Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Rules Explicit Solutions For A

advertisement
[Journal of Economic Theory]
Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules
in a Continuous-Time Model
Robert C. Merton (1971)
Yuna Rhee
Seyong Park
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
Contents
I.
Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Rules
II.
Explicit Solutions For A Particular Class of Utility Functions
III.
The effects on the consumption and portfolio rules of
alternative asset price dynamics
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
2
I. Optimal Portfolio and Consumption rules
Contents
1.
Procedures of solving the optimal equation
2.
Optimal Equation & PDE
3.
First order conditions of the PDE
4.
Optimal Portfolio and Consumption rules expressed by
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
3
J
I. Optimal Portfolio and
Consumption rules
01. Procedures
Construct the optimal equation
Derive the partial differential
equation
First Order Conditions of the
PDE
Optimal portfolio and
consumption rules expressed
by J and U
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
4
I. Optimal Portfolio and
Consumption rules
02. Optimal Equation & PDE
 The problem of choosing the optimal portfolio and consumption rules,
T
max E0{ U (C (t ), t )dt  B[W (T ), T ]}
0
 The dynamic programming equation is
T
J (W , P, t )  max Et { U (C , s )ds  B[W (T ), T ]}
{c , w}
 Define
t
 (C , w;W , P, t )  U (C , t ) L [J ]
 Then the partial differential equation becomes,
n
n
J
J
J
 (C , w;W , P, t )  U (C , t )   ( wi iW  C )
   i Pi
t
W 1
Pi
1
2
1 n n
1 n n
2J
2  J
   ij wi w jW
  Pi Pj ij 2
2 1 1
W 2 2 1 1
P
1 n n
2 J
  PiWw j ij
2 1 1
WP i
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
5
I. Optimal Portfolio and
Consumption rules
02. Optimal Equation & PDE
 By the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation (I),
0   (C * , w* ;W , P, t )   (C, w;W , P, t )
In other words,
0  max  (C, w;W , P, t )
{c , w}
*
where C is the optimal consumption and
w*
is the optimal weight.
 In this paper, Theorem I is the HJB equation (I).
 The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation (I) is written on the Stochastic Differential
Equations by Bernt Øksendal.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
6
I. Optimal Portfolio and
Consumption rules
03. First Order Conditions of the PDE
 Define the lagrangian
n
L     (1   wi )
1
 Then first order conditions
for maximum are
0  LC (C * , w* )  U C  JW ,...................(1)
n
n
0  Lwk (C , w )   kWJ W  JW W   kj w W   J jW  kj PjW ,........(2)
*
*
*
j
2
1
1
n
0  L  1   wi* ................................(3)
1
 The sufficient conditions for interior maximum
LCC  CC  U CC  0, LCwk  Cwk  0,
Lwk wk   k2W 2 J W W , Lwk w j  J W WW 2 kj , k  j.
 s.c.J W W
C *
 0. 
0
W
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
7
04.
C *, w* expressed by
I. Optimal Portfolio and
Consumption rules
J and U
 Optimal Consumption rules expressed by J ,
C *  G ( J W , t ), G  [U C ]1
 Optimal Portfolio rules expressed by J ,
wk*  hk ( P, t )  m( P,W , t ) g k ( P, t )  f k ( P,W , t ), k  1,2,..., n
1 hk  1, 1 g k 0, 1 f k  0,
n
n
n
hk ( P, t )  
n
vkj
1

