Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy Simon Gilchrist∗ Egon Zakrajšek† May 6, 2010 Abstract We construct a new credit spread index, employing an extensive micro-level data set of secondary market prices of outstanding senior unsecured bonds over the 1973– 2009 period. Compared with the standard default-risk indicators such as the Baa-Aaa corporate bond spread and the paper-bill spread, our credit spread index is a robust predictor of future economic activity across a variety of economic indicators, sample periods, and forecast horizons. Using a flexible empirical bond-pricing framework, we decompose our credit spread index into a predictable component that captures the available firm-specific information on default risk and a residual component—the so-called excess bond premium. The results indicate that a substantial portion of the predictive content of our credit spread index for economic activity is attributable to the excess bond premium. Indeed, in the post-1985 period, the excess bond premium accounts for all of the predictive content of our credit spread index. Shocks to the excess bond premium that are orthogonal to current economic activity, the information contained in the term structure of interest rates, and news embedded in the stock market returns are shown to cause economically and statistically significant declines in consumption, investment, and output. Overall, our findings are consistent with the notion that an increase in the excess bond premium reflects a reduction in the risk appetite of the financial sector and, as a result, a contraction in the supply of credit, which has significant adverse consequences for economic outcomes. JEL Classification: E32, E44, G28 Keywords: corporate bond credit spreads, economic fluctuations, financial frictions Robert Kurtzman and Michael Levere provided outstanding research assistance. The views expressed in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of anyone else associated with the Federal Reserve System. ∗ Department of Economics Boston University and NBER. E-mail: sgilchri@bu.edu † Division of Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board. E-mail: egon.zakrajsek@frb.gov 1 Introduction The United States is in the process of emerging from the throes of an acute liquidity and credit crunch, by all accounts, the most severe financial crisis since the Great Depression. At the height of the crisis in the autumn of 2008, the government, in an attempt to prevent the financial meltdown from engulfing the real economy, effectively assumed control of a number of systemically important financial institution; the Congress, faced with investors’ rapidly deteriorating confidence in the financial sector, approved the plan to inject a massive amount of capital into the banking system; and the Federal Reserve dramatically expanded the number of emergency credit and liquidity facilities in an attempt to support the functioning of private debt markets. Throughout this period of extreme financial turmoil, credit spreads—the difference in yields between various private debt instruments and government securities of comparable maturity—served as a crucial gauge of the degree of strains in the financial system. In addition, movements in credit spreads were thought to contain important signals regarding the evolution of the real economy and risks to the economic outlook.1 This focus on credit spreads is motivated, in part, by financial theories that depart from the Modigliani and Miller [1958] paradigm of frictionless financial markets, theories that emphasize linkages between the quality of borrowers’ balance sheets and their access to external finance. Movements in credit spreads may also reflect shifts in the effective supply of funds offered by financial intermediaries, which, in the presence of financial market frictions, have important implication for the usefulness of credit spreads as predictors of future economic activity. In this interpretation, a deterioration in the balance sheets of financial intermediaries leads to a reduction in the supply of credit, causing an increase in the effective cost of external funds—the widening of credit spreads—and a subsequent reduction in spending and production. In either case, credit spreads play a crucial role in the dynamic interaction of financial conditions with the real economy. In this paper, we re-examine and reconsider the evidence on the relationship between credit spreads on corporate bonds and economic activity. We extend the standard empirical analysis by attempting to separate the predictive content of such default-risk indicators for economic activity into two components: a component capturing the usual countercyclical movements in expected defaults; and a component representing the cyclical changes in the relationship between expected default risk and credit spreads. Our approach builds on the recent work of Gilchrist, Yankov, and Zakrajšek [2009] (GYZ hereafter), in that we use prices 1 The predictive content of various credit spreads for future economic activity has been analyzed by Bernanke [1990]; Friedman and Kuttner [1992, 1998]; Emery [1999]; Gertler and Lown [1999]; Mody and Taylor [2004]; King, Levin, and Perli [2007]; Mueller [2007]; Gilchrist, Yankov, and Zakrajšek [2009]; and Faust, Wright, Gilchrist, and Zakrajšek [2010]. 1 of individual corporate securities traded in the secondary market to construct a credit spread index with a high information content for future economic activity. Our forecasting results indicate that the predictive content of this credit spread for various measures of economic activity significantly exceeds that of widely-used financial indicators such as the standard Baa-Aaa corporate credit spread and indicators of the stance of monetary policy such as the shape of the yield curve or the real federal funds rate. However, as shown recently by Philippon [2009], the predictive content of credit spreads for economic activity could reflect—absent any financial market frictions—the ability of the corporate bond market to signal more accurately than the stock market a decline in economic fundamentals resulting from a reduction in the expected present-value of corporate cash flows prior to a cyclical downturn.2 To address this thorny identification issue, we decompose our high-information content credit spread index into a component that captures expected default risk and other observable pricing factors and a residual component that reflects a premium in the bond market. We then examine the extent to which the forecasting power of credit spreads is due to the measurable default component or the excess bond premium. According to our analysis, a substantial portion of the information content of default-risk indicators can be attributed to the deviations in the pricing of corporate debt instruments relative to the expected default risk of the underlying issuer. This finding indicates that information about impending financial disruptions embedded in prices of corporate bonds may account for a significant portion of the forecasting power of credit spreads for economic activity. Using an identified vector autoregression (VAR) framework, we also analyze the dynamic interaction between the real economy, the stock market, and the excess bond premium. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the construction of our high-information content credit spread index. In Section 3, we compare the forecasting power of the GZ index to that of some standard financial indicators. In Section 4, we describe the methodology for decomposing credit spreads into a predicted component due to expected defaults and a residual component—the so-called excess bond premium. In Section 5, we evaluate the relative predictive ability of the default component and the excess bond premium for various measures of economic activity; we also analyze the effect of financial shocks—identified by orthogonalized movements in the excess bond premium—on the macroeconomy. Section 6 concludes. 2 The information content of the stock market for future economic activity has been analyzed by Fama [1981] and Harvey [1989]. 2 2 Data Sources and Methods Yield spreads on corporate debt instruments have long been used to gauge the degree of strains in the financial system. Moreover, because financial asset prices are forward looking, movements in corporate credit spreads have been shown to be particularly useful for forecasting economic activity. Despite considerable empirical success, results from this strand of research are often sensitive to the choice of a credit spread index under consideration, as credit spreads that contained useful information about macroeconomic outcomes in the past often lose their predictive power for the subsequent cyclical downturn.3 These mixed results are partly attributable to the rapid pace of financial innovation that likely alters the forecasting power of financial asset prices over time or results in one-off developments that may account for most of the forecasting power of a given credit spread index. In part to address these problems, GYZ utilized secondary market prices of individual senior unsecured corporate debt issues to construct a broad array of corporate bond spread indexes that vary across maturity and default risk. Compared with other corporate financial instruments, senior unsecured bonds represent a class of securities with a long history containing a number of business cycles, and the rapid pace of financial innovation over the past two decades has done little to alter the basic structure of these securities. Thus, the information content of spreads constructed from yields on senior unsecured corporate bonds is likely to provide more consistent signals regarding economic outcomes relative to spreads based on securities with a shorter history or securities whose structure or the relevant market has undergone a significant structural change. The results of GYZ confirm this: At forecast horizons associated with business cycle fluctuations, the predictive ability of their credit spreads significantly exceeds—both in-sample and out-of-sample—that of the commonly-used default-risk indicators, such as the paper-bill spread or the Baa and the high-yield corporate credit spread indexes. In this paper, we employ the same “bottom-up” approach. In particular, for a sample of U.S. nonfinancial firms, month-end secondary market prices of their outstanding securities were obtained from the Lehman/Warga (LW) and Merrill Lynch (ML) databases.4 To 3 For example, the spread of yields between nonfinancial commercial paper and comparable-maturity Treasury bills—the so-called paper-bill spread—has lost much of its forecasting power since the early 1990s. Indeed, according to Thoma and Gray [1998] and Emery [1999], the predictive content of the paper-bill spread may have reflected a one-time event. Similarly, yield spreads based on indexes of high-yield corporate bonds, which contain information from markets that were not in existence prior to the mid-1980s, have done particularly well at forecasting output growth during the previous decade, according to Gertler and Lown [1999] and Mody and Taylor [2004]. Stock and Watson [2003], however, find mixed evidence for the high-yield spread as a leading indicator during this period, largely because it falsely predicted an economic downturn in the autumn of 1998. 