Policy Success ( Marsh & Lewis) - Institute for Governance and

advertisement
David Marsh and Chris Lewis
Chapter 15: Evaluating Policy Success
In this Chapter we examine the ‘success’ of the Gillard Government, relying mainly on the
expositions of various policy issues in this section of the book. To evaluate policy success or
failure, we rely primarily on Marsh and McConnell’s heuristic (Marsh and McConnell, 2010;
McConnell, 2010), which is one of the first attempts systematically to analyse policy
success/failure. This heuristic is useful because it looks beyond most analyses of policy
success which focus exclusively on the programmatic dimension of success, recognising two
other dimensions of success; process success and political success. Here, we begin by
outlining the heuristic and developments of it, before considering the Gillard Government’s
performance in a broad range of economic and social policy. In addition, and in contrast to
the Marsh and McConnell heuristic, we also examine policy areas in which there was little or
no change, even where there were significant demands for such change.
The Conceptual Frame: Assessing Success
i)
The Marsh and McConnell Heuristic
The question of policy success has received limited academic attention. In fact, more
attention has been paid to the question of policy failure (Adonis, Butler and Travers, 1994;
Bovens and t’Hart, 1996; Boin, McConnell and t’Hart, 2008), or related concepts such as
scandals (Tiffen, 1999; Garrard and Newell, 2006), crises (Boin et al., 2008) and disasters
(Handmer and Dovers, 2007). Obviously, focusing on failure is important, given that, if we
understand why a policy has failed, we may be able to learn from the mistake and improve
policy making in that field, and others, in the future. However, such a focus may neglect the
fact that some, at least, policies are a success.
In our view, we need to focus on both policy success and policy failure, in effect to see the
two as at different ends of a continuum; an issue we return to below. In addition, we would
emphasise two other, related, points. First, policies are rarely either a total success or a total
failure; many, if not most, exist in what McConnell (201o) terms the ‘gray area in-between’.
In particular, using the framework we adopt below, a policy may be a success on one
dimension, process, programmatic or political, and less successful, or unsuccessful on
another dimension. Second, and relatedly, even on a single dimension, a policy may be
successful in some ways, but not in other.
When research has turned its attention to assessing the success of policies, the focus has been
narrow, with the concentration almost exclusively upon the extent to which the
aims/objectives of the policy have been met; what here we term, following earlier literature,
the programmatic dimension of success. Much of this work has been done by economists
and, perhaps consequently, it ignores the fact that policies are incontrovertibly ‘political’. In
our view, shared by the emerging literature on success, we need to go beyond a focus on the
programmatic dimension, to acknowledge the importance of other dimensions when we are
trying to assess success.
To date, the key work on ‘policy success’ is that by Bovens, t’Hart and their various
collaborators (Bovens, t’Hart and Peters, 2001), Marsh and McConnell (2010) and
McConnell (2010) and Rutter, Marshall and Sims (2012). We have reviewed this literature
elsewhere (Marsh and Lewis, 2014). Here, we focus on the Marsh and McConnell heuristic,
while acknowledging that it builds on a critical appreciation of the work of Bovens, t’Hart
and Peters (2001).
a) The Dimensions of Policy Success
Marsh and McConnell add a process dimension to the programmatic and political dimensions
identified by Bovens, t’Hart and Peters (see Table 1). In addition, they discuss a series of
complexity factors, which are important to acknowledge in undertaking any assessment of
policy success/failure, here we consider two: the fact that one person/group’s success may
another person/group’s failure; and the temporal dimension, whereby politicians operate with
a limited timescale for assessing success (see Marsh and Lewis, 2014).
The process dimension of policy formation is important, but rarely considered in any
assessment of policy success. By ‘process’ we are referring to the initial stages of
policymaking, where issues and options are framed, options considered, interests consulted
and decisions made. Often policymaking is more rushed and less considered, but,
nevertheless, processes are important, in both practical and symbolic terms. In particular, a
policy process which is thorough and ‘constitutional’ confers greater legitimacy on policy
outcomes, even if/when those outcomes are contested. So, establishing or conferring
legitimacy is an important indicator of process success.
Table 1: Three Dimensions of Policy Success: The Marsh and McConnell Framework
PROCESS DIMENSION
PROGRAMME
POLITICAL DIMENSION
DIMENSION

Preserving Policy Goals

Meeting Objectives
and Instruments

Effective

Conferring Legitimacy

Building a Sustainable
Coalition


Enhancing Electoral
Prospects/Reputation of
Implementation
Government and
Efficient Use of
Leaders
Resources

Controlling the Policy
Agenda and Easing the
Business of Governing

Sustaining the Broad
Values and Direction of
Government
Source: Adapted from McConnell (2010), Table 2.2, p. 46.
It is widely assumed that programmatic ‘success’ is more likely if the policy process
involves, and reflects the interests of, a sufficiently powerful coalition of interests. The key
point her is that, for the policymakers, putting together a strong alliance to support a
particular policy is a putative measure of process success. Of course, a process success is
likely also to be measured in terms of the Government’s capacity to get a Bill through the
legislative process without alterations to its key objectives or detailed policy instruments.
As we emphasised, Programmatic success is often seen as synonymous with policy success
and the contemporary focus among most Western democracies on evidence-based policy
making, or, as Tony Blair’s put it, ‘what matters is what works’, is further confirmation that
the assessment of success is outcomes-based and judged by ‘the evidence’ (Parsons, 2002;
Sanderson, 2002). Here, a policy is successful to the extent that it achieves its objectives.
Hence, there is a significant focus on effective policy implementation, together with a
recognition that this is a more complex problem, given the growth of multi-level governance
and public sector fragmentation (Exworthy and Powell, 2004).
