Tutorial 3 Chapter 3: The fundamentals of economic growth Chapter 4: Explaining economic growth in the long run Multiple choice questions Question 1 Which ONE of the following describes the ‘Solow Residual’? *a. The share of GDP growth that is NOT explained by the growth in labour hours and capital. Feedback: Correct. Page reference: 75 b. The share of GDP growth that is NOT explained by technological progress. Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 75 c. The share of GDP growth NEITHER explained by the growth of inputs, NOR technological progress. Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 75 d. The share of GDP that remains after deducting consumption, government spending, and net exports. Feedback: Incorrect. Note that this misses the point that the chapter is devoted to economic growth! Page reference: 75 Question 2 Assume two economies with identical rates of growth of labour (n) and labouraugmenting technological progress (a), the same depreciation rate of capital (δ), and the identical underlying production function relating capital per effective unit of labour (K/(AL)) to output per effective unit of labour (Y/(AL)). Suppose that the saving ratio (s) in Economy I is LARGER than that of Economy II. According to the Solow model of growth, which ONE of the following will be true? a. The Solow residual will be larger in Economy II than in Economy I. Feedback: Incorrect. They have the same a. Page reference: 66; 75 b. Economy I will grow faster than Economy II in the steady state. Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 66; 75 *c. Economy I will have a higher output per unit effective labour than Economy II. Feedback: Correct. Page reference: 66; 75 d. Economy I will be dynamically more efficient than Economy II. Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 66; 75 Question 3 Total hours worked and population have [(A)_____] at roughly similar rates over time in a group of advanced countries discussed in the text, because the average hours worked per employed person has [(B)______] at the same time that the proportion of the population working has [(C)_______]. a. (A) declined; (B) gone down ; (C) declined Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 76, 77 b. (A) grown; (B) increased; (C) remained roughly constant Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 76, 77 c. (A) grown; (B) increased; (C) gone down Feedback: Incorrect. Page reference: 76, 77 *d. (A) grown; (B) gone down; (C) increased Feedback: Correct. Page reference: 76, 77 Question 4 Starting in the steady state, which (exogenous) shock would result initially in a situation in which the capital stock would happen to be above its new steady state value? a. An economy experiences the reduction of much of its capital stock through a war due to negative net investment during the war years. Feedback: Incorrect. Part of the story of the recovery of post-war Europe was rebuilding its capital stock. Page reference: 75, 76 b. The population growth rate drops through a reduction in fertility (n decreases). Feedback: Incorrect. See Figure 3.15. Page reference: 73 *c. A sudden increase in labour-augmenting technological progress (a increases). Feedback: Correct. See Figure 3.15. Page reference: 73 d. The saving rate increases. Feedback: Incorrect. See Figure 3.15. Page reference: 73 Question 5 Endogenous growth theory differs in what essential aspect from the Solow theory of economic growth? a. Endogenous growth theory is a monetary theory, whereas the Solow theory is a real theory. Feedback: Incorrect. In both theories, money does not play any role whatsoever. Page reference: 94 b. Endogenous growth theory assumes diminishing returns to capital and the Solow theory assumes constant returns. Feedback: Incorrect. Exactly the opposite is true. Page reference: 94 *c. In endogenous growth theory, economies with the same technology and saving rate need not converge to the same steady state as in the Solow model. Feedback: Correct. Page reference: 94 d. All of the other answers given are correct. Feedback: Incorrect. The only answer that is true is that in endogenous growth theory, economies with the same technology and saving rate need not converge to the same steady state as in the Solow model. Page reference: 94 Question 6 The fundamental disincentive for private producers to produce costly new knowledge is the ___________ characteristic of knowledge. *a. Non-excludability. Feedback: Correct. Without intellectual property rights that can be enforced, knowledge producers cannot reap much, if any, of what they sow. Page reference: 97 b. Rivalrous. Feedback: Incorrect. It is hard to imagine how your learning what I have learned would make me ‘unlearn’ the new knowledge. Page reference: 97 c. Learning by doing. Feedback: Incorrect. This is treated in the textbook as an issue of the diffusion of existing knowledge, although it was originally conceived in the literature as an explanation for the falling costs in the production of airplanes. Page reference: 97 d. All of the other answers given are accurate. Feedback: Incorrect. Non-excludability is the only right answer. Page reference: 97 Open question: Exercise 4 and 5 from the book (Chapter 4). 