Wealth Effects of Accretive Acquisitions: Evidence from Asian REITs Date: December 1, 2007 Joseph T.L. Ooi#, Seow-Eng Ong and Poh-Har Neo Department of Real Estate School of Design and Environment National University of Singapore 4 Architecture Drive Singapore 117566 # contact author: rstooitl@nus.edu.sg Wealth Effects of Accretive Acquisitions: Evidence from Asian REITs Abstract Mergers and acquisitions are important avenues for a firm to grow. Whilst many theories have been advanced to justify why REIT should acquire properties, this paper focuses on the yield-accretive acquisition strategy adopted by many REITs in Asia to boost earnings and dividends for their shareholders. We offer some initial evidence on the effect of accretive acquisitions on shareholders wealth by analyzing 284 property acquisitions made by REITs listed in Japan and Singapore between 2002 and 2007. The event-study shows that acquisition announcements convey information useful for the valuation of acquiring REITs. We observe that acquisition announcement enhances the acquiring REIT stock price by 0.29% over a three-day period. Our regression analysis shows that the magnitude of the abnormal return is dependent on whether the acquisition is yield-accretive or dilutive. The evidence supports the view that the markets in Asia like and reward acquisitions that lead to higher earnings and dividends for the shareholders. Key words : Asia REITs, accretive acquisitions, event-study JEL Classification: G11, G14, G34, Wealth Effects of Accretive Acquisitions: Evidence from Asian REITs Introduction Acquisitions and mergers are important events in the calendar of a corporation. Although they provide a fast lane for the firm to grow, acquisition and mergers decisions consume massive corporate resources and expose shareholders to high uncertainty. Many theories have been advanced in the corporate finance literature to explain why acquisitions and mergers take place. These include the differential efficiency theory, which prescribes that more efficient firms will acquire less efficient firms and realize gains by improving their efficiency; the operating synergy theory which postulates that there are economies of scale or of scope that can be achieved through mergers and acquisitions; and the market power theory which holds that merger gains are the result of increased concentration leading to collusion and monopoly effects (Weston, Siu and Johnson, 2001). From the shareholders’ perspective, the main concern is whether corporate acquisitions and mergers create or destroy value. To the extent that firms adopt shareholder wealth maximization as the penultimate goal of corporate investment decisions, acquisitions and mergers are expected to produce a rate of return that at least equals the cost of capital. In theory, the net present value (NPV) is the best criteria for evaluating new ventures because it is consistent with shareholder wealth maximization. However, in practice, firms focus a lot on the impact of acquisitions on current earnings, particularly earnings per share (EPS), which they perceive to have a positive impact on equity valuation. Corporate managers pursue accretive acquisitions because they get to report higher earnings and distribute more dividends to their shareholders. Much anecdotal evidence suggests that managers try to maintain a pattern of increasing earnings. Burgstahler and Dichev (1997), for example, cite several incidents of managers who emphasized the importance of earnings in the opening lines of the management 1 discussion section of the annual reports.1 Andrade (1999, p.1) went further as to suggest that many practitioners are obsessed with EPS because they believe that “analysts and investors will often focus excessively on EPS and EPS growth in valuing securities, almost ‘blindly’ applying a multiple, such as a P/E or market-to-book ratio, to the reported figures. Therefore, the story goes, firms that engage in transactions which depress their EPS growth will be penalized with lower valuations in the market”. Financial theorists will, however, counter that the higher earnings associated with accretive acquisition are not free since shareholders are exposed to higher business and financial risks. Furthermore, the efficient market hypothesis prescribes that the market will not be fooled by accounting measures to boost corporate earnings. Despite what corporate finance theory has to say, earnings accretion remains a major factor in acquisition decisions. During a roundtable discussion hosted by the Financial Management Association, Wessels (2006, p. 63) highlighted, “when considering an acquisition of another company, one of the very first questions a company will ask is whether the transaction is ‘EPS accretive’ or ‘EPS dilutive’. There is no way around it; a senior executive wants the answer to this question”. In order for a proposed acquisition or merger to be acceptable to existing shareholders, Reiss and Pizak (2000, p. 214) maintained that the transaction must be “accretive” to the existing shareholders; that is, “there must be a belief that the acquisition or merger will result in increased growth, flow from operations, cash flow, dividends and share price”. A number of studies in the accounting literature have shown that managers placed great importance on earnings management and that market may be influenced by accounting numbers. Burgstahler and Dichev (1997) provide empirical evidence that firms do manage reported earnings to avoid earnings decreases and losses. Whilst the wealth effects of mergers and acquisitions have been extensively studied, the economic gains associated with accretive acquisitions have not been examined. This is 1 For example, in its 1994 annual report, Tenneco’s CEO stated: “I must emphasize that all our strategic actions are guided by and measured against the goal of delivering consistently high increase in earnings over the long term.” Similarly, in the release of 1994 earnings, Bank of America’s CEO commented that “Increasing EPS was our most important objective of the year”. 2 due primarily to the difficulties researchers faced in determining the direct impact of acquisitions on earnings.2 As noted by Andrade (1999), it is not easy to isolate the effects of an acquisition on corporate earnings because of accounting and valuation uncertainties. Particularly, mergers and acquisitions are often accompanied by simultaneous spin-offs, corporate reorganizations, capital restructuring or distribution of extraordinary dividends to the shareholders, which make it difficult to isolate the wealth effects due to earnings accretion. The possibility of over-payment would further complicate any attempts to measure the earning accretion associated with an acquisition. For example, if the acquirer grossly overpay for a company, there is a high likelihood that the reported EPS will be diluted. Moreover, valuation of a business as a going-concern is not easy due to the subjectivity involved in estimating the value of the target’s intangible assets such as goodwill and future growth opportunities. The valuation problem is compounded further when the acquiring company’s stocks are used to finance the takeover or merger.. The literature typically indicates that bidder abnormal returns are expected to be larger for cash transactions than for securities transactions. 3 Finally, there is the contentious issue of purchase versus pooling methods of accounting related to mergers.4 Property acquisitions by REITs, however, provide a unique opportunity for us to overcome these difficulties. First, property deals are comparatively simple as they do not involve massive reorganizations at the corporate level. Thus, the accounting of a property acquisition is relatively straightforward. Second, the intrinsic value of the targets can be 2 One exception is a working paper by Andrade (1999) who found that EPS accretion has a positive and statistically significant effect on the acquirers’ abnormal performance. 3 This follows Myers and Majluf’s (1984) pecking order theory which postulates that an acquisition with stocks signals the bidder’s belief that the stock as overvalued. Similarly, Hansen (1987) and Eckbo and Thorburn (2000) develop models that postulate that when there is high uncertainty on the target’s real value, the bidder should make a stock offer to force the target to share part of the risk of overpaying for the target. 4 US GAAP prescribes two different methods of accounting for mergers, namely pooling-ofinterests (pooling) and purchase. In the pooling transaction, the two companies merely combine their existing financial statement together. There are no write-ups of assets to account for the re-valuation of the target implicit in the price paid for the acquisition. In a purchase deal, on the other hand, target assets are re-valued and recorded on the combined company’s balance sheets at their new, fair market value. In addition, any difference between the price paid for the target and the fair market value of its assets is incorporated as goodwill (Andrade, 1999; pp. 7-8) 3 determined more accurately due to the tangible nature of the assets involved. REITs also do not pay corporate taxes and hence, any observed wealth effects will not be confounded by tax considerations. In this study, we specifically focus on the REIT sector in Asia because of their heavy emphasis on “yield-accretive” acquisitions, which essentially involve buying buildings that generate higher rental yield than that of the REIT portfolio; thus, increasing the yield of the combined portfolio. 