, m( P, W , t ) 
 JW
,
WJ W W
n
n
1 n
g k ( P, t )   vkl ( l   vij j )
 1
1
1
n
n
1
1
f k ( P, t )  (J kw Pk   J iw Pi  vkj ) / WJ W W
 If the nth asset is risk free,
J
w  W
JWWW
*
k
m
 vkj ( j  r ) 
1
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
J kW Pk
, k  1,2,..., m
JWWW
8
II. Explicit Solutions for A Particular Class of Utility Functions
Contents
1.
Procedures of the solving the optimal equation
2.
HARA (Hyperbolic Absolute Risk-Aversion)
3.
CRRA (Constant Relative Risk-Aversion)
4.
CARA (Constant Absolute Risk-Aversion)
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
9
01. Procedures
II. Explicit Solutions
Substitute C *, w* expressed by
J and U into the PDE
Solve the PDE for
J
Substitute J into the optimal
consumption and weight
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
10
02. HARA (Hyperbolic Absolute Risk-Aversion)
 HARA family: Hyperbolic Absolute Risk Aversion.
U (C , t )  exp(  t )V (C ),
1   C
V (C ) 
(
  ) ,
 1 
C 
A(C )  V ' ' / V '  1 /(
 )  0,
1  
C
s.t.  1,   0,
   0,  1if .  ,
1 
 Optimal Portfolio and Consumption rules expressed by
1   exp( t ) JW 1/( 1) (1   )
C (t ) 
(
)




JW   r
*
w (t )  
JW WW  2
*
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
11
J
II. Explicit Solutions
02. HARA (Hyperbolic Absolute Risk-Aversion)
 PDE for
II. Explicit Solutions
J
exp( t ) JW  /( 1)
JW2 (  r ) 2
(1   ) 2
(1   )
0
exp(  t )(
)
 Jt  [
 rW ]JW 



JW W 2 2
 Guess the solution to the PDE for
J
 W
1 

r ( t T ) 
J (W , t ) 
F (t )
 [1  e
] 

 1   


 Then we can get the solution to the above PDE

  (1  e
J (W , t )    e  t 
  


   

 (T  t )
  



)  W 
 r (T  t ) 

(
1

e
)
   

 

where   1   and   r  (a  r ) 2 / 2 2
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
12
02. HARA (Hyperbolic Absolute Risk-Aversion)
 The optimal portfolio and consumption rules



[    ]W (t )  (1  e r (t T ) )


  
*
C (t ) 


 (    )

 1  exp 
(t  T ) 
 


w* (t )W (t ) 
(  r )
 (  r )
r ( t T )
W
(
t
)

(
1

e
)
2
2

r
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
13
II. Explicit Solutions
03. CRRA (Constant Relative Risk-Aversion)
II. Explicit Solutions
 CRRA family: Constant Relative Risk Aversion.
C
U (C )  ,   1 and   0 or U (C )  log C ,   0

U '' (C )C
where  '
 1     is Pr att ' s measure of relative risk aversion
U (C )
 Optimal Portfolio and Consumption rules expressed by
1
 1
 t I t 
C (t )  e

 W 
I
 (a  r ) t
W
w* (t ) 
2

It
 2W
W 2
*
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
14
I
03. CRRA (Constant Relative Risk-Aversion)
 I t 

 t

2 


1
(a  r )  W 
 I  1   I t I t
0  e1  t 


rW 
 2 It

t W
2 2
 W 
Guess the solution to the PDE for I
W 2
b(t )  t

I (W , t ) 
e W (t )

 PDE for

I
 Then we can get the solution to the above PDE


1  (  1)e
I (W , t ) 
 ( t T )

 / 
1
e  t W (t )

(a  r ) 2
1 
where      {r  2
},  
2 (1   )

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
15
II. Explicit Solutions
2
03. CRRA (Constant Relative Risk-Aversion)
II. Explicit Solutions
 The optimal portfolio and consumption rules


C * (t )   /(1  (  1)e (t T ) ) W (t ), for   0
C * (t )  1 /(T  t   )W (t ), for   0
(  r )
w (t )  2
 (1   )
*
*
 In this, the consumption C (t ) is a constant proportion of wealth and the optimal portfolio
*
rules w (t ) is a constant independent of W or t.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
16
04. CARA (Constant Absolute Risk-Aversion)
II. Explicit Solutions
 CARA family: Constant Absolute Risk Aversion.
e C
U (C )  
,  0

