Investment Course - 2005 Day One: Global Asset Allocation and Portfolio Formation 1-0 Two Important Concepts Involving Expected Investment Returns 1. Investors perform two functions for capital markets: - Commit Financial Capital - Assume Risk so, E(R) = (Risk-Free Rate) + (Risk Premium) 2. The expected return (i.e., E(R)) of an investment has a number of alternative names: e.g., discount rate, cost of capital, cost of equity, yield to maturity. It can also be expressed as: k = (Nominal RF) + (Risk Premium) = [(Real RF) + E(Inflation)] + (Risk Premium) where: Risk Premium = f(business risk, liquidity risk, political risk, financial risk) 1-1 Historical Real Returns, 1954-2003: The Global Experience Historical Real Returns, 1954-2003 9% 8% Annually Compounded Real Return, % 7% 6% 5% Equities Bonds 4% 3% 2% 1% Chile: Returns 1/54 – 6/03 Chile*: Returns 1/54 – 12/71; 1/76 – 6/03 Source: Global Financial Data d a rla n tze Sw i ay Af ric So uth No rw ala nd d Ze Ire lan w Ne ar k ile tria nm De Au s Ch ds A rla n US the Ne * Ch ile Ja pa n Au str ali a Ge rm an y UK um da Be lg i na in ly ce Ca Fr an Sp a Ita Sw ed en 0% 1-2 d rla n d ca ay Af ri tze th rw No ala n d ar k Ire lan Ze Sw i So u w Ne nm a ile tr i Au s A * ds Ch er lan US Ch ile y lia rm an De th Ne Ge an UK ium tr a Au s ce in ly n da Ja p Be lg na Ca Fr an Sp a Ita Sw ed e Annually Compounded Real Return, % Global Historical Volatility Measures, 1954-2003 Historical Risk, 1954-2003 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% Equities Bonds 15% 10% 5% 0% 1-3 rla n d ca ay Af ri tze th rw d d ala n No a ar k Ire lan Ze Sw i So u w Ne nm ile tr i Au s A ds Ch er lan De th US * y ile Ch ma n tr a lia Au s an UK Ja p Ge r Ne da ce in ly n um Be lgi na Ca Fr an Sp a Ita Sw ed e Annually Compounded Real Return, % Global Historical Risk Premia, 1954-2003 Risk Premia of Stocks and Bonds to Cash, 1954-2003 18% 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% Equities-Cash Bonds-Cash 6% 4% 2% 0% -2% 1-4 Historical Returns and Risk for Various U.S. Asset Classes 1-5 Historical Global Stock Market Volatility 1-6 More on Historical Asset Class Returns: U.S. Experience Stocks: Bonds: T-Bills: Inflation: 1926-2004: Avg. Return Std. Deviation 12.39% 20.31% 6.19% 8.56% 3.76% 3.14% 3.13% 4.32% 1980-2004: Avg. Return Std. Deviation 14.73 16.33 11.05 11.51 6.09 3.26 3.75 2.43 1995-2004: Avg. Return Std. Deviation 14.00 21.09 9.45 9.32 3.92 1.90 2.49 0.81 2000-2004: Avg. Return Std. Deviation -0.70 20.32 9.92 5.04 2.72 2.10 2.60 0.97 Source: Ibbotson Associates 1-7 Historical Risk Premia vs. T-bills: U.S. Experience Stocks: Bonds: Stock - Bond Difference: 1926-2004: 8.63% 2.43% 6.20% 1980-2004: 8.64 4.96 3.68 1995-2004: 10.08 5.53 4.55 2000-2004: -3.42 7.20 -10.62 1-8 Performance of U.S.-Oriented Investment Strategies: 1975-2004 Growth of $1 Avg. Ann. Ret. Std. Dev. Sharpe Ratio 100% Stock $47.52 14.90% 16.13% 0.540 100% Bond $16.06 10.23 11.26 0.359 100% Cash $6.19 6.19 3.09 nm “60-30-10” Mix $30.70 12.63 11.12 0.579 1-9 Portfolio Management Strategy: Broad View Passive Management Attempt to generate “normal” returns over time commensurate with investor risk tolerance Typically achieved through diversified asset class selection and asset-specific portfolio formation Active Management Attempt to generate above-normal returns over time relative to acceptable risk level Typically achieved either through periodic asset class or securityspecific portfolio adjustments 1 - 10 Two Ways to Increase Returns (i.e., “Add Alpha”): Tactical Allocation Decisions - Global Market Timing - Asset Class Timing - Style/Sector Timing Security Selection Decisions - Stock or Bond Picking 1 - 11 Allure of Tactical Market Timing Suppose that on January 1st each year from 1975-2004, you put 100% of your money in what turned out to be the best asset class (stocks, bonds, or cash) at the end of the year. This is equivalent to owning a perfect lookback option that entitles you to receive the return for the best performing asset class each year. What difference would that type of tactical portfolio rebalancing make to your investment performance? 1 - 12 Allure of Tactical Market Timing (cont.) Growth of $1 Avg. Ann. Ret. Std. Dev. Sharpe Ratio 100% Stock $47.52 14.90% 16.13% 0.540 100% Bond $16.06 10.23 11.26 0.359 100% Cash $6.19 6.19 3.09 nm “60-30-10” Mix $30.70 12.63 11.12 0.579 “Perfect Foresight” $237.68 20.48 10.92 1.309 1 - 13 Danger of “Missing the Boat” (i.e., Not Being Invested): S&P 500 Annualized Return: 1980-1989 S&P 500 Annualized Return: 1990-1999 12.6% 15.3% Less: 10 Best Days 7.7 11.1 Less: 20 Best Days 4.7 8.1 Less: 30 Best Days 2.1 5.6 Less: 40 Best Days -0.3 3.4 Less: 10 Worst Days 21.0 20.1 Less: 20 Worst Days 24.7 23.4 Less: 30 Worst Days 27.5 26.4 Less: 40 Worst Days 30.5 28.9 Investment Period Entire Decade (2,528 Days) 1 - 14 The Asset Allocation Decision A basic decision that every investor must make is how to distribute his or her investable funds amongst the various asset classes available in the marketplace: Stocks (e.g., Domestic, Global, Large Cap, Small Cap, Value, Growth) Fixed-Income (e.g., Government, Investment Grade, High Yield) Cash Equivalents (e.g., T-bills, CDs, Commercial Paper) Alternative Assets (e.g., Private Equity, Hedge Funds) Real Estate (e.g., Residential, Commercial) Collectibles (e.g., Art, Antiques) The Strategic (or Benchmark) allocation is the proportion of wealth the investor decides to place in each of these asset classes. It is sometimes also referred to as the investor’s long-term normal allocation because it is presumed to be the “baseline” allocation that will remain in place until the investor’s life circumstances change appreciably (e.g., retirement) 1 - 15 The Importance of the Asset Allocation Decision In an influential article published in Financial Analysts Journal in July/August 1986, Gary Brinson, Randolph Hood, and Gilbert Beebower examined the issue of how important the initial strategic allocation decision was to an investor They looked at quarterly return data for 91 pension funds over a ten-year period and decomposed the average returns as follows: Actual Overall Return (IV) Return due to Strategic Allocation (I) Return due to Strategic Allocation and Market Timing (II) Return due to Strategic Allocation and Security Selection (III) 1 - 16 The Importance of the Asset Allocation Decision (cont.) Graphically: In terms of return performance, they found that: 1 - 17 The Importance of the Asset Allocation Decision (cont.) In terms of return variation: Ibbotson and Kaplan support this conclusion, but argue that the importance of the strategic allocation decision does depend on how you look at return variation (i.e., 40%, 90%, or 100%). 1 - 18 Examples of Strategic Asset Allocations Public Endowments: 1 - 19 Examples of Strategic Asset Allocations (cont.) Public Retirement Fund: 1 - 20 Examples of Strategic Asset Allocations (cont.) 1 - 21 Asset Allocation and Building an Investment Portfolio I. Global Market Analysis - Asset Class Allocation - Country Allocation Within Asset Classes II. Industry/Sector Analysis - Sector Analysis Within Asset Classes III. Security Analysis - Security Analysis Within Asset Classes and Sectors 1 - 22 Asset Allocation Strategies Strategic Asset Allocation: The investor’s “baseline” asset allocation, taking into account his or her return requirements, risk tolerance, and investment constraints. Tactical Asset Allocation: Adjustments to the investor’s strategic allocation caused by perceived relative mis-valuations amongst the available asset classes. Ordinarily, tactical strategies overweight the undervalued asset class. Also known as market timing strategies. Insured Asset Allocation: Adjustments to the investor’s strategic allocation caused by perceived changes in the investor’s risk tolerance. Usually, the asset class that experiences the largest relative decline is underweighted. Portfolio insurance is a wellknown application of this approach. 