4 These two data sources include secondary market prices for a majority of dollar-denominated bonds publicly issued in the U.S. corporate cash market. The ML database is a proprietary data source of daily bond prices that starts in 1997. Focused on the most liquid securities in the secondary market, bonds in the 3 ensure that we are measuring long-term borrowing costs of different firms at the same point in their capital structure, we limited our sample to senior unsecured issues only. For the securities carrying the senior unsecured label and with market prices in both the LW and LM databases, we spliced their month-end prices across the two data sources. To calculate credit spreads, we constructed for each individual corporate issue a corresponding risk-free security that mimics exactly the cash-flows of the corresponding corporate debt instrument. In particular, consider a corporate bond k issued by firm i that at time t is promising a sequence of cash-flows {C(s) : s = 1, 2, . . . , S}, consisting of the regular coupon payments and the repayment of the principle at maturity. The price of this bond is given by Pit [k] = S X C(s)D(ts ), s=1 where D(t) = e−rt t is the discount function in period t. To calculate the price of a corresponding risk-free security—denoted by Ptf [k]—we discounted the cash-flow sequence {C(s) : s = 1, 2, . . . , S} using continuously-compounded zero-coupon Treasury yields in period t, obtained from the daily estimates of the U.S. Treasury yield curve reported by Gürkaynak, Sack, and Wright [2007]. The resulting price Ptf [k] can then be used to calculate the yield—denoted by ytf [k]—of a hypothetical Treasury security with exactly the same cash-flows as the underlying corporate bond. The credit spread sit [k] = yit [k] − ytf [k], where yit [k] denotes the yield of the corporate bond k, is thus free of the “duration mismatch” that would occur were the spreads computed simply by matching the corporate yield to the estimated yield of a zero-coupon Treasury security of the same maturity.5 Table 1 contains summary statistics for the key characteristics of bonds in our sample. Note that a typical firm has only a few senior unsecured issues outstanding at any point in time—the median firm, for example, has two such issues trading at any given month. This distribution, however, exhibits a significant positive skew, as some firms can have as many as 74 different senior unsecured bond issues trading in the market at a point in time. The distribution of the real market values of these issues is similarly skewed, with the range running from $1.2 million to more than $5.6 billion. Not surprisingly, the maturity of these debt instruments is fairly long, with the average maturity at issue of about 13 years. ML database must have a remaining term-to-maturity of at least two years, a fixed coupon schedule, and a minimum amount outstanding of $100 million for below investment-grade and $150 million for investmentgrade issuers. By contrast, the LW database of month-end bond prices has a somewhat broader coverage and is available from 1973 through mid-1998 (see Warga [1991] for details). 5 To mitigate the effect of outliers on our analysis, we eliminated all observations with credit spreads below 5 basis points and with spreads greater than 3,500 basis points. We also eliminated a small number of putable bonds from our sample. These selection criteria yielded a sample of 5,269 individual securities between January 1973 and December 2009. We matched these corporate securities with their issuer’s quarterly and annual income and balance sheet data from Compustat and daily data on equity valuations from CRSP, yielding a matched sample of 944 firms. 4 Because corporate bonds typically generate significant cash flow in the form of regular coupon payments, the effective duration is considerably shorter, with both the average and the median duration of about 6 years. According to the S&P credit ratings, our sample spans the entire spectrum of credit quality, from “single D” to “triple A.” At “BBB1,” however, the median bond/month observation is still solidly in the investment-grade category. Turning to returns, the (nominal) coupon rate on these bonds averaged 7.31 percent during our sample period, while the average total nominal return, as measured by the nominal effective yield, was 7.82 percent per annum. Reflecting the wide range of credit quality, the distribution of nominal yields is quite wide, with the minimum of 0.66 percent and the maximum of more than 44 percent. Relative to Treasuries, an average bond in our sample generated a return of about 202 basis points above the comparable risk-free rate, with the standard deviation of 284 basis points. Figure 1 shows the average credit spread (GZ spread) for our sample of bonds at each point in time; it also displays two widely used default-risk indicators: the yield spread between 1-month A1/P1-rated nonfinancial commercial paper and the 1-month Treasury yield (i.e., the paper-bill spread); and the spread between yields on indexes of Baa- and Aaa-rated seasoned industrial corporate bonds (i.e., Baa-Aaa spread).6 All three credit spreads exhibit pronounced countercyclical movements, rising prior to and during economic downturns. Nonetheless, the pair-wise correlations between the three series are fairly small: The correlation between the paper-bill and the Baa-Aaa spread is 0.22, whereas the correlation between the paper-bill spread and the GZ credit spread is only 0.09. Perhaps not too surprising, the highest correlation, 0.36, is between the two corporate bond credit spread indexes. With regards to variability, the Baa-Aaa spread is the least volatile with a standard deviation of about 50 basis points. In contrast, the volatility of the paper-bill and the GZ spread, at about 67 basis points, is somewhat higher.7 6 Other than than the GZ spread, all yields are taken from the “Selected Interest Rates” (H.15) statistical release published by the Federal Reserve Board. Note that the GZ credit spread is measured relative to Treasury yields, whereas the Baa-Aaa spread is defined as the difference between yields on long-term corporate debt instruments of varying credit quality. As emphasized by Duffee [1998], for example, the corporate-Treasury yield spreads can be influenced significantly by time-varying prepayment risk premiums, reflecting the call provisions on corporate issues. According to Duca [1999], corporate bond spread indexes measured relative to the yield on Aaa-rated bonds are more reflective of default risk than those measured relative to comparable-maturity Treasuries. 7 A significant portion of the volatility in the paper-bill spread reflects year-end funding pressures. These pressures can arise as the maturity of the paper crosses over year-end, and investors demand a premium to hold paper—especially lower-rated paper—over the turn of the year. Trends in business sector credit quality and the amount of outstanding commercial paper are important determinants of year-end pressures. 5 3 Credit Spreads and Economic Activity This section examines the predictive power of the GZ credit spread for various measures of economic activity and compares its forecasting performance with that of several commonly used financial indicators. Letting Yt denote a measure of economic activity—in logarithms if necessary—in period t, we define h ∇ Yt+h c ≡ h Yt+h Yt , where h denotes the forecast horizon and c is a scaling constant, with c = 1, 200 in the case of monthly data and c = 400 in the case of quarterly data. We estimate the following univariate forecasting specification: h ∇ Yt+h = α + p X i=0 βi ∇Yt−i + γ1 TSt3M −10Y + γ2 RFFt + γ3 CSt + ǫt+h , (1) where TSt3M −10Y denotes the “term spread”—that is, the slope of the Treasury yield curve, defined as the difference between the three-month constant-maturity Treasury yield and the 10-year constant-maturity yield;8 RFFt denotes the real federal funds rate;9 CSt denotes a credit spread; and ǫt+h is the forecast error. The forecasting regression given by equation 1 is estimated using OLS, and the MA(h − 1) structure of the error term induced by overlap- ping observations is taken into account by computing the covariance matrix of regression coefficients according to Hodrick [1992].10 Within this forecasting framework, we analyze the predictive content of financial asset 8 The role of the term spread in forecasting economic growth or for assessing the near-term risk of recession has been analyzed by Dotsey [1998], Estrella and Hardouvelis [1991], Estrella and Mishkin [1998], and Hamilton and Kim [2002]. More recent work on this topic includes Ang, Piazzesi, and Wei [2006] and Wright [2006]. 9 In calculating the real federal funds rate, we employed a simplifying assumption that the expected inflation is equal to lagged core PCE inflation. Specifically, real funds rate in period t is defined as the average effective federal funds rate during period t less realized inflation, where realized inflation is given by the log-difference between the core PCE price index in period t − 1 and its lagged value a year earlier. Of course, under the expectations hypothesis—and neglecting term premiums—the term spread is an indicator of the stance of monetary policy—the higher the term spread, the more restrictive is the current stance of monetary policy and, hence, the more likely is economy to decelerate in subsequent quarters. In general, however, the shape of the yield curve contains information about term premiums and the average of expected future short-term interest rates over a relatively long horizon. As emphasized by Hamilton and Kim [2002] and Ang et al. [2006], the term premium and expectations hypothesis components of the term spread have very different correlations with future economic growth. The federal funds rate, in contrast, is a measure of the stance of monetary policy that is relatively unadulterated by the effects of time-varying term premiums. 10 In a recent paper, Ang and Bekaert [2007] undertook a systematic comparison of various HAC estimators of standard errors in the context of overlapping observations. According to their findings, the use of Newey and West [1987] standard errors leads to severe over-rejections of the null hypothesis of no predictability, whereas the standard errors developed by Hodrick [1992] retain the correct size even in relatively small samples. That said, all of our results were robust to the choice of Newey-West or Hodrick standard errors. 6 prices for several categories of economic activity indicators. First, we examine the forecasting ability of financial indicators for changes in monthly economic indicators related to labor market conditions: the growth of private (nonfarm) payroll employment and the change in the (civilian) unemployment rate. Given the lagging nature of labor market indicators, we also consider a coincident economic indicator, the growth in manufacturing industrial production. Using quarterly data, we also consider the broadest measures of economic activity, namely the growth rate of real GDP. Our first set of forecasting results utilizes data over the entire sample period (1973–2009). In light of the well-documented decline in macroeconomic volatility since the mid-1980s, we also examine the predictive power of these financial indicators for economic activity over the post-1984 period, the so-called “Great Moderation.” 