Pension Distribution Crisis: The Right Scheme between Defined Benefit and Defined Contribution in Solving Inadequate Pension Coverage in Singapore A Thesis Presented to the College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Santo Tomas In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Bachelor of Science in Commerce and Business Administration Major in Business Economics By Lao, Princess Chezica T. Cruz, Carla Felize C. Kim Eun Hyun 1 ABSTRACT Within the past years, the pensions systems around the world have experienced inadequate pension distributions. More and more of the retiring workers and elderly fear of old – age poverty. The pension distribution crisis was clear and evident for more developed countries like the OECD countries. However, this is fast approaching to other parts of the globe. In South – East Asia, these countries were labeled to be ‘youthful countries’ where much of its population was much relatively younger. Unexpectedly, the sudden changes in the countries’ demographic profiles now pose as an economic and social challenge, calling for policy attention regarding its pension distribution. Singapore faces this public concern known as the pension distribution crisis. There are several distinct factors that continue to deter this crisis namely, the unanticipated sudden increases in life expectancies, the continuous decline in fertility rates, and mortality rates. All these factors which have been looked upon are now seen as a threat for economic and social stability of workers and pensioners. The intent of this thesis is to serve as an eye – opener. The research provides different points concerning on the matter of pension distribution crisis. This aims to raise the level of awareness for future social and economic policy formations which could be adaptable to one’s home country. Thus, in the long run, one’s home country can learn from and prepare for the impacts of pension distribution crisis. 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Title Abstract Table of Contents List of Tables List of Figures CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 3 CHAPTER 4 CHAPTER 5 INTRODUCTION Background of the Study Key Issues / Trends Objective of the Study Significance of the Study REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE Pensions Defined Benefit Scheme Defined Contribution Scheme Pension Distribution Crisis Life Expectancy Women and Fertility Rates Medical Care and Mortality Rates Synthesis Simulacrum RESEARCH METHOD Econometric Model Statistical Treatment Data Gathering Procedure RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS Life Expectancy Fertility Rates Mortality Rates CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS Life Expectancy Fertility Rates Mortality Rates BIBLIOGRAPHY APPENDICES ABOUT THE AUTHOR 3 6 6 6 7 7 8 8 8 8 11 12 14 15 17 19 20 20 20 22 23 23 24 24 27 27 27 28 31 36 46 List of Tables Table 1A. Central Provident Fund (CPF) Contribution Rates and Allocation Rates 38 Table 1B. CPF Contributions Credited to each Account for each Age Bracket 38 Table 2A. CPF Members by Age Group 41 Table 2B. Active CPF Members by Age Group 41 Table 3A. Withdrawals of CPF by Type (In Million Dollars) 42 Table 3B. Withdrawals of CPF by Type (In Numbers) 42 Table 4.Total CPF Savings at Age 55 among the Elderly who were Age 59 – Above in 1999 43 Table 5. Median Age for Singapore in 1911 – 2000 44 Table 6. Medical Research in Singapore in 2006 – 2012 44 4 List of Figures Figure 1. Simulacrum 19 Figure 2A. Life Expectancy Regression Output 39 Figure 2B. Fertility Rates Regression Output 39 Figure 2C. Mortality Rates Regression Output 40 Figure 3. Singapore’s Dependency Ratios in 1960 – 2011 43 Figure 4. Singapore’s Health Expenditure (Thousands), PPP (Constant 2005, International $) 45 5 Introduction People all over the world are living longer than before. The progressive fall in fertility and greater longevity are changing the structure of the world’s population (UN, 2005). According to the World Health Organization, global life expectancy at birth, now 66 years, is projected to reach 73 years by 2025. Many thousands of people born at the end of the 20 th century will live throughout the 21st century. For example, France is projected to have 150,000 centenarians by the year 2050 compared to only 200 in 1950 (see The World Health Report 1998). Thus, it is imperative for the worker to retire later than the usual retirement age of 65 to have sufficient income when retirement comes. Better medical care aggravates longevity risk. The pressures placed on national health – care systems by the recent demographic and epidemiological transitions are amplified by the growing demands of an increasingly educated and affluent population for high – quality health care and the supply of the latest medical technology. (Chongsuvivatwong, et. al, 2011). Increase in female education induces Asians to have fewer children and to participate in the labor force, leading to a decline in the fertility rates. For example, in Indonesia, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan (Province of China) and Thailand—where modern contraception has been widely accepted, many girls are educated, and family sizes have declined dramatically—the number of women who have moved into professional, technical, and administrative positions have increased substantially in recent decades. The decline in fertility rates translates to fewer young workers. Thus, financial, economic and social problems regarding adequate pension funds, 6 equitable pension distribution, and sufficient retirement income is at stake (see Labour Force Participation and Employment under Women’s Empowerment and Reproductive Health). Old age income support will be one of the biggest social and economic challenges facing developing Asia (henceforth Asia) in the 21st century. In contrast to industrialized countries, most Asian countries do not yet have mature, well functioning pension systems. As a result, they are ill prepared to provide economic security for the large number of retirees who loom on the horizon (Park & Estrada, 2012). Because of the emergence of the pension distribution crisis in South – East Asia, the main goal of this research is to show how life expectancy, female participation, and medical care can help better reshape Singapore’s pension system by taking all these factors into account. The researchers highlight on the principle of horizontal equity and pension wealth in terms of pensions received and how the chosen pension scheme may affect workers. Therefore, this paper serves to provide fresh insights by looking at the issue on a different perspective because the significance of doing so could mean a brighter retirement scene for elderly workers and for future workers. In connection, this paper focuses solely on Singapore. 7 Review of Related Literature Pensions are a form of compensation deferred or delayed until the worker decides to leave his or her job (Friedberg & Webb, 2005). The retirement decision of the worker revolves around two things: difference on derived utilities between work and leisure – which is retirement in this sense – and net present value between current and expected rewards and future compensation in the form of pensions (Friedberg & Webb, 2005). How the worker receives his or her pensions is resolved through a pension scheme. A pension scheme can be thought of as a long - term medium wherein resources are transferred from the current young workers to retiring ones. The two key types of funded pension schemes are known to be either a Defined Benefit or a Defined Contribution scheme (Duval, 2003; Blake, 2000). Defined Benefit schemes (DB scheme hereafter) are traditional. Typically, retiree benefits from this scheme depend on the number of years of service and his or her final occupational salary. Defined Contribution schemes (DC scheme hereafter) on the other hand are characterized by the firm’s promise of contributing a certain amount for the worker annually (Blake, 2000; Kapinos, 2009). As to what type of pension scheme the rational worker should choose from is based on several factors. At the bottom line, this is where he or she can derive stable income sources for retirement when all costs and benefits for each pension scheme have been looked upon (Sundali, Westerman, &Stedham, 2008). These sources of income are usually referred to as “pillars” of the pension scheme (Hogler& Hunt III, 2008). 