Beyond the CPI: An Augmented Cost of Living Index (ACOLI) William D. Nordhaus Yale University and NBER P.O. Box 208268, New Haven, CT 06520-8268 nordhaus@econ.yale.edu February 1, 1999 Abstract This note examines an augmented cost of living index (ACOLI) for the purpose of accounting for “augmented consumption” in real-income measures. Well-being includes not only conventional consumer purchases but also goods and services provided by employers, by mandated social regulations, and by tax-financed public goods. Because augmented consumption is often provided in ways that raise prices but not market incomes, deflating with conventional price indexes may understate real income growth. An exploratory application of the ACOLI approach to the United States during the 1960 - 1997 period suggests that the consumer price index (CPI) has grown about 19 percent faster than the ACOLI. This correction would reduce the estimated cost of living increase by 0.47 percent per year over the last 37 years. Keywords: consumer price index, public goods William D. Nordhaus is Professor of Economics, Yale University, P. O. Box 208269, New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8268 (email: nordhaus@econ.yale.edu). This paper was stimulated by a discussion with Zvi Griliches and comments of the participants in the NBER Productivity Program Meeting, April 1996. The author is grateful for suggestions by participants in that meeting, the Editor, and three anonymous referees. The electronic file is ACOL020199.wpd. Forthcoming: Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, April 1999. Vol 17, No. 2 Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 2 The United States is currently undertaking a searching inquiry into measuring “the cost of living.” Ideally, the cost of living would compare the minimum expenditure necessary to maintain the representative consumer at the same level of well-being at different time periods or sets of prices. As implemented by the consumer price index (CPI) with some recent exceptions, the U. S. measures the cost of living as an index of the price of a fixed basket of purchased goods and services in different time periods. It is widely recognized that the CPI has numerous flaws, such as substitution bias and inadequate correction for new goods and quality change. In this note, I address the question of whether too-narrow a definition of consumption may also distort our measures of real income. The question arises because the U. S. and other nations have begun moving beyond traditional measures of national output to include nonmarketed consumption (housework, services of government capital, environmental services, etc.) into their national accounts. The idea is to measure “augmented consumption,” which includes all consumption along with consumer purchases of marketed goods and services. Rough estimates indicate that augmented consumption will be at least twice as large as conventionally measured personal consumption expenditures. The major categories of augmented consumption are included in Table 1. Should we also move beyond the traditional definition of the cost of living to calculate the price of augmented consumption? I call such a measure the “augmented cost of living index,” or ACOLI. There are many important questions that would be addressed by an ACOLI. Such an index would correct for defects in the current conceptual definition of the CPI and would include the price of nonmarket and public goods. For example, an augmented measure would take into account the rapid growth in the consumption of health services financed by employer-financed fringe benefits; these enter into costs and prices but not into wages or incomes. An ACOLI would also capture the fact that some price-raising taxes or regulations have corresponding benefits and may not really raise the cost of living. The purpose of the present paper is to provide a conceptual definition of an extended cost of living index and to provide an exploratory application of the concept to include a limited number of goods and services. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 3 1. Analytical Background The basic idea behind the ACOLI is to measure how much consumer satisfaction in private and public goods can be bought with market incomes at different times and at the prices and taxes of those different periods. We often, for example, measure real wages as the ratio of money wages to the CPI. The difference between the ACOLI and traditional cost-of-living indexes is that the ACOLI includes certain goods and services that are provided by firms or governments and whose costs enter into market prices. A simple example is a benefit tax. Suppose the government builds a free bridge that is financed by gasoline taxes. The gasoline tax will raise prices and the CPI, and this will be counted as a decline in real wages and real incomes. (For this analysis, I assume that all cost-raising measures are fully shifted to product prices. This is inessential to the analysis, however, and different shifting assumptions are discussed below.) The counterpart of the tax is the benefit provided by the bridge. If the incremental benefits of the bridge just equal its incremental costs, then the apparently lower post-bridge real income will attain the same level of economic well-being as the higher pre-bridge real income. Hence, in terms of augmented income there is no rise in the cost of living. We would also not measure this as a cost-of-living increase if the bridge were built by a private firm; in this case, it would be a new good. The conceptual basis for an ACOLI extends the standard Konüs cost-of-living measure to include taxes along with nonmarket and public goods and services. A comprehensive survey is contained