3.1 Forecasting Results: 1973–2009 The results in Table 2 detail the predictive power of various financial indicators for the growth rate of the three monthly economic indicators over the full sample period. The top panel of the table reports baseline results, which include as predictors the lagged growth rates of the variable to be forecasted, along with the term spread and the real federal funds rate. Consistent with previous findings, the term spread provides significant predictive content for all three monthly indicators at both the 3- and 12-month horizons. The real funds rate provides additional predictive content for employment growth and the change in the unemployment rate at both forecast horizons but does not add significant explanatory power to the regression for growth in industrial production. The next panels of Table 2 report results from adding the various credit indexes to this baseline regression. Relative to the baseline, the paper-bill spread adds explanatory power for all three economic indicators at the 3-month horizon and to the unemployment and IP growth regressions at the year-ahead horizon. The improvement in in-sample goodness of fit as measured by the adjusted R2 is relatively modest however. At the 3-month horizon, the Baa-Aaa spread adds significant explanatory power only in the regression for the changes in the unemployment rate. At the 12-month horizon, the Baa-Aaa spread adds significant explanatory power for the growth in employment but not the other two monthly indicators. Moreover, conditional on the term-spread, a rise in the Baa-Aaa spread predicts an increase in employment growth over the subsequent year, a finding that highlights the the capricious nature of signals obtained from the Baa-Aaa credit spread regarding the course of future economic activity. In contrast to the forecast results obtained for standard credit spread indexes, the GZ credit spread is highly statistically significant at both the 3-month and 12-month horizons for all three monthly economic indicators. Moreover, the coefficients estimates imply a 7 robust economically significant negative relationship between credit spreads and real economic activity. For example, a one standard deviation increase in the GZ credit spread predicts a 0.25 percentage point reduction in employment, a 0.32 percentage point increase in unemployment and a 0.36 percentage point drop in the growth of industrial production at the 1-month horizon. In addition, the gains in the goodness-of-fit obtained by adding the GZ credit spread to the baseline regression are substantial. This is especially true at the 12-month horizon, where the addition of the GZ credit spread results in an increase in the adjusted R2 from 0.43 to 0.59 for employment growth and from 0.23 to 0.38 for the growth in industrial production. Table 3 examines the predictive content of these financial indicators for the growth of real GDP. Here we report results for the 1-, 2-, and 4-quarter forecast horizons. According to the baseline specification, the shape of the yield curve contains substantial predictive power for the growth in real output at the 2- and 4-quarter horizons, whereas the current stance of monetary policy—as measured by the real federal funds rate—has no marginal predictive content. The standard Baa-Aaa credit spread index and the paper-bill spread also have no marginal predictive power for real GDP growth at any horizon. Similar to the findings reported for the monthly indicators of economic activity, the GZ credit spread is, economically and statistically, a highly significant predictor of real GDP growth at all three forecasting horizons. For example, a one standard deviation widening in the GZ credit spread implies a 0.36 percentage point drop in economic growth over the subsequent four quarters. 3.2 Forecasting Results: 1985–2009 As a robustness check, this section repeats the in-sample forecasting exercise for the Great Moderation period, namely from 1985:Q1 onward. Although no clear consensus has emerged regarding the dominant cause(s) of the decline in macroeconomic volatility since the mid1980s, changes in the conduct of monetary policy appear to be at least partly responsible for the significantly diminished variability of both output and inflation over the past two decades; see, for example, Clarida, Galı́, and Gertler [2000] and Stock and Watson [2002]. Because monetary policy affects the real economy by influencing financial asset prices, the change in the monetary policy regime may have also altered the predictive content of various financial indicators for economic activity. Moreover, as emphasized by Dynan, Elmendorf, and Sichel [2006], the rapid pace of financial innovation since the mid-1980s—namely, the deepening and emergence of lending practices and credit markets that have enhanced the ability of households and firms to borrow and changes in government policy such as the demise of Regulation Q—may have also changed the information content of financial asset 8 prices for macroeconomic outcomes.11 Table 4 contains forecasting results for the growth in real GDP over the 1985–2009 period. As evidenced by the entries in these tables, the GZ credit spread continues to provide significant information for real GDP growth at the 1-, 2-, and 4-quarter horizons. Indeed, the estimated coefficients on the credit spread are very similar in magnitude to those reported in Table 3. As to be expected given the smaller sample size, the associated confidence intervals are somewhat larger compared with those estimated over the full sample period. All told, forecasting results using the GZ credit spread appear to be highly robust across sample periods. Using data for the 1985–2009 subsample, the paper-bill spread and the Baa-Aaa spread now provide significant predictive content for GDP growth. This contrasts with the full sample results where neither index provided additional explanatory power. The explanatory power of the paper-bill spread is strongest at the 1-quarter horizon, while the explanatory power of the Baa-Aaa credit spread is strongest at the year-ahead horizon. In all cases, the coefficients on these credit spread indexes have increased relative to the full sample results. This finding is mainly attributable to the rise in all credit spreads during the current economic crisis, however. Although not reported, estimates over the 1985–2007 period imply similar results to the full sample estimates—that is, neither the paper-bill nor the Baa-Aaa spread provide predictive content for GDP growth unless one uses a relatively short sample that includes the most recent financial crisis. All told, these results are consistent with those reported by GYZ for the 1990–2008 period: Credit market conditions as measured by the GZ credit spread index hold substantial information content for leading, coincident, and lagging economic indicators. Moreover, in contrast to forecasting results using either the paper-bill spread or the Baa-Aaa spread, forecasting results using the GZ index appear to be remarkably stable across the full sample versus the post-1985 period. 4 The Excess Bond Premium The above results imply that the GZ credit spread index constructed as a series of the crosssectional average of properly constructed credit spreads of individual bond issues provides substantial predictive content for economic activity. As emphasized by Philippon [2009], 11 Although a full formal investigation of potential parameter instability is beyond the scope of this paper, we tested for time variation in the coefficients associated with financial indicators in the forecasting equation 1, using the methodology proposed by Elliott and Müller [2006]. These tests do not reject—even at the 10 percent level—the null hypothesis of fixed regression coefficients on financial indicators for all specifications reported in Tables 2 and 3. This limited evidence suggests a stable relationship between our set of financial indicators and changes in labor market conditions, the growth in industrial output, inventories, and the growth in real GDP. 9 corporate bond spreads may predict future economic activity if such spreads reflect changes in expected default risk owing to lower expected future cash flows. This result would be true even in environments where there is no significant frictions in the financial markets. In addition, in an environment where financial frictions have real economic consequences, disruptions in financial markets may cause corporate bond spreads to widen relative to the change implied by movements in expected default risk. To the extent that these disruptions in financial markets have a causal influence on economic activity, movements in corporate bond spreads that are unrelated to expected default risk may also predict future economic outcomes. In this section, we exploit the panel aspect of our underlying data set to decompose the GZ credit spread index into a component that is related to systematic movements in expected default risk and a residual component that we label the excess bond premium. We then examine the extent to which the ability of the GZ credit spread to forecast economic activity can be accounted for by the default component versus the excess bond premium. More concretely, our methodology considers a standard bond pricing framework, where the log of the credit spread on bond k at time t, ln Sit [k], is related to a firm-specific measure of expected default (DFit ), additional bond-specific controls Xit [k], and a residual component εit [k]: ln Sit [k] = α + βDFit + γXit [k] + ǫit [k]. This regression is estimated using a standard OLS procedure. Given the estimated parameter vector (α̂, β̂, γ̂, σ̂ǫ ), we then obtain the predicted component for the level of the spread of bond k of firm i at time t using: Sitp [k] = exp α̂ + β̂DFit + γ̂Xit [k] + 0.5σ̂ǫ2 . Aggregating across bonds at time t, we can define the realized average spread and its predicted component as: St = X Sit [k] X Sitp [k]. i,k Stp = i,k The excess bond premium is then defined by the linear decomposition: St = Stp + EBPt Within this framework we are interested in determining the extent to which the forecasting power of St documented in the previous section is due to variation in the default component, 10 Stp , versus the excess bond premium, EBPt . We now discuss in more detail the variables that serve as proxies for the default risk and other controls. We then turn to the estimation results. 4.1 Distance to Default: To measure a firm’s probability of default at each point in time, we employ the “distanceto-default” (DD) framework developed in the seminal work of Merton [1973, 1974]. The key insight of this contingent claims approach to corporate credit risk is that the equity of the firm can be viewed as a call option on the underlying value of the firm with a strike price equal to the face value of the firm’s debt. Although neither the underlying value of the firm nor its volatility can be directly observed, they can, under the assumptions of the model, be inferred from the value of the firm’s equity, the volatility of its equity, and the firm’s observed capital structure. The first critical assumption underlying the DD-framework is that the total value of the a firm—denoted by V —follows a geometric Brownian motion: dV = µV V dt + σV V dW, (2) where µV denotes the expected continuously compounded return on V ; σV is the volatility of firm value; and dW is an increment of the standard Weiner process. The second critical assumption pertains to the firm’s capital structure. In particular, it is assumed that the firm has just issued a single discount bond in the amount D that will mature in T periods.12 Together, these two assumption imply that the value of the firm’s equity E can be viewed as a call option on the underlying value of the firm V with a strike price equal to the face value of the firm’s debt D and a time-to-maturity of T . According to the Black-Scholes-Merton option-pricing framework, the value of the firm’s equity then satisfies: E = V Φ(δ1 ) − e−rT DΦ(δ2 ), (3) where r denotes the instantaneous risk-free interest rate, Φ(·) is the cumulative standard normal distribution function, and δ1 = ln(V /D) + (r + 0.5σV2 )T √ σV2 T 12 and δ2 = δ1 − σV √ T. Recent structural default models relax this assumption and allow for endogenous capital structure as well as for strategic default. In these models, both the default time and default boundary are determined endogenously and depend on firm-specific as well as aggregate factors; the voluminous literature on structural default models is summarized by Duffie and Singleton [2003]; Lando [2004] contains an excellent practical exposition of the contingent claims approach to corporate credit risk. 11 According to equation 3, the value of the firm’s equity depends on the total value of the firm and time, a relationship that also underpins the link between volatility of the firm’s value σV and the volatility of its equity σE . In particular, it follows from Ito’s lemma that V ∂E σV . σE = E ∂V Because under the Black-Scholes-Merton option-pricing framework (4) ∂E ∂V = Φ(δ1 ), the rela- tionship between the volatility of the firm’s value and the volatility of its equity is given by V Φ(δ1 )σV . σE = E (5) From an operational standpoint, the most critical inputs to the Merton DD-model are clearly the market value of the equity E, the face value of the debt D, and the volatility of equity σE . Assuming a forecasting horizon of one year (T = 1), we implement the model in two steps: First, we estimate σE from historical daily stock returns. Second, we assume that the face value of the firm’s debt D is equal to the sum of the firm’s current liabilities and one-half of its long-term liabilities.13 Using the observed values of E, D, σE , and r (i.e., the 1-year constant-maturity Treasury yield), equations 3 and 5 can be solved for V and σV using standard numerical techniques. However, as pointed out by Crosbie and Bohn [2003] and Vassalou and Xing [2004], the excessive volatility of market leverage (V /E) in equation 5 causes large swings in the estimated volatility of the firm’s value σV , which are difficult to reconcile with the observed frequency of defaults and movements in financial asset prices. To resolve this problem, we implement an iterative procedure recently proposed by Bharath and Shumway [2008]. The procedure involves the following steps: First, we initialize the procedure by letting σV = σE [D/(E + D)]. We then use this value of σV in equation 3 to infer the market value of the firm’s assets V for every day of the previous year. In the second step, we calculate the implied daily log-return on assets (i.e., ∆ ln V ) and use the resulting series to generate new estimates of σV and µV . We then iterate on σV until convergence. The resulting solutions of the Merton DD-model can be used to calculate the firm-specific distance-to-default over the one-year horizon as DD = ln(V /D) + (µV − 0.5σV2 ) . σV 13 (6) This assumption for the “default point” is also used MKMV in the construction of their Expected Default Frequencies (EDFs) based on the Merton DD-model, and it captures the notion that short-term debt requires a repayment of the principal relatively soon, whereas long-term debt requires the firm to meet only the coupon payments. Both current and long-term liabilities are taken from quarterly Compustat files and interpolated to daily frequency using a step function. 