1 - 23 Sharpe’s Integrated Asset Allocation Model C1 Capital Market Conditions I1 Investor Assets, Liabilities and Net Worth C2 Prediction Procedure I2 Investor's Risk Tolerance Function C3 Expected Returns, Risk and Correlations I3 Investor's Risk Tolerance M1 Optimizer M2 Investor's Asset Mix M3 Returns 1 - 24 Sharpe’s Integrated Asset Allocation Model (cont.) Notice that the feedback loops after the performance assessment box (M3) make the portfolio management process dynamic in nature. The strategic asset allocation process can be viewed as going through the model once and then removing boxes (C2) and (I2), thus removing any temporary adjustments to the baseline allocation. Tactical asset allocation effectively removes box (I2), but allows for allocation adjustments due to perceived changes in capital market conditions (C2). Insured asset allocation effectively removes box (C2), but allows for allocation adjustments due to perceived changes in investor risk tolerance conditions (I2). 1 - 25 Measuring Gains from Tactical Asset Allocation Example: Consider the following return and allocation characteristics for a portfolio consisting of stocks and bonds only. Allocation: Strategic Actual Stock 60% 50 Returns: Benchmark Actual 10% 9 Bond 40% 50 7% 8 The returns to active management (i.e., tactical and security selection) are: Policy Performance: Actual Performance: (.6)(.10) + (.4)(.07) (.5)(.09) + (.5)(.08) Active Return = = 8.80% = 8.50% - 30 bp 1 - 26 Measuring Gains from Tactical Asset Allocation (cont.) Also: (Policy & Timing): (.5)(.10) + (.5)(.07) = 8.50% (Policy & Selection): (.6)(.09) + (.4)(.08) = 8.60% so: 8.50 – 8.80 = -0.30% Selection Effect: 8.60 – 8.80 = -0.20% Other: 8.50 – 8.60 – 8.50 + 8.80 = +0.20% Timing Effect: Total Active = -0.30% 1 - 27 Example of Tactical Asset Allocation: Fidelity Investments 1 - 28 Example of Tactical Asset Allocation: Texas TRS 1 - 29 Example of Tactical Asset Allocation: Texas TRS 1 - 30 Overview of Equity Style Investing The top-down approach to portfolio formation involves prudent decision-making at three different levels: Asset class allocation decisions Sector allocation decisions within asset classes Security selection decisions within asset class sectors The equity style decision (e.g., large cap vs. small cap, value vs. growth) is essentially a sector allocation decision There is tremendous variation in the returns produced by the myriad style class-specific portfolios, so investors must pay attention to this aspect of the portfolio management process 1 - 31 Defining Equity Investment Style The investment style of an equity portfolio is typically defined by two dimensions or characteristics: - Market Capitalization (i.e., Shares Outstanding x Price) - Relative Market Valuation (i.e., “Value” versus “Growth”) 1 - 32 Equity Style Classification: Specific Terminology Market Capitalization - Large (> $10 billion) - Mid ($1 - $10 billion) - Small (< $1 billion) Relative Valuation - Value (Low P/E, Low P/B, High Dividend Yield, Low EPS Growth) - Blend - Growth (High P/E, High P/B, Low Dividend Yield, High EPS Growth) 1 - 33 Equity Style Grid Value Large Growth Large-Cap Value (LV) Large-Cap Blend (LB) Large-Cap Growth (LG) Mid-Cap Value (MV) Mid-Cap Blend (MB) Mid-Cap Growth (MG) Small-Cap Value (SV) Small-Cap Blend (SB) Small-Cap Growth (SG) Small 1 - 34 Style Indexes & Representative Stock Positions: January 2005 Value Growth - Russell 1000 Value - Russell 1000 - Russell 1000 Growth - ExxonMobil Citigroup - General Electric Pfizer - Microsoft Wal-Mart - Russell Mid Value - Russell Mid - Russell Mid Growth - Archer Daniels Midlan Norfolk Southern - Monsanto Kroger - Apple Computer Adobe Systems - Russell 2000 Value - Russell 2000 - Russell 2000 Growth - Goodyear Tire & Rubber Energen - First Bancorp Crown Holdings - Allegheny Technologies Aeropostale Large Small 1 - 35 Comparative Classification Ratios: January 2005 (Source: Morningstar) Value Large Growth Fwd P/E: 15.3 P/B: 2.1 Div Yld: 2.2% Fwd P/E: 17.8 P/B: 2.8 Div Yld: 1.6% Fwd P/E: 21.6 P/B: 3.7 Div Yld: 0.9% Fwd P/E: 16.1 P/B: 2.1 Div Yld: 1.8% Fwd P/E: 18.4 P/B: 2.5 Div Yld: 1.2% Fwd P/E: 22.9 P/B: 3.6 Div Yld: 0.4% Fwd P/E: 13.7 P/B: 1.7 Div Yld: 1.7% Fwd P/E: 13.1 P/B: 2.1 Div Yld: 1.1% Fwd P/E: 12.3 P/B: 3.0 Div Yld: 0.3% Small 1 - 36 Historical Equity Style Performance: 1991-2004 (Source: Frank Russell) Style Class Avg Ann Ret Std Deviation Sharpe Ratio LV 13.75% 13.36% 0.731 LB 12.67 14.44 0.602 LG 11.38 17.78 0.416 MV 16.01 13.42 0.896 MB 15.25 15.02 0.751 MG 14.03 21.76 0.462 SV 16.98 14.51 0.896 SB 14.58 18.40 0.576 SG 12.34 23.78 0.352 1 - 37 Equity Style Rotation: 1991-2004 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 SG SV SV LG LV LG LV LG MG SV SV MV SG MV 48.62% 26.52% 21.84% 3.12% 33.04% 21.72% 31.35% 35.84% 44.26% 21.54% 14.54% -8.56% 41.54% 21.93% MG MV SB LB LB LB MV LB SG MV SB SV SB SV 41.10% 20.07% 17.86% 0.85% 32.60% 20.95% 30.55% 26.53% 39.03% 19.20% 5.15% -9.81% 40.49% 21.04% SB SB LV SV LG LV LB MG LG MB MV LV SV MB 39.94% 18.02% 16.97% -1.11% 32.18% 20.19% 29.85% 20.53% 30.33% 9.78% 3.36% -14.84% 39.54% 19.07% SV MB MV SB MV SV SV LV SB LV MB MB MG SB 36.59% 15.57% 14.84% -1.31% 30.54% 19.95% 28.50% 16.80% 21.01% 8.32% -3.62% -15.82% 36.84% 17.93% MB LV MB LV MB MV LG MB LB SB SG SB MB LV 36.44% 13.28% 13.70% -1.53% 30.20% 19.00% 28.37% 12.35% 19.92% 0.52% -4.14% -20.21% 34.89% 15.60% LG SG SG MG MG MB MB MV MB MG LV LB MV MG 36.44% 9.04% 13.34% -1.59% 29.96% 18.13% 26.60% 7.04% 17.83% -4.73% -4.95% -22.26% 33.45% 15.14% MV LB MG MB SG MG MG SG LV LB LB MG LV SG 33.62% 8.94% 11.19% -1.60% 28.01% 17.21% 21.76% 6.79% 7.92% -6.66% -11.32% -29.08% 27.30% 14.74% LB MG LB MV SB SB SB SB MV SG MG LG LB LB 29.99% 8.89% 9.91% -1.69% 25.73% 16.41% 21.51% 1.14% 0.70% -17.29% -15.09% -30.16% 27.00% 11.12% LV LG LG SG SV SG SG SV SV LG LG SG LG LG 23.06% 5.19% 3.17% -1.72% 23.43% 12.78% 14.44% -4.35% -0.54% -22.07% -18.09% -32.39% 26.76% 8.96% 1 - 38 200412 200406 200312 200306 200212 200206 200112 -30.00 200106 40.00 200012 200006 199912 199906 199812 199806 199712 199706 199612 199606 199512 199506 199412 199406 199312 199306 199212 199206 199112 Annualized Return Difference (%) Relative Return Performance: Value vs. Growth 50.00 LV Outperforms 30.00 20.00 10.00 0.00 -10.00 -20.00 LG Outperforms -40.00 -50.00 1 - 39 1 - 40 200412 200406 200312 200306 200212 200206 200112 200106 200012 200006 199912 199906 -20.00 199812 20.00 199806 199712 199706 199612 199606 199512 199506 199412 199406 199312 199306 199212 199206 199112 Annualized Risk Difference (%) Relative Risk Performance: Value vs. Growth 30.00 LV Riskier 10.00 0.00 -10.00 LG Riskier -30.00 200406 200412 200312 200212 200306 200112 200206 200106 50.00 40.00 30.00 20.00 10.00 0.00 -10.00 -20.00 -30.00 -40.00 -50.00 200006 200012 199912 199812 199906 199806 199706 199712 199612 199512 199606 199506 199406 199412 199306 199312 199212 199112 199206 Annualized Return Difference (%) Relative Return Performance: Large Cap vs. Small Cap LB Outperforms SB Outperforms 1 - 41 200406 200412 200306 200312 200212 200112 200206 200012 200106 200006 -20.00 199906 199912 199806 199812 199712 199612 199706 199606 199506 199512 199406 199412 199312 199212 199306 199112 199206 Annualized Risk Difference (%) Relative Risk Performance: Large Cap vs. Small Cap 30.00 LB Riskier 20.00 10.00 0.00 -10.00 SB Riskier -30.00 1 - 42 Value vs. Growth: Global Evidence (Source: Chan and Lakonishok, Financial Analysts Journal, 2004) 1 - 43 Equity Style Investing: Instruments and Strategies Passive Style Alternatives - Index Mutual Funds - Exchange-Traded Funds (ETFs) Active Style Alternatives - Investor Portfolio Formation - Open-Ended Mutual Funds 1 - 44 Methods of Indexed Investing Open-End Index Mutual Funds: There is a long-standing and active market for mutual funds that hold broad collections of securities that mimic various sectors of the stock market. Examples include the Vanguard 500 Index Fund, which recreates the holdings and weightings of the Standard & Poor’s 500, and the various Fidelity Select Funds, which reproduce the profiles of different industry sectors. Exchange-Traded Funds (ETF): A more recent development in the world of indexed investment products has been the development of exchange-tradable index funds. Essentially, ETFs are depository receipts that give investors a pro-rata claim on the capital gains and cash flows of the securities held in deposit. 