Another aspect of programmatic success focuses more directly on the operation of policy,
whether the policy instruments are appropriate, the skills of those delivering the policy
adequate and the resources available sufficient to ensure that the policy is implemented as
intended. This focus on the effective use of resources has been reflected in the growth of
public audit bodies, value for money studies, national competition councils and productivity
commissions. In this context, policy success is often claimed on the grounds that the policy
led to ‘waste’ reduction, cost cutting or more efficient use of available resources.
Political success is crucial from the perspective of the government and the governing party.
Crucially here, a policy is seen as successful if it assists the government’s reputation and
electoral prospects, evidenced perhaps in public opinion polls. Of course, a policy can also
help the government retain control of the political agenda or help it retain its image of
governing competence and the idea that it is ‘on track’, while, in contrast, a policy disaster
may undermine that image and presage electoral defeat.
When considering these different dimensions of policy success, it is important to recognise,
as Bovens, t’Hart and Peters (2001) acknowledge, that a policy may be a success on one
dimension, but not on another.
For example, the Home Insulation Programme (HIP),
introduced by the Rudd Government, was, in many senses at least, a process success, but, in
most senses, a programmatic disaster (REFS). In addition, a policy may be successful along
one dimension at one time, but this may change over time. Again, the HIP provides an
example here, as it was initially a political success, but subsequently a political disaster.
b) Complexity Problems
Even if we recognise the various dimensions of policy success, the issues/problems involved
with assessing/measuring success don’t end there. So, Marsh and McConnell (2010) identify
a number of what they term complexity factors, particularly: the importance of ontological
and epistemological issues; the question of success for whom; and the fact that success varies
across time, space and cultures. Here, we consider only two of these issues: the question of
success for whom; and the temporal dimension involved in accessing success (for a
discussion of the other factors in relation to the ‘success’ of recent Australian policy making
see Marsh and Lewis, 2014).
Marsh and McConnell emphasise that any policy is unlikely to affect all citizens equally.
Indeed, the nature of politics means that outcomes will always be, to some extent, contested.
So, we should not expect government, politicians, civil servants, interest groups, citizens and
others to all agree on whether, or not, any aspect of a particular policy is successful. At the
same time, some policies may benefit some interests/sections of society, while
disadvantaging others, given that politics and policy is sometimes, perhaps often, a zero-sum
game. Inevitably, this raises crucial issues about power relations and a key question becomes
the extent to which one interest or set of interests is consistently benefited (Marsh and
McConnell, 2010, 575).
The temporal dimension of policy making is particular important, given that the timeframes
with which politicians operate, clearly related to electoral cycles, are much shorter than those
necessary to assess whether a policy has been successful (see Marsh and McConnell, 2010,
577). Sometimes, this difficulty can be exacerbated by political factors, so a government can
introduce a policy which is then repealed by a succeeding government, before there has been
a chance to assess whether it has been successful in programmatic terms. Here, the key issue
is that the time-scale of the Gillard Government is insufficient to definitively, perhaps even
adequately, judge whether a policy was a programmatic success. At best, we can suggest that
it appears likely a particular policy will be a programmatic success/failure. All this means
that the process and political dimensions feature more strongly in situations, such as this,
where an assessment of policy success is being conducted with a short time-frame.
ii)
Beyond Marsh and McConnell
McConnell (2010a) deepens and broadens the discussion by emphasising that the distinction
between policy success and policy failure is not an absolute one. He identifies (McConnell,
2010b) five points on a ‘spectrum of success’: process success; resilient success; conflicted
success; precarious success; and process failure.
Table 2: Policy as Program: The Spectrum from Success to Failure
Program Success
Resilient Success
Conflicted Success
Precarious Success
Implementation in
Implementation
Mixed results, some
Minor
line
objectives broadly
successes,
towards
achieved,
unexpected problems.
with
objectives.
with
but
also
minor changes.
progress
Program Failure
Implementation
fails to be executed
implementation
as
intended, but beset
in
line
with
objectives.
by chronic failures
Achievement
of
desired outcomes.
Outcomes broadly
Some successes, but
Limited outcomes
Failure to achieve
achieved, despite
partial achievement of
achieved, but
desired outcomes.
some shortfalls.
outcomes
overwhelmed
counterbalanced
by
by
controversial, high
unwanted results.
profile failures.
Creating benefit for
A few shortfalls,
Partial benefits, but
Small benefits,
Damaging
a target group.
but
not as widespread or
accompanied and
particular
deep as intended.
overshadowed
by
damage
to
intended
target
group
broadly benefits.
a
target
group.
beneficiary group.
Meets
policy
domain criteria.
Some
minor
shortfalls
in
relation to desired
Partial achievement of
A
few
minor
goals,
successes,
but
accompanied
by some failures.
Clear inability to
meet the criteria.
plagued by
outcome.
unwanted
media
attention.
Opposition
Some opposition
Opposition
program
to
support for program
program
program
aims/values/
aims/values/
aims/values/
aims/values/
aims/values/
implementation
implementation,
implementation
implementation
implementation
virtually
but
equally balanced.
outweighs support.
virtually
existent
to
non-
program
outweighed
by support.
and
Opposition
to
Opposition
to
non-
existent.
McConnell’s continuum is laid out in Table 2. He examines the continuum in relation to each
of the three dimensions of policy success; process, programmatic and political success. The
Figure largely speaks for itself, but the key point is, again, that we need to be much more
sophisticated about how we conceptualise, and therefore assess, success than is the case in the
mainstream, rationalist, literature, which treats the measurement of success as a
straightforward, largely technical, exercise.
The Gillard Government’s Record
Here, we could have looked at individual policies, or policy fields, and assess, for either or
each, whether it was a process, programmatic or political success. However, instead, we
organise our treatment in terms of the Marsh and McConnell frame, assessing the policy
output of the Gillard Government in relation to each dimension of success. Subsequently, we
will examine a number of areas in which there were no policy innovations, on the grounds
that this also tells us something about the policy ‘success’, or otherwise, of the Gillard
Government.
i) Process Success
In broad terms, as Chapter Three, the Gillard Government was successful in getting policy
through, even in the context of minority government. So, as Singleton (Chapter 3)
emphasises, 561 pieces of legislation received Royal Assent, compared to 549 during the last
term of the Howard government and 409 for the Rudd Government. Notably, no government
bills were defeated on the floor of the House of Representatives although five were
withdrawn by the government through lack of sufficient support. This success was achieved
despite 50 per cent of the bills introduced into the House of Representatives being contested
by the Opposition (Singleton, 2013).