U '' (C )
where  '
  is Pr att' s measure of absolute risk aversion
U (C )
 Optimal Portfolio and Consumption rules expressed by
1
C * (t )   ln J ' (W )

 (a  r ) J ' (W )
w* (t )  2
 WJ ' ' (W )
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
17
I
04. CARA (Constant Absolute Risk-Aversion)
 PDE for
II. Explicit Solutions
J
J ' (W )
J ' (W )
(a  r ) 2 [ J ' (W )]2
0
 J (W )  rWJ ' (W ) 
ln J ' (W ) 


2 2 J ' ' (W )
 Guess the solution to the PDE for
J
p qW
J (W )   e
q
 Then we can get the solution to the above PDE
p
J (W )   e qW
q
r    (a  r ) 2 / 2 2
where p  exp(
), q  r
r
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
18
04. CARA (Constant Absolute Risk-Aversion)
II. Explicit Solutions
 The optimal portfolio and consumption rules
  r  (a  r ) 2 / 2 2
C (t )  rW (t ) 
r
(  r )
w* (t ) 
r 2W (t )
*
 In this unlike the CRRA case, that consumption
of wealth although it is still linear in wealth.
C * (t )
is no longer a constant proportion
*
 Instead of the proportion of wealth invested in the risky asset being constant (i.e., w
(t )
a constant), the total dollar value of wealth invested in the risky asset is kept constant (i.e.,
w* (t )W (t )
a constant).
 As one becomes wealthier, the proportion of his wealth invested in the risky asset falls, and
asymptotically, as W goes to infinity, one invests all his wealth in the certain asset and
consumes all his (certain) income.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
19
III. The effects of alternative asset price dynamics
Contents
1.
Noncapital Gains Income: Wages (Constant Case)
2.
Poisson processes (Case1, Case2, Case3)
3.
Alternative Price Expectations to the Geometric
Brownian Motion (Case1, Case2, Case3)
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
20
01. Noncapital Gains Income: Wages
III. Alternative dynamics
 In the previous sections, it was assumed that all income was generated by capital gains. If a
(certain) wage income flow (constant case) in introduced, then the optimal consumption
and portfolio rules are as the follwoing
Y (1  e r (t T ) ) 
[    ][W 
 (1  e r (t T ) )]

r

*
C (t ) 

 (1  exp[(    )(t  T ) /  ])

(  r )
Y (1  er (t T ) ) (  r )
r ( t T )
w (t )W (t ) 
(
W

)

(
1

e
)
2
2

r
r
*
 Comparing these results with the HARA case’s one, we finds that the individual capitalizes
the lifetime flow of wage income at the market (risk-free) rate of interest and then treats the
capitalized value as an addition to the current stock of wealth.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
21
02. Poisson Processes(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Consider first the two-asset case. Assume that one asset is a common stock whose price is
log-normally distributed and that the other asset is a “risky” bond which pays an
instantaneous rate of interest r when not in default but, in the event of default, the price of
the bond becomes zero.
 The optimality equation can be written as
0  U (C * , t )  J t  [ J ( w*W , t )  J (W , t )]  JW {[ w* (  r )  r ]W  C *}
1
 JW W 2 w*2W 2
2
 First order conditions with respect to
C*
and
w* are
0  U C (C * , t )  JW (W , t )
0  JW ( w*W , t )  JW (W , t )(  r )  JW W (W , t ) 2 w*W

C
Consider the particular case when U (C , t ) 
, for   1 , in other words the CRRA

case.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
22
02. Poisson Processes(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Then the optimal portfolio and consumption rules are
C * (t )  AW (t ) /(1   )(1  exp[ A(t  T ) / 1   )
 (  r ) 2
  (2   ) *  (  r ) * 1 
 r    1 
w  2
w 
where A   
2

2 (1   )

