ECO 4119 POLITICAL ECONOMY Chapter 2 The History of Political Economy Introduction • Current political and economic issues cannot be fully understood without an appreciation of the historical evolution of both institutions and ideas. • All history is subject to interpretation, and the history of ideas is particularly controversial. • No single interpretation of the history of political economy commands universal agreement. Origins of Political Economy • Between the fourteenth and eighteenth centuries --a “great transformation” in Western Europe as the impact of commerce gradually eroded the feudal economy of the Middle Ages • The newly emerging market economy --provided individual aspirations --encouraged entrepreneurial behavior that had previously been suppressed by church, state, and the community. • The church struggled to maintain its control over society by placing limitations on the accumulation and use of property. Origins of Political Economy • Along with changes in production and trade, new ideas were • • • • emerging. The Renaissance of the fourteenth century paved the way for the scientific inquiries of Copernicus, Galileo, Bacon, and Newton. Another impetus for change came from the Protestant Reformation initiated by Martin Luther in Germany. By the early eighteenth century, the Age of Reason, or Enlightenment, had arrived, and with it came a rejection of the medieval view of society as a divinely ordered hierarchy in which each person had a proper role and purpose. The new worldview centered around the autonomous individual and the human capacity for reason. Origins of Political Economy • The philosophers of Enlightenment such as Voltaire, Diderot, believed that most human problems were attributable to poorly structured institutions and to uncritical acceptance of traditional authority emanating from church and state. • They blamed prejudice, intolerance, and emotions for suppressing the human capacity to envision a better society and to act accordingly. • Enlightenment thinkers demanded the liberation of the individual from all social, political, and religious bonds. Origins of Political Economy • A total restructuring of society • The rising importance of science • Revealing the universal laws that govern nature and society • Liberating mankind from both material deprivation and social oppression • With advances in the understanding of human behavior, Enlightenment thinkers began to anticipate a science of society. If the laws and regularities of human interaction could be understood, a scientific basis for identifying the ideal set of social institutions would be established. • This emergent science of society came to be known as political economy. Origins of Political Economy • The actual term “political economy” was introduced in 1616 by • • • • a French writer, Antoine de Montchrétien (1575-1621), in his book Treatise on Political Economy. The first known English usage occurred in 1767 with the publication of Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy by Sir James Steuart (1712-1780). These early political economists sought to develop guidelines and offer policy recommendations for government efforts to stimulate commerce Markets were still relatively undeveloped at the time, so government took on significant responsibilities in opening new areas for trade, offering protection from competition, and providing control over product quality. The ideas and policies developed for this early stage of capitalism came to be known as “mercantilism”. Origins of Political Economy • By the late eighteenth century, however, many manufacturers and merchants perceived government not as a beneficent director of economic activities, but as a major obstacle to the pursuit of wealth. • The formation of markets in England by the second half of the eighteenth century along three lines • First, the elimination of many single-family farms created a market for cheap and mobile labor. • Second, the accumulation of wealth through piracy, looting, and early successes in commerce created a mass of financial capital available for borrowing. • Third, the confiscation and subsequent sale of church property and public land that had previously been reserved for common use created a market for land. • Political freedom --the combination of the Magna Carta --the English civil war, and the Glorious Revolution of 1688 greatly diminished the power of the monarch and the aristocracy. • The market would become the dominant institution for organizing society. What is Industrial Revolution and why it started in Britain? • Between 1770 and 1850 the economy of England changed • • • • from mostly agricultural to mostly industrial This was the result not of one key invention but of technological progress in different fields coming together Its center is the development of factories (which hadn’t really existed before this time), but they couldn’t have developed without better transportation creating larger markets and better transportation couldn’t have existed without the growth of the iron industry, which couldn't have grown without steam engines Society had a hard time adjusting to the new economic system This is the beginning of technology changing quickly enough that peoples lives were transformed by technology within their lifetimes, not over many generations What