1 - 45 Index Fund Example: VFINX 1 - 46 Index Fund Example (cont.) 1 - 47 Top ETFs in the Large Blend Style Category Name Category Style Box YTD 1 mo Return % Return % Consumer Staples Select Sector SPDR (XLP) Large Blend 0.91 0.91 Industrial Select Sector SPDR (XLI) Large Value -4.06 iShares Dow Jones US Cons Goods (IYK) Large Blend iShares Dow Jones US Industrial (IYJ) Large Blend iShares Dow Jones US Total Market Ind (IYY) Large Blend iShares Morningstar Large Core Index (JKD) Large Blend iShares NYSE Composite Index (NYC) Large Blend iShares Russell 1000 Index (IWB) 3 mo Return % 1 yr Return % 3 yr Return % Trading Volume 7.18 9.53 -0.79 1,183,000 -4.06 4.98 11.68 5.81 452,700 -0.36 -0.36 10.52 10.83 8.48 61,500 -3.98 -3.98 5.06 10.06 4.85 101,300 -3.40 -3.40 5.11 6.01 3.70 22,100 -3.01 -3.01 5.54 --- --- 6,400 -3.29 -3.29 5.81 --- --- 600 Large Blend -2.99 -2.99 4.77 5.84 3.42 136,900 iShares Russell 3000 Index (IWV) Large Blend -3.56 -3.56 4.58 5.45 3.78 166,000 iShares S&P 1500 Index (ISI) Large Blend -3.57 -3.57 4.55 6.31 --- 33,400 iShares S&P 500 Index (IVV) Large Blend -3.11 -3.11 4.21 5.25 2.77 731,700 Rydex S&P Equal Weight (RSP) Large Blend -4.16 -4.16 5.71 9.22 --- 43,400 SPDRs (SPY) Large Blend -2.85 -2.85 4.52 5.57 2.76 60,817,300 streetTRACKS DJ Global Titans (DGT) Large Blend -2.67 -2.67 4.27 3.01 0.87 1,600 streetTRACKS Fortune 500 Index (FFF) Large Blend -3.12 -3.12 4.98 5.63 2.55 8,700 Vanguard Consumer Staples VIPERs (VDC) Large Blend 0.97 0.97 9.29 11.77 --- 58,600 Vanguard Large Cap VIPERs (VV) Large Blend -3.84 -3.84 4.66 5.66 --- 2,400 Vanguard Total Stock Market VIPERs (VTI) Large Blend -3.48 -3.48 4.87 6.12 4.46 85,700 1 - 48 ETF Example: SPY 1 - 49 ETF Example (cont.) 1 - 50 Growth of U.S. Equity Mutual Funds Morningstar Mutual Fund Style Category: Year LV LB LG MV MB MG SV SB SG Total 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 133 138 154 166 211 269 346 406 500 615 750 813 946 158 166 178 197 238 303 371 436 571 778 1036 1198 1407 117 119 124 137 174 228 293 351 421 651 808 1061 1245 60 60 65 67 69 87 102 126 167 212 259 269 301 46 48 53 54 62 69 95 101 121 140 209 268 349 79 78 78 82 106 150 183 221 288 415 559 670 784 25 28 31 38 47 62 79 96 120 193 230 259 270 29 30 30 37 52 71 97 123 147 201 228 299 384 42 44 49 59 77 112 152 206 262 383 472 570 672 689 711 762 837 1036 1351 1718 2066 2597 3588 4551 5407 6358 Source: Morningstar, Frank Russell 1 - 51 Mutual Fund Performance Characteristics: 1991-2003 Style Group Avg. Annual Fund Return (%) Avg. Fund Std. Dev. (%) Sharpe Ratio Large Value 11.81 13.03 0.587 Large Blend 11.43 13.98 0.520 Large Growth 12.44 17.57 0.471 Mid Value 13.85 13.09 0.740 Mid Blend 13.88 14.91 0.652 Mid Growth 14.57 21.35 0.488 Small Value 16.18 14.33 0.839 Small Blend 14.89 16.00 0.671 Small Growth 15.86 22.81 0.513 1 - 52 Mutual Fund Performance Characteristics: 1991-2003 (cont.) Style Group Avg. Fund Firm Size ($MM) Avg. Fund Expense Ratio (%) Avg. Fund Turnover (%) Median Tracking Error (%) Large Value 24,966 1.41 69.24 4.72 Large Blend 38,137 1.32 73.32 4.24 Large Growth 37,596 1.54 100.41 6.28 Mid Value 6,672 1.56 87.06 6.60 Mid Blend 7,848 1.48 90.58 6.78 Mid Growth 5,924 1.64 135.76 7.88 Small Value 1,710 1.56 67.50 7.12 Small Blend 2,596 1.66 88.21 8.32 Small Growth 1,119 1.70 120.02 8.07 1 - 53 Notion of Tracking Error When managing an active investment portfolio against a well-defined benchmark (such as the Standard & Poor’s 500 or the IPSA index), the goal of the manager should be to generate a return that exceeds that of the benchmark while minimizing the portfolio’s return volatility relative to the benchmark. Said differently, the manager should try to maximize alpha while minimizing tracking error. Tracking error can be defined as the extent to which return fluctuations in the managed portfolio are not correlated with return fluctuations in the benchmark. The concept is analogous to the statistic (1 – R2) in a regression context. A flexible and straightforward way of measuring tracking error can be developed as follows: Let: wi = investment weight of asset i in the managed portfolio Rit = return to asset i in period t Rbt = return to the benchmark portfolio in period t. With these definitions, we can define the period t return to managed portfolio as: R pt N w i 1 i Rit where: N = number of assets in the managed portfolio and: N w i 1 i 1 (i.e., the managed portfolio is fully invested). 1 - 54 Notion of Tracking Error (cont.) We can then specify the period t return differential between the managed portfolio and the benchmark as: t N w R i i 1 it - R bt R pt - R bt . Notice two things about the return differential . First, given the returns to the N assets in the managed portfolio and the benchmark, it is a function of the investment weights that the manager selects (i.e., = f({wi}/{Ri}, Rb)). Second, can be interpreted as the return to a hedge portfolio where wb = -1. With these definitions and a sample of T return observations, calculate the variance of as follows: T ( t - ) 2 2 t 1 (T - 1) . Then, the standard deviation of the return differential is: 2 = periodic tracking error, so that annualized tracking error (TE) can be calculated as: TE = P where P is the number of return periods in a year (e.g., P = 12 for monthly returns, P = 252 for daily returns). 1 - 55 Notion of Tracking Error (cont.) Generally speaking, portfolios can be separated into the following categories by the level of their annualized tracking errors: Passive (i.e., Indexed): TE < 1.0% (Note: TE < 0.5% is normal) Structured: 1.0% < TE < 3% Active: TE > 3% (Note: TE > 5% is normal for active managers) 1 - 56 “Large Blend” Active Manager: DGAGX 1 - 57 Tracking Errors for VFINX, SPY, DGAGX 1 - 58 Risk and Expected Return Within a Portfolio Portfolio Theory begins with the recognition that the total risk and expected return of a portfolio are simple extensions of a few basic statistical concepts. The important insight that emerges is that the risk characteristics of a portfolio become distinct from those of the portfolio’s underlying assets because of diversification. Consequently, investors can only expect compensation for risk that they cannot diversify away by holding a broad-based portfolio of securities (i.e., the systematic risk) Expected Return of a Portfolio: n E(R p ) = w i * E(R i ) i = 1 where wi is the percentage investment in the i-th asset Risk of a Portfolio: p2 [w1212 ... w 2n n2 ] [2w1w 21 2 1,2 ... 2w n-1w n n1 n n 1,n ] Total Risk = (Unsystematic Risk) + (Systematic Risk) 1 - 59 Example of Portfolio Diversification: Two-Asset Portfolio Consider the risk and return characteristics of two stock positions: E(R1) = 5% 1 = 8% E(R2) = 6% 2 = 10% 1,2 = 0.4 Risk and Return of a 50%-50% Portfolio: E(Rp) = (0.5)(5) + (0.5)(6) = 5.50% and: p = [(.25)(64) + (.25)(100) + 2(.5)(.5)(8)(10)(.4)]1/2 = 7.55% Note that the risk of the portfolio is lower than that of either of the individual securities 1 - 60 Another Two-Asset Class Example: Suppose that a portfolio is divided into two different subportfolios consisting of stocks and bonds, respectively. Further assume that the subportfolios have the following risk and expected return characteristics: E(Rstock) = 12.0% E(Rbond) = 5.1% stock = 21.2% bond = 8.3% = 0.18 Then, an overall portfolio consisting of a 60%-40% mix of stocks and bonds would have the following characteristics: E(Rp) = (0.6)(0.120) + (0.4)(0.051) = 0.0924 or 9.24% and p = [(0.6)2(0.212)2 + (0.4)2(0.083)2] + [2(0.6)(0.4)(0.212)(0.083)(0.18)] = 0.0188 or p = (0.0188)1/2 = 0.1371 or 13.71% For different asset mixes and different levels of correlation between stocks and bonds, the portfolio variance is given as: ( = 0.18) ( = 1) ( = -1) Portfolio wstock wbond E(Rp) p p p 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0.00 0.25 0.28 0.40 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.00 0.75 0.72 0.60 0.50 0.25 0.00 5.10% 6.83 7.04 7.86 8.55 10.28 12.00 8.30% 8.87 9.16 10.58 12.06 16.40 21.20 8.30% 11.53 11.93 13.46 14.75 17.98 21.20 8.30% 0.93 0.00 3.50 6.45 13.83 21.20 1 - 61 Example of a Three-Asset Portfolio: Suppose that a portfolio is divided into three different subportfolios consisting