 2 (1   )  
(  r )

w*  2
 2
( w* ) 1
 (1   )  (1   )
 As might be expected, the demand for the common stock is an increasing function of  .
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
23
02. Poisson Processes(Case2)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Consider an individual who receives a wage, Y (t ) , which is incremented by a constant
amount  at random points in time. In other words, dY   dq . Suppose further that the
 t
individual’s utility function is of the form U (C , t )  e V (C ) and that his time horizon is
infinite (i.e.,T   ).
 For the two-asset case, the optimality equation can be written as
0  V (C * )  I (W , Y )  [ I (W , Y   )  I (W , Y )]  IW (W , Y )
1
2 *2
 [( w (  r )  r )W  Y  C ]  IW W (W , Y ) w W 2
2
Consider the particular case when V (C )   exp( C ) / 
*

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
*
24
, in other words the CARA case.
02. Poisson Processes(Case2)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Then the optimal portfolio and consumption rules are
2
Y
(
t
)

1

exp(


)
1
(


r
)
C * (t )  r[W (t ) 
 2
]  [  r 
]
2
r
r

r
2
 r
*
w (t )W (t )  2
 r

 In this, [W (t )  Y (t ) / r   (1  e ) / r ] is the general wealth term, equal to the sum of
present wealth and capitalized future wage earnings.
2
 If   0 , then the above optimal consumption
constant wage case.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
25
C * (t )
is same as the result of previous
02. Poisson Processes(Case2)

 1  exp(  )
When   0 , 2
r

III. Alternative dynamics
is the capitalized value of (expected) future increments to
the wage rate, capitalized at a some what higher rate than the risk-free market rate
reflecting the risk-aversion of the individual.

Et  exp( r ( s  t ))(Y ( s)  Y (t )) d s 
t
 [1  exp(  )]

, if   0
2
2
r
r
 The individual, in computing the present value of future earnings, determines the Certaintyequivalent flow and the capitalizes this flow at the (certain) market rate of interest.


0
exp( rs ) X ( s) 
Y (0) [1  exp(  )]

r
r 2
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
26
02. Poisson Processes(Case3)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Consider an individual whose age of death is a random variable. Further assume that the
event of death at each instant of time is an independent Poisson process with parameter  .
Then, the age of death, , is the first time that the event (of death) occurs and is an
exponentially distributed random variable with parameter  .
 The optimality criterion is to

max E0{ U (C, t )dt  B[W ( ), ]}
0
 The associated optimality equation is
0  U (C * , t )  [ B(W , t )  J (W , t )]  L( J )
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
27
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 First case is the “asymptotic ‘normal’ price-level” hypothesis which assumes that there
exists a “normal” price function, P (t ) , such that
lim ET ( P(t ) / P (t ))  1, 0  T  t  
t 
i.e., independent of the current level of the asset price, the investor expects the “long-run”
price to approach the normal price.
 A particular example which satisfies the hypothesis is that
P (t )  P (0)et
and
dP
  {  vt  log( P(t ) / P(0))}dt  dz,
P
where
  k  v /    2 / 4 , k  log( P (0) / P(0))
 This implies an exponentially-regressive price adjustment toward a normal price, adjusted
for trend.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
28
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
Y  log( P(t ) / P(0)) . Then by Ito’s Lemma, we can write the dynamics for Y as
dY   (u  vt  Y )dt  dz
 Let
where u
    2 / 2 . This process is called Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process.
 The Y is a normally-distributed random variable generated by a Markov process which is
not stationary and does not have independent increments. And from the definition of Y ,

P (t ) is log-normal and Markov.
The Y (t ) , conditional on knowing Y (T ) , as
2
t

