Made in Chelsea? The evolution and transmission of inequality Andrew Hood Outline 1. Theoretical framework: how do economists think about inequality? 2. Measurement: how do economists measure inequality? 3. Evolution: what has happened to inequality? 4. Transmission: what will determine future inequalities? • An apology: empirics UK-focused throughout © Institute for Fiscal Studies How do economists think about inequality? • Economic theory approaches inequality from the perspective of a benevolent social planner maximising social welfare – Usually assumed to be a function only of the welfare of individuals • Why might reducing inequality increase social welfare? 1. Usually assumed that the marginal utility of income falls as income rises (concave utility) – This means the most efficient use of income is to give everyone the same amount (if the aim is to maximise utility) 2. Can choose to incorporate inequality in measure of social welfare – © Institute for Fiscal Studies Care more about giving additional utility to those who are worse off (Atkinson index) 3 (implicit) assumptions in welfare economics 1. The only inequalities that matter are inequalities in resources (and hence in individual’s welfare) – No room for inequalities in rights, status etc. 2. People with expensive tastes should always be compensated – The social planner cares about the distribution of welfare, regardless of the distribution of wealth required to achieve it 3. Increasing the welfare of an individual always increases social welfare – © Institute for Fiscal Studies The state of the world can never be improved by making the rich worse off and leaving the poor unaffected Inequality and economic policy (in theory) • 2nd fundamental theorem of welfare economics: the market can deliver any desired (efficient) allocation of resources given the right initial conditions (endowments) – Assuming perfect competition and perfect information • Theoretical benchmark is that government should only seek to change initial endowments, not allocation mechanism... • ..but not possible to redistribute all endowments (eg. skills) • Policy makers have to manage the disincentive effects of nonlump sum redistributive taxation – Classic efficiency/equity trade-off © Institute for Fiscal Studies Inequality of what? • Ultimately care about inequality in lifetime utility – But economists have given up on directly measuring utility • Usually assumed that people get utility from consumption and leisure – But economists don’t usually try to measure leisure • So best proxy from a theoretical perspective is consumption – Key determinant of individual welfare – If individuals can borrow or save, a “snapshot” consumption measure shouldn’t be too different to a “lifetime” measure – Return to lifetime/snapshot issue later © Institute for Fiscal Studies Consumption inequality vs. income inequality • Despite theoretical superiority of consumption, majority of work in economics looks at income inequality – Growing literature on wealth inequality • Focus on income inequality is largely pragmatic – Income data is easier to collect/more reliable than consumption data – And in practice income and consumption look pretty closely related • Important to remember the limitations of “snapshot” measures of income – Don’t distinguish between permanent and temporary inequalities – Don’t account for any insurance against income shocks © Institute for Fiscal Studies Those with the lowest incomes do not have the lowest consumption… £490 Median Expenditure £420 £350 £280 £210 £140 £70 £0 £0 £100 £200 £300 Income £400 £500 ...nor do they have the highest material deprivation scores Deprivation score 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 £0 £50 £100 £150 £200 £250 £300 £350 £400 £450 £500 Weekly BHC income, 2010-11 prices How do we measure income? • Income as measured by UK government in “Households Below Average Income” (HBAI) • Based on Family Resources Survey (from 1994-5 onwards) – 25,000 households across the UK – Subject to sampling error • Income is measured net of direct taxes and benefits • Measured at the household level (implicitly assumes income sharing) • Adjusted for inflation © Institute for Fiscal Studies The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 1,500 Childless couple: £440pw 1,000 Single person: £295pw Couple with 2 young children: £616pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 The UK income distribution in 2012–13 Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 How do we measure inequality? • Key assumption: inequality is a relative concept – If everyone’s income is doubled, inequality unchanged 1. Look at deviations from same proportional change across the distribution © Institute for Fiscal Studies Income changes by percentile point: 2011-12 to 2012-13 4% Cumulative income change 2% 0% -2% -4% -6% -8% -10% -12% 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies How do we measure inequality? • Key assumption: inequality is a relative concept – If everyone’s income is doubled, inequality unchanged 1. Look at deviations from same proportional change across the distribution – Uses all the information, but a picture not a number 2. Compare incomes at different points (parts) of the income distribution: ratio (share) measures © Institute for Fiscal Studies Measuring income inequality: the 90:10 ratio Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 Measuring income inequality: the 90:10 ratio Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 Measuring income inequality: the 90:10 ratio Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 