Establishing the case for prevention in public health: QALYs, Cost benefit analysis, Social Return on Investment, multiple criteria decision analysis and the kitchen sink Edwards RT, Lloyd-Williams H, McIntosh E, Jones CL, Ferguson B, Baughan S. Abstract Background The way public health is organised and delivered varies across the UK. In England, much of the public health function has been devolved to local government, whilst this function remains within the NHS in Wales and Scotland. NICE, the Department of Health in England, Public Health England, the King’s Fund, Public Health Wales, NHS Health Scotland and NHS Healthcare Improvement Scotland are all currently exploring technical methods for the evaluation of the case for prevention, producing case studies to guide future resource allocation. Objective From a theoretical and pragmatic policy perspective, to review the types of economic appraisal that might be relevant in particular circumstances, drawing upon illustrative case studies in the area of prevention. The strengths and weaknesses of different approaches are explored. Methods We present a review of prioritisation frameworks and approaches to the economic evaluation of public health interventions, spanning QALYs, Social Return on Investment, and multiple criteria decision analysis. Results A review of current methods for the evaluation of public health interventions and their strengths and weaknesses in particular circumstances. Presentation of case studies of economic evaluations of public health interventions designed to illustrate theoretical, operational and policy support issues. Conclusion At present there is a need for a range of methods to be applied to the evaluation of public health interventions, and a definite need for some standardisation of techniques, including wider use of thresholds, as is current practice in health technology assessment. We would welcome discussion of these issues at HESG in Glasgow. 1 Background Public health is the science and art of promoting and protecting health and well being, preventing ill-health and prolonging life through the organised efforts of society (Faculty of Public Health 2014). This paper considers current NICE guidance on the evaluation of public health preventive interventions, considers the reason why markets for preventative goods and services fail, and argues the case for government investment in health promoting activities. We review a range of evaluative methods currently in use, which expand the traditional health economics toolbox and provide case studies. The way public health is organised and delivered varies across the UK. In England, much of the public health function has been devolved to local government, whilst this function remains within the NHS in Wales, Scotland and Northern Ireland. NICE, the Department of Health in England, Public Health England, the King’s Fund, Public Health Wales, NHS Health Scotland and NHS Healthcare Improvement Scotland are all currently exploring technical methods for the evaluation of the case for prevention. There are an increasing number of case studies being published to demonstrate the use of these methods (Buck and Gregory, 2013). Economic evaluation alongside trials of Public Health interventions are often more expensive due to the need for large sample sizes (Fischer et al, 2012). However this depends on the study design and the complexity and resources required in the identification, measurement and valuation of all costs and outcomes across all affected sectors. Finally, economic models of Public health interventions are complex (Squires, 2013). To some extent, all these technical methods consider, and attempt to make explicit, the concept of opportunity cost, that is, to identify the benefits foregone from investing in one activity and not another. Resources are finite and should be used in a way that maximises the health gain for the population, the implicit goal of NICE, or another such societal objective such as reducing health inequalities, a central tenet of public health. Techniques such as multiple-criteria decision analysis (MCDA), social return on investment (ROI/SROI) and the consideration of capabilities as an outcome 2 measure, are being added to the traditional economic evaluation toolbox with reference to the evaluation of public health interventions. MCDA in particular is a potentially useful tool when decision makers are faced with conflicting criteria and the complexity of balancing health gain and reducing inequalities can be addressed using this method. Health economists are looking to fields of environmental economics, transport economics and economic evaluation by central government e.g. the UK Treasury (Edwards et al, 2013) that commonly use broader measures of evaluation such as cost-benefit analysis and SROI. These methods can use information from randomised trials (or in public health, often cluster randomised trials), or use the results of longer term modelling of the costs and outcomes from investment in prevention. Concepts such as ‘rule of rescue’ (an ethical imperative to save individual lives even when money might be more efficiently spent to prevent deaths in the larger population (Doughety, 1993, quoted in McKie and Richardson, 2003)) means that prevention with its often-distant time horizon, struggles to gain an equitable share of resources. NICE guidance on the Economic Evaluation of Public Health interventions Since the responsibility for many public health programmes has been devolved to local authorities in England the approach that is now taken by NICE in their latest guidance (NICE 2012) is to broaden its approach to appraisal. The tools of economic evaluation must reflect the fact that local authorities are now responsible for the overall ‘well-being’ of its citizens and decision making that is much more decentralised. There is a wider remit