12 The corresponding implied probability of default—the so-called EDF—is given by ln(V /D) + (µV − 0.5σV2 ) = Φ(−DD), EDF = Φ − σV (7) which, under the assumptions of the Merton model, should be a sufficient statistic for predicting defaults.14 To assess the relevance of the Merton model for the pricing of corporate bonds, Figure 2 plots the median distance to default along with the inter-quartile range for the firms in our sample over the 1973–2009 time period. The firms in our sample all have senior unsecured debt outstanding that can be matched to the Lehman-Warga/Merill-Lynch bond pricing data. As a point of comparison, this figure also plots the median distance to default for the entire set of nonfinancial firms for which distance to default is available (i.e., firms that are reported on CRSP and can be matched to Compustat to obtain information on their liability structure). For both our sample and the full sample of nonfinancial firms, distance to default is strongly pro-cyclical, implying that expected default rises in recessions. On average, the firms in our sample have a higher distance to default than the full sample. This reflects the fact that firms with senior unsecured debt are on average higher-quality firms. In the current financial crisis, distance to default reached its lowest point in the sample period. Thus, according to this measure, default risk rose substantially during the crisis. The insights of the Merton model are regularly used by industry practitioners to provide information on expected default. Notably, MKMV provides explicit estimates of expected default using a semi-parametric mapping between a modified distance to default measure and realized defaults. The MKMV year-ahead expected default frequency (EDFit ) for firm i at time t is available for our sample of firms over the 1990–2009 period. Figure 3 plots the log of the EDF against the distance to default measure that we have constructed. Although there is a clear systematic relationship, there is substantial variation between the two measures. Thus, when decomposing credit spread movements into a default component versus a residual component, it is natural to start with a direct comparison of MKMV’s EDFit and the distance-to-default measure, DDit described above. Table 5 reports the results of this comparison. As discussed above, the dependent variable is the log of the credit spread for issue k of firm i at time t which is regressed on the default measure (either EDFit or DDit ), along with control variables that capture bondspecific characteristics that could influence bond yields through either liquidity or term premiums, including the bond’s duration (DURt [k]); the amount outstanding (PARt [k]); the bond’s (fixed) coupon rate (COUP[k]); and an indicator variable that equals one if the 14 Note that, even if the EDF is not a sufficient statistic for predicting defaults, DD may still be a good indicator for ranking firms into different categories of risk. Indeed, that is essentially the operational philosophy used by MKMV when constructing their EDFs; see Crosbie and Bohn [2003] for a complete discussion. 13 bond is callable and zero otherwise (CALL[k]). The equation is estimated over the sample period from February 1990 to December 2009 by OLS. The first two columns of table report baseline results. In both cases, the default measure is a highly statistically significant predictor of the logarithm of the credit spread. According to the entries in the first rows of columns 1a and 1b, a 10 percent increase in the expected default frequency implies about a 1 percent increase in the credit spread. The estimate is slightly higher when using distance to default rather than MKMV’s expected default frequency as a measure of default risk. In the baseline equation, the distance to default measure provides a substantially higher R2 however—0.524 when estimated using DDit relative to 0.420 when estimated using EDFit as the proxy for default risk. The next two columns add bond rating dummy variables to this regression. The bond rating dummy variables are highly statistically significant and the R2 improves substantially. Nonetheless, both default measures still provide important explanatory power, although not surprisingly, the coefficients fall with the introduction of the bond-rating dummy variables. Finally, the last two columns allow for a nonlinear effect of the default measure by including a quadratic term. Consistent with the nonlinear relationship between credit spreads and leverage documented by Levin, Natalucci, and Zakrajšek [2004], the quadratic terms are highly statistically significant. Again, the regression results imply that using distance to default rather than expected default frequency provides a better overall fit to the bond pricing equation. The above set of results imply that the distance-to-default measure provides as good if not a better proxy of default risk for bond pricing equations than the widely used expected default frequency constructed by MKMV. We now turn to estimation results over the full sample period when only the distance to default measure is available as a proxy for default risk. The Merton model implies that distance to default is a sufficient statistic for the credit spread. In particular, movements in risk free rates only influence the credit spread to the extent that they changes expected future cash flows and hence distance to default. To the extent that corporate bonds are callable, interest rate movements have a direct effect on credit spreads however. In particular, as interest rates rise, the call option becomes more valuable and the price response of callable bonds is muted relative to the price response of non-callable bonds. As a result, a rise in interest rates reduces the credit spread for callable bonds relative to non-callable bonds. In addition, callable bonds are more sensitive to interest rate volatility owing to their embedded options. Similarly, to the extent that callable bonds have an effectively lower duration, they may be less sensitive to default risk. One way to deal with this issue would be to confine the analysis to a sub-sample of noncallable bonds. As shown in Figure 4, the fraction of callable bonds in our sample varies over 14 time, with nearly 100 percent of bonds having call options prior to 1982 and the fraction falling to less than 30 percent by 1994 before returning to roughly 90 percent by then end of the sample period. Thus, confining the analysis to non-callable bonds would result in a substantially reduced sample especially during the current crisis period. As an alternative, we follow Duffee [1998] and control for the effects of interest rates and interest rate volatility directly by including a call option dummy variable interacted with three standard interest rate factors that capture the level, slope, and curvature of the Treasury yield curve. We also interact the call option dummy with the realized volatility of the 10-year Treasury yield, and the firm-specific measure of the distance to default. The results of this regression exercise are reported in Table 6. The first two columns of the table report estimation results for the full-sample period (1973–2009) that are comparable to those reported in column 3b of Table 5 for the 1990–2009 subsample. The coefficient values on the distance to default variables are virtually identical and the overall fit of the regression is highly comparable across the two estimation periods. The second two columns of Table 6 report results from the regression that allows for the call-option dummy interacted with the interest rate factors and distance to default. Consistent with theoretical predictions, the call option attenuates the effect of interest rate movements on bond prices. As a result, the credit spreads of callable bonds fall as interest rates rise. The effect of distance to default is similarly mitigated by the call-option mechanism. Also consistent with theory, increased interest rate volatility raises the callable bond spreads relative to the non-callable bond spreads. Table 7 translates the implications of the coefficients obtained from this log specification into economic impact of variation in the interest rate factors and default risk for the level of the credit spread. Both the level of interest rates and the interest rate volatility have a quantitatively important effect on credit spreads for callable bonds. A 1 standard deviation increase in the level of interest rates implies a 60 basis point reduction in the credit spread for callable bonds. A 1 standard deviation increase in the realized volatility of the 10-year Treasury yield implies a 29 basis point rise in the credit spread of callable bonds. The attenuation effect also applies to default risk—a 1 standard deviation increase in distance to default implies a 35 basis point rise in the default probability. For non-callable bonds this increase in default risk implies a 20 basis point increase in credit spreads whereas for callable bonds, credit spreads rise by only 15 basis points in response. The distance to default measure is composed of several components: the log of leverage, the return on assets, and the volatility of asset returns. In the previous regression, these terms are constrained to enter the credit spread regression through their effect on distance to default. To the extent that distance to default is not a sufficient statistic for firm-specific default risk, these terms may have independent influences that should be accounted for when 15 fitting the bond pricing equation. Thus, our final and most general specification allows for these individual components of the distance to default to influence credit spreads separately in both linear and quadratic terms. These individual components are also interacted with the call-option dummy variable to allow for the attenuation discussed above. The estimation results for this specification are reported in Table 8. The log of leverage, the return on assets and the log-volatility all have coefficients that are statistically and economically significant and of the right sign relative to the theoretical predictions. Again we translate these coefficients into more easily understandable economic quantities by reporting the marginal effects for the level of the credit spreads in Table 9. For example, a 1 standard deviation increase in firm value relative to debt (V /D) implies a 9 basis point reduction in credit spreads when evaluated at the mean leverage. The estimation results again imply attenuation of the marginal impact of each component of distance to default for the credit spreads of callable bonds. The effect of the interest rate factors and realized interest rate volatility on the credit spreads for callable bonds is economically very similar to the results reported in Table 7 that were obtained