8 Both pension schemes incur economic costs and benefits but they differ in kind. In a DB scheme, the pension provider accumulates assets held in trust. The uncertainty it brings are the pension fund’s investment rate of return and final occupational salary. The latter is daunting since employers do not know the progression of its workers. Also, the promise of the DB scheme provider can be indeterminate since final cost is not known until the worker’s retirement (Eaton &Nofsinger, 2008). A DB scheme can provide a reasonable replacement ratio – the ratio of annual benefits to earnings just prior to retirement (Duval, 2003; Blake, 2000) – to workers who only opt to use the DB scheme over his or her career. Thus, frequent job changers would be worse off since these workers would experience large portability losses. This is because employers give different schemes when workers shift from one job to another (Friedberg & Webb, 2005; Friedberg, Owyang, & Sinclair, 2006). As a result, these workers lose their pension entitlement. With DC schemes, it is important to distinguish between accumulation and decumulation stages. Starting from the accumulation stage, a DC scheme – sometimes referred to as a personal pension scheme – would be more ideal for the frequent job changer since the portability losses here do not take any effect. However, following a DC scheme is often connected with higher charges since DC schemes are frontloaded. This means that the initial charges are drawn from the start of the scheme rather than having it dispersed evenly throughout – leading to higher operating costs. From the decumulation stage known as annuities, DC schemes would prove to be reliable if it were only able to provide adequate pensions in retirement. Unfortunately, this is impeded by the cases of annuities. Annuitants and annuity providers both face several serious problems. The major reason behind this blockage is the adverse selection bias connected to 9 mortality risk. This is the risk where workers who believe that they would live longer would purchase annuities. Apparently, annuities markets are known to be relatively thin. Another is the uncertainty of assumptions on mortality risks. It would be consequential for annuity providers to update their mortality assumptions (Blake, 2000; Byrne & Winter, 2009). Furthermore, while there is the presence of portability of jobs in the DC scheme, this is not the case between pension scheme providers. Transfers from DB schemes to DC schemes translate to greater economic costs. DB plan users transferring to DC plans forego the accrued benefits – the ’backloading loss’ – and incur portability loss. The marginal benefit derived from an additional year from the newly chosen scheme (DC scheme) only equals the return of that year’s contributions (Blake, 2000). Despite the numerous flaws of the DC scheme, much of the private – sector pension provision still has shifted away from using the traditional DB schemes (Kiosse & Peasnell, 2009; Kapinos, 2009). The declining popularity of DB schemes to pension providers directly stem from: longevity risk – employees, on average, have longer life expectancies – which is the most significant risk borne by DB schemes (Byrne & Winter, 2009) – interest rate risk – interest rates might fall, increasing the risks associated from long – term liabilities, inflation risk – final salaries might increase higher than predicted, and investment return risk – employer’s rate of return from contributions to the plan are lower (Kiosse&Peasnell, 2009). Default risks are also associated with a DB scheme due to the incidence of the adverse selection problem where employers are likely to default on their obligations (Kiosse&Peasnell, 2009). In retrospect, the DB schemes are ultimately linked with higher net losses than DC schemes (Banks, Blundell, 10 Emmerson, 2005) and are seen to be unsustainable during today’s economic conditions (Sundali, Westerman, Stedham, 2008). One prominent issue found on pension is its distribution. Specifically, it is tied to the recurring thought of inadequate coverage. There is a widespread fear that retiring workers are not saving enough for their future consumption and public awareness has elevated the concerns on the adequacy of retirement savings (Kiosse&Peasnell, 2009). The pension distribution crisis has been evident throughout the OECD countries whereby international organizations raise concerns on the sustainability of these pensions systems. The two principal concerns are maintaining the level of economic activities of older workers and preserving their living standards. In other words, these organizations see the need to raise or delay the effective retirement age of older workers and secure them from poverty during old – age (Pestieau, 2003). However, increasing the pensionable age creates inconsistencies regarding their reduced competitiveness in the labor market. Older workers are also more prone to health issues. Thus, these workers could not compete as extensively as they did during their younger years (Bredt, 2008). Transition economies are now facing the same social and economic challenges of pension distribution. Countries coming from Asia are now left with the same crisis – but at a greater cost. Singapore’s pension system is not tailor – fitted to the rapid changing of demographics and economic conditions that continue to deter the already imperfect pension schemes and its distribution (Salditt, Whiteford, &Adema 2008; Brodjonegoro&Simanjuntak, 2002). 11 The ongoing trend of increasing life expectancy of the population has been the most popular dominant factor of pension distribution crisis. This trend of a longer life expectancy has accelerated in a way not previously anticipated (Everness, 2001). Life expectancy risk relates to the projected length of life of a cohort or generation while longevity risk relates to individuals. Though the increasing life spans are seen to be wonderful and worth celebrating, it challenges the economic and social stability of pensions systems. In line with the risks that life expectancy bears against DB and DC schemes are the regrettable decisions which have been based on miscalculated estimates. Most Asian countries still follow an unrealistic retirement age ranging from 55 – 60. Many were set during the onset of world war. Perceptively during the 1950’s, life expectancy would be much lower than today. Indeed this was the case since Asian life expectancy was at 41 back then. However, more recent is the fact that many Asians are now living longer – experiencing longer life expectancies – ranging from 60 – 80. This happens to be the case for women since women live longer than their counterparts. Since women live longer than males, they are more prone to the risk of poverty since they would accumulate fewer resources (Dordea & Popovici, 2008). With this understanding, pension payments would be much more expensive since retirees live longer than expected for pension providers. In DC schemes, benefits received by the worker would be lower due to higher life expectancy. This is because there is a longer duration for pension payments. This also verifies the asset decumulation of the elderly (De Nardi, French, & Jones, 2009). In DB schemes, there is a fixed amount regardless of life expectancy (Whitehouse, 2007) which causes a shift from DB schemes to DC schemes. 