The best examples of process success were in the social welfare, health and education fields;
areas of Labor’s historical policy strengths. Here, we would point to four substantial policy
initiatives which were achieved, although often through compromise, and rarely with total
community and political support.

The National Disability Insurance Scheme (beginning July 2013) which had
bipartisan political support.

A new hospital funding scheme concluded with all State Premiers and Territory Chief
Ministers to provide the States with $16.4 billion from July 2014 to 2020, including
strict national standards, such as a four-hour emergency treatment “target” and the
delivery of 95% of elective surgery procedures within a recommended time (Packham
and Kelly, 2011).

A National Education Reform Agreement which offered $14.5 billion extra to primary
and high school education over six years; although only NSW, South Australia and
the ACT signed up by the end of the Gillard Government. For the first time, there was
a funding entitlement and formula for all students, regardless of whether they attend
government or non-government schools (Ferrari, 2013). With a base level of funding
for each student starting in 2014 at $9,271 for a primary student and $12,193 for a
secondary student, amounts would be topped up by “loadings” targeting categories of
disadvantage, based on disability and low socio-economic status (Hurst, 2013).

A $4.1 billion dental package, supported by the Australian Dental Association, the
Australian Medical Association, the Public Health Association of Australia and the
Australian Healthcare and Hospitals Association; although most of the money would
not be available until 2014. This included $2.7 billion over six years to give free or
subsidised dental care to 3.4 million children (aged 2 to 17) for families that qualify
under Family Tax Benefit A, up to $1,000 over two years. Another $1.3 billion would
go to State-run public dental clinics to fund 1.4 million dental services for low-income
adults, while $225 million will be spent on improving facilities and boosting the
dental workforce. These programs allow the closure of the Howard-era Chronic
Disease Dental Scheme, which cost taxpayers nearly $1 billion annually, and Labor's
own Teen Dental scheme, which cost $65 million in 2011-12, but had consistently
failed to hit its targets, because it funds only check-ups and not the treatments found
to be needed cleaning and fillings (Cresswell, 2012). This was despite the Chairman
of the Association for the Promotion of Oral Health (Professor Hans Zoellner) arguing
that few children needed enough dental treatment to get near the $500-a-year cap,
whereas the few children with more serious problems would be disadvantaged by the
new cap and were previously covered by the much higher $4250 limit available
through the CDDS (Cresswell, 2012).
However, elsewhere, the pattern is more mixed. So, the controversial carbon tax, which, as
we shall see later, was a major ‘programmatic’ and ‘political’ failure, could be seen as a
conflicted process success, because, while the policy was introduced without major
amendment, and accompanied by a taxation reform that increased the tax free threshold to
$18,200, its implementation was strongly contested and this clearly affected its chances of
programmatic success (Check carbon tax chapter).
In the same vein, while the Murray Darling Basin Plan (MDBP) could be viewed as a
sensible attempt to balance economic and environmental sustainability, the supposed
consultation process which underpinned its development was deeply flawed. As Linnegar
(2012) argues: ‘the (Murray Darling Basin) Authority (MDBA) simply turned up in rural
towns, told the local residents, business people and farmers that somewhere between 30-40
per cent of the water sustaining the town (some 3,000-4,000 gigalitres) would be removed
and then left’. As such, the MDBP was generally perceived by affected rural and regional
communities to have failed to respond to their interests and as a cave-in to urban city voters.
While later concessions were made to rural/farming interests and the MDBA has significantly
changed its approach, this is still, at best, a conflicted process success (Evans Ref).
While the Rudd Government’s flawed handling of the Resource Super Profits Tax was one of
the main reasons for the replacement of Rudd by Gillard as Prime Minister, the compromise
Gillard subsequently agreed with the mining sector was a major process, and indeed
programmatic and political, failure, given Labor’s initial aims (see Bell and Hindmoor, 2013;
Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013). The 2012-13 Budget set aside the putative proceeds of the
new tax to fund: family payments; a bonus for school-aged children; small business tax
breaks; and a compulsory superannuation increase. However, the scale of the tax was heavily
curtailed, as a result of concessions to the big miners. So, the Minerals Resource Rent Tax
(MRRT) established a 30% tax on just a few minerals (iron ore and coal), whereas the
initially proposed Resource Super Profit Tax had proposed a 40% levy on all extractive
industry. Consequently, the tax yield was derisory. It is difficult to see this as other than a
process failure, as the Government failed to argue its case strongly enough to the public in the
face of pressure from the miners (see Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013).
iii)
Programmatic Success
As we argued, it is still too early to judge the programmatic success of most of the Gillard
Government’s policies given the short-time frame. This is particularly true in the case of the
Government’s four main process successes: the National Disability Insurance Scheme; the
latest hospital funding scheme to operate from July 2014 to 2020; the dental reforms; and the
National Education Reform Agreement.
However, the Gillard Government had a number of major programmatic failures. Here, we
highlight three examples: the budget surplus and related economic policy; the carbon tax;
and the mining tax. At the same time, it important to emphasise that judging a policy a
programmatic success, almost by definition, involves a longer time frame than judging a
policy a failure.
Gillard committed to delivering a budget surplus by 2013-14 in her first press conference as
Prime Minister on 23 June 2010. This commitment is dealt with at more length by Garnett
and Lewis, who argue that it was a policy largely driven by the Opposition. However, as
Garnett and Lewis emphasise, in the Gillard years, average Government spending, as a
proportion of GDP, was 24.6%, while average Government receipts were 23.5% of GDP.
