Individual vs. Group Randomized Trials Jens Ludwig University of Chicago, Brookings Institution and NBER Three things to consider • Realizing randomization • Power • Nature of the intervention Realizing randomization • “Should I randomize at the individual or the group level?” Realizing randomization • “Should I randomize at the individual or the group level?” • Sort of like asking: – Should I take my $30 million Powerball prize all at once, or spread it out in installments? Why are so many American public schools not performing better? • Four major hypotheses: – – – – Inadequate resources Inefficient production technologies (curriculum, etc.) Unmotivated teachers Unmotivated students • Education researchers usually can only randomize what they can pay for – Severely limits which of these we can study with randomized experimental designs of any sort Keep our eye on the prize • Our real goal has to be to convince governments to do more randomization – Tennessee STAR – Progressa • Even Roland Fryer w/ Eli Broad at his back is taking on just a modest slice (pay for grades) • First consideration: Choose unit to randomize you need to in order to be able to randomize The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” • City official: “Sure. We do pilot programs all the time.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • Me: “How do you decide who gets the pilot program if there is excess demand?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” • City official: “Sure. We do pilot programs all the time.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • Me: “How do you decide who gets the pilot program if there is excess demand?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” • City official: “Sure. We do pilot programs all the time.” • City official: “Good question.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • Me: “How do you decide who gets the pilot program if there is excess demand?” • Me: “Could we flip a coin, which would be the fair thing to do?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” • City official: “Sure. We do pilot programs all the time.” • City official: “Good question.” The rhetoric of randomization • Me: “Can we randomly assign the intervention?” • Me: “Well, could we do a pilot program?” • Me: “How do you decide who gets the pilot program if there is excess demand?” • Me: “Could we flip a coin, which would be the fair thing to do?” • City official in very large Midwestern city: “No way.” • City official: “Sure. We do pilot programs all the time.” • City official: “Good question.” • City official: “Ah, now I get it.” The rhetoric of randomization • Never use term “randomized experiment” The rhetoric of randomization • Never use term “randomized experiment” • Acceptable talking points: – “Pilot program” – “Excess demand” – “Fair, random lotteries” • If there would be a natural unit for doing “regular” pilot program, randomize that – I.e., we’d just be implementing an unusually informative pilot program – For many education interventions would seem to argue for group randomization (ex: pay for grades) Second consideration: Power • There is the standard statistics version: – More power from 1,000 kids distributed across 1,000 schools than 1,000 kids distributed across < 1,000 schools • Due to non-independence of student observations within schools Then there is the real-world version of this issue • We live in a resource-constrained world • Are there economies of scale in data collection? – Cluster randomization could reduce data collection costs for same reason that population surveys use two-phase sampling • Are there economies of scale in delivering the intervention itself? For a given budget, cluster randomization could in principle generate more power • Imagine rapidly declining marginal costs of “treating” and studying kids w/in a school – Suppose school-based self-administered student and teacher surveys plus use of student administrative school records – Suppose we have a DARE-like intervention (“Don’t do drugs kids, look what happened to me!”) Power considerations in a resource-constrained environment • It’s conceivable you could get more power out of a clustered sample of given size N, even with non-trivial intra-class correlations (ICCs) • Significant information requirements: – Need to know ICCs for your sample & outcome – Need school system to help you think about average cost & marginal cost schedules for intervention – Need very good survey subcontractor to help you think about economies of scale in data collection Power considerations • On the other hand, you can run out of observational units quickly in clustered experiments • Imagine randomizing schools: – Even in Chicago, “just” 116 high schools, 483 elementary schools – Imagine half of schools meet your eligibility criteria, then half of principals agree to cooperate in experiment, then you randomize half to T and C • That would be 14 treatment high schools, 14 controls • Or 60 treatment elementary schools, 60 controls Nature of the intervention • Previous two issues are shamelessly pragmatic • Individual vs. group choice could also hinge on substantive considerations Spillover effects • Stable unit treatment value (SUTVA): – Your treatment effect is independent of how many others get treated – If violated, then your treatment effect estimates generates only to situations with similar take-up rates • Sometimes you want to study intervention independent of these spillovers, while sometimes spillovers key part of treatment Spillover effects example: Moving to Opportunity (MTO) • Initial concerns: – Generic SUTVA concern – Groups of public housing families moving in to new areas might generate backlash – Also didn’t want families to recreate any unproductive baseline social ties • New concerns: – Families lose access to productive social ties, so should we have randomized in groups? Spillover effects example number 2 • Roland Fryer, paying kids for grades in Chicago, DC, NYC – Wants to change whole school climate around academic achievement • Generic adolescent (American?) antiintellectualism • Plus specific “acting white” concerns – Only by paying everyone (or offering to pay everyone) can you change peer norms (or try to change peer norms) Interventions as public goods • MTO suggests neighborhood safety key factor for parental mental health – Maybe for kids, too – Could also affect learning in other ways, too • If you reduce crime in neighborhood, every kid in neighborhood will benefit – This is sort of another way of talking about economies of scale in providing intervention Bottom lines • Clustered experiments might help realizing randomization • Power considerations complex in a resourceconstrained environment – Research community needs to develop infrastructure to meet informational requirements for decisions • Substantive considerations about role of spillovers and “public good” interventions • ‘Tis better to have randomized at the wrong level than to have never randomized at all?