using distance to default as the proxy for default risk. In addition, this more general specification provides a similar goodness of fit as measured by adjusted R2 (0.692) to the specification that uses distance to default directly. Thus, most of the variation in credit spreads that is related to firm-specific measures of default risk appears to be well captured by the distance to default measure without further need for generalization. Nonetheless for robustness, we use the more general specification defined in column 3 of Table 8 to construct the fitted values for the log of the credit spread at the individual bond issue level. We then aggregate these spreads in the manner described at the beginning of this section. This produces the fitted value for the aggregate spread, Stp . For comparison purposes, we also construct the fitted value obtained from the specification that does not allow for the callable bond interaction terms which is obtained using the regression reported in column 1 of Table 8. Figure 5 plots the GZ credit spread along with the fitted values from the two specifications for the bond equation—the specification that adjusts for callable bonds (optionadjusted) and the specification that assumes callable and non-callable bonds are priced in the same manner. Overall, the fitted values capture a substantial fraction of the movement in the GZ credit spread. Nonetheless, there is a clear divergence between the GZ credit spread and the fitted values, especially during the periods of financial and economic turmoil. Over most of the sample period the option adjustment has relatively little effect. The 1979–1982 period of non-borrowed reserves targeting resulted in increased interest rate volatility which implies a higher fitted value for the spread when adjusting for the option component relative to the fitted value that does not adjust for this volatility. In addition, 16 the volatility of the credit spread implies a more volatile fitted value over this time period. The option adjustment has a clearly noticeable effect during the current economic downturn, owing to the fact that interest rates are at an all time low during the economic crisis. Low interest rates implies a higher predicted value for the credit spreads on callable bonds. This adjustment accounts for a full 2 percentage points of the total increase in the GZ index during the financial crisis.15 Figure 6 plots the excess bond premium—that is the difference between the GZ credit spread index and the fitted value from the option-adjusted specification. The excess bond premium increases noticeably during all economic downturns except the 1990 recession. It also reaches an all time low during the easy-credit period in 2003 and remains low during the ensuing boom in house prices. The excess bond premium rises sharply in the first quarter of 2007 as housing prices growth turned negative and continues to rise throughout the onset of the financial crisis. The excess bond premium reaches an all time high of 2.5 percentage points in October 2008, following the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Since then, the excess bond premium has fallen considerably as financial market turmoil has subsided. 5 The Excess Bond Premium and Economic Activity The decomposition of the GZ index discussed above implies that an important component of the variation in corporate credit spreads is due to an excess bond premium that arguably reflects variation in the pricing of default risk rather than variation in the risk of default. We now examine the extent to which variation in the excess bond premium provides independent information about future economic activity. We do this in two stages. First, we consider the extent to which the forecasting power of the GZ credit spread documented in Section 3 is attributable to the predicted component, Stp versus the residual component, EBPt . We then add the excess bond premium to an otherwise standard macroeconomic VAR and examine whether orthogonalized shocks to the excess bond premium cause movements in economic activity and other asset prices in the economy. Table 10 reports the results from re-estimating our forecasting equation for monthly economic activity variables, this time allowing for the two individual components of the GZ credit spread—StP and EBPt to enter the regression separately. The top panel of this table reports estimation results based on the 1973–2009 period, while the bottom panel reports estimation results based on the 1985–2009 subsample. The estimates reported in table highlight the fact that the excess bond premium provides predictive content for all three 15 Because there is such a strong negative comovement of credit spreads and economic activity during this episode, the option adjustment attributes more explanatory power to the predicted component of credit spreads rather than the excess bond component relative to the predicted series that does not adjust for the option on callable bonds. 17 economic activity measures at both the short (3-month) and long (12-month) horizons. For the full sample period, both the predicted component and the excess bond premium provide independent explanatory power. The coefficient estimates and the t-statistics are roughly equivalent in magnitude. In the later sample period, the predictive content of the excess bond premium increases, as evidence by a substantial increase in the t-statistic. In contrast, the predictive component, Stp , is no longer significant for either employment or industrial production at the 3-month horizon, and the t-statistics of the coefficient estimate decline in value across all variables and forecast horizons. Table 11 reports estimation results for GDP growth at the 1-, 2-, and 4-quarter horizons. Estimation results based on the full sample period imply that the excess bond premium provides economically and statistically significant explanatory power for GDP growth at all three horizons. The coefficient estimates imply that a 1 percentage point increase in the excess bond premium predicts a 25 basis point drop in economic growth at all horizons. Consistent with the results reported in the upper panel of Table 10, both the predicted component, Stp and the EBPt provide independent explanatory power over the full sample period. In contrast, the estimation results for the 1985–2009 subsample imply that only the excess bond premium provides predictive power for real GDP growth. The coefficient estimate on Stp is both economically small and statistically insignificant across all horizons. The coefficient estimate on the excess bond premium is substantially higher in the later sample period—a 1 percentage point increase in the excess bond premium predicts a 50 basis point decline in the real GDP growth at all horizons. In summary, the excess bond premium is a robust predictor of economic activity. This finding is true across economic indicators, forecast horizons, and sample periods. Furthermore, these forecasting results imply that, in the latter sample period, all of the predictive content of the GZ credit spread for output growth can be attributed to variation in the excess bond premium rather than variation in default risk as measured by Stp . We now consider the economic consequences of shocks to the excess bond premium for future economic activity. To do so, we add the excess bond premium to an otherwise standard VAR framework and consider the effect of a shock to the excess bond premium that is orthogonal to standard measures of macroeconomic activity, namely the stance of monetary policy and returns on other financial assets. The VAR includes the following variables: real GDP growth, real consumption growth, real growth in business fixed investment, inflation as measured by the change in the GDP price deflator, the effective federal funds rate, the 10-year Treasury yield, and the excess return on the value-weighted CRSP stock market portfolio. By including short and long-term interest rates along with stock market returns, we are therefore considering shocks to the excess bond premium that are orthogonal to the information embedded in the level and slope of the yield curve and news in the stock 18 market. Figure 7 presents the impulse responses to an orthogonalized shock to the excess bond premium for the VAR estimated over the full sample period. A one standard deviation rise in the excess bond premium causes a statistically significant reduction in all three economic activity variables—consumption, investment, and output—with the peak output response occurring about five quarters after the shock. The rise in the excess bond premium also causes a decline in the price level and a significant easing of monetary policy, evidenced by the decline in the effective federal funds rate. The magnitude of the decline in output is large—a 20 basis point shock to the excess bond premium implies a 25 basis point decline in the level of output. Despite falling interest rates, the stock market experiences a significant decline—on the order of 4 percentage points relative to trend growth. Figure 8 presents the amount of variation that can be explained by orthogonalized shocks to the excess bond premium for the variables in the VAR. The excess bond premium accounts for roughly 10 percent of the variation in output and 20 percent of the variation in investment at business cycle frequencies. This exceeds the amount of variation typically explained by monetary policy shocks. Figure 9 presents the impulse responses for the VAR estimated over the 1985–2009 period. Orthogonalized shocks to the excess bond premium are the same order of magnitude as in the full-sample case—a 1 standard deviation implies a 20 basis point rise in the excess bond premium upon impact. Again, these shocks have statistically and economically important effects on consumption, output, and investment. The overall decline in output is nearly 60 basis points, more than double the size of the effect obtained from the full sample estimates. It is also much more persistent. The decline in the cumulative market return is also larger. The larger impact of shocks to the excess bond premium for the later period may be attributable to the fact that the federal funds rate no longer exhibit a sharp decline in response to the rising excess bond premium. Shocks to the excess bond premium also account for a larger fraction of the variation in output as measured by the variance decomposition. According to Figure 10, the amount of variation in output that can be explained by this shock has roughly doubled. Because the fraction of variance for investment that can be explained by this shock remains unchanged across the different estimation periods, most of this increase is attributable to an increase in the explanatory power of shocks to the excess bond premium for consumption rather than investment during the later sample period. The VAR findings are consistent with the notion that the excess bond premium measures credit supply conditions and that a deterioration in those conditions causes a contraction in both asset prices and economic activity through the financial accelerator mechanisms emphasized by Kiyotaki and Moore [1997] and Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist [1999]. More 19 recently, Gertler and Karadi [2009] and Gertler and Kiyotaki [2009] have emphasized models in which shocks to the value of assets held by financial intermediaries have independent effects on economic activity through the reduction in credit supply. Because the banking sector is a relatively small source of funding for the corporate sector, it is difficult to argue that the direct effects of contractions in bank lending have large economic effect via the corporate bond market unless these contractions also influence the supply of credit more broadly. To the extent that “financial shocks” cause variation in the risk attitudes of the agents pricing corporate bonds, such variation may also influence the supply of credit available via the corporate bond market. By and large, the corporate bond market is dominated by large institutional players such as banks, insurance companies, pensions funds, and other financial entities. These institutional players have specialized knowledge and thus may be considered “natural buyers” in this market. These institutional players also face either explicit or implicit capital requirements. As financial capital becomes impaired, such agents act in a more risk-averse manner, causing a rise in the excess bond premium and a reduction in the supply of credit available to potential borrowers, both within the banking system and those who rely on external forms of credit such as corporate bonds. Figure 11 provides one piece of evidence in favor of this interpretation. It plots the change in lending standards on C&I loans at commercial banks obtained from the Federal Reserve’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices along with the excess bond premium. The C&I lending standard series is available from 1973 to 1982 and again during the 1990–2009 period. The correlation between these two series—one obtained from survey information and the other obtained from bond market prices—is strikingly high. Effectively, the willingness of banks to make loans comoves strongly with the supply conditions in corporate credit markets as measured by the excess bond premium. These findings are also consistent with recent work by Adrian, Moench, and Shin [2010], who emphasize variation in the risk attitudes of financial intermediaries as a source of macroeconomic risk premiums. 