12 On a different light, population ageing is occurring more rapidly in Asia than in Western countries. Population ageing induces ‘greying’ of the working – age population. Given that these workers have weaker labor market attachment as compared to prime – age workers, the tendency is that old – age dependency ratios will rise which is caused by the decline in aggregate participation levels and employment rates of these workers. Simply stated, the serious effect of population ageing due to longer life expectancies reduces workers in the labor force (Goh, 2005). Eventually, it all adds pressure to the current pensions systems and living standards of the retiring workers (Duval, 2003). Population ageing is a classic demographic transition. It increases adult longevity and thus, increases life expectancy. It becomes evident that pensions become expensive as the number of workers for every retiree falls since pensions for these retiring workers are taken from young workers. Raising the effective retirement age could help alleviate the burden of ageing populations since they would be able to compensate for reduced pensions (Ghilarducci, 2010). However, some distinct factors greatly affect the retirement decision of the worker and thus, the supply of labor. The two major components are the strong preference of the worker for leisure and the increased wealth effects which are associated with rising living standards (Duval, 2003; Ghilarducci, 2010; Roberts, Rice, & Jones, 2010). Also, work is not necessarily good for the older workers. In fact, more time for retirement could be the cause of longer lives assuming that retirement produces healthier outcomes (Ghilarducci, 2010; Roberts, Rice, & Jones, 2010). π»0 : The increase in life expectancies in Singapore does not affect the pension distribution crisis π»π : The increase in life expectancies in Singapore affects the pension distribution crisis 13 Fertility rates are defined as birth rates per female (Blake & Mayhew 2006). The dramatic increase on population ageing due to longer life expectancies is concurrent to a decrease in fertility rates. Thus, the replacement level of young – to – old needed for the sustainability of old age pensions becomes problematic. Taken differently, declining birth rates per woman results to fewer workers contributing to the pensions system; and labor force participation of the young workers would be relatively lower (Hogler& Hunt III, 2008). Thus, the decline in fertility rates raises the ratio of the elderly to the working age (Brooks, 2005). There are several factors that affect the decline of total fertility rates and one of which is the higher participation rates of women. Women were underrepresented in the labor market. These women were mostly found in the informal sector and this displays inequality in labor outcomes (Caceres – Delpiano, 2012). But now, more women are given brighter opportunities in their career and changes in preferences must have increased the female participation rate too (Euwals, Knoef, & van Vuuren, 2011). The increase of female participation in the labor market occurs when females consider the opportunity cost of income foregone from disregarding paid employment. Another form of opportunity cost is the career path the female worker has set for herself. She forgoes future higher income, recognition and awards, and other benefits. These females would put off having children when opportunity cost is relatively higher (Mishra, Nielsen, & Smyth, 2010). The increase in female employment induces the female worker to delay her childbearing which causes the decline in fertility rates (Caceres – Delpiano, 2012). In addition, they have greater control over their fecundity (Cesaratto, 2006). Since more women are now participating in the labor force, women’s role has changed. 14 As times have changed, family ties and work for women became more optional as well. The fertility decision – in short – offers a negative impact on the increase of female participation (Caceres – Delpiano, 2012). Moreover, the choice between the two results to a trade – off. Since this is the case, this leads to lower levels of fertility. The introduction of family planning contributed much to the decline as couples have used such method during the formation of their family. The dramatic decline of fertility rates – in effect – causes demographic transitions too or what can be referred to as a ‘demographic dividend’ (Blake & Mayhew, 2006). The impact poses a great threat to Asia since 60% of the world’s population is Asians (Goh, 2005). π»0 : The declining fertility rates in Singapore do not affect the pension distribution crisis π»π : The declining fertility rates in Singapore affect the pension distribution crisis The impact of new medical technologies (NMT’s) in Asia has increased the financial insolvency in their healthcare systems. This is due to the insurgence of high demand for technologically advanced medicine and medical services of the receiving population. The high demand for medical care services and healthcare is due to the increased awareness of the benefits of better health status (Grosskopf, Self, & Zaim, 2006; Sheiner, 2007) and creation of wider access to health care systems (Sheiner, 2007). In addition, medical advances have contributed much in the decline of mortality rates. There are two contradicting theories that matter on the mortality of persons. The theory on compression of morbidity – disabilities would appear at shorter periods before death – suggests that medical progress and healthier lifestyles cause a fall in mortality rates (Shiu& Chiu, 2008; Espigares, Torres, & Munoz, 2008). States with lower mortality rates lead to healthier populations (Thornton & Rice, 2008). This confirms the 15 importance of societal health which is growing than ever (Shaw, Horrace, & Vogel, 2005). The theory on expansion of morbidity – reduction of risk associated with healthier lifestyles – explains the zero effect of appreciable health gains to the elderly, which is also true since more of the elderly experience old age sickness and diseases (Shiu & Chiu, 2008; Espigares, Torres, & Munoz, 2008). The deterioration of health of the elderly means more medical costs to incur especially for the cohort ages 65 and above as compared to lower cohorts (Thornton & Rice, 2008). As a result, the disability prevalence of these workers reacts negatively to the fall of mortality rates (Espigares, Torres, & Munoz, 2008). This also proves to generate adverse consequences on the funding of pension schemes since pensioners would have to pay longer. Relatively speaking, older workers would consume more of health care than with younger workers since they are more exposed to health problems (Shaw, Horrace, & Vogel, 2005; Sheiner, 2007). Many believe that health care expenditures rise along with life expectancy. However, research has found that population ageing is not the primary factor of rising health care expenditures. Rather, it highlights the time of death and health status of these workers which is explained by mortality rates. In fact, most empirical evidence suggests that longevity or longer lives of people does not necessarily entail higher health care expenditures. It is argued that economic development is the root cause of such longer natural life spans and medical progress (Shiu& Chiu, 2008). This simply means that there are improvements in mortality risk because of the technological advancement in medical technology. 