of stocks, bonds, and cash equivalents, respectively. Further assume that the subportfolios have the following risk and expected return characteristics: E(Rstock) = 12.0% E(Rbond) = 5.1% E(Rcash) = 3.6% stock = 21.2% bond = 8.3% cash = 3.3% stock,bond = 0.18 cash,stock = -0.07 cash,bond = 0.22 Then, an overall portfolio consisting of a 60%-30%-10% mix of stocks, bonds, and cash equivalents would have the following characteristics: E(Rp) = (0.6)(0.120) + (0.3)(0.051) + (0.1)(0.036) = 0.0909 or 9.09% and: p = [(0.6)2(0.212)2 + (0.3)2(0.083)2 + (0.1)2(0.033)2] + {[2(0.6)(0.3)(0.212)(0.083)(0.18)] + [2(0.6)(0.1)(0.212)(0.033)(-0.07)] + [2(0.3)(0.1)(0.083)(0.033)(0.22)]} = 0.01793 or p = (0.01793)1/2 = 0.1339 or 13.39% 1 - 62 Diversification and Portfolio Size: Graphical Interpretation Total Risk 0.40 0.20 Systematic Risk Portfolio Size 1 20 40 1 - 63 Advanced Portfolio Risk Calculations Total Portfolio Risk Suppose you have formed a portfolio consisting of N asset classes. Suppose also the portfolio weight in the j-th asset class is denoted as wj while jk represents the covariance between assets j and k (where jk equals the variance, j2, when j = k). With this notation, the return variance, p2, of the portfolio is given by: σ 2p N N w w j j 1 k 1 k σ jk (1) or, equivalently: σ 2 p N w j1 2 j σ 2 j N N w j1 k 1 j k j w k σ jk (2) The standard deviation of the portfolio is: σp N w 2j σ 2j j1 w j w k σ jk j1 k 1 j k N 1/ 2 N (3) 1 - 64 Advanced Portfolio Risk Calculations (cont.) Marginal Asset Risk In order to compute the contribution of asset k’s risk to the overall risk of the portfolio, we can take the derivative of equation (3) with respect to asset k’s weight in the portfolio: σ p w k 1N w 2j σ 2j 2 j1 w j w k σ jk j1 k 1 j k 1 / 2 N 2 w σ 2 2 w σ k k j jk j1 j k N w 2σ 2 j j j1 w j w k σ jk j1 k 1 j k 1 / 2 w σ 2 k k = = σ 2 -1/2 p N N w σ 2 k k N N w j σ jk j1 j k N w j σ jk j1 j k N which can be simplified to: σ p w k 1 N 1 N w j σ jk w j σ j σ k ρ jk σ p j1 σ p j1 (4) where j and k are the standard deviations of asset classes j and k, respectively, and jk is the correlation coefficient between them. 1 - 65 Advanced Portfolio Risk Calculations (cont.) Equation (4) shows that the marginal volatility of asset k in a portfolio is the weighted sum of the kth row (or, equivalently, the k-th column) of the return covariance matrix divided by the standard deviation of the portfolio. Notice that the magnitude of this marginal risk contribution is determined by three factors: (i) the volatility of the asset itself, (ii) the asset’s weight in the portfolio, and (iii) the asset’s covariance with all of the other portfolio holdings and their investment weights. A convenient property of marginal volatilities is that the weighted sum over all assets is, in fact, the overall volatility of the portfolio. By contrast, recall that the standard deviation of a portfolio is not simply a weighted average of the standard deviations of the underlying assets whenever the correlations between the asset classes are less that +1.0. However, by redefining the risk of asset k within the portfolio taking those correlations into account—which is what equation (4) does—it is possible to view overall portfolio risk as an additive statistic. To see this notice that: σ p N w k 1 k w k 1 N w k w j σ jk σ p j1 k 1 N 1 = σp N N w w j1 k 1 j k σ jk σ 2p σp σp (5) 1 - 66 Advanced Portfolio Risk Calculations (cont.) This feature provides a mechanism for the portfolio manager to “roll-up” marginal volatilities to a higher level (e.g., the sector or country level) without having to recompute the derivatives. In other words, assume that the marginal volatility of each of the N assets has been calculated. Assume also that we are interested in knowing the aggregate marginal volatility of a collection of M assets where k = 1 to M < N (i.e., the M assets comprise a subset of the total portfolio). The marginal volatility of this sub-portfolio is given by: σ p M σ p w M w k 1 k w k (6) M w k 1 k This additive property also allows the portfolio manager to interpret the weighted marginal volatilities directly as the asset’s contribution to overall portfolio risk or as the contribution to tracking error if asset class returns are defined in excess of the returns to a benchmark. That is: σ p Asset k’s Marginal Risk: Asset k’s Total Contribution to Risk: w k wk σ p w k (7) (8) Once again, equations (7) and (8) highlight two facts: (i) Asset k’s marginal volatility within the portfolio depends not only on its own inherent riskiness (i.e. k) but also how it interacts with every other asset held in the portfolio (i.e., jk), and (ii) Asset k’s total contribution to the risk of the overall portfolio also depends on how much the manager invests in that asset class (wk). 1 - 67 Example of Marginal Risk Contribution Calculations 1 - 68 Fidelity Investment’s PRISM Risk-Tracking System: Chilean Pension System – March 2004 PRISM (CR) / Return, Volatility and Tracking Error for 200401 Obs 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 AFP LLLL MMMM NNNN PPPP QQQQ RRRR SSSS SISTEMA AFP Id Assets Volatility 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 733 738 635 257 469 54 31 2918 0.081731 0.081423 0.080780 0.077193 0.079808 0.073797 0.061490 0.080525 Obs 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 AFP LLLL MMMM NNNN PPPP QQQQ RRRR SSSS SISTEMA Assets 733 738 635 257 469 54 31 2918 0.3646 0.3514 0.4187 0.4713 0.3791 0.8308 2.0927 0.0000 Mean Portfolio Return Tracking Error 0.003646 0.003514 0.004187 0.004713 0.003791 0.008308 0.020927 0.000000 PRISM (CY) / AFP Value at Risk for 200401 Tracking Error (%) March 17, 2004 0.23543 0.23476 0.22947 0.21804 0.22660 0.22981 0.20014 0.23089 Mean Excess Return 0.004531 0.003862 -0.001425 -0.012857 -0.004296 -0.001082 -0.030757 0.000000 March 17, 2004 50bp Shortfall Probability (%) 8.5130 7.7410 11.6213 14.4383 9.3576 27.3640 40.5582 . 200bp Shortfall Probability (%) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0011 0.0000 0.8034 16.9613 . 1 - 69 Chilean Sistema Risk Tracking Example (cont.) PRISM (CX) / Risk Diagnostics Sistema-Relative Tracking Error for 200401 Obs 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 AFP LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL LLLL Asset Class PRD_BCD PDBC_PRBC BCP RECOGN_BOND CERO PRC_BCU BCE PCD_PTF ZERO DEPOSITS_OFFNO DEPOSITS_OFFUF LHF BEF BSF CC2 CFI CORPORATE_BOND CTC_A ENDESA COPEC ENTEL CMPC SQM-B CERVEZAS COLBUN D&S ENERSIS Chile_SMALL_CAP US EUROPE UK JAPAN GLOBAL ASIA_EX_JAPAN LATIN_AMERICA EASTERN_EUROPE EMERGING_MARKETS G7_BOND HY EMB MM March 17, 2004 Active Weight (%) Worst Case Contribution (%) Contribution to Tracking Error (%) -0.2144 -1.1800 0.1830 -1.2731 -0.2823 -1.1605 0.0385 -0.0002 -0.0184 0.4018 3.7074 -0.9636 -0.0080 -0.0395 -0.2398 -0.3106 -0.1932 -0.3847 -0.0505 0.1789 -0.0672 0.2043 -0.1966 0.0069 0.0184 -0.4237 0.3731 0.6830 0.8959 0.0364 -0.0954 0.0710 0.8999 -2.1238 -0.5469 -0.1620 1.8244 0.1123 0.0364 0.2535 0.0094 ========== 0.0000 -0.0194 -0.0331 0.0111 -0.1965 -0.0026 -0.0822 0.0011 -0.0000 -0.0017 0.0041 0.1039 -0.0363 -0.0011 -0.0029 0.0000 -0.0212 -0.0084 -0.0826 -0.0095 0.0424 -0.0179 0.0436 -0.0356 0.0018 0.0032 -0.1334 0.1107 0.0677 0.1332 0.0063 -0.0158 0.0149 0.1219 -0.3475 -0.0898 -0.0299 0.2729 0.0062 0.0041 0.0304 0.0008 ============ -0.1870 0.0023 -0.0097 -0.0003 0.1040 0.0002 0.0193 0.0003 -0.0000 0.0002 0.0001 0.0304 0.0074 0.0002 0.0005 0.0000 0.0004 0.0006 0.0148 0.0001 0.0031 0.0015 0.0104 -0.0010 -0.0001 -0.0001 0.0127 0.0286 0.0039 0.0607 0.0022 -0.0064 0.0029 0.0518 -0.0165 -0.0272 -0.0061 0.0638 0.0008 0.0011 0.0069 0.0002 ============== 0.3640 1 Implied View (%) -1.0527 0.8206 -0.1709 -8.1706 -0.0617 -1.6626 0.8206 0.8206 -1.0363 0.0347 0.8206 -0.7657 -2.4299 -1.3547 0.0000 -0.1428 -0.3317 -3.8358 -0.2352 1.7448 -2.1698 5.1077 0.5129 -1.2372 -0.4791 -2.9882 7.6550 0.5649 6.7785 6.0088 6.7521 4.0322 5.7571 0.7754 4.9767 3.7790 3.4975 0.7247 3.0627 2.7101 2.5109 1 - 70 Chilean Sistema Risk Tracking Example (cont.) PRISM (CX) / Risk Diagnostics Sistema-Relative Tracking Error for 200401 Obs 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 AFP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP PPPP Asset Class PRD_BCD PDBC_PRBC BCP RECOGN_BOND CERO PRC_BCU BCE PCD_PTF ZERO DEPOSITS_OFFNO DEPOSITS_OFFUF LHF BEF BSF CC2 CFI CORPORATE_BOND CTC_A ENDESA COPEC ENTEL CMPC SQM-B CERVEZAS COLBUN D&S ENERSIS Chile_SMALL_CAP US EUROPE UK JAPAN GLOBAL ASIA_EX_JAPAN LATIN_AMERICA EASTERN_EUROPE EMERGING_MARKETS G7_BOND HY EMB MM March 17, 2004 Active Weight (%) 0.5674 -1.1800 -0.5650 -0.2379 -0.2119 0.8570 -0.0128 -0.0002 -0.0184 6.9872 -3.3930 1.2495 -0.0080 -0.0790 -0.2401 -1.2552 -0.6841 -0.4095 -0.1138 -0.0081 0.0744 -0.0372 0.0650 0.0145 0.1316 -0.4237 0.2388 0.8843 -0.1981 -0.2826 -0.0419 0.0953 0.1448 0.0479 -0.5673 -0.3052 -1.7698 -0.1264 0.3431 -0.0563 0.5247 ========== -0.0000 Worst Case Contribution (%) Contribution to Tracking Error (%) 0.0515 -0.0331 -0.0343 -0.0367 -0.0020 0.0607 -0.0004 -0.0000 -0.0017 0.0717 -0.0951 0.0471 -0.0011 -0.0057 0.0000 -0.0858 -0.0298 -0.0880 -0.0213 -0.0019 0.0198 -0.0079 0.0118 0.0038 0.0232 -0.1334 0.0708 0.0876 -0.0295 -0.0492 -0.0069 0.0200 0.0196 0.0078 -0.0931 -0.0563 -0.2647 -0.0070 0.0386 -0.0068 0.0460 ============ -0.5113 0.0224 0.0101 0.0010 0.0009 0.0001 0.0138 0.0001 0.0000 -0.0006 0.0131 0.0290 0.0084 -0.0002 -0.0010 0.0000 0.0207 -0.0005 0.0246 0.0045 0.0001 -0.0017 0.0007 -0.0013 0.0001 -0.0009 0.0434 -0.0028 -0.0165 0.0147 0.0297 0.0038 -0.0090 -0.0122 -0.0051 0.0635 0.0318 0.2148 0.0005 -0.0167 0.0023 -0.0150 ============== 0.4708 4 Implied View (%) 3.9475 -0.8560 -0.1737 -0.3819 -0.0523 1.6098 -0.8560 -0.8560 3.3578 0.1876 -0.856 0.6692 1.9925 1.2991 0.0000 -1.6488 0.0663 -6.0021 -3.9277 -0.8357 -2.2350 -2.0070 -2.0004 0.4622 -0.6567 -10.2519 -1.1930 -1.8696 -7.4319 -10.5277 -8.9775 -9.4234 -8.3883 -10.5855 -11.1915 -10.4358 -12.135 -0.3814 -4.8702 -4.1709 -2.863 1 - 71 Notion of Downside Risk Measures: As we have seen, the variance statistic is a symmetric measure of risk in that it treats a given deviation from the expected outcome the same regardless of whether that deviation is positive of negative. We know, however, that risk-averse investors have asymmetric profiles; they consider only the possibility of achieving outcomes that deliver less than was originally expected as being truly risky. Thus, using variance (or, equivalently, standard deviation) to portray investor risk attitudes may lead to incorrect portfolio analysis whenever the underlying return distribution is not symmetric. Asymmetric return distributions commonly occur when portfolios contain either explicit or implicit derivative positions (e.g., using a put option to provide portfolio insurance). Consequently, a more appropriate way of capturing statistically the subtleties of this dimension must look beyond the variance measure. 1 - 72 Notion of Downside Risk Measures (cont.): We will consider two alternative risk measures: (i) Semi-Variance, and (ii) Lower Partial Moments Semi-Variance: The semi-variance is calculated in the same manner as the variance statistic, but only the potential returns falling below the expected return are used: E(R) Semi - Variance = R p = - p p (R p - E(R)) 2 Lower Partial Moment: The lower partial moment is the sum of the weighted deviations of each potential outcome from a pre-specified threshold level (t), where each deviation is then raised to some exponential power (n). Like the semi-variance, lower partial moments are asymmetric risk measures in that they consider information for only a portion of the return distribution. The formula for this calculation is given by: t LPM n = R p = - p p (t - R p ) n 1 - 73 Example of Downside Risk Measures: To see how these alternative risk statistics compare to the variance consider the following probability distributions for two investment portfolios: Potential Return -15% -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Prob. of Return for Portfolio #1 Prob. of Return for Portfolio #2 5% 8 12 16 18 16 12 8 5 0 0 0% 0 25 35 10 7 9 5 3 3 3 Notice that the expected return for both of these portfolios is 5%: E(R)1 = (.05)(-0.15) + (.08)(-0.10) + ...+ (.05)(0.25) = 0.05 and E(R)2 = (.25)(-0.05) + (.35)(0.00) + ...+ (.03)(0.35) = 0.05 1 - 74 Example of Downside Risk Measures (cont.): Clearly, however, these portfolios would be viewed differently by different investors. nuances are best captured by measures of return dispersion (i.e., risk). These 1. Variance As seen earlier, this is the traditional measure of risk, calculated the sum of the weighted squared differences of the potential returns from the expected outcome of a probability distribution. For these two portfolios the calculations are: (Var)1 = (.05)[-0.15 - 0.05]2 + (.08)[-0.10 - 0.05]2 + ... + (.05)[0.25 - 0.05]2 = 0.0108 and (Var)2 = (.25)[-0.05 - 0.05]2 + (.35)[0.00 - 0.05]2 + ... + (.03)[0.35 - 0.05]2 = 0.0114 Taking the square roots of these values leaves: SD1 = 10.39% and SD2 = 10.65% 1 - 75 Example of Downside Risk Measures (cont.): 2. Semi-Variance The semi-variance adjusts the variance by considering only those potential outcomes that fall below the expected returns. For our two portfolios we have: (SemiVar)1 = (.05)[-0.15 - 0.05]2 + (.08)[-0.10 - 0.05]2 + (.12)[-0.05 - 0.05]2 + (.16)[0.00 - 0.05]2 = 0.0054 and (SemiVar)2 = (.25)[-0.05 - 0.05]2 + (.35)[0.00 - 0.05]2 = 0.0034 Also, the semi-standard deviations can be derived as the square roots of these values: (SemiSD)1 = 7.35% and (SemiSD)2 = 5.81% Notice here that although Portfolio #2 has a higher standard deviation than Portfolio #1, it's semistandard deviation is smaller. 1 - 76 Example of Downside Risk Measures (cont.): 3. Lower Partial Moments For these two portfolios, we will consider two cases (n = 1 and n = 2), both having a threshold level of 0% (i.e., t = 0): (i) LPM1 (LPM1)1 = (.05)[0.00 - (-0.15)] + (.08)[0.00 - (-0.10)] + (.12)[0.00 - (-0.05)] = 0.0215 and (LPM1)2 = (.25)[0.00 - (-0.05)] = 0.0125 (ii) LPM2 (LPM2)1 = (.05)[0.00 - (-0.15)]2 + (.08)[0.00 - (-0.10)]2 + (.12)[0.00 - (-0.05)]2 = 0.0022 and (LPM2)2 = (.25)[0.00 - (-0.05)]2 = 0.0006 For comparative purposes, it is also useful to take the square root of the LPM2 values. These are: (SqRt LPM2)1 = 4.72% and (SqRt LPM2)1 = 2.50% Notice again that Portfolio #2 is seen as being less risky when the lower partial moment risk measures are used. 1 - 77 Overview of the Portfolio Optimization Process The preceding analysis demonstrates that it is possible for investors to reduce their risk exposure simply by holding in their portfolios a sufficiently large number of assets (or asset classes). This is the notion of naïve diversification, but as we have seen there is a limit to how much risk this process can remove. Efficient diversification is the process of selecting portfolio holdings so as to: (i) minimize portfolio risk while (ii) achieving expected return objectives and, possibly, satisfying other constraints (e.g., no short sales allowed). Thus, efficient diversification is ultimately a constrained optimization problem. We will return to this topic in the next session. Notice that simply minimizing portfolio risk without a specific return objective in mind (i.e., an unconstrained optimization problem) is seldom interesting to an investor. After all, in an efficient market, any riskless portfolio should just earn the risk-free rate, which the investor could obtain more cost-effectively with a T-bill purchase. 1 - 78 The Portfolio Optimization Process As established by Nobel laureate Harry Markowitz in the 1950s, the efficient diversification approach to establishing an optimal set of portfolio investment weights (i.e., {wi}) can be seen as the solution to the following non-linear, constrained optimization problem: Select {wi} so as to minimize: p2 [w 12 12 ... w 2n n2 ] [2w 1 w 2 1 2 1,2 ... 