5 Conversely, acquisition deals which are “dilutive” would not be well received. For illustration, Whiting (2007) suggests that shareholders of a REIT yielding 6.2% would raise their eyebrows if their trust manager opted to buy a property with a yield of 6% because the deal would result in a reduction in their dividend payouts. Moreover, the UPREIT or umbrella partnership REIT scheme, which is commonly used in the U.S. to transfer the ownership of private properties to a public REIT on a tax-deferred basis, is not permitted in Asia. Under the UPREIT structure, the REIT does not own the underlying assets directly, but rather it acts as the general partner of the umbrella partnership that owns interests in the properties. The UPREIT structure also allows U.S. REITs to finance their acquisitions through the issuance of “operating partnership units”.6 Since cash payment is the primary mode of payment for property transactions in Asia, our study avoids the necessity to consider the stock value of the bidding REITs as well as the reverse effect of stock financing when the target is privately held (Chung, 1998). Furthermore, we have information on both the purchase price and valuation of the target properties. This enables us to identify instances of REITs over-paying for an asset and thereby, control for any spurious correlation between over-payment and earnings dilution. In sum, our sample provides a cleaner testing ground for examining the wealth effects of accretive acquisitions. 5 As an illustration, the mission statement of a major REIT in Asia openly states, “We constantly seek investment grade and yield-accretive acquisitions to grow and diversify our portfolio…With our yieldaccretive acquisitions, proactive asset management and optimal capital structure strategies, returns for our shareholders are maximized.” 6 For a discussion on the UPREIT structure, see Campbell (2002). Due to their special tax treatment, REITs in the U.S. would typically pay a premium for cash transactions in order to offset the seller’s tax burden. Hardin and Wolverton (1999) observe that REITs tend to overpay when they acquire apartments. 4 Our empirical study relies on a sample of 228 acquisition deals announced by REITs listed in Japan (JREIT) and Singapore (SREIT). Underlining the importance of the “accretive” motive in their acquisition decisions, the data reveals that four out of every five acquisitions announced by Asian REITs are accretive. The event-study results show a positive market reaction to acquisition news. Furthermore, when the acquisitions are divided according to their impact on the portfolio yield, we find that the sub-sample comprising accretive acquisitions registered significantly positive abnormal returns. In contrast, the returns for the sub-sample of dilutive acquisitions recorded significantly negative returns around their announcement dates. The positive impact of accretive acquisitions on stock valuation continues to persist even after we control for other factors that have been found in prior studies to influence abnormal gains associated with acquisition announcements. The paper is organized as follows. To give some background information, the next section briefly reviews the development and rapid growth of the REIT markets in Asia. The third section, which presents the research methodology, covers the data collection process as well as our measurements of the abnormal returns and yield accretion associated with each sampled acquisition. The fourth section discusses the empirical results and presents the robustness tests. The fifth section contains the conclusions. REIT Markets in Asia Since their emergence in 2001, REITs have spread widely across the continent of Asia. Japan, South Korea and Singapore were amongst the first Asian countries to adopt REIT. Other jurisdictions which have since joined the REIT bandwagon include Thailand, Taiwan, Malaysia and Hong Kong. The REIT concept is now openly embraced as a strategic initiative for restructuring real estate markets and tapping international capital in Asia. Within five years, 93 REITs have been listed in various stock markets across Asia with a combined capitalization of close to US$ 83 billion (Table 1). Several countries, such as Philippines, China and India, are reported to be deliberating on the appropriate 5 REIT framework to adopt. As the number of REITs continues to increase rapidly, the market capitalization for Asia REITs is estimated to reach US$ 200 billion within the next decade. [ Table 1 ] The phenomenal growth of REIT markets in Asia can be attributed to a boom in the number of new IPOs as well as to the aggressive growth-by-acquisition strategy adopted by most of the newly listed REITs. The growth and market performance of the REIT sector in Japan and Singapore, which are by far the two largest REIT markets in Asia, have been robust. Since their initiation, REIT stocks have registered annual capital growth of 10.2% and 38.2% in Japan and Singapore, respectively. On top of the impressive capital growth, investors also earn an annualized dividend of 3.84% for JREIT stocks and 4.79% for SREIT stocks. Unlike REITs in the U.S. where dividend income comprises 71% of the total returns (Gyourko and Siegel, 1994), property returns in Asia have traditionally been dominated by capital growth with prime real estate commanding low capitalization rate. The low rental yield imposes an obstacle for REIT sponsors and managers in the region to cater to the demand of international and institutional investors who are accustomed to high dividend paying REIT stocks. Thus, one popular strategy adopted by Asian REITs to increase their earnings and dividends is engaging in accretive acquisitions. 7 Between September 2002 and April 2007, JREITs and SREITs spent a combined sum of US$24.58 billion in property acquisitions. This amount represented more than one-third of their market capitalization as at April 2007. Our data collection begins by shifting through the local press for news of acquisitions made by REITs in Japan and Singapore. The event date is taken as the first day the 7 Merrill Lynch research reported that the aggregate investment portfolio of SREITs increased by 83% in 2006 and half of the growth are attributed to new acquisitions. In addition, the dividend per share (DPS) of the average SREIT grew by 13.8% in 2005. Only four percentage points of the dividend growth were attributed to rent escalation at building owned by REITs, while nearly 10 percentage points of the growth came from yield accretive acquisitions (Whiting, 2007). 6 announcement first appeared in the publication. If the announcement is made on a nontrading day, the next trading day after the announcement is used as the event day. We exclude from our analysis closely clustered acquisitions, where a REIT acquires two or more properties within 21 days, because the returns surrounding the event window cannot be isolated. In the case of acquisition announcements involving more than one property, we aggregate the value of the acquired properties and treated them as a single event. Some observations had to be omitted due to overlapping event periods and incomplete information. Our final sample covers 228 acquisitions made by JREITs and SREITs between September 2002 and April 2007. The average size of the acquisitions was US$ 75.3 million, ranging from US$ 1.9 million to US$ 814.9 million. The average transaction size made by JREITs (US$ 75.4 million) was not significantly different from that registered by SREITs (US$ 75.0 million).8 REITs traded on the other stock exchanges in Asia are not included in the study either because they have a short trading history (Hong Kong and Malaysia) or because they do not engage in acquisitions due to their close-end structure (South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand). Also, REITs in Japan and Singapore are usually formed by acquiring properties from property holding/development entities. After their formation and listing, most REITs continue to transact with these “related parties”, which include either a director, CEO or controlling shareholder of the REIT manager or a controlling shareholder of the REIT itself (Koh, 2006). Our sample shows that one-third of the deals involved REITs acquiring properties from a related party. Such deals are exposed to potential conflict of interests between the shareholders and the REIT managers and sponsors.9 8 In terms of aggregate transaction value, the most active buyer was Japan Retail Fund Investment, which acquired US$ 3.50 billion worth of properties over the sample period. This is followed by Nippon Building Fund (US$ 2.64 billion) and Japan Real Estate Investment (US$ 2.01 billion). The largest buyers in Singapore are CapitaMall Trust Limited and Ascendas REIT, which acquired US$ 1.59 billion and US$ 1.45 billion worth of real estate, respectively. 9 In one instance, the Japan Securities and Exchange Surveillance Commission called for disciplinary action against a JREIT manager and its parent company because the REIT had not conducted proper due diligence before acquiring some properties from its parent (Whiting, 2007). The regulations in Singapore are stricter with respect to “interested person transactions”. In addition to requiring two independent valuations for each property to be acquired, an independent financial expert, usually an 7 Research Methodology The main aim of this study is to examine the wealth effects of accretive acquisitions from the perspective of the acquiring firm shareholders. We carry out empirical tests to determine whether the sector’s apparent obsession with earnings accretion is beneficial to the shareholders. Based on the traditional valuation framework, the null hypothesis of our empirical research is, “the abnormal gains surrounding acquisition announcements are not related to the degree of accretion resulting from the acquisition.” In other words, the null hypothesis is that the accretion story does not affect stock price and hence, we do not expect to see a significant regression coefficient for yield accretion. However, if the market believes in the accretive story, the abnormal returns surrounding announcements of accretive acquisitions will be significantly higher. Conversely, if the stock market thinks the accretive story is detrimental to stockholders wealth, then an inverse relationship could be expected. The empirical research is carried out as follows: First, we measure the yield accretion and abnormal returns associated with each acquisition announcements. Next, both univariate and multivariate analyses are carried out to examine the relationship between yield accretion and the abnormal returns observed around the announcement day. Yield Accretion For the purpose of this paper, accretion (and dilution) is defined as the change in the portfolio yield as a direct consequence of an acquisition. To illustrate the mechanics of an accretive acquisition, consider REIT A which has an existing asset portfolio worth US$500 million. It announces an acquisition of a US$ 50 million property with a 7% net investment bank, has to be appointed to render an opinion stating whether the transaction is on normal commercial terms and whether it is prejudicial to the shareholders (Koh, 2006). 