16 An individual has two stages in life: working period and retirement period. This is important to note in understanding the declining mortality rates of workers. This is shown when the certain worker chooses a health investment on the first or second stage. If health investment was placed on the preceding stage, it is imperative to conclude that this worker would reduce his or her probability of death and thus, improve his mortality. If the health investment of the worker is placed on the second period, then he or she becomes less susceptible to chronic diseases since the worker has benefited from the fruits of more efficient medical technology. These fruits are known to be the worker’s resiliency against sickness and better health. These both contribute to the decline of mortality risk (Zhang, Zhang & Leung, 2006). Much of the pension providers use mortality tables to calculate scheme valuations for the retiring workers. Mortality tables are set out on the probability of the certain worker’s death period. These tables are based on historical data on death rates (Byrne & Winter, 2009; Espigares, Torres, & Munoz, 2008) and unfortunately, mortality assumptions are considerably underestimated (Blake, 2000; Byrne & Winter, 2009). π»0 : The declining mortality rates in Singapore do not affect the pension distribution crisis π»π : The declining mortality in Singapore affects the pension distribution crisis In totality, the pension distribution crisis is further intensified by the differing factors of: unexpected increases in the life expectancies of workers where many workers fear that they are not saving enough for retirement. The continuing decline of fertility rates due to the increased participation rate of women in the labor force since there would be less of resources to pass on to 17 retiring workers since there would be relatively fewer marginal additions to the working – age population. The declining mortality rates of workers make people less susceptible to chronic diseases because of the innovation of medical technology due to its high demand. Apparently, these workers fear of old age poverty considering too of longer pension payments and high medical costs. This is known to be the cases of OECD and other developed countries in the world where pensions systems are known to be inadequate in coverage. Hence, the researchers came to test if this is also true for Singapore that happens to find difficulties in their pension distribution. 18 Simulacrum – Figure 1. Life Expectancy (+) Fertility Rates (-) Pension Distribution Crisis (-) Mortality Rates 19 Research Method Censored Normal Regression (Tobit) Model: Maximum Likelihood Method π∗ , ππ = { π π, ππ π∗π > π ππ π∗π ≤ π π∗π = π + πΈ′ π³ππππ¬πππππππππππ + πππ π∗π = π + πΈ′ π΄πππππππππΉπππππ + πππ π∗π = π + πΈ′ ππππππππππΉπππππ + πππ Where: π∗π = Required sufficient amount of pensions (in constant LCU) πΎ ′ π₯ = Vector of regression coefficients on independent variables, x i = ith country observation t = tth time observation Econometric Model: In this model, the variable of interest, π∗π is left – censored at zero. Left – censoring indicates that all values that fall below or from the left of 0 will be cut – off. When the latent variable takes up the value of 0, it is therefore, left - censored while values taking up 1 are still observed and therefore, are uncensored. Binary values (0, 1) represent our latent variable. Thus, πΎ = max(0|π¦ ∗ ). These values have been used as an indicator wherein 1 = Pension Distribution Crisis or 0 otherwise 20 (See Appendix I; pp.29-30). The required sufficient amount of pensions (in constant LCU) is solved through the use of Singapore’s current pension structure. In order to properly determine whether pensions accrued for future consumption is sufficient; retirement income must equal or go beyond Singapore’s living standards (See Appendix I; pp.29-30). This makes life more promising for the retiree in financial and social security terms. Pension computations were patterned to Singapore’s current pension system as reference for the binary values (See Appendix I; pp.29-30). Therefore, if pensions computed fall below the required amount for sufficient retirement income, then it will take up the value of 1 as this indicates that pensions received by current and future retirees is and will experience pension distribution crisis. If pensions computed exceed the required amount for sufficient retirement income, then it states otherwise. Thus, pensions are compared to Singapore’s GDP per capita or prices (constant, LCU) of Singapore’s living standards. This is a useful indicator of standard of living or quality of life. Its significance is deemed necessary to understand how the current pension structure becomes obsolete and thus, creates an air of old age financial insecurity. Life Expectancy is defined as expected number of years of life of the worker which quantifies for Life Expectancy. Fertility rate is defined as birth per woman during her reproductive years which quantifies for Female Participation Rate. Mortality rate is defined as incidence of death in a population which quantifies for Medical Care. Maximum Likelihood (ML) is more appropriate since OLS estimates can cause bias in interpretation and can provide inconsistent estimates of the parameters. The time – series, t, and 21 cross section data, π, were gathered from year 1960 – 2011 for Singapore – where pension distribution crisis is arguably evident and troubling. The data were taken from IndexMundi, and Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States. In order to simplify the process of determining pensions, several basic assumptions must be formulated: a.) the retiree is eligible and entitled to receive pensions - This means the pensioner for Singapore has passed all qualifications necessary for pension entitlement and eligibility b.) Pensioner has started accumulating resources at the age of 35 years old up to the retirement age of 55 years old. 35 years old is the youngest age necessary for eligibility and pension entitlement. 55 years old is the retirement age mandated by each of the country’s social security laws - This information is useful in pension computations for Singapore’s Defined Contribution scheme 22 Results and Discussions Singapore uses 3 types of accounts: Ordinary Accounts, Special Accounts, and Medisave Accounts. Ordinary Accounts can be used for housing and investment schemes, Medisave Accounts can be used for hospitalization expenses and catastrophic health insurance while the Special Accounts can be used solely on retirement and other purposes. The pensioners can choose among the 3 types depending on their preferred contribution rate or where their pensions are credited to based solely on the pensioner’s level of preference (See Appendix II: Table1A; p.31). Thus, the final pensions accrued do not depend on whether it should be under an Ordinary, Special, or Medisave account. It simply states that under any of the 3 accounts, there is a certain credit rate from the estimated contributions for each age bracket. I. Ordinary Accounts, Special Accounts, and Medisave Accounts Pensioners who have invested in an Ordinary Account, Special Account, and Medisave Account are all collectively reflected in the regression outputs (See Appendix III: Fig.2A, Fig.2B, & Fig.2C; pp.32-33). Tobit coefficients are all statistically significant at 5%. Analysis and Interpretation Life Expectancy Life expectancy positively affects our latent variable, which is the required sufficient amount of pensions (in constant LCU) that will cover the pensioners from financial insecurity. In the case of Singapore, for every 1 year increase in the life expectancy of a Singaporean pensioner who invests in any of the 3 accounts, there is a corresponding 0.267030 Singaporean dollar 23 increase required to sufficiently cover the pensioners’ future. The intercept, on the other hand, negatively affects our latent variable. This is the case when the regressor, LE, is equated