is Industrial Revolution and why it started in Britain? • Economy becoming more capitalist (free market), decline of: • Feudalism--farmers were no longer bound to the land • Guild system--the guild for a particular trade could no longer control who set up a new business • The system of customary prices--the market is more free, instead of the old system where changing the price because of a shortage was seen as profiteering • These changes were a necessary condition but not perhaps the immediate cause What is Industrial Revolution and why it started in Britain? • Agricultural changes • Enclosure =the abolishment of the old system of communal farming and its replacement with family farms. Supposedly everyone had the same share of land as before, but the smallest farmers didn’t have enough to survive as an independent farm and they went out of business and went looking for work. Took place 16th century to about 1820. • Four field crop rotation--wheat, turnips, barley, clover or alfalfa (turnips and hay crops make it possible to keep more livestock) • New scientific approaches to farming (one of the pioneer scientific investigators of agriculture was an Englishman named Jethro Tull) • Average agricultural surplus per worker doubled from about 25% to about 50% • Workers no longer needed in agriculture were available for industrial jobs (details on this argument) What is Industrial Revolution and why it started in Britain? • Increasing population--but it didn’t really start increasing until the industrial revolution began • The scientific revolution--but it happened 100 years earlier • England was a Protestant country and the protestant work ethic benefited the economy (this idea was put forth by a sociologist named Max Weber in a book titled The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism • Many scientists and inventors were members of religious minorities • Most professions were closed to them because in England you had to belong to the Church of England in order to be a lawyer or hold a government job, other kinds of protestants, called dissenters, were not allowed to hold such positions or even to go to the best universities • In England the dissenters also became the leaders of the industrial revolution • France was Catholic--for a while it tolerated a protestant minority called the Huguenots, but then they were told they would have to convert or leave the country because the king feared they were disloyal • But Hobsbawm points out that other Protestant countries did not industrialize rapidly • a domestic market with manufacturing already established • expansion of trade, mercantile economic policy Classical Political Economy • Adam Smith (1723-1790) • A Scottish professor of moral philosophy, was fascinated by the market’s potential for promoting both individual freedom and material prosperity. • The Wealth of Nations (1776) presented the case for free markets and formed the basis for classical political economy. • This school of thought dates roughly from 1776 to the midnineteenth century and its proponents include, in addition to Smith, Thomas Malthus (1766-1834), David Ricardo (17721823), Nassau Senior (1790-1864), and Jean Baptiste Say (1767-1832). • Classical political economy is linked with the Enlightenment, demonstrating that when the shackles of religious and political restrictions are removed, individuals will prosper and society will remain orderly. Classical Political Economy • Optimism and pessimism of Classical political economists in their visions of a market economy • The optimism centers around the anticipation that the market will generate both increasing wealth and individual freedom without the need for supervision by church or state. • Malthus --population theory • Ricardo --stationary state Classical Political Economy • With population growing rapidly and the available supply of land relatively fixed, they predicted an inevitable future of subsistence living for the vast majority of the population. • Landlords would prosper as they received ever-larger rents due to the increasing demand for land on which to grow food, but capitalists’ profits would dwindle as they were forced to pay higher wages so workers could afford to buy increasingly expensive food. • Eventually profits would be insufficient to provide capitalists with either the incentive or the means to expand production, and the entire economy would settle into a gloomy “stationary state”. The Radical Extension • The classical political economists were failing to carry out the mission of the • • • • • • • Enlightenment. Although the power of the state had been challenged and restrained, the power of private property had actually increased due to the elimination of most government restraints. Central to the Radical call for a reconstruction of society was a strong commitment to egalitarianism. Radicals condemned private property for breeding selfish interests that conflict with the common good of society. In a private property system, individuals have opposing interests and social cohesion disintegrates as the owners of property oppress those with little or no property. The threat of starvation coerces propertyless people to work for subsistence wages. Radicals also condemned private property for alienating individuals from any sense of community or control