6 Conclusion In this paper, we construct a new corporate credit spread index—the GZ credit spread index—employing an extensive micro-level data set of secondary market prices of outstanding senior unsecured bonds. In contrast to the widely-used credit spread indexes, the GZ index uses all information embedded in the Treasury yield curve, along with the bond’s coupon payments and the remaining time-to-maturity, to correctly compute the risk-free interest rate necessary to construct the credit spread for each underlying bond issue. Com- 20 pared with standard credit spread indexes such as the Baa-Aaa corporate bond spread and the paper-bill spread, the GZ credit spread is shown to be a robust predictor of future economic activity across a variety of economic indicators, sample periods, and forecast horizons. Using a flexible empirical bond-pricing framework, we also decompose the GZ credit spread index into a predictable component that reflects all available firm-specific information on default risk and a residual component that we label the excess bond premium. According to our results, a substantial fraction of the predictive content of the GZ credit spread index for economic activity is attributable to the excess bond premium. Indeed, in the post 1985 period, the excess bond premium can account for all of the predictive content of credit spreads for economic activity. Shocks to the excess bond premium that are orthogonal to current economic activity, the information contained in the term structure of interest rates, and news embedded in the stock market returns are shown to cause economically significant contractions in economic activity. These findings are consistent with the notion that a rise in the excess bond premium reflects a reduction in the risk appetite of the financial sector and, as a result, a reduction in the supply of credit, which has significant adverse consequences for macroeconomic outcomes. 21 References Adrian, T., E. Moench, and H. S. Shin (2010): “Financial Intermediation, Asset Prices, and Macroeconomic Dynamics,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 422. Ang, A. and G. Bekaert (2007): “Stock Return Predictability: Is It There?” Review of Financial Studies, 20, 651–707. Ang, A., M. Piazzesi, and M. Wei (2006): “What Does the Yield Curve Tell Us About GDP Growth?” Journal of Econometrics, 131, 359–403. Bernanke, B. S. (1990): “On the Predictive Power of Interest Rates and Interest Rate Spreads,” New England Economic Review, November, 51–68. Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist (1999): “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in The Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V, 1341–1393. Bharath, S. T. and T. Shumway (2008): “Forecasting Default with the Merton Distance to Default Model,” Review of Financial Studies, 21, 1339–1369. Clarida, R., J. Galı́, and M. Gertler (2000): “Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 147–180. Crosbie, P. J. and J. R. Bohn (2003): “Modeling Default Risk,” Research Report, Moody’s|K·M·V Corporation. Dotsey, M. (1998): “The Predictive Content of the Interest Rate Term Spread for Future Economic Growth,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 84, 31–51. Duca, J. V. (1999): “An Overview of What Credit Market Indicators Tell Us,” Economic and Financial Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Third Quarter, 2–13. Duffee, G. R. (1998): “The Relation Between Treasury Yields and Corporate Bond Yield Spreads,” Journal of Finance, 53, 225–241. Duffie, D. and K. J. Singleton (2003): Credit Risk, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Dynan, K. E., D. W. Elmendorf, and D. E. Sichel (2006): “Can Financial Innovation Help Explain the Reduced Volatility of Economic Activity,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53, 123–150. Elliott, G. and U. K. Müller (2006): “Efficient Tests for General Persistent Time Variation in Regression Coefficients,” Review of Economic Studies, 73, 907–940. Emery, K. M. (1999): “The Information Content of the Paper-Bill Spread,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 48, 1–10. 22 Estrella, A. and G. A. Hardouvelis (1991): “The Term Structure as Predictor of Real Economic Activity,” Journal of Finance, 46, 555–576. Estrella, A. and F. S. Mishkin (1998): “Predicting U.S. Recessions: Financial Variables as Leading Indicators,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 45–61. Fama, E. F. (1981): “Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation and Money,” American Economic Review, 71, 545–565. Faust, J., J. H. Wright, S. Gilchrist, and E. Zakrajšek (2010): “Bayesian Model Averaging and Real-Time Forecasts of Economic Activity,” Mimeo in progress, Johns Hopkins University. Friedman, B. M. and K. N. Kuttner (1992): “Money, Income, Prices, and Interest Rates,” American Economic Review, 82, 472–492. ——— (1998): “Indicator Properties of the Paper-Bill Spread: Lessons From Recent Experience,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 34–44. Gertler, M. and P. Karadi (2009): “A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy,” Mimeo, New York University. Gertler, M. and N. Kiyotaki (2009): “Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis,” Mimeo, New York University. Gertler, M. and C. S. Lown (1999): “The Information in the High-Yield Bond Spread for the Business Cycle: Evidence and Some Implications,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15, 132–150. Gilchrist, S., V. Yankov, and E. Zakrajšek (2009): “Credit Market Shocks and Economic Fluctuations: Evidence From Corporate Bond and Stock Markets,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 471–493. Gürkaynak, R. S., B. Sack, and J. H. Wright (2007): “The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to the Present,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2291–2304. Hamilton, J. D. and D. H. Kim (2002): “A Reexamination of the Predictability of Economic Activity Using the Yield Spread,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 34, 340–360. Harvey, C. R. (1989): “Forecasts of Economic Growth from the Bond and Stock Market,” Financial Analysts Journal, 45, 38–45. Hodrick, R. J. (1992): “Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns: Alternative Procedures for Inference and Measurement,” Review of Financial Studies, 5, 357–386. King, T. B., A. T. Levin, and R. Perli (2007): “Financial Market Perceptions of Recession Risk,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series Paper No. 57, Federal Reserve Board. 23 Kiyotaki, N. and J. H. Moore (1997): “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, 105, 211–248. Lando, D. (2004): Credit Risk Modeling: Theory and Applications, Princeton, NJ: Princeton Series in Finance, Princeton University Press. Levin, A. T., F. M. Natalucci, and E. Zakrajšek (2004): “The Magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2004-70, Federal Reserve Board. Litterman, R. B. and J. A. Scheinkman (1991): “Common Factors Affecting Bond Returns,” Journal of Fixed Income, 1, 54–61. Merton, R. C. (1973): “A Rational Theory of Option Pricing,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4, 141–183. ——— (1974): “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Finance, 29, 449–470. Modigliani, F. and M. H. Miller (1958): “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, 38, 261–297. Mody, A. and M. P. Taylor (2004): “Financial Predictors of Real Activity and the Financial Accelerator,” Economic Letters, 82, 167–172. Mueller, P. (2007): “Credit Spreads and Real Activity,” Mimeo, Columbia Business School. Newey, W. K. and K. D. West (1987): “A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix,” Econometrica, 55, 703–708. Philippon, T. (2009): “The Bond Market’s q,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 1011–1056. Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (2002): “Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why?” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. by M. Gertler and K. Rogoff, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 159–218. ——— (2003): “How Did Leading Indicators Forecasts Perform During the 2001 Recessions?” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 89, 71–90. Thoma, M. A. and J. A. Gray (1998): “Financial Market Variables Do Not Predict Real Activity,” Economic Inquiry, 36, 522–539. Vassalou, M. and Y. Xing (2004): “Default Risk and Equity Returns,” Journal of Finance, 59, 831–868. Warga, A. D. (1991): “A Fixed Income Database,” Mimeo, University of Houston. Wright, J. H. (2006): “The Yield Curve and Predicting Recessions,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series Paper No. 7, Federal Reserve Board. 24 Tables & Figure Table 1: Summary Statistics of Corporate Bond Characteristics Bond Characteristic Mean SD Min P50 Max # of bonds per firm/month Mkt. value of issuea ($mil.) Maturity at issue (years) Term to maturity (years) Duration (years) Credit rating (S&P) Coupon rate (pct.) Nominal effective yield (pct.) Credit spread (bps.) 2.83 310.1 13.3 11.4 6.50 7.31 7.82 202 3.46 315.6 9.5 8.6 3.20 1.95 3.24 284 1.00 1.22 1.0 1.0 0.91 D 1.95 0.66 5 2.00 231.0 10.0 8.2 6.10 BBB1 7.00 7.25 116 74.0 5,628 50.0 30.0 15.6 AAA 17.5 44.3 3,499 Panel Dimensions Obs. = 322, 371 N = 5, 539 bonds Min. Tenure = 1 Median Tenure = 48 Max. Tenure = 302 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009; No. of firms = 1,086. Sample statistics are based on trimmed data (see text for details). a Market value of the outstanding issue deflated by the CPI (1982–84 = 100). 25 Table 2: Financial Indicators and Economic Activity (Sample Period: Jan1973–Dec2009) Forecast Horizon (h months) h=3 h = 12 Financial Indicator EMP UER IPM EMP UER IPM Term spread -0.080 [1.919] -0.079 [1.753] 0.661 -0.085 [2.028] -0.009 [0.143] -0.108 [2.410] 0.668 -0.084 [2.037] -0.075 [1.624] -0.019 [0.494] 0.661 -0.097 [2.373] -0.125 [2.737] -0.274 [6.660] 0.706 0.131 [4.815] 0.071 [2.431] 0.344 0.148 [5.754] -0.089 [2.555] 0.239 [9.924] 0.378 0.155 [5.707] 0.048 [1.667] 0.088 [3.443] 0.348 0.166 [6.132] 0.134 [4.517] 0.316 [14.08] 0.415 -0.144 [2.152] -0.070 [0.973] 0.276 -0.166 [2.476] -0.117 [1.277] -0.285 [4.225] 0.325 -0.174 [2.716] -0.048 [0.667] -0.108 [1.632] 0.283 -0.189 [2.875] -0.142 [2.046] -0.359 [4.941] 0.365 -0.240 [4.814] -0.122 [2.340] 0.432 -0.241 [4.783] -0.108 [1.706] -0.023 [0.683] 0.431 -0.220 [4.719] -0.156 [3.154] 0.108 [2.197] 0.441 -0.264 [5.447] -0.204 [4.011] -0.474 [14.64] 0.590 0.356 [42.22] 0.063 [7.569] 0.287 0.369 [45.51] -0.037 [4.083] 0.154 [29.09] 0.300 0.353 [42.50] 0.066 [8.283] -0.014 [1.792] 0.286 0.391 [46.88] 0.148 [17.99] 0.418 [81.91] 0.431 -0.332 [3.953] -0.099 [1.075] 0.225 -0.346 [4.115] 0.016 [0.151] -0.179 [3.020] 0.243 -0.323 [3.882] -0.107 [1.201] 0.032 [0.393] 0.224 -0.371 [4.478] -0.187 [2.122] -0.434 [6.099] 0.375 Real FFR Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR CP-Bill spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR Baa-Aaa spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR GZ spread Adj. R2 Note: Dependent variable is ∇h Yt+h , where Yt denotes an indicator of economic activity in month t and h is the forecast horizon: EMP = log of private nonfarm payroll employment; UER = civilian unemployment rate; and IPM = log of the index of manufacturing industrial production. In addition to the specified financial indicator in month t, each specification also includes a constant, current, and p lags of ∇Yt (not reported), where p is determined by the AIC. Entries in the table denote standardized estimates of the OLS coefficients associated with each financial indicator; absolute t-statistics reported in brackets are based on the asymptotic covariance matrix computed according to Hodrick [1992]. 