2w n-1w n n 1 n n 1,n ] subject to: (i) E(Rp) = R* (ii) S wi = 1 The first constraint is the investor’s return goal (i.e., R*). The second constraint simply states that the total investment across all 'n' asset classes must equal 100%. (Notice that this constraint allows any of the wi to be negative; that is, short selling is permissible.) Other constraints that are often added to this problem include: (i) All wi > 0 (i.e., no short selling), or (ii) All wi < P, where P is a fixed percentage 1 - 79 Example of Mean-Variance Optimization: (Three Asset Classes, Short Sales Allowed) 1 - 80 Example of Mean-Variance Optimization: (Three Asset Classes, No Short Sales) 1 - 81 Mean-Variance Efficient Frontier With and Without Short-Selling 1 - 82 Efficient Frontier Example: Five Asset Classes 1 - 83 Example of Mean-Variance Optimization: (Five Asset Classes, No Short Sales) 1 - 84 Efficient Frontier Example: 2003 Texas Teachers’ Retirement System 1 - 85 Efficient Frontier Example: Texas Teachers’ Retirement System (cont.) 1 - 86 Efficient Frontier Example: Texas Teachers’ Retirement System (cont.) 1 - 87 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (Source: Fidelity Investments) Risk Premium Chile Stock 7.19% Chile Bond 2.65% Chile Cash 0.00% Developed Stock 4.89% Developed Bond 1.66% US Stock 5.83% US Bond 1.41% Real Cash Return 0.60% 0.60% 0.60% 0.60% 0.60% 0.60% 0.60% Expected Real Return 7.79% 3.25% 0.60% 5.49% 1.66% 6.43% 2.01% Volatility 25.02% 6.75% 1.50% 12.57% 3.33% 14.75% 5.05% Base Case Assumptions: -Expected real returns based on 1954 – 2003 risk premiums -Real returns for developed market stocks and bonds are GDP-weighted excluding US (equally-weighted returns for stocks and bonds are 5.73% and 1.39%, respectively) - Chilean risk-premium volatility estimates exclude the period 1/72 – 12/75 1 - 88 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (cont.) Domestic Stocks Domestic Bonds Domestic Cash DM Stocks DM Bonds US Stocks US Bonds Chile Stock 100.00% Chile Bond 21.85% 100.00% Chile Developed Developed Cash Stock Bond US Stock US Bond 13.51% 35.28% -20.91% 38.78% -23.13% 31.04% 2.71% -0.98% -1.39% 2.37% 100.00% 1.79% 10.31% 6.27% 3.77% 100.00% 26.01% 71.23% 11.06% 100.00% 7.54% 73.19% 100.00% 16.56% 100.00% - Correlation matrix is based on real returns from the period 1/93 – 6/03 using Chilean inflation and based in Chilean pesos - Real returns for developed market stocks and bonds are GDP-weighted excluding US 1 - 89 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (cont.) Unconstrained Frontier: 1 - 90 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (cont.) Constraint Set: Chile Stock Chile Bond Chile Cash All Foreign Investments Min Total Equity Max Total Equity Fund A 60% 40% 40% Fund B 50% 40% 40% Fund C 30% 50% 50% Fund D 15% 70% 70% Fund E 0% 80% 80% 30% 40% 80% 30% 25% 60% 30% 15% 40% 30% 5% 20% 30% 0% 0% 1 - 91 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (cont.) Constrained Frontier for Fund A: Point on EF 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Chile Stock 10.0% 10.6% 11.3% 12.1% 13.2% 14.4% 15.7% 17.2% 18.7% 20.3% 22.1% 23.9% 25.8% 27.8% 29.9% 32.3% 34.8% 37.6% 40.9% 45.6% Chile Bond 20.0% 21.0% 22.4% 23.8% 24.9% 25.7% 26.3% 26.9% 27.2% 27.5% 27.7% 27.8% 27.8% 27.6% 27.2% 26.7% 25.9% 25.1% 24.2% 23.0% Chile Cash 40.0% 38.4% 36.3% 34.1% 32.1% 30.2% 28.3% 26.4% 24.5% 22.7% 20.9% 19.3% 17.8% 16.4% 15.3% 14.1% 12.9% 11.6% 10.3% 8.0% Developed Developed Expected Stock Bond US Stock US Bond Return Volatility 24.2% 0.0% 5.8% 0.0% 3.37 5.65 22.3% 0.2% 7.2% 0.3% 3.43 5.73 20.7% 0.5% 8.2% 0.6% 3.51 5.85 19.3% 0.7% 9.0% 0.9% 3.59 6.00 18.0% 0.9% 9.6% 1.3% 3.68 6.18 16.9% 1.1% 10.0% 1.7% 3.76 6.38 15.9% 1.4% 10.3% 2.0% 3.85 6.62 15.0% 1.6% 10.6% 2.3% 3.95 6.89 14.2% 1.9% 10.9% 2.6% 4.05 7.19 13.5% 2.1% 11.0% 2.8% 4.16 7.51 13.0% 2.3% 11.1% 3.0% 4.27 7.86 12.4% 2.4% 11.1% 3.2% 4.38 8.23 11.9% 2.3% 11.2% 3.3% 4.49 8.63 11.4% 2.3% 11.3% 3.2% 4.61 9.06 10.9% 2.1% 11.4% 3.2% 4.74 9.53 10.5% 2.0% 11.5% 3.1% 4.87 10.04 10.1% 1.8% 11.5% 2.9% 5.01 10.61 9.6% 1.7% 11.6% 2.8% 5.17 11.23 8.8% 1.4% 11.6% 2.7% 5.34 11.97 7.9% 1.2% 12.2% 2.2% 5.63 13.08 1 - 92 Efficient Frontier Example: Chilean Pension System (cont.) Asset Allocations of Various Funds Using Point 20 on Unconstrained Frontier: Unconstrained Fund A Fund B Fund C Fund D Fund E Chile Stock 42.8% 45.6% 35.5% 18.6% 6.5% 0.0% Chile Bond 11.2% 23.0% 32.2% 40.3% 54.9% 63.8% Chile Developed Developed US US Expected Cash Stock Bond Stock Bond Return Volatility 0.0% 15.2% 1.6% 26.0% 3.2% 6.3% 13.9% 8.0% 7.9% 1.2% 12.2% 2.2% 5.6% 13.1% 10.1% 6.1% 1.7% 11.1% 3.3% 5.0% 10.6% 15.7% 6.0% 2.5% 10.7% 6.2% 4.0% 6.9% 14.5% 4.9% 5.4% 6.7% 7.1% 3.3% 4.9% 15.3% 0.0% 7.4% 0.0% 13.5% 2.6% 4.5% 1 - 93 Example of Mean-Lower Partial Moment Portfolio Optimization: (Five Asset Classes, No Short Sales) 1 - 94 Estimating the Expected Returns and Measuring Superior Investment Performance We can use the concept of “alpha” to measure superior investment performance: a = (Actual Return) – (Expected Return) = “Alpha” In an efficient market, alpha should be zero for all investments. That is, securities should, on average, be priced so that the actual returns they produce equal what you expect them to given their risk levels. Superior managers are defined as those investors who can deliver consistently positive alphas after accounting for investment costs The challenge in measuring alpha is that we have to have a model describing the expected return to an investment. Researchers typically use one of two models for estimating expected returns: Capital Asset Pricing Model Multi-Factor Models (e.g., Fama-French Three-Factor Model) 1 - 95 Developing the Capital Asset Pricing Model Recall that one of the most fundamental notions in all of finance is that an investor’s expected return can be expressed in terms of these activities: E(R) = (Risk-Free Rate) + (Risk Premium) Clearly, the practical challenge in measuring expected returns comes from assessing the risk premium component properly. The Capital Market Line (CML) offers one tractable definition of the risk premium by writing this relationship as follows: E(R m ) RFR E(R p ) RFR p m While this is a reasonable first step, the CML expresses the risk-expected return tradeoff that investors should expect in an efficient capital market if they are purchasing entire portfolios of securities. To be fully useful, financial theory must address the following question: What is the appropriate risk-expected return relationship for individual securities? The problem posed by individual securities (compared to fully diversified portfolio holdings) is that the risk of those securities contains both systematic and unsystematic elements. Simply put, investors cannot expect to be compensated for risk that they could have diversified away themselves (i.e., unsystematic risk). 1 - 96 Developing the Capital Asset Pricing Model (cont.) One way to handle this problem in the context of the CML is to adjust the number of “total risk” units that the investor assumes for security i (i.e., i) to account for just the systematic portion of that risk. This can be done by multiplying i by the security’s correlation with the market portfolio (i.e., rim): E(R m ) RFR E(R i ) RFR (i rim ) m Rearranging this expression leaves: i rim E(R i ) RFR m [E(R m ) RFR] or: E(R i ) RFR i [E(R m ) RFR] This is the celebrated Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). Notice that the CAPM redefines risk in terms of a security’s “beta” (i.e., i), which captures that stock’s riskiness relative to the market as a whole. The graphical representation of the CAPM is called the Security Market Line (SML). 1 - 97 Using the SML in Performance Measurement: An Example Two investment advisors are comparing performance. Over the last year, one averaged a 19 percent rate of return and the other a 16 percent rate of return. However, the beta of the first investor was 1.5, whereas that of the second was 1.0. a. Can you tell which investor was a better predictor of individual stocks (aside from the issue of general movements in the market)? b. If the T-bill rate were 6 percent and the market return during the period were 14 percent, which investor should be viewed as the superior stock selector? c. If the T-bill rate had been 3 percent and the market return were 15 percent, would this change your conclusion about the investors? 