Measuring income inequality: the 90:10 ratio Equivalised household income (£ per week) 2,500 2,000 90th percentile: £884pw 1,500 50th percentile: £440pw 1,000 10th percentile: £227pw 500 0 10 20 30 40 50 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 60 70 80 90 Measuring income inequality: the top 1% share 10% 20% bottom 90% next 9% top 1% 70% © Institute for Fiscal Studies Measuring income inequality: the top 1% share 10% 10% bottom 90% next 9% top 1% 80% © Institute for Fiscal Studies How do we measure inequality? • Key assumption: inequality is a relative concept – If everyone’s income is doubled, inequality unchanged 1. Look at deviations from same proportional change across the distribution – Uses all the information, but a picture not a number 2. Compare incomes at different points (parts) of the income distribution: ratio (share) measures – Easy to understand, but throws away lots of information 3. Summary measures of inequality – Aim to capture the whole distribution in a single number – Most popular measure is the Gini coefficient © Institute for Fiscal Studies Measuring income inequality: the Gini coefficient 100 Perfect equality Share of total income (%) 90 Gini = 80 70 A A + B 60 50 A 40 30 20 B 10 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Percentage of population, ranked by income 90 100 Changes in income inequality: long run trends • Sharp increase in inequality through the 1980s – After at least 20 years of relative stability © Institute for Fiscal Studies Big rise in inequality through the 1980s Gini coefficient 0.40 0.35 0.30 © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2012-13 2009–10 2006–07 2003–04 2000–01 1997–98 1994–95 1991 1988 1985 1982 1979 0.25 Unchanged since then across most of distribution... 5 4 3 2 1 90/10 ratio © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2012-13 2009-10 2006-07 2003-04 2000-01 1997-98 1994-95 1991 1988 1985 1982 1979 1976 1973 1970 1967 1964 1961 0 ...but top 1% continued to “race away” © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2012-13 2009-10 2006-07 2003-04 2000-01 1997-98 1994-95 1991 top 1% share 1985 1982 1979 1976 1973 1970 1967 1964 1961 90/10 ratio 1988 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Changes in income inequality: long run trends • Sharp increase in inequality through the 1980s – After at least 20 years of relative stability • Since then, inequality broadly unchanged across most of the distribution... – Not often discussed – why? • ...but the very top of the distribution has continued to “race away” – The topic of most public discussion of inequality – why? © Institute for Fiscal Studies Why has income inequality risen over the long run? • Lots of explanations – Skills-biased technological changes [see Acemoglu (2002), Machin (2001) and Goldin and Katz (2008)] – Labour market institutions: weaker trade unions and a decline of collective bargaining (Goodman and Shephard 2002) – More inequality in employment status across households (Gregg and Wadsworth, 2008) – Changes in the tax and benefit system • Requirements for a good explanation – Needs to explain similar trends across countries – In the UK, needs to explain why top 1% have continued to race away, but inequality has been flat across rest of the distribution © Institute for Fiscal Studies Why has top income inequality continued to rise? • Q1. Does increase in remuneration reflect higher marginal product? – Globalisation could have increased the marginal product of the most high-skilled individuals (Geoff Hurst vs. Wayne Rooney) – Or those individuals could be extracting much larger rents (breakdown of social norms) • Q2. Does higher marginal private product reflect higher marginal social product? – Growing share of high-income individuals from the financial sector – Is the financial sector more valuable in a globalised economy? Or are employees sharing in abnormal profits? © Institute for Fiscal Studies Changes in income inequality: recent years • Income inequality has fallen across most of the distribution in recent years © Institute for Fiscal Studies Income inequality has fallen in recent years 4% Cumulative income change 2% 0% -2% -4% -6% -8% 2007–08 to 2012–13 -10% -12% 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 Percentile © Institute for Fiscal Studies Changes in income inequality: recent years • Income inequality has fallen across most of the distribution in recent years – Although lower income households have faced higher inflation • Real earnings fell sharply but benefit entitlements remained relatively stable – 40% of total fall in inequality explained by “catch up” of non-working households • Hard to say much about what has happened to the very top – Underlying trends obscured by temporary responses to tax changes © Institute for Fiscal Studies What are the implications for public policy? • We need to be clear what kind of inequality we’re talking about – And what kind of inequality we care about • Inequality broadly flat across the majority of the distribution (with small fall in recent years) – Although (given relative concept) this means real incomes have risen more in cash terms further up the distribution • Dramatic change has been increasing share of income going to the top 1% – Do we care? If so, why? © Institute for Fiscal Studies Inter- and intra-generational inequality • Inequality in the population as a whole combines two kinds of inequality that we might want to consider separately 1. Intergenerational inequality: inequality between birth cohorts 2. Intra-generational