than just health and a greater local element which has led NICE to advocate more emphasis be placed on cost consequence and cost benefit analysis rather than cost-effectiveness and cost-utility analysis. This is outlined by NICE in their technical guidance for new drugs and health technologies. A scoping study commissioned by NICE has also explored the potential of SROI as a method of evaluation in public health (NICE 2011). Public Health and preventative Strategies In his seminal book, Geoffrey Rose distinguished between population strategies and high risk strategies to prevention (Rose, 1992). Population strategies aim to achieve a small change in behaviour across the whole population (e.g. salt consumption); high 3 risk strategies aim to change the behaviour of those in the extreme tails of a population behaviour distribution (e.g. drug or alcohol misuse). Getting the public health message across is increasingly part of the role of GPs. GPs are now under increasing pressure to provide their patients with up to date information, and proactive brief intervention lifestyle-changing advice that may prevent ill-health in future. In 1990 a contract was introduced for GPs that offered payments for achieving certain public health prevention targets (such as cervical screening and immunisation). This role was strengthened with the introduction of incentive payments to GPs through the Quality and Outcomes framework (QOF) in 2004. It is estimated that only about 4% of NHS spending is on prevention (NHS 2013). In terms of shifting this balance in resource allocation, Hale et al (2012) argue that public health interventions in general, and those providing preventive measures specifically, are expected to demonstrate that they are cost saving as well as than merely cost-effective at the NICE thresholds. That is, in order to justify investment of resources, they are expected to use less resources and be more effective than treatment as usual. Shurcke et al (2007) argue that prevention should not be judged against a higher criterion than medical care. The question often asked is whether preventive interventions can prevent admissions to hospital in the short and medium term. The answer to this is often ‘no’. Market Failure for Prevention goods Hale et al (2012) base their economic approach to prevention on an idea of market failure. Governments, it is said in economic theory, should intervene in the supply of goods and services when there is some form of market failure in their provision. This leads to an outcome that is not Pareto optimal, that is, one can make someone better off without making at least one other person worse off. In the case of prevention, three reasons for market failure can occur (Hale et al 2012). The first is time inconsistent preferences. This is where individuals prefer instant gratification over future long-term interests. This is such that any commitment to behave in a certain way now will not be honoured in the future when the time comes. The second source 4 of market failure is when people do not act rationally, in accordance with the assumptions of micro-economic theory. This, it is argued is especially true in children and young people where as economic agents they are not making decisions to maximise their utility over the long-term but seek behaviour that maximises utility over the short term and may damage their health. There is an argument that there is an economic case for prevention to prevent them from harming themselves. The third type of market failure comes in the form of imperfect information. Information on healthy living is a public good and therefore expected to be under supplied by the free market. A public good displays aspects of non-rivalry in consumption and nonexcludability. Non-rivalry means that once a good is consumed this does not diminish the amount left for others to consume – this is true of information on health harming consumer goods. Non-excludability means that one cannot exclude anyone from consuming the good – also true of information. There is therefore a case for government intervention in the provision and production of health information. We see therefore that by recourse to economic theory there is a strong case for prevention within public health based on the possibility that provision by the free market will be sub-optimal and lead to inefficient outcomes. This market failure in preventive activity, and the reasons behind it, may lead to the need to consider different forms of evaluation on behalf of the government or other payer for preventive services. Within the NHS, NICE provides evidence of relative cost-effectiveness of new drugs and technologies using a threshold of £20,000 £30,000, which may be revised downwards given recent evidence (Claxton 2013). Owen et al 2011, using a cost-utility analysis framework, review and present evidence that many public health prevention initiatives fall well below this threshold and some are cost-saving (Owen et al, 2011). Acknowledgement that QALYs may not capture all benefits derived from public health interventions, and that many such interventions may have wide reaching costs and outcomes has led to interest in methods to identify, measure and value the full and broad range of costs and outcomes relevant to the evaluation of public health interventions (Weatherly et al, 2009; Payne et al,2012; Edwards et al, 2013). Many public health interventions have the potential to have an impact on health, housing, transport, education and the environment. Central and local government 5 departments have not traditionally used a framework of cost-per QALY - using concepts of “a business case”, or “the return on investment”. It is this kind of evidence that local government in England is now asking for, in order to guide commissioning and investment decisions (Buck et al, 2013). The key question in this paper