Consumer, Producer and Markets Overall: Greatest human satisfaction from scarce resources. Allocative Efficiency – resources are dedicated to the combination of goods and services that best satisfy consumer wants Production Efficiency – goods and services are produced using the least cost combination of resources and technology Dynamic Efficiency – how the economy over time promotes allocative and productive efficiency Positive – an objective analysis of how economic variables are related Normative – a prescriptive analysis to help determine what ought to be. Welfare economics – the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Economic agents, unlike many variables in other sciences, are not passive. Therefore, it is difficult to measure willingness to pay. Normal Auction – Ascending price with sale to the highest bidder. May yield the person who most highly values the item, but does not measure their maximum willingness to pay. Dutch Auction – Descending Price with sale to first bidder. May yield the person who most highly values the good and the maximum willingness to pay. So far, we have demonstrated that people maximize total net benefits from an activity at the point where MB=MC Marginal benefits are equal to the (max.) willingness to pay and decline as quantity demanded increase because of the law of diminishing marginal utility (jelly bean example). Since consumer as price takers in competitive markets, the price equals the marginal costs to consumers. Consumer surplus equals willingness to pay minus the price, which is the same as net benefits we have discussed before. Using the demand curve to measure consumer surplus Before: giving a price and finding the corresponding quantity demanded Now: giving the quantity and finding the amount people are willing to pay for a good or go without it MB=MC occurs where price intersects the demand curve and total net benefits=consumer surplus is maximized. Cool, no! The demand curve is usually ready as – at a given price how much will a consumer buy. The maximum willingness to pay is just the buyer value in Aplia and our measure of the MB. Consumer surplus is the difference between what the consumer is willing to pay and the price(s) that they have to pay. Note that, if the demand curve is the marginal benefit curve and the price is the marginal cost, consumer equilibrium is nothing more that MB=MC and we are back to the stack of boxes example. The supply curve is usually ready as – at a given price how much will a firms sell. The minimum willingness to sell is just the seller cost in Aplia and our measure of the MC. Producer surplus is the difference between the price(s) sellers receive and minimum willingness to sell or MC. Note that, if the supply curve is the marginal cost curve and the price is the marginal benefit, the seller equilibrium is nothing more that MB=MC and we are back to the stack of boxes example. (a) Price = $80 Price of Album $100 John’s consumer surplus ($20) 80 70 50 Demand 0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of Albums Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (b) Price = $70 Price of Album $100 John’s consumer surplus ($30) 80 Paul’s consumer surplus ($10) 70 50 Total consumer surplus ($40) Demand 0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of Albums Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (a) Consumer Surplus at Price P Price A Consumer surplus P1 B C Demand 0 Q1 Quantity Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (b) Consumer Surplus at Price P Price A Initial consumer surplus P1 P2 0 C B Consumer surplus to new consumers F D E Additional consumer surplus to initial consumers Q1 Demand Q2 Quantity Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning Consumer surplus measures the difference between the (max.) willingness to pay and the price. Producer surplus measure the difference between the (min.) needed to be willing to sell and the price. Remember, the Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns causes marginal costs to rise in the short-run as output increases. As more the the variable input is added to the fixed input, its marginal product eventually begins to diminish (production exercise in class). If all workers are paid the same wage, the LDMR implies that the extra (marginal) costs of producing extra (marginal) outputs increases. If the seller is a price taker, they receive the same price for very output sold. So the difference between the price and the marginal cost (the willingness to sell) is the: Producer Surplus (a) Price = $600 Price of House Painting Supply $900 800 600 500 Grandma’s producer surplus ($100) 0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of Houses Painted Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (b) Price = $800 Price of House Painting $900 Supply Total producer surplus ($500) 800 600 Georgia’s producer surplus ($200) 500 Grandma’s producer surplus ($300) 0 1 2 3 4 Quantity of Houses Painted Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (a) Producer Surplus at Price P Price Supply P1 B Producer surplus C A 0 Q1 Quantity Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning (b) Producer Surplus at Price P Price Supply Additional producer surplus to initial producers P2 P1 D E F B Initial producer surplus C Producer surplus to new producers A 0 Q1 Q2 Quantity Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning Assume competitive markets (many buyers and sellers, identical products, free entry and exit, price takers, etc.) Assume that consumer surplus measures consumers economic well-being and producer surplus that of sellers. So, MB = willingness to pay by consumers and MC = willingness to sell to producers MB=MC Occurs where the demand and supply curve intersect, and Total Well-being is Maximized Price A D Supply Consumer surplus Equilibrium price E Producer surplus B Demand C 0 Equilibrium quantity Quantity Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning Price Supply Value to buyers Cost to sellers Cost to sellers 0 Value to buyers Equilibrium quantity Value to buyers is greater than cost to sellers. Demand Quantity Value to buyers is less than cost to sellers. Copyright©2003 Southwestern/Thomson Learning Competitive markets result in the combination of goods and services that maximize consumer well-being (allocative efficiency) and produce goods at least