to zero. With this, there is no need for an increase of -20.40154 Singaporean dollars. Simply stated, when a Singaporean is not expected to live (LE = 0), then there is no needed requirement of an additional -20.40154 Singaporean dollars. Cohort differences in the CPF coverage are important. Table 2A (Appendix IV; p.34) clearly depicts that during 2012; 30% of the age bracket 56 – above are actually covered by the CPF as compared to 18% of the age bracket 31 – 40. However, this is not truly the case because the active CPF members depicted in Table 2B (Appendix IV; p.34) clearly shows that only 18% of the age brackets 56 – 60 and 60 – above are truly covered and are actively contributing against 26% of the age bracket 31 – 40. In connection to CPF savings shown in table 4 (Appendix IV; p.36), 30.7% of the elderly has accumulated less than the ordinary wage ceiling of S$5,000 while 24.9% have none at all (See Appendix IV: Table 4; p.36). Because of low coverage rates among the elderly, this will result to low reliability on the CPF savings overtime. Fertility Rates and Mortality Rates Fertility rates and Mortality rates negatively affect our latent variable, which is the required sufficient amount of pensions (in constant LCU) that will cover the pensioners from financial insecurity. In the case of a Singaporean pensioner who invests in any of the 3 accounts, for every 1 increase in birth per woman and 1 increase in incidence of death, a -4.815733 and 1.634027 Singaporean dollar is not needed respectively (See Appendix III: Fig.2B, & Fig.2C; pp.32-33). The intercepts of Fertility Rates and Mortality Rates, on the other hand, both positively affect our latent variable. This is the case when the regressors, LOG(FR) and 24 LOG(MR), are both equated to zero. With this, there is a need for an increase of 2.158468 and 2.411387 Singaporean dollars respectively. Simply stated, when there are no births per female during her reproductive years(LOG(FR) = 0) and no incidence of death (LOG(MR) = 0) in Singapore, then there is a needed requirement of an additional 2.158468 and 2.411387 Singaporean dollars respectively. Because of low replacement levels due to a decline in the fertility rates, the continuous decline exacerbates the ratio of the elderly to the working age. This is depicted in figure 3 (See Appendix IV; p.36) where the increasing old age dependency ratio also leads to the decreasing support ratio as well. Since less of workers are entering the labor force, then there are less of workers contributing to the pension systems. A smaller resource base unfortunately, makes pensions relatively more expensive. This can also be portrayed in table 5 (Appendix IV; p.37) where the total median age in Singapore has risen and is projected to further increase until 2030. Because of this, Singapore will continue to experience a demographic dividend. Singaporeans continue to put emphasis on better health status that leads to a growing demand for new medical technologies (NMT’s) and its continuous innovation shown in table 6 (Appendix IV; p.37). Because of this thinking, pensioners face to live a life full of old age disease and sickness (theory on expansion of morbidity) or an extended healthier life (theory on compression of morbidity). Figure 4 (Appendix IV; p.38) also shows Singapore’s rising total health expenditure. In addition, Singapore’s healthcare systems place the responsibility of ensuring better health on the pensioner through the Medisave account (if chosen). This is also known as the national medical savings scheme where 80% of primary care is delivered by private practitioners while the remaining 20% is provided by public polyclinics. However, 25 hospital care is mainly delivered by public hospitals (80%) while the remaining 20% is delivered by private hospitals. 26 V. Conclusions and Recommendations A step forward for the Singaporean pension system is to analyze the labor market attachment of their workers. This can provide one solution to address its inadequate pension coverage. If Singaporean workers tend to keep their jobs up until their retirement then it would be best to use a Defined Benefit scheme since pensioners would accumulate more of resources. If Singaporean workers tend to shift from one job to another (job portability), then it would be wise to use a Defined Contribution scheme since job portability losses here do not take any effect. The Singaporean government needs to address the longevity risk associated with retirement. Apparently, there is less emphasis on how rapid Singaporeans spend their accumulated balances. There is significance in knowing since if the pensioner has too few of resources due to longer life then there is a need to address the income received especially by the older workers. On average, women live longer than men yet they experience lower exposure in the labor market and receive relatively lower income as well. In this case, gender equality plays a huge part. This policy relates to delaying the formal effective retirement age from 55 – 65 years old. With this, formal discussions will arise between the employer and employee regarding the terms and conditions on work and employment. Because there would be more of elderly workers, workplace arrangements and services should then be conducive for them as well. Social risk pooling arrangements is one way for Singapore’s pension structure to cover all pensioners from different socio – economic and demographic classes. This means creating public pension systems that is available for Singaporeans of different walks in life. In order to induce female workers not to delay their childbearing in the short run, it is imperative for Singapore to provide family – friendly services and workplace environments 27 through financial incentives. This means that workplace policies and other discussions that may arise between the employer and the female worker relating to this matter should be formally given attention to. In order for female workers to be further encouraged in childbearing in the short run, daycare centers, childcare centers, and other infant and children – based services should be considered. Since childcare centers are privately – run, these centers become expensive and thus, add up to their cost of living. In order to help ease the financial burden, the government may subsidize for a certain period of time as well under licensed infant care and childcare centers. Since Singaporeans do place a huge value on staying healthy and having healthier lifestyles, unfortunately and even so, healthcare systems are actually relatively more expensive to the elderly as compared to younger workers. This is the case since the elderly consume more of these goods than the younger population. There is an increase in the use of Medisave Accounts and other elderly – based schemes like ElderShield Accounts. However, not much attention is given to these since most of the pensioners choose the Ordinary Accounts where housing and investment schemes take place (See Appendix, Tables 3A & 3B; p.35). Therefore, our 1st policy will focus on expanding medical services in order for ‘medical accounts’ to be more competitive in nature. The Singaporean government should issue more licenses to approved institutions or qualified institutions of medical services and the like to make healthcare systems more affordable and more redistributive to all Singaporeans. At the same time, the Singaporean government should continue to fund medical research in order to combat popular and deadly old age diseases. In this case, top old age diseases will be shouldered under Medisave accounts and similar accounts. This will meet the demand of the elderly who are experiencing old age diseases who are users of Medisave accounts. The 2nd policy will focus on the estimated actuaries where 28 annuitants buy life annuities. This is needed in order to reduce the adverse selection bias connected to mortality rates. The Singaporean government should also consider the mortality rates between a male and a female since there are certain health risks and lifestyles that are distinctive between the two categories. 