,487 19 13% Kicker Shield 18 17 16 15 14 13% 13% 13% Principal Interest Tax Kicker Shield MIT*NT Paymt Part*PermFin IT*Kicker $1,165 $3,328 $7,458 $103,538 $28,814 $140,000 $10,085 $4,500 $1,575 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4,200 $15,400 $22,400 $29,400 $37,800 $47,600 $58,800 $70,000 $79,800 $89,600 $99,400 $109,200 $121,800 $135,800 $140,000 $140,000 $1,400 $109 $398 $579 $760 $977 $1,230 $1,519 $1,808 $2,062 $2,315 $2,568 $2,821 $3,147 $3,508 $3,617 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $140,000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $10,085 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4,500 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,575 20 NPV of Project -(2)+(3)+(4)+(1 1) -(1 2)+(13)-(1 5)-(16) +(17)-(18)+(19) $141,699.25 $33,802.85 Increase in Vacant Land Value on Commercial Property--Column 3 The increase in the property value on the commercial property is calculated as an inflow upon the removal of the favelados. Debt--Column 4 (see Exhibit 2) This flow is calculated as an inflow to the developer. The maximum debt which can be taken, under the federal housing system, 1 3 4 is 80% of the direct construction costs with a maximum limit of 3,500 OTN per unit. Depending on the scenario, 80% of the cost of the low-income units is financed and a maximum of 3,500 OTN per unit is financed on the market units. The debt for each project is separate; one is paid off and then the other is taken out. The disbursement schedules are taken from the SFH estimates on a 15-month construction period. Debt--Column 14,15,16 Debt is also calculated as an outflow when repaid (serviced). the balance of the debt over time. Column 14 shows Column 15 shows the points paid, the insurance and the interest on the debt. It is assumed that points are charged at 1% of the total loan amount and are paid up front. 1 3 5 at 1% per month and interest at 13% per year. 1 3 6 Insurance is estimated Both interest and insurance are calculated on the outstanding balance of the debt, although the payment of 134 SFH--Sistema Financeiro Da Habitagdo which also provides permanent financing 135 SFH 136 SFH. The interest fluctuates from 12% to 15%, depending on the project. 191 both insurance and interest is one month behind the funds received, i.e. interest is only paid on what has been received. Column 16 show the pay-down of the debt. the completion of each of the projects. This takes place one month after It is assumed that one month will be necessary to legally transfer the property and pay off the last interest payment. 192 Exhibit 2 Low-Inc Debt Disbursement Months % Dispursed 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Total 80%CC | Market Unit Debt Disbursements Months % of Costs 3.00% 10.00% 8.00% 12.00% 22.00% 15.00% 18.00% 7.00% 3.00% 2.00% 100.00% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 _ _ 13 14 15 Total 80% Cost 3.00% 8.00% 5.00% 5.00% 6.00% 7.00% 8.00% 8.00% 7.00% 7.00% 7.00% 7.00% 9.00% 10.00% 3.00% 100.00% 193 Costs Construction All construction costs were assumed to increase 1% per month above the OTN rate. The cost of construction usually rises faster that the index of inflation. These increases are applied over the construction period. Note that the financing was based on estimated cost of construction without inflation. Architectural, Legal Construction and Administration Fees--Col. 5: The architectural fees were based on 5% of the estimated cost of construction (without inflation) and paid up front, at the beginning of the low-income project and the market project. apartment 5% is a typical fee for the design of an building. 1 37 The fee for administration of the construction, the legal work done on at closing were estimated to be a total of 15% of the actual construction costs per month, paid each month. 1 3 8 Low-income construction costs--Column 6: (see Exhibit 3) It is assumed that a low-cost construction, (5-story walk-up apartments) would be used as replacement housing for the favelados. retail stores would be built. It is also assumed that no This is a simplification, but it is most likely that some of the thirty people would prefer a shop or both housing and a shop. It was also assumed that no major infrastructure investments would be needed, water and electricity are already present on site. 13 7 Oliveira 13 8 Gongalves Again, this is a interview. interview. 194 simplification, but if the project is unworkable without these extra costs its probability of success will be even worse with added infrastructure costs. According to the Habitagdes de Interesse Social (HIS) standards which relax building standards if the units are destined for low-income families, as estimated cost of construction is 20 OTN/m 2 . Thirty units are required, determined by the existing number of families which occupy the site. On average, 40 m 2 were allocated per unit, which is greater than the existing average of 30 m2 . 1 3 9 Assuming that the buildable area needs to be 1212.75 m 2 (40m 2 multiplied by 30 units), and approximately 60% occupation of the site, an FAR of approximately 2.75 is required. Thus, the cost of construction would be 24,255 OTN, (1212.75 multiplied by 20 OTN m2 )- The disbursement of construction costs is estimated over a ten-month build-out period. 1 4 0 It is assumed that there was not a great variation in the cost per square meter of construction since there are limited amenities and no elevators. 13 9 Paoliello and SEMPLA interviews. from interviews with Gongalves and monthly tables of construction costs in A Construcio. 14 0 Estimates 195 Exhibit 3 Low-income Const Schedules Market Units Const Schedule % Spent Month % Spent Month 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Total 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 5.00% 10.00% 15.00% 15.00% 20.00% 15.00% 10.00% 5.00% 2.50% 2.50% 100.00% Total 11.00% 8.00% 5.00% 4.00% 5.00% 7.00% 7.00% 7.00% 6.00% 7.00% 6.00% 7.00% 8.00% 9.00% 3.00% 100.00% 196 Market Units Construction Costs--Column 7 (see Exhibit 3) The market units construction costs are much more complex. The amount of buildable area is determined by the allowable FAR on the property. The FAR was first adjusted to reflect a uniform buildable area as a reflection of the costs of the different parts of the building, i.e. the cost of constructing a garden is not the same as constructing a bathroom. Thus, an effective buildable area FAR is used to calculate the total cost. Table 13: FAR effective FAR for Sale f(Land Area) effective FAR for Area Cstr f(Land Area) Effective FARs 1 3 2 4 3.5 4.43 5.51 6.6 2.38 3.41 4.52 5.54 SOURCE: Jolo Rocha Lima, Jr. "Andlise do Beneffcio Gerado pela Legislagio do Solo Criado." Unpublished paper, 1988. It can be seen that the total buildable area is less than the FAR indicated by the zoning code. It is assumed that the FAR is an input. With an FAR of 2 , the effective FAR multiplied by the land area equals the buildable area. The average cost of construction is estimated to be 35 OTNm 2 multiplied by the total buildable area yielding a total construction cost of 238,700 OTN (without inflation of 1% per month). 