ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM Erasmus School of Economics Master Thesis Location Decisions of Chinese MNEs in European Regions: The Role of Overseas Chinese Communities J.L. (Jan) van den Hombergh Student Number: 280481 November 2010 Supervisor: Martijn J. Burger MSc TABLE OF CONTENTS Table of Contents 1 Chapter 1: Introduction 3 Paragraph 1.1: Introduction 3 Paragraph 1.2: Outward Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) 4 Paragraph 1.3: Location Decisions of Chinese Multinational Enterprises (MNEs) 5 Paragraph 1.4: Research Question 5 Paragraph 1.5: Proceedings 6 Chapter 2: Theoretical Framework 7 Paragraph 2.1: Introduction 7 Paragraph 2.2: The General FDI Theory 7 Paragraph 2.2.1: The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm 7 Paragraph 2.2.2: Four Motivations for FDI 8 Paragraph 2.3: A Special Theory for Chinese FDI? 9 Paragraph 2.4: Motivations Underlying Chinese FDI in Europe 9 Paragraph 2.5: The Role of Overseas Chinese Communities in the Location Decisions of 10 Chinese MNEs in European Regions Paragraph 2.5.1: Introduction 10 Paragraph 2.5.2: The History of Chinese Immigration into Europe 11 Paragraph 2.5.3: Networks of Overseas Chinese 13 Paragraph 2.5.4: The Role of Overseas Chinese Communities in the Location 14 Decisions of Chinese MNEs in European Regions Chapter 3: Data & Methodology 17 Paragraph 3.1: Introduction 17 Paragraph 3.2: Dataset 17 Paragraph 3.3: The Distribution of Chinese Greenfield Investments in Europe 18 Paragraph 3.4: Variables 19 Paragraph 3.4.1: Dependent Variable 19 Paragraph 3.4.2: Independent Variables 19 Paragraph 3.4.3: Control Variables 20 Paragraph 3.5: Methodology 23 1 Chapter 4: Empirical Results 25 Paragraph 4.1: Introduction 25 Paragraph 4.2: Base Model 25 Paragraph 4.3: Testing for the Relationship between the Size of the Chinese Population in 26 a European Region and the Number of Chinese Greenfield Investments Made Paragraph 4.4: Testing for Differences Between Firms Based in Mainland China and Firms 31 Based in Hong Kong Paragraph 4.5: Testing for Differences Between Firms with Different Economic Functions 36 within the Value Chain of a Firm Paragraph 4.6: Hausman-McFadden Test 37 Paragraph 4.7: Conclusion 38 Chapter 5: Conclusion 40 References 42 Appendix 48 Appendix A.1: Greenfield Investments in Europe in the Years 1997-2008 (China vs. Total) 48 Appendix A.2: A List of All NUTS-1 (Regions) in Europe (including the number of greenfield 48 investments made in each region in the period 1997-2008) Appendix A.3: Chinese Greenfield Investments in Europe in the Period 1997-2008 50 (subdivided by economic function) Appendix A.4: Descriptive Statistics 51 Appendix A.5: Correlation Matrix of All Independent Variables (including all control 52 variables) Appendix A.6: Expected Signs (control variables) 53 Appendix A.7: Wald Test (to test for the equality of the coefficients) 53 Appendix A.8: Description of the Economic Functions (within the value chain of a firm) 54 Appendix A.9: Hausman-McFadden Test (to test the assumption of the independence of 55 irrelevant alternatives) 2 CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION Paragraph 1.1: Introduction Barely 30 years ago, most would consider China to be a poor agricultural economy. Today, China is seen by many as an (emerging) major economic power (Morck et al., 2008). This phenomenal development started in the late 1970s with the ‘Open Door’ policies, and accelerated in the late 1990s when China introduced its ‘Go Global’ (zou chu qu) initiative, which resulted in China’s accession into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001 (Buckley et al., 2007). Between 1978 and 2008, China’s gross domestic product (GDP) grew by an average of 9.9% per annum (World Bank, 2010).1 Furthermore, when GDP in current US$ is considered, China is ranked the third economy in the world, superseded only by the United States and Japan (World Bank, 2010).2 In recent years, China has become increasingly active on the global economic stage (Prime, 2009). In 2002, exports of goods and services totaled to 25.1% of GDP (World Bank, 2010). In 2008, this number had already risen to 36.6% (World Bank, 2010). Furthermore, in 2008, imports of goods and service added up to 28.5% of GDP, while in 2002, this number had only been 22.6% (World Bank, 2010). What is more, in 2008, China was already responsible for 8.1% of the world’s exports and 6.4% of the world’s imports (World Bank, 2010).3 More important, however, is that the projected growth rate in the value of exports (7.8%) and imports (6.6%) for China for the period 2005-2020 is far above the projected growth rates for Western economies (Winters & Yusuf, 2007).4 Furthermore, in 2008, total foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows into China amounted to $US 173 billion,5 representing 10.2% of the world’s total inward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2009).6 In 2006, total FDI inflows into China accumulated to only $US 119 billion,7 representing just 8.2% of the world’s total inward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2009).8 These calculations indicate that FDI inflows into China are increasing at a rapid pace. 1 Calculations were made by the author. Year of measurement: 2008. 3 Exports: China ($US 1,582 billion), World ($US 19,557). Imports: China ($US 1,233 billion), World ($US 19,165 billion). Calculations were made by the author. 4 Exports: US: 3.4%, Japan: 4.2%, Germany: 1.8%. Imports: US: 3.4%, Japan: 3.5%, Germany: 2.0%. 5 China: $US 108 billion, Hong Kong: $US 63 billion, Macau: $US 2 billion. Total: $US 173 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 6 China: $US 173 billion. World: $US 1,697 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 7 China: $US 73 billion, Hong Kong: $US 45 billion, Macau: $US 2 billion. Total: $US 119 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 8 China: $US 119 billion. World: $US 1,461 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 2 3 Paragraph 1.2: Outward Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) The increasing importance and integration of China in the world economy is also signified by the globalization of Chinese firms, as measured, for example, by increasing outward FDI (Brienen et al., 2010). A substantial body of literature has grown over the years that examines the prominence of China in terms of its position in global trade flows (e.g., Lall & Albalajedo, 2004), and as a recipient of foreign direct investment (inward FDI) (e.g., Buckley et al., 2002). By contrast, less attention has been paid to China’s position as an FDI source. Only recently, this increase in outward FDI from Chinese multinational enterprises (MNEs) has received considerable attention in the (academic and public policy) literature. In 2002, outward FDI flows from China, including Hong Kong and Macau, amounted to $US 21 billion,9 representing only 3.2% of the world’s total outward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2003).10 When Hong Kong and Macau are not included in these calculations, outward FDI flows from China amounted to only $US 3 billion in 2002, representing just 0.4% of the world’s total outward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2003). In 2008, outward FDI flows from China, including Hong Kong and Macau, accumulated to $US 113 billion,11 representing 6.1% of the world’s total outward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2009).12 When Hong Kong and Macau are not included in these figures, outward FDI flows from China amounted to $US 52 billion in 2002, representing 2.8% of the world’s total outward FDI flows (UNCTAD, 2009).13 Compared to outward FDI flows from other (developed) countries (UNCTAD, 2009),14 China’s share is still comparably small, but these calculations indicate that China is catching up rapidly. With their continued economic growth, expanding purchasing power, market liberalization and extensive state support, it may be expected that China will continue to boost its FDI outflows in the near future (Brienen et al., 2010). Not only the scale, but also the geographical distribution of Chinese outward FDI flows have changed over the years. Until the 1990s, FDI from developing countries, such as China, was mainly directed at other developing countries in the same region (Brienen et al., 2010). Although Chinese MNEs still invest most heavily in their neighboring countries, particularly the countries of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN), investments into developed countries outside their 9 China: $US 3 billion, Hong Kong: $US 18 billion, Macau: $US 0 billion. Total: $US 21 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 10 China: $US 21 billion. World: $US 647 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 11 China: $US 52 billion, Hong Kong: $US 60 billion, Macau: $US 1 billion. Total: $US 113 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 12 China: $US 113 billion. World: $US 1,858 billion. Calculations were made by the author. 13 It should be noted, however, that these official figures are probably inaccurate, since a substantial share of Chinese foreign direct investments in tax havens and Hong Kong are reinvested in other countries (Morck et al., 2008). In the literature, such investments are characterized as ‘round-trip’ investments. 14 US: $US 312 billion, France: $US 220 billion, Germany: $US 156 billion, Japan: $US 128 billion. 4 own region (i.e., Europe, North America) are found to be of increasing importance as well (Dunning, 2003; Gugler & Boie, 2008). Paragraph 1.3: Location Decisions of Chinese Multinational Enterprises (MNEs) Within the contemporary globalization literature, it is acknowledged that multinational enterprises (MNEs) are the basic units of global production and integration (Barba Navaretti & Venables, 2004; Brakman & Garretsen, 2008). Accordingly, with increasing levels of outward FDI flows, it may be expected that Chinese MNEs will become an important aspect of the globalizing world economy. In this context, the question arises where Chinese firms locate and what (location) factors determine their location decisions. For host countries and regions, the location choice of Chinese MNEs is important, as their investments can boost the host location’s prospects for (national and/or regional) economic development through, for example, employment creation, capital growth and export promotion (Romer, 1993; Young et al., 1994).15 With increasing numbers of Chinese firms choosing to invest in Europe, the question arises where these firms locate and what (location) factors determine these location decisions. In recent years, a number of empirical studies have been published that examine the location decisions of Chinese firms abroad (e.g., Buckley, 2007). However, few of these studies focus specifically on the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe. Instead, most of these studies investigate the general pattern of Chinese outward FDI. As a consequence of that, the empirical findings in these studies may be biased, since location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe may be determined by different (location) factors, compared to the (location) factors that determine the location decisions of Chinese firms in other parts of the world. In their study, Brienen et al. (2010) specifically test which location factors are important for Chinese MNEs seeking to establish their subsidiaries in Europe. One of the findings is that a significant and positive relationship is found between the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region and the location decision of a Chinese firm. Unfortunately, Brienen et al. (2010) do not further investigate this relationship. Paragraph 1.4: Research Question The importance of business and social networks in facilitating international trade has been the focus of many recent studies, both theoretical (Greif, 1993; Rauch & Casella, 1998) and empirical (Gould, 1998; Rauch & Trindade, 2002). Few papers, however, have focused on the role of networks in promoting FDI. In her study, Tong (2005) investigates the role of overseas Chinese networks in 15 Following Barba Navaretti & Venables (2004), Brienen et al. (2010) note that inward FDI can also have adverse effects on the host location’s economy. The academic literature is still inconclusive regarding the overall positive effects of FDI on the host economy (Lipsey & Sjöholm, 2005). 5 promoting cross border investments.16 By using a standard gravity model, it is found that overseas Chinese networks play a crucial role in facilitating FDI. Tong (2005), however, does not focus specifically on the role of these networks in the location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe. Instead, their role in the general pattern of Chinese outward FDI is investigated. With increasing numbers of Chinese firms seeking to establish their subsidiaries in Europe, it becomes of special interest to investigate the impact of overseas the Chinese communities on location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe. Accordingly, in this study, the following research question will be answered: Research Question: What is the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in European regions? By answering this research question, this thesis contributes to the existing literature on the role of overseas Chinese networks in promoting cross border investments in two ways. First, a novel perspective will be taken, since only investments in Europe will be considered. Second, instead of investigating the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe at a national level, in this thesis, the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe will be studied at a regional level. In this context, 351 location decisions of Chinese firms in 89 European regions during the period 2002-2008 will be studied. In this study, only greenfield investments will be considered. As the location choice in greenfield investments is not directly influenced by past capital installments of the investor or investee, unlike brownfield investments (i.e., expansion) or mergers and acquisitions, these types of investments are very useful for studying the locational determinants of FDI (Brienen et al., 2010). Paragraph 1.5: Proceedings The remainder of this thesis is organized as follows. In the next chapter, the theoretical framework of this study will be drafted. In this context, it will be investigated by which mechanisms overseas Chinese communities in Europe may influence the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in European regions. In chapter 3, the dataset that is used in this study will be presented. Furthermore, the conditional logit model, which is used to test the hypotheses, will be explained. In chapter 4, the empirical results will be discussed. In chapter 5, this thesis will be concluded with an answer to the research question that was posed in paragraph 1.4. 16 In Tong (2005), the presence of an overseas Chinese network in a country is proxied by the size of the overseas Chinese community in a country. 