26 Table 3: Financial Indicators and Output Growth (Sample Period: 1973:Q1–2009:Q4) Forecast Horizon (h quarters) Financial Indicator h=1 h=2 h=4 Term spread -0.148 [1.429] -0.112 [1.055] 0.171 -0.179 [1.675] 0.104 [0.717] -0.264 [2.402] 0.192 -0.185 [1.646] -0.074 [0.681] -0.112 [1.002] 0.165 -0.202 [1.991] -0.171 [1.694] -0.337 [3.624] 0.240 -0.245 [2.127] -0.132 [1.130] 0.229 -0.258 [2.193] -0.005 [0.035] -0.178 [1.521] 0.241 -0.251 [2.067] -0.129 [1.101] -0.030 [0.268] 0.224 -0.289 [2.679] -0.226 [1.997] -0.378 [3.967] 0.333 -0.380 [2.849] -0.072 [0.537] 0.235 -0.384 [2.843] -0.033 [0.199] -0.056 [0.486] 0.232 -0.369 [2.602] -0.081 [0.599] 0.054 [0.428] 0.232 -0.418 [3.332] -0.152 [1.158] -0.364 [3.747] 0.341 Real FFR Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR CP-Bill spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR Baa-Aaa spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR GZ spread Adj. R2 Note: Dependent variable is ∇h Yt+h , where Yt denotes the log of real GDP in quarter t and h is the forecast horizon. In addition to the specified financial indicator in quarter t, each specification also includes a constant, current, and p lags of ∇Yt (not reported), where p is determined by the AIC. Entries in the table denote standardized estimates of the OLS coefficients associated with each financial indicator; absolute tstatistics reported in brackets are based on the asymptotic covariance matrix computed according to Hodrick [1992]. 27 Table 4: Financial Indicators and Output Growth (Sample Period: 1985:Q1–2009:Q4) Forecast Horizon (h quarters) Financial Indicator h=1 h=2 h=4 Term spread -0.112 [1.026] 0.120 [0.907] 0.235 -0.218 [1.788] 0.356 [1.768] -0.254 [2.070] 0.265 -0.222 [1.832] 0.172 [1.213] -0.280 [1.846] 0.267 -0.065 [0.623] -0.007 [0.060] -0.321 [2.109] 0.283 -0.186 [1.472] 0.175 [1.171] 0.231 -0.293 [2.294] 0.411 [2.056] -0.266 [1.986] 0.265 -0.257 [1.988] 0.179 [1.205] -0.205 [1.761] 0.249 -0.125 [0.125] 0.014 [0.097] -0.343 [2.590] 0.291 -0.255 [1.999] 0.157 [1.064] 0.182 -0.387 [2.853] 0.436 [2.188] -0.262 [1.822] 0.203 -0.400 [2.958] 0.244 [1.704] -0.288 [2.921] 0.223 -0.201 [1.707] 0.036 [0.260] -0.382 [3.029] 0.263 Real FFR Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR CP-Bill spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR Baa-Aaa spread Adj. R2 Term spread Real FFR GZ spread Adj. R2 Note: Dependent variable is ∇h Yt+h , where Yt denotes the log of real GDP in quarter t and h is the forecast horizon. In addition to the specified financial indicator in quarter t, each specification also includes a constant, current, and p lags of ∇Yt (not reported), where p is determined by the AIC. Entries in the table denote standardized estimates of the OLS coefficients associated with each financial indicator; absolute tstatistics reported in brackets are based on the asymptotic covariance matrix computed according to Hodrick [1992]. 28 Table 5: Credit Spreads and Expected Default Risk (Sample Period: Feb1990–Dec2009) Model Specification Explanatory Variable a = EDFit / b = −DDit a = EDF2it / b = (−DDit )2 CALL[k] ln(DUR[k]) ln(PAR[k]) ln(COUP[k]) Adj. R2 Industry Effectsa Credit Rating Effectsb (1a) (1b) (2a) (2b) (3a) (3b) 0.104 (0.005) - 0.112 (0.004) - 0.065 (0.003) - 0.075 (0.003) - 0.482 (0.033) -0.011 (0.017) 0.162 (0.032) 1.293 (0.070) 0.420 0.000 - 0.497 (0.027) 0.003 (0.016) 0.140 (0.028) 1.015 (0.069) 0.524 0.000 - 0.264 (0.020) 0.136 (0.012) 0.106 (0.016) 0.380 (0.052) 0.621 0.000 0.000 0.292 (0.018) 0.137 (0.011) 0.101 (0.017) 0.259 (0.055) 0.669 0.000 0.000 0.164 (0.009) -0.004 (0.000) 0.262 (0.019) 0.142 (0.012) 0.106 (0.016) 0.348 (0.052) 0.636 0.000 0.000 0.173 (0.007) 0.006 (0.000) 0.291 (0.017) 0.146 (0.011) 0.080 (0.016) 0.278 (0.054) 0.694 0.000 0.000 Note: Obs. = 265,936; No. of bonds/firms = 5,222/1,021. Dependent variable is ln(S[k]it ), the log of the credit spread on bond k—issued by firm i—in period t. In columns 1a, 2a, and 3a, the default-risk indicator is the year-ahead expected default frequency (EDF) as calculated by the MKMV; in columns 1b, 2b, and 3b, the default-risk indicator is the negative of the distance-to-default (DD) based on the Merton [1974] model (see text for details). All specifications include a constant term (not reported) and are estimated by OLS. Robust asymptotic standard errors are clustered at the firm level and are reported in parentheses. a p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of industry fixed effects. b p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of credit rating fixed effects. 29 Table 6: Credit Spreads and the Distance-to-Default (Sample Period: Jan1973–Dec2009) Model Specification Explanatory Variable Est. −DDit (−DDit )2 −DDit × CALL[k] (−DDit )2 × CALL[k] LEVELt × CALL[k] SLOPEt × CALL[k] CURVEt × CALL[k] VOLt × CALL[k] CALL[k] ln(DUR[k]) ln(PAR[k]) ln(COUP[k]) Adj. R2 Industry Effectsa Credit Rating Effectsb 0.170 0.007 0.006 0.000 0.263 0.017 0.100 0.012 0.138 0.014 0.472 0.059 0.649 0.000 0.000 S.E. Est. S.E. 0.193 0.012 0.006 0.001 -0.046 0.012 -0.001 0.001 -0.320 0.013 -0.073 0.008 -0.035 0.005 0.120 0.004 -0.351 0.047 0.107 0.011 0.025 0.013 0.770 0.055 0.685 0.000 0.000 Note: Obs. = 322,371; No. of bonds/firms = 5,539/1,086. Dependent variable is ln(S[k]it ), the log of the credit spread on bond k—issued by firm i—in period t. The term structure is represented by the following three factors: LEVEL = level; SLOPE = slope; and CURVE = curvature; see Litterman and Scheinkman [1991] for details; VOL = annualized realized monthly volatility of the daily 10-year Treasury yield (see text for details). All specifications include a constant term (not reported) and are estimated by OLS. Robust asymptotic standard errors are clustered at the firm level. a p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of industry fixed effects. b p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of credit rating fixed effects. 30 Table 7: Selected Marginal Effects by Type of Bond Non-Callable Bonds Callable Bonds Variable Est. S.E. Est. S.E. Mean STD Distance-to-default: −DDit Term structure: LEVELt Term structure: SLOPEt Term structure: CURVEt Term structure: VOLt (%) 0.205 - 0.008 - 0.153 -0.608 -0.138 -0.067 0.289 0.005 0.025 0.015 0.010 0.008 6.754 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.866 4.055 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.249 Note: The table contains the estimates of the marginal effect of a one unit change in the specified variable on the level of credit spreads (in percentage points) for non-callable and callable bonds based on the parameter estimates reported in Table 6; see text for for details. All marginal effects are evaluated at sample means; by construction, the level, slope, and curvature factors are standardized to have the mean equal to zero and the standard deviation equal to one. Robust asymptotic standard errors are computed according to the delta method. 31 Table 8: Credit Spreads and Components of the Distance-to-Default (Sample Period: Jan1973–Dec2009) Model Specification Explanatory Variable Est. ln[V /D]it µit ln σit (ln[V /D]it )2 µ2it (ln σit )2 ln[V /D]it × CALL[k] µit × CALL[k] ln σit × CALL[k] (ln[V /D]it )2 × CALL[k] µ2it × CALL[k] (ln σit )2 × CALL[k] LEVELt × CALL[k] SLOPEt × CALL[k] CURVEt × CALL[k] VOLt × CALL[k] CALL[k] ln(DUR[k]) ln(PAR[k]) ln(COUP[k]) Adj. R2 Industry Effectsa Credit Rating Effectsb S.E. -0.566 0.066 -0.649 0.021 0.530 0.130 0.114 0.011 0.148 0.042 0.012 0.051 0.242 0.017 0.112 0.012 0.026 0.013 0.535 0.054 0.660 0.000 0.000 Est. S.E. -0.771 0.061 -0.669 0.039 1.248 0.183 0.145 0.015 0.061 0.077 0.221 0.070 0.241 0.066 0.147 0.042 -1.063 0.175 -0.045 0.016 0.088 0.081 -0.302 0.065 -0.293 0.012 -0.068 0.009 -0.033 0.005 0.114 0.004 -1.222 0.114 0.117 0.010 0.028 0.012 0.792 0.051 0.692 0.000 0.000 Note: Obs. = 322,371; No. of bonds/firms = 5,539/1,086. Dependent variable is ln(S[k]it ), the log of the credit spread on bond k—issued by firm i—in period t. The term structure is represented by the following three factors: LEVEL = level; SLOPE = slope; and CURVE = curvature; see Litterman and Scheinkman [1991] for details; VOL = annualized realized monthly volatility of the daily 10-year Treasury yield (see text for details). All specifications include a constant term (not reported) and are estimated by OLS. Robust asymptotic standard errors are clustered at the firm level. a p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of industry fixed effects. b p-value for the robust Wald statistics of the exclusion test of credit rating fixed effects. 32 Table 9: Selected Marginal Effects by Type of Bond Non-Callable Bonds Variable Leverage: [V /D]it Return on assets: µit (%) Volatility of assets: σit (%) Term structure: LEVELt Term structure: SLOPEt Term structure: CURVEt Term structure: VOLt (%) Callable Bonds Est. S.E. Est. S.E. Mean STD -0.087 -1.259 4.416 - 0.006 0.072 0.230 - -0.060 -0.962 2.851 -0.558 -0.128 -0.063 0.217 0.005 0.042 0.144 0.024 0.017 0.010 0.008 6.730 5.292 27.33 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.866 7.514 27.33 12.56 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.249 Note: The table contains the estimates of the marginal effect of a one unit change in the specified variable on the level of credit spreads (in percentage points) for non-callable and callable bonds based on the parameter estimates reported in Table 8; see text for for details. All marginal effects are evaluated at sample means; by construction, the level, slope, and curvature factors are standardized to have the mean equal to zero and the standard deviation equal to one. Robust asymptotic standard errors are computed according to the delta method. 33 Table 10: Excess Bond Premium and Economic Activity Sample Period: Jan1973–Dec2009 Forecast Horizon (h months) h=3 h = 12 Financial Indicator EMP UER IPM EMP UER IPM Term spread -0.098 [2.403] -0.112 [2.342] -0.179 [4.250] -0.173 [2.999] 0.708 0.170 [6.321] 0.110 [3.539] 0.185 [7.777] 0.229 [11.18] 0.422 -0.198 [3.016] -0.107 [1.470] -0.195 [2.848] -0.292 [4.604] 0.382 -0.266 [5.487] -0.195 [3.771] -0.344 [8.814] -0.262 [9.958] 0.591 0.403 [47.81] 0.112 [13.49] 0.243 [41.16] 0.325 [65.73] 0.444 -0.382 [4.442] -0.161 [1.796] -0.284 [4.015 -0.297 [4.208] 0.381 Real FFR Predicted GZ spread Excess bond premium Adj. R2 Sample Period: Jan1985–Dec2009 Forecast Horizon (h months) h=3 h = 12 Financial Indicator EMP UER IPM EMP UER IPM Term spread -0.101 [2.891] 0.053 [1.267] -0.064 [1.424] -0.181 [5.523] 0.824 0.126 [3.832] -0.030 [0.763] 0.157 [4.192] 0.290 [10.76] 0.495 -0.155 [1.871] 0.089 [0.852] -0.163 [1.478] -0.395 [4.409] 0.451 -0.264 [7.579] 0.067 [1.722] -0.096 [2.691] -0.295 [10.00] 0.718 0.320 [34.34] -0.092 [9.851] 0.112 [14.18] 0.395 [64.72] 0.548 -0.294 [3.448] 0.134 [1.372] -0.218 [2.672] -0.455 [4.927] 0.402 Real FFR Predicted GZ spread Excess bond premium Adj. R2 Note: Dependent variable is ∇h Yt+h , where Yt denotes an indicator of economic activity in month t and h is the forecast horizon: EMP = log of private nonfarm payroll employment; UER = civilian unemployment rate; and IPM = log of the index of manufacturing industrial production. In addition to the specified financial indicators in month t, each specification also includes a constant, current, and p lags of ∇Yt (not reported), where p is determined by the AIC. Entries in the table denote standardized estimates of the OLS coefficients associated with each financial indicator; absolute tstatistics reported in brackets are based on the asymptotic covariance matrix computed according to Hodrick [1992]. 