Garnett and Lewis argue that this deficit resulted from a combination of a failure to rein in
public expenditure and seriously over-optimistic estimates of receipts from the carbon and
mining taxes. In addition, they point out that Australia had its highest-ever debt levels and
this was recalculated by Rudd’s new Treasurer, Chris Bowen, as standing at $30billion, up
from $18b three months earlier. In this context, the Government withdrew its commitment to
balance the budget at the end of 2012; which reflected a political, as well as a programmatic,
failure.
At the same time, the Australian Bureau of Statistics indicated that Australia’s employment
rate was 13.1%, if one included: those who worked just one hour a week; discouraged
jobseekers; the underemployed; and those who wanted to start work within a month, but
couldn’t begin immediately (ABS, 2013). In addition, the average hours worked per
Australian worker declined from 35 in the 1980s, to 34 in the 1900s, 33 since 2000; reaching
32.9 in 2011 (ABS, 2012). Total manufacturing employment fell to 938,300 in the March
2013 Quarter, thus meaning that manufacturing job losses under Rudd-Gillard were 143,300
(Mirabella, 2013). Manufacturing’s share of Australia GDP also declined further, to 7.1% in
2011-12, after being 11.2% in 2003-04 (Colebatch, 2013). In addition, despite a low
Consumer Price Index being aided by periods of low food prices, there was double-digit
growth in electricity prices after 2007, including 14% in 2012-13 (Wood, 2013). Overall, this
is hardly a picture of success in terms of economic policy.
The carbon tax, legislated as part of the Clean Energy Bill 2011 and intended to last for three
to five years before a full emissions trading scheme (ETS) was implemented (Packham and
Massola, 2012), can also be seen as a major programmatic failure. It is true that the Climate
Commission revealed that Australia’s emissions from electricity generation dropped by 4.7%
between 2010 and 2011. However, this was because of the greater use of renewable energy
and a decline in Australia’s manufacturing sector (Marszalek, 2013), rather than the carbon
tax (Dennis and McIntosh’s chapter). More broadly, global CO2 emissions reached a record
31.6 gigatonnes in 2012 (Zhu, 2013), while the average concentration of atmospheric carbon
dioxide reached 400 parts per million in some monitoring stations (Artic and Hawaii), with a
recent prediction that the level would rise to 450ppm would be faster than previous rates of
increase (Landau, 2013). Of course, supporters of the carbon tax may argue that it is better
than doing nothing, but it is hard to argue that it has delivered in either economic or
environmental terms. In addition, the Government failed effectively to counter the Opposition
argument that it would lead to higher electricity prices and a loss of Australian jobs offshore;
a political failure.
As Garnett and Lewis stress, the carbon tax was designed to be budget-neutral, raising $4
billion in the first year, which would pay for compensation, tax cuts and clean energy
programs. However, the Treasury’s forward estimates for the period when Australia moved to
an ETS were based on an assumption that the carbon price would rise to $38/tonne by 2019.
In early 2013, the European Union’s carbon price, to which the Australian one will be fixed,
was $6/tonne. The problem is, of course, that the Gillard Government’s policies which will
require heavy expenditure, like the Gonski reforms or the National Disability Scheme, are
dependent, in large part, on a high carbon price generating significant income.
The mining tax is also widely viewed as a programmatic failure. As Garnett and Lewis
emphasise, the Gillard Government had originally budgeted for the tax to raise $3.7 billion on
average during its first three years (2012/3-2015/6), but raised just $126 million during its
first six months. In large part this results from the concessions which the Government made
to the large miners during the evolution of the legislation (see Garnett and Lewis, 2013; Bell
and Hindmoor, 2013; and Lewis, Marsh and Chesters, 2013). Here, we can see how process
failure linked to programmatic failure.
iii)
Political Success
Political success is not easy and, as the introduction to this volume indicates, there were
several contextual realities that may have hindered the Gillard Government’s prospects of
political success, particularly its minority government status and the tough economic
environment.
However, as we have seen, both process and programmatic terms failures hindered the
Government’s prospects of political success. Here, we are thinking particularly of the
inaccurate budget predictions, along with the mining and carbon taxes. In the case of the
latter, the political reputation of the Gillard Government was also severely damaged from the
start of its term when it reneged on a promise not to introduce a carbon tax, without
community debate, a development which Ireland (2013) argues reinforced a negative public
perception of Gillard that had originated in response to the way in which she overthrew Rudd.
In contrast, Johnson (2011a and b) argues that Gillard had the chance to utilise the past Labor
tradition of enhancing educational opportunity and to build upon Rudd’s initial promotion of
the National Broadband Network and the National Disability Insurance Scheme, not to
mention the Rudd Governments’ efforts to avoid economic recession. In that context, he
suggests, the Gillard Government’s many policy failures entrenched an unfavourable view of
its economic competence. So, early in Gillard’s term, Labor only trailed the Coalition slightly
(43% to 40%; Newspoll, 13-15 August, 2010) in terms of economic governing competence,
by early 2013 it tariled 28% to 50% (Newspoll, 23-26 February, 2013), at a time when
Australia had one of the lowest OECD unemployment rates at around 5% (OECDa).
The Government’s political standing was also weakened by its decision to appoint the former
Liberal MP Peter Slipper as Speaker of the House, given he later resigned for inappropriate
conduct (Ireland and Wright 2012), and its support from the disgraced former Federal Labor
MP Craig Thomson, who was arrested on 1 February 2013 and charged with 150 counts of
fraud, because of his previous conduct as head of the Health Services Union, which had
already led to civil action against him.
Towards the end of its term, this lack of political success led the Gillard Government to
modify its policy stance, often seeming desperate to court popularity. One of its biggest
policy reversals occurred in regard to asylum seekers (see Walsh). Initially, the Government,
like the previous Rudd Government, opposed the Howard Government’s offshore processing
approach, using the Nauru option, on the grounds that it was not a signatory to the UN
Refugee Convention. As such, they preferred East Timor as a location for new detention and
processing facilities, although this proposal was rejected by the East Timorese (Kelly, 2010).