8 yield.10 The financial positions pre- and post-acquisition are set out in Table 2. Assuming the property is purchased at a fair market value, the REIT’s post-acquisition portfolio value would simply be the sum of its pre-acquisition portfolio value and the market value of the acquired property. The new acquisition will increase the REIT portfolio value to US$ 550 and its net property income to US$ 28.50 million. The proposed acquisition is yield accretive with REIT A’s stockholders enjoying a higher post-acquisition yield, rising from 5.00% to 5.18%.11 [ Table 2] The yield accretion ( δ k REIT ) can be represented mathematically by the following expression: ⎡ k REIT ( MVREIT ) + k ppty ( MV ppty ) ⎤ ⎥ − k REIT MVREIT + MV ppty ⎣⎢ ⎦⎥ δ k REIT = ⎢ (1) where k REIT and k ppty are the yield of the pre-acquisition yield of the REIT portfolio and target property respectively, whilst MV REIT and MV ppty are their respective market values. The mathematical expression (1) can be simplified by denoting MV ppty / ( MV REIT + MV ppty ) as λ . Then MV REIT / ( MV REIT + MV ppty ) will be equal to (1- λ ) and the yield accretion definition will be: δ k REIT = (k ppty − k REIT ) λ (2) Equation (2) shows that the combined yield will increase so long as the yield of the acquired property is higher than the existing portfolio’s. Conversely, when the yield of 10 The net property yield is often referred to as the building’s capitalization rate, or cap rate in short. It is represented by the ratio of the building’s annual rental income after expenses over its purchase price. 11 After the acquisition, the weighted average property yield of the REIT would increase to 5.18% (5.0%xUS$500m/US$550m + 7%xUS$50.0m/US$ 550.0m). 9 the target property is lower than the yield of the REIT portfolio, the resulting effect is dilutive on earnings. Besides the differential yield between the acquired property and the existing portfolio, (k ppty − k REIT ) , Equation (2) indicates that the accretive effect is also dictated by λ , the relative size of the target property (over the combined portfolio size). Going back to our earlier illustration in Table 2, the property yield is two percentage points higher than the portfolio yield. Although the target may cost $50 million, it is still small relative to the size of the REIT portfolio. Consequently, despite the significantly higher yield of the target property, the acquisition only resulted in a marginal yield accretion of 18 basis points. To compute the accretion effect of each acquisition, we had to collect information on the market value and net operating income (NOI) of the asset portfolio as well as the purchase price and net income of the acquired property. The market value and the NOI of the existing portfolio, which is represented by the annualized net property income generated by the REIT portfolio prior to the acquisition, are extracted from the last published financial statement of the individual REITs. Since REITs revalue their properties at least once every year, we do not anticipate the book- and market-value of their assets to be significantly different. In cases where an individual REIT announced more than one acquisition event during the financial period, we adjust the value and NOI of the asset portfolio incrementally to take into account the earlier acquisitions announced. For price and income information on the target property, we consulted websites and public statements released by the acquiring REITs. The net yield of the target property is measured by the ratio of its NOI over the purchase price, excluding fees and acquisition expenses paid by the acquiring REIT. 12 The NOI includes non-rental property income, such as revenue from promotion and advertising, income from car park, and additional 12 Where specific information on an acquired property is not available, one could impute its market value and income by taking the differences in the portfolio value and income pre- and post-acquisition, particularly in cases where only one acquisition took place in between the financial period. However, we decided against adopting this measure because it would incorporate any synergy between the target property and existing portfolio of the REITs in between the accounting periods. Furthermore, where asset revaluation exercises have been carried out within the same financial period, it is difficult to attribute how much of the change in portfolio value is due to capital appreciation of the incumbent assets and how much of it is due to new additions to the portfolio. 10 charges on tenants for items such as air conditioning, cleaning and other services. It takes into account costs such as building management costs and utilities, but not debt leverage. Note that the yield accretion as defined in Equation (2) reflects simply the “accounting” accretion effect when the acquired property is merged with the REIT’s portfolio. This definition is advantageous because it isolates the “accounting” effect from the “real” effects due to synergy or opportunistic buying at a low price, which we can accommodate separately in the multivariate regressions. In addition, our definition of the REIT’s portfolio yield is equivalent to dividing the earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA) of the REIT by its enterprise value (equity plus debt minus cash). It has the advantage of not being affected by debt, interest costs, taxation or any extraordinary gains or losses, or the REIT’s dividend payout policy.13 Table 3 reports the yield accretion for the 228 acquisitions. On average, the acquisitions are accretive because the yield of the average target (6.28%) is higher than the average portfolio’s (4.64%). However, despite the 164 basis points differential, the mean accretion of the acquisitions was only 4.3 basis points. This is because λ , the relative size of the target over the post-acquisition portfolio, is only 5.45%. Comparing the acquisitions made by JREITs and SREITs, the accretive effect seems to be stronger for JREITs, due to the wider yield gap between the target property and the REIT portfolio. This is, however, mitigated by a smaller size leverage ( λ ) effect for JREITs, 4.10% as compared to 8.37% for SREITs. Table 3 implies that as REITs grow larger, the accretive effect of subsequent acquisitions will diminish if there is no corresponding increase in the acquisition size.14 13 Andrade (1999) also justifies that EBITDA captures the profitability of the acquirer, while avoiding any of the spurious merger accounting effects, such as the extra depreciation and amortization due to purchase, as well as the financing choices made by the acquirer (cash, debt or stock). 14 This corresponds to the “bootstrap effect” cautioned by Brealey and Myers (2000, p.949), that “in order to keep fooling the investors, you must continue to expand by merger (acquisition) at the same compound rate. Obviously you cannot do this forever; one day expansion must slow down or stop. Then earnings growth will cease, and your house of cards will fall”. 11 [ Table 3 ] Event-study Methodology A number of studies have examined market reactions to acquisition and merger announcements, but the evidence remains inconclusive. If an acquisition is a positive NPV venture and to the extent that the positive NPV represents gains to the shareholders of the firm, one should expect to see an increase in the stock price of the acquiring firm. Furthermore, corporate acquisitions and mergers have often been justified on the basis of synergy or the acquirer’s ability to extract value from the target.15 However, a number of studies have reported returns to acquirers that are insignificantly different from zero.16 In line with the present value hypothesis, the authors of these studies contend that in a competitive market where there are numerous buyers in the market and the product is unique, the economic gain is captured mostly by the vendor. Consequently, shareholders of the target firm would enjoy positive wealth effects, but shareholders of the acquiring firm should not expect any abnormal gains associated with acquisition announcements. In a hotly contested market the winning bidder could instead end up paying a premium, which could lead to a reduction in its stock price (Campbell, Ghosh and Sirmans, 2001; Sahin, 2005). Most of the prior studies on the wealth effects of real estate acquisitions are based on U.S. data, where the REIT sector is considerably more mature. In addition, a number of the acquisitions involved REITs either acquiring or merging with other REITs. Thus, a side contribution of our research is extending the literature on wealth effects of acquisitions to direct property acquisition in a nascent REIT market. 15 Empirical studies which have reported positive abnormal gains associated with real estate acquisitions include Allen and Sirmans (1987), Campbell, Ghosh and Sirmans (2001), Li, Elayan and Mayer (2001) and Campbell, Petrova and Sirmans (2003). 16 Prior studies which have observed insignificant abnormal returns for acquiring REITs include Owers and Rogers (1986), Glascock, Davidson and Sirmans (1991), Booth, Glascock and Sarkar (1996) and Pierzak (2001). In the mainstream finance literature, Mulherin and Boone (2000) also find a slightly negative but insignificant return for the bidder. 