Y (t )  Y (T )  [k  vT 
 Y (T )](1  exp(  )  v   exp( t ) exp( s)dz
T
4

where   t  T  0 .
 The instantaneous conditional variance of Y (t ) is
2
var(Y (t ) | Y (T ))  [1  exp( 2 )]
2
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
29
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 The conditional expected price can be derived
ET ( P(t ) / P(T ))  ET {exp( Y (t )  Y (T ))}
2
 exp{[ k  vT 
 Y (T )](1  exp(   ))
4
2
 v   [1  exp( 2 )]})]
4
 Consider the two-asset model is used with the individual having an infinite time horizon
and a constant absolute risk-aversion utility function, U (C , t )   exp( C ) /  .
 The fundamental optimality equation then is written as
0   exp( C * ) /   J t  JW {w*[  (  vt  Y )  r ]W  rW  C *}
1
1
*2 2 2
 JW W w W   J Y  (u  vt  Y )  J YY  2  J YW w*W 2
2
2
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
30
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 From the FOC, the associated equations for the optimal rules expressed by
log( JW )
C 

J [  (  vt  Y )  r ] J YW
w*W   W

2
JW W
JW W
After solving the previous PDE for J , we obtain the optimal rules in explicit form as
  2 
2 2
 
C*  rW  2 Y 
t    r      r  Y  a(t )
2 
2 r
r 
2


*

J

1   
 2  2
w *W 
1  ( ( P, t )  r )  2    r 
2 
r  r 
r  2

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
31
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case1)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Recall the optimal rules when the geometric Brownian motion hypothesis is assumed
  r  (a  r ) 2 / 2 2
C (t )  rW (t ) 
r
(  r )
*
w (t ) 
r 2W (t )
*
 We find that the proportion of wealth invested in the risky asset is always larger under the
“normal price” hypothesis than under the geometric Brownian motion hypothesis.
 Even if   r , unlike in the geometric Brownian motion case, a positive amount of the
risky asset is held.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
32
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case2)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Second case is the same type of price-dynamics equation as was assumed for the
geometric Brownian motion, namely,
dP
 dt  dz
P
 However, instead of the instantaneous expected rate of return  being a constant, it is
assumed that  is itself generated by the stochastic differential equation,
dP  dt  dz,
d   (u   )dt  dz
 The first term implies a long-run, regressive adjustment of the expected rate of return
toward a “normal” rate of return,  , where  is the speed of adjustment.
 The second term implies a short-run, extrapolative adjustment of the expected rate of
return of the “error-learning” type, where  is the speed of adjustment.
 This assumption is called the “De Leeuw” hypothesis.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
33
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case2)
 The
 (t ) conditional on knowing  (T )
 (t )   (T )  (   (T ))(1  e
where   t  T  0 .
 
III. Alternative dynamics
is
)   e
 Then, the conditional mean and variance of
 t

t
T
e s dz,
 (t )   (T )
are
ET ( (t )   (T ))  (   (T ))(1  e   )
and
 2 2
var[ (t )   (T ) |  (T )] 
(1  e2  )
2
 Thus, the
Y (t )
conditional on knowing
P(T )
and  (T ) ,
t s
t
1 2
(    (T ))
 
  ( s ' s )
Y (t )  Y (T )  (    ) 
(1  e )     e
dz ( s' )ds    dz
T
T
T
2

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
34
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case2)
 Therefore, the conditional mean and variance of Y (t )  Y (T ) are
III. Alternative dynamics
1 2
(    (T ))
ET [Y (t )  Y (T )]  (    ) 
(1  e   )
2

and
 2 2
1
2
 
 2 
var[Y (t )  Y (T ) | Y (T )]    
[


2
(
1

e
)

(
1

e
)]
2
2
2
2 2
 2 [   (1  e   )]

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
35
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case2)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Again, the two-asset model is used with the individual having an infinite time horizon and a
constant absolute risk-aversion utility function, U (C , t )   exp( C ) /  .
 The fundamental optimality equation is written as
0
e
C *