Subsequently, on 31 August 2011 the High Court rejected an alternative plan to exchange
800 asylum seekers for 4,000 processed refugees from Malaysia (Gordon, 2011), given it was
also not a signatory to the UN Refugee Convention, which by that time Nauru had signed.
The Government then, after convening and accepting the recommendations of the Expert
Panel on Asylum Seekers panel chaired by Angus Houston, moved towards the resumption of
processing at Nauru and Manus Island, endorsing the plan during August 2012. During
October 2012, the Gillard Government confirmed support for offshore processing and
announced the re-opening of sites at Nauru and Manus Island, in response to growing
numbers of boat arrivals, along with reported deaths at sea. In line with the recommendation
of the panel, the Government also increased Australia’s humanitarian program to 20,000
places in 2012-13 from 13,750 for 2011-12 (Gillard and Bowen, 2012).
During June 2013, the Government even introduced tougher legislation to require subclass
457 visa sponsors to demonstrate that there are no qualified and experienced Australian
workers readily available to fill a position to be taken by a proposed 457 visa holder, unless
an exemption applies. They did so, despite previously ignoring criticism from trade unionists
and Labor MPs during May 2012, when re-stating approval for mining magnate Gina
Rinehart to bring in 1700 skilled foreign workers to get her $9.5 billion Roy Hill iron ore
mine underway in the Pilbara (Farr, 2012).
The Gillard Government’s lack of political success also led it to look for political scapegoats.
Notably, during 2012, Swan accused mining magnates Clive Palmer, Andrew Forrest and
Gina Rinehart of trying to assert too much influence over Australian politics, given their
strident opposition to the carbon tax and the mining tax (Swan, 2012). Similarly, Gillard,
responding to another debate over the economics of education, suggesting that people who
lived on Sydney's North Shore were not ‘real people’ (Nadin and Salusinszky, 2012). The
Government also sought to counter perceived media bias, although it failed to win
parliamentary support for its media law reform bill. Similarly, Gillard’s description of Abbott
as ‘sexist and misogynist’ gave, at best, a temporary boost to Gillard’s approval ratings
(Essential Report, Essential Research 15 October 2012).
The Absence of Policy
Marsh and McConnell’s framework focuses on policies which have been introduced to
examine whether they have been successful. However, another issue is clearly important:
what issues did the Gillard Government avoid, even where there appeared to be a need for
policy changes?
In a sense, the most important are here again is economic policy. The Gillard Government
gave little attention to how best to generate wealth or, even, as we saw earlier, to achieving a
balanced budget. In this context, Johnson (2011a) claims that the Gillard Government was
closer to the economic rationalism of Hawke and Keating, than to Rudd, given the latter had
provided a critique of neo-liberalism. Certainly, the Gillard Government appeared happy to
accept a growing reliance upon mining and services, while Australia’s manufacturing and
agricultural sectors faced further relative decline, as export-exposed industries experienced
much greater competition, given the rise in the Australian dollar.
Australia continued to benefit from mining and fuels (including coal), after the global export
value of those sectors increased by 16% between 2000 and 2005 and 14% between 2005 and
2011, the latter occurring despite a decline of 39% in 2009 (WTO, 2012). However, with
global manufacturing exports (non-food products) worth around 65% of total global
merchandise exports, and still dwarfing global commercial service exports by a ratio of
nearly 4.5 to 1, Australia was being asked to compete with the world’s developed nations for
global trade exports. At the same time, the value of Australia’s food product imports
increased by 371% between 2000 and 2011, while exports went up just 204% (WTO, 2012).
Of course, these growing economic problems, which, as Garnett and Lewis emphasise,
resulted at least in part from Gillard Government policies, impacted on Gillard Government’s
social policies, given the need to pay for them.
However, the Gillard Government failed to acknowledge, or even discuss, possible fiscal
limitations in the future. All this meant that, while Labor was committed to maintaining the
Coalition’s level of government expenditure as a percentage of GDP, the total level of social
welfare expenditure reached a near record level of 18% of GDP in 2012 (OECDb). This was
funded by deficit spending, at a time when, as we saw, budgetary forecasts proved wrong
time and time again.
Of course, there was some attempt to balance the ledger. In this context, the Government’s
social policy innovation (discussed by Singleton in Chapter Three) was often only enabled by
controversial cuts and reforms in other policy areas. So, Labor increased means-testing of the
private health insurance rebate after July 2012 (Deloitte 2011; ANOP 2011) and increase the
Medicare levy to partially fund the National Disability Insurance Scheme. It also adopted a
temporary flood levy to raise $1.8 billion from July 2011 after the devastating flood caused
widespread damage to Queensland. However, at the same time, $2.5 billion was to be cut out
of the university sector in the four years from 2013, while $520 million was raised by
capping tax deductions for self-education expenses.
Some cuts particularly effected the more disadvantaged. So, around 84,000 sole parents were
moved off parenting payments, when their youngest child turns eight, which meant 60,000
single parents moved on to Newstart from January 2013, with estimates that many would lose
$60-100 a week - this policy even led to a damning letter from the UN (AAP 2013). In
addition, the Newstart allowance (unemployment benefit) was frozen, meaning that the base
rate had not increased in real terms since 1994, with even the Business Council of Australia
President Tony Shepherd calling for an increase at a National Press Club address (Crook,
2013). However, the Gillard Government’s 2013 budget did allow welfare recipients to keep
an extra $19 a week from part-time work before payments are affected.
Such policies hardly helped the 13% of Australians living below the poverty line, deemed by
ACOSS to now be $358 per week for a single person and $573 per single parent, given
Newstart weekly rates were $256.30 for a single person and $266.50 for a single parent, far
less than the disability pension of $375 a week and the minimum wage of $590 (Crook,
2013).
.