12 Abnormal returns surrounding the acquisition announcements are estimated using the standard market model event-study methodology. A 21-day event window surrounding the announcement (Day-10 to Day+10; abbreviated hereinafter as -10,+10) is employed with the date of announcement designated as day 0 in the event study. Following the recommendation of Campbell, Lo and MacKinlay (1996), we employ a multivariate regression model with dummy variables for the event date to handle cases were there is partial clustering, that is, where the event date is not the same across firms but there is an overlap in the event windows. Consequently, an estimation window of –100 days to +10 days was employed and where a REIT acquires on dates less than 100 days apart, the estimation windows for the REIT were combined so that one market model would apply to these consecutive periods. The excess return or the prediction error ( γ ek ) for the corresponding day is estimated using the following equation: Kj R jt = α j + β j Rmt + ∑ k =1 10 ∑γ e = −10 ek Dek + ε jt (3) where Rjt and Rmt are the period-t returns for acquirer j and the market portfolio, respectively. Daily returns for the market index and the individual securities were obtained from the DATASTREAM. For the market index, we employ the All Singapore Equities Index for Singapore and the Nikkei All Stocks Price Index for Japan. They are the most comprehensive price index comprising all stocks listed on the respective stock exchange. The coefficients α j and β j are the least squares estimates of the intercept and slope respectively, and ε jt is the residual error of i.i.d. normal distribution with a zero mean and a constant variance. K is the number of events included in the estimation, while Dek is a dummy variable equal to zero for all the dates except that it equals one on the e- th day of the k-th event window. Our final sample consists of 38 estimation equations (W = 38) and 228 events (N = ∑ W i =1 K i = 228). To test the significance of the measured abnormal returns, we constructed the J2 statistics for the e-th day of all the event windows: J 2 ,e = N − 1 W 2 Ki γ eki ∑∑ σ i =1 k =1 (4) eki 13 where σ eki is the standard error of the abnormal return estimate γ eki . Under the null hypothesis that the abnormal returns follow a zero-mean normal distribution, the J2 statistics have an approximate standard normal distribution. A significantly positive abnormal return would be inconsistent with the “present value” hypothesis (NPV = 0), which prescribes that REIT acquirers pay a fair price for the asset. Empirical Results Abnormal Returns Table 4 reports the announcement effects of the total sample of 228 acquisitions. The table reports the average abnormal return over the 21-day window period as well as the cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) for four different intervals. Exhibit 1 tracks the mean CARs for the sample over the corresponding 21-day window period. [Table 4 & Exhibit 1] We find that acquisition announcements result in a positive stock price adjustment for the acquiring firm. The CAR-10,+10 for the 21-day window period is 0.39% with nearly all the abnormal gains recorded in the post-announcement period (CAR0,+10, 0.31%). Whilst the abnormal return on the day prior to announcement is negligible (D-1), the average abnormal gain is +0.04% on the event day (D0), +0.17% one day after (D+1), and +0.09% two days after (D+2). Since the pattern of the abnormal returns indicates that most of the announcement effects are significantly captured on the first three days after the announcement, we focus our subsequent analysis on the 3-day CAR (0, +2) which has a 17 mean value of 0.29%. Judging by the spread of the value (-8.62% to +10.24%), the observed abnormal returns do vary tremendously across the sample. 17 Although the magnitude of the CAR appears to be small compared to prior studies on mergers and acquisition activities of U.S. REITs, such as Campbell, Petrova and Sirmans (2003) who observed a 0.53% CAR, it should be clarified that our sample primarily involves firms that make multiple acquisitions within a short period of time. Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) argue that when firms make multiple bids as 14 Overall, the event-study results show that acquisition announcements made by Asian REITs contained good news. As shown in Table 5, the mean CAR (0, +2) for all the observations is positive +0.29% and statistically significant. However, the observed CARs for the segregated samples indicate that the economic gains are driven primarily by JREITs’ acquisitions, which registered +0.36% average return over the three-day analysis period. The mean return for SREITs’ acquisitions, whilst positive, is much lower (+0.14%) and insignificant. One possible explanation for the observed abnormal gains is that the targets in our sample involved privately held assets, which according to Hansen and Lott (1996) and Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) tend to be priced at a discount to publicly-listed targets.18 However, the “private value” explanation is unable to clarify the differences in the abnormal returns observed across the two markets even though the targets in both markets involved privately held properties. [Table 5] Following Ching and Fu’s (2003) proposition that wealth effects associated with acquisitions is dependent on market contestability,19 all else being equal, any variations in the magnitude of the abnormal returns between SREITs and JREITs could be attributed to their comparative market structure, particularly the degree of competition and freedom of entry and exit as well as the existence of other barriers such as restrictions on credit. Judging by the comparative magnitude of the economic gains, Table 5 indicates that the commercial real estate market in Japan is less contestable than in Singapore. part of an announced acquisition program, any finding of significant bidder abnormal returns at an acquisition announcement is noteworthy since the impact of the acquisitions is already impounded in the stock price. 18 Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) attribute this to a liquidity effect, namely private firms cannot be bought and sold as easily as publicly traded firms. This lack of liquidity makes the investment less attractive and thus less valuable than similar, more liquid investments. They further postulate that the acquirer captures this discount in purchasing the privately held firms. 19 Ching and Fu (2003) argue that a contestable market offers firms no more than a normal rate of profit because competition compels bidders to bid up rent equal to the economic profit from the use. Conversely, in an imperfectly contestable market, positive abnormal returns would be accrued to incumbent firms. 15 Apart from the handicap on local knowledge, foreign investors in the Japanese markets also face other entry barriers in the form of language and cultural disadvantages. In contrast, Singapore has successfully attracted a number of foreign-based REITs listed on its stock exchange due to its reputation for having the most open and progressive REIT legislation in Asia. 20 This may explain why the abnormal returns associated with acquisition announcements by JREITs are stronger and more significant than SREITs’. A simpler explanation is that there are more dilutive acquisitions, as we shall see below are inversely related to the market reaction, in the SREIT sample (37.5%) as compared to the JREIT sample (10.3%). Yield Accretion and Abnormal Returns To examine the relationship between abnormal returns surrounding acquisition announcements and yield accretion, we first segregate the acquisitions in our sample into those that are accretive and those that are dilutive. Underlining the emphasis of Asian REITs on earnings and yield growth, 81.3% of the acquisitions are accretive, whilst only 18.7% are dilutive. Panel A in Table 6, which compare the cumulative abnormal returns for the two groups over different window periods, show that the wealth effects for the two groups are significantly different. Whilst their cumulative abnormal returns prior to the acquisition announcements, CAR (-10,-1), are comparable, the difference in their abnormal returns after the announcement is striking. Judging by the statistically significant and positive CAR (0, +2) of 0.51%, accretive acquisitions are viewed positively by the market. Dilutive acquisitions, in contrast, convey bad news as inferred by the significantly negative stock price reaction, CAR (0, +2) of -0.67%. A similar conclusion is reached when the sample observations are divided into five quintiles ranked according to their accretive effect (Table 6 Panel B). The univariate test results, thus, reject the null hypothesis in favor of the alternate hypothesis that the economic gain from an acquisition is positively related to its yield accretion effect on the acquirer’s existing asset portfolio. 