6 CHAPTER 2: THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK Paragraph 2.1: Introduction The theory of MNEs indicates that the goal of firms in a global market economy is to increase or protect their profitability and/or capital value (UNCTAD, 2006). As noted by UNCTAD (2006), one of the ways in which firms are achieving this goal is by engaging in FDI, either to better exploit their existing competitive advantages or to safeguard, increase or add to these advantages. Following a definition from the OECD (1996, p. 7), “foreign direct investment reflects the objective of obtaining a lasting interest by a resident entity in one economy (‘direct investor’) in an entity resident in an economy other than that of the investor (‘direct investment enterprise’)”. In this context, three types of foreign direct investment can be distinguished (Van Marrewijk, 2002; Brienen et al., 2010). First, greenfield investments, which is a form of FDI where a parent company is setting up a new production location in a foreign country. Second, brownfield investments, which is a form of FDI where a parent company increases the production facility of an existing production location in a foreign country. Third, mergers & acquisitions, which is a form of FDI where a parent company acquires the existing assets of a local firm in a foreign country. As it is explained in chapter 1 (paragraph 1.4), in this thesis, only greenfield investments will be considered. The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. In paragraph 2.2, the general theory on (outward) foreign direct investment will be introduced. In this context, special attention will be paid to how mainstream theory explains location decisions of MNEs. In paragraph 2.3, it will be argued that location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe cannot fully be understood by applying the general FDI theory, and that some special theories, nested within the general theory, are needed as well. In paragraph 2.4, it will be studied which location-specific factors are identified by the mainstream theory to be important to Chinese firms in their location decisions abroad. Finally, in paragraph 2.5, it will be investigated by which mechanisms overseas Chinese communities in Europe may influence the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in European regions. Paragraph 2.2: The General FDI Theory Paragraph 2.2.1: The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm In the field of economic geography, international business and international economics, many theories have been proposed over the years to understand the extent and pattern of (outward) FDI by MNEs. Among those theories, the eclectic (OLI) paradigm is one of the most powerful tools, as it integrates many of the existing concepts (Dunning, 1981b; Gugler & Boie, 2008). The OLI paradigm 7 asserts that, at any given moment of time, the extent and pattern of international production, i.e. production financed by FDI and undertaken by MNEs, will be determined by the configuration of three sets of forces (Dunning, 2001). First, ownership-specific (O) advantages: the (net) competitive advantages that firms of one nationality possess over those of another nationality in supplying any particular market or set of markets, given by the ownership of products or production processes. Second, location (L) advantages: the extent to which firms choose to locate these activities in a foreign country rather than in their home country. Third, internalization (I) advantages: the extent to which firms perceive it to be in their best interests to internalize their foreign activities in wholly owned subsidiaries, rather than carrying them out through market transactions (trade) or hybrid relationships with other firms (e.g., franchising and licensing). Given the scope of this thesis, location advantages will be the prime subject of this study. Paragraph 2.2.2: Four Motivations for FDI As the FDI literature suggests, investments by MNEs are attracted by favorable economic location factors in the host countries (Brienen et al., 2010). In this context, Dunning (1993, 1998) has distinguished four motivations of firms to internationalize their activities, each of which stress the locational aspects of FDI. First, foreign market-seeking FDI, which may be undertaken by firms to supply their goods and services to foreign markets. Accordingly, existing markets can be sustained or protected and new markets can be exploited or promoted (Dunning & Lundan, 2008). A new subsidiary may not only be used to serve the region in which it is located, but also the surrounding regions, which is especially interesting if a new location provides access to a large integrated market (Brienen et al., 2010). Second, efficiency-seeking FDI, which may undertaken by firms to reduce their costs of production related to labor, machinery and materials. Accordingly, differences in costs of production across regions, countries or continents may induce a firm to decide to split up its activities geographically (Brienen et al., 2010). Third, resource-seeking FDI, which may be undertaken by firms to acquire specific resources of a higher quality and/or at lower costs than could be obtained in their home country, if available at all (Dunning & Lundan, 2008). Fourth, strategic asset-seeking FDI, which may be undertaken by firms to acquire the assets of foreign corporations, in order to promote their long-term strategic objectives, i.e. sustaining and advancing the firm’s global competitiveness (Dunning & Lundan, 2008). In this sense, Dunning’s (1993, 1998) outline represents a general framework, which links a firm’s motives to invest abroad to location-specific factors of host countries that provide a competitive advantage for the firm (Brienen et al., 2010). Accordingly, foreign market-seeking MNEs are considered to be attracted to locations with different 8 characteristics than, for example, efficiency-seeking, resource-seeking or strategic asset-seeking MNEs. Paragraph 2.3: A Special Theory for Chinese MNEs? The general FDI theory, as it is outlined in paragraph 2.2, has been developed to understand the extent and pattern of foreign direct investment by firms from developed countries (i.e., Europe, North America). Accordingly, the question then arises as to whether FDI from emerging economies and, more specifically, from China can also be explained by using conventional theory. In the context of this study, the question arises if location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe can be understood by applying the general FDI theory. Some scholars argue that an alternative framework is needed to explain the extent and pattern of FDI by MNEs from developing countries, such as China (Matthews, 2002; Moon & Roehl, 2001). The majority view, however, is that mainstream theory does work, but that some special theories, nested within the general theory, are needed as well to account for the special character of late-comer MNEs (Lecraw, 1977; Wells, 1983; Lau, 2003; Child & Rodrigues, 2005; Erdener & Shapiro, 2005; UNCTAD, 2006; Buckley et al., 2007; Morck et al., 2008). In this thesis, the majority view is adopted. Accordingly, two questions arise. First, which of the four aforementioned motivations may be expected to drive Chinese MNEs to invest in Europe? By answering this question, it may be identified which location-specific factors of host countries, derived from the mainstream theory, are expected to be important to Chinese firms in their location decisions in Europe. Second, how can the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region affect location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe? Accordingly, by answering the second question, a special theory will be introduced that can be nested within the general FDI theory, to account for the special character of Chinese FDI in Europe. The first question will be addressed in paragraph 2.4, while the second question will addressed in paragraph 2.5. Paragraph 2.4: Motivations Underlying Chinese FDI in Europe Brienen et al. (2010) argue that Chinese MNEs are primarily motivated to invest in Europe for market-seeking reasons. Following Child & Rodrigues (2005), it is argued that, although the Chinese economy is growing at an incredible rate,17 its home market is limited in scale and opportunities to expand. Moreover, Cheng & Stough (2007) posit that increasingly severe competition and overcapacity are one of the most important pushing factors to expand abroad. Combined with the existence of trade barriers and a lack of international linkages with customers in target markets, Chinese MNEs are increasingly induced to set up subsidiaries abroad to serve these markets 17 It is referred to paragraph 1.1. 9 (Mathieu, 2006). This argument is supported by several recent studies (Cai, 1999; Taylor, 2002; Zhang, 2003; Deng; 2004), which signal the rise of offensive market-seeking motives driving Chinese MNEs. It is posited by Buckley et al. (2007) that these investments may be increasingly directed at large markets. Moreover, it is noted by UNCTAD (2006) that market-seeking FDI is by far the most common type of strategy for MNEs from developing countries in their process of internationalization. Strategic-asset seeking FDI is considered to be the second motivation for Chinese MNEs to invest in Europe (Deng, 2007; Gugler & Boie, 2008; Milelli & Hay, 2008). However, given the need to develop some technical and cognitive abilities to absorb these assets, for the upcoming years, it may be expected that such FDI will more likely occur through mergers and acquisitions than through the greenfield investments that are analyzed empirically in this study (Milelli & Hay, 2008). Given the low production costs in China, efficiency-seeking will unlikely be an important motive for Chinese MNEs to invest in Europe (or in any other place in the world) (UNCTAD, 2006; Buckley et al., 2007). Furthermore, due to the high extraction costs, resource-seeking FDI by Chinese MNEs will unlikely be directed towards any European region (Brienen et al., 2010). Instead, such FDI will more likely be directed towards other developing countries, for example in Africa and Central Asia (Dunning, 2003; Gugler & Boie, 2008). With Chinese MNEs expected to be primarily motivated to invest in Europe for market-seeking reasons, it may be hypothesized that they will be drawn to locations with good market access. Market access may be good, because the location has a large (high-income) population, or because it is well located to access to such markets (Barba Navaretti & Venables, 2004). Paragraph 2.5: The Role of Overseas Chinese Communities in the Location Decisions of Chinese MNEs in European Regions Paragraph 2.5.1: Introduction As it is outlined in paragraph 1.4, the importance of business and social networks in facilitating international trade has been the focus of many recent studies, both theoretical (Greif, 1993; Rauch & Casella, 1998) and empirical (Gould, 1998; Rauch & Trindade, 2002). Among the various types of business and social networks, co-ethnic networks have attracted the most empirical research (Rauch & Trindade, 2002). This may not be surprising, since the members of these networks are fairly easy to identify, compared to the members of other business and social networks. In the literature, two mechanisms have been identified, whereby co-ethnic networks may promote international trade. The first mechanism is identified by Greif (1993). In his paper, he argues that co-ethnic networks may govern agency relations. In this sense, a co-ethnic network may provide community enforcement of 10 sanctions, in order to deter violations of contracts, mainly in a weak international legal environment. A second mechanism is identified by Gould (1994). In his study, he posits that co-ethnic networks may influence bilateral trade flows through a decrease in transaction costs associated with obtaining foreign market information and establishing trade relationships. To this date, few papers have focused on the role of networks in promoting cross border investments (FDI). As it is argued by Tong (2005), foreign direct investment requires large start-up costs and intensive information. In this context, compared to international trade, FDI calls for cooperation and commitment at a much deeper level between the parties concerned. Accordingly, co-ethnic networks may be promote foreign direct investment by providing foreign investors with both (foreign market) information and support with the establishment of business relationships, as well as providing community enforcement of sanctions, in order to deter violations of contracts. In this sense, it may be reasonable to expect that co-ethnic networks will play an important role in facilitating FDI, maybe even more important than in encouraging international trade (Tong, 2005). In this thesis, it is examined how both mechanisms, whereby co-ethnic networks may facilitate international trade, may also promote foreign direct investment of Chinese MNEs in European regions. Accordingly, it will be investigated how location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe can be influenced by the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region. Since it is hypothesized that Chinese MNEs in Europe will be drawn to locations with good market access, it is of special interest to study how overseas Chinese communities in Europe may help Chinese firms with obtaining such market access. Before these issues will be addressed, however, in paragraph 2.5.2, the history of Chinese immigration into Europe will be examined. Furthermore, in paragraph 2.5.3, it will be studied how networks among overseas Chinese are formed. Paragraph 2.5.2: The History of Chinese Immigration into Europe Compared to Chinese immigration into Southeast Asia, which started hundreds of years ago (Poston & Yu, 1990), Chinese immigration into Europe is only a relatively recent phenomenon. The earliest Chinese immigrants in Europe arrived at the beginning of the twentieth century (Li, 2005). With the end of World War II, Europe entered a new stage of economic development. Not surprisingly, this has attracted many people from around the world (Ember et al., 2005). In the past 65 years, the migration of Chinese people into Europe has seen three major waves (Li, 2005). The first wave of Chinese immigration into Europe occurred in the early 1960s, with the migrants mainly coming from the rural areas located in the New Territories of Hong Kong (Li, 2005). During that time, the so-called ‘green revolution’ took place (Karim, 1986). As a consequence, many peasants had to look for alternative means of livelihood. Accordingly, a steady stream of people decided to leave their homeland for countries in Europe (first Britain, then the Netherlands and 11 Belgium, and later on Germany and France). The second wave occurred in the late 1970s, with the migrants mainly coming from Indochina (Live, 1998; Li, 2005). During that time, political conflicts made it impossible for many (ethnic) Chinese to stay in their (new) home country. The third wave of Chinese immigration into Europe started in the early 1980s and continues on until today (Li, 2005). Contrary to the first two waves, this wave mainly consists of Chinese immigrants from mainland China. Not surprisingly, it coincides with China’s ‘Open Door’ policies, which were initiated in the late 1970s (Thunø, 2001). Following Li (2005), the regular entry channels include work-permit or shortterm work contracts, the setting up of businesses or investments, education and family reunifications. In Table 1, for 29 European countries in four different years of measurement (1955, 1980, 1990, 2000), the number of (ethnic) Chinese immigrants are listed. Table 1: Ethnic Chinese Immigrants in Europe (1955-2000)18 Country Austria Belgium Bulgaria Switzerland Cyprus Czech Republic Germany Denmark Estonia Spain Finland France Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Lithuania Luxembourg Latvia Malta Netherlands Norway Poland Portugal 1955 30 118 1 11 1 11 800 900 1 43 1 3,300 4 1 1 260 1 1 1 1 2,017 3 1 73 1980 4,500 4,000 25 3,200 1 16 20,165 2,000 1 3,500 9 210,000 186 24 1,000 3,500 1 1 1 15 60,000 600 77 2,500 1990 6,000 13,000 30 5,000 1 20 39,500 6,000 1 15,000 10 200,000 100 23 1,000 20,662 1 1 1 1 45,500 950 80 4,700 2000 41,000 23,000 10 13,000 10 12,000 100,000 7,257 20 35,000 1,500 225,000 600 10,000 10,000 70,000 40 1,300 100 10 127,500 5,000 15,000 2,700 18 Sources: 1955:Poston & Yu (1990), 1980: Poston et al. (1994), 1990: Poston et al. (1994), 2000: Li (2005). For further information on these figures, it is referred to chapter 3 (more specifically, paragraph 3.4.2). 12 Romania Sweden Slovenia Slovakia United Kingdom Total 1 24 1 1 2,549 10,157 33 5,000 1 1 230,000 550,357 1 12,000 1 1 250,000 619,584 3,000 12,800 10 10 250,000 965,867 Paragraph 2.5.3: Networks of Overseas Chinese Overseas Chinese, like many other co-ethnic groups living outside their country of origin, establish various formal or informal associations to which co-ethnic business people from both the host country and the home country have access to (Rauch & Trindade, 2002). In this context, it is argued by Tong (2005) that these associations have traditionally been based on kinship, dialect and place (region) of origin in China. In the early days of Chinese immigration (into Europe), such associations were mainly created to help those in need in the community, especially new immigrants. As an overseas Chinese community becomes more commercially developed, these associations start to serve as nodes for information exchange between co-ethnic business people working both locally and internationally (Rauch & Trindade, 2002; Tong, 2005). In this sense, the overseas Chinese can be considered to form a set of inter-connected networks at various levels, both regionally and nationally, but not as a unified international network. It should be noted, however, that the international links have become more formalized through the biennial meetings of the World Chinese Entrepreneurship Convention, which are held since 1991 (Rauch & Trindade, 2002). Furthermore, Thunø (2001) emphasizes that the Chinese government, contrary to PRC policies on overseas Chinese before 1978, is now actively seeking to retain transnational ties to the millions of Chinese citizens and ethnic Chinese spread across the world by connecting to local networks of overseas Chinese. In some countries, where Chinese migrants have not yet organized (along regional lines), PRC embassy personnel have encouraged local Chinese to form locality associations to be better able to meet official PRC delegations. Compared to other co-ethnic groups, the overseas Chinese have been exceptionally successful in their networking activities (Redding, 1995; Weidenbaum & Hughes, 1996).19 Accordingly, the question arises why the (overseas) Chinese have always been and continue to be such excellent networkers. In this thesis, it is suggested that the answer to this question may be found in a special characteristic of the Chinese society and culture, namely guanxi. Following Luo (1999) and Park & Luo (2001), guanxi refers to the concept of drawing on a web of connections in 19 In Southeast Asia, the overseas Chinese are particularly well known for their commercial success. What is more, it is believed that overseas Chinese networks have played a crucial role in the region’s fast economic growth in recent years (Tong, 2005). 