is therefore: How do alternative methods of economic evaluation, within and outwith the health economists’ toolbox help to address questions about the cost-effectiveness of investment in prevention? The following section considers some approaches to both formal evaluation and those that simply facilitate organisation of costs and benefits within a public health context. NOISE Analysis NOISE analysis is a variant of SWOT Analysis. NOISE1 analysis allows researchers or teams within an organisation to set out explicitly the Need, Opportunity, Improvements, Strengths and Exceptions of various options. We apply this in Table 1 to a range of methods of economic evaluation that are currently being applied to the evaluation of Public Health prevention interventions. NOISE analysis begins by looking across all techniques of analysis and highlights the need by service commissioners for evidence of the cost effectiveness of prevention initiatives. Table 2 provides additional information on the theoretical basis of these methods of evaluation and signposts the analyst to useful websites. In terms of opportunities we see that funding streams such as the PHR enables more trials and cohort studies in public health. There is also guidance from NICE on the application of economic evaluation of public health interventions. All techniques could be improved by extending their application to more examples, and thus increasing the evidence base. Applying these evaluation techniques leads to a more robust, evidencebased allocation of resources. It can be argued that an exception to the need for economic evaluation is in the cases of low cost interventions with strong evidence of effectiveness- this still needs to be documented as part of evidence based policy. 1 http://create-learning.com/article/manager-training/noise-analysis-an-alternative-toswot-strategic-planning 6 Cost-effectiveness Analysis Cost-effectiveness Analysis (CEA) –This method is useful when a clear unidimensional metric of effectiveness across a Public Health prevention programme is known e.g. number of quitters per year from a smoking prevention programme. It does not allow for comparison across prevention programmes tackling different health problems across different populations. Cost Utility Analysis (CUA) Cost Utility Analysis (CUA) – In a single metric the QALY brings together two of the most important features of an intervention, that is, the length of life extended by the intervention and the quality of that life. It is a utility based measure focusing as it does on the weights assigned to particular health states which come from utility theory. The main advantage of using QALYs is that CUA can be used to compare across as well as within Public Health prevention programmes. Some proponents of the QALY approach argue that one of its strengths is the potential to compare across different types of interventions. Owen 2011 delivers a powerful message that of the 200 Public Health interventions reviewed, 85 percent had a cost-per QALY ratio well below the current NICE threshold. Case study 1 is based on an example from Dalziel et al (2006) looking at the cost utility of physical activity counselling in general practice in New Zealand and Australia. It is noted that physical activity acts as a preventative measure to reduce the risk of a number of ailments including coronary heart disease, stroke, high blood pressure, non-insulin diabetes, osteoporosis and obesity. In addition, the costs of disorders associated with physical inactivity are high - $24billion or 2.4% of total healthcare expenditure in the US in 1995. It is generally postulated that preventive interventions that aim to increase physical activity will improve quality of life, reduce mortality and generate savings in downstream costs of care. It can be said that a main drawback with the QALY approach is where the incremental benefit is very small it yields a very large incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER). In this situation, along with when ICERs are negative, a net benefit approach is preferable. This approach aims to give a monetary value to QALYs by multiplying them with different values for willingness to pay thresholds and then uses regression to regress net benefit on the 7 treatment variable thus giving an incremental net benefit that does not depend on small changes in QALYs. The authors chose the cost utility framework to assess whether a ‘Green Prescription’ intervention was cost effective compared to usual care as this intervention had not previously been evaluated. A cost utility method was chosen and their reasoning for using QALYs was that it allowed comparison with other approaches to prevention and management and so policy makers are able to make better decisions on resource allocation. This is because the QALY combines the impact on quality of life and mortality into a single measure. The main outcomes used to inform the economic model were changes in the proportion of people who became physically active (defined as having at least two and a half hours of activity in a week) and change in quality of life over 12 months. Impact on mortality was gleaned from the literature on the relationship between physical activity and mortality. They found a 90% likelihood that the program is more cost effective than usual care when the threshold is set at NZ $7,500 per QALY. The cost per QALY gained was $NZ 2,053 which falls well below the generally accepted funding thresholds. This intervention, therefore, can be seen to be highly cost effective. Further a Markov model was employed to extrapolate quality of life beyond the 12 month duration of the trial. Individuals were allocated into one of three Markov states: active, inactive and dead. The transition probabilities between each state at each cycle were derived from the published literature. The results were found