20 Ooi, Newell and Sing (2006) and Whiting (2007) provide comparative reviews of the REIT regimes in Asia. 16 [ Table 6 ] We also employ cross-sectional regressions to assess the market reaction to acquisition announcements. The basic regression model is set up as follows: y is defined as an (N x 1) vector of observations and X as an (N x K) matrix of characteristics. The regression equation is as follows: y = Xθ +η , where θ is the ( K x 1) coefficient vector and η is the ( N x 1) disturbance vector. Assuming E[ X 'η ] = 0, we can consistently estimate θ using ordinary least squares (OLS). The dependent variable in all the regressions is the 3-day CAR (0, +2) earned by the acquirer’s stock. The explanatory variable of key interest to us is the yield accretion variable. If the capital market views the accretive motive to be beneficial to the shareholders of the acquiring REIT, the abnormal returns surrounding announcement of accretive acquisitions are expected to be positive. Conversely, if yieldaccretive story is detrimental to shareholders wealth, we would see an insignificant or negative regression coefficient for this variable. Table 7 reports the estimation results of our cross-sectional regression of the abnormal returns against a set of explanatory variables. The F-statistic for the OLS regressions indicate that the null hypothesis (that is all the partial regression coefficients in the model are zero) can be rejected at the 5% level of significance in favor of the alternative hypothesis that there is a linear relationship between the dependent variable and the regressors. The reported t-statistics for the explanatory variables are the White’s tstatistics corrected for heteroscedasticity. [ Table 7 ] Model 1 is the base OLS model, which comprises a constant, a dummy variable to distinguish the wealth effects of JREITs from SREITs, and another binary variable to distinguish the wealth effects of accretive acquisitions from dilutive acquisitions. In 17 Model 2, we partitioned the yield accretion effect into two separate components as presented previously in Equation (2), namely the differential yield between the acquired property and the existing portfolio (k ppty − k REIT ) and the relative size of the target property over the combined asset size, λ . The regression results confirm that yield accretion is an important determinant of the abnormal gains surrounding acquisition announcements. Consistent with the univariate results, the evidence shows that accretive acquisitions yield higher economic gains for the acquiring firm’s shareholders. The positive relationship between the yield accretion and abnormal returns persists when we substitute the binary variable with actual values of the yield differential between the target and portfolio’s in Model 2. However, the insignificant regression coefficient for λ indicates that there is no premium to be achieved beyond the fact the acquisition is accretive or dilutive. In other words, the size of the target relative to the size of the existing portfolios does not seem to matter. In Model 3, we incorporate a set of dummy variables to account for the fixed effects of omitted variables specific to each firm. This specification is commonly known as the least squares dummy variable (LSDV) or fixed-effects model. The Breush-Pagan Lagrange test statistic, however, indicates that the classical OLS regression without any firm effects is preferred over the fixed-effects model. More important, the positive and statistically significant relationship between yield accretion and abnormal returns continue to persist in the LSDV regression model. The first three regressions are estimated using the ordinary least squares (OLS) method. Model 4 uses the generalized least square (GLS) method where each observation is scaled (multiplied) by the inverse of the standard error of the abnormal return estimate so that the observations with a more precise γ(0,+2) estimate receive a greater weight in the regression. This is consistent with the approach employed by Ching and Fu (2003). The results reported in the last column of Table 7 show that the positive correlation between accretive acquisition and economic gains are significant. Further tests, results not reported for brevity reason, also confirm that the relationship is robust to alternative 18 window period used to compute the cumulative returns as well as to the omission of acquisitions less than US$20 million from our sample.21 Other Sources of Economic Gains The preceding evidence does not rule out other possible explanations for the market reaction to acquisition announcements. In this section, we expand the base regression to incorporate a fuller set of variables to take into account other possible explanations for the abnormal returns. Specifically, we control for the extent individual REITs may exploit other value enhancing opportunities in their acquisition activities, namely bargain buys, scale economy, synergy, and risk diversification. First, we incorporate a variable to differentiate “arms length” deals from “related party” acquisitions. Unlike REITs in the US which are internally-managed, REITs in the Singapore and Japan markets are required to delegate the REIT management and functions to an external party, which is usually controlled by the sponsoring party. Consequently, potential conflict of exists between the REIT shareholders and the external management party who may elect to inject poor-quality assets owned by the sponsors into the REIT. In this scenario, “related party” transaction should be correlated negatively with abnormal returns. Alternatively, the market may already have anticipated that the property would be injected into the REIT; hence, no new information is actually conveyed when the firm announced a “related party” transaction. Allen and Sirmans (1987) attribute the economic gains they observed for their sample to better asset management for related acquisitions. Campbell, Petrova and Sirmans (2003) also find that focusing acquisitions yield significantly higher abnormal returns than diversifying acquisitions. Following these two studies, a convenient way to control for 21 The accretion variable remains significant when we substitute the dependent variable, CAR(0,+2) , in our regression models with CAR (-1,+1). The positive relationship between accretive acquisition and abnormal returns is also robust when deals that involved less than US$ 20 million are filtered out of the sample. 19 expected synergy from the acquisitions would be to introduce a binary variable to reflect diversification across property type and geographical location. However, there were not enough variations in our sample to do this. 22 We, instead, employ the change in the operating efficiency ratio (operating expenses before financing over market value of the REIT portfolio) to gauge the potential synergy and economies of scale generated by the acquisition. A tenet of the synergy and scale economy story is that acquisitions are undertaken to increase efficiency and consequently, the relative operating expenses should decrease following a merger (Li, Elayan and Meyer, 2001). We expect this variable to have a positive and significant coefficient. We also control for firm risk to ensure that the accretive variable is not merely picking up any omitted effects arising from a shift in the business and financial risk of the individual firms following the acquisitions. Financial risk is represented by changes in the debt ratios of the acquiring REIT following the acquisition, whilst firm risk is proxied by changes in the stock price volatility of the acquiring REIT three months before and after the acquisition. Two separate binary variables with the value of unity are used to represent a positive expected change in these two variables. Based on the conventional risk-return tradeoffs, both variables are expected to have a positive relationship with returns.23 Previous studies have also suggested that the method of payment and fund raising for an acquisition may provide valuable information to the market. To account for this, we include a binary variable to distinguish REITs which disclosed their intention to place equity shares to fund the announced acquisition. On the basis that equity issues tend to signal that the stock is overpriced (Myers and Majluf, 1984), we expect this variable to be negatively related to market reaction. To examine how overpayment influence the economic gains associated with acquisition news, we benchmark the property’s purchase 22 Another proxy which could be employed to reflect potential synergy is a binary variable to reflect new acquisitions that are located in a development which the REIT already partially owned. Again, there was no variation in the sample to examine this. 23 Although both the firm risk and synergy measures are not observable at the event date, they are the best proxies we have on the market’s expectations. 20 price against the valuation determined independently by professional appraisers. The abnormal return should decrease with the degree of overpayment. Table 8 defines the independent variables in the extended regression models and reports their sample statistics. Due to incomplete data on some of the new variables, 40 observations had to be omitted. This leaves us with a final sample of 188 observations for the expanded regressions. As is shown in Table 8, 80.3% of the acquisitions are accretive, increasing the acquiring REITs’ portfolio yield by 4.2 basis points. The relative size of target property over the combined portfolio is 5.6%. On average, the targets are acquired at close to their market valuation. 33.5% of the targets are purchased from related parties and 58.0% of the sample resulted in positive synergy and scale economies, reflected by a reduction in the operating efficiency ratio of the acquiring REITs. However, 52.7% of the acquisitions lead to higher volatility in the REITs stocks. 16% of the acquisition announcements were accompanied by secondary equity offerings (SEOs). 41.5% of acquisitions resulted in an increase in the financial risk of the acquiring REITs, as reflected by their pre- and post-acquisition debt ratio. [ Table 8 ] The estimation results, which are reported under Model 5 in Table 9, are similar to what we have observed earlier for the base regressions. In particular, the market reaction is positive and significant for accretive acquisitions. The adjusted R-squared is modestly higher than that for Model 1 and Model 2. Most of the variables carry the expected signs. The market reacts negatively to announcements where the targets are acquired at a premium price and from related parties. Similarly, acquisition announcements that are accompanied by SEOs to fund the purchase have lower economic gains. Conversely, acquisitions that lead to higher business and financial risks for the acquiring REIT have higher returns. Nevertheless, only the coefficients for accretive acquisition and change in total risk are statistically significant. [ Table 9 ] 21 Model 6 examines the possibility that the observed abnormal returns are due to differences in the characteristics of the bidder as well as the attributes of the target property. 24 Due to their frequent participation, the capital market may have already factored into their stock price future acquisitions. Alternatively, aggressive bidders are more likely to overbid for a property, and expose themselves to the winner’s curse. An aggressive bidding strategy is, thus, expected to be correlated negatively or insignificantly with the abnormal return. To measure the firm’s aggressiveness and frequency of participation in the property investment market, the time interval between the current and previous acquisitions is used. A second variable is introduced to account for the wealth effects of maiden acquisitions. Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) posit that the first bid contain relatively more information about the acquiring firm than subsequent bids made within a short time interval. A third variable is included to control for firm size. On the basis that smaller-sized REITs have more scope to benefit from scale economies, it is expected to be inversely related to the observed wealth effects. The estimation results in Table 9 show the expected negative but insignificant coefficient for aggressive REITs. Consistent with Campbell, Petrova and Sirmans (2002), we did not find significant difference between returns in the first transaction than in later transaction of the same firms. Interestingly, once firm attributes are controlled for, the coefficient for JREITs turns positive but it still remains insignificant. Overall, the insignificant coefficients confirm our earlier finding of the LSDV regression model that adding firmspecific dummy variables does not really enhance the model’s explanatory power. In Model 6, we also take into account the attributes of the target property, particularly whether it is a single asset or a portfolio of assets, and whether it is a retail property or a mixed-use property. If any of these classes of properties offer buyers scope to extract value and improve their efficiency, we should to see a positive market reaction. Whilst the coefficient for retail property is positive, the benefit is not large enough to be 24 It should be noted that since the size of the REIT and purchase price of the target property is included in the regression, the relative size of the acquisition is not included to avoid possible multicollinearity problems. 22 statistically significant. Conversely, targets which involve mixed-use properties or a portfolio of properties are associated with significantly lower abnormal returns. This is consistent with the notion that firms are rewarded for corporate focus, and penalized for diversification. Following Ching and Fu (2003) and Ooi and Sirmans’ (2004) argument that the market for larger and more expensive properties tend to be thinner and less contestable, we incorporate the purchase price as an additional variable in Model 6. The regression results show the market reaction does depend on the property size, but not in a significant way. Overall, the empirical results presented in Model 6 are supportive of Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) contention that it is the characteristics of the target and its potential relationship with the bidding firm rather than the bidding firm itself that determine the wealth effects. Model 7 incorporates a dummy variable to account for deals that are announced in 2006. We choose 2006 because it coincides with a hot market and accounts for 41.5% of the acquisitions in our sample. As the investment market becomes more contestable, we expect to see a corresponding reduction in the abnormal returns. The coefficient for the dummy variable in our regression is negative, as predicted, but not statistically significant. We also tried to control for the sentiment in the real estate market by measuring the dollar value of all property transacted in the particular market over the past six months. Again, the relationship is insignificant. In Model 8, we observe that the REIT stock price performance prior to the acquisition adds to the explanatory power of the regressions. As shown in the last column of Table 9, the estimation results indicate that the market reaction to acquisition news is associated positively and significantly with the REIT stock returns prior to the announcement. Going on the logic that pre-acquisition stock price performance may reflect the market’s view on the ability of the REIT manager, property acquisitions announced by wellmanaged REITs are, not surprisingly, better received than those made by poorly-managed REITs. 23 On the whole, models 6, 7 and 8 explained around 15% to 18% of the variation observed in the economic gains. 25 While this may be indicative of the presence of other determinants, we are unable to find any significant relationship between the ex ante economic profit and other firm attributes. For example, we employed the number of times an individual firm have acquired properties prior to the current acquisition as a measure of the REIT’s experience in the property market. An incremental number was used to denote the learning curve with successive property purchased by the REIT over the sample period.26 On the other hand, Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) suggest that after making many quick acquisitions, bidders may negotiate less efficiently and create less synergy in later deals. Hence, we have no a priori expectation on the relationship of this variable on abnormal returns associated with acquisition announcements. A set of time dummies for each year of the study period was also added on the intuition that bidding of prime properties will intensify over time (given the limited supply of institutional properties available for purchase and the increasing number of potential acquirers as more REITs are listed). Consequently, REIT may find it harder to earn economic profit from property acquisitions over time. Thirdly, we examined the possible influence of book-to-market equity ratio of the acquiring firms on the rationale that the market reaction to acquisitions by “value” and “glamour” firms may well be different.27 We do not report the results since none of these variables are significant and do not add to the interpretation of the results. The coefficient for the accretive variable remains positive and statistically significant in all the regressions.28 25 Judging by the adjusted R2 values of between 7.8% and 10.7%, the explanatory power of our regression models fare relatively well. In comparison, the regression model in prior studies, such as Campbell, Petrova and Sirmans (2003) had adjusted R2 values in the range of 3.2% - 3.5%. 26 For illustration, assume a REIT acquired four properties over the sample period. For that individual company, the first property purchase will be given a value of 1, the second purchase 2, the third purchase 3, and the last purchase 4. This would capture the firm’s gradual accumulation of experience with each successive acquisition. 27 Rau and Vermaelen (1998) observe that acquirers with low book-to-market equity (growth or glamour firms) earn negative abnormal returns for up to 36 months. 28 We also run separate regressions for the acquisitions by SREITs and JREITs. Results for the SREIT sample are consistent with the conclusion that accretive acquisitions are good news. The JREIT sample, however, did not show a significant relationship, primarily because of the lack of heterogeneity with 90% of the acquisitions yield-accretive. 24 Conclusions This paper examines the wealth effects of accretive acquisitions based on a sample of 228 acquisitions made by REITs listed in Asia. Despite what corporate finance has to say, yield accretion remains an important consideration in the acquisition decisions of Asian REITs. The research provides some initial evidence that the market reacts favorably to announcements of accretive acquisitions and negatively to dilutive acquisitions. The positive relationship between yield accretion and abnormal returns surrounding the acquisition announcement continue to persist even after we control for other determinants of the market reaction. The results have important implications for shareholders and managers of REITs which adopts active acquisition as a strategy for corporate growth and value enhancement. At the least, the empirical evidence indicates that the managers’ obsession with earnings growth is not detrimental to the shareholders welfare in the short-run. On the contrary, our empirical evidence shows that shareholders benefit when REITs engage in property acquisitions that lead to higher earnings. On the basis that REITs are required to disburse at least 90% of their earnings as dividends, accretive acquisitions would lead to higher current earnings and hence, result in more dividend income for the shareholders. 29 This study, thus, provides indirect evidence supporting the stream of literature which argues that market reacts positively to news of dividend hikes and negatively to news of dividend cuts. To the extent that REIT management is able to exercise discretion and effectively employ yield-accretive acquisitions to enhance operating cash flows and dividends to shareholders, our study also contributes to the accounting literature on earnings management. In particular, the findings are consistent with price earnings management studies which show that firms with a long string of earnings growth are priced at a premium. 29 Given that REITs distribute most of their earnings, an alternative measure of portfolio yield is distribution yield to REIT equity holders (the equivalent of dividend yield for common stocks). Dividend yield is, however, affected by the firm’s capital structure and susceptible to financial engineering such as deferred payment scheme or dividend waivers by the REIT sponsor and or manager. 