13 order to secure favors in personal and organizational relations. In this context, it should be emphasized that in China transactions follow successful guanxi, while in the Western world a relationship follows successful transactions. Accordingly, following Kao (1993), the guanxi network may be considered the lifeblood of the Chinese business society. When a situation arises that is beyond an individual’s or firm’s capacity, the guanxi network may be mobilized to accomplish the desired results (Redding & Ng, 1982). In this sense, guanxi is valuable entrepreneurial tool to bridge gaps in information (and resource) flows between unlinked firms and important outside stakeholders (Park & Luo, 2001). Likewise, it represents an informal social obligation to another party as a result of invoking a guanxi relationship (Standifird & Marshall, 2000). In the next paragraph, it will be examined how the guanxi network may help Chinese MNEs in their quest for European success. Paragraph 2.5.4: The Role of Overseas Chinese Communities in the Location Decisions of Chinese MNEs in European Regions In paragraph 2.5.1, two mechanisms have been identified, whereby co-ethnic networks may facilitate international business transactions, such as international trade and foreign direct investment (Tong, 2005). In this paragraph, it will be investigated how these mechanisms may promote FDI by Chinese MNEs in Europe, and more specifically how location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe can be influenced by the presence of an overseas Chinese network in a European region. Since it was hypothesized in paragraph 2.4 that Chinese MNEs in Europe are expected to be drawn to locations with good market access, special attention will be paid in this regard to how overseas Chinese networks in Europe may help Chinese firms with obtaining such market access. In his paper on the Maghribi traders’ coalition, Greif (1993) argues that a co-ethnic network may provide community enforcement of sanctions, in order to deter violations of contracts, mainly in a weak international legal environment, which is primarily found in developing countries (Tong, 2005). In the Chinese society and culture, this mechanism is embedded in guanxi. When a party violates the terms of a (unwritten) contract, he or she loses face (Yang, 1994). The Chinese have traditionally compared ‘losing face’ to the physical mutilation of an eye, the nose or the mouth (Hwang, 1987). What is more, losing face jeopardizes the guanxi network (Park & Luo, 2001). As guanxi may be considered the lifeblood of the Chinese business society (Kao, 1993), violating a contract may seriously harm future business opportunities (with third parties) (Weidenbaum & Hughes, 1996). Accordingly, guanxi provides an incentive not to violate the terms of a contract (Standifird & Marshall, 2000). All European regions and countries (included in the sample) have a solid legal system, which provides Europe (as a whole) with a sound international legal environment. When a contract is violated or other legal problems occur, a party may appeal to the legal system 14 that is imposed by the government. Accordingly, for Chinese MNEs in Europe, doing only business with overseas Chinese does not seem necessary from this point of view. As a consequence, when only the first mechanism is considered, locating in close geographical proximity to overseas Chinese communities will unlikely be a prerequisite for successful FDI of Chinese firms in Europe. As it is outlined in paragraph 2.5.1, a second mechanism, whereby co-ethnic networks may facilitate international business transactions, is identified by Gould (1994). In his study, he posits that co-ethnic networks may influence bilateral trade flows through a decrease in transaction costs associated with obtaining foreign market information and establishing trade relationships. In the context of this thesis, the question then arises how this mechanism may influence location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe. For Chinese MNEs, successful foreign direct investment (in Europe) requires intensive information (Tong, 2005), such as information on the local/regional/country market in the host region/country, information on potential business partners, information on the most suitable and profitable investment opportunities, information on local business practices and/or information on local government regulations (Buckley et al., 2007; Gould, 1994; Rauch & Casella, 1998). For a Chinese firm, which is not already embedded in the local (host country) market, this information may be difficult and costly to obtain (Zhan, 1995). Furthermore, establishing fruitful commercial relationships with local partners may be difficult and costly to realize. Accordingly, both transaction costs and business risks associated with investing in Europe will be high (Sung, 1996; Braütigam, 2003; Erdener & Shapiro, 2005; Tong, 2005). Therefore, a linkage to a local network, through which the firm can more easily gain access to (foreign market) information and establish business relationships, may be a crucial determinant for successful foreign direct investment by Chinese MNEs in Europe. In the 1970s, the concept of ‘psychic distance’ was introduced, which is defined as the distance between a firm’s country of origin (e.g., China) and another country (e.g., countries/regions in Europe), resulting from the perception and understanding of cultural, linguistic, institutional, (economic) developmental and business differences between two countries (Johanson & Wiedersheim-Paul, 1975; Johanson & Vahlne, 1977). The larger the psychic distance, other things being equal, the more difficult it will be to build new relationships (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009).20 Due to the large psychic distance between China and Europe, it may be expected that establishing a linkage to a local network is difficult for Chinese firms in Europe. With this mind, the extant theory asserts that early foreign direct investments of firms frequently occur in countries with a similar cultural background to the home country (Johanson & Vahlne, 1977), or where relational assets, in 20 In the literature, this effect is termed the liability of foreignness (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009). 15 the form of ethnic or familial ties with a specific minority population in the host country, can be exploited (Lecraw, 1977; Wells, 1983; Lau, 2003). For Chinese MNEs, the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region may offer the best possibility to establish a linkage to a local network in Europe. As these overseas Chinese networks function as nodes for information exchange (Gould, 1994), Chinese firms may obtain the information they need for successful FDI in Europe (at lower costs) by connecting to the members of these networks. Following paragraph 2.5.3, contacts between Chinese MNEs and local Chinese networks are probably made through guanxi (Luo, 1997; Standifird & Marshall, 2000; Tong, 2005). In this context, the development of trust through guanxi may decrease the transaction costs associated with communicating, negotiating and coordinating transactions (e.g., business relationships), as well as maladaptation and/or failure to adapt (Gould, 1994; Standifird & Marshall, 2000). In this sense, the flexible and socially-based nature of guanxi permits the members of a guanxi network to deal with unforeseen contingencies that arise after agreement is reached (Standifird & Marshall, 2000). Accordingly, fruitful commercial relationships can be established both more easily and at lower costs within overseas Chinese networks, which may facilitate market entry and development of Chinese firms in Europe (Buckley et al., 2007). Furthermore, overseas Chinese communities may be sources of specific human capital, such as local highly educated Chinese workers. For Chinese MNEs, this offers advantages, because these workers are proficient in the Chinese language, and have knowledge of both the Chinese culture and Chinese entrepreneurship. With Chinese MNEs expected to be primarily motivated to invest in Europe for marketseeking reasons, it is hypothesized in paragraph 2.4 that Chinese firms will be drawn to locations with good market access. This may not only be indicated by the market potential of a region or how quickly a location can be reached, but also by the presence of an overseas Chinese community. In this context, overseas Chinese networks may be particularly useful to Chinese MNEs by providing them with linkages to customers in international (European) target markets. Based on the arguments provided in this paragraph, it is expected that Chinese MNEs, who consider to invest in Europe, are attracted to locations with a sizeable (overseas) Chinese community. Accordingly, it is hypothesized that: Hypothesis: The probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is positively associated with the size of the overseas Chinese population in a region. 16 CHAPTER 3: DATA & METHODOLOGY Paragraph 3.1: Introduction With the theoretical framework of this thesis having been drafted in the previous chapter, this chapter will discuss the dataset that is being used in this study and the empirical method (conditional logit model) that will be applied to test the hypothesis that was posed in paragraph 2.4. In paragraph 3.2, the Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor (EIM) 2009 database will be discussed, followed by an analysis of the distribution of Chinese greenfield investments across 89 European regions in paragraph 3.3. In paragraph 3.4, the variables that will be entered into the empirical model will be described. This chapter will be concluded with a discussion of the conditional logit model in paragraph 3.5. Paragraph 3.2: Dataset In this study, the Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor (EIM) 2009 database is used to analyze the spatial pattern of Chinese FDI in European regions.21 This database monitors foreign direct investments in Europe, which may be new projects, expansions to existing ventures or relocation investments. The main sources of information that are used by Ernst & Young are formal announcements by the media (e.g., newspapers), financial information providers (e.g., Reuters) and national investment agencies (e.g., Invest in France Agency). To be considered as cross border investments, projects have to comply with several criteria. In this sense, the EIM database excludes acquisitions, license agreements and joint ventures, except in cases where these operations lead to an extension or a new establishment. Furthermore, investments in retail establishments, hotels and leisure activities, fixed infrastructures, extraction facilities and portfolio investments are also excluded from the database. There are no minimum investment size criteria, but it turns out that small investment projects, i.e. involving a total investment of less than US$ 1 million or where less than 10 jobs are created, are relatively uncommon. Although the Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor is recognized as one of the most comprehensive (international) investment databases across Europe, not all greenfield investment projects are covered. Nevertheless, estimates indicate that the majority of the total number of investments are included, especially the larger ones (Brienen et al., 2010). The investment project data are at the individual firm level, and include the name of the firm, the parent company name, the parent firm’s country of origin, the industry sector served, the firm’s function within the value chain, and the region of destination of each investment. 21 Detailed information on this database can be found at <http://www.eyeim.com>. 17 Overall, the Ernst & Young EIM 2009 database consists of 32,535 investment projects in the EU-27, Norway and Switzerland, during the period 1997-2008, of which 23,615 are new establishments or relocations, and 8,920 represent firm expansions. In this study, brownfield investments (i.e., firm expansions) are excluded from the analysis, because no new location choice is made. Henceforth, the term “greenfield investments” will refer to both new investments and relocations. Between 1997 and 2008, Chinese MNEs made 407 greenfield investments in Europe, which is 1.7% of the total number of greenfield investments made in that period. In this regard, it should be noted, however, as it is outlined in Appendix A.1, that the number of Chinese greenfield investments in Europe has grown exponentially over the years. In the period 1997-2001, only 40 of such investments were made, representing just 0.52% of all greenfield investments in Europe in that period. In 2008, China’s share had already risen to 2.9%. Furthermore, compared to the preceding year (i.e., 2007), the number of greenfield investments from all source countries (in total) stabilized in 2008, which is probably due to the worldwide financial crisis, while China’s investments in Europe increased by more than 50% in 2008. Hence, it seems that the global financial crisis has not affected the number of Chinese greenfield investments in Europe in any major way (Brienen et al., 2010). In order to answer the research question that was posed in Chapter 1, 351 Chinese greenfield investments in 89 European regions (NUTS-1) during the period 2002-2008 will be studied.2223 It is referred to Appendix A.2 for a list of these regions, which also includes the number of investments made in each region in the period 1997-2008, both from China and from all source countries in total. Paragraph 3.3: The Distribution of Chinese Greenfield Investments in Europe Appendix A.2 provides an overview of the spatial distribution of Chinese greenfield investments in Europe across 89 (NUTS-1) regions for the period 1997-2008. It may be noticed that these investments are not evenly spread across the continent, as such investments occur disproportionately within the United Kingdom, Germany, France, the Benelux Countries and Scandinavia, especially Denmark and Sweden. In particular, Chinese greenfield investments are clustered in Southeast England (Greater London area), West Germany (Ruhr-Rhine area), Newcastle and Paris. Furthermore, Appendix A.2 also provides an overview of the spatial distribution of all greenfield investments (in total) made in Europe in the period 1997-2008. It may be noticed that these investments, compared to only Chinese greenfield investments, are more evenly spread across the continent. In this context, it is remarkable that both the Greater London area and the Ruhr-Rhine area are less prominent, when all greenfield investments made in Europe are considered. 