over their work. They believed that people can join together to collectively direct their social existence. Radicals envisioned a classless society in which free individuals could live in harmony with each other in their work, their communities, and their government. Such a society would be egalitarian and communal. The Radical Extension • Examples of early Radical thinkers include William Godwin (1756-1836) in England, Thomas Paine (1737-1809) in America, and the Marquis de Condorcet (1743-1794) in France. • These writers were opposed not so much to the principle of private property as to the excessive concentration of ownership that restricted the opportunities and freedom of the majority of the population. • In the early 1800s, thinkers such as Robert Owen (1771-1858) of England and Charles Fourier (1772-1837) and Henri de Saint-Simon (1760-1825) of France popularized the idea of eliminating private property. • “Utopian socialists” formulated detailed plans for small communities based on shared ownership of property The Radical Extension • Nineteenth century, industrialization, modernization, declining power of tradition, urbanization • Karl Marx (1818-1883), a German philosopher and political economist • • • • who constructed an impressive theoretical analysis of capitalism by weaving together classical political economy, the ideas of the German philosopher G. W. F. Hegel (1770-1831), and the communal vision of the utopian socialists. According to Marx capitalism would eventually crumble and be replaced by a society in which the means of production were communally owned and operated. This new society, Marx claimed, was incubating within capitalism and its birth would coincide with the death of the parent. Unlike the utopian socialists who sought to turn their backs on capitalist society, Marx portrayed capitalism as the essential precondition for a new and better organization of society. In capitalist factories, workers were acquiring the technical knowledge, cooperative skills, and sense of solidarity that would enable them to revolt and establish a communal society. The Radical Extension • The historical evolution of Radical thought (Marx and his influence) • When a proletarian revolution failed to appear by the early twentieth century, Russian theorists V. I. Lenin (1870-1924) and Leon Trotsky (1879-1940) introduced into Marxism the notion of a “vanguard party” of intellectuals who would lead the workers in the struggle for socialism. This strand of Marxism served as the theoretical basis for the Soviet Union. • In Western Europe and the United States, a different revision of Marx’s ideas was formulated by theorists such as Edward Bernstein (1850-1932) in Germany, and Eugene Debs (1855-1926) and Norman Thomas (1884-1968) in the United States. Acknowledging the rising standard of living enjoyed by workers in capitalist societies, these “social democrats” rejected the Marxian concept of proletarian revolution. Instead, they defended socialism as a more just and efficient economic system whose obvious appeal to the working class would permit an evolutionary transition from capitalism to socialism through the democratic political process. The task of the revisionists was not to foment revolution, but to establish a working-class political party and to educate all citizens about the attractions of socialism. The Radical Extension • The historical evolution of Radical thought (Marx and his influence) • Thorstein Veblen (1857-1929) • Institutional economics --critique of Marx --critique of Classical political economy --coined the term neoclassical economics --increasing the role of government in coordinating economic activity. • Veblen rejected much of Marxism as being unscientific and metaphysical, but he remained a trenchant critic of capitalism. • His ideas became influential in the Progressive political movement in the United States that sought to reform capitalism by enlarging the role of government in coordinating economic activity. The Conservative Response • The attack on repressive social institutions broadened the • • • • • scope for individual initiative and development, resulting in the industrialization and urbanization of western Europe. However, disintegration of the traditional social order created both economic and emotional insecurity for many people. Feudalism had been based on stable, hierarchical social relations, with individual identity derived from one’s role within a web of mutual expectations and duties. In contrast, the newly emerging industrial society wrenched people out of their accustomed roles. Small farmers lost their lands Factories took artisans’ jobs --guilds disappeared Even aristocrats suffered declining power and status as capital replaced land as the primary source of wealth. The Conservative Response • People formerly enmeshed in extended families, neighborhoods, churches, • • • • • • • • and communities now faced the impersonal forces of the market as isolated entities. The French Revolution of 1789 magnified concerns about a “dark side” of the Enlightenment. The ideals: “liberty, equality, fraternity” To halt the corrosive impact of the Enlightenment, a renewed defense of traditional society was needed. Edmund Burke (1729-1797), an Irish member of the British parliament, was among the first to develop a Conservative