25 The evidence also lends support to the catering theory of dividends. On the basis that earnings and dividends are highly relevant to share prices, Barker and Wurgler (2004) suggest that managers do cater to the time-varying investor demand in an effort to maximize current share price. Given the infancy stage of the REIT market in Asia, accretive acquisitions seems to be a credible story for newly listed REITs to signal to the market their devotion to increase earnings. Best and Best (2001) hypothesis that if the market participants are relatively uncertain about future earnings, that is they are not sure of the reliability of the earnings projections, then a dividend change may convey more information about the firm’s cash flow. Since dividend stocks are more valuable in periods of high uncertainty, accretive acquisitions may be the only viable option for the REITs to establish their track record during the initial years. Hence, the positive stock price reaction to accretive acquisitions may well reflect Grinblatt and Titman’s (2002, p.708) contention that “the stock returns of the bidder at the time of the announcement of the bid may tell us more about how the market is reassessing the bidder’s business than it does about the value of the acquisition.” Moving forward, it is debatable whether such yield-accretive game can continue for several reasons. Over time, the market participants will have more information and, hence, be able to assess directly the management track record and performance. As the REIT markets in Asia continue to develop, the investors will become more knowledgeable and sophisticated and hence, better able to discern accretive earnings that are purely cosmetic in nature. Furthermore, as the REIT markets in Asia become more competitive and mature, it will be harder play the yield-accretive game. Although it has been suggested that the current level of securitized real estate in Asia is still low as compared to that in the US and Australia, increased competition from new REITs and private real estate funds entering the market will bid up the prices of prime real estate. To sustain their growth momentum, some REITs have considered buying overseas properties or assuming property development risks. In their continual pursuit of accretive acquisitions, REIT managers and shareholders would do well to be cautious of the “bootstrap effect” (Brealey and Myers, 2000). 26 One limitation of our current study is the potential problem of sample selectivity bias. As pointed out by Andrade (1997), if dilution is truly detrimental to stock prices, then the most dilutive transactions would not actually get done. As a result, the data we observe are the least ex-ante dilutive acquisitions. This implies that our estimates of the effect of accretion on returns are actually downward biased. Unfortunately, there is little scope for us to address this problem since we cannot observe the deals that are not done. However, this potential bias may be mitigated by the fact that Asian REITs are managed externally. The external REIT managers have incentives to execute and close every possible deal because their management fees are tied to the size of the asset under management; plus they get to earn a percentage commission of the purchase price for every acquisition deal. Finally, although we established that accretive acquisitions increases shareholders welfare in the short-run, it would be interesting to examine how long the observed benefit will last. In particular, do accretive acquisitions lead to improved stock performance by the acquirers in the long-run? We reserve this question for a future study when there are enough data to calculate the long-term performance of the REITs. 27 References Allen, P. R. and C. F. Sirmans. 1987. An Analysis of Gains to Acquiring Firm’s Shareholders: The Special Case of REITs. Journal of Financial Economics 18, 175-84. Ambrose, Highfield and Linneman. 2005. Real Estate and Economies of Scale: The Case of REITs. Real Estate Economics 33(2), 323-350. Andrade, Gregor. 1999. Do Appearances Matter? The Impact of EPS Accretion and Dilution on Stock Prices. Working Paper Harvard Business School. Barker, M. and J. Wurgler. 2004. A Catering Theory of Dividends. Journal of Finance 56(3), 1125-1165. Booth, R. 2006. Real Estate Investment Trusts: A Global Analysis. Globe Law & Business: London. Booth, G.G., J.L. Glascock and S.K. Sarkar. 1996. A Reexamination of Corporate Sell-offs of Real Estate Assets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 12, 195-202. Brealey, R.A. and S.C. Myers. 2000. Principles of Corporate Finance (6th ed.) Irwin McGrawHill: Homewood, III. Burgstahler, D. and I. Dichev. 1997. Earnings Management to avoid Earnings Decreases and Losses. Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, 99-126. Campbell, J., A. Lo, and C. MacKinlay. 1996. The Econometrics of Financial Markets, Princeton University Press: Princeton, New Jersey. Campbell, Robert D. 2002. Shareholder Wealth Effects in Equity REIT Restructuring Transactions: Sell-Offs, Mergers & Joint Ventures. Journal of Real Estate Literature 10(2), 205222. Campbell, Robert D., Chinmoy Ghosh and C. F. Sirmans. 2001. The Information Content of Method of Payment in Mergers: Evidence from Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs). Real Estate Economics 29(3), 361-387. Campbell, Robert D., Milena Petrova, and C. F. Sirmans. 2003. Wealth Effects of Diversification and Financial Deal-Structuring: Evidence from REIT Property Portfolio Acquisitions. Real Estate Economics 31(3). 347-365. Ching S. and Fu Yuming. 2003. The contestability of the urban land market; an event study of Hong Kong land auctions. Regional Science and Urban Economics 33. Chang, S. 1998. Takeovers of Privately Held Targets, Methods of Payment, and Bidder Returns. Journal of Finance 53, 773-784. Eckbo, B.E. and K. Thorburn. 2000. Gains to Bidder Firms Revisited: Domestic and Foreign Acquisitions in Canada. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35, 1-25. 28 Fuller, K., J. Netter and M. Stegemoller. 2002. What Do Returns to Acquiring Firms Tell Us? Evidence from Firms That Make Many Acquisitions. Journal of Finance 57(4), 1763-1793. Glascock, J., W. Davidson, and C.F Sirmans. 1991. An Analysis of the Acquisition and Disposal of Real Estate Assets. Journal of Real Estate Research 4(3), 131-40. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman. 2002. Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy, (2nd edition), McGraw Hill Irwin: New York. Gyourko, J. and J. Siegel. 1994. “Long-term Return Characteristics of Income-Producing Real Estate. Real Estate Finance 11(2), 14-22. Hansen, R.G. 1987. A Theory for the Choice of Exchange Medium in Mergers and Acquisitions. Journal of Business 60, 75-95. Hansen, R.G. and J. Lott. 1996. Externalities and Corporate Objectives in a World with Diversified Shareholders/Consumers. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 43-68. Hardin, William G. III and Marvin L. Wolverton. 1999. Equity REIT Property Acquisitions: Do Apartment REITs Pay a Premium? Journal of Real Estate Research 17(1/2), 113-126. Koh, J. 2006. Singapore. R. Booth, editor, Real Estate Investment Trusts: A Global Analysis. Globe Business Publishing: London. Li, J., F.A. Elayan and T.O Meyer. 2001. Acquisitions by Real Estate Investment Trusts as a Strategy for Minimization of Investor Tax Liability. Journal of Economics and Finance 25(1), 115-134. Merrill Lynch research. 2006. Singapore REITs. June 27, 2006. Mulherin, J.H. and A. Boone. 2000. Comparing Acquisitions and Divestures. Journal of Corporate Finance 6, 117-129. Myers, S.C. and N. Majluf. 1984. Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics 87, 355-374. Ooi, Joseph T.L., Graeme Newell and Tien-Foo, Sing. 2006. The Growth of REIT Markets in Asia. Journal of Real Estate Literature 14(2), 203-222. Ooi, Joseph T.L. and C.F. Sirmans. 2004. The Wealth Effects of Land Acquisition. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 29(3), 277-294. Owers, J.E. and R.C. Rogers. 1986. The Divesture of Real Estate Assets by Sell-off. Real Estate Issues 11, 29-35. Pierzak, Edward F. 2001. Payment Choice in REIT Property Acquisitions. Journal of Real Estate Research 21(1/2), 105-139. Rau, P. and T. Vermaelen. 1998. Glamour, Value and the Post-Acquisition Performance of Acquiring Firms. Journal of Financial Economics 49, 223-253. 29 Reiss, Dale and Elizabeth Pizak.1998. Mergers and Acquisitions. R. T. Garrigan and J. F. C. Parsons, editors. Real Estate Investment Trusts: Structure, Analysis and Strategy, McGraw-Hill: New York. Sahin, Olgun F. 2005. The Performance of Acquisitions in the Real Estate Investment Industry. Journal of Real Estate Research 27(3), 321-342. Weston, J. Fred, Juan A. Siu, and Brian A. Johnson. 2001. Takeovers, Restructuring & Corporate Governance (3rd ed.). Prentice-Hall: New Jersey. Wessels, David. 2006. FMA Roundtable on Stock Market Pricing and Value-Based Management. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 18(2), 56-81. Whiting, Dominic. 2007. Playing the REIT Game: Asia’s New Real Estate Investment Trusts. John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte. Ltd: Singapore. 30 Table 1: Market capitalization of Asian REITs Market capitalization of REITs listed in various markets in Asia as at April 2007. Figures in parentheses refer to the size of market capitalization in each country relative to the total market capitalization in Asia. Country Japan South Korea Singapore Thailand Taiwan Malaysia Hong Kong Total: Source: Datastream Listing Date of Maiden REIT Number of REITs Market Capitalization# Sep 2001 Jan 2002 Jul 2002 Oct 2003 Mar 2005 Aug 2005 Nov 2005 40 8 15 8 7 9 6 93 US$ ‘ billion 52.288 (63%) 0.711 (1%) 17.453 (21%) 0.628 (1%) 1.814 (2%) 0.803 (1%) 8.967 (11%) US 82.662 billion 31 Table 2: The mechanics of an accretive acquisition This table illustrates the mechanics of an accretive acquisition using an the example of a REIT, which has an existing asset portfolio worth US$500 m, acquiring US$ 50 m property with a 7% net yield. REIT property Target Combined portfolio portfolio property (post-acquisition) 500 50 550 Net Income (US$ m) 25.00 3.50 28.50 Property Yield 5.00% 7.00% 5.18% Market value (US$ m) 32 Table 3: Yield accretion of property acquisitions The reported figures are mean values for 228 property acquisitions by REITs in Singapore (SREIT) and Japan (JREIT). Yield accretion refers to the difference in the portfolio yield before and after the acquisition. Property Yield Portfolio Yield Yield Differential Purchase price (US$ million) Purchase price (% of portfolio value postacquisition) Yield accretion SREIT 7.86% 7.14% 0.72% US$ 75.53 m 8.37% 0.000% JREIT 5.55% 3.49% 2.06% US$ 75.78 m 4.10% 0.063% All 6.28% 4.64% 1.64% US$ 75.70 m 5.45% 0.043% 33 Table 4: 21-day abnormal returns surrounding acquisition announcements This table reports the announcement effects of the sample, which consists of 228 acquisition announcements for REITs listed in Singapore and Japan between Sep 2002 and Apr 2007. Event time is measured in days relative to the announcement date (0). Event Day/ Window -10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 -10,+10 -10, -1 0,+10 0,+2 Mean J statistic -0.03% -0.11% -0.13% -0.04% -0.02% 0.10% 0.18% -0.02% 0.09% 0.00% 0.04% 0.17% 0.09% -0.02% -0.03% -0.11% -0.06% 0.15% 0.02% 0.13% -0.01% 0.39% 0.08% 0.31% 0.29% -0.20 -0.49 -0.86 -0.13 -0.53 0.95 2.24* 0.13 0.99 0.16 1.01 2.61* 1.35 -0.22 -0.87 -0.94 -0.46 1.58 0.13 1.36 -0.08 1.14 0.38 1.31 2.01* Std. Deviation 1.38% 1.49% 1.40% 1.21% 1.38% 1.52% 1.29% 1.27% 1.33% 1.39% 1.38% 1.64% 1.62% 1.43% 1.41% 1.21% 1.55% 1.22% 1.26% 1.31% 1.30% 5.00% 3.50% 3.92% 2.57% Median Min. Max. -0.07% -0.09% -0.07% -0.06% -0.01% -0.01% -0.01% -0.05% -0.05% -0.10% 0.03% 0.07% -0.08% -0.01% -0.10% -0.05% -0.09% 0.00% -0.01% 0.01% -0.08% 0.02% 0.00% 0.04% 0.18% -4.59% -5.62% -5.48% -4.31% -6.00% -3.42% -4.09% -3.32% -5.91% -5.33% -7.32% -4.92% -5.22% -5.94% -5.09% -4.54% -5.11% -3.92% -3.58% -4.07% -5.70% -11.74% -12.94% -13.80% -8.62% 5.60% 6.07% 7.16% 4.17% 5.81% 6.85% 5.20% 5.30% 5.47% 5.63% 4.39% 7.64% 7.31% 5.72% 6.84% 5.52% 6.92% 3.50% 3.50% 5.29% 4.56% 16.80% 15.24% 12.16% 10.24% * denotes statistical significance at 10% level or higher. 