22 In this context, for each of these firms, it is known whether their parent company originates from either mainland China or Hong Kong. 23 NUTS: Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics. 18 Furthermore, it may be noticed that there is a general lack of interest in investing in Southern and Southeastern Europe. Central European regions, on the other hand, in particular the Czech Republic and Romania, have received a considerably higher total share of greenfield investments, compared to what they receive from Chinese MNEs. Appendix A.3 provides an overview of the distribution of Chinese greenfield investments in Europe across nine economic functions, i.e., a stage or activity within the value chain of a firm. As shown in this table, more than 55% of Chinese greenfield investments in Europe are in sales and marketing offices, followed by headquarters (14%), production plants (11%), research and development centers (7%), and logistics centers (7%). Only a very limited number of investments are made in contact centers (<1%), education and training centers (<1%), shared services centers (1%), and testing and servicing centers (1%). Accordingly, following Brienen et al. (2010), it may be concluded that Chinese MNEs in Europe, compared to firms from other source countries, tend to invest relatively more in sales and marketing offices and headquarters and less in production plants. This would support the argument that Chinese firms that invest in Europe are primarily motivated by market-seeking (Brienen et al., 2010). Paragraph 3.4: Variables2425 Paragraph 3.4.1: Dependent Variable Each of the 351 Chinese firms that is included in the dataset and has established a subsidiary in Europe in the period 2002-2008 has faced 89 possible location alternatives (i.e., European regions) in their location decision-making process. In this empirical study, the dependent variable is equal to 1 for region j if firm i is set in region j, and zero for all regions different from j. Paragraph 3.4.2: Independent Variables To test the hypothesis that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is positively associated with the size of the overseas Chinese population in a region, for each European region, the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in the year 2000 is measured and entered into the empirical model as an explanatory variable.26 To test for the robustness of the empirical results, eight additional variables will be included in the empirical model, which each measure the size of an overseas Chinese community in a European region in a different way. 24 It is referred to Appendix A.4 for the descriptive statistics of all variables. It is referred to Appendix A.5 for a correlation matrix of all variables. 26 Sources: Parsons et al. (2005), Özden & Schiff (2007). 25 19 In this context, four variables will be entered into the empirical model that measure the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region, subdivided by the immigrants’ region of origin in China. In this study, the following regions of origin in China are distinguished: (a) mainland China, (b) Hong Kong and Macau, (c) mainland China, Hong Kong and Macau, and (d) Taiwan.27 The data on the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region is obtained by summing up the variables (c) and (d). In this study, a migrant in a European region is defined to be Chinese, if he/she holds citizenship (i.e., nationality) of either the People’s Republic of China (mainland China), Hong Kong or Macau, or Taiwan at the time of his/her migration to Europe (Parsons et al., 2005; Özden & Schiff, 2007). Unfortunately, data on these five variables is only available on a national level. Furthermore, to test for the robustness of the empirical results, four variables will be included in the empirical model that measure the size of the overseas Chinese population in a region in four different years: (a) 1955, (b) 1980, (c) 1990, and (d) 2000.28 Although this data has been collected from various sources, for all measured years, a uniform definition of the overseas Chinese has been employed. In this sense, the overseas Chinese are broadly defined to refer to all Chinese living outside mainland China and Taiwan, including Huaqiao (Chinese citizens residing abroad), Huaren (naturalized citizens of Chinese descent), and Huayi (descendants of Chinese parents) (Poston et al., 1994). Accordingly, this definition of the overseas Chinese includes all persons with any Chinese ancestry. Unfortunately, this data is also only available on a national level. To conclude this paragraph with, for all nine variables,29 a positive relationship is hypothesized with location choice. Paragraph 3.4.3: Control Variables Following paragraph 2.4, the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region is not likely to be the only (location) factor that determines the location choice of Chinese MNEs in Europe. Therefore, a number of control variables will be included in the empirical model. Demand Factors – In chapter 2, it is argued that Chinese MNEs are expected to be primarily motivated to invest in Europe for market-seeking reasons. Accordingly, it was hypothesized that Chinese firms will be drawn to locations in Europe with good market access. Therefore, control variables should be included in the empirical model that measure the attractiveness of a European region in this respect. In this context, not only local demand should be considered, but also the proximity of a region to other important sources of demand. Following Head & Mayer (2004), in this thesis, the market potential function of Harris (1954), which gravitationally equates the potential 27 Sources: Parsons et al. (2005), Özden & Schiff (2007). The year of measurement of these variables is 2000. Sources: 1955; Poston & Yu (1990), 1980: Poston et al. (1994), 1990: Poston et al. (1994), 2000: Li (2005). 29 In order to reduce the positive skew (Field, 2005), all nine variables are log-transformed. 28 20 demand for goods and services produced in a location with that location’s proximity to areas of consumer demand, will be included in the empirical model: 𝑀𝑃𝑗𝑡 = ∑ 𝑘 𝐾𝜀 ( 𝑌𝑘𝑖 ) 𝐷𝑗𝑘𝑡 (1) The market potential of a region j in year t is the sum of the GDP in the accessible regions k, weighted by the distance between j and k. This data is available on a regional level (NUTS-1) for the years 20022008, and is log-transformed.30 Market potential is not the only indicator of market access, however. Specifically, the location choice of headquarters and sales and marketing offices is also based on how quickly a particular location (European region) can be reached (Brienen et al., 2010). Accordingly, both an international airport dummy, which takes the value 1 if a region has an international airport with over 10 million international flights per year, and an international seaport dummy, which takes the value 1 if a region has an international seaport with a total cargo volume of at least 40 million metric tons per year, are included in the empirical model.31 Both variables are available on a regional level (NUTS-1), but are not year-specific.32 The presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region may also be considered to be an indicator of good market access for Chinese MNEs, because these communities may provide Chinese firms in Europe with important (foreign market) information, and thereby with market access. In this paragraph, it is referred to chapter 2 for further information on this argument, and to paragraph 3.4.2 for the variables that have been selected in this study to measure the presence and size of an overseas Chinese community in a European country/region. Supply Factors – As it is only an assumption that Chinese MNEs are expected to be primarily motivated to invest in Europe for market-seeking reasons, there should also be controlled for other location factors, which may be particularly important to firms that are investing in Europe for efficiency-seeking, resource-seeking or strategic asset-seeking reasons. In this context, following Brienen et al. (2010), there will be controlled for costs of production, most notably labor and capital costs. As a proxy for labor costs, sector-specific wage per hour is selected. This data is available on a regional level (NUTS-1) for the years 2002-2008, and is log-transformed.33 Wages do not represent all labor costs, however, since the functioning of the labor market (measured by the unemployment rate),34 the efficiency of the labor force (measured by the percentage of the population that has a university education (ISCED 5 and 6)), and non-wage labor costs (measured by the social charges rate) may also contribute to the total costs of labor (Head & Mayer, 2004). For the years 2002-2008, 30 Source: Brienen et al. (2010). Source: Brienen et al. (2010). 32 The year of measurement of these variables is 2005. 33 Source: Cambridge Econometrics Database. 34 The unemployment rate is measured as a percentage of the total labor force. 31 21 the data on the first two variables is available on a regional level (NUTS-1),35 while the data on the third variable is only available on a national level.36 Finally, the corporate tax rate in a country, which is measured as the statutory tax percentage rate at the national level, is included as a proxy for the costs of capital.37 Data on this variable is year-specific (2002-2008). Agglomeration Effects – The presence of an overseas Chinese community in a region can be characterized as an agglomeration advantage for Chinese firms locating in that particular region. More ‘traditional’ forms of agglomeration advantages may also play a role in the location choice of Chinese firms in Europe, however. Therefore, four variables are added to the model to test for these agglomeration effects. In their empirical study on location decisions of Japanese firms in Europe, Head & Mayer (2004) find that related firms tend to cluster in the same regions. In this thesis, two forms of relatedness will be considered. First, as a proxy for localization advantages, the (logtransformed) sector-specific employment level in a European region for the years 2002-2008 will be included in the empirical model.38 This variable captures the idea that firms demonstrate a statistical tendency to locate in regions, where firms from the same (sub)sector have already located. Second, for the years 2002-2008, a (log-transformed) variable will be entered into the empirical model that measures the number of greenfield investments in a European region (NUTS-1), which were made by Chinese firms in the five years previous to the year of measurement.39 Accordingly, this variable captures the idea that firms demonstrate a statistical tendency to locate in regions, where firms from the same country of origin have already located.40 Likewise, for the years 2002-2008, a (logtransformed) variable will be entered into the empirical model that measures the number of greenfield investments in a European region (NUTS-1), which were made by firms from all source countries in total in the five years previous to the year of measurement.41 Accordingly, this variable may serve as a proxy to measure the foreign direct investment climate in a region. In this sense, firms may derive agglomeration benefits by locating in regions where many foreign firms are already 35 Source: Brienen et al. (2010). The social charges rate is measured as a percentage of the total labor costs. Source: Ernst & Young International Human Capital Database. 37 Source: Ernst & Young International Tax Database. 38 Source: Cambridge Econometrics Database. 39 For a specific year (e.g., 2002), this number is measured by taking the sum of the Chinese greenfield investments in a region in the previous five years (e.g., for 2002: 1997-2001). As it is not possible to get a log value of zero or negative numbers, a constant (1) is added to this data. Calculations were made by the author. Source: Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor 2009 database. 40 Following Brienen et al. (2010), this may result in a path-dependent process of FDI concentration in space. 41 For a specific year (e.g., 2002), this number is measured by taking the sum of all greenfield investments in a region in the previous five years (e.g., for 2002: 1997-2001). As it is not possible to get a log value of zero or negative numbers, a constant (1) is added to this data. Calculations were made by the author. Source: Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor 2009 database. 36 22 established. Finally, as a proxy for urbanization advantages, the total employment level in a region will be included in the empirical model.42 Urbanization advantages can be derived from locating in an urban environment, close to firms in different (sub)sectors (Breschi & Malerba, 2005). This data is available on a regional level (NUTS-1) for the years 2002-2008, and is log-transformed. Appendix A.6 contains a list of all control variables, with the expected sign for the coefficient. Paragraph 3.5: Methodology In order to answer the research question that was posed in Chapter 1, a conditional logit model will be used (McFadden, 1974). Essentially, this model assumes that each Chinese firm is faced with a set of alternative location options (i.e., 89 European regions) for the establishment of its European subsidiary, with each firm comparing the relevant (location) attributes (Cameron & Trivedi, 2009). Accordingly, each location decision is considered to be the outcome of a discrete choice among 89 alternatives (Wu & Strange, 2000). In this context, it is assumed that a rational firm will choose to locate its subsidiary i in region j, if and only if this decision maximizes the expected future profits from its investment (Cheng & Stough, 2006).43 Unfortunately, the true profits yielded by each alternative location cannot be observed. One does, however, observe the actual choice of each firm and the characteristics of each alternative location (Cheng & Stough, 2006; Defever, 2006). Accordingly, it is assumed that the expected profit for firm i derived from locating in region j is a function of the observable attributes of region j (Xj), and a random disturbance term, εij (Cheng, 2007). This disturbance term reflects the unique advantages of region j to firm i (Wu & Strange, 2006). It differs across regions for any one firm, and across firms for any one region. Hence: 𝑅𝑖𝑗 = 𝛽𝑋𝑗 + 𝜀𝑖𝑗 (2) Rij is the expected profit earned by a Chinese firm if their subsidiary i is located in region j. Xj is a vector of choice-specific attributes for region j, β is a vector of coefficients to be estimated by maximum likelihood, and εij is the unobservable advantage of location j for firm i. As a result of the existence of the random component (εij) in the profit function, the exact choice made by a firm cannot be estimated or predicted through function (2). Instead, only the probability can be identified that a Chinese firm chooses region j, out of S potential regions, to locate its subsidiary i (Cheng & Stough, 2006). Following McFadden (1974), by assuming that the random terms are independently and identically distributed (IID) in the conditional logit model, the probability that subsidiary i will be located in region j may be mathematically expressed as follows: 42 Source: Cambridge Econometrics Database. This assumption fits right into the neoclassical economic theory of utility-maximizing behavior (McFadden, 2001). 43 23 𝑃𝑖𝑗 = 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝑋𝑖𝑗 𝛽𝑗 ) 𝑆 ∑𝑠=1 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝑋𝑖𝑠 𝛽𝑗 ) (3) Following Cheng (2007), the IID assumption implies an important property of the conditional logit model: independence from irrelevant alternatives (IIA). The IIA property specifies that for any firm the probability ratio of any two alternatives depends only on the (location) attributes of those two alternatives and is independent of other available alternatives. In other words, working on a subsample of the dataset (e.g., only the EU-15), instead of on the whole dataset (i.e., the EU-27, Norway and Switzerland), should produce the same empirical results, except of course for the loss of information in the omitted location decisions. The IIA property is violated when the unobserved disturbance terms (εij) are correlated (Train, 2003; Cheng & Stough, 2006). In such a case, estimations of conditional logit models may inconsistent. Therefore, in order to detect potential violations of the IIA property, a Hausman-McFadden test should be conducted (Hausman & McFadden, 1984). In a conditional logit model, the interpretation of estimated coefficients is not straightforward, because they are not directly related to marginal effects (Cheng & Stough, 2006). Following Head & Mayer (2004), in this study, average probability elasticity is used to measure the marginal magnitudes of the estimated parameters. When the explanatory variables have been entered into the model as natural logarithms, the elasticity’s with respect to these variables may be calculated directly from the estimated coefficients, by using the following formula (Greene, 2008): 𝐸𝑘 = 𝑑 𝑙𝑛 𝑃𝑗 = 𝛽𝑘 (1 − 𝑃) 𝑑 𝑙𝑛 𝑋𝑘 (4) Pj is the probability of locating in region j, P is the average probability elasticity, Xk is the explanatory variable under consideration, and βk is the estimated coefficient associated with variable X (Wu & Strange, 2000). Given that 89 European regions may be considered by Chinese firms, the average probability elasticity is 1/89 and thus (1 – P) equals 0.989 (Head & Mayer, 2004). A commonly used goodness-of-fit measure in conditional logit regressions is McFadden’s likelihood ratio index (Wu & Strange, 2006): 𝐿(𝑚𝑎𝑥) 𝜌2 = 1 − [ ] 𝐿(0) (5) The McFadden ρ2 index ranges from 0 to 1, just as the conventional R2 does. Following Hensher & Johnson (1981) in their comprehensive review of discrete choice models, values of ρ2 between 0.2 and 0.4 are considered to represent very good fits. 24 CHAPTER 4: EMPIRICAL RESULTS