The Gillard Government’s almost hopeful attitude to economic and social matters was
critiqued by experts concerned about how future social welfare policies would be funded. In
relation to health, a Grattan Institute report (April, 2013) predicted that health expenditure
would be the biggest contributor to a blowout in State and Federal budget deficits by 2023,
due primarily to an ageing population (Daley, 2013). Similarly, John Deeble, the health
economist who advised both the Whitlam and Hawke Governments on universal healthcare
(Medibank and Medicare), argued that the States were shouldering too much of the burden of
health funding and that subsidising private health insurance could help to solve the problem, ,
as long as it became more ‘comprehensive and stayed comprehensive’. Deeble declared: ‘I
don’t see how you are going to solve the problem in an equitable way unless you make some
very nasty decisions” (Heath, 2013).
At the same time, the Chief Executive of one of Australia’s largest private health insurers
(NIB), Mark Fitzgibbon, also argued that the level of public health expenditure was
‘impossible’ and that the private health system would have to be expanded to include GP
visits, while supporting the introduction of means-testing, given the rollback of government
support for private health was inevitable (Heath, 2013). Similarly, during May 2013, the
AMA noted that financial pressures (wages and costs) on medical practices meant that the
bulk billing rate for GP services was likely to fall after the Gillard Government’s decision to
delay the indexation of the GP Medicare rebate (currently $36.30) by eight months, from
November 2013 to July 2014 (AMA 2013).
In contrast to Australia, Canada, which is also faced with an ageing population, and where the
bulk of healthcare spending is by Provincial Governments, slashed healthcare spending
during the 1990s, in face of a public debt crisis. The argument here was that increased
spending was a choice for governments, until they had no choice but to cut public spending
(Keane, 2013). The point here is that the need to balance wealth creation and social welfare
policies appeared largely lost on the Gillard Government, given its almost cavalier approach
to economic matters.
Perhaps this is why new policies are emerging, albeit begun much earlier than the Gillard
Government, which mask the real solutions through rhetorical aims based more on wishful
thinking. For example, while the Government built upon the National Assessment Program –
Literacy and Numeracy (NAPLAN), which, since 2008, has annually assessed students in
Years 3, 5, 7 and 9, by launching a revamped My School website during March 2011, another
report by the Grattan Institute stated that “neither creating more competition among schools
nor giving them more autonomy without support to improve learning are the vital solutions”
would “lift the performance of Australian students”. The Myth of Markets in School
Education report noted a number of reasons: at least 40-60% of schools ‘face no or very
limited competition’; ‘providing more information about schools, cutting private school fees
or increasing the capacity of high-performing government schools will do little to increase
school competition and lift student performance’; and giving school leaders autonomy to run
their schools ‘has little impact on performance when governments do not implement it as part
of a larger plan to improve teaching and learning’, a point strengthened by the fact that
greater school autonomy in Victoria did not lead to greater performance than in NSW, which
remained centralised until recently. As summarised by Jensen in a summary of his Grattan
Institute Report The myth of markets in school education, the world’s best systems: ‘have
varying levels of autonomy but they all articulate the best way to teach and learn, then make
sure they have the best teachers to carry it out’ (Jensen, 2013).
The failure to even consider, let alone face up to, difficult issues is clear in the debates about
climate change and population growth. As we saw, the Gillard Government answer to
generating wealth in these difficult times, focused on more of the same, So, Australia exports
pollution at the same time as cutting, admittedly in a limited way, its own greenhouse gas
emissions, with no consideration of this apparent contradiction. Such contradictions are
similarly present if we consider the population debate. While Gillard, rhetorically, repositioned Labor away from Rudd’s original “Big Australia” population goal (Leslie, 2010),
the Government maintained Australia's long-term support bi-partisan support for a large,
multi-ethnic, annual immigration program. So, during the 2011-12 year, there were 184,998
legal migrants, including 125,755 for the skill stream and 58,604 for the family stream (Dept.
of Immigration and Citizenship, 2012).
Conclusion
As earlier chapters also demonstrate, the Government’s economic and social policy record
was mixed at best, even allowing for a tough international economic environment, with
Australia continuing to embrace freer trade, the instability caused by a former leader (Rudd),
determined to regain the prime ministership, and the reality of a minority government, which
demanded a careful monitoring of numbers and support from controversial MPs. The
Government’s inability to win over public opinion even led to the return of Rudd as Prime
Minister, as caucus members feared a loss of their seats.
The Government was successful in achieving a legislative process success, with the support
of the Greens and key independents. In particular, it achieved some significant changes in
health and education (notably the NDIS), although this was at the cost of tougher conditions
for a substantial minority of welfare recipients. Unfortunately, the policy areas in which it
achieved process success will require time before any assessment can be made of
programmatic success.
However, in the areas in which there were significant process
failures, notably in economic policy and on the carbon and mining taxes, programmatic and
political failure quickly followed.
In the end, the Gillard Government did not do enough to convince a sufficient number of
Australians of their policy success, despite Australia’s strong economic performance, when
compared to other developed nations. Even allowing for the particularly difficult context in
which the Government operated, it fail to implement an effective economic policy mix that
could help win public support, at time when a growing minority faced tougher times, due to
employment uncertainty, higher housing prices and, even, rapidly increasing utility bills.