in Diewert (1983). In this extension, because of the spillover effects of taxes and public goods, we should recognize that there are multiple households and firms. The basic setup is the following. Assume that there are H households, h = 1,..., H, and J private goods and services, denoted by the vector x. Denote q as the vector of pretax market prices or nonmarket shadow prices attached to each of the private goods. J is the vector of taxes, so that the prices facing households are p = q + J. G is the vector of public goods. The preferences of household h are represented by the continuous utility function u = F (xh, G). We can represent the expenditure function of household h as E h(p,G,u h*), where uh* is the reference level of maximum attainable utility level for the reference expenditure level. We then define the price index for individual h as the ratio of expenditures necessary to maintain the reference utility level for the two periods, as defined in (1): h h Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 (1) Page 4 P h(p1, p0 ; G1, G0 , u h*) = E h(p1 , G1 ,u h*) /E h(p0 , G0 ,u h*) The major new element in this specification as compared to the standard one is that it incorporates public goods and taxes into the expenditures, prices, and utilities. The next step is to obtain a price index for all consumers. This can be accomplished in a number of ways. One approach, due to Pollak (1981) and Diewert (1983), is to calculate the expenditures necessary to keep all households at a reference level of the Bergson-Samuelson social welfare function. In this approach, let W = F(u1, ..., uH) be the social welfare function, while W* = F(u1*, ..., uH*) is the reference level of social welfare that is to be maintained. We then define the augmented cost of living index (ACOLI) as the ratio of the expenditures necessary to attain the reference level of social welfare (W*) with the new prices and public goods (p1 , G1 ) relative to the expenditures necessary to attain W* at the original levels (p0 , G0 ): (2) P( p1 , p0 ; G1, G0 ,W*) = E h( p1 ; G1 ,W*) / E h( p0 ; G0 ,W*) In (2), P is the augmented cost of living index for all households. This price index can be implemented in any of the standard ways (Laspeyres, Paasche, Fisher, superlative, etc.). By “expenditures” we mean the expenditures of market incomes. The main feature of the ACOLI is to recognize that price-raising elements which lead to increased levels of public goods, or private goods not purchased by consumers may raise conventionally measured price indexes such as the CPI while leaving the ACOLI unchanged. This is an important point because some measures will lower the measured standard of living as calculated with the CPI while leaving utility and therefore the ACOLI unchanged. 2. Examples of ACOLI Adjustments Some examples where the ACOLI would be conceptually preferable to conventionally measured price indexes are the following. For these examples, we assume that all households are identical except for position in the life cycle. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 5 CSocial regulation. Many government regulations raise costs and prices to consumers or producers. The counterpart of these higher prices is more stringent levels of environmental, health, and safety regulations. For example, a Department of Transportation regulation might require an airbag, which would raise the price of the car; or an EPA regulation might require reducing sulfur emissions, which would raise electricity prices. In these cases, the higher costs and prices are in effect purchasing private or public goods (automobile safety and reduced health damage from pollution). Current practice is generally to treat regulatory measures as price increases rather than as quality changes and therefore to pass them through into higher price indexes. The ACOLI, by contrast, would treat these higher prices as quality changes in the purchased goods. It is interesting to note that mandated environmental and safety requirements in automobiles actually are removed from the CPI and are treated in the way that we propose in this discussion. CEmployer-provided fringe benefits. Many consumption goods are provided by firms as tax-free fringe benefits to consumers. Suppose that firms provide their workers with employer-financed medical care that is worth one-dollar-of-utility per dollar-of-cost. It is assumed that these costs would be passed on into higher prices, and therefore raise the CPI. However, the higher prices would simply be a reflection of the fact that the medical care was being paid for by the firm rather than the worker. In this case, the ACOLI would treat the price-raising fringe benefit as a purchase of a service rather than as a price increase. (For simplicity, this paragraph assumes that the these fringe benefits are passed on in higher prices. The point applies equally well if the costs are shifted backwards to workers and result in lower wages. In this second case, measured real wages will be lower than without the fringe because the numerator of the real wage (W/P) declines. In the forward-shifting case, the denominator increases. In either case, the measured decline in the real wage or real income would be a biased measure of economic welfare because it omits the value of the fringe benefit.) CSocial insurance taxes. Say that employment taxes are levied and the revenues from those taxes provide public pensions or medical care for retired workers. In the simplest case, assume that the benefits are actuarially fair, so that the present value of benefits corresponds to the present value of employees’ taxes. Here again, costs and prices will rise, but there are offsetting consumption or future-income benefits. For social security