 J t  JW [ w* (  r )W  rW  C * ]
1
1
*2
2 2
 JW W w W   J   (    )  J   2 2  JW  2 w*W
2
2
 From the FOC, the associated equations for the optimal rules expressed by
log( JW )
C 

J (  r ) JW 
w*W   W

2
JW W
JW W
*
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
36
J
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case2)
 After solving the previous PDE for
III. Alternative dynamics
J , we obtain the optimal rules in explicit form as

1
 (   r ) 
wW 
(r    2 )(  r ) 

2
r (r  2  2 ) 
r     
*
 Assuming
r
, compare this with the Brownian motion case
w* (t ) 
(  r )
, then
2
r W (t )
we find that under the De Leeuw hypothesis, the individual will hold a smaller amount of the
risky asset than under the geometric Brownian motion hypothesis.
 Note that w*W is a decreasing function of the long-run normal rate of return  . This is
because as  increases for a given  , the probability increases that future “  ' s” will be
more favorable relative to the current  , and so there is a tendency to hold more of one’s
current wealth in the risk-free asset as a “reserve” for investment under more favorable
conditions.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
37
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case3)
III. Alternative dynamics
 Last case assumed that prices satisfy the geometric Brownian motion,

dP
 dt  dz
P
However, it is also assumed that the investor does not know the true value of the parameter,
 , but must estimate it from past data.
 Suppose the investor has price data back to time  . Then, the best estimator for  , ˆ (t ) ,
1
ˆ (t ) 
t 
dP
 P , ˆ ( )  0
t
 Then E(ˆ (t ))   , and if we define the error term  t
written as
dP
 ˆdt  dzˆ
P
dzˆ  dz   t dt / 
By differentiating ˆ (t ) , we have the dynamics for ̂ ,

dˆ 
dzˆ
t 
where

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
38
   ˆ (t ) , then
dP
can be reP
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case3)
III. Alternative dynamics
 By differentiating ˆ (t ) , we have the dynamics for ̂ ,
dˆ 

dzˆ
t 
 We see that this “learning” model is equivalent to the special case of the De Leeuw
hypothesis of pure extrapolation (i.e.,  0 ), where the degree of extrapolation  is
decreasing over time.
 If the two-asset model is assumed with an investor who lives to time T with a constant
absolute risk-aversion utility function, and if (for computational simplicity) the risk-free
asset is money (i.e., r  0 ), then the optimal portfolio rule
t 
T 
w W  2 log(
)ˆ (t )

t 
*
and the optimal consumption rule is
C* 
W 1
2
T  t  (T   ) log( T   )  (t   ) log( t   )
 [log( T   ) 
T t 
T t
ˆ 2 (t   ) 2
T   (T   )
 2[
log(
)
]]
2 (T  t )
t 
t 
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
39
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case3)
 By differentiating w*W with respect to
time for t  t , reached a maximum at
III. Alternative dynamics
t , we find that w*W is an increasing function of
t  t , and then is a decreasing function of time for
t  t  T , where t is defined by
t  [T  (1  e) ] / e
 In early life, the investor learns more about the price equation with each observation, hence
investment in the risky asset becomes more attractive.
 But as he approaches the end of life, he is generally liquidating his portfolio to consume a
larger fraction of wealth.
*
 Consider the effect on w W of increasing the number of available previous observations
(i.e. increase ). As expected, the dollar amount invested in the risky asset increases
monotonically.
 Taking the limit
w*W 
w*W a    , we have that the optimal portfolio rule is
T t
 , as   
2

MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
40
03. Alternative price dynamics(Case3)
III. Alternative dynamics
*
 Consider the effect on w W of increasing the number of available previous observations
(i.e. increase ). As expected, the dollar amount invested in the risky asset increases
monotonically.
 Taking the limit
w*W a   , we have that the optimal portfolio rule is
T t
w W  2  , as   

*
which is the optimal rule for the geometric Brownian motion case when  is known with
certainty.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
41
Questions
&
Comments
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance
Download