to be consistent with other studies thus improving the authors’ confidence in the results. The main limitation of the study was the short follow up period (12 months) which meant that modelling had to be used to extrapolate results beyond the time frame of the trial. Another one of the main limitations of the study was that they used SF-36 data to calculate quality of life. The authors admit that utility data based on directly collected utility scores (such as EQ5D) would have been the preferred approach. However, it can be seen that the decision to use cost utility through QALYs was very apt in this case. Cost Benefit Analysis Cost benefit analysis can be seen as the most comprehensive and theoretically robust approach to economic evaluation (Robinson 1993). It allows the researcher to estimate the total cost and total benefit of an intervention and see whether total 8 benefits exceed total costs and so whether society experiences a net gain from the intervention in question. It differs from cost effectiveness and cost utility analysis in that it attempts to put a monetary valuation on benefits. It does this through a number of avenues including the human capital approach and contingent valuation methods. The human capital approach was the more traditional approach, has a long history in economics and is based on the idea that people’s working lives yield a rate of return similar to that of physical capital. In terms of valuing health, “…the benefits of health care can be measured in terms of the future flow of income that would otherwise have been forgone because of ill health” (Robinson 1993, p. 924) in McIntosh, 2010. The contingent valuation (CV) method is a stated preference approach designed to directly estimate welfare gains/losses as appropriate. Individuals are asked to consider a hypothetical scenario where they are asked to imagine that a market exists for the benefits or losses of a public programme. The exercise proceeds on the hypothetical contingency that such a market exists. Various design instruments can then be applied to ask individuals to state their willingness to pay (WTP) to ensure a welfare gain occurs or willingness to accept (WTA) to tolerate the welfare loss from the programme. The WTP or the WTA amount is then taken as a measure of the individual perceived value of the programme (i.e. the demand), which is then aggregated across all individuals (McIntosh et al 2010). There have been criticisms of both these methods. First, the human capital approach can be seen by some critics as unethical as it attempts to give a monetary value on human life. There may therefore be some distrust from decision makers about the method and uneasiness in applying its results. However, it must be noted that decision makers should be made aware of the fact that economists are not valuing human life per se but rather placing a monetary value on the costs of extending human life beyond a certain point. Another criticism is that the approach, focusing as it does on rates of pay, is not able to capture the health benefits that accrue to those not in employment. 9 The contingent valuation method also has a large number of methodological drawbacks mainly related to the various types of bias that arise when designing stated preference questions. For a comprehensive summary of such biases, see Mitchell and Carson, 1989. The following case study is based on work by Nichol (2001) who expored the costbenefit of vaccination for influenza among 18-64 year olds in the US. The objective of the study is to assess the economic implications of vaccinating this group on an annual basis. According to data from the National Health Interview Survey, influenza was responsible for 100 million days of bed disability, 75 million days of absenteeism and 25 million health visitor visits for this group in 1995. It is therefore apparent that there are potentially large savings to be made from a programme of vaccination. Here a CBA was carried out from a societal perspective allowing the researcher to look at wider costs and benefits. It measured the net cost or savings associated with the use of influenza virus vaccine in healthy working adults compared with no vaccination. This is not a traditional cost-benefit study whereby the authors attempt to put a monetary value on benefits. Here the benefits are seen as averted costs and vaccination can lead to direct and indirect costs being averted. Direct costs are those such as physician visits and hospitalisation while indirect costs include work absenteeism, reduced productivity and forgone future earnings (the human capital method of valuing benefits). Parameters for worker absenteeism and lower productivity were estimated from the National Health Survey. It was estimated that influenza on average results in 3.2 to 3.4 days of work loss. Productivity is measured on a scale of effectiveness (1 to 10) and the mean score for UK workers with influenza like symptoms was 4.6 according to Keech et al (1998). This was converted into a number of days lost due to reduced productivity. This was then compared with the cost of vaccination which includes the cost of the vaccination itself and cost of a health care provider visit. The metric of analysis was then cost savings (whereby costs averted were greater than costs incurred) or net costs (vice versa) and it was found that vaccination was cost saving. However there were notable limitations to the study. Perhaps the most obvious was that they failed to take into account the economic value of leisure time or the value that people place on the avoidance of suffering. Also the findings here may not be applicable to part time workers as they were based on full time, year round workers. However, if we view prevention as performing some kind of cost saving 10 function in the NHS then clearly this type of cost-benefit analysis is a good