pensions, public savings would be replacing private savings and these measures are in reality financial transactions that raise prices. The ACOLI would treat social insurance as a financial transaction rather than a cost-raising item and would therefore Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 6 omit these costs from the ACOLI. (As was discussed in the parenthetical point in the last paragraph, it is assumed that social insurance taxes are shifted forward, but the bias in the CPI would be the same if they were shifted backward. Also, we assume that property taxes are shifted forward, and the discussion about shifting applies equally to these taxes. Finally, note that income taxes do not drive a wedge between market factor costs and product prices, so no adjustment in the ACOLI is necessary for income taxes.) These examples share a common point. We want to compare the expenditures needed to attain a given level of economic welfare with and without the price-raising measure. But these higher prices are in reality nonmarket transactions which provide health services, environmental protection, or future pensions. In other words, what appear to be price increases are actually purchases of goods, services, or assets by entities outside the household sector. Because there are (in these idealized cases) no changes in utility, the augmented cost of living index in (2) is unchanged even though the CPI increases. These measures lower conventionally measured real incomes (nominal incomes divided by the CPI) but leave consumer well-being unchanged. The major difficulty with actually measuring the ACOLI arises because we have very poor measures of the benefits of many of the expenditure or mandated cost programs. In the case of private expenditures, we feel confident (probably, too confident) that the increment to consumer welfare is one dollar per dollar of additional expenditure. For public goods or transfer programs, this linkage is much more indirect; we cannot be confident that the benefit from a mandated regulation, a social insurance program, or an employer-provided fringe benefit will be on a one-for-one basis with the expenditures. Whether the goods are worth 100 cents on the dollar is particularly questionable for mandated private goods like health care or appliance standards; for public goods like smallpox vaccinations or air-pollution regulation, the benefit-cost relationship is controversial but could bias our ACOLI calculations either upward or downward. 3. Narrow v. Broad ACOLIs There are two different approaches to calculating an augmented cost of living index. The first, which is a “broad ACOLI,” includes the augmented items in consumption and income and then recalculates a price index for augmented consumption. A second approach, which is called a “narrow ACOLI” and followed here, strips the augmented items out of consumption and then calculates the price of narrow or “stripped” Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 7 consumption. The first approach would be preferable, but we do not have the data to implement it, so this paper follows the second approach. For this section, we separate total consumption into two parts. For simplicity, “private” consumption is defined as those items that are bought by consumers (cars, pizzas, shoes, etc.). “Public” consumption are those that are purchased by sectors other than consumers. Public consumption comprises primarily the three areas discussed above — government-provided goods, fringe benefits, and tax-financed social insurance. The derivation of the ACOLI can be explained as follows. Suppose that C1 and C2 are the quantities of private and public goods, p1 is the market price of the private good, and q1 and q2 are the “true” prices of the two goods. We cannot directly observe either of the “true” prices of the two goods or the quantity of the public good, but we can observe p1, C1, q1C1, and q2C2 . The crucial assumption is that the public good is paid for by a tax which increases the price of the private good. Hence the spending on the private good is given by: (3) p1C1 = q1C1 + q2C2. In other words, total spending on the private good covers both the cost of the private good and the cost of the public good. We would like to calculate a price index that covers both consumption goods (the broad ACOLI), but this is not possible with the given information. However, by using existing data we can derive the true price of the private good, and this is the narrow ACOLI. The narrow ACOLI (q1) can be derived from (3): q1 = p1(1+ q2C2 /q1C1)-1 which gives (4) )log(q1) = )log(p1) - )log(1 + q2C2 /q1C1) Ñ )log(p1) - )( q2C2 /q1C1) In other words, the rate of change of the narrow ACOLI can be calculated by correcting the measured price index to reflect the change in the share of the public good in total consumption spending. Table 2 shows the ratio of augmented to stripped consumption [(q1C1+ q2C2 )/q1C1]. As shown in equation (4), the change in this ratio provides an Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 8 estimate of the bias from measuring real wages or real income using the CPI to deflate market incomes. What is the difference between the narrow and the broad ACOLIs? If the augmented items (q2C2) have a dollar-of-benefit per dollar-of-cost, then the narrow ACOLI will to a first-order approximation be a good price index for both narrow and broad consumption. However, to the extent that the benefit-cost ratios for expenditures on augmented consumption diverge from unity, the narrow ACOLI will only provide an accurate measure of real income in terms of narrowly defined consumption. In this case, the trend in total consumption will not be adequately captured by the narrow ACOLI correction. Augmented consumption will be growing faster or slower than the ACOLI measure indicates depending upon whether the benefit-cost ratio of the omitted items is above or below unity. To summarize, the augmented cost of living index (ACOLI) is the appropriate price index or deflator to apply to market incomes for calculating economic well-being, where well-being includes not only privately purchased goods and services but also those goods and services provided by price-raising, non-household expenditures. The narrow ACOLI provides an appropriate price index for private consumption in all cases and an appropriate price index for augmented consumption only in the case where the benefitcost ratios for public goods and fringe benefits are equal to unity. 