inequality: inequality within birth cohorts • Intergenerational inequality has achieved greater prominence in recent years – Effect of the recession has varied significantly by age © Institute for Fiscal Studies Real median income by age group (2007-08=100) 110 105 100 95 90 85 2007–08 2008–09 2009–10 Age 22–30 © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2010–11 2011–12 Age 31–59 2012–13 2013–14 Age 60 and over 2014–15 Real median income by age group (2007-08=100) 110 105 100 95 90 85 2007–08 2008–09 2009–10 2010–11 2011–12 2012–13 2013–14 2014–15 Age 22–30 Age 22–30 (group-specific inflation) Age 31–59 Age 31–59 (group-specific inflation) Age 60 and over Age 60 and over (group-specific inflation) © Institute for Fiscal Studies Intergenerational income inequality: big picture • Each cohort is usually better off than their predecessors were at the same age... – • As a result of economic growth But this is no longer true in the UK and the US – © Institute for Fiscal Studies Very slow income growth for those of working-age in the 2000s, followed by the Great Recession Equivalised median household income by age and birth cohort 800 Real household income (£ per week, 2011-12 prices) 700 600 500 400 300 200 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 100 20 © Institute for Fiscal Studies 25 30 35 40 45 Age 50 55 60 65 70 Intergenerational income inequality: big picture • Each cohort is usually better off than their predecessors were at the same age... – • As a result of economic growth But this is no longer true in the UK and the US – • Very slow income growth for those of working-age in the 2000s, followed by the Great Recession Those born in the 1960s and 1970s did have higher incomes in early adult life – © Institute for Fiscal Studies But also spent more and (if anything) saved less than predecessors Intergenerational inequality: beyond income • Income at a given age not enough to assess the relative position of different cohorts • What we really want to know is how total economic resources across the lifetime compare for each generation • Things other than earnings can matter a lot: 2 (UK-focused) examples 1. Home ownership – access to capital gains 2. Inheritances and gifts © Institute for Fiscal Studies Intergenerational inequality: beyond income 1. Homeownership rates at a given age much lower for those born in the 1970s and 1980s – Looks unlikely these cohorts will ever achieve the homeownership rates of their predecessors © Institute for Fiscal Studies Homeownership rates by age and birth cohort (1) Percentage of individuals who own their home 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 30% 25 30 35 40 Age © Institute for Fiscal Studies 45 50 Homeownership rates by age and birth cohort (2) Born 1963–67 Born 1973–77 Born 1983–87 Homeownership rate (%) 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 Age Source: Figure 3.13 of Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality: 2014 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Intergenerational inequality: beyond income 1. Homeownership rates at a given age much lower for those born in the 1970s and 1980s – Looks unlikely these cohorts will ever achieve the homeownership rates of their predecessors – Smaller proportion access capital gains from housing © Institute for Fiscal Studies Real house prices in Great Britain (1968-69 = 100) 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2011–12 2006–07 2001–02 1996–97 1991–92 1986–87 1981–82 1976–77 1971–72 0 Intergenerational inequality: beyond income 1. Homeownership rates at a given age much lower for those born in the 1970s and 1980s – Looks unlikely these cohorts will ever achieve the homeownership rates of their predecessors – Smaller proportion access capital gains from housing 2. But more recent cohorts much more likely to inherit © Institute for Fiscal Studies Percentage of individuals who have received, or expect to receive, an inheritance, by birth year 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1940–44 1945–49 1950–54 1955–59 1960–64 Year of birth 1965–69 1970–74 Source : Authors’ calculations using wave 1 of the Wealth and Assets Survey © Institute for Fiscal Studies 1975–79 Intergenerational inequality: beyond income 1. Homeownership rates at a given age much lower for those born in the 1970s and 1980s – Looks unlikely these cohorts will ever achieve the homeownership rates of their predecessors – Smaller proportion access capital gains from housing 2. But more recent cohorts much more likely to inherit – 70% of those born in the late ‘70s expect to receive or have received an inheritance, compared to 28% of those born in the early ‘40s – Main reason why younger cohorts might expect to have higher incomes in later life than their predecessors © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distribution of size of inheritances received 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% Total size of inheritance(s) received (2012 prices) © Institute for Fiscal Studies What about intra-generational inequality? • Intra-generational income inequality similar across cohorts – But younger cohorts have lived more of their working lives post-1980 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Gini coefficients for equivalised household income by age and birth cohort Within-cohort Gini coefficient of household income 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 0.20 20 25 30 35 40 45 Age 50 55 60 Source : Authors’ calculations using Family Expenditures Survey, various years © Institute for Fiscal Studies 65 70 What about