34 Table 11: Excess Bond Premium and Output Growth Sample Period: 1973:Q1–2009:Q4 Forecast Horizon (h quarters) Financial Indicator h=1 h=2 h=4 Term spread -0.210 [2.936] -0.138 [1.305] -0.161 [1.831] -0.279 [3.619] 0.254 -0.298 [2.702] -0.198 [1.681] -0.200 [2.183] -0.279 [3.263] 0.343 -0.421 [3.298] -0.142 [1.038] -0.250 [2.454] -0.205 [2.448] 0.338 Real FFR Predicted GZ spread Excess bond premium Adj. R2 Sample Period: 1985:Q1–2009:Q4 Forecast Horizon (h quarters) Financial Indicator h=1 h=2 h=4 Term spread -0.293 [2.115] 0.321 [1.675] 0.061 [0.332] -0.505 [3.737] 0.320 -0.353 [2.598] 0.365 [2.056] 0.130 [0.915] -0.524 [4.056] 0.381 -0.401 [3.089] 0.322 [2.093] 0.023 [0.162] -0.475 [3.773] 0.322 Real FFR Predicted GZ spread Excess bond premium Adj. R2 Note: Dependent variable is ∇h Yt+h , where Yt denotes the log of real GDP in quarter t and h is the forecast horizon. In addition to the specified financial indicators in quarter t, each specification also includes a constant, current, and p lags of ∇Yt (not reported), where p is determined by the AIC. Entries in the table denote standardized estimates of the OLS coefficients associated with each financial indicator; absolute tstatistics reported in brackets are based on the asymptotic covariance matrix computed according to Hodrick [1992]. 35 Figure 1: Selected Corporate Credit Spreads Percentage points 8 NBER Peak Monthly GZ spread Baa-Aaa spread CP-Bill spread 6 4 2 0 -2 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009. The figure depicts the following default-risk indicators: GZ spread = average credit spread on senior unsecured bonds issued by nonfinancial firms in our sample (the black line); Baa-Aaa = the spread between yields on Baa- and Aaa-rated long-term industrial corporate bonds (the blue line); and CP-Bill = the spread between the yield on 1-month A1/P1 nonfinancial commercial paper and the 1-month Treasury yield (the red line). The shaded vertical bars represent the NBER-dated recessions. 36 Figure 2: Distance-to-Default Std. deviations 20 NBER Peak Monthly Nonfinancial corporate sector (median) Median Interquartile range 15 10 5 0 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009. The figure depicts the distance-to-default (DD) calculated using the Merton [1974] model (see text for details). The black line depicts the (weighted) median DD of the firms in our sample, and the shaded yellow band depicts the corresponding (weighted) inter-quartile range. The red line depicts the (weighted) median DD in the U.S. nonfinancial corporate sector; all percentiles are weighted by the firm’s outstanding liabilities. The shaded vertical bars represent the NBER-dated recessions. 37 Figure 3: Expected Default Frequency and Distance-to-Default 40.00 Expected default frequency (percent, log scale) 20.00 10.00 5.00 1.00 0.25 0.05 0.01 -5 0 5 10 15 20 Distance-to-default (std. deviations) Note: Sample period: Feb1900–Dec2009 (Obs. = 265,936; No. of firms = 1,021) The figure depict the scatter plot of the year-ahead expected default frequency (EDF) for firm i in month t calculated by MKMV and the corresponding year-ahead distance-to-default (DD) calculated using the Merton [1974] model (see text for details). 38 Figure 4: Callable Senior Unsecured Corporate Bonds Percent NBER Peak Monthly 100 Proportion of total bonds Proportion of total par value 80 60 40 20 0 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009. The figure depicts the proportion of bonds in our sample that are callable. The shaded vertical bars represent the NBER-dated recessions. 39 Figure 5: Actual and Predicted Credit Spreads Percentage points 8 NBER Peak Monthly Actual GZ spread Predicted GZ spread Predicted GZ spread with option adjustments 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009. The black line depicts the average credit spread for our sample of bonds. The blue line depicts the predicted credit spread based on the regression specification that includes linear and quadratic components of the distance-to-default but excludes the option-adjustment terms; the red line depicts the predicted credit spread based on the same regression specification but that includes the option-adjustment terms (see text for details). The shaded vertical bars represent the NBER-dated recessions. 40 Figure 6: Option-Adjusted Excess Bond Premium Percentage points 2.5 NBER Peak Monthly 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: Sample period: Jan1973–Dec2009. The figure depicts the estimated excess bond premium based on the regression specification that includes linear and quadratic components of the distance-to-default and the option-adjustment terms (see text for details). The shaded vertical bars represent the NBER-dated recessions. 41 Figure 7: Implications of a Shock to the Excess Bond Premium (Sample Period: 1973:Q1–2009:Q4) Consumption Investment Percentage points Percentage points 0.6 1 0.4 0 0.2 -1 0.0 -2 -0.2 -3 -0.4 -4 -0.6 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -5 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Output Prices Percentage points Percentage points 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.0 0.2 0.0 -0.5 -0.2 -1.0 -0.4 -1.5 -0.6 -0.8 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -2.0 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Cumulative excess market return 10-year Treasury yield Percentage points Percentage points 2 0.1 0.0 0 -0.1 -2 -0.2 -4 -0.3 -6 -0.4 -8 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -0.5 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Federal funds rate Excess bond premium Percentage points Percentage points 0.2 0.25 0.0 0.20 0.15 -0.2 0.10 -0.4 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0.05 -0.6 0.00 -0.8 -0.05 20 0 Quarters after shock 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Note: The figure depicts the impulse response functions from an 8-variable VAR(2) model to a 1 standard deviation orthogonalized shock to the excess bond premium. The VAR is ordered as follows: (1) log-difference of real PCE; (2) log-difference of real BFI; (3) log-difference of real GDP; (4) log-difference of the GDP price deflator; (5) 1-quarter value-weighted excess (total) log-return from CRSP; (6) nominal 10-year Treasury yield; (7) effective federal funds rate; and (8) (optionadjusted) excess bond premium. The responses of consumption, investment, and output growth and that of the excess market return have been cumulated. Shaded bands denote 95-percent confidence intervals based on 2,000 bootstrap replications. 42 Figure 8: Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (Sample Period: 1973:Q1–2009:Q4) Consumption Investment Percent 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Output Prices Percent Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Cumulative excess market return 10-year Treasury yield Percent Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Federal funds rate Excess bond premium Percent Percent 40 100 30 80 60 20 40 10 20 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 Forecast horizon (quarters) 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Note: The figure depicts the forecast error variance decomposition from an 8-variable VAR(2) model to a 1 standard deviation orthogonalized shock to the excess bond premium. The VAR is ordered as follows: (1) log-difference of real PCE; (2) log-difference of real BFI; (3) log-difference of real GDP; (4) log-difference of the GDP price deflator; (5) 1-quarter value-weighted excess (total) log-return from CRSP; (6) nominal 10-year Treasury yield; (7) effective federal funds rate; and (8) (option-adjusted) excess bond premium. The responses of consumption, investment, and output growth and that of the excess market return have been cumulated. Shaded bands denote 95-percent confidence intervals based on 2,000 bootstrap replications. 43 Figure 9: Implications of a Shock to the Excess Bond Premium (Sample Period: 1985:Q1–2009:Q4) Consumption Investment Percentage points Percentage points 1 0.2 0 0.0 -1 -0.2 -2 -0.4 -3 -0.6 -4 -0.8 -5 -1.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -6 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Output Prices Percentage points Percentage points 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.2 -0.2 0.1 -0.4 0.0 -0.6 -0.1 -0.8 -0.2 -1.0 -0.3 -1.2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -0.4 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Cumulative excess market return 10-year Treasury yield Percentage points Percentage points 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 -0.05 -0.10 -0.15 -0.20 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 0 2 4 6 Quarters after shock 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Federal funds rate Excess bond premium Percentage points Percentage points 0.2 0.25 0.1 0.20 0.0 0.15 -0.1 0.10 -0.2 0.05 -0.3 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 -0.4 0.00 -0.5 -0.05 20 0 Quarters after shock 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Quarters after shock Note: The figure depicts the impulse response functions of an 8-variable VAR(2) model to a 1-standard-deviation orthogonalized shock to the excess corporate bond premium. The VAR is ordered as follows: (1) log-difference of real PCE; (2) log-difference of real BFI; (3) log-difference of real GDP; (4) log-difference of the GDP price deflator; (5) 1-quarter value-weighted excess (total) log-return from CRSP; (6) nominal 10-year Treasury yield; (7) effective federal funds rate; and (8) (option-adjusted) excess bond premium. The responses of consumption, investment, and output growth and that of the excess market return have been cumulated. Shaded bands denote 95-percent confidence intervals based on 2,000 bootstrap replications. 44 Figure 10: Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (Sample Period: 1985:Q1–2009:Q4) Consumption Investment Percent 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Output Prices Percent Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Cumulative excess market return 10-year Treasury yield Percent Percent 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 2 4 Forecast horizon (quarters) 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Federal funds rate Excess bond premium Percent Percent 40 100 30 80 60 20 40 10 20 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 20 0 Forecast horizon (quarters) 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Forecast horizon (quarters) Note: The figure depicts the forecast error variance decomposition of an 8-variable VAR(2) model to a 1-standard-deviation orthogonalized shock to the excess corporate bond premium. The VAR is ordered as follows: (1) log-difference of real PCE; (2) log-difference of real BFI; (3) logdifference of real GDP; (4) log-difference of the GDP price deflator; (5) 1-quarter value-weighted excess (total) log-return from CRSP; (6) nominal 10-year Treasury yield; (7) effective federal funds rate; and (8) (option-adjusted) excess bond premium. The responses of consumption, investment, and output growth and that of the excess market return have been cumulated. Shaded bands denote 95-percent confidence intervals based on 2,000 bootstrap replications. 45 Figure 11: Excess Bond Premium and Changes in Bank Lending Standards Percentage points 2.0 Net percent 100 NBER Peak Quarterly Excess bond premium (left scale) Change in C&I lending standards (right scale) 1.5 75 1.0 50 0.5 25 0.0 0 -0.5 -25 -1.0 -50 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Note: The black line depicts the quarterly average of the estimated (option-adjusted) excess bond premium (see text for details). The red line depicts the net percent of respondents to the Federal Reserve’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices that indicated that they had tightening their credit standards on C&I loans to large and middlemarket firms over the quarter. Reported net percent equals the percent of banks that reported tightening their standards minus the percent that reported easing their standards. (There was no survey conducted during the 1984-89 period.) The shaded vertical bars denote NBER-dated recessions. 46