4. Illustrative Estimates of the ACOLI Adjustment How important is the difference between the ACOLI and the CPI or other conventional price indexes? This question is a major policy issue, yet there is apparently no empirical research on this topic. The answer is of considerable importance in light of the ongoing debate about the bias in the CPI as well as the more general debate about appropriate indexes to use for indexing federal programs. To illustrate the quantitative importance, I will provide order-of-magnitude estimates of the difference between the CPI and an ACOLI over the last four decades. For this example, I correct conventional cost of living indexes for four biases as follows: (1) Social insurance taxes are considered to be financial transfers rather than price-increasing taxes. (2) Employer-provided fringe benefits are assumed to provide consumer goods and services on a dollar-of-utility per dollar-of-cost basis; hence, the higher prices induced by the increased costs are assumed to purchase an equivalent value Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 9 of consumption. (3) Indirect business taxes are assumed to be benefit taxes which increase the quantity of public goods on a dollar-of-benefit per dollar-of-cost basis. (4) Mandated costs from social regulation are assumed to purchase public goods or publicly mandated private goods on a dollar-of utility per dollar-of-cost basis. Clearly, each of these assumptions need further research, and there are particularly tricky issues involving the valuation of tax-free fringe benefits, forced saving, and the benefits of public goods. To examine the effect of augmenting the concept of consumption, we look primarily at conventional consumption and “stripped” consumption for the years 1960 and 1997 and years in between. To compare conventional measurement of real income or real wages with measures of augmented real income, we subtract all four items listed in the last paragraph from consumption, which gives us “stripped consumption” (that is, stripped consumption is consumption less the four price-raising items which do not decrease consumer utilities). We then calculate the growth of the ratio of conventional consumption to stripped consumption. In addition, for comparative purposes, I have made the calculation of stripped income for both net national product and for national income (which is national output calculated at factor prices). These alternative concepts provide an estimate of a deflator for all market incomes instead of only for wages. The sources of the data from the national income and product accounts are the following: Social insurance taxes are “employer contributions for social insurance.” Employer-provided fringe benefits are “other labor income.” Indirect business taxes are that item. Pollution abatement spending is taken from Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business, various issues. The cost of personal pollution abatement expenditures on motor vehicles is subtracted from the total to reflect the correction of the CPI for mandated pollution abatement spending. An additional correction should be made for mandated automobile safety equipment, but no estimates are available for that cost. Non-pollution social regulation includes nuclear power, occupational safety, highway safety, pharmaceuticals, equal opportunity, and consumer products. The estimates for 1988 are from Robert Hahn, “The Costs and Benefits of Regulation: Review and Synthesis,” Yale Journal on Regulation, vol. 8, 1991, pp. 233-287. For 1988/89, pollution abatement is $88.5 billion while non-pollution social regulation is $38.3 billion. I calculate the cost of non-pollution social regulation for other years by assuming that the ratio of total social regulation to pollution abatement expenditures is constant. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 10 Table 2 shows the results, and the detailed calculations are provided in Table 3. The results indicate that an augmented cost of living index shows dramatically different results from a standard price index. The total upward bias over the period 1960-97 is 19 percent. This indicates that stripped consumption grew 19 percent more rapidly than conventionally measured consumption. The upward bias was around 0.47 percent per year. The bias will differ for different price indexes depending upon the definition of consumption. For example, the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) in the national income and product accounts include employer provided fringe benefits in consumption, so that part of the bias would not be present when applying the PCE price index to an income figure that include the employer fringes. On the other hand, no price index makes the ACOLI correction for indirect business taxes or public goods. Table 2 also shows the breakdown of the bias among the four components. Threequarters of the bias is due to fringe benefits and contributions to social insurance, with one-quarter due to social regulations