References
AAP. 2013, ‘Gillard snubs UN on single parent welfare’, The Australian, 4 March 2013.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/breaking-news/govt-silent-on-poverty-reportacoss/story-fn3dxiwe-1226589883703
ABS. 2012. 1393.0 - As a Matter of Fact, 2012, 23 May 2012.
http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@.nsf/latestmf/1393.0~5
ABS, 2013. 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, 10 July 2013.
http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/Latestproducts/6105.0Feature%20Article1July%20
2013?opendocument&tabname=Summary&prodno=6105.0&issue=July%202013&num=&vi
ew=
AMA (Australian Medical Association). 2013. ‘Bulk billing warning as rebates freeze’, 17
May 2013.
https://ama.com.au/ausmed/bulk-billing-warning-rebates-freeze
Anderson, John. 2013. ‘Desperate graziers will meet at a summit as prices push the beef
industry
into
crisis’,
Townsville
Bulletin,
May
06.
http://www.couriermail.com.au/news/queensland/desperate-graziers-will-meet-at-a-summitas-prices-push-the-beef-industry-into-crisis/story-e6freoof-1226635598112
ANOP Research Services, 2011. Means Testing the Private Health Insurance Rebate The
Impact on Private Health Insurance Membership in Australia, Report on the 2011 ANOP
Survey for the AHIA, April 2011.
http://youshouldknow.com.au/wp-content/uploads/ANOP-full-report-for-AHIA2011.pdf
Colebatch, Tim. 2013. How we lost our place in the global car industry, Canberra Times, 28
May 2013.
http://www.canberratimes.com.au/federal-politics/political-opinion/how-we-lost-our-placein-the-global-car-industry-20130527-2n7a1.html
Cooper, Hayden. 2013. ‘Workers accuse IT giant of 457 abuse’, Australian Broadcasting
Corporation, 20 June 2013.
http://www.abc.net.au/7.30/content/2013/s3786315.htm
Coorey, Phillip. 2013. ‘Gillard, Lowy defend multiculturalism’, Sydney Morning Herald
(online), 20 September 2012.
http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/gillard-lowy-defend-multiculturalism20120919-2671o.html
Cresswell, Adam. 2012. ‘Truth of federal government's $4bn dental boost like pulling teeth’,
The Australian, 30 August 2012.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/health/truth-of-federal-governments-4bndental-boost-like-pulling-teeth/story-fn59nokw-1226461149159
Crook, Andrew. 2013, ‘PromiseWatch 2013: Newstart Allowance comparison’, Crikey, 2
May 2013.
http://www.crikey.com.au/2013/05/02/promisewatch-2013-newstart-allowance-comparison/
Daley, John. 2013, Budget pressures on Australian governments, Grattan Institute, April
2013.
http://grattan.edu.au/static/files/assets/ff6f7fe2/187_budget_pressures_report.pdf
Deloitte. Australian Health Insurance Association, Economic Impact Assessment of the
Proposed Reforms to Private Health Insurance, Final Report, 28 April 2011.
http://youshouldknow.com.au/wp-content/uploads/Deloitte-Final-Report_28-April-2011.pdf
Dept. of Immigration and Citizenship. 2012. 2011–12 Migration Program Report
Program year to 30 June 2012.
http://www.immi.gov.au/media/statistics/pdf/report-on-migration-program-2011-12.pdf
Durie, John. 2013. ‘Simplot, maker of Chiko rolls, Edgell and Birdseye, may close local
plants’, The Australian, 5 June 2013.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/business/companies/simplot-maker-of-chico-rolls-edgelland-birdseye-may-close-local-plants/story-fn91v9q3-1226657841656
Evershed, Nick, 2013. ‘Was Julia Gillard the most productive prime minister in Australia's
history?’, The Guardian, 28 June 2013.
http://www.guardian.co.uk/news/datablog/2013/jun/28/australia-productive-prime-minister
Farr, M. 2012. "Gillard labels Abbott "Gina Rinehart's butler"". news.com.au. 28 May 2012.
http://www.news.com.au/national-news/gillard-labels-abbott-gina-rineharts-butler/storye6frfkvr-1226369949693
Ferrari, Julia with Michael Owen. 2013. ‘Gillard to punish Gonski school funding hold-outs’,
The Australian, 5 June 2013.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/education/gillard-to-punish-gonski-holdouts/story-fn59nlz9-1226657377599
Firsova, A; Strezov, V and Taplin, R, 2012, ‘After 20 years of creating Australian climate
policy: was the proposed carbon pollution reduction scheme a change in direction?’,
Australian Journal of Environmental Managment 19(1):21-34.
Gillard, J and Chris Bowen, ‘Refugee Program increased to 20 000 places’, Joint media
release, 23 August 2012.
http://www.minister.immi.gov.au/media/cb/2012/cb189459.htm
Gordon, Michael. 2011. ‘The Malaysia solution is shipwrecked". The Australian, 1 Sept.
2011.
http://www.theage.com.au/national/the-malaysia-solution-is-shipwrecked-201108311jmfm.html
Heath, Joanna. 2013. ‘Medicare architect backs private health’, Australian Financial Review,
23 April 2013.
http://www.afr.com/p/national/medicare_architect_backs_private_t69vQWT3GamZsOQavC
HlYO
Hurst, Daniel. 2013. ‘Gonski school funding reforms now law’, Sydney Morning Herald, 26
June 2013.
http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/gonski-school-funding-reforms-nowlaw-20130626-2own5.html
Ireland, J. 2013, ‘There may be achievements, but voters still aren't getting Labor's message’,
SMH (online), 24 March 2013.
http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/there-may-be-achievements-butvoters-still-arent-getting-labors-message-20130323-2gmft.html
Ireland, Judith and Jessica Wright. 2012. ‘Coalition fails to oust Slipper’, Sydney Morning
Herald, 9 Oct. 2012.
http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-news/coalition-fails-to-oust-slipper20121009-27a2g.html
Jensen, Ben. 2013. ‘The myth of markets in school education’, Grattan Institute (online), 10
July 2013.
http://grattan.edu.au/publications/reports/post/the-myth-of-markets-in-school-education/
Johnson, Carol. 2011a, ‘Gillard, Rudd and Labor Tradition’, Australian Journal of Politics
and History 57(4):562-579.
Johnson, Carol. 2011b, ‘The Politics of Broadband: Labor and New Information Technology
from Hawke to Gillard’, Australian Journal of Political Science 46(1):3-18.