clear way of getting the message across about cost effectiveness. Cost consequence analysis Cost consequence analysis lists the costs and benefits associated with an intervention in a disaggregated way. NICE advocates the use of CCA in its technical guidance and this support can be seen as one of its strengths. However it does not provide decision makers with a single metric or ‘bottom line’ for evaluation and this may be seen as a weakness or exception of the method. Having said this the lack of a single criterion such as cost per QALY can be seen as a strength. Decision makers rarely make decisions based on one criterion and maybe the strength of CCA is that it measures impact across a range of criteria and compares it to cost. As such it shapes the analysis to the decision making context, whereas other techniques try and shape the decision making context to the analysis. Cost capability analysis This may be a novel concept and is suggested by the authors as a possible avenue of investigation in the future. Maximising QALY gains is not the only aim of public health interventions. NICE also considers the effect of interventions on the distribution of health within society. Reducing health inequalities is sometimes viewed as being equally important to maximising health for the population. One way of capturing changes in inequality is through the capability approach (Sen 1985). This is defined as the ability to function given the choice and looks to distribute capability equally across society. The development of the ICECAP (Flynn 2013) (Al Janabi 2012) measures and a planned version for children represents a big opportunity for this method. The concern with this approach however is the idea that consumers of preventive goods are essentially healthy today and whether the capability approach will pick up any effects. (We plan to add a case study after discussion of the concept of “cost-capability” analysis at HESG Glasgow). Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis (MCDA) Multiple criteria decision analysis (MCDA) is aimed at supporting decision makers faced with evaluating alternatives taking into account multiple, sometimes conflicting, criteria. The first step of MCDA is to identify the alternatives to be appraised and the 11 criteria against which the alternatives are to be assessed. This is known as problem structuring and is performed by the stakeholders involved through a process of decision conferencing. The final stage involves scoring each alternative’s expected performance on each criterion and then using weights to adjust each criterion’s importance. Perhaps the traditional way of thinking about decision making has been by recourse to a single objective function whereby the decision makers seek to maximise (or minimise) this function e.g. profit maximisation (Figueira et al 2005). Most of the techniques of priority setting, e.g. evidence-based medicine, burden of disease analysis, cost effectiveness analysis and equity analysis are based on a single criterion. However MCDA has developed over the last thirty years and sets decision problems in the context of a multitude of points of view taking into account their pros and cons. It is argued (Baltussen et al 2006) that public health interventions need to be evaluated in this broader context. For example, the need to address equity issues, to maximise population health, all to budget, requires the decision maker to be able to rationally choose which interventions deliver across a range of criteria. MCDA is not confined to simple weighting and scoring and approaches are available that are more relevant to NICEs health technology evaluation process. It can be seen that the first step of MCDA, that is problem structuring, is akin to the scoping stage in health technology assessments. Where the two methods differ is in the decision making stage. With the NICE approach the ICER is used to capture and evaluate the evidence whereas with the MCDA approach this evidence is inputted into mathematical models to identify the best alternatives. The way these models are specified accounts for the difference in the techniques that can be used. There are three main approaches classified as value measurement models, outranking models and goal, aspiration or reference models. The first approach uses and compares numerical scores to assess the degree to which one option is preferred over another. This approach is also the basis for programme budgeting marginal analysis (PBMA). The outranking approach compares alternatives pair wise in terms of each criterion. This is to establish the preference for each alternative for each specific criterion. The preference information is then aggregated in order to arrive at the total preference for 12 each alternative. The last method is involved with setting pre-determined levels of achievement for each criterion and identifying those alternatives that are closest to matching these. The case study for this section comes from the Netherlands. In it the authors (Bots & Hulshof 2000) use MCDA to assess a) the most important health problems in the Netherlands and b) efficiency gains in the health sector. Let us concentrate on the first of these. This case was developed by initially clustering the diseases that needed to be taken into account. The authors then determined the criteria to be used to rate these clusters by importance. These criteria were prevalence, potential years of life lost and cost of health care and the disease clusters were importance rated according to these criteria. The next step was to find data on all the criteria for all the disease clusters and using this data the three criteria scores were aggregated in order to determine the rank order. This was the basic structure of the MCDA in this case. The rest of the process involved policy design and this is where the case for prevention comes to