1 - 98 Using the SML in Performance Measurement (cont.) a. To tell which investor was a better predictor of individual stocks we look at their alphas. Alpha is the difference between their actual return an that predicted by the SML, given the risk of their individual portfolios. Without information about the parameters of this equation (risk-free rate and the market rate of return) we cannot tell which one is more accurate. b. If RF = 0.06 and Rm = 0.14, then Alpha1 = .19 – [.06+1.5(.14-.06)] = .19 - .18 = 0.01 Alpha2 = .16 – [.06+1(.14-.06)] = .16 - .14 = 0.02 Here, the second investor has the larger alpha and thus appears to be a more accurate predictor. By making better predictions the second investor appears to have tilted his portfolio toward undervalued stocks. c. If RF = 0.03 and Rm = 0.15, then Alpha1 = .19 – [.03+1.5(.15 -.03)] = .19 - .21 = -0.02 Alpha2 = .16 – [.03+1(.15 -.03)] = .16 - .15 = 0.01 1 - 99 Using CAPM to Estimate Expected Return: Empresa Nacional de Telecom 1. Expected Return/Cost of Equity (Assumes RF = 4.73%) (i) RPm = 4.2%: E(R) = k = 4.73% + 0.79(4.2%) = 8.05% (ii) RPm = 7.2%: E(R) = k = 4.73% + 0.79(7.2%) = 10.42% 2. Expected Price Change (Recall that E(R) = E(Capital Gain) + E(Cash Yield)): (i) RPm = 4.2%: E(P1) = (4590)[1 + (.0805 - .0196)] = CLP 4869.53 (ii) RPm = 7.2%: E(P1) = (4590)[1 + (.1042 - .0196)] = CLP 4978.31 1 - 100 Estimating Mutual Fund Betas: FMAGX vs. GABAX 1 - 101 Estimating Mutual Fund Betas: FMAGX vs. GABAX (cont.) 1 - 102 Estimating Mutual Fund Betas: FMAGX vs. GABAX (cont.) 1 - 103 The Fama-French Three-Factor Model The most popular multi-factor model currently used in practice was suggested by economists Eugene Fama and Ken French. Their model starts with the single market portfolio-based risk factor of the CAPM and supplements it with two additional risk influences known to affect security prices: A firm size factor A book-to-market factor Specifically, the Fama-French three-factor model for estimating expected excess returns takes the following form: (Rit – RFRt) = ai + bi1(Rmt – RFRt) + bi2SMBt + bi3HMLt + eit where, in addition to the excess return on a stock market portfolio, two other risk factors are defined: SMB (i.e., “Small Minus Big”) is the return to a portfolio of small capitalization stocks less the return to a portfolio of large capitalization stocks HML (i.e., “High Minus Low”) is the return to a portfolio of stocks with high ratios of book-to-market values (i.e., “value” stocks) less the return to a portfolio of low bookto-market value (i.e., “growth”) stocks 1 - 104 Estimating the Fama-French Three-Factor Return Model: FMAGX vs. GABAX 1 - 105 Fama-French Three-Factor Return Model: FMAGX vs. GABAX (cont.) 1 - 106 Fama-French Three-Factor Return Model: FMAGX vs. GABAX (cont.) 1 - 107 Style Classification Implied by the Factor Model Growth Value FMAGX * Large * GABAX Small 1 - 108 Fund Style Classification by Morningstar FMAGX GABAX 1 - 109 Does Investment Style Consistency Matter? Consider the style classification of two funds (A &B) over time: 1 - 110 Does Investment Style Consistency Matter? (cont.) Study conducted using several thousand mutual funds from all nine style classes over the period 1991-2003 (see K. Brown and V. Harlow, “Staying the Course: Performance Persistence and the Role of Investment Style Consistency in Professional Asset Management”) Calculates style consistency measure for each fund using two different methods (i.e., R-squared from threefactor model, tracking error from style benchmark) and correlated these statistics with several portfolio characteristics, including returns Estimated regressions of future fund returns on past performance, style consistency, and other controls (e.g., fund expenses, turnover, assets under management) 1 - 111 Correlation of Style Consistency (i.e., R-Squared) With Other Fund Characteristics 1 - 112 Regression of Future Predicted Returns on: (i) Past Performance (i.e., Alpha), (ii) Style Consistency (i.e., RSQ), and (iii) Portfolio Control Variables in both Up and Down Markets 1 - 113 Investment Style Consistency: Conclusions In general, the findings strongly suggest that fund style consistency does matter in evaluating future fund performance Overall, there is a positive relationship between fund style consistency and subsequent investment performance However, the nature of how style consistency matters is somewhat complicated: In “up” markets, style-consistent funds outperform style- inconsistent funds, everything else held equal The reverse is true in “down” markets: style-inconsistent funds outperform style-consistent funds, everything else held equal “Up” and “down” markets are predictable in advance Being able to maintain a style-consistent portfolio is a valuable skill for a manager to have 1 - 114 Using Derivatives in Portfolio Management Most “long only” portfolio managers (i.e., non-hedge fund managers) do not use derivative securities as direct investments. Instead, derivative positions are typically used in conjunction with the underlying stock or bond holdings to accomplish two main tasks: “Repackage” the cash flows of the original portfolio to create a more desirable risk-return tradeoff given the manager’s view of future market activity. Transfer some or all of the unwanted risk in the underlying portfolio, either permanently or temporarily. In this context, it is appropriate to think of the derivatives market as an insurance market in which portfolio managers can transfer certain risks (e.g., yield curve exposure, downside equity exposure) to a counterparty in a cost-effective way. 1 - 115 The Cost of “Synthetic” Restructuring With Derivatives Consider the relative costs of rebalancing a stock portfolio in two ways: Cost Factor (i) physical rebalancing by trading the stocks themselves; or (ii) synthetic rebalancing using future contracts United States (S&P 500) Japan (Nikkei 225) United Kingdom (FT-SE 100) France (CAC 40) Germany (DAX) Hong Kong (Hang Seng) A. Stocks Commissions Market Impact Taxes Total 0.12% 0.30 0.00 0.42% 0.20% 0.70 0.21 1.11% 0.20% 0.70 0.50 1.40% 0.25% 0.50 0.00 0.75% 0.25% 0.50 0.00 0.75% 0.50% 0.50 0.34 1.34% 0.01% 0.05 0.00 0.06% 0.05% 0.10 0.00 0.15% 0.02% 0.10 0.00 0.12% 0.03% 0.10 0.00 0.13% 0.02% 0.10 0.00 0.12% 0.05% 0.10 0.00 0.15% B. Futures Commissions Market Impact Taxes Total Source: Joanne M. Hill, “Derivatives in Equity Portfolios,” in Derivatives in Portfolio Management, edited by T. Burns, Charlottesville, VA: Association for Investment Management and Research, 1998. 1 - 116 The Hedging Principle Suppose a portfolio manager holds a $100 million position in U.S. equity securities and she is concerned with the possibility that the stock market will decline over the next three months. How can she hedge the risk that her portfolio will experience significant declines in value? 1) Hedging With Stock Index Futures: Economic Event Actual Stock Exposure Desired Futures Exposure Stock Prices Fall Loss Gain Stock Prices Rise Gain Loss 2) Hedging With Stock Index Options: Economic Event Actual Stock Exposure Desired Hedge Exposure Stock Prices Fall Loss Gain Stock Prices Rise Gain No Loss 1 - 117 The Hedging Principle (cont.) Consider three alternative methods for hedging the downside risk of holding a long position in a $100 million stock portfolio over the next three months: 1) Short a stock index futures contract expiring in three months. Assume the current contract delivery price (i.e., F0,T) is $101 and that there is no front-expense to enter into the futures agreement. This combination creates a synthetic T-bill position. 2) Buy a stock index put option contract expiring in three months with an exercise price (i.e., X) of $100. Assume the current market price of the put option is $1.324. This is known as a protective put position. 3) (i) Buy a stock index put option with an exercise price of $97 and (ii) sell a stock index call option with an exercise price of $108. Assume that both options expire in three months and have a current price of $0.560. This is known as an equity collar position. 1 - 118 1. Hedging Downside Risk With Futures Expiration Date Value of a Futures-Hedged Stock Position: Potential Portfolio Value Value of Short Futures Position 60 (101-60) = 41 0 (60+41) = 101 70 (101-70) = 31 0 (70+31) = 101 80 (101-80) = 21 0 (80+21) = 101 90 (101-90) = 11 0 (90+11) = 101 0 (100+0) = 101 100 0 Cost of Futures Contract Net Futures Hedge Position 110 (101-110) = -9 0 (110-9) = 101 120 (101-120) = -19 0 (120-19) = 101 130 (101-130) = -29 0 (130-29) = 101 140 (101-140) = -39 0 (140-39) = 101 Notice that this net position can be viewed as a synthetic Treasury Bill (i.e., risk-free) holding with a face value of $101. 