Karvelas, Patricia, 2012. "Historic Constitution vote over indigenous recognition facing
hurdles". The Australian. 20 Jan. 2012.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/indigenous/historic-constitution-vote-overindigenous-recognition-facing-hurdles/story-fn9hm1pm-1226248879375
Keane, Bernard. 2013. ‘The rise and rise of health spending — but don’t blame the old
people’, 23 April 2013.
http://www.businessspectator.com.au/article/2013/4/23/health-and-pharmaceuticals/rise-andrise-health-spending
Kelly, Joe. 2010. ‘East Timor's parliament rejects Gillard plan for regional asylum-seeker
centre’, The Australian (online), 25 July 2011.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/politics/east-timors-parliament-rejects-gillard-plan-forregional-asylum-seeker-centre/story-e6frgczf-1225890881986
Kelly, Paul, 2012a, (11 May 2012). "Military spending slumps to 1930s level". The
Australian, 11 May 2012.’
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/columnists/military-spending-slumps-to-1930slevel/story-e6frg74x-1226352458112
Kelly, Paul. 2012b. ‘Labor's choice is Rudd or oblivion’, The Australian (online), 25 July
2012.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/opinion/columnists/labors-choice-is-rudd-or-oblivion/storye6frg74x-1226434217314
Ker, P. 2013. ‘BHP, Rio pay mining tax; Xstrata doesn't’, Sydney Morning Herald (online),
29 April 2013.
http://www.smh.com.au/business/mining-and-resources/bhp-rio-pay-mining-tax-xstratadoesnt-20130429-2io7o.html (accessed 4th July 2013)
Landau, Elizabeth, 2013. ‘CO2 levels hit new peak at key observatory’, CNN (online), May
14, 2013.
http://edition.cnn.com/2013/05/10/us/climate-change
Leslie, Tim. 2010. ‘Claims Gillard opposed paid parental leave’, Australian Broadcasting
Corporation (online), 27 July 2010.
http://www.abc.net.au/news/2010-07-27/claims-gillard-opposed-paid-parental-leave/921538
Linnegar, Matt, 2012. ‘Murray Darling Basin: work together on water’, 9 Jan. 2012.
http://www.abc.net.au/unleashed/3764018.html
Marszalek, Jessica. 2013. ‘Carbon tax and tight consumers help lower emissions, new report
says’, News Limited Network (online), April 29, 2013.
http://www.news.com.au/national-news/carbon-tax-and-tight-consumers-help-loweremissions-new-report-says/story-fncynjr2-1226631177867
McAllister, I. and J. Clark. 2007. Trends in Australian Political Opinion: Results from the
Australian Election Study, 1987–2004. Canberra: Australian Social Science Data Archive.
Mirabella, Sophie. 2013. ‘Manufacturing Jobs Hit Record Low’, 20 June2013.
http://www.liberal.org.au/latest-news/2013/06/20/manufacturing-jobs-hit-record-low
Nadin, Mitchell; Salusinszky, Imre. 2012. "Julia Gillard takes on Tony Abbott in a reality
showdown". The Australian, 10 May.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/julia-gillard-takes-on-tony-abbott-in-areality-showdown/story-fn59niix-1226351462739
OECDa, Economic Outlook Annex Tables
http://www.oecd.org/economy/outlook/economicoutlookannextables.htm
OECDb. Social Expenditure - Aggregated data, OECD StatExtracts.
http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=SOCX_AGG
Packham, Ben. 2012. 'Huge whack' to revenue means budget surplus is now unlikely: Wayne
Swan’, The Australian (online), Dec. 20, 2012.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/revenue-slide-in-2012-13-makes-laborssurplus-task-harder/story-fn59niix-1226541057969
Packham, Ben and Joe Kelly, 2011. ‘Tony Abbott says Julia Gillard's revamped health
reform
package
is
yet
another
backdown’,
The
Australian,
11
Feb.
2011.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/julia-gillard-details-revamped-healthreform-package-with-the-states-before-coag/story-fn59niix-1226004336983
Packham, Ben; Massola, James. 2012. ‘Australia to have carbon price from July 1, 2012,
Julia Gillard announces’, The Australian, 24 Feb. 2012.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/gillard-to-reveal-climate-policy-today/story-e6frg6n61226011223441
Parliament of Australia. 2010. ‘ Multiculturalism: a review of Australian policy statements
and recent debates in Australia and overseas’, Elsa Koleth, Social Policy Section, Research
Paper no. 6 2010–11, 8 October 2010.
http://www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_Departments/Parliamentary_Librar
y/pubs/rp/rp1011/11rp06#_Toc275248124
Plibersek, Tanya. 2013. ‘Transcript - Doorstop - Parliament House Canberra’, 16 May 2013.
http://www.health.gov.au/internet/ministers/publishing.nsf/Content/tr-yr13-tptpsp120516.htm
Swan, W. (2012), ‘The 0.01 Per Cent: The Rising Influence of Vested Interests in Australia’,
The Monthly, March.
http://www.themonthly.com.au/issue/2012/march/1344425290/wayne-swan/001-cent-risinginfluence-vested-interests-australia
Tavan, Gwenda, 2012, ‘No Going Back? Australian Multiculturalism as a Path-Dependent
Process’, AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF POLITICAL SCIENCE 47(4):547-561.
Willox, Innes. 2013. ‘Business pays too much for carbon’, The Australian, 26 June 2013.
http://www.theaustralian.com.au/national-affairs/opinion/business-pays-too-much-forcarbon/story-e6frgd0x-1226669728678
Wood, Tony. 2013. ‘Why Australians are getting a raw deal on electricity prices’, The
Conversation, 22 April 2013.
http://theconversation.com/why-australians-are-getting-a-raw-deal-on-electricity-prices13296
World
Trade
Organization,
International
Trade
Statistics
2012
http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2012_e/its2012_e.pdf
Zhu, Wenqian. 2013. ‘Global CO2 emissions at record high in 2012’, CNNMoney, 11 June
2013.
http://money.cnn.com/2013/06/11/news/economy/co2-emissions-record-high/index.html
Download