and very little to indirect business taxes. Table 3 shows the breakdown by sub-periods. The bias was substantial in all sub-periods except during the Reagan administration, during which the bias was actually negative. In the most recent period, from 1989 to 1997, the bias was very close to that of the entire period. There are a number of reservations that apply to this calculation. A great deal of further refinement is necessary to put an ACOLI on a sound theoretical and empirical framework. More work needs to be done on estimating each of the components of the ACOLI correction and on determining whether these fringe benefits and public goods in fact deliver benefits on a dollar-of-benefit per dollar-of-cost basis. There are traditional index-number issues involving differences in the ACOLI for different groups as well as the substitution induced by tax and price changes. The shifting assumptions need more refinement. These numbers should be put in the context of the findings of the Boskin Commission, which estimated that the upward bias in the CPI from index-number problems, outlet bias, and quality change was in 1996 1.1 percent per annum. It is striking that over the last quarter century conventional price indexes may have overestimated the true cost of living by a total of 0.47 percent per year because of the omission of fringe benefits and mandated public goods. This number is a significant fraction of current estimates of the bias of the CPI. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Author's footnote: Page 11 Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 12 Table 1. Categories in “Augmented Consumption” Private goods Marketed Purchased by households (food, clothing)* Purchased by other sectors (health care, pension plans)** Nonmarket Goods and services (leisure, housework) Other (longevity, improved health status) Publicly provided private goods Market (bridges, town beaches)*** Nonmarket (crime, drugs, personal safety) Public goods Environmental, health, and safety (pollution abatement expenditures, FDA certification)*** Science and technology (space exploration) Note: *Items with one asterisk are consumer expenditures covered by the CPI. **Items with one or two asterisks are in personal consumption expenditures in the national income accounts. ***Items with one, two, or three asterisks are in the ACOLI concept measured here. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 13 Table 2. Estimated Bias to Inflation Corrected by Using Augmented Cost of Living Index, 1960-1997 A. Total Difference between ACOLI and Standard Price Index Output Measure Ratio of conventional to stripped measure of output 1960 Net national product National income Consumption 1.172 1.059 1.264 1997 1.293 1.179 1.504 Ratio 1.104 1.114 1.190 Bias in inflation rate, 1960-97 (in basis points per year, average annual rate) 27 29 47 B. Contribution of Different Components for Consumption ACOLI Component Amount of Bias, 1960-97 (basis points per year) Contributions to social insurance Supplements to wages and salaries Social regulations Indirect business taxes 15 17 12 3 Total 47 For derivation, see Table 3. The calculation of the contribution of the components in part B is a geometric mean of the individual indexes or contributions calculated from consumption and stripped consumption as a base. Source: For derivation, see Table 3. The calculation of the contribution of the components in part B is a geometric mean of the individual indexes or contributions calculated from consumption and stripped consumption as a base. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 14 Table 3. Data Underlying Calculation of ACOLI 1960 Output measure Net national product National income Consumption 1970 1981 1989 1997 Ratio of conventional to stripped measure of output 1.172 1.059 1.264 1.235 1.110 1.378 1.290 1.175 1.471 1.290 1.180 1.433 1.293 1.179 1.504 Bias in conventional price indexes (basis points per year) 1960-70 1970-81 1981-89 1989-97 53 40 -0 3 48 52 5 -1 87 60 -33 61 Net national product National income Consumption Underlying data (billions of dollars) 1960 1970 1981 1989 1997 Gross national product 529.8 1042.0 3150.6 5452.8 6922.4 Net national product 473.2 935.0 2762.1 4827.4 7192.2 National income (NI) 429.8 840.6 2501.4 4397.3 6649.7 Consumption 332.2 648.1 1941.3 3594.8 4867.5 1960-97 27 29 47 Corrections to obtain the augmented social cost of living: Employer contributions to social insurance Other labor income Social regulations Price additions to NI 12.6 34.3 146.8 280.4 408.4 11.2 0.0 23.8 32.5 16.6 83.4 153.0 72.5 372.3 273.1 117.3 670.8 416.6 186.8 1011.8 Indirect business taxes Price additions to NNP and C 45.5 69.3 94.3 177.7 249.3 621.6 414.7 1085.5 619.4 1631.2 403.9 406.0 262.9 757.3 757.2 470.4 2140.5 2129.1 1319.7 3741.9 3726.5 2509.3 5561.0 5637.9 3236.3 NNP less price additions NI less price additions C less price additions Sources: All data except non-pollution social regulation from U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, various issues. See text for description of transformations. Data on non-pollution social regulation for 1988 are from Robert Hahn and scaled to other years assuming the ratio of total to pollution abatement is constant over time. Personal expenditures on pollution abatement for motor vehicles are subtracted from social regulation to reflect the adjustment in the CPI. Beyond the CPI: February 1, 1999 Page 15 References Diewert, W. E. (1983), “The Theory of the Cost-of-Living Index and the Measurement of Welfare Changes,” in W. E. Diewert and C. Montmarquette, eds., Price Level Measurement, Ottawa, Statistics Canada, 163-239. Pollak, Robert A. (1981), “The Social Cost of Living Index,” Journal of Public Economics, 15, 311-336.