29 References Population Division of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the UN Secretariat. World population prospects: the 2005 revision highlights. Retrieved July 2012, from http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/wpp2005/ wpp2008_highlights.pdf World Health Organization. The World Health Report 1998. Retrieved July 2012, from http://www.who.int/inf-pr-1998/en/pr98-WHA4.html. Chongsuvivatwong, et. al. (n.d.). Health and Healthcare Systems in Southeast Asia. United Nations University. Retrieved July 2012, from http://unu.edu/publications/articles/health-andhealthcare-systems-in-southeast-asia.html. Women’s Empowerment & Reproductive Health. Labour Force Participation & Employment. Retrieved July 2012, from http://web.unfpa.org/intercenter/cycle/labour.htm. Park, D. & Estrada, G. (2012). Pension Systems and Old-Age Income Support in East and Southeast Asia. Overview and Reform Directions. Routledge publisher. 30 Bibliography Banks, J., Blundell, R., &Emmerson, C. (2005). The Balance Between Defined Benefit, Defined Contribution, and State Provision. Journal Of The European Economic Association, 3(2/3), 466476. Bardasi, E., & Jenkins, S. P. (2010).The Gender Gap in Private Pension. Bulletin Of Economic Research, 62(4), 343-363. Blake, D. (2000). Does It Matter What Type of Pension Scheme You Have? Economic Journal, 110(461), F46-F81. Blake, D., & Mayhew, L. (2006).On The Sustainability of the UK State Pension System in the Light of Population Ageing and Declining Fertility.Economic Journal, 116(512), F286-F305. Bongaarts, John. (2004). Populations Aging and the Rising Cost of Public Pensions.Population and Development Review, Vol. 30, (No. 1), pp. 1-23. Bong-Min, Y. (2009).The Future of Health Technology Assessment in Healthcare Decision Making in Asia. Pharmacoeconomics, 27(11), 891-901. Bredt, S. (2008). Between labour market and retirement pension — flexible transition as a new paradigm for ageing societies?. International Social Security Review, 61(4), 95-112. Brodjonegoro, Bambang; Simanjuntak, Robert. (2002). Pension Plan in Indonesia: Avenues for Reform. HitotsubashiJournal of Economics, 43(2): pp. 151-162. Brooks, Sarah M. (2005). Interdependent and Domestic Foundations of Policy Change: The Diffusion of Pension Privatization around the World. International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 49(No. 2), pp. 273-294. Brugiavini, A., Maser, K., & Sudén, A. (2005). Measuring Pension Wealth. Journal of Pension Measurement. Byrne, A., &Winter, N. (2009). Living with longevity. Pensions: An International Journal, 14(2), 115-127. Cáceres-Delpiano, J. (2012). Can We Still Learn Something From the Relationship Between Fertility and Mother's Employment? Evidence From Developing Countries. Demography, 49(1), 151-174. Cebula, R., & Coombs, C. (2008).Recent Evidence on Factors Influencing the Female Labor Force Participation Rate. Journal Of Labor Research,29(3), 272-284. 31 Cesaratto, S. (2006). Pensions in an ageing society: a symposium. Review Of Political Economy, 18(3), 295-299. Cohen, C. (1983). The Impact on Women of Proposed Changes in the Private Pension System: A Simulation. Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 36(2), 258-270. Creedy, J., &Scobie, G. M. (2005).Population Ageing and Social Expenditure in New Zealand. Australian Economic Review, 38(1), 19-39. De Nardi, M., French, E., & Jones, J. (2009).Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings. American Economic Review, 99(2), 110-115. Dordea, S. & Popovici, V. (2008). The Different Impact of Pension Reform on Women and Men. Awards Of the Oradea, Economic Science Series, 17(1), 294-287. Duval, Romain.(2003). The Retirement Effects of Old-age Pension and Early Retirement Schemes and OECD Countries. OECD Economic Studies, Vol. 2003 (No. 2), p7-50. Eaton, T. V., &Nofsinger, J. R. (2008).Funding Levels and Gender in Public Pension Plans. Public Budgeting & Finance, 28(3), 108-128. Engelhardt, G. V. (2002). Pre-Retirement Lump-Sum Pension Distributions and Retirement Income Security: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Study. National Tax Journal, 55(4), 665-685. Espigares, J., Torres, E., & Muñoz, T. (2008).Population Ageing, Dependency and Healthcare Services Utilisation. Estudios De EconomíaAplicada, 26(2), 1-30. Euwals, R., Knoef, M., & van Vuuren, D. (2011). The trend in female labour force participation: what can be expected for the future?.Empirical Economics, 40(3), 729-753. Even, W. E., & MacPherson, D. A. (1994).Gender Differences in Pensions. Journal Of Human Resources, 29(2), 555-587. Everness, G. (2001). The Effect on Pensions of Increasing Life Expectancy. Journal Of Pensions Management, 7(2), 178. Frericks, P. H., & Maier, R. M. (2008). Pension norms and pension reforms in Europe - the effects on gender pension gaps. Community, Work & Family, 11(3), 253-271. Frericks, P., Knijn, T., & Maier, R. (2009).Pension Reforms, Working Patterns and Gender Pension Gaps in Europe. Gender, Work & Organization, 16(6), 710-730. Friedberg, L., & Webb, A. (2005).Retirement and the Evolution of Pension Structure. Journal Of Human Resources, 40(2), 281-308. 32 Friedberg, L., Owyang, M. T., & Sinclair, T. M. (2006).Searching For Better Prospects: Endogenizing Falling Job Tenure and Private Pension Coverage. B.E. Journal Of Economic Analysis & Policy: Topics In Economic Analysis & Policy, 6(1), 1-40. Ghilarducci, T. (2010).The future of retirement in aging societies.International Review Of Applied Economics, 24(3), 319-331. Goh, Victor HH. (2005). Aging in Asia: A cultural, socio-economical and historical perspective. Department of Obstetrics and Gynaecology, National University of Singapore, National University Hospital, Singapore, Vol. 8, No. 2 , Pages 90-96. Grosskopf&ThickSpace;, S. S., Self&ThickSpace;, S. S., &Zaim, O. O. (2006). Estimating the efficiency of the system of healthcare financing in achieving better health. Applied Economics, 38(13), 1477-1488. Guralnik, J. M., Alecxih, L., Branch, L. G., & Wiener, J. M. (2002). Medical and Long-Term Care Costs When Older Persons Become More Dependent. American Journal Of Public Health, 92(8), 1244-1245. Gyu-Jin, H. (2007). The Rules of the Game: The Politics of National Pensions in Korea. Social Policy & Administration, 41(2), 132-147. Hashimoto, K., &Tabata, K. (2010).Population aging, health care, and growth. Journal Of Population Economics, 23(2), 571-593. Higuchi, T. (1977).Pensions in the Japanese rural sector. International Labour Review, 116(3), 315. Hogler, R. L., & Hunt III, H. (2008). Pension Reform in the United States: Lessons from the Italian Experience. Labor Law Journal,59(1), 26-39. Jean, S., Causa, O., Jiménez, M., &Wanner, I. (2010).Migration and Labour Market Outcomes in OECD Countries. OECD Journal: Economic Studies, 2010(1), 235-268. Johnson, J. M., & Williamson, J. B. (2006). Do universal non-contributory old-age pensions make sense for rural areas in low-income countries?International Social Security Review, 59(4), 47-65. Kapinos, K. (2009). On the Determinants of Defined Benefit Pension Plan Conversions. Journal Of Labor Research, 30(2), 149-167. Kaur, A. (2010). Labour migration in Southeast Asia: Migration Policies, LabourExploitation and Regulation. Journal Of The Asia Pacific Economy,15(1), 6-19. Kemnitz, A. (2003). Immigration, Unemployment and Pensions.Scandinavian Journal Of Economics, 105(1), 31-48. 