1 - 119 1. Hedging Downside Risk With Futures (cont.) Graphically, restructuring the long stock position using a short position in the futures contract creates the following synthetic restructuring: Now Three Months Long Stock Short Futures Net Position: Long T-Bill (p = 0) Long Stock (p = 1) 1 - 120 2. Hedging Downside Risk With Put Options Expiration Date Value of a Protective Put Position: Potential Portfolio Value Value of Put Option Cost of Put Option Net Protective Put Position 60 (100-60) = 40 -1.324 (60+40)-1.324 = 98.676 70 (100-70) = 30 -1.324 (70+30)-1.324 = 98.676 80 (100-80) = 20 -1.324 (80+20)-1.324 = 98.676 90 (100-90) = 10 -1.324 (90+10)-1.324 = 98.676 100 0 -1.324 (100+0)-1.324 = 98.676 110 0 -1.324 (110+0)-1.324 = 108.676 120 0 -1.324 (120+0)-1.324 = 118.676 130 0 -1.324 (130+0)-1.324 = 128.676 140 0 -1.324 (140+0)-1.324 = 138.676 1 - 121 2. Hedging Downside Risk With Put Options (cont.) Long Stock Plus Long Put: Terminal Position Value Equals: Terminal Position Value Long Stock Put-Protected Stock Portfolio 98.676 98.676 100 -1.324 Expiration Date Stock Value Long Put 100 Expiration Date Stock Value -1.324 1 - 122 3. Hedging Downside Risk With An Equity Collar Expiration Date Value of an Equity Collar-Protected Position: Potential Portfolio Value Net Option Expense Value of Put Option Value of Call Option Net CollarProtected Position 60 (0.56-0.56)=0 (97-60)=37 0 60 + 37 = 97 70 (0.56-0.56)=0 (97-70)=27 0 70 + 27 = 97 80 (0.56-0.56)=0 (97-80)=17 0 80 + 17 = 97 90 (0.56-0.56)=0 (97-90)= 7 0 90 + 7 = 97 97 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 0 97 + 0 = 97 100 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 0 100 + 0 = 100 108 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 0 108 - 0 = 108 110 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 (108-110)= -2 110 - 2 = 108 120 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 (108-120)= -12 120 - 12 = 108 130 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 (108-130)= -22 130 - 22 = 108 140 (0.56-0.56)=0 0 (108-140)= -32 140 - 32 = 108 1 - 123 3. Hedging Downside Risk With An Equity Collar (cont.) Terminal Position Value Collar-Protected Stock Portfolio 108 97 97 108 Terminal Stock Price 1 - 124 Zero-Cost Collar Example: IPSA Index Options 1 - 125 Zero-Cost Collar Example: IPSA Index Options (cont.) 1 - 126 Another Portfolio Restructuring Suppose now that upon further consideration, the portfolio manager holding $100 million in U.S. stocks is no longer concerned about her equity holdings declining appreciably over the next three months. However, her revised view is that they also will not increase in value much, if at all. As a means of increasing her return given this view, suppose she does the following: Sell a stock index call option contract expiring in three months with an exercise price (i.e., X) of $100. Assume the current market price of the at-the-money call option is $2.813. The combination of a long stock holding and a short call option position is known as a covered call position. It is also often referred to as a yield enhancement strategy because the premium received on the sale of the call option can be interpreted as an enhancement to the cash dividends paid by the stocks in the portfolio. 1 - 127 Restructuring With A Covered Call Position Expiration Date Value of a Covered Call Position: Potential Portfolio Value Value of Call Option Proceeds from Call Option Net Covered Call Position 60 0 2.813 (60+0)+2.813 = 62.813 70 0 2.813 (70+0)+2.813 = 72.813 80 0 2.813 (80+0)+2.813 = 82.813 90 0 2.813 (90+0)+2.813 = 92.813 100 0 2.813 (100+0)+2.813 = 102.813 110 -(110-100) = -10 2.813 (110-10)+2.813 = 102.813 120 -(120-100) = -20 2.813 (120-20)+2.813 = 102.813 130 -(130-100) = -30 2.813 (130-30)+2.813 = 102.813 140 -(140-100) = -40 2.813 (140-40)+2.813 = 102.813 1 - 128 Restructuring With A Covered Call Position (cont.) Long Stock Plus Short Call: Equals: Terminal Position Value Terminal Position Value 102.813 Long Stock Covered Call Portfolio Expiration Date Stock Value 2.813 100 Short Call 2.813 100 Expiration Date Stock Value 1 - 129 Some Thoughts on Currency Hedging and Portfolio Management Question: How much FX exposure should a portfolio manager hedge? Exchange R ate Chi lean P eso p er U.S. Do llar Monthly: Feb 2 9, 20 00 - Feb 28 , 200 5 Hi gh: 7 49 Lo w: 50 2 La st: 573 75 0 Weakening CLP Strengthening CLP 70 0 65 0 60 0 55 0 50 0 00 01 02 03 04 1 - 130 Conceptual Thinking on Currency Hedging in Portfolio Management There are at least three diverse schools of thought on the optimal amount of currency exposure that a portfolio manager should hedge (see A. Golowenko, “How Much to Hedge in a Volatile World,” State Street Global Advisors, 2003): Completely Unhedged: Froot (1993) argues that over the long term, real exchange rates will revert to their means according to the Purchasing Power Parity Theorem, suggesting currency exposure is a zero-sum game. Further, over shorter time frames—when exchange rates can deviate from long-term equilibrium levels—transaction costs make involved with hedging greatly outweigh the potential benefits. Thus, the manager should maintain an unhedged foreign currency position. Fully Hedged: Perold and Schulman (1988) believe that currency exposure does not produce a commensurate level of return for the size of the risk; in fact, they argue that it has a long-term expected return of zero. Thus, since the investor cannot, on average, expect to be adequately rewarded for bearing currency risk, it should be fully hedged out of the portfolio. Partially Hedged: An “optimal” hedge ratio exists, subject to the usual caveats regarding parameter estimation. Black (1989) demonstrates that this ratio can vary between 30% and 77% depending on various factors. Gardner and Wuilloud (1995) use the concept of investor regret to argue that a position which is 50% currency hedged is an appropriate benchmark. 1 - 131 Hedging the FX Risk in a Global Portfolio: Some Evidence Consider a managed portfolio consisting of five different asset classes: Monthly returns over two different time periods: Chilean Stocks (IPSA), Bonds (LVAC Govt), Cash (LVAC MMkt) US Stocks (SPX), Bonds (SBBIG) February 2000 – February 2005 February 2002 – February 2005 Five different FX hedging strategies (assuming zero hedging transaction costs): #1: Hedge US positions with selected hedge ratio, monthly rebalancing #2: Leave US positions completely unhedged #3: Fully hedge US positions, monthly rebalancing #4: Make monthly hedging decision (i.e., either fully hedged or completely unhedged) on a monthly basis assuming perfect foresight about future FX movements #5: Make monthly hedging decision (i.e., either fully hedged or completely unhedged) on a monthly basis assuming always wrong about future FX movements 1 - 132 Investment Performance for Various Portfolio Strategies: February 2000-February 2005 1 - 133 Investment Performance for Various Portfolio Strategies: February 2002-February 2005 1 - 134 Sharpe Ratio Sensitivities for Various Managed Portfolio Hedge Ratios 1 - 135 Currency Hedging and Global Portfolio Management: Final Thoughts Foreign currency fluctuations are a major source of risk that the global portfolio manager must consider. The decision of how much of the portfolio’s FX exposure to hedge is not clear-cut and much has been written on all sides of the issue. It can depend of many factors, including the period over which the investment is held. It is also clear that tactical FX hedging decisions have potential to be a major source of alpha generation for the portfolio manager. Recent evidence (Jorion, 1994) suggests that the FX hedging decision should be optimized jointly with the manager’s basic asset allocation decision. However, this is not always possible or practical. Currency overlay (i.e., the decision of how much to hedge made outside of the portfolio allocation process) is rapidly developing specialty area in global portfolio management. 1 - 136