1 4 1 141 ibid. 197 Sales Commission--Column 10 A sales commission has been calculated at 6% of the sale price, only for the Half of the commission is paid at the beginning of construction market units. and the remaining half is paid at closing. Loss in Revenue Due to Low-Income Units--column 13 The difference between the value of the low-income unit minus the sale price received. The value of the low-income units within the area of Parais6polis was estimated to be 1,000 OTN per unit. 14 2 In the option of relocation outside Parais6polis, the value of the unit was estimated at 500 OTN per unit. This lower value is due a less desirable market location. Revenues-Market Units Revenues--Column 8 Based on the location of the parcels within the city, taking into account that new favelado housing will be within the area, the size of the units--221 m2 gross--, with a total of 40 units in the building, and permanent financing of 5,000 OTN per unit--a sale price of 12,500 OTN was estimated. According to market research, the range of prices per square meter (based on the total saleable area) in the area of Parais6polis is 43-75 OTN/m 2 , with an average of 58 OTN/m 2 . Thus the sale price for the project units, which is 57 OTN/m 2 , is approximately equal to the the average of the area. 14 2 Campana and Gongalves interview. 198 Table 14: Apartment Sale Prices in Area Market Price per Square Meter: No. of rooms 3 3 4 4 Apt. size (square m.) 220 200 380 403 of Parais6polis Neighborhood of Parals6polls Total price (OTN) 13,333 15,000 16,333 22,000 OTN/square meter 60.60 75.00 42.98 54.59 58.29 - mean Source: Estado de Sao Paulo, October 16,1988 For the land sharing deal it was assumed that the value of the market units would be approximately half of the value calculated for the other STEP options. This is an estimation by the author. the overall value of the option. This value will be tested for sensitivity in It is assumed that sharing the land will reduce the sale value of the market units, by how much it is hard to say. Knowing that moderate income people buy units for 4-6,000 OTN in locations which are less comparable to this, it would be safe to assume that the estimate of 6,000 OTN would be a reasonable estimate. 14 3 The buyer is expected to be a move-up buyer, selling his previously owned apartment , plus his savings to finance the difference between the financing and the cost. Two scenarios of inflows have been assumed: 1) A normal downpayment schedule: 20% of the unfinanced portion in the first month 20% of the remaining balance the second month 1.43% for the remainder of the months 143Apartments in Villa Nova Cachoeirinha sell for 4,500 OTN and have a smaller area. 199 2) Only enough each month to cover the difference between the debt and the construction costs and the interest on the construction debt. Low-Income Revenue--Column 9 (see Exhibit 4) It is assumed that 25% of the monthly income could support a mortgage. 1 4 4 With a 5% downpayment and a 10-year mortgage the sale price of a unit would be 150 OTN. This would require 1.5 to 2 minimum salaries to qualify. Again this is a simplification, since there are families who could afford to pay more, but without being able to directly identify the families a minimum sale price has been calculated. Different values can be charged for a similar unit depending on the location and the end use within the building, even lowincome individuals perceive this difference. It should be remembered that there are different levels of ability to pay and willingness to pay for housing even among lower-income families. Accordingly, a sale price structure should be devised to capture these differences in ability and taste. The potential for cross-subsidization,and diversification, within the favelados is possible. If the group could bee seen as a cooperative, with both high and low risk clients, the risk would be mitigated. would be reduced. higher. As a result of one larger mortgage, service costs Thus, it is entirely possible that this sale price could be For simplicity's sake this has not been factored into the model, but should be utilized in real life. 14 4 This is only a benchmark figure. Generally, 25% of net monthly income is considered an affordable amount for servicing housing costs. Due to lack of information, this figure is based on gross income. 200 Exhibit 4 Affordability Table Minimum Salary per month * Cruzados 1 $10,464.00 2 $20,928.00 3 $31,392.00 5 $52,320.00 10 $104,640.00 15 $156,960.00 OTN** $5.23 $10.46 $15.70 $26.16 $52.32 $78.48 I_ 25% Monthly Annual Morto Payment Income, OTNs $1.31 $62.78 $2.62 $125.57 $3.92 $188.35 $6.54 $313.92 $13.08 $627.84 $19.62 $941.76 Est. Housing Sale Price 2.5*Annual Inc $156.96 $313.92 $470.88 $784.80 $1,569.60 $2,354.40 1 Minimum Salary-10,464.00 cruzados, Note: Diario Economico e Financeiro, August 23, 1988 *1 OTN-approximately 2,000 cruzados, August 1988 Mortgage Table Sale Price Downpayment Principal 150 OTN 5% 142.5 5 years #DIV/01 10% 11% 12% 13% 14% 15% 0~ 15 years 10 year 60 120 180 20 240 ($3.03) ($3.10) ($3.17) ($3.24) ($3.32) ($3.39) ($1.88) ($1.96) ($2.04) ($2.13) ($ 2 .21) ($2.30)3 ($1.53) ($1.62) ($1.71), ($1.80) ($1.90) ($1.99) ($1.38) ($1.47) ($1.57) ($1.67) ($1.77) ($1.88) 11 Revenues-Expenses---Column This column is the compilation of the present value of the sum of the revenues of column 8 and column 9 minus the sum of expenses of columns 5, 6, and 7. The calculation done in this way to allow different discounting rates for the expense and revenues. (Details of the determination of the discount rates are explained in the following section.) Tax on Operation--Column 