34 Exhibit 1: Cumulative abnormal returns for acquiring REITs The sample consists of a total of 228 acquisition announcements for REITs listed in Singapore and Japan between Sep 2002 and Apr 2007. Event time is measured in days relative to the announcement date (0). The reported cumulative abnormal return for each event day is the mean value for all the sampled transactions. 0.50% 0.40% Abnormal Return 0.30% 0.20% 0.10% 0.00% -10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 -0.10% -0.20% -0.30% Event Day 35 10 Table 5: Abnormal returns surrounding acquisition news The reported figures are mean values for 228 property acquisitions by REITs in Singapore (SREIT) and Japan (JREIT) between Sep 2002 and Apr 2007. CAR(-10,+10) refers to the cumulative abnormal gains for a 21-day window period covering ten days before and after the event date. CAR(-10,-1), CAR(0,+10) CAR(0,+2) are the cumulative abnormal returns for 10-day, 11-day, and 3-day event window, respectively. No of Obs CAR (-10,+10) CAR (-10,-1) CAR (0,+10) CAR (0,+2) JREIT 156 0.65% 0.20% 0.45% 0.36%* SREIT 72 -0.17% -0.19% 0.02% 0.14% 228 0.39% 0.08% 0.31% 0.29%* All REIT * denotes statistical significance at 10% level or higher. 36 Table 6: Relationship between yield accretion and abnormal returns The reported figures in the last four columns are mean values of the cumulative abnormal returns for subsamples of for 230 property acquisitions announced by REITs in Asia between Sep 2002 and Apr 2007. CAR(-10,+10) refers to the cumulative abnormal gains for a 21-day window period covering ten days before and after the event date. CAR(-10,-1), CAR(0,+10) CAR(0,+2) are the cumulative abnormal returns for 10-day, 11-day, and 3-day event window, respectively. In Panel A, “Accretive” refers to the sub-sample of acquisitions which resulted in an increase in the portfolio yield, whilst “Dilutive” refers to the sub-sample of acquisitions which resulted in a decrease in the portfolio yield. In Panel B, the 228 sampled observations are divided into five quintiles according to their yield accretion following each acquisition announcement. Q1 contains events ranked in the bottom one fifth (i.e. acquisitions which are mostly dilutive), whilst Q5 comprises acquisitions ranked in the top twenty per cent (i.e. acquisitions which have the largest yield accretive effect). The figures in parenthesis besides the Q1 to Q5 sub-samples are the mean values of the yield accretion for each quintile sample. CAR(-10,+10) refers to the cumulative abnormal gains for a 21-day window period covering ten days before and after the event date. CAR(-10,-1), CAR(0,+10) CAR(0,+2) are the cumulative abnormal returns for 10-day, 11-day, and 3-day event window, respectively. No. of Obs CAR (-10,+10) CAR (-10,-1) CAR (0,+10) CAR (0,+2) Accretive 185 0.51% 0.05% 0.45%* 0.51%* Dilutive 43 -0.11% 0.18% -0.28% -0.67%* Q1 (-0.16%) 46 -0.26% 0.02% -0.28% -0.71%* Q2 (0.02%) 46 1.05% 0.47% 0.59% 0.07% Q3 (0.04%) 46 -0.49% -1.35%* 0.85% 0.69%* Q4 (0.08%) 46 0.91% 0.47% 0.44% 0.95%* Q5 (0.32%) 44 0.76% 0.81%* -0.05% 0.45%* All REIT 228 0.39% 0.08% 0.31% 0.29%* Panel A Panel B * denotes statistical significance at 10% level or higher. 37 Table 7: Base regression models Estimation results of regression models with CAR (0,+3) as the dependent variable. The independent variables are defined as follows: Accretive Acq is a binary variable equals one if the acquisition results in an increased yield for the combined portfolio; JREIT is a binary variable equals one if the acquiring REIT is listed in Japan; yield accretion is the difference between the differential yield between the acquired property and the existing portfolio, and Relative Size is the ratio of the target property over the combined portfolio asset size. The models are estimated using the ordinary least squares (OLS) for Regression 1 and 2, the LSDV estimator for Regression 3, and the generalized least squares (GLS) estimator for Regression 4. Total number of observation for each regression is 228. Reported t-statistics are based on White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors. The statistical significance is indicated by ** and *, which represents significance at 0.05 and 0.10, respectively. Model Constant Accretive JREIT Yield accretion Relative Size R-square Adj R-square F-ratio 1 coeff. -0.0062 0.0122 -0.0012 2 t-stat -1.22 2.31** -0.31 0.033 0.024 3.790** coeff. 0.0029 3 t-stat 0.74 -0.0018 -0.47 0.1880 2.28** -0.0342 -1.07 0.038 0.025 2.960** coeff. 4 t-stat 0.1672 1.84* -0.0266 -0.74 0.165 0.070 1.750** coeff. -0.0051 0.0104 0.0005 t-stat -1.01 2.07** 0.13 0.027 0.019 3.140** 38 Table 8: Definition and summary statistics of the explanatory variables Definitions and summary statistics for the filtered sample of 188 property acquisitions announced by Asian REITs between September 2002 and April 2007. Variable Accretive Definition A binary variable equals one if the post-acquisition yield of the REIT portfolio increase. Yield Chg Annual net yield of the target property less the annual net yield of the REIT’s existing portfolio. Relative Size Ratio of target property’s purchase price over the postacquisition portfolio size of the REIT. JREIT A binary variable equals one if the REIT is listed in Japan Premium Ratio of purchase price over valuation of the target property minus one. Related Party Binary variable equals one if target property is acquired from parties related to the REIT manager or sponsors. Synergy Binary variable equals one if the REIT’s post-acquisition operating expenses (relative to asset value) decreases. Add Risk Binary variable equals one if the REIT’s post-acquisition total risk (measured by the standard deviation of its daily stock price over a three month period) increases. New Equity Binary variables equals one if REIT also announce a SEO to finance the purchase. Add Debt Binary variable equals one if the REIT’s post acquisition debt ratio increases. Interval The time interval between the firm’s current acquisition and the previous acquisition.* 1st Bid Binary variable equals one if it is the first acquisition by the REIT since listing. REIT Size Value of the REIT’s prior-acquisition asset portfolio (in USD million).* Shop Binary variable equals one if the target involves retail properties. Mixed-use Binary variable equals one if the target involves a mixedused property. No. Properties Number of properties that are acquired on the same day. Property Size Purchase price of the target property (in USD million).* Yr2006 Binary variable equals one if the acquisition new occurs in 2006. Past Returns Change in REIT stock price one month prior to the acquisition * Natural logarithm of these variables was employed in the regressions. Mean 0.80319 Std Dev. 0.39865 0.01684 0.02291 0.05618 0.07191 0.65957 -0.00308 0.47512 0.04082 0.33511 0.47329 0.57979 0.49491 0.52660 0.50063 0.15957 0.36719 0.41489 0.49402 89.1489 157.406 0.06383 0.24510 1,535.84 1075.31 0.32447 0.46943 0.37766 0.48610 0.27128 76.94 0.41489 0.44581 118.84 0.49402 0.00080 0.00170 39 Table 9: Multivariate regression models Estimation results of regression models with CAR (0,+3) as the dependent variable. The independent variables are defined in Table 8. All the models are estimated using the OLS. Total number of observation for each regression is 188. Reported t-statistics are based on White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors. The statistical significance is indicated by ***, ** and *, which represents significance at 0.01, 0.05 and 0.10, respectively. Model Constant Accretive Relative Size JREIT Premium Related Party Synergy Add Risk SEO Add Debt Interval 1st Bid REIT Size Shop Mixed use No. Property Property Size YR2006 Past Returns R-square Adj R-square F-ratio 5 coeff. -0.0092 0.0118 -0.0285 -0.0021 -0.0277 -0.0019 -0.0018 0.0089 -0.0030 0.0039 6 t-stat -1.45 2.09** -0.88 -0.49 -0.68 -0.50 -0.56 2.58** -0.42 1.06 0.0955 0.0498 2.09** 7 8 coeff. 0.0169 0.0145 t-stat 0.71 2.46** coeff. 0.0209 0.0145 t-stat 0.83 2.46** 0.0068 -0.0192 -0.0027 -0.0019 0.0081 -0.0025 0.0026 -0.0020 0.0142 -0.0041 0.0044 -0.0090 -0.0023 0.0018 1.24 -0.41 -0.68 -0.62 2.29** -0.38 0.72 -1.23 1.22 -1.22 1.04 -1.96* -4.41** 1.11 0.0076 -0.0201 -0.0025 -0.0025 0.0089 -0.0019 0.0028 -0.0020 0.0133 -0.0044 0.0045 -0.0093 -0.0023 0.0015 -0.0032 1.32 -0.42 -0.63 -0.78 2.47** -0.30 0.79 -1.21 1.19 -1.28 1.05 -2.02** -4.20*** 0.87 -0.82 0.1570 0.0835 2.14** 0.1604 0.0819 2.09** coeff. 0.0156 0.0152 t-stat 0.63 2.57** 0.0058 1.00 -0.0144 -0.30 -0.0015 -0.38 -0.0021 -0.68 0.0074 2.07** -0.0034 -0.53 0.0023 0.66 -0.0017 -1.05 0.0145 1.28 -0.0039 -1.16 0.0050 1.18 -0.0093 -2.02** -0.0024 -4.34*** 0.0011 0.67 -0.0013 -0.32 2.6139 2.70*** 0.1889 0.1078 2.33*** 40