intra-generational inequality? • Intra-generational income inequality similar across cohorts – But younger cohorts have lived more of their working lives post-1980 • Tentative evidence of increasing inequality in housing wealth – No decline in the proportion owning their home outright © Institute for Fiscal Studies Outright homeownership rates by age and cohort Percentage of individuals who own their own home outright 80% 70% 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 Age © Institute for Fiscal Studies Source : Authors’ calculations using Family Expenditures Survey and Family Resources Survey, various years 65 70 What about intra-generational inequality? • Intra-generational income inequality similar across cohorts – But younger cohorts have lived more of their working lives post-1980 • Tentative evidence of increasing inequality in housing wealth – No decline in the proportion owning their home outright – More generally, bigger minority with no access to (future) capital gains • (Expected) inheritances very unequally distributed © Institute for Fiscal Studies Expected value of future inheritances, by age and current net household wealth £0 £1 to £9,999 £10,000 to £99,999 £100,000+ 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% Highest wealth Mid wealth Source : Authors’ calculations using wave 1 of the Wealth and Assets Survey 55–59 50–54 45–49 40–44 Lowest wealth Age group and (within-age-group) wealth tertile © Institute for Fiscal Studies 35–39 30–34 25–29 55–59 50–54 45–49 40–44 35–39 30–34 25–29 55–59 50–54 45–49 40–44 35–39 30–34 25–29 0% Expected value of future inheritances among those in their 30s, by partner’s expectations £0 £1 to £9,999 £10,000 to £99,999 £100,000+ 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% £0 £1 to £9,999 £10,000 to £100,000+ £99,999 Partner's expected future inheritance Source : Authors’ calculations using wave 1 of the Wealth and Assets Survey © Institute for Fiscal Studies No partner What about intra-generational inequality? • Intra-generational income inequality similar across cohorts – But younger cohorts have lived more of their working lives post-1980 • Tentative evidence of increasing inequality in housing wealth – No decline in the proportion owning their home outright – More generally, bigger minority with no access to (future) capital gains • (Expected) inheritances very unequally distributed – Strong positive correlation with existing wealth – Strong positive correlation across couples • Inheritances increase absolute inequality, but impact on relative inequality is ambiguous © Institute for Fiscal Studies A growing inheritance: implications for policy • Key change: inherited wealth will account for a larger share of lifetime economic resources for younger cohorts – Not confined to the UK (Piketty etc.) • Implication 1: increased inequality of opportunity – Who my parents are matters more for my lifetime resources – Usual remedies ineffective – not about earnings inequality (productivity, access to professions etc.) • Implication 2: relaxation of the equity/efficiency trade-off? – Opportunity to shift from income (labour) taxation to lump-sum (inheritance) taxation – But creates disincentive to work and save for future givers © Institute for Fiscal Studies Conclusions • 2 big stories in inequality over the last 20/30 years 1. The “racing away” of the very top of the income distribution 2. The shift from income inequality to wealth inequality, particularly the growing importance of inheritances • Both present new challenges for public policy 1. Given the Laffer curve, should governments attempt to reduce pre-tax inequality? Is there rent-seeking behaviour that should be regulated? 2. How should wealth be taxed? Is there political appetite for a more comprehensive wealth transfer tax? • Important to bear in mind the limitations of economic analysis – No room for non-material inequalities, social welfare the (weighted) sum of individual welfare © Institute for Fiscal Studies References Acemoglu, D. (2002)“Technical Change, Inequality and the Labor Market”, Journal of Economic Literature 40 (1) Adam, S., and Browne ,J. (2010) “Redistribution, work incentives and thirty years of UK tax and benefit reform”, IFS Working Paper 10/24 Belfield, C., Cribb, J., Hood, A., and Joyce, R. (2014) “Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2014” IFS Report R96 Brewer, M., and O’Dea, C. (2012) “Measuring Living Standards with income and consumption: Evidence from the UK”, IFS Working Paper W12/12 Cribb, J., Hood, A., Joyce, R., and Phillips, D. (2013) “Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2013” IFS Report R81 Cribb, J., Joyce, R., and Phillips, D. (2012) “Living Standards, Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2012” IFS Report C124 Goldin, C., and Katz, L. (2008) “The Race Between Education and Technology”, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA Goodman, A. and Shephard, A. (2002), Inequality and living standards in Great Britain: some facts, IFS Briefing Note 19 , Institute for Fiscal Studies, London Gregg , P. and Wadsworth, J. (2008) “Two Sides to Every Story: Measuring Polarization and Inequality in the Distribution of Work”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A Hood, A. and Joyce, R. (2013) “The economic circumstances of cohorts born between the 1940s and 1970s”, IFS Report R89 Machin, S. (2001) “The Changing Nature of Labour Demand in the New Economy and Skill-Biased Technology Change”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 63 (S1) © Institute for Fiscal Studies