Paragraph 4.1: Introduction In the previous chapter, the dataset that is being used in this study has been discussed. Furthermore, the conditional logit model has been explained. In this chapter, the empirical results will be presented. In paragraph 4.2, the base model will be discussed, followed by paragraph 4.3, in which nine model specifications will be introduced that will enable to test for the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in Europe. In paragraph 4.4, six additional model specifications will be presented that will enable to test for differences between firms that are based in mainland China and Hong Kong. Furthermore, in paragraph 4.5, five model specifications will be introduced that will enable to test for differences between firms with different economic functions within the value chain of a firm. In paragraph 4.6, a Hausman-McFadden test will be conducted, in order to test for potential violations of the IIA assumption. In paragraph 4.7, this chapter will be ended with a conclusion. Paragraph 4.2: Base Model As it is outlined in paragraph 3.4.3, the selected control variables can be categorized into three groups: (a) variables related to market access (i.e., demand factors), (b) variables related to costs of production (i.e., supply factors), and (c) variables related to agglomeration advantages (i.e., agglomeration effects). In model specification (1), all control variables are included. Accordingly, this model may be characterized as the base model. Furthermore, in this thesis, nine variables have been selected to measure the presence and size of an overseas Chinese community in a European region.44 Due to the high correlation between these nine variables,45 they will be entered into the model separately. Accordingly, model specifications (2) to (10) add these variables (separately) to the first model specification. Hence, nine new model specifications are constructed, which can be found in Table 2. In chapter 2, it was hypothesized that Chinese greenfield investments in Europe are primarily motivated by market-seeking. In this study, evidence is found that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is indeed positively associated with variables that indicate good market access. Following Table 2, a positive relationship is found between market potential and the number of yearly investments made. Only in model specifications (4) and (6), this relationship is not found to be significant. The presence of an international airport in a region is also 44 45 It is referred to paragraph 3.4.2. It is referred to appendix A.5. 25 found to be positively associated with the number of yearly investments made. This relationship is found to be significant in all model specifications. The presence of an international seaport in a region, on the other hand, is not found to have a significant relationship with the number of yearly investments made in any of the model specifications. Following Table 2, when supply factors are considered, a positive relationship is found between wage per hour and the number of yearly investments made. Only in model specification (9), this relationship is not found to be significant. The sign of the coefficient is contrary to what was expected, however, as a negative relationship was hypothesized. The unemployment rate in a region is found to be positively associated with the number of yearly investments made. However, only in model specifications (2) to (5), this relationship is found to be significant. The corporate tax rate in a country is found to be negatively associated with the number of yearly investments made, as it was hypothesized. Only in model specifications (1) and (4), this relationship is not found to be significant. The remaining control variables, i.e. the percentage of university educated people and the social charges rate, are not found to have a significant relationship with the number of yearly investments made in any of the model specifications. Accordingly, it may be concluded that the hypothesis that Chinese greenfield investments in Europe are primarily motivated by market-seeking is not invalidated by these empirical results. Following Table 2, when agglomeration effects are considered, for all model specifications, a significant and positive relationship is found between localization advantages and the number of yearly investments made. Furthermore, for all model specifications, a significant and positive relationship is found between total previous (Chinese) greenfield investments in a region and the number of yearly investments made, potentially indicating a path-dependent process of FDI concentration in space (Brienen et al., 2010). Accordingly, following Appendix A.6, the signs of these coefficients are as expected. Urbanization advantages, on the other hand, are not found to have a significant relationship with the number of yearly investments made in any of the model specifications. Paragraph 4.3: Testing for the Relationship between the Size of the Chinese Population in a European Region and the Number of Chinese Greenfield Investments Made In this thesis, nine variables have been selected to measure the presence and size of an overseas Chinese community in a European region. Following column (2), and in accordance with the main hypothesis of this thesis, it is found that there is a significant and positive relationship between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. The question then arises what the magnitude of this relationship is. As it is 26 outlined in paragraph 3.5, in a conditional logit model, the interpretation of the estimated coefficients is not straightforward, because they are not directly related to marginal effects. In this thesis, for all log-transformed variables, the average probability elasticity of a location attribute (Xk), i.e. its estimated marginal effect, is equal to 0.989βk. Accordingly, with the coefficient of the variable at stake being 0.2730728, the estimated marginal effect is 0.27%. Hence, a 10 percent increase in the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region increases the probability of attracting Chinese greenfield investments into that region by 2.7%. To test for the robustness of these empirical results, in the columns (3) to (10), eight alternative measures of the size of the overseas Chinese population in a European region are (separately) added to the base model. In this context, model specifications (3) to (6) add four variables to the base model, which measure the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region, subdivided by the immigrants’ region of origin in China: (3) mainland China; (4) Hong Kong and Macau; (5) mainland China, Hong Kong and Macau; (6) Taiwan. Following Table 2, for each of these four variables, a significant and positive relationship is found with the number of yearly investments made. Following column (3), a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China increases the probability of attracting Chinese greenfield investments into that region by 2.7%. Following column (4), a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong increases the probability of attracting Chinese greenfield investments into that region by 0.9%. Following column (5), a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China, Hong Kong and Macau increases the probability of attracting Chinese greenfield investments into that region by 2.7%. Finally, following column (6), a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Taiwan increases the probability of attracting Chinese greenfield investments into that region by 1.5%. To test for the equality of these coefficients, ten Wald tests have been performed, which can be found in Appendix A.7A. In model specifications (7) to (10), to test for the robustness of the empirical results, four variables are added to the base model that measure the size of the ethnic Chinese community in a European region in four different years: (7) 1955; (8) 1980; (9) 1990; (10) 2000. As it is outlined in chapter 2, Chinese firms are hypothesized to locate in regions with a sizeable overseas Chinese community, through which they may obtain both important (foreign market) information and support in the establishment of business relationships. In this respect, the size of such a community in the past seems of less relevance to Chinese MNEs than the size of the current (ethnic) Chinese population in a European region. Nevertheless, the presence of these communities in the past may indicate the longtime presence of an ethnic Chinese community in a European region. Therefore, a significant and positive relationship is expected between the size of the ethnic Chinese community in 27 a European region (in all measured years) and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made between 2002 and 2008. In this respect, the more recent the year of measurement, the stronger the relationship is hypothesized to be, though. For each of these four variables, a significant and positive relationship is found with the number of yearly investments made. For the year 1955, the estimated marginal effect is 0.09%, as can be calculated from column (7). Following column (8), for the year 1980, the estimated marginal effect is 0.08%. When a variable is added to the base model that measures the size of the ethnic Chinese community in a European region in 1990, it is found that its estimated marginal effect is 0.11%, as can be calculated from column (9). Following column (10), for the year 2000, the estimated marginal effect is 0.16%. To test for the equality of these coefficients, six Wald tests have been performed, which can be found in Appendix A.7B. Following these empirical results, it may not be concluded that the relationship between the size of the ethnic Chinese community in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made in a region between 2002 and 2008 is stronger for more recent years of measurement of the size of the ethnic Chinese community in a European region. To conclude this paragraph with, in all nine model specifications, a significant and positive relationship is found between the size of the overseas Chinese community in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. In this regard, it should be noted, however, that the magnitude of this relationship varies, depending on the variable that is chosen to measure the size of the Chinese population in an area. Based on the empirical results that were presented in this paragraph, it may be concluded that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is indeed positively associated (at a significant level) with the size of the overseas Chinese community in a European region, as it was hypothesized in chapter 2 of this thesis. The question then remains whether these model specifications represent a good fit. Following Hensher & Johnson (1981) in their comprehensive review of discrete choice models, values of ρ2 between 0.2 and 0.4 are considered to represent very good fits. Following Table 2, model specifications (2) to (10) are found to have values of ρ2 between 0.169 and 0.174. 28 Table 2: Model Specifications (1)-(10) Demand Factors Location Factors Market Potential (log) Airport Dummy Seaport Dummy Supply Factors Wage per Hour (log) Unemployment Rate University Education Social Charges Rate Corporate Tax Rate Agglomeration Effects Localization Advantages (log) Urbanization Advantages (log) Total Greenfield Investments (log) Chinese Greenfield Investments (log) (1) 0.72a (0.23) 0.35b (0.15) -0.06 (0.17) 0.31b (0.12) 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.02 (0.02) 0.31a (0.10) -0.03 (0.17) 0.27a (0.10) 0.68a (0.10) (2) 0.50b (0.24) 0.45a (0.15) 0.14 (0.16) 0.24c (0.13) 0.04b (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02) -0.05a (0.02) 0.35a (0.10) -0.19 (0.17) 0.39a (0.11) 0.56a (0.10) (3) 0.52b (0.25) 0.35b (0.15) 0.09 (0.16) 0.24c (0.13) 0.03c (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.05a (0.02) 0.32a (0.10) -0.16 (0.17) 0.40a (0.11) 0.60a (0.09) (4) 0.33 (0.24) 0.50a (0.15) 0.11 (0.17) 0.26b (0.12) 0.03c (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.02 (0.02) 0.34a (0.10) -0.12 (0.17) 0.35a (0.11) 0.57a (0.09) (5) 0.51b (0.24) 0.45a (0.15) 0.13 (0.16) 0.24c (0.13) 0.04b (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.05a (0.02) 0.35a (0.10) -0.19 (0.17) 0.38a (0.11) 0.56a (0.09) (6) 0.26 (0.25) 0.44a (0.15) 0.15 (0.17) 0.22c (0.13) 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.03c (0.02) 0.31a (0.10) -0.03 (0.18) 0.34a (0.11) 0.58a (0.09) (7) 0.57b (0.25) 0.48a (0.16) -0.02 (0.16) 0.25c (0.13) 0.02 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.04b (0.02) 0.33a (0.10) -0.10 (0.18) 0.28a (0.10) 0.63a (0.09) (8) 0.61b (0.24) 0.51a (0.17) -0.01 (0.16) 0.23c (0.14) 0.02 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.03c (0.02) 0.33a (0.10) -0.12 (0.18) 0.27b (0.11) 0.64a (0.09) (9) 0.62a (0.24) 0.51a (0.17) -0.01 (0.16) 0.20 (0.14) 0.02 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.04b (0.02) 0.33a (0.10) -0.15 (0.18) 0.29a (0.11) 0.62a (0.09) (10) 0.51b (0.26) 0.51a (0.17) -0.01 (0.16) 0.26b (0.13) 0.02 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) -0.03c (0.02) 0.34a (0.10) -0.14 (0.18) 0.27a (0.11) 0.63a (0.09) 29 Table 2: Model Specifications (1)-(10) (continued) Chinese Population Test Statistics Location Factors Migrant Stock (Total) (log) Migrant Stock (Mainland China) (log) Migrant Stock (Hong Kong + Macau) (log) Migrant Stock (Mainland China + Hong Kong + Macau) (log) Migrant Stock (Taiwan) (log) Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1955 (log) Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1980 (log) Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1990 (log) Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 2000 (log) (1) Number of Observations Number of Cases Likelihood Ratio Index (Pseudo R2) AIC BIC 28666 338 0.1672 2523.9 2623.0 (2) 0.27a (0.07) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) 0.27a (0.07) 0.09a (0.03) 0.27a (0.06) 0.15a (0.05) 0.09b (0.04) 0.08b (0.03) 0.11a (0.04) 0.16a (0.06) 28666 338 0.1743 2504.4 2611.9 28666 338 0.1724 2510.1 2617.6 28666 338 0.1723 2510.6 2618.0 28666 338 0.1742 2504.7 2612.2 28666 338 0.1711 2514.2 2621.7 28666 338 0.1687 2521.4 2628.9 28666 338 0.1689 2520.6 2628.0 28666 338 0.1698 2518.1 2625.5 28666 338 0.1696 2518.5 2626.0 Note: Standard errors in parentheses with a, b and c respectively denoting significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels. 30 Paragraph 4.4: Testing for Differences Between Firms Based in Mainland China and Firms Based in Hong Kong In Table 3, six model specifications (11-16) are introduced that enable to test for differences between firms that are based in mainland China and Hong Kong. Accordingly, model specifications (11) to (13) contain exactly the same variables as respectively columns (2) to (4). The difference is that in model specifications (2) to (4) the location choice of all firms in the dataset is analyzed, irrespective of their region of origin in China (i.e., mainland China or Hong Kong), and that in columns (11) to (13) only firms are included in the analysis that are based in mainland China. Likewise, model specifications (14) to (16) only include firms in the analysis that are based in Hong Kong. Accordingly, by comparing the two sets of model specifications, differences between firms that are based in mainland China and Hong Kong – on the role of overseas Chinese communities in their location decisions in Europe – can be analyzed. Both for firms that are based in mainland China and for firms that are based in Hong Kong, it is hypothesized, in accordance with the main hypothesis of this thesis, that their location choice is positively associated with the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region, the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China and the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong and Macau. For firms based in mainland China, the magnitude of these coefficients is hypothesized to be stronger for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China than for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong and Macau. Likewise, for firms based in Hong Kong, the magnitude of these coefficients is hypothesized to be stronger for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong and Macau than for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China. Accordingly, it is hypothesized that Chinese firms have a preference for European regions with a (sizeable) overseas Chinese community, with whom they share a region of origin in China. Following Tong (2005), associations of overseas Chinese (in Europe) have traditionally been based on kinship, dialect and place (region) of origin in China. Since contacts between Chinese MNEs and local Chinese networks