critique of the Enlightenment. Burke claimed that the Enlightenment effort to fundamentally restructure society was destroying the authority and emotional attachments that unite individuals into communities. Human reason was not a reliable guide for redesigning society The exercise of reason should be confined to efforts by individuals to improve their private lives. A stable social order (similar to the feudal system) must be grounded in traditional institutions such as the church and the patriarchal family. The Conservative Response • From the Conservative perspective, the degeneration of the French Revolution into violent anarchy was attributable to individualism and the pursuit of self-interest. • The Revolution foreshadowed an impending collapse of civilization that could be averted only by strengthening traditional values and institutions. • Romanticism --German reaction to the Enlightenment: Having been subjected to military conquest by France and the threat of economic domination by British industry, many Germans expressed disdain toward the cultures of their western neighbors. They wanted to avoid disintegration of their own culture. Writers such as Johann Fichte (1762-1814), August von Schlegel (1767-1845), Friedrich von Schelling (1775-1854), and Johann Herder (1744-1803) expressed their opposition to the effects of modernization on Germanic culture. The Conservative Response • The German romantics defended the unpredictability and irrationality of humans, the importance of traditional culture in maintaining a cohesive society, and a view of reality that includes spiritual and even mystical elements. They believed that personal fulfillment could be achieved only within the context of a stable culture based on widely shared values. • Even England, the most industrialized country in the world, experienced a flourishing romantic movement. Partly inspired by their German counterparts, British writers such as Samuel Taylor Coleridge (1772-1834), William Wordsworth (1770-1850), and William Blake (1757-1827) expressed the common theme that society had been damaged by modernization and industrialization. The Conservative Response • Nationalism: The idea that a group of people sharing a common language, culture, and heritage could collectively determine their future lay at the root of the French Revolution. • However, the alliance between nationalism and liberalism was short-lived. Whereas liberalism stresses the rights of autonomous individuals, nationalism demands submersion of personal identity in the national group. • By the mid-nineteenth century, Conservatives in Europe had gained the upper hand in their battle against the forces unleashed by the Enlightenment. • Later in the nineteenth century, Bismarck in Germany and Disraeli in England sought to gain popular support for Conservative governments by establishing rudimentary welfare programs. Government would replace the aristocracy in dispensing charity. The Conservative Response • The emphasis on cultural purity led Conservative nationalists to oppose free trade. Any nation opening its borders to the free flow of resources, products, and ideas will gradually lose its unique identity. • Only government can effectively oppose the cosmopolitan influences of the international market economy. A strong government enables a nation to be self-determining, free from constraints imposed by other nations and by the forces of the market. • Nationalists also find war and imperialism to be useful in diverting public attention away from internal problems and toward the glory and prestige of the nation. Neoclassical Economics • The rise of Radicalism and Conservatism established • • • • alternatives to classical political economy. Reactions to radicalism and conservatism Radicalism aroused fears of the confiscation of private property. Conservatism was seen as a threat to democracy and modernization. The combination of an increasingly powerful working class and social problems accompanying industrialization created new demands for government intervention to improve education, old-age security, public health, and occupational safety. Neoclassical Economics • In the face of these pressures, the policy of laissez-faire became increasingly unpopular. • Marginalist revolution: Carl Menger (1840-1921) of Austria, W. Stanley Jevons (1835-1882) of England, and Leon Walras (1834-1910) of France • Changed the focus of political economy from the classical concern with distribution and growth to a “neoclassical” orientation that dealt solely with the behavior of individual consumers and firms operating in competitive markets. • Neoclassical economists sought to construct a theory that matched the scientific rigor of physics. To achieve this goal, they applied mathematics as an analytical method to explain the choices of individual consumers and producers. Neoclassical Economics • Disagreement among economists in Austria and England gave rise to two separate traditions: Austrian economics and Cambridge economics. • Austrian economists were undoubtedly influenced by the political climate in their country during the late nineteenth century. As the Hapsburg empire crumbled, the working class grew increasingly receptive to socialist ideas. In this environment, a group of academic economists in Vienna, including Carl