33 Kemnitz, A. (2005). Discrimination and Resistance to Low-skilled Immigration. LABOUR: Review Of Labour Economics & Industrial Relations,19(2), 177-190. Kiosse, P., &Peasnell, K. (2009). Have changes in pension accounting changed pension provision? A review of the evidence. Accounting & Business Research (Wolters Kluwer UK), 39(3), 255-267. Krieger, T. (2004). Fertility rates and skill distribution in Razin and Sadka’s migration-pension model: A note. Journal Of Population Economics,17(1), 177-182. Krieger, T. (2008). Public pensions and return migration. Public Choice,134(3/4), 163-178. Lacomba, J. A., & Lagos, F. (2010).Immigration and Pension Benefits in the Host Country. Economica, 77(306), 283-295. Lagos, F., &Lacomba, J. (2005). The Role of Immigration in the Retirement Age Reform : A Theoretical Analysis. B.E. Journal Of Economic Analysis & Policy: Topics In Economic Analysis & Policy, 5(1), 1-20. Malhotra, N., & Witt, M. (2010). Determinants Of Financial And Retirement Planning: A Female Perspective. Journal Of Business & Economics Research, 8(6), 40-46. McKinnon, R. (2007). Dynamic social security: A framework for directing change and extending coverage. International Social Security Review,60(2/3), 149-168. Mishra, V., Nielsen, I., & Smyth, R. (2010). On the relationship between Female Labour Force Participation and Fertility in G7 Countries: Evidence from Panel Cointegration and Granger causality. Empirical Economics,38(2), 361-372. Mohan, R., &Mirmirani, S. (2008). An Assessment of OECD Health Care System Using Panel Data Analysis. Southwest Business & Economics Journal, 1621-35. Pestieau, P. (2003). Ageing, retirement and pension reforms. World Economy, 26(10), 1447-1457. Philip, L. J., & Gilbert, A. (2007). Low Income amongst the Older Population in Great Britain: A Rural/Non-rural Perspective on Income Levels and Dynamics. Regional Studies, 41(6), 735-746. Rammohan, A. (2004). Fertility Transition in South and Southeast Asia.ASEAN Economic Bulletin, 21(2), 183-197. Roberts, J., Rice, N., & Jones, A. (2010). Early Retirement Among Men in Britain and Germany: How Important is Health? Geneva Papers On Risk & Insurance - Issues & Practice, 35(4), 644667. 34 Salditt, F., Whiteford, P., &Adema, W. (2008).Pension reform in China.International Social Security Review, 61(3), 47-71. Serrano, F., Eguia, B., &Ferreiro, J. (2011). Public pensions' sustainability and population ageing: Is immigration the solution?InternationalLabour Review, 150(1/2), 63-79. Shaw, J. W., Horrace, W. C., & Vogel, R. J. (2005). The Determinants of Life Expectancy: An Analysis of the OECD Health Data. Southern Economic Journal, 71(4), 768-783. Sheiner, L. (2007). The Effects of Technology on the Age Distribution of Health Spending: A Cross-Country Perspective. Public Finance & Management, 7(1), 44-72. Shih-Jiunn, S. (2006). Left to Market and Family – Again? Ideas and the Development of the Rural Pension Policy in China. Social Policy & Administration, 40(7), 791-806. Shiu, Y., & Chiu, M. (2008).Re-estimating the Demographic Impact on Health Care Expenditure: Evidence from Taiwan. Geneva Papers On Risk & Insurance - Issues & Practice, 33(4), 728-743. Simona-Luize, D., & Veronica, P. (2008).The Different Impact of Pension Reform on Women and Men. Annals Of The University Of Oradea, Economic Science Series, 17(1), 284-287. Sundali, J., Westerman, J. W., &Stedham, Y. (2008). The Importance of Stable Income Sources in Retirement: An Exploratory Study. Journal Of Behavioral & Applied Management, 10(1), 1846. Thornton, J. A., & Rice, J. L. (2008). Determinants of healthcare spending: a state level analysis. Applied Economics, 40(22), 2873-2889. Whitehouse, E. (2007). Life Expectancy Risk and Pensions: Who Bears the Burden? OECD Papers, 7(10), 1-45. Zhang, J., Zhang, J., & Leung, M. M. (2006).Health investment, saving, and public policy. Canadian Journal Of Economics, 39(1), 68-93. 35 Appendix I Tables of Statistical Figures, Regression Outputs, and Graphs Singapore Data Summary Year 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 Life Fertility Expectancy Rate, Total 65.66 5.45 66.09 5.26 66.43 5.20 66.70 5.01 66.91 4.85 67.09 4.70 67.26 4.50 67.45 3.95 67.67 3.56 67.95 3.25 68.28 3.09 68.66 3.04 69.07 3.05 69.48 2.80 69.89 2.36 70.27 2.08 70.62 2.11 70.93 1.82 71.21 1.76 71.45 1.79 71.68 1.74 71.91 1.72 72.16 1.71 72.45 1.61 72.78 1.62 73.16 1.61 73.60 1.43 74.07 1.62 74.57 1.96 75.08 1.75 75.58 1.87 76.05 1.77 76.48 1.76 76.86 1.78 76.30 1.75 76.40 1.71 Mortality Rate, Infant 35.60 33.60 31.80 30.20 28.80 27.50 26.30 25.10 24.00 22.90 21.70 20.30 18.70 17.20 15.90 14.70 13.90 13.10 12.40 11.90 11.50 11.00 10.50 9.90 9.30 8.80 8.30 7.80 7.30 6.70 6.10 5.50 5.00 4.60 4.30 4.10 36 GDP per Capita, constant, LCU 3,881 4,272 4,153 4,410 4,321 4,797 5,189 5,696 6,361 7,122 7,979 8,779 9,784 10,667 11,170 11,517 12,208 12,938 13,888 15,001 16,304 17,204 17,646 18,915 20,200 20,039 20,320 22,168 24,008 25,697 27,216 28,167 29,256 31,799 34,077 35,463 Accounts 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Pensions 848.13 1,848.13 2,848.13 3,848.13 4,848.13 5,848.13 6,848.13 7,848.13 8,848.13 9,848.13 10,848.13 11,848.13 12,848.13 13,848.13 14,848.13 15,848.13 16,848.13 17,848.13 18,848.13 19,848.13 20,848.13 21,848.13 22,848.13 23,848.13 24,848.13 25,848.13 26,848.13 27,848.13 28,848.13 29,848.13 30,848.13 31,848.13 32,848.13 33,848.13 34,848.13 35,848.13 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 76.75 77.05 77.40 77.55 78.05 78.35 78.70 79.04 79.49 79.99 80.14 80.44 80.79 81.24 81.64 81.89 1.70 1.64 1.49 1.48 1.60 1.41 1.37 1.27 1.26 1.26 1.28 1.29 1.28 1.22 1.15 1.20 3.80 3.60 3.40 3.10 2.90 2.70 2.60 2.40 2.40 2.30 2.30 2.20 2.20 2.10 2.10 2.00 Source: IndexMundi 37 36,647 38,452 36,361 38,307 41,053 39,500 40,785 43,287 46,664 48,939 51,588 53,866 51,943 49,906 56,269 57,801 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 36,848.13 37,848.13 38,848.13 39,848.13 40,848.13 41,848.13 42,848.13 43,848.13 44,848.13 45,848.13 46,848.13 47,848.13 48,848.13 49,848.13 50,848.13 51,848.13 Appendix II Singapore’s Defined Contribution Scheme Valuation Table 1A. Central Provident Fund (CPF) Contribution Rates and Allocation Rates Employee Age (Years) Contribution Rate (Ordinary wage ceiling: S$5,000) Total Employer Employee (% of wage) (% of wage) Contribution 35 – below 36 – 45 46 – 50 51 – 55 55 – 60 60 – 65 65 – above 16 16 16 14 10.5 7 6.5 20 20 20 18.5 13 7.5 5 Credited to (% of wage) Ordinary Account (% of wage) Special Account (% of wage) Medisave Account (% of wage) 36 36 36 32.5 23.5 14.5 11.5 23 21 19 13.5 12 3.5 1 6 7 8 9.5 2 1.5 1 7 8 9 9.5 9.5 9.5 9.5 Sources: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg Equation: (employee – employer contribution in current year) x (no. of years contributing) x (adjustment factor)* *adjustment factor: assumed rate of return on the contributions and also adjusts for the growth in contributions over the years contributing Given: Ordinary Wage Ceiling: S$5,000 Adjustment Factor: 2.5% 0 = No PDC 1 = PDC where; Total Contributions > GDP per Capita = 0; Total Contributions < GDP = 1 Table 1B. CPF Contributions Credited to each Account for each Age Bracket Employee Age (Years) 35 – below Total Contributions per Age Bracket (S$) 1,845 36 – 45 18,450 46 – 50 9,225 51 – 55 8,328.125 Total 37,848.125 Ordinary Account (S$) Special Account (S$) Medisave Account (S$) 1,178.75 (23% / 36%) 10,762.5 (21% / 36%) 4,868.75 (19% / 36%) 3,459.375 (13.5% / 32.5%) 307.5 (6% / 36%) 3,587.5 (7% / 36%) 2,050 (8% / 36%) 2,434.375 (9.5% / 32.5%) 358.75 (7% / 36%) 4,100 (8% / 36%) 2,306.25 (9% / 36%) 2,434.375 (9.5% / 32.5%) Sources: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg 38 Appendix III Regression Outputs Figure 2A.Life Expectancy Figure 2B.Fertility Rates: log(fr) 39 Figure 2C. Mortality Rates: log(mr) 40 Appendix IV Life Expectancy, Fertility Rates, and Mortality Rates Tables and Figures Table 