are probably made through guanxi, it is hypothesized that relationships are more likely to exist or develop between Chinese firms and local Chinese networks that share the same region of origin in China. As a consequence of that, it is hypothesized that Chinese firms have a preference for European regions with a (sizeable) overseas Chinese community, with whom they share a region of origin in China. In this thesis, no hypothesis is proposed on whether the relationship between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region and the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a region is stronger for firms based in mainland China or for firms based in Hong Kong, because it could 31 be argued both ways. Since Hong Kong has been a colony/dependent territory of the United Kingdom until 1997 (Thunø, 2001), Hong Kong has been integrated in the global economy for a much longer time than mainland China, which has only recently decided to open up its borders. Accordingly, it may be assumed that over the years firms based in Hong Kong have been able to develop and maintain better contacts with overseas Chinese communities in Europe than their mainland Chinese counterparts. Hence, it could be argued that firms based in Hong Kong will more easily be able to connect to local Chinese networks in Europe. Accordingly, following this reasoning, when their location decisions in Europe are considered, it could be hypothesized that the relationship between the size of the of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region and the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a region is stronger for firms based in Hong Kong than for firms based in mainland China. However, it could also be argued that, because firms based in Hong Kong have been active on the global economic stage for a much longer time than their mainland Chinese counterparts, they no longer need to connect to local Chinese networks to obtain important (foreign market) information and support in the establishment of business relationships. Accordingly, following this reasoning, it could also hypothesized that the relationship between the size of the of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region and the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a region is stronger for firms based in mainland China than for firms based in Hong Kong. Following model specification (12), for firms based in mainland China, a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China increases the probability of locating in that region by 3.3%. Following model specification (13), for firms based in mainland China, a 10 percent increase in the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong and Macau increases the probability of locating in that region by 1.1%. Following model specification (11), for firms based in mainland China, a 10 percent increase in the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region increases the probability of locating in that region by 3.2%. To test for the equality of these coefficients, three Wald tests have been performed, which can be found in Appendix A.7C. The question then remains whether these model specifications represent a good fit. Following Hensher & Johnson (1981), values of ρ2 between 0.2 and 0.4 are considered to represent very good fits. Following Table 3, model specifications (11) to (13) are found to have values of ρ2 between 0.165 and 0.177. Following model specifications (14) to (16), for firms based in Hong Kong, it is found that neither of the selected variables that measure the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a European region has a significant coefficient. Furthermore, many of the control variables that were found to be significant in most of the other model specifications are found to be insignificant, when only firms based in Hong Kong are considered. Moreover, it is found that some control variables, such as the presence of an international seaport in a region and the percentage of university educated people, 32 have a significant coefficient in these model specifications, while these variables are not found to be significant in most of the other model specifications. Accordingly, based on these empirical results, it can be questioned if the estimated coefficients for Hong Kong firms offer an accurate picture of reality, as it may also be possible that these empirical results may be biased due to the (relatively) low number of observations of firms in the dataset that are based in Hong Kong. Therefore, it seems prematurely to draw any conclusions on location decisions of Hong Kong based firms in Europe, grounded on only these empirical results. As a consequence of that, no comparison can be made between firms based in mainland China and firms based in Hong Kong, regarding the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of these firms in Europe. Following Table 3 and Appendix A.7C, support is found for the hypothesis that for firms based in mainland China, the relationship between the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region and the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a region is stronger for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from mainland China than for the size of the Chinese migrant stock in a region originating from Hong Kong and Macau. Accordingly, it would seem that support is found for the hypothesis that Chinese firms have a preference for European regions with a (sizeable) overseas Chinese community, with whom they share a region of origin in China. However, one should be very precautious about drawing such a conclusion, when only these empirical results are considered. Following paragraph 3.4.2, a migrant in a European region is defined to be Chinese, if he/she holds citizenship of either the People’s Republic of China, Hong Kong or Macau, or Taiwan at the time of his/her migration to Europe. However, a person’s nationality does not imply that a person may not be rooted in another country/region in China. Likewise, regarding a firm’s region of origin in China, such a registration does not imply that a firm may not be rooted in another country/region in China. Accordingly, the data may give an indication of a person’s or firm’s region of origin in China, but not a definitive answer. 33 Table 3: Model Specifications (11)-(21) Location Factors Origin of the Firm Function of the Firm Demand Factors Market Potential (log) Airport Dummy Seaport Dummy Supply Factors Wage per Hour (log) Unemployment Rate University Education Social Charges Rate Corporate Tax Rate Agglomeration Effects Localization Advantages (log) Urbanization Advantages (log) Total Greenfield Investments (log) Chinese Greenfield Investments (log) (11) China* x 0.63b (0.28) 0.48a (0.17) -0.03 (0.19) 0.23 (0.14) 0.04c (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.01) -0.06a (0.02) 0.41a (0.11) -0.36c (0.19) 0.42a (0.12) 0.57a (0.10) (12) China* x 0.64b (0.29) 0.36b (0.16) -0.10 (0.19) 0.23 (0.14) 0.03 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02) -0.06a (0.02) 0.39a (0.11) -0.33c (0.19) 0.43a (0.12) 0.61a (0.10) (13) China* x 0.48c (0.27) 0.55a (0.17) -0.08 (0.19) 0.26c (0.14) 0.03 (0.02) -0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02) -0.03c (0.02) 0.41a (0.10) -0.29 (0.19) 0.37a (0.12) 0.60a (0.10) (14) HK** x 0.11 (0.48) 0.16 (0.37) 0.67c (0.36) 0.41 (0.30) 0.06 (0.05) 0.05c (0.03) -0.01 (0.04) -0.01 (0.04) -0.06 (0.27) 0.65 (0.43) 0.39 (0.27) 0.48b (0.22) (15) HK** x 0.13 (0.48) 0.15 (0.37) 0.65b (0.36) 0.42 (0.31) 0.06 (0.05) 0.05b (0.03) -0.02 (0.04) -0.01 (0.05) -0.07 (0.27) 0.67 (0.44) 0.38 (0.27) 0.48b (0.21) (16) HK** x -0.09 (0.57) 0.22 (0.39) 0.74b (0.38) 0.40 (0.30) 0.06 (0.05) 0.05c (0.03) -0.01 (0.04) -0.01 (0.04 -0.05 (0.27) 0.64 (0.42) 0.41 (0.28) 0.44c (0.23) (17) x H** 0.61 (0.74) 1.22a (0.45) 0.55 (0.76) -0.54 (0.45) -0.01 (0.08) 0.09a (0.03) 0.19b (0.08) -0.22a (0.07) 0.72a (0.25) -0.76c (0.42) 0.23 (0.35) 0.46 (0.29) (18) x L** 0.71 (0.92) -1.00 (0.65) 0.64 (0.72) 0.29 (0.57) 0.06 (0.06) 0.04 (0.04) 0.01 (0.05) -0.04 (0.06) -0.05 (0.27) -0.03 (0.62) 0.71c (0.41) 0.12 (0.34) (19) x M** -0.87 (0.60) -0.63 (0.48) -0.75 (0.80) 0.24 (0.47) 0.09b (0.04) -0.05 (0.04) -0.01 (0.04) -0.02 (0.04) 0.22 (0.52) -0.05 (0.60) 0.91a (0.34) 0.44c (0.26) (20) x RD** -0.94 (0.75) -0.16 (0.49) -15.10a (0.51) 1.35a (0.36) -0.33a (0.10) -0.10b (0.04) 0.01 (0.05) 0.09c (0.05) 0.21 (0.23) -0.33 (0.48) 0.77a (0.26) 0.44 (0.27) (21) x SM** 0.74b (0.36) 0.73a (0.21) 0.44b (0.18) 0.37b (0.17) 0.04 (0.03) 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.02) -0.05c (0.02) 0.34a (0.12) -0.04 (0.23) 0.19 (0.14) 0.61a (0.14) 34 Table 3: Model Specifications (11)-(21) (continued) Location Factors Origin of the Firm Function of the Firm Chinese Population Test Statistics Migrant Stock (Total) (log) Migrant Stock (Mainland China) (log) Migrant Stock (Hong Kong + Macau) (log) Number of Observations Number of Cases Likelihood Ratio Index (Pseudo R2) AIC BIC (11) China* x 0.32a (0.07) (12) China* x (13) China* x (14) HK* x 0.02 (0.13) 0.33a (0.08) (15) HK* x (16) HK* x (17) x H** 0.50a (0.41) (18) x L** 0.01 (0.17) (19) x M** 0.21 (0.23) (20) x RD** -0.15 (0.17) (21) x SM** 0.37a (0.10) -0.01 (0.15) 0.11a (0.03) 0.04 (0.06) 23660 279 0.1773 23660 279 0.1749 23660 279 0.1746 4921 58 0.2100 4921 58 0.2099 4921 58 0.2110 4165 49 0.3846 1947 23 0.0990 2797 33 0.1035 2205 26 0.2410 16449 194 0.2208 2064.5 2169.4 2070.4 2175.3 2071.2 2176.1 433.0 517.5 433.0 517.5 432.4 517.0 293.9 376.3 210.0 282.4 288.7 365.9 201.2 275.3 1368.4 1468.6 Note: Standard errors in parentheses with a, b and c respectively denoting significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels. * ** China: Mainland China; HK: Hong Kong H: Headquarters; L: Logistics; M: Manufacturing: RD: Research & Development; SM: Sales & Marketing 35 Paragraph 4.5: Testing for Differences Between Firms with Different Economic Functions within the Value Chain of a Firm The Ernst & Young European Investment Monitor 2009 database contains information on 351 Chinese greenfield investments in Europe in the period 2002-2008. In this context, Appendix A.3 provides an overview of the distribution of these investments across nine economic functions: (1) contact centre; (2) education & training; (3) headquarters; (4) logistics; (5) manufacturing; (6) research & development; (7) sales & marketing; (8) shared services centre; (9) testing & servicing.46 In this context, it may be expected that greenfield investments in different stages or activities within the value chain of a firm will be drawn to locations with different (location) characteristics. Accordingly, firms that invest in sales and marketing offices are hypothesized to make different location decisions than firms that invest in manufacturing plants. As in model specifications (1) to (16) no distinction is made between firms with different economic functions, the empirical results that were obtained in these regression analyses may be biased, since these firms may prefer different location characteristics because of those differences. Accordingly, model specifications (17) to (21) each contain exactly the same variables as model specification (2). However, where in model specification (2), the location choice of all firms in the dataset is analyzed, irrespective of their economic function, in model specification (17), only firms are included in the empirical analysis that invest in headquarters. Likewise, in model specifications (18) to (21), only firms are included in the empirical analysis that invest in (respectively) logistics centers, manufacturing plants, research & development centers, and sales & marketing offices. No separate regression analyses are run for contact centers, education & training facilities, shared service centers and testing & servicing facilities, because too little observations are available for these economic functions to run a statistically sound regression analysis. Following model specifications (17) to (21), only for firms that invest in headquarters and sales & marketing offices, a significant and positive relationship is found between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. For firms that invest in either logistics centers, manufacturing plants or research & development centers, no significant relationship is found, whether positive or negative, between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. Furthermore, when the coefficients of the control variables in the model specifications (18) to (20) are considered, some very remarkable results, compared to the other model specifications, are found as well. Therefore, following the same argument as in paragraph 4.4, it can be questioned if the estimated coefficients in these model specifications offer an accurate 46 It is referred to Appendix A.8 for a definition of these economic functions. 36 picture of reality. More likely, these empirical results are biased due to the (relatively) low number of observations of firms in the dataset that invest in either of these economic functions. Hence, drawing any conclusions on location decisions of Chinese firms in Europe that invest in either logistics centers, manufacturing plants or research & development centers seems prematurely, when only these empirical results are considered. Following model specification (17), for Chinese firms in Europe that invest in headquarters, it is found that there is a significant and positive relationship between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of such greenfield investments made, with the coefficient being 0.50. Accordingly, when only Chinese greenfield investments in headquarters are considered, a 10 percent increase in the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region increases the probability of attracting such investments into that region by 5.0%. Likewise, following column (21), for Chinese firms in Europe that invest in sales and marketing offices, it is found that there is a significant and positive relationship between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of such greenfield investments made, with the coefficient being 0.37. Accordingly, when only Chinese greenfield investments in sales and marketing offices are considered, a 10 percent increase in the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a region increases the probability of attracting such investments into that region by 3.7%. In this context, it should be emphasized, however, that the empirical results that were obtained in model specification (17) may also be biased, due to a (relatively) low number of observations. Accordingly, with almost 70% of all Chinese greenfield investments in Europe being made in headquarters and sales and marketing offices, running these separate regression analyses enables to obtain interesting insights on the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of the majority of Chinese MNEs in Europe. The question then remains whether these model specifications represent a good fit. Following Table 3, model specifications (17) and (21) are found to have values of ρ2 of respectively 0.385 and 0.221, which are both considered to represent very good fits (Hensher & Johnson, 1981). Paragraph 4.6: Hausman-McFadden Test As it is outlined in chapter 3, in order to detect potential violations of the IIA property, a HausmanMcFadden test should be conducted (Hausman & McFadden, 1984). For model specification (2), such is a test is carried out in Appendix A.8. It is found that the IIA property is violated for 8 alternatives. In this context, it should be noted, however, that such a violation of the IIA property is not that surprising, when it is taken into account that 89 different alternatives may be considered. Nevertheless, this violation indicates that this conditional logit model might not be well specified and might generate improper estimations and forecasts (Cheng, 2007). Following Cheng & Stough (2006), 37 however, the IIA assumption is often violated in the industrial location literature. This is primarily the case because discrete choice models, such as the conditional logit model, are not developed in a spatial context. Unlike non-spatial alternatives, spatial alternatives are less likely to be equally substitutable as a result of their geographic locations (Cheng, 2007). To remedy the potential violation of the IIA property, a number of alternative methodologies have been suggested, that may be applied in the industrial location literature, such as a nested logit model or a mixed logit model (Head & Mayer, 2004). The nested logit model is a viable alternative to the conditional logit model, because it relaxes the restrictive IIA property by grouping closely substitutable alternatives into one group (nest). Accordingly, the nested logit model is able to preserve equal