the fore. MCDA can be used to rank diseases in order of importance which can then be used to inform on policy goals and instruments. These instruments were categorised into ‘cure’, ‘care’ and ‘prevention’ and were defined for the 14 most ‘important’ disease clusters resulting in 42 distinct instruments. The case for prevention is highlighted therefore in these policy instruments. Return on Investment (ROI) and Social Return on Investment (SROI) ROI and SROI are both pragmatic versions of CBA. They seek to link the inputs of a process with its outputs. These methods report results as a ratio of the value created by an intervention (£) in relation to the investment made £ for £. Within the NHS, the aim of ROI analysis is to use economics to guide decision makers in the NHS as to which public health prevention interventions should be invested in in order to receive the highest returns possible. NICE have developed a return on investment tool for smoking cessation2 and a tobacco control tool will be launched soon. They have also launched alcohol3 and physical activity4 tools. 2 (http://www.nice.org.uk/usingguidance/implementationtools/returnoninvesment/TobaccoROITool.jsp) 3 http://beta.nice.org.uk/About/What-we-do/Into-practice/Return-on-investment-tools/Alcohol-return-oninvestment-tool 4 http://beta.nice.org.uk/About/What-we-do/Into-practice/Return-on-investment-tools/Physical-activity-return-oninvestment-tool 13 SROI takes a wider societal perspective generating a triple bottom line - financial, social and environmental. According to the Cabinet Office (2010), “Social Return on Investment (SROI) is a framework for measuring and accounting for this much broader concept of value; it seeks to reduce inequality and environmental degradation and improve wellbeing by incorporating social, environmental and economic costs and benefits.” Olsen & Lingane (2003) offer the following definition, “A term originating from return on investment (ROI) used by traditional investors. It describes the social impact of a business or nonprofit’ operation in dollar terms, relative to the investment required to create that impact and exclusive of its financial return to investors.” (Olsen & Lingale, p. 4) We are interested in measuring inputs, outputs and outcomes. The inputs are those that are needed to make the intervention work and are measured in terms of costs. Outputs relate to the direct result of the intervention on patients in terms of metrics such as life years gained, reduced prevalence of some disease etc. Outcomes measure longer term benefits. These are adjusted to take account of deadweight – what would have happened anyway without the intervention. In order to investigate how SROI analysis works in real terms we will look at the feasibility of applying this type of analysis to the field of work site health promotion programs. This is a type of prevention based at work places intended to promote the health of the workforce. Goetzel and Ozminkowski (2008) have conducted a review of ROI studies in this field and this will serve as our case study. Healthcare interventions in the workplace can produce health benefits and reduce healthcare costs. Ill-health in the workplace is seen to affect absenteeism, staff turnover and decreased productivity. The question is whether these work related health programmes can improve employees’ health, reduce health costs, limit 14 absenteeism and decrease productivity loss in relation to the cost of the intervention. A 1998 review of work place health programmes yielded estimated ROI savings of between $1.40 and $3.14 per dollar spent with a median ROI of ~$3.00 saved per dollar spent. It can be seen that SROI is particularly apt in this case for prevention as it allows the researcher to isolate specific program elements and see which elements deliver the “biggest bang for the buck” or highest ROI ratio. Resources can then be channelled into those elements that seem to perform better and have the greatest effect on health for the cost involved. SROI ratios also provide a comparable framework in which to assess these interventions. A downside to this method however is the fact that many public health interventions, especially preventative ones, do not show a positive ROI for many years – the return is far from being instant. This may put employers off and make them reluctant to implement work place health promotion. Another weakness with the method is that negative results, or ROI ratios less than one, are unlikely to be reported in the literature. Finally an important element to consider in ROI analysis is selection bias. This may inflate cost savings and ROI ratios in work site studies. It may be seen that changes in medical expenditures or absenteeism can be attributed to underlying characteristics which may be independent of the program being evaluated. It is sometimes unclear whether the participants are healthier than nonparticipants to begin with. There are methods available however, such as those suggested by Heckman (propensity matching e.g.), that correct for this selection bias. There is growing evidence that these types of preventive interventions generate a positive ROI to employers that invest in them. The authors note however that the ROI research in this field is largely based on employer-sponsored health programmes. Most of the research is therefore funded by these employers and therefore likely to provide artificially positive ROI metrics, as the employers want a positive assessment to justify their investment decisions. To conclude, the authors note that in order for an intervention to have a positive ROI it needs to be funded at an optimal investment level so that the savings from the programme are equal to or greater than the programme’s costs. Most employers do not know where this tipping point is and so further research is required on the optimal design and cost of these interventions. 