2A. Central Provident Fund (CPF) Members by Age Group Age Group (Years) Total Thousand 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 3,099.6 3,163.0 3,234.4 3,291.3 3,343.3 3,376.3 3,418.6 20 – below 21 - 25 26 – 30 31 – 35 94.5 197.2 249.8 303.5 105.5 198.0 256.5 299.8 104.5 210.3 265.3 299.4 101.3 214.8 271.4 303.4 106.0 220.5 267.8 305.1 110.4 229.4 257.6 301.8 112.8 236.6 252.6 303.7 36 – 40 41 – 45 46 – 50 336.2 416.7 410.6 334.2 404.7 417.9 336.6 389.8 425.0 340.0 372.5 428.2 335.6 359.4 425.7 333.9 349.6 419.6 326.8 346.6 407.3 51 – 55 56 – above Not Specified 336.8 727.5 26.8 349.2 770.9 26.3 359.6 818.1 25.8 369.5 864.8 25.4 379.3 919.0 24.8 384.9 965.2 24.1 390.5 1,018.1 23.7 *Includes self – employed persons who had made CPF contributions Source: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg Table 2B. Active CPF Members by Age Group Age Group (Years) Thousand 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1,461.9 38.9 107.1 193.2 217.6 1,545.0 44.0 108.2 200.9 220.0 1,610.1 40.5 110.3 207.8 222.8 1,644.6 38.9 109.7 211.7 227.5 1,700.4 43.9 115.5 209.3 231.1 1,735.4 42.5 118.6 202.2 229.4 1,788.8 45.7 122.4 199.8 232.2 36 – 40 41 – 45 46 – 50 203.1 201.0 183.0 213.3 206.7 191.6 222.4 209.0 198.0 229.3 208.0 201.8 232.0 210.6 206.9 234.3 214.0 210.4 233.2 220.9 212.6 51 – 55 56 – 60 60 – above Not Specified 144.0 95.4 78.7 - 157.3 105.9 97.0 - 168.1 116.1 115.0 - 174.2 122.3 121.3 - 182.7 132.0 136.2 - 188.1 142.6 153.3 - 194.4 153.9 173.5 - Total 20 – below 21 - 25 26 – 30 31 – 35 Source: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg 41 Table 3A. Withdrawals of Central Provident Fund by Type Withdrawals of Central Provident Fund by Type 2007 2008 2009 2010 Million Dollars 14,351 11,562 10,966 10,719 9,617 2006 2011 10,437 Totaπ₯π Housing Schemeππ 4,957 4,679 4,500 4,058 4,007 5,464 Public Housing 3,398 1,189 1,347 1,769 846 1,347 Residential Properties 2,357 2,404 2,061 1,800 1,771 1,940 Reached 55 Years of Agππ 391 436 443 455 506 Leaving Singapore & 367 Malaysia Permanentlπ² π 284 269 286 359 378 435 Death 445 517 558 601 678 722 Medisave Scheme 136 173 195 234 286 336 Private Medical Scheme 2,406 1,940 1,583 1,446 1,196 -312 Others Source: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg 2012 11,727 5,703 2,291 2,048 542 488 767 385 -497 Table 3B. Withdrawals of Central Provident Fund by Type (Numbers) Housing Schemeπ¬ π Public Housinπ π Residential Properties Reached 55 Years of Agππ Leaving Singapore & Malaysia Permanentlπ² π Death Withdrawals of Central Provident Fund by Type 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Number 2011 2012 12,904 40,576 11,059 48,512 15,016 32,355 15,349 47,222 14,154 49,617 37,608 43,560 46,690 46,789 274,246 204,808 189,610 199,552 207,868 227,540 245,645 10,479 10,848 11,130 12,255 13,454 14,619 15,038 23,358 17,075 17,258 19,802 18,544 19,869 18,472 Source: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg Notes: 1 – Refers to net amount withdrawn (gross amount withdrawn less amount refunded) by members in the year 2 – Includes first and subsequent withdrawals 3 – Includes Malaysians leaving Singapore permanently 4 – Includes withdrawals by persons who are physically / mentally incapacitated and under the various CPF schemes – Minimum Sum, Medishield, Home Protection, Dependants’ Protection, Education, Non – Residential Properties, Investment, Delgro Shares (ceased Feb 04), Special Discounted Shares and Eldershield Scheme 42 5 – Refers only to members who joined the scheme this year 6 – Data refer only to the increase in membership size for the year Table 4. Total CPF Savings at Age 55 among the Elderly who were Age 59 and above in 1999 Total CPF Savings (S$) 4,999 – below 5,000 – 9,999 10,000 – 19,999 20,000 – 29,999 30,000 – 39,999 40,000 – 49,999 50,000 – 99,999 100,000 – 149,999 150,000 – above None Total Percent 30.7 7.8 12.0 5.6 4.7 3.2 6.1 2.7 2.4 24.9 100.0 Source: 1999 Transitions in Health, Wealth, & Welfare of Elderly Singaporeans: 1995 – 1999; mycpf.cpf.gov.sg Figure 3. Singapore’s Dependency Ratios Singapore Dependency Ratios: 1960 - 2011 100 90 80 70 60 50 Support Ratio 40 Old - Age Dependency Ratio 30 20 10 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 0 Source: IndexMundi 43 Table 5. Median Age for Singapore (1911 – 2000) Census Year 1911 1921 1931 1947 1957 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 Median Age 28 28 26 23 19 20 24 29 34 37 39 41 Source: Singapore Census Population 2000 and the Inter – Ministerial Committee Report on Ageing Population (1999) Table 6. Medical Research in Singapore Medical Research Grants committed under National Medical Research Council (NMRC) ($M) % of Medical Research Grants: a. Enabling Grants / Centre / Program Grants1 b. Individual Research Grants c. Exploratory / Developmental Grants d. New Investigator Grants e. Singapore Translational Research (STaR) Investigator Awards 3 f. Talent Development 2 g. Enablers & Infrastructure h. Individual PI – Initiated Research Grants (inclusive of New Investigator Grants) i. Strategic Research Grant Programs FY 2006 53.5 FY 2007 125.7 FY 2008 94.4 FY 2009 121.3 FY 2010 95.0 FY 2011 116.0 FY 20πππ 213.4 57.9 22.3 30.7 21.0 10.0 - - 32.1 - 24.4 4.5 4.2 4.2 33.0 5.4 5.6 5.6 28.2 4.6 4.2 4.2 42.6 6.0 5.4 5.4 29.2 4.7 4.7 4.7 - 10 - 14.4 - 25.3 - 18.5 - 26.0 - 28.5 - 13.4 4.4 40.6 - - - - - - 37.1 - Source: Social Security Association: Office of Retirement and Disability Policy of the United States; moh.gov.sg/content/moh_web/home.html Notes: 1 – There was no commitment in FY2011 because NMRC is in the process of revamping the centre grants framework for the new tranche of funding (RIE2015) 2 – Awards are only given to established researchers (local & international). No award will be given if NMRC cannot find any suitable researchers 3 – Includes Clinician Scientific Award, Master Clinical Investigation, NMRC fellowship, etc. 4 – NMRC programs have ceased and transited to new funding initiatives FY2012 44 Figure 4. Health Expenditures (Thousands), PPP (Constant 2005, International $) in Singapore Helth Expenditure in Singapore 3000 In Thousands 2500 2000 Health Expenditure 1500 1000 500 Source: IndexMundi 45 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 0 ABOUT THE AUTHOR Princess Chezica T. Lao (tan_lao789@yahoo.com.ph) is currently a fourth year Business Economics student in the College of Commerce and Business Administration. She is a member of 3 organizations namely, Thomasian Writer’s Guild, UST Scarlet Commerce Organization, and UST – Economics Society. She had her internship program in the Philippine National Bank head office under the Corporate Planning and Economic Research Department where she had utilized her skills and knowledge that she acquired in UST. Carla Felize C. Cruz (carlafelizecruz@yahoo.com) is currently a fourth year Business Economics student in the College of Commerce and Business Administration. She was a Student Coordinator of the College of Commerce Student Council (2010-2011) and is a member of UST Scarlet Commerce Organization, RCYC Red Cross Youth Council, and UST Economics Society. She also offered her services in the Guidance Office as a Peer Facilitator. In addition, she took her internship at the Philippine National Bank where she had applied what she had learned from UST. EunHyun Kim (k_eunhyun@yahoo.com) is currently a fourth year Business Economics student in the College of Commerce and Business Administration. She finished her secondary education in Miriam College High School Quezon City (S.Y. 2010). She is a member to a total of three school organizations namely, The UST Economics Society, UST International Student Association, and UST Red Cross Youth Council. She had her practicum at the Philippine National Bank Delta branch where she had applied what she had learned from UST. 46 47