substitutability within each nest, in order to satisfy the IIA property, while accommodating substitutability across different nests (Ben-Akiva & Lerman, 1985). Accordingly, an investor faces a hierarchical and staged decision process, i.e. first the investor chooses a country (group of countries), then he/she chooses a region within a country (a country within a group of countries). The nested logit model also has a few drawbacks, however. First, it offers only a partial solution, because it is still assumed that the IIA assumption holds among alternatives within the same nest (Cheng & Stough, 2006). Second, the determination of the nests requires a priori information, and this information, in some cases, might seem arbitrary (Knapp et al., 2001). A mixed logit model, with the help of simulation techniques, does not rely on the IIA assumption for coefficient estimation (McFadden & Train, 2000; Train, 2003). In addition, the mixed logit model, unlike the conditional logit model or the nested logit model, allows heterogonous tastes among decision-makers regarding a particular alternative attribute (Cheng & Stough, 2006). Accordingly, this taste heterogeneity can reveal different reactions in response to a change of alternative attributes. The mixed logit model also has its drawbacks, however. Particularly, the computational burden of simulation techniques has discouraged many scholars from applying it to empirical applications on large datasets (Basile et al., 2008). Paragraph 4.7: Conclusion In this chapter, the relationship between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made has been tested. In this context, nine different variables have been selected to measure the presence and size of an overseas Chinese community in a European region. In this study, for all nine variables, a significant and positive relationship was found between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. The magnitude of this relationship was found to vary, though, depending on the variable that was chosen to measure the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in an area. 38 Furthermore, the relationship between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made has been tested, separate for firms based in mainland China and for firms based in Hong Kong. Unfortunately, too little observations were available for firms based in Hong Kong, as a result of which no conclusions could be drawn on the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of these firms in Europe. As a consequence of that, it could not be tested for differences on this topic between firms with different regions of origin in China. Furthermore, the relationship between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made has been tested, separate for firms with different economic functions within the value chain of a firm. For both headquarters and sales & marketing offices, it was found that there is a significant and positive relationship between the size of the (total) Chinese migrant stock in a European region and the number of such greenfield investments made. Based on the empirical results that were presented in this chapter, it may be concluded that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is indeed positively associated (at a significant level) with the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a region, as it was hypothesized in chapter 2 of this thesis. 39 CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSION In this thesis, the role of overseas Chinese communities in the location decisions of Chinese MNEs in European regions has been investigated. In this context, only greenfield investments have been considered. In this study, it has been argued that successful foreign direct investment in Europe by Chinese MNEs requires intensive information. For a Chinese firm, which is not already embedded in the local (host country) market, this information may be difficult and costly to obtain, however. Furthermore, for Chinese MNEs, establishing fruitful commercial relationships with local partners may be difficult and costly to realize. Accordingly, following this reasoning, both transaction costs and business risks associated with investing in Europe would be high for Chinese firms. Therefore, it was argued that a linkage to a local network, through which a firm can more easily gain access to (foreign market) information and establish business relationships, may be a crucial determinant for successful foreign direct investment by Chinese firms in Europe. For Chinese MNEs, it was argued that the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region may offer the best possibility to establish a linkage to a local network in Europe. Accordingly, it was hypothesized that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is positively associated with the size of the overseas Chinese population in a region. In this thesis, 351 Chinese greenfield investments in 89 European regions (NUTS-1) during the period 2002-2008 have been studied. To test the relationship between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made, nine different variables have been selected to measure the presence and size of an overseas Chinese community in a European region. In this study, by employing a conditional logit model, for all nine variables, a significant and positive relationship was found between the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in a European region and the number of Chinese greenfield investments made. The magnitude of this relationship was found to vary, though, depending on the variable that was chosen to measure the size of the (overseas) Chinese population in an area. Furthermore, in this thesis, it was hypothesized that Chinese greenfield investments in Europe were primarily motivated by market-seeking. In this study, evidence was found that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is indeed positively associated with variables that indicate good market access, such as market potential and the presence of an international airport in a region. In this context, it should be noted that the presence of an overseas Chinese community in a European region may also be considered to be an indicator of good market access for Chinese MNEs. 40 An important property of the conditional logit model is the assumption of the independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). In this thesis, a Hausman-McFadden test has been conducted, in order to detect potential violations of the IIA property. In this context, it was found that the IIA property is violated for 8 alternatives. Although it is not quite uncommon in the industrial location literature for the IIA assumption to be violated, this violation indicates that the conditional logit model employed in this thesis might not be well specified and might generate improper estimations and forecasts. It should be noted, however, that a violation of the IIA property is not that surprising, when it is taken into account that 89 different alternatives may be considered. Nevertheless, it may be suggested for future research to use a different model, such as a nested logit model or a mixed logit model. However, each of these alternative methodologies also has its own drawbacks. As China increasingly makes its appearance on the global economic stage and becomes an important and assertive player in the world and European economies, the countries’ outward FDI is expected to develop at an even more rapid rate in the near future. This analysis has shown that the probability of Chinese greenfield investments in a European region is positively associated (at a significant level) with the size of the overseas Chinese population in a region. For host countries and regions, Chinese greenfield investments can boost the host location’s prospects for (national and/or regional) economic development through, for example, employment creation, capital growth and export promotion. Accordingly, for policy-makers in European regions, it may be in their own interest to try to increase the size of the overseas Chinese population in their region, for example by relaxing restraints on Chinese immigration into Europe. Furthermore, policy-makers in Europe may connect to local overseas Chinese communities and offer them their help in the support they offer to Chinese MNEs, who consider to invest in Europe. Accordingly, they may be able to increase the attractiveness of their region to Chinese MNEs and, as a results of that, boost the region’s prospects of economic growth. 41 REFERENCES Barba Navaretti, G. & Venables, A.J. (2004). Multinational Firms in the World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Basile, R., Castellani, D. & Zanfei, A. (2008). ‘Location Choices of Multinational Firms in Europe: The Role of EU Cohesion Policy’. Journal of International Economics, Vol. 74(2): 328-340. Ben-Akiva, M. & Lerman, S.R. (1985). Discrete Choice Analysis: Theory and Application to Travel Demand. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Brakman, S. & Garretsen, H. (2008). ‘Foreign Direct Investment and the Multinational Enterprise: An Introduction’, in: Brakman, S. & Garretsen, H. (eds.), Foreign Direct Investment and the Multinational Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 1-10. Braütigam, D. (2003). ‘Close Encounters: Chinese Business Networks as Industrial Catalysts in SubSaharan Africa’. African Affairs, Vol. 102(408): 447-467. Breschi, S. & Malerba, F. (eds.) (2005). Clusters, Networks & Innovation. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Brienen, M.J., Burger, M.J. & Van Oort, F.G. (2010). ‘The Geography of Chinese and Indian Greenfield Investments in Europe’. Eurasian Geography and Economics, Vol. 51(2): 254-273. Buckley, P.J., Clegg, L.J., Wang, C. (2002). ‘The Impact of Inward FDI on the Performance of Chinese Manufacturing Firms’. Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 33(4): 637-655. Buckley, P.J., Clegg, L.J., Cross, A.R., Liu, X., Voss, H. & Zheng, P. (2007). ‘The Determinants of Chinese Outward Foreign Direct Investment’. Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 38(4): 499-518. Cai, K.G. (1999). ‘Outward Foreign Direct Investment: A Novel Dimension of China’s Integration into the Regional and Global Economy’. The China Quarterly, No. 160: 856-880. Cameron, A.C. & Trivedi, P.K. (2009). Microeconomics using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press. Cheng, S. & Stough, R.R. (2006). ‘Location Decisions of Japanese New Manufacturing Plants in China: A Discrete-Choice Analysis’. Annals of Regional Science, Vol. 40(2): 369-387. Cheng, S. (2007). ‘Structure of Firm Location Choices: An Examination of Japanese Greenfield Investment in China’. Asian Economic Journal, Vol. 21(1): 47-73. Cheng, S. & Stough, R.R. (2007). ‘The Pattern and Magnitude of China’s Outward FDI in Asia’. Paper presented at the conference: ICRIER Project on Intra-Asian FDI Flows. New Delhi, India. Child, J. & Rodrigues, S.B. (2005). ‘The Internationalization of Chinese firms: A Case for Theoretical Extension?’ Management and Organization Review, Vol. 1(3): 381-410. Defever, F. (2006). ‘Functional Fragmentation and the Location of Multinational Firms in the Enlarged Europe’. Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 36(5): 658-677. 42 Deng, P. (2004). ‘Outward Investment by Chinese MNCs: Motivations and Implications’. Business Horizons, Vol. 47(3): 8-16. Deng, P. (2007). ‘Investing for Strategic Resources and Its Rationale: The Case of Outward FDI from Chinese Companies’. Business Horizons, Vol. 50(1): 71-81. Devereux, M.P. & Griffith, R. (1998). ‘Taxes and the Location of Production: Evidence from a Panel of US Multinationals’. Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 68(3): 335-367. Dunning, J.H. (1981b). International Production and the Multinational Enterprise. London, UK: Allen and Unwin. Dunning, J.H. (1993). Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Wokingham, UK: AddisonWesley. Dunning, J.H. (1998). ‘Location and the Multinational Enterprise: A Neglected Factor?’ Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 29(1): 45-66. Dunning, J.H. (2001). ‘The Eclectic (OLI) paradigm of International Production: Past, Present and Future’. International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 8(2): 173-190. Dunning, J.H. (2003). ‘Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment: Globalization-Induced Changes and the Role of Policies’. Proceedings of Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 279-290. Dunning, J.H. & Lundan, S.M. (2008). Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Wokingham, UK: Addison-Wesley. Ember, M., Ember, C.R. & Skoggard, I. (eds.) (2005). Encyclopedia of Diasporas, Immigrant and Refugee Cultures Around the World. New York, NY: Springer. Erdener, C. & Shapiro, D.M. (2005). ‘The Internationalization of Chinese Family Enterprises and Dunning’s Eclectic MNE Paradigm’. Management and Organization Review, Vol. 1(3): 411-436. Field, A. (2005). Discovering Statistics Using SPSS. London, UK: SAGE. Gould, D.M. (1994). ‘Immigrant Links to the Home Country: Empirical Implications for US Bilateral Trade Flows’. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 76(2): 302-316. Greene, W.H. (2008). Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson/Prentice Hall. Greif, A. (1993). ‘Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: the Maghribi Traders’. American Economic Review, Vol. 83(3): 525-548. Gugler, P. & Boie, B. (2008). ‘The Emergence of Chinese FDI: Determinants and Strategies of Chinese MNEs’. Paper presented at the conference: Emerging Multinationals: Outward Foreign Direct Investment from Emerging and Developing Economies. Copenhagen, Denmark: Copenhagen Business School. Harris, C.D. (1954). ‘The Market as a Factor in the Localization of Industry in the United States’. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 44(4): 315-348. 43 Hausman, J. & McFadden, D. (1984). ‘Specification Tests for the Multinomial Logit Model’, Econometrica, Vol. 52(5): 1219-1240. Hensher, D.A. & Johnson, L.W. (1981). Applied Discrete-Choice Modeling. New York, NY: Wiley. Hwang, E.R. (1987). ‘Face and Favor: The Chinese Power Game’. American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 92(4): 944-974. Johanson, J. & Vahlne, J.E. (1977). ‘The Internationalization Process of the Firm: A Model of Knowledge Development and Increasing Foreign Market Commitments’. Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 8(1): 23-32. Johanson, J. & Vahlne, J.E. (2009). ‘The Uppsala Internationalization Process Model Revisited : From Liability of Foreignness to Liability of Outsidership’. Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 40(9): 1411-1431. Johanson, J. & Wiedersheim-Paul, F. (1975). ‘The Internationalization of the Firm: Four Swedish Cases’. Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 12(3): 305-322. Kao, J. (1993). ‘The World-Wide Web of Chinese Business’. Harvard Business Review, Vol. 71(2): 2436. Karim, M.B. (ed.) (1986). The Green Revolution: An International Bibliography. New York, NY: Greenwood Press. Knapp, T., White, N. & Clark, D. (2001). ‘A Nested Logit Approach to Household Mobility’. Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 41(1): 1-22. Lall, S. & Albalajedo, M. (2004). ‘China’s Competitive Performance: A Threat to East Asian Manufactured Exports?’ World Development, Vol. 32(9): 1441-1466. Lau, H.-F. (2003). ‘Industry Evolution and Internationalization Processes of Firms from a Newly Industrialized Economy’. Journal of Business Research, Vol. 56(10): 847-852. Lecraw, D.J. (1977). ‘Direct Investment by Firms from Less Developed Countries’. Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 29(3): 442-457. Li, M. (2005). ‘Chinese in Europe’, in Ember, M., Ember, C.R. & Skoggard, I. (eds.), Encyclopedia of Diasporas, Immigrant and Refugee Cultures Around the World. New York, NY: Springer, pp. 656663. Lipsey, R.E. & Sjöholm, F. (2005). ‘The Impact of Inward FDI on Host Countries: Why Such Different Answers?’, in: Moran, T.H., Graham, E.M. & Blomström, M. (eds.), Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics and Centre for Global Development, pp. 23-44. Live, Y.S. (1998). ‘The Chinese Community in France: Immigration, Economic Activity, Cultural Organization and Representations’, in Benton, G. & Pieke, F.N. (eds.), The Chinese in Europe. Houndmills, UK: Macmillan, pp. 96-124. 44 Luo, Y. (1997). ‘Guanxi: Principles, Philosophies, and Implications’. Human Systems Management, Vol. 16(1): 43-51. Matthews, J.A. (2002). Dragon Multinational: A New Model for Global Growth. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Mathieu, E. (2006). ‘Investments from Large Developing Economies in France and Europe’. IFA Research Papers, 2006/11. McFadden, D. (1974). ‘Conditional Logit Analysis of Quantitative Choice Behavior’, in: Zarembka, P. (ed.), Frontier in Econometrics. New York, NY: Academic Press, pp. 105-142. McFadden, D. & Train, K. (2000). ‘Mixed MNL Models of Discrete Response’. Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 15(5): 447-470. McFadden, D. (2001). ‘Economic Choices’. American Economic Review, Vol. 91(3): 351-378. Milelli, C. & Hay, F. (2008). ‘Characteristics and Impacts of the Arrival of Chinese and Indian Firms in Europe: First Evidence’. Paper presented at the conference: Emerging Multinationals: Outward Foreign Direct Investment from Emerging and Developing Economies. Copenhagen, Denmark: Copenhagen Business School. Moon, H.-C. & Roehl, T.W. (2001). ‘Unconventional Foreign Direct Investment and the Imbalance Theory’. International Business Review, Vol. 10(2): 197-215. Morck, R., Yeung, B. & Zhao, M. (2008), ‘Perspectives on China’s Outward Foreign Direct Investment’. Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 39(3): 337-350. OECD (Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development) (1996), OECD Benchmark Definition of Foreign Direct Investment. Paris, France: OECD. Özden, C. & Schiff, M. (eds.) (2007). International Migration Policy and Economic Development: Studies Across the Globe. Washington, DC: World Bank (Chapter 1: 17-58). Park, S.H. & Luo, Y. (2001). ‘Guanxi and Organizational Dynamics: Organizational Networking in Chinese Firms’. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 22(5): 455-477. Parsons, C., Skeldon, R., Walmsley, T. & Winters, A. (2005). ‘Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants’. Sussex University, DRC Working Paper, No. WP-T13. Poston, D.L. & Yu, M.Y. (1990). ‘The Distribution of the Overseas Chinese in the Contemporary World’. International Migration Review, Vol. 24(3): 480-508. Poston, D.L., Mao, M.X. & Yu, M.Y. (1994). ‘The Global Distribution of the Overseas Chinese Abroad Around 1990’. Population and Development Review, Vol. 20(3): 631-645. Prime, P.B. (2009), ‘China and India Enter Global Markets: A Review of Comparative Economic Development and Future Prospects’. Eurasian Geography and Economics, Vol. 50(6): 621-642. Rauch, J.E. & Casella, A. (1998). ‘Overcoming International Barriers to International Resource Allocation: Prices and Group Ties’. The Economic Journal, Vol. 113(484): 21-42. 45 Rauch, J.E. & Trindade, V. (2002). ‘Ethnic Networks in International Trade’. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84(1): 116-130. Redding, G. (1995). ‘Overseas Chinese Networks: Understanding the Enigma’. Long Range Planning, Vol. 28(1): 61-69. Redding, G. & Ng, M. (1982). ‘The Role of Face in the Organizational Perceptions of Chinese Managers’. Organizational Studies, Vol. 3(3): 201-219. Romer, P.M. (1993). ‘Idea Gaps and Object Gaps in Economic Development’. Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32(3): 543-573. Standifird, S.S. & Marshall, R.S. (2000). ‘The Transaction Cost Advantage of Guanxi-Based Business Practices’. Journal of World Business, Vol. 35(1): 21-42. Sung, Y.-W. (1996). ‘Chinese Outward Investment in Hong Kong: Trends, Prospects, and Policy Implications’. OECD Development Centre Working Papers, 113. Taylor, R. (2002). ‘Globalization Strategies of Chinese Companies: Current Developments and Future Prospects’. Asian Business and Management, Vol. 1(2): 209-225. Thunø, M. (2001). ‘Reaching Out and Incorporating Chinese Overseas: The Trans-Territorial Scope of the PRC by the End of the 20th Century’. The China Quarterly, No. 168: 910-929. Tong, S.Y. (2005). ‘Ethnic Networks in FDI and the Impact of Institutional Development’. Review of Development Economics, Vol. 9(4): 563-580. Train, K.E. (2003). Discrete Choice Models with Simulation. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development) (2003), World Investment Report 2003 – FDI Policies for Development: National and International Perspectives. New York, NY: United Nations. UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development) (2006), World Investment Report 2006 – FDI from Developing and Transition Countries: Implications for Development. New York, NY: United Nations. UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development) (2009), World Investment Report 2009 – Transnational Corporations, Agricultural Production and Development. New York, NY: United Nations. Van Marrewijk, C. (2002). International Trade & The World Economy. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Weidenbaum, M. & Hughes, S. (1996). The Bamboo Network: How Expatriate Chinese Entrepreneurs Are Creating a New Economic Superpower in Asia. New York, NY: The Free Press. Wells, L.T. (1983). Third World Multinationals: The Rise of Foreign Investments from Developing Counties. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 46 Winters, L.A. & Yusuf, S. (2007), ‘Introduction: Dancing with Giants’, in Winters, L.A. & Yusuf, S. (eds.), Dancing with Giants: China, India and the Global Economy. Washington, DC/Singapore: World Bank and the International Institute for Policy Studies, pp. 1-34. World Bank (2010). ‘World Development Indicators & Global Development Finance’ (database), Washington, DC: World Bank, 2010, <http://databank.worldbank.org>. Wu, X. & Strange, R. (2000). ‘The Location of Foreign Insurance Companies in China’. International Business Review, Vol. 9(3): 383-398. Yang, M.M. (1994). Gifts, Favors and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China. New York, NY: Cornell University Press. Young, S., Hood, N. & Peters, E. (1994). ‘Multinational Enterprises and Regional Economic Development’. Regional Studies, Vol. 28(7): 657-677. Zhan, J.X. (1995). ‘Transnationalization and Outward Investment: The Case of Chinese Firms’. Transnational Corporations, Vol. 4(3): 67-100. Zhang, Y. (2003). China’s Emerging Global Businesses: Political Economy and Institutional Investigations. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan. 47 APPENDIX Appendix A.1: Greenfield Investments in Europe in the Years 1997-2008 (China vs. Total) Year 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 total Chinese Greenfield Investments 5 7 9 11 8 16 21 51 54 60 65 100 407 Total Greenfield Investments 1708 1416 1435 1672 1406 1355 1249 1962 2144 2480 3373 3415 23615 Appendix A.2: A List of All (NUTS-1) Regions in Europe (including the number of greenfield investments made in each region in the period 1997-2008) Country Austria Belgium Bulgaria Switzerland Cyprus Czech Republic Germany Region Code AT1 AT2 AT3 BE1 BE2 BE3 BG1 BG2 CH CY CZ DE1 DE2 DE3 DE4 DE5 DE6 DE7 DE8 DE9 DEA DEB DEC Region Name Ostösterreich Südösterreich Westösterreich Région de Bruxelles-Capitale/ Brussels Hoofdstedelijk Gewest Vlaams Gewest Région Wallonne Severna Bulgaria Yuzhna Bulgaria Switzerland Cyprus Czech Republic Baden-Württemberg Bayern Berlin Brandenburg Bremen Hamburg Hessen Mecklenburg-Vorpommern Niedersachsen Nordrhein-Westfalen Rheinland-Pfalz Saarland China 0 1 0 6 Total 304 50 120 268 14 7 1 3 4 2 2 3 9 4 0 32 9 12 1 2 32 0 0 600 240 181 187 688 11 844 179 443 184 70 32 132 428 35 49 360 31 17 48 Denmark Estonia Spain Finland France Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Lithuania Luxembourg Latvia Malta Netherlands Norway Poland DED DEE DEF DEG DK EE ES1 ES2 ES3 ES4 ES5 ES6 FI FR1 FR2 FR3 FR4 FR5 FR6 FR7 FR8 GR1 GR2 GR3 GR4 HU1 HU2 HU3 IE ITC ITD ITE ITF ITG LT LU LV MT NL1 NL2 NL3 NL4 NO PL1 PL2 PL3 PL4 PL5 PL6 Sachsen Sachsen-Anhalt Schleswig-Holstein Thüringen Denmark Estonia Noroeste Noreste Comunidad de Madrid Centro (ES) Este Sur Finland Île de France Bassin Parisien Nord - Pas-de-Calais Est Ouest Sud-Ouest Centre-Est Méditerranée Voreia Ellada Kentriki Ellada Attiki Nisia Aigaiou, Kriti Közép-Magyarország Dunántúl Alföld és Észak Ireland Nord Ovest Nord Est Centro (IT) Sud (IT) Isole (IT) Lithuania Luxembourg Latvia Malta Noord-Nederland Oost-Nederland West-Nederland Zuid-Nederland Norway Centralny Poludniowy Wschodni Pólnocno-Zachodni Poludniowo-Zachodni Pólnocny 0 0 1 2 14 0 0 0 3 1 6 2 1 17 3 0 3 3 3 7 3 1 0 0 0 9 4 1 1 10 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 12 3 0 1 0 0 0 1 4 70 76 26 46 454 160 51 92 441 71 628 86 179 1291 352 210 317 185 251 385 367 22 3 54 0 438 313 228 795 344 49 100 26 18 182 66 154 10 50 56 593 191 84 383 207 67 188 210 82 49 Portugal Romania Sweden Slovenia Slovakia United Kingdom PT RO SE SI SK UKC UKD UKE UKF UKG UKH UKI UKJ UKK UKL UKM UKN Portugal Romania Sweden Slovenia Slovakia North East North West (including Merseyside) Yorkshire and The Humber East Midlands West Midlands Eastern London South East South West Wales Scotland Northern Ireland 1 3 18 0 1 29 10 8 3 9 5 34 39 3 7 2 2 260 696 748 72 376 231 303 207 171 366 194 2060 827 202 221 416 161 Appendix A.3: Chinese Greenfield Investments in Europe in the Period 1997-2008 (subdivided by economic function) Economic Function Contact Centre Education & Training Headquarters Logistics Manufacturing Research & Development Sales & Marketing Shared Services Centre Testing & Servicing total Chinese Greenfield Investments 2 2 49 24 39 26 200 4 5 351 50 Appendix A.4: Descriptive Statistics Variable A Market Potential (log) B Airport Dummy C Seaport Dummy D Wage per Hour (log) E Unemployment Rate F University Education G Social Charges Rate H Corporate Tax Rate I Localization Advantages (log) J Urbanization Advantages (log) K Total Greenfield Investments (log) L Chinese Greenfield Investments (log) M Migrant Stock (Mainland China) (log) N Migrant Stock (Hong Kong + Macau) (log) O Migrant Stock (Mainland China + Hong Kong + Macau) (log) P Migrant Stock (Taiwan) (log) Q Migrant Stock (Total) (log) R Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1955 (log) S Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1980 (log) T Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1990 (log) U Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 2000 (log) Obs. 31239 31239 31239 29804 31239 31239 31239 31239 30373 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 31239 Mean 9.47 0.20 0.11 2.64 7.99 26.10 22.69 29.07 4.01 7.56 3.97 0.59 9.26 6.41 9.50 5.84 9.56 4.46 7.96 8.27 9.90 Std. Dev. 0.45 0.40 0.32 0.77 5.42 8.10 4.83 7.32 1.31 0.77 1.29 0.79 2.21 3.96 2.35 3.09 2.35 3.13 3.75 4.00 2.86 Min. 8.13 0 0 0 0 8.85 6.92 10 0 4.99 0 0 3.14 0 3.18 0 3.22 0 0 0 2.30 Max. 10.17 1.00 1.00 6.06 24.90 51.52 31.12 40.22 7.81 9.14 6.90 3.37 11.55 11.50 11.92 9.06 11.96 8.10 12.35 12.43 12.43 51 Appendix A.5: Correlation Matrix of All Independent Variables (including all control variables) A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Q R S T U * ** A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Q R S T U 1.00 0.24 0.22 0.52 -0.14 0.21 0.18 0.48 0.22 0.23 0.38 0.31 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.68 0.61 0.66 0.60 0.61 0.65 1.00 0.09 0.30 -0.22 0.28 0.10 0.08 0.23 0.39 0.46 0.26 0.20 0.05 0.17 0.10 0.17 0.11 0.15 0.19 0.14 1.00 0.21 -0.01 0.12 0.23 0.26 0.01 0.06 0.11 0.16 0.17 0.05 0.15 0.06 0.15 0.18 0.17 0.19 0.15 1.00 -0.43 0.43 0.15 0.49 -0.08 0.13 0.18 0.32 0.62 0.54 0.62 0.55 0.63 0.63 0.64 0.64 0.52 1.00 -0.30 0.01 0.04 -0.04 -0.04 -0.21 -0.29 -0.13 -0.19 -0.17 -0.13 -0.17 -0.19 -0.16 -0.15 -0.03 1.00 -0.05 0.06 -0.04 0.02 0.38 0.35 0.22 0.18 0.25 0.13 0.25 0.25 0.26 0.26 0.16 1.00 0.30 0.19 0.28 0.15 0.07 0.35 0.10 0.28 0.15 0.29 0.24 0.21 0.28 0.27 1.00 0.04 0.07 -0.13 0.05 0.66 0.51 0.64 0.52 0.64 0.67 0.62 0.64 0.52 1.00 0.62 0.40 0.15 0.22 0.08 0.20 0.09 0.20 0.15 0.17 0.21 0.25 1.00 0.57 0.27 0.34 0.12 0.33 0.11 0.32 0.27 0.32 0.38 0.42 1.00 0.50 0.13 0.09 0.15 0.11 0.15 0.17 0.21 0.22 0.28 1.00 0.26 0.30 0.29 0.31 0.29 0.35 0.34 0.34 0.29 1.00 0.73 0.99 0.73 0.99 0.85 0.85 0.90 0.88 1.00 0.79 0.93 0.79 0.80 0.76 0.73 0.65 1.00 0.75 0.99 0.87 0.88 0.92 0.82 1.00 0.76 0.80 0.76 0.74 0.69 1.00 0.87 0.88 0.92 0.88 1.00 0.93 0.93 0.80 1.00 0.98 0.89 1.00 0.91 1.00 It is referred to Appendix A.3 for a list of all variables. Observations: 31,239. 52 Appendix A.6: Expected Signs (control variables) Control Variables Market Potential (log) Airport Dummy Seaport Dummy Wage per Hour (log) Unemployment Rate University Education Social Charges Rate Corporate Tax Rate Localization Advantages (log) Urbanization Advantages (log) Total Greenfield Investments (log) Chinese Greenfield Investments (log) Expected Sign + + + ? + + + + + Appendix A.7: Wald Test (to test for the equality of the coefficients) Coefficient 1 mchin (0.27) mchin (0.27) mchin (0.27) mchin (0.27) mhkmc (0.09) mhkmc (0.09) mhkmc (0.09) mchhm (0.27) mchhm (0.27) mtwan (0.15) Coefficient 2 mhkmc (0.09) mchhm (0.27) mtwan (0.15) mchtot (0.27) mchhm (0.27) mtwan (0.15) mchtot (0.27) mtwan (0.15) mchtot (0.27) mchtot (0.27) Appendix A.7B eth55 (0.09) eth55 (0.09) eth55 (0.09) eth80 (0.08) eth80 (0.08) eth90 (0.11) eth80 (0.08) eth90 (0.11) eth00 (0.16) eth90 (0.11) eth00 (0.16) eth00 (0.16) Appendix A.7C mchin (0.33) mchin (0.33) mhkmc (0.11) mhkmc (0.11) mchtot (0.32) mchtot (0.32) Appendix A.7A chi2(1) 8.90 0.11 0.53 0.01 14.09 3.26 14.56 4.58 8.91 4.95 prob>chi2 0.00 0.74 0.06 0.92 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.37 0.35 1.50 6.95 3.15 1.00 0.54 0.55 0.22 0.00 0.08 0.32 9.33 0.07 15.27 0.00 0.78 0.00 * mchin: Migrant Stock (Mainland China), mhkmc: Migrant Stock (Hong Kong + Macau), mchhm: Migrant Stock (Mainland China + Hong Kong + Macau), mtwan: Migrant Stock (Taiwan), mchtot: Migrant Stock (Total), eth55: Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1955, eth80: Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1980, eth90: Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 1990, eth00: Size Ethnic Chinese Community in 2000. 53 Appendix A.8: Description of the Economic Functions (within the value chain of a firm)47 1. Headquarters: Following Defever (2006), this economic function within the value chain of a firm corresponds to all the administration, management and accounting activities localized internationally. It includes decision centers, but unfortunately the dataset does not describe their importance in the global decision-making process. Nevertheless, it is known that these headquarters are not the principal decision center. In most cases, these centers correspond to European or regional headquarters or are only intended for the network organization at the national level. 2. Logistics Centers: Following Defever (2006), logistics centers refer to all the entities linked to the transport of goods, including warehousing (e.g., regional distribution of goods). These centers can be internal to the firm or external, being involved in the distribution of goods to customers or with suppliers. Furthermore, they may also be viewed as acting as an intermediary between component production and assembly. 3. Manufacturing Plants: This economic function within the value chain of a firm corresponds to the whole entity related to the physical production of goods. 4. Research & Development Centers: Following Defever (2006), R&D centers refer to all activities related to either fundamental scientific research or to applied development, which is directly linked to the production process. 5. Sales & Marketing Offices: This economic function within the value chain of a firm includes both wholesale trade and business representative offices. 47 The activities of contact centers, education & training facilities, shared services centers, and testing & servicing facilities are not defined in this appendix, because too little observations are available for these economic functions for a separate regression analysis to be run. For further information on this topic, it is referred to paragraph 4.3.3. 54 Appendix A.9: Hausman-McFadden Test (to test the assumption of the independence of irrelevant alternatives) Omitted Variable AT1 AT2 AT3 BE1 BE2 BE3 BG1 BG2 CH CY CZ DE1 DE2 DE3 DE4 DE5 DE6 DE7 DE8 DE9 DEA DEB DEC DED DEE DEF DEG DK EE ES1 P-value 1.00 1.00 0.89 1.00 1.00 0.01 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.99 0.99 0.99 1.00 0.99 1.00 0.99 0.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 0.99 1.00 0.56 0.85 1.00 1.00 1.00 Omitted Variable ES2 ES3 ES4 ES5 ES6 FI FR1 FR2 FR3 FR4 FR5 FR6 FR7 FR8 GR1 GR2 GR3 GR4 HU1 HU2 HU3 IE ITC ITD ITE ITF ITG LT LU LV P-value 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.99 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.20 1.00 0.99 0.99 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.85 1.00 0.82 1.00 Omitted Variable MT NL1 NL2 NL3 NL4 NO PL1 PL2 PL3 PL4 PL5 PL6 PT RO SE SI SK UKC UKD UKE UKF UKG UKH UKI UKJ UKK UKL UKM UKN P-value 0.04 0.99 1.00 0.01 0.05 0.99 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.06 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 0.50 0.24 1.00 0.72 1.00 0.99 1.00 0.71 0.00 0.95 1.00 0.99 1.00 1.00 1.00 * Hausman-McFadden test for model specification (2) – Table 2 (Chapter 4) 55