15 Discussion At present there is a need for a range of methods to be applied to the evaluation of public health prevention interventions, and a clear need for some standardisation of techniques, including wider use of thresholds, as is current practice in health technology assessment. We would welcome discussion of these issues at HESG in Glasgow. 16 Table 1: A NOISE Analysis of Techniques of Economic Analysis and related techniques being applied to the evaluation of Public Health intervention EVALUATION NEED METHOD Service commissioners in local government (England) and in the NHS Applies to all and local government techniques of (Scotland, Wales and N analysis Ireland) increasingly asking for evidence of the cost effectiveness of prevention initiatives OPPORTUNITIES IMPROVEMENTS NEEDED STRENGTHS EXCEPTIONS 1.Funding streams such as PHR mean more opportunity for trials and cohort studies in public health 2. NICE centre for public health Application to more excellence proposes methods for examples economic evaluation of public Avoids ad hoc investment decision making Arguably no need for economic evaluation of low cost interventions with strong evidence of effectiveness health interventions, ongoing consultation CMA rarely applicable as it is rare that 2 prevention initiatives have Cost Analysis exactly the same outcome Useful within a single Cost effectiveness As above analysis public health Cannot be used to compare across prevention public health prevention programme (e.g. programmes for different health smoking cessation problems or population groups programme). Cost utility analysis As above Increased evidence base of cost Further use of utility CUA allows Measurement of utility may be very per QALY for public health weights in particular comparison of value difficult in prevention initiatives 17 interventions Owen et al 2010 population groups e.g. for money of public where consumers are essentially children. health prevention healthy now, with ceilings effects initiatives with e.g. EQ-5D. Also measurement of medical utility may be difficult in certain interventions. Also groups such as children or the very allows comparison elderly. across prevention programmes for different health problems and in different population groups Application of treasury approach to CBA places public Cost benefit analysis As above health prevention at NICE supports use of CBA in cross-government its technical guidance level and allows for comparison with other government investment decisions Cost consequence As above NICE supports use of CCA in Advocated by NICE its technical guidance 18 Does not provide commissioners/policymakers with a “bottom-line” or ratio of benefits to analysis cost Cost capability analysis As above Development of capability Need for the planned measures, ICECAP-O and A ICECAP-C for children Capability theory fits Consumers of prevention goods and planned version for to allow for evaluation very well with public essentially healthy today, will children. Applicable to public of prevention initiatives health concerns over capability approach pick-up health and provide alternative to for children and young inequalities in health. anything? QALYs people Traditional CEA, CUA and CBA Multiple criteria decision analysis Public health initiatives methods have one often have many metric of outcome. simultaneous goals. MCDA allows for multiple criteria to be used 1. Increased volume of SROIs Negative results or relating to Public Health. SROI ratios less than Return on Organisations such as New £1/£1 rarely reported in investment / Economics Foundation teaching the literature. Need for this technique and accrediting standardisation of researchers round UK discount rates, time 2. Increased range of proxy horizon and range of values/ shadow prices available stakeholders Social return on investment As above 19 Collation of evidence for local government in England e.g. King’s Fund Report, 2013 from NEF and other sources 3. NICE developing a suite of ROI tools for NHS(e.g. smoking, alcohol misuse and obesity prevention) 20 Table 2: Key Features of Evaluative Methods EVALUATION THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVE TIME METHOD FRAMEWORK OF ANALYSIS HORIZON Accounting NHS Any SOURCES OF TECHNICAL WEBSITE SUPPORT GUIDANCE Applies to all techniques of analysis Cost Analysis Cost effectiveness analysis NHS or public Extra-welfarist sector multi agency NHS or public Cost utility analysis Extra-welfarist sector multi agency Cost benefit analysis Cost consequence analysis Any Welfarist Societal Public sector Extra-welfarist multi agency or societal n/a www.cdc.gov/owcd/eet/cost/1.html NICE technical NICE www.nice.org.uk guidance 2008 www.cdc.gov/owcd/eet/costeffect2/fixed/1.html Any, often NICE technical lifetime guidance 2008 NICE NICE public Any, often health guidance lifetime NICE Centre for Public Health Excellence 2012 NICE public Any, often health guidance lifetime NICE 2012 ICECAP website Cost capability analysis Capability theory Societal (?) Any n/a http://www.birmingham.ac.uk/research/activity/mds/projects/ HaPS/HE/ICECAP/index.aspx Multiple criteria Operations decision analysis Research Stakeholder Any n/a 21 www.ncsu.edu/nrli/decision-making/MCDA.php New Economics Foundation (NEF) www.neweconomics.org Return on investment / Social return on investment Public sector Stakeholder or Typically 1 to Cabinet Office economics societal 3 years 2010 Social Return on Investment Network www.thesroinetwork.org Treasury https://www.gov.uk/government/organisations/hmtreasury 22 References Al Janabi H, Flynn T, Coast J. Development of a self-report measure of capability wellbeing for adults: The ICECAP-A. Quality of Life Research 2012; 21:167-176 Baltussen et al (2006) “Priority setting of health interventions: the need for multi criteria decision analysis” Cost Effectiveness