12 Taxes of operation are calculated at 35% of the Revenue-Construction Costs, which includes the loss on the low-income units sold below costs. Interest Tax Shield--Column 17 This is calculated at 35% of the total interest payment. The interest tax shield is an inflow,( i.e., an outflow of taxes which did not have to be made) because interest is a cost to the project. Kicker to Debt--Column 18 Under the SFH financing system extra points are charged to the developer on the difference between the total of the construction financing and the permanent financing. The points range from 7.5% to 15%. It is assumed that the maximum permanent financing on all the market units was taken and a 7.5% kicker was charged, regardless of the amount of permanent financing. This is standard practice for SFH. A likely explanation for this participation is that bank realizes that the developer can charge a higher price for the units 202 with higher financing, and it is easier to sell the units with financing. Thus the bank is charging for its services. Kicker Tax Shield--Column 19 The points charged by Caixa Econdmica Federal are considered costs to the project. for the permanent financing Thus, the kicker, like the interest tax shield, offers a 35% shield of income from taxes, (i.e., an outflow of taxes which did not have to be made) This amount is an added inflow for the developer. NPV of the Project--Column 20 The project with the highest positive net present value (VC) is the best project. Lender's Point of View (see Exhibit 5) Outflows: o The investment of the loan amount o The taxes paid on the income Inflows: o The income from the up-front points o The income from insurance o The income from the interest on the construction loan o The income from the kicker 203 Exhibit 5: Example of VC for Lender under Relocation within area option (In OTN) 13% NPV 4:h Months Investment $140,000 67% Revenue Interest Revenue Kicker 13% Taxes NPV $25,591 $1.887 1 2 3 $1.400 $109 $398 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 4 $579 $0 $0 5 6 7 $760 $977 $1.230 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 8 9 $1,519 $1,808 $0 $0 $0 $0 10 11 12 13 14 15 61 6 $2*0 6 2 $$0315 2.31 $2,568 $2,821 $3,147 $3.508 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0_ $0 $0 $3.617 $0 $0 $0 $0 $4.500 $9.814 $11,660 $17,664 1 Favelados' Point of View: Outflows: o The monthly payment for utilities, above that which they are paying now. o Up-front costs, such as downpayments, if a mortgage exists. o The monthly service for a mortgage, if there is one. o The repayment of the mortgage at the time the resale value of the units is calculated (if a mortgage is held). o The forgone sale price of their present dwelling, exclusive of the land because they do not own the land. property taxes Additional o Inflows: o The resale price of the new unit. This price should reflect secure tenure. o Mortgage, if given o Any property tax exemptions, if given Due to lack of information, a simplification of the favelados' VC calculation will be based on the following: (see Exhibit 6) Inflows: o the resale value of the unit estimated at 1,000 OTN within the area of Parais6polis and 500 OTN outside of the area.1 4 5 The unit will be sold after one year. Outflows: o the amount of the mortgage, approximately 145 OTN for 15 years at an interest rate of 10%, with a 5% downpayment. 14 5 According to the dwelling plus land is also estimated by the area of Parais6polis. administration of the Lei de Desfavelamento, each worth 1,000 OTN. The value of the low-income unit was developer Gongalves to be approximately 1,000 OTN in the Campana and Gongalves interview. 205 Example of VC for Favelado under Relocation within Area Op tion, (one unit. 3 4 5 1 2 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% 10.00% Discount Rate Resale price Repayment of Mortoage Service Investment Mortae Received Downpayment $819 $115 $128 $18 $7 Discounted Exhibit 6: 14 1_ 16 $8 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $8 $0 $0 $0 $21 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 -$0 $0 $0 $0 $2 $2 $2 17 $0 $2 18 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $2 $2 $2 $2 $2 $2 $2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 19 2C 21 22 23 24 $143 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $143 $0 $0 $0 $141 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1.000 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $141 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $1,000 in OTN) 6 NPV - (2) + (3) - (4) + (5) $815 Government's Point of View Outflows: o The cost of increased density or development of the area o Infrastructure costs, if needed and if paid for by government o Loss of property tax revenue due to tax exemptions, if any are given o The cost of transferring the favelados Inflows: o The increase in property taxes from the market and low-income developed properties For simplicity sake the following assumptions have been made regarding the government. Outflows: o There are no added costs due to density, or added infrastructure. 1 4 6 o It is assumed that the cost of transferring the favelados will be the same for all of the projects, except the three plot scheme where transferring is done twice, once to the temporary site and secondly to the new housing. Inflows: o The property taxes are seen as a function of the final sale price of all the units, thus a function of location. 14 6 This is not an over-simplification for the first project in the area of Parais6polis. Future projects will have added costs. On the other hand, it is assumed that if there are any costs they will be approximately equal for all of the options. 