4. Conditional convergence means that countries will converge in levels and growth rates of GDP per capita only if they share values of other attributes which are essential or influential for economic growth. In addition to climate and geographical factors, these include education, physical infrastructure, social infrastructure, political stability, and health. Thus, it is not surprising that Ghana and South Korea have had very different growth experiences in the period 1960-2005, even if they started this period with similar values of per capita GDP. 5. First, it is important to note that the production function Y K H L1 is a Cobb-Douglas production function in three arguments with constant returns to scale. Divide both sides by labour L to obtain the intensive form y k h . Let population growth be n (you could also set it equal to zero). It follows that physical capital and ~ ~ human capital per capita evolve according to k sy k and h sy h respectively. Define the steady state to hold when per capita values of physical capital and human capital are constant. This implies sy ~ k 0 sy k k ~ sy ~ h 0 sy h h ~ sy sy So y ~ ~ which can be solved as s 1 y ~ It is easy to see that per capita GDP is higher, the higher the saving rate and the lower the depreciation rate (assumed equal for human and physical capital). Yet there is no economic growth per capita in the steady state, and economic growth occurs at rate n. To change this, it would be necessary to introduce total factor productivity growth in the usual way. Extra questions: Exercises 1, 6, 9, and 10 from the book (Chapter 4). 1. The Solow model assumes a common production technology and an exogenous and common rate of technical progress, a. Under these conditions, the level of capita per effective unit of labour is the only distinguishing feature between two economies – capital accumulation is the sole means of achieving higher productivity relative to other nations. In the diagram below, two nations 0 and 1 share the same constant returns production function. When divided by AL, this yields the same intensive-form production function: y = f(K/AL). The only factor distinguishing them is their levels of capital per unit of effective labour. The Solow model predicts that both economies will converge in level to GDP per capita y* with capital per capita k* and per capita output growth in both will converge to a. 6. A Marshallian externality is a positive externality in which each individual agent causing the externality is not aware of the effects of his or her actions, or the effect is simply so small to be of any aggregate consequence. At the same time, if many or all individuals perform the same action, there will be perceptible aggregate effects. For example, individuals may reap private rewards from their education but may also bestow advantages on others, even if these others are not educated themselves, especially if a great deal of people are well-trained. (It is always good to have a welleducated workforce). Similarly, research and development may yield private benefits for firms in the form of patentable inventions, yet there may be advantages to the community at large in the form of research spillovers and networks. Network externalities is another example of a Marshallian externality. If I buy a mobile telephone, I improve not only my own communication capabilities, but I also improve others’ ability to communicate with me. Please note that we use the general definition of an externality, given in the chapter and glossary. The definition of a Marshallian externality given in the glossary is never discussed in the main text. 9. The distinction refers to public goods. Some public goods are non-excludable; by legal construction, design or nature, it is impossible to restrict access to them. Public resources such as parks, athletic facilities, public roads and beaches are examples, as are national defense and radio transmissions. The fact that their access cannot be restricted may or may not mean that they are rivalrous. Rival goods imply that there may be congestion or dilution. Thus, some nonexcludable goods can well be rivalrous – parks and highways, clean air, or public parking spaces. Some, however, are both nonexcludable and non-rivalrous - national defense or knowledge are standard examples. Some non-rivalrous goods are excludable, usually meaning that while the marginal cost of extending the service is low or nonexistent, there exist legal means to prevent “free-riding.” 10. Since the production of knowledge is a public good that is both non-rival and nonexcludable, it may not be very attractive for private firms and individuals to produce very much of it. To see why, consider James Watt, the inventor of the steam engine, who truly revolutionized the progress of mankind with his invention but received in his lifetime precious little for his trouble. Often inventive activity produces spin-offs which are hardly related to the invention or discovery which is actually sought. Because knowledge is so essential to human progress, the state often encourages inventive activity and basic research. Governments (and international agreements among governments) offer patent protection for a limited time which grants exclusive rights to some discoveries and inventions. Similarly, copyrights and trademarks offer limited monopoly power to exploit so-called intellectual property commercially for some period of time. Second, governments frequently subsidize basic research and scientific development activities, either by providing competitive grant funds or by financing research institutions such as laboratories and universities. Third, governments can also offer financial incentives in the form of tax breaks for firms to engage in research and development. They may also subsidize the education of specialists in areas which are normally not particularly lucrative in the private sector. Patents shield firms which innovate from competition by granting them monopoly rights over the innovation for some period of time. In general, it is not a good idea to restrict competition, so patent protection is granted only for a limited time. In the long run these ideas become part of the public domain and can be produced by anyone willing to pay the costs of production.