Externalities Externalities a. What are externalities? b. Pollution November 21, 2006 c. Private solutions to externalities Reading: Chapter 19 d. Policies toward pollution This topic examines externalities, or side effects of activities that are not paid for. We discuss how externalities lead to market failures and how government policy can make things better. We devote some attention to a major externality, pollution. e. Production, consumption and externalities 2 Pollution What are externalities? Costs and Benefits of Pollution Externalities are costs and benefits that are side effects of activities done by economic agents (individuals, firms) who do not have an economic incentive to take these costs and benefits into account. External costs or external diseconomies result in costs to others. Cost which an agent imposes on others without compensating them for it. External benefits or external economies result in benefits to others. Benefit which an agent provides others without being compensated for it. Since agents do not take into account these external costs and benefits, individual optimizing behavior, even under conditions of perfect competition, results in market failure. We will discuss two cases, those in which: (1) the side effects can be directly measured and quantified, as in the case of environmental pollution; and (2) only the original activity, not the side effect, can be observed and measured. 3 Pollution Pollution: damage to the environment (clean air, clean water, land) caused by economic activities such production, consumption. Also refers to deforestation, loss of biodiversity, damage to the ozone layer, and global warming. Often measured by amount of “bad” effluents released. Marginal social cost of pollution: additional cost imposed on society as a whole by an additional unit of pollution. MSC increases with the amount of pollution. Marginal social benefit of pollution: additional benefit to society as a whole from an additional unit of pollution. Reducing pollution requires scarce resources which could have been used to produce goods and services. As pollution falls, these additional resources are higher (think in terms of amount of pollution reduction). Socially optimal quantity of pollution: amount of pollution that maximizes the difference between total social benefits and total social costs of pollution. Amount of pollution society would choose if all costs and benefits of pollution 4 are fully accounted for. Where MSC = MSB for pollution. Not zero pollution. Private Solutions to Externalities Market failure Coase theorem: even in the presence of externalities an economy can always reach an efficient solution provided that transaction costs (costs of making deals) are sufficiently low. Pollution, like other externalities, results in market failure. Marginal benefits (additional cost of pollution control) accrues to private firms and individuals. The theorem implies that externalities need not lead to inefficiency because individuals have an incentive to find a way to make mutually beneficial deals (usually with payments) that lead them to take externalities into account (that is, internalize the externality) when making decisions. Marginal costs accrue to society as a whole in the form of an externality, not to polluter. In the absence of government intervention, polluters face no marginal costs, only marginal benefits. So they will pollute up to where MSB=0; there will be no pollution control. The free market results in QMKT level of pollution. The socially efficient or optimal level of pollution is QOPT level of pollution. Ronald Coase (b. 1910), American economist and Novel Prize winner Problem: Individuals cannot always make such deals because of high transaction costs due to: 1. High costs of communication if many people are involved 2. High legal expenses for legally binding agreements. 3. Delays in bargaining, with parties holding out to get better deals. So the free market will not lead to a socially optimal outcome. 5 So government action is usually required. 6 1 Policies Toward Pollution Policies Toward Pollution Environmental Standards versus Emissions Taxes 1. Environmental standards: rules that protect the environment by specifying actions by producers and consumers. Generally such standards are inefficient because they are inflexible, but historically reduce pollution. 2. Emissions tax: a form of Pigouvian tax, a tax designed to reduce external costs that depends on the amount of pollution a firm produces. Efficient because marginal cost of pollution control, or marginal benefit of pollution equalized among all polluters. Optimal tax is at the level MSB=MSC. 3. Tradable emissions permits: licenses to emit limited quantities of pollutants that can be bought and sold by polluters. Those who can reduce pollution efficiently will do so, while others may prefer to buy licenses. Arthur Cecil Pigou (1877-1959), British economist In some cases taxes and tradable permits are not feasible, and environmental standards must be imposed. Sometimes some pollution may be so destructive that standards have to be used. Catalytic converters, no 7 smoking rules. Production, Consumption, and Externalities For some externalities, it is not possible to directly measure and control the amount of an externality. In such cases, we can focus directly on the activity, rather than its side effect. This is true for some kinds of pollution, eg. livestock rearing results in air pollution and “muck”, and for smoking. But it is common for external benefits – such as technology spillovers and education. Sometimes analysis in terms of units of externality (like pollution) and in terms of units of production, can be complementary. For policy purposes, if it is possible to measure externality it is usually better to deal with it directly – with taxes, for instance, than taxing the output of the good. Doing the latter will not create incentives to reduce pollution per unit of output. But if it is not possible to measure the externality, government policy may have to focus on the production and consumption of goods and services that give rise to externalities. 9 MBA shows marginal benefit of pollution to Plant A and MBB shows marginal benefit of pollution to Plant B. Without government intervention, each plant emits 600 tons. Cost of reducing emissions is lower for Plant A (MBA lies below MBB). Panel (a) shows the an environmental standard that requires both plants to cut emissions in half is inefficient, because it leaves the marginal benefit of pollution higher for Plant B than for Plant A. Panel (b) shows how an emissions tax achieves the same quantity of overall pollution efficiently: faced with an emissions tax of $200 per ton, both plants reduce pollution8 to the point where its marginal benefit is $200. Least cost way of achieving 600. Production, Consumption and Externalities Negative Externalities and Production Private versus Social Costs: When there are external costs, the marginal social cost of a good or activity exceeds the firms’s private marginal cost of producing the good. In the absence of government intervention, the industry typically produces too much of the good. The socially optimal quantity can be achieved by an optimal Pigouvian tax, equal to the marginal external cost, or by a system of tradable production permits. Without government action, the market produces QMKT >QOPT,. At QMKT, the market price, PMKT, is less than PMSC, the true marginal cost to society of production. An optimal Pigouvian tax on production, equal to its marginal external cost, moves the production to QOPT, resulting in lower output and a higher price to consumers. 10 Production, Consumption and Externalities Positive Externalities and Production Private versus social benefits: The most common examples of external benefits are technology spillovers. When these occur, the marginal social benefit of a good or activity exceeds the private marginal benefit to consumers, and too little of the good is produced in the absence of government intervention. The socially optimal quantity can be achieved by an optimal Pigouvan subsidy (a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits) equal to the marginal external benefit. Such a subsidy is an example of an industrial policy is a policy that supports industries believed to yield positive externalities. Some economists don’t like these because positive externalities are hard to measure and subsidies can become political in nature. Without government action, the market produces QMKT < QOPT,. At QMKT, the market price, PMKT, is less than PMSB, the true marginal benefit to society. An optimal Pigouvian subsidy to producers, equal to its marginal external benefit, moves the production to QOPT, resulting in higher output and a higher price to producers. 11 2