207 Risk Analysis and Packaging with Comparative Advantage The Valuation by Components method incorporates finance theory under uncertainty and specifically the Capital Asset Pricing Model(CAPM) which identifies two different types of risks which impact on the value of any asset: systematic (non-diversifiable risks) and non-systematic risks (diverisfiable). The model finds that: the total expected return on any risky asset can be disaggregated into two components. The first component is the return on a risk-free asset. The second component is a risk premium which is a function of the covariance of the asset's return with the return on the market. ...The only risk that matters in asset pricing (in the sense that it affects the equilibrium expected return of the asset) is the extent to which the nominal return on the asset moves with the nominal return on the market,i.e. its beta. The component of the risk of the asset is called the undiversifiable or systematic risk. The remainder of the asset's risk, that is, the movement in the assets return that is not correlated with movements in the return on the overall market is called the diversifiable or non-systematic risk. According to modern finance theory, the risk of an investment from the perspective of a specific investor depends on the riskiness of the investment when viewed by itself, and the extent to which that risk can be diversified away in the investor's relevant portfolio of other investment opportunities. The former will be the same for all investors, Obviously, no but the latter may vary significantly among investors. investor can avoid systematic elements that derive from the economic system and, therefore, affect all investments to some degree. The additional required expected return--the risk premium--is the price of risk-bearing and has important implications for investment decisions. 147 Once the risk factor is known the discount rates can be determined. Stemming from this theory the first step is to analyze the systematic and non-systematic risks. Often times projects have different risks according to their phases and as such should be analyzed differently to incorporate the proper discount rates and thus risk-premiums associated with each phase. 14 7 Blitzer, In the case of land Cavoulacos, and Paddock, p. 174. 208 sharing there are two distinct phases which need to be addressed for purpose of analysis and valuation, a negotiation phase and a development phase. The first being the development phase, the analysis of the value of the project as if the negotiation were over. The project itself is not necessarily anything other than a cross-subsidized project of low- and high-income apartments and as Once such is dependent on the risk-premium associated with such projects. this value is know the second analysis can take place--the negotiation phase-the value of the project which is to be negotiated over an expected time period, which is a conditional value. For this phase an expected VC can be calculated, incorporating the probability of succeeding or failing to negotiate the project, and discounted at the proper risk adjusted discount rate, reflecting the systematic risk of during the negotiation stages. With this value and the incorporation of the costs of negotiation it can be estimated if the value of the subsidy through zoning will make the project worthwhile, if so which project is most feasible, and if not where there is room for further subsidy or packaging. Risk Analysis of the Project and Determination of the Discount Rates and Comparative Advantage: The Project Stage All projects consist of two types of risk, operational or business risk and financial risk. The operational risk, as described above, is risk attributable to the operation of the specific project, without any financing involved. risk always exists. It is a factor in the equity position of a project. This Financial risk is the risk attributable to the use of financing, it is the risk that the project will not generate enough funds to cover its debts. In project finance, like real estate and land sharing deals, the ability of the project to pay its debt 209 is considered the financial risk. This risk is carried both by the equity investor and the debt supplier in project finance. By separating the cash flows from the project and the financing in the VC analysis and applying the correct discount rates which correspond to these flows the financial risk and the operational risk is decomposed. 1 4 8 In general there are several risks, all of which are systematic, that impact on the inputs and outputs of any construction of apartments in Brazil. In defining the financing and structuring of a land sharing deal the systematic risks should go to the party who has a comparative advantage in holding this risk. Below the risks will be outlined and assigned to the stakeholders who is best able to "bear" and/or "manage" the risk. Cost of Construction--the developer/owner Resale Price of Market Units--developer/owner Determining the Discount and lender Rates For the purposes of this thesis, two basic types of discount rates utilized in the VC analysis are those for the contractural and non-contractural cash flows. (Many more can be used but at least these two categories need to be distinguished). 14 9 One important difference between a contractural and non- contractural cash flow is in the risk surrounding the expected value of these 14 8 1n the traditional WACC method of project analysis, these two risks are averaged together and utilized in a uniform discount rate applied to the entire project's cash flows, i.e. both debt and equity. Lessard and Paddock. 14 9 ibid. 210 flows. In a STEP deal the following list identifies the contractual and non- 150 : contractual cash flows for the VC of each stakeholder Non-Contractural: Developer--equity, land values, construction costs, loss in value of low-income units Lender--kicker to debt These cash flows exhibit extreme amounts of uncertainty relative to the other cash flows. Equity for the developer is a function of the needs of the project over time. The construction costs have a high degree of uncertainty due to inflationary problems in the Brazilian economy. Equity can also be very volatile due to preselling of units and the possibility of increase in the 15 1 construction costs over the estimated value. Finally, land values are also considered risky and equivalent to the equity put up in any project. For the lender, the value of the kicker is also considered to be a cash flow of a risky nature. buyers. It is dependent on the final amount of financing taken out by the For the favelados, a non-contractual cash flow would be the resale value of their low-income units. If a guarantee from the developer for the 15 0 There are no non-contractural cash flows for the government or for the favelados, especially if there is a guarantee for the resale price or resale financing provided for the low-income units. 