Menger, Friedrich von Wieser (1851-1926), and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851-1914) sought to demonstrate the appeal of a free-market economy with virtually no government intervention. • In addition to defending the virtues of capitalism, Austrian economists have been harsh critics of Marxism and socialism. Neoclassical Economics • Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) claimed that without the forces of supply and demand operating in a free market, prices could not accurately reflect consumer preferences or the relative scarcity of different resources. • Socialist planners, he argued, could not possibly gather enough information about resource availability and consumer preferences to permit calculation of appropriate prices for all products and resources. As a result, shortages and surpluses for different commodities would inevitably plague a socialist economy and inefficiency would be rampant. • Only capitalism provides incentive for gathering the information required for efficient choices by allowing individuals to reap the rewards of their own foresight, initiative, and innovation. Neoclassical Economics • In contrast to Austrian economists, Stanley Jevons and subsequent economists at Cambridge University recognized a more positive role for government. • Although committed to preserving the freedom of individual choice, their analysis of market failures provided rationales for government intervention to improve the workings of the market. • The most prominent of the early Cambridge economists, Alfred Marshall (1842-1924), demonstrated that economic efficiency could be enhanced by taxing those industries in which average costs rose as output expanded and using the revenue to subsidize those industries, such as utilities and transportation, in which average costs fell as they served more customers. Neoclassical Economics • Another Cambridge economist, Arthur C. Pigou (1877- 1959), developed the analysis of externalities in which the market fails to allocate resources efficiently because the actions of one person or firm create costs or benefits that are not reflected in market prices. • Pigou recommended taxation of those actions creating external costs and subsidies for actions creating external benefits. Since externalities pervade society, the scope for government intervention created by this market failure is potentially quite large. Neoclassical Economics • In 1933, Cambridge economist Joan Robinson (1903- 1982) showed that the absence of perfect competition will cause an inefficient allocation of resources and exploitation of workers. • She suggested that government could intervene either to promote competition or to directly respond to the problems caused by lack of competition. • Three years later, the most significant contribution of Cambridge economics occurred with John Maynard Keynes’s (1883-1946) powerful claim that laissez-faire capitalism is inherently prone to depression and unemployment. To remedy this problem, he proposed active government policies to stimulate the market. Modern Political Economy • Within the field of political economy, four broad perspectives currently contend for prominence: Classical Liberalism, Radicalism, Conservatism, and Modern Liberalism. • The persistence of these dramatically different viewpoints attests to an irreducible ideological element in political economy. • Scientific methods cannot resolve the disputes among alternative perspectives because their differences are ultimately based on commitments to conflicting values. • To understand these divisions within political economy, we need to briefly review the historical evolution of ideological labels. Modern Political Economy • The ideas associated with the Enlightenment have traditionally been called “liberal”. • Liberalism stands for individual freedom and rights against the arbitrary exercise of power by church, state, and other persons. • In the French National Assembly of 1789, the defenders of aristocratic privilege and hierarchy stood on the right side of the chamber, while the proponents of greater equality and individual freedom stood on the left. As a result, proponents of equality have since been called “leftists”, while those who defend hierarchy are called “rightists”. Modern Political Economy • Rightists claim that hierarchical social relations are essential to a good society. Individuals need distinctions of status to differentiate themselves from others. • A society lacking sufficient hierarchy will fail to provide incentives for citizens to excel, resulting in a stifling mediocrity and dragging the entire society into economic stagnation, boredom, and apathy. • Rightists also defend hierarchy as essential to organize the complex social processes needed to maintain prosperity and order. • Just as armies rely on hierarchical chains of command to wage war, other institutions such as corporations, schools, and families also must be hierarchically structured to achieve their objectives. Modern Political Economy • Leftists claim that human development flourishes when individuals engage in cooperative, mutually respectful relations that can thrive only when excessive differences in status, power, and wealth are eliminated. • According to leftists, a society without substantial equality will distort the development