and Resource Allocation 2006, 4:14 Bots PWG, Hulshof JAM, (2000) “Designing Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis Processes for Priority Setting in Health Policy”. Journal of Multi Criteria Decision Analysis, 9: 56-75 Boyce, T, Peckham, S, Hann, A, Trenholm, S (2010), “A proactive approach. Health promotion and ill-health prevention”, The Kings Fund. Buck D, Gregory S, “Improving the public’s health: a resource for local authorities”, King’s Fund, 2013. Butterfield R., Henderson, J. and Scott R. (2009) Public Health and Prevention Expenditure in England – Health England Report No.4. Health England. Cabinet Office 2010. A Guide to Social Return on Investment. Prepared by the new Economics Foundation. Available at: http://www.bond.org.uk/data/files/Cabinet_office_A_guide_to_Social_Return_on_Inv estment.pdf Claxton, K et al (2013) “Methods for estimation of the NICE cost-effectiveness threshold”, Centre for Health Economics, University of York. Cohen (1984) Utility model of preventive behaviour. J Epidemiol Community Health. 1984 Mar;38(1):61-5. Dalziel et al (2006) “Cost utility analysis of physical activity counselling in general practice” Australian and New Zealand Journal of Public Health. Vol 30, No 1. Drummond M, Weatherly H, Claxton K, Cookson R, Ferguson B, Godfrey C, Rice N, Sculpher M, & Sowden A: Assessing the Challenge of Applying Standard Methods of Economic Evaluation to Public Health Interventions. [http://phrc.lshtm.ac.uk/papers/PHRC_D1-05_Final_Report.pdf] Edwards RT: Paradigms and Research Programmes: Is it Time to Move From Health Care Economics to Health Economics? Health Econ 2001 10:635-649 Edwards RT, Charles J, Lloyd-Williams H, (2013). “Public health economics: a systematic review of guidance for the economic evaluation of public health interventions and discussion of key methodological issues”, BMC Public Health, 13: 1001. Faculty of Public Health (2014). http://www.fph.org.uk/ 23 Figuieira, J et al (2005) “Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: State of the Art Surveys”, 78ed Springer New York, 133-153. Fischer AJ et al (2013). “The appraisal of public health interventions: an overview”, Journal of Public Health, 1-7. Flynn T, Huynh E, Peters T, Al Janabi H, Clemens S, Moody A et al. Scoring the ICECAP_A Capability instrument: Estimation of a UK general population tariff. Health Economics 2013; Early View Online. Goetzel RZ, Ozminkowski RJ, “The health and cost benefits of work site healthpromotion programs”, Annual Review of Public Health, 2008, 29:303-23 Hale, J, Phillips, CJ, Jewell, T, (2012) “Making the economic case for prevention – a view from Wales”, BMC Public Health, 12:460. Keech M, Scott AJ, Ryan PJ The impact of influenza and influenza-like illness on productivity and healthcare resource utilization in a working population. Occup Med (Lond). 1998;4885- 90 Kelly, M.P., McDaid, D., Ludbrook, A., & Powell, J. (2005). “Economic appraisal of public health interventions”. London: Health Development Agency. Retrieved from http://www.nice.org.uk/nicemedia/documents/Economic_appraisal_of_public_health_ interventions.pdf Kelly MP (2005). “Public health guidance and the role of new NICE”, Public Health 119, 960-968. McIntosh, E et al, “Applied Methods of Cost-Benefit Analysis in Health Care”, Oxford Handbooks In Health Economic Evaluation. 2010 McKie, J & Richardson J (2003). "The Rule of Rescue" Social Science & Medicine Volume 56, Issue 12, June 2003, 2407-2419 Mitchell RC, Carson RT. Using surveys to value public goods. 3rd ed. Resources for the Future; 1989.National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence (NICE) (2012) Methods for the development of NICE public health guidance (third edition). National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence (NICE) (2011): Supporting Investment in Public Health: Review of Methods for Assessing Cost Effectiveness, Cost Impact and Return on Investment. [http://www.nice.org.uk/media/664/AC/cost_impact_proof_of_concept.pdf]. New Economics Foundation. Measuring Social Impact: the foundation of social return on investment (2004). Available at http://sroi.london.edu/Measuring-SocialImpact.pdf 24 NHS England (2013) “A call to action: commissioning for prevention”, Available at http://www.england.nhs.uk/wp-content/uploads/2013/11/call-to-action-com-prev.pdf Nichol KL “Cost-Benefit Analysis of a Strategy to Vaccinate Healthy Working Adults Against Influenza.” Internal Medicine. 2001. 161 (5). 749-759 Olson, S, Lingane, A, “Social Return on Investment: Standard Guidelines”, (2003), Centre for Responsible Business. Working Paper Series. Available from: http://escholarship.org/uc/item/6xp540hs Owen L, Morgan A, Fischer A, Ellis S, Hoy A & Kelly M:. The cost-effectiveness of public health interventions, Journal of Public Health 2011, doi: 10.1093/pubmed/fdr075 [Published Online First]. Payne K, McAllister M, & Davies LM: Valuing the economic benefits of complex interventions: When maximising health is not sufficient. Health Econ 2012, doi:10.1002/hec.2795 [Published Online First]. Robinson R, “Cost Benefit Analysis”, BMJ , 307, 1993. Rose, G (1992). “The Srtategy of Preventive Medicine” OUP, Oxford. Sen AK: Commodities and Capabilities. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1985 Squires, H (2013). “A Methodological Framework for developing the structure of Public Health models”. PhD theses, University of Sheffield. Suhrcke M, Urban D, Moesgaard Iburg K, Schwappach D, Boluarte T, McKee M: The economic benefits of health prevention in a high-income country: the example of Germany. Gutersloh: Bertelsmann Foundation; 2007. Weatherly H, Drummond M, Claxton K, Cookson R, Ferguson B, Godfrey C, Rice N, Sculpher M, & Sowden A (2009). “Methods for assessing the cost-effectiveness of public health interventions: Key challenges and recommendations”. Health Policy 93:85-92. 25