151One might also argue that the income from the market units is also a noncontractual cash flow due to its dependence on the overall economic situation, in order for the buyer to meet his obligation of the monthly downpayment. I have assumed that it is not a problem to presell the units. One could factor in a probability of buyers dropping out over the course of construction, although it would not necessarily be incorporated into the discount rate. 211 resale price or resale financing is promised by the government then the resale value would be considered a contractural cash flow. "Both of these discount rates, contractural and non-contractural, reflect only the systematic risk of that cash flow whether contractual or non-contractual. The interest rate on debt may give us a 'floor' on the discount rate." 152 Thus the discount rate for the contractural cash flows was assumed to be equal to the interest rate given for housing. 1 53 In determining the non-contractural discount rate, the CAPM is utilized. The beta of an average risk project is 1 and the return to this is based on the following formula: Project Discount Rate=Minimum Required Rate of Return= Real Interest Rate+inflation Premium+(project Beta*average risk premium)154 where the average risk premium = Market Rate-Riskless Rate In Brazil the following minimum required rate of return for an average project is approximated by the return on the stock market, this value is estimated to be 42% per year (in real terms) 15 5 . The real riskless rate is 15 2 Paddock class notes. 153 This is not the market interest rate but a subsidized rate for housing finance. 15 4 Lessard, Flood, and Paddock, and class notes 1 5 5 David Davies interview, 26 July 1988. The return on the Brazilian stock market is estimated to be between 2 and 5 percent (real) per month. Using an 212 estimated at 6%, this is the rate received on savings accounts in federal Thus working the above formula backwards, utilizing a B=1 to savings banks. signify an average project, the average risk premium is determined to be 36%. Minimum Rate of Return=Real Interest Rate+(project Beta*average[real] risk premium) 42% 42% Therefore 36% = = = +[1*(market rate - 6%)] 6% market rate average (real) risk premium If it is assumed that a STEP project, in which the occupants must be moved off the site after the low-income housing is built the systematic risk is high. This is due to the increased possibility of the market moving away from the estimated costs and sale prices. Thus a project of this type might have a B=1.7156, illustrating that the project is 70% more risky than an average project, would yield a non-contractural real discount rate of 67%, for the owner. Minimum Rate of Return=Real Interest Rate+(project Beta*average[real] risk premium) 67% = 6% + (1.7*36%) average of 3.5% per month yields an average real minimum rate of return on the stock market of 42% per year. 15 6 These are assumed to be unlevered betas. These betas are estimates by the author. 213 In the case of the use of the three parcels of land, the systematic risk for the owner is less because both the parcels for the low-income and high-income parcels are free for use at the beginning of construction. As such the market units could be sold at the beginning of the project, and there is less of a time lag during which the market may move away from the developer either on the construction costs or the resale price. Thus I have used a B=1.5, which yields a discount rate equal to 60%. The non-contractural discount rates for each of the stakeholders reflect the type of portfolio that they have access to. should For simplicity I have assumed that all the parties have the same non-contractural discount rates, this is equal to the interest rate from the lender, 13%.157 The two options, moving occupants outside of the area or keeping them in the area, in the development phase are assumed to have the same risk. The only difference between these two projects is the risk of the cost of the land for the relocation of the occupants. This has been calculated in the expected cash flow component of the VC. With these discount rates the following values can be seen for all the stakeholders, assuming an increase of one FAR. 15 7 For example, the contractual discount rate for the favelados should be the This value will probably be different rate at which they can borrow funds. than either the bank's or the land owner's. Due to lack of information and for the purpose of simplicity, I have used the interest rate of 10% for the discount rate for all of the cash flows for the favelados--the interest rate which will be charged to the favelados. This is only the author's estimate for subsidized housing finance for the favelados. 214 Table Net 15: Present Values During the Development Phase (in OTN) Relocation within Area Three Parcels 10,780 141,699 100,517 17,664 13,290 17,664 21,320 12,150 24,420 24,450 23,610 Relocation out of Area Land Same 150,227 Lender Favelados Owner (30 Sharing Parcel Units) It can be seen from the above table that all of the projects have positive VCs. Thus each project would be feasible. alternate types option. 158 of financing The variation between the projects due to is relatively small except in the land sharing More importantly, the type of project appears to offer a greater deviation in the value of the project. As was stated in Chapter five, these values only reflect each STEP option if the project were agreed upon, i.e., during the development phase. The expected negotiation value of each project still needs to be calculated to understand which option would be the best for all of the stakeholders. Expected Negotiation Value Before the project can be developed it has to be negotiated. This requires additional estimates of the VC, the expected negotiation value of each of the options. The systematic and non-systematic risks need to be accounted for as a function of the probability of negotiation a consensus as well as a function of 15 8 The impact of financing will be analyzed in the section, Financing Effects. 