of not only deprived persons, but also those whose privileges undermine their motivation and sense of social responsibility. • This suppression of human development, together with the resentment and conflict engendered by sharp class distinctions, will ultimately reduce the efficiency of the economy. Modern Political Economy • The right/left dichotomy is often treated as synonymous with the conservative/liberal dichotomy. Although this usage of ideological labels may have been appropriate for analyzing political debate in the late eighteenth century, modern discourse has become more complex. • In addition to the dispute over hierarchy and equality, both rightists and leftists have developed internal splits over another question: should the private interests of individuals take precedence over the interests of society? • Individualists defend the priority of individual interests, while communitarians defend the priority of society's interests. Modern Political Economy • Individualists claim that a community has no interests other than the aggregation of the individual interests within it. • The good community is one that allows individuals to freely pursue their private interests. • In contrast, communitarians view human development as a function of the quality of the social environment and therefore expect the community to provide a supportive and nurturing environment. • By themselves, individuals are rather helpless in the face of social forces over which they have no control, but the community as a whole can consciously engage in actions to facilitate the development of individual interests and shape individual character. Modern Political Economy • Individualists and communitarians have sought to discredit • • • • each other through caricature. Communitarians are portrayed as supporting “anthill” or “beehive” societies in which members simply serve their assigned role with no room for individual creativity or expression. Individualists, on the other hand, are accused of advocating an amoral society in which selfish, isolated persons pursue their narrow interests, constrained only by laws and the threat of punishment. Yet communitarians are vigorous defenders of individual dignity, claiming that a nurturing community enables individuals to achieve their full potential. Conversely, individualists value healthy communities but argue that communities are most peaceful and prosperous when individuals are permitted to freely pursue their interests. Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy • The debate between individualists and communitarians has occurred on both the right and left sides of the political spectrum, resulting in four major perspectives within political economy. • In the top-right quadrant, the Classical Liberal perspective is associated with both hierarchy and individualism. • Although the earliest forms of liberal thought were highly egalitarian, by the beginning of the nineteenth century, many liberals concluded that the pursuit of individual freedom results in hierarchy and that hierarchy is essential for economic prosperity. • Classical Liberalism was clearly articulated in the early nineteenth century by classical political economists and was later reinvigorated by neoclassical economists, particularly those of the Austrian school. Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy • In the bottom-right quadrant, the Conservative perspective defends both hierarchy and community. • Conservatives from Burke onward have stressed the importance of a harmonious community in molding virtuous persons, but they also view hierarchy as essential to provide leadership by those with superior abilities. • A hierarchical community not only establishes the authority and traditions essential for inspiring loyalty and allegiance among citizens, but it also provides the social context within which individuals can successfully find meaning and purpose in their lives. Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy • The bottom-left quadrant shows the Radical perspective combining commitments to both equality and community. • Radicals uphold the original egalitarian impulse associated with early liberalism but view this goal as achievable only when the entire community is empowered to collectively establish institutions and allocate resources. • Radicals believe that when all citizens participate in constructing society, both personal development and economic prosperity will advance. Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy • The top-left quadrant illustrates the Modern Liberal perspective’s simultaneous commitments to equality and individualism. • Like Classical Liberals, Modern Liberals view individual autonomy as essential to guaranteeing both human dignity and a thriving economy; however, they also defend substantial equality as necessary for all persons to develop their capacities fully. • Although Modern Liberals recognize potential conflicts between the values of individualism and equality, they remain confident that the two values can reinforce each other when the powers of government and the market are appropriately balanced. Value Commitments of Perspectives in Political Economy • As John Maynard Keynes observed: • “The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, the world is ruled by little else”.