possible cost (production efficiency). Over time, competitive forces will move to promote allocative and production efficiency (dynamic efficiency). Adam Smith, building on the work of other philosophers, was the first to develop a comprehensive argument for the efficiency of markets. The efficiency of markets has proven a powerful force in altering historical perspectives on effective ways humans can interact. The revolutionary idea that the pursuit of selfinterest, tempered by competition, promotes social interest is the basis for the tremendous economic growth of the last century. If markets are not competitive, efficiency might not be guaranteed. In some cases, consumer surplus might not be considered a good measure of consumer well-being (drugs or externalities), or producer surplus might not be a good measure of producer wellbeing (externalities or inefficiency due to monopoly). Changes in the allocation of resources alters the human satisfaction generated from resources. How do we “maximize” human satisfaction with as few value judgments as possible? This is Welfare Economics and Vilfredo Pareto was a pioneer in the area. Pareto Efficient Change – at least one person is made better off without making someone worse off. Pareto Efficiency – no one can be made better off without making someone worse off. Voluntary trades are Pareto Efficient Changes. At the competitive market equilibrium (in the absence of market failures such as monopoly, externalities, and public goods), MB=MC Total Surplus (CS+PS) is maximized All voluntary trades are carried out All Pareto Efficient Changes are made Pareto Efficiency holds! The formula for Pareto Efficiency is: (MB=) P=MC A market for transplantable organs Current price is zero and there is a shortage of transplantable organs Allowing companies to contract with individuals to donate organs for a price would likely increase the supply of organs Positive versus normative considerations Pilgrims, communal agriculture, and starvation Is a tuition cap a price control? NPR presentation http://www.npr.org/features/feature.php?wfId =1474621 Who pays the cost of a college education? Why are the costs of a college education rising? Demand side Supply side What are the likely effects of tuition caps? Increased financial aid as an alternative to price controls. Taxes create a wedge between the price buyers pay and sellers receive and result in a reduction in quantity bought and sold. The reduction in quantity leaves production at a point where MB>MC and consumer surplus and producer surplus is not maximized. The consumer and producer surplus that is lost from not producing where MB=MC is call the Deadweight Welfare Loss (DWL). DWL is the economic cost of taxation. Price Supply Price buyers pay Size of tax Price without tax Price sellers receive Demand 0 Quantity with tax Quantity without tax Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western Price Supply Price buyers pay Size of tax (T) Tax revenue (T × Q) Price sellers receive Demand Quantity sold (Q) 0 Quantity with tax Quantity without tax Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western Price Price buyers = PB pay Supply A B C Price without tax = P1 Price sellers = PS receive E D F Demand 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western The loss in economic welfare from restricting voluntary exchange. When the MB, or the willingness to pay, is greater than the MC, or the willingness to sell, then more voluntary transactions would increase economic welfare (net benefits) Graph – ignore the tax and just think about anything that restricts trade like a price floor or ceiling As in the case of tax incidence, the key to understanding the extent of DWL are the elasticities of demand and supply. When demand and supply are more elastic or responsive, the greater will be the decline in equilibrium quantity for any tax increase. The greater the tax, the larger the deadweight welfare loss. (a) Inelastic Supply Price Supply When supply is relatively inelastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is small. Size of tax Demand 0 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western (b) Elastic Supply Price When supply is relatively elastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is large. Size of tax Supply Demand 0 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western (c) Inelastic Demand Price Supply Size of tax When demand is relatively inelastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is small. Demand 0 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western (d) Elastic Demand Price Supply Size of tax Demand When demand is relatively elastic, the deadweight loss of a tax is large. 0 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western (a) Small Tax Price Deadweight loss Supply PB Tax revenue PS Demand 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western (c) Large Tax Price PB Tax revenue Deadweight loss Supply Demand PS 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity Copyright © 2004 South-Western Taxes on labor (federal income tax, social security, medicare) add up to about a 50% marginal tax on labor for many US workers. DWL and the labor market Elastic or inelastic labor supply? Full time work regardless of wage or is labor responsive to wages? Overtime, second earners, retirement, underground economy (barter and illegal activity) Increasing taxes may raise or lower tax revenues. This occurs for reasons analogous to why increases in prices may raise or lower total revenue. Increases in excise taxes raise the price ot the buyer and lower the price to the seller. This creates disincentives to buy and to sell. If tax rates increase (helps tax rev), ceteris paribus, tax revenue would rise, BUT all is not equal – the quantity transacted falls (hurts tax rev). Whether taxes revenues rise or fall depends on the tax elasticity = % change in Quantity Traded (OE(ffect))/ % change in taxes (TE(ffect)). If the TE > OE (Et<1)and tax rates increase, tax revenue will rise. If TE <OE (Et>1), tax revenues will rise. This is the logic behind the Laffer curve and supply side economics – large tax rates create a disincentive to work and invest. The Promoting equity while minimizing tax shifting and DWL Is land in inelastic or elastic supply? land tax and Henry George Raw land versus improvements A tax for today?