215 the time in which the a consensus will be reached. These variables can be incorporated in the valuation process by calculating a expected negotiated VC. This has been done in Chapter five. The Financing Effects: Once the components have been defined the next step is to identify the financing combinations under each option and to show the effects of the different combinations. This is an important to understand the financing needs that contribute to the creation of viable options for each of the stakeholders. In addition, each party needs to understand the impact it may have in structuring the deal. The goal is to identify the financing structure that produces the highest VC within each STEP option. In the highest VC for each option is used in the expected negotiated value. Returning to the owner's VC several financing combinations were simulated for each of the STEP options. They were tested to understand the necessary financing needs and the best possible combination according to the developer and the lender, assuming an affordable sales price and financing for the lowincome units . The tested combinations were chosen based on the norms of the industry (as defined in the components section) in order to avoid complication of the profile of the final buyer. 1 59 15 9 As outlined in the components section, construction and permanent financing for the market units is normal if the sale price is within the limit of the SFH finance system. If the sales price is higher, the buyer is usually able to purchase the unit with cash and thus finance the construction with these downpayments. In all cases, it is assumed that the sale price falls into the category of a buyer who would need to have permanent financing. 216 Diagram Lov4ncome 4 Market rte FINANCING OPTIONS BANKIDEBT BUYER (A1) ownerlequity 8ANKI DEBT (82) OWNERIEQUITY TOTAL PROJECT BANK IDEBT (B1) bankldebt (02) The four STEP options can be financed utilizing a combination of the following sources of financing (as illustrated in the above diagram): the downpayment of the market units. portion of the project; debt, equity and Concentrating first on the low-income financing can be obtained from equity (Al) or debt (A2). The market units need to be financed with debt (a traditional mortgage), but due to the limits for financing on units in higher sales price brackets, as these have been estimated to be, additional financing will come partially from the 217 monthly installments of the buyers of these units. developed within this scheme. typical downpayment schedule. Two scenarios have been The buyer can pay what would be considered a With this scenario the project still lacks The shortfall in financing is due to the restrictions on financing. construction financing, only 80% of the construction costs. The remaining 20% is reduced through monthly buyer downpayments from the presale of the units. It is traditional for the buyers to pay a fixed monthly amount over the life of the project. The shortfall in funds is thus due to a mis-match in the sequencing of the funds paid out over the life cycle of the construction project. Thus the shortfalls each month can either be made-up through equity (B2) or the developer passing on the total shortfall to the buyers each month (B1). 16 0 The following permutations, in the table, define the financing options tested in the above simulations, for the land sharing scheme, relocation within the area and relocation outside the area. 16 0 1f the developer were to pass on the total amount to the buyer, the buyer would not be paying more for the unit overall. He would be paying only more upfront. In any event, the buyer ends up paying the total 20% shortfall in construction funding. 218 16: VC Results of Financing Simulation for Developer (in OTN) Low-income Market Within Area Outside Area Land Sharing $133,851 $142,501 $1,061 Debt/Equity Case 2--A2,B2 Debt Table Case 3--A2,B1 Debt Debt/Buyer $132,914 $141,565 $10,780 Case 4--A1,B1 Equity Debt/Buyer $141,699 $150,227 ($2,945) Case 5--A1,B2 Equity Debt/Equity $139,403 $148,046 ($14,935) The value added by different financing combinations is much greater for the land sharing scheme than for the relocation schemes. Among the relocation options, the added value due to financing produces a range of 8,000 OTN from the lowest value to the highest. On the other hand, the influence of financing in the land sharing case is strong. sharing option is 25,000 OTN. The range of values among the land The numbers illustrate that if debt financing is not obtained for the entire project, then the land sharing option is not viable, as represented by the negative VCs. The valued added by financing for the other options, however, does not affect their viability. There is a larger difference between the VCs of the various options than there is due to financing within any one option. The highest VC for the owner, under both relocation options, is the equity and debt/buyer financing combination. For the land sharing scheme the highest financing combination is the debt and debt/buyer combination. Two financing schemes were tested for the three parcel option. The bank would finance the entire project and the owner(B2) or the buyer (B1) would finance the shortfall during construction. (shown in diagram below) 219 Diagram 5 BANK IDEBT (B 1) BANK XDEBT (B2) 'WONER I EQUITY Table 17: VC Results of Financing Simulation for Developer (in OTN) Case 6--B2 Debt/Equity Case 7--B1 Debt/Buyer $100,517 $96,671 Under this STEP option, the highest VC for the developer is to have the owner and the bank finance the project. This analysis shows once again that there is a small difference in the VC due to the financing combination. From this analysis of the owner's VC , the different financing options do not appear to have significant impact on the final VC of the project. It is only in the Land Sharing Option with the use of bank and buyer financing that a substantial change in the owner's value is created. Thus one might conclude 220 The lender's VC must also be reviewed under the various options. The table below shows the VC for the various financing combinations. Table 18: Present Values for the Lender Financing Combinations (OTN) Within Area/ Land Sharing Three Parcel Outside Area Case 2&3 $17,229 $13,920 Debt: low & Market units Case 4&5 Debt: Market units $17,664 $11,573 Case 6&7 Debt: Low&Market units $21,320 The highest VC for the lender is the three parcel option. lower discount rate ind a shorter built-out period. the relocation options. This is due to the The next highest values are Both of these values are higher than the land sharing scheme due to the kicker component--the sale value of the market units is higher in the relocation scheme. Conclusions: This analysis has shown that for all the options the different means of financing, among the combinations tested, produce very small additions to the VC of either the lender or the owner for all the options except the land sharing option, i.e., land sharing is sensitive to financing combinations for both the owner and the lender. Therefore, other than the 221 the land sharing option, i.e., land sharing is sensitive to financing combinations for both the owner and the lender. Therefore, other than the land sharing option, the financing could be done in any of the ways. aforementioned financing within This analysis shows that there is flexibility in regard to each of the options, except for land sharing, thus depending on the owner's position, i.e whether or not he has cash, a deal can be structured without significant value changes in his VC, Table 19: Financing as well as the lender. The Highest VC for Each Option as a Function of (in OTN) Sharing Three Parcel Relocation outside Relocation within area Land (a) (b) 150,227 8,996 141,699 25,455 10,780 2,905 100,517 9,423 Lender 17,664 17,664 13,920 21,320 Owner Note: (a) This is the expected development VC for the owner (b) This is the expected negotiated VC for the owner Based on the VC criteria, the best option is the VC with the highest value, there is a discrepancy between the best option for the lender and the best option for the owner, i.e., Relocation within the area is the best for the owner yet the three parcel options is the highest VC for the lender. As stated in the text of chapter five, the relocation within the area is also the preferred option of the favelados and the government. In order to bring the option of the lender in line with the other preferences of the stakeholders, an increase in the interest rate or an increase in the participation rate would have to be arranged. 222 BIBLIOGRAPHY Agmon, Tamir, Donald R. Lessard and James L. Paddock. "Appropriate Financing for Petroleum Development in Developing Countries." The journal. 5. No. 3 (1984), pp. 27-40. de Almeida, Paulo Guilherme. Alves, Man6el A.L.R. Slo Paulo. Attorney. Architect. de Amberosis, Clementina D.A. Paulo. Interview on 25 July 1988. Energy Sio Paulo. Interviews on various dates July/August 1988. SEMPLA. Interview on 16 August 1988. Sao Angel, Shlomo and Somsook Boonyabancha. "Land Sharing as an Alternative to Eviction: The Bangkok Experience." Unpublished paper. May 1987. -------------. "Land Tenure for Urban Poor." Asian Institute of Technology. --------- and Yap Kioe Sheng. Preliminary Evaluation." "The Sengki Land-Sharing Project: Telephone A Report for United Nations Centre for Human Settlements (HABITAT), Nairobi, Kenya. ----------. The Human Settlements Division, Working Paper 1. interview. June de Azevedo Neto, Domingos Theodoro. August 1988. Slo Paulo. June 1988. 1988. Architect, SEMPLA. Bacow, Lawrence S. and Michael Wheeler. New York: Plenum Press, 1984. Environmental Interview on 11 Dispute Resolution. Blay, Eva Alterman. Eu N5o Tenho Onde Morar Vilas Operarias na Cidade de Sdo Paulo. Slo Paulo: Livraria Nobel S.A., 1985. Blitzer, Charles R., P.E. Cavoulacos, D.R. Lessard and J.L. Paddock. "An Analysis of Fiscal and Financial Impediments to Oil and Gas Exploration in Developing Countries." The Energy Journal. 6, Special Tax Issue (1985), pp. 59-72. Blitzer, Charles R., D.R. Lessard and J.L. Paddock. "Risk Bearing and The Choice of Contract Forms for Oil Exploration and Development." The Energy Journal. 5, No. 1 (1984), pp. 1-28. -------------- , P.E. Cavoulacos and J.L. Paddock. "Risk Bearing and Contract Design: Are Stable Contracts Feasible?" in K. Khan, ed. Petroleum Resources and Development: Economic, Legal and Policy Issues for Developing Countries. London: Belhaven Press, 1988. Brealey, Richard and Stewart Myers. Edition). New York: Principles of Corporate Finance (Second McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1984. 223 Campana, Isaura Regina Parente. Architect, SEMPLA. dates July/Augustl988. Sao Paulo. Interviews on various Campanario, Milton de Abreu. Land Rent and The Reproduction of Labor Force: Some Evidence from Sio Paulo. published dissertation. Cornell University, Graduate Field of City and Regional Planning, Ithaca, NY, 1981. Cardoso, Maria Cecilia. Architect, SEMPLA. July/August 1988. Sao Paulo. Carvalho, Isolda Paiva. Sao Paulo. Interview on various dates Municipal social worker. Interview on 17 August 1988, Cavoulacos, Panos. "Financial Evaluation of the Prinos/South Kavala Project in Greece." MIT Energy Laboratory Working Paper MIT-EL 82-063WP. Ceneviva, Laura. Architect, CDH. Interview on 11 August 1988. Sao Paulo. Centre for Development and Environmental Planning, Oxford Polytechnic. "Unregulated Urban Housing Submarkets in the Third World: A Review of the Literature." Unpublished document. December 1987. Cornejo, Ione Marisa K. Architect. Interviews on 2 and18 August 1988. Paulo. Cortin, Regina. CDH. Davies, David. Financial Analyst. Interview on 18 August 1988. Sao Sao Paulo. Interview on 26 July 1988. Sao Paulo. Devas, Nick. "Financing Urban Land -Development for Low Income Housing: An Analysis with Particular Reference to Jakarta, Indonesia." Third World Planning Review. 5, No. 3 (August 1983), pp. 209-226. Durand-Lasserve, Alain. "Land and Housing in Third World Cities: Are Public and Private Strategies Contradictory?" CITIES. (November 1986), pp. 325-338. Evans, Alan W. "The Determination of the Price of Land." Urban (1983), pp. 119-120. Fisher, Roger and William Ury. Without Giving In. New York: Froes, Marilda. Getting to Yes: Negotiating Agreement Penguin Books, 1981. Architect, EMURB. Gandra, Por Josd Rui. 1988., pp. 10-17. Studies. 20, Interview on 18 August 1988. "A Face Vertical do Alto de Pinheiros." Sao Paulo. Veia. April 6, 224 Gilbert, Alan. "Planning, Invasions and Land Speculation: The Role of the State in Venezuela." Third World Planning Review. 6, No. 1, (August 1984), pp. 225-238. Gonealves, Marcos Mendes. July/August 1988. Engineer, Imobras. Interviews on various dates Slo Paulo. Habitaglo em Ouestgo. Editores, 1979. ed. Licia do Prado Vallardes. Rio de Janeiro: Zahar Harrison, Fred. The Power in the Land: An Inquiry into the Unemployment. the Profits Crisis and Land Speculation. New York: Universe Books, 1983. Harvard Business School Case Services. "Diversification, The Capital Asset Pricing Model, and The Cost of Capital.". Harvard Business School Case Services. "Risk-Adjusted Discount Rates." Revised March 1984. Housing Needs and Policy Approaches: Trends in Thirteen Countries. Willen van Vliet et al. Durham: Duke University Press, 1985. ed. Jaffe, Austin J. and C. F. Sirmans. Real Estate Investment Decision Making. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1982. Land for Housing the Poor. 1983. ed. Shlomo Angel et al. Las, Cristina Ofelia. Architect, SEHAB. July/August 1988. Slo Paulo. Singapore: Interviews on various dates Lessard, Donald, Eugene Flood, Jr. and James L. Paddock. Corporate Finance. To be published. 1986. Lewicki, Roy J. and Joseph A. Litterer. 1985. Lima, Armilindo. Madeira, Arnaldo. 1988. Attorney. Negotiation. International Homewood, IL: Interview on 29 July 1988. Irwin, Sao Paulo. Vereador (City Council Member). Interviews on 4, 12 August Camera Municipal. Slo Paulo. "Making Housing Markets More Efficient." (November 1987), pp. 1-5. M~molo, Carlos. Select Books, The Urban Edge. 11, No. 9 President of "Sociadade dos Amigos do Bairro de Interview on 3 August 1988. Paraisopolis." Slo Paulo. Mendonga, Maria Betania Ferreira. Secretary of "Unilo de Moradores da Favela Paraisopolis." Interview on 27 July 1988. Slo Paulo. 225 Municipio de SAo Paulo. SEHAB. Paulo1987. April 1988. ---------------. EMURB. Censo das Favelas do Municipio de Sao "ReurbanizagIo Parais6polis." 1984. Municipio de Slo Paulo. EMURB. "Reurbanizagio Parais6polis: Estudo Preliminar, Informaq6es Gendricas, Introdugio ao Problema das Favelas na Area." July 1978. ---------------. EMURB. "ReurbanizagIo Parais6polis: Decis6es." August 1983. Subsfdios a Tomada de ---------------. SEMPLA. Operagoes Interligadas em Terrenos Piblicos: de Chamamento no. 1. 1988. Nogami, Monica. "An Attempt to Assess the Dynamics of a Participatory Process: The Heli6polis Integrated Housing Project." Institute for Housing Studies, Rotterdam, 1987. -----------. Edital CDH. Unpublished Interviews on various dates July/August 1988. paper. Sao Paulo. Oberlander, H. Peter. Land and Human Settlement Policy: A Review and Analysis of Selected Recent Policy Developments. Vancouver, BC: The Centre for Human Settlements, University of British Columbia, 1982. Oliveira, Celso N.E. Architect/Planner, Kellogg Foundation Fellow. on various dates, August-October 1988. Paddock, James L.. "Teaching Notes for 'Construction Finance."' Institute of- Technology. Paoliello, Arnaldo. Pfeiffer, Peter. Interviews Slo Paulo and Boston. Masachusetts Spring 1988. Architect. Interview on 27 July 1988. "Urbanizagio Sim, Remoglo Nunca! Slo Paulo. Politische, sozio- 6konomische und urbanistische Aspekte der Favelas und ihre Organisation in Rio de Janeiro: Entwicklung - Tendenzen - Perspektiven. "Unpublished thesis. Berlin: soziale 1987. Planning and Development International Collaborative. The Land and Housing Markets of Bangkok: Strategies for Public Sector Participation. (Volume 1: Final Report). 1987. Pruitt, Dean G. and Jeffrey Z. Rubin. Settlement. New York: Raiffa, Howard. Social Conflict: Escalation. Stalemate. and Random House, 1986. The Art and Science of Negotiation. Belknap Press of Harvard University, Cambridge, MA: The 1982. 226 Rocha Lima Jr. , Jolo. Professor responsivel da Area de gerenciamento na construego civil da Escola Politecnica da Universidade de Slo Paulo. Interview on 5 August 1988. Slo Paulo. ------------------. "Andlise do Beneffcio Gerado pela Legislaelo do Solo Criado." Unpublished paper. 1988. Sachs, Celine. "The Growth of Urban Squatter Settlements in Slo Paulo: A Study of the Perverse Effects of the State Housing Policies." Man and His Environment. 22, (1983), pp. 749-775. -------------. "Low Income Housing in Brazil: Public Policies and Peoples' Responses." Presented at International Symposium on Strategies for Slum and Squatter Upgrading in the Developing World. Berlin: November 1986. Santos, Alvaro Pereria. President of "Unigo de Moradores da Favela Paraisopolis." Interviews on 1 and 20 August 1988. Sao Paulo. S-o Paulo 1975: Crescimento e Pobreza. Slo Paulo: Ediedes Loyola, 1982. Saule Junior, Nelson. Assessor Juridicio da Bancada do PT (Workers' Party) na Assembleia Legislativa, Parte da Associae~o em Defesa da Moradia Sao Paulo. Telephone interview on 22 August 1988. Slo Paulo. Schnidman, Frank. 2-6. "Land Readjustment." Urban Land. (February 1988), pp. Secretaria Municipal da Famflia e Bem Estar Social - Butanti. Parais6polis: Relatorio Preliminar." August 1984. Shelter. Settlement. and Development. Unwin, 1987. ed. Lloyd Rodwin. Sullivan, Timothy J. Resolving Development New York: Plenum Press, 1984. "Favela Boston: Disputes Through Allen and Negotiations. Suplicy, Eduardo Matarazzo. "Income and Citizen's Right's Distribution." Presented at University of Tennessee Workshop on Income Distribution, 1988. ------------. Prof. of Economics, Escola de Administrae~o de Empresas de Sao Paulo, Fundaeio Gettilio Vargas. Interview on 11 August 1988. Sio Paulo. Susskind, Lawrence and Jeffrey Cruikshank. Breaking the Impasse: Consensual Approaches to Resolving Public Disputes. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1987. Tanaka, Marta. Paulo. Universidade de S~o Paulo. Interview on 5 August 1988. S5o 227 Taschner, Suzana Pasternak. Ano VI. 2, No. 18 (1986). "Favelas: Fatos e Politicas." Espago e Debates: Teixeira, Antonio. Director of HABI 1, Municipal Government. August 1988. Slo Paulo. Interview on 8 Trivelli, Pablo. "Access to Land By Urban Poor: An Overview of the Latin American Experience." Land Use Policy. (April 1986), pp. 101-121. The Urban Land Institute. "Downtown Linkages." Education Forum. New York: April 11, 1985. Presented at Policy Price Indices. Supply Measures. and Public Policy Urban Land Markets: Effects. ed. J. Thomas Black and James E. Hoben. Washington, D.C.: The Urban Land Institute, 1980. Urban Land Policy: Issues and Opportunities. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 1983. ed. Harold B. Dunkerley. London: The Estates Valuation and Investment Appraisal. Gazette Ltd., 1983. ed. Clive Darlow. Vasconcellos, Eliane J. Godoy de et al. Slo Paulo: Cortez Editoria, 1984. Terra de Habitaelo. Terra de Espoliag2o. "Low-Income Housing Policy for Development: Vetter, David Michael. Evaluation of the Brazilian Experience." Diss. UCLA 1977. The World Bank Annual Report 1987. An Washington, D.C. Architect, Assessor de Programaefo e Planejamento, Zaratin, Sergio. Interviews on various dates July/August 1988. S~o Paulo. EMPLASA. 228