Graduate employment and the returns to higher education in Africa Mahdi Barounia and Stijn Broeckeb a b Institute for Research in the Sociology and Economics of Education, University of Bourgogne, France Research Department, African Development Bank, Tunis, Tunisia Abstract In this paper, we estimate the return to higher education for 12 African countries using recent data and a variety of methods. Importantly, one of our methods adjusts for the effect of higher education on the rate of joblessness, which is substantial in most African countries, and particularly for women. Our results confirm that Mincerian coefficients cannot be interpreted as a true rate of return, and that the latter (even after taking into account the employment effect) is considerably lower than what has previously been suggested in the literature (less than half). For Sub-Saharan Africa, we also uncover an interesting relationship between a country’s level of education and the return to higher education: contrary to expectations, we find that in countries where a high proportion of the working age population is educated to tertiary level, the return to higher education is highest. JEL classification: I21, I23, J31 Key words: graduate unemployment, returns to education, higher education 1. Introduction Estimates of the return to higher education are a potentially useful tool for policy-makers. In England, for example, the increase in fees from September 2012 was largely defended on the grounds that the private returns to higher education are high: “The lifetime earnings of graduates are higher than those of non-graduates. The so-called graduate premium, net of tax, is still worth comfortably over £100,000 in today's money.”1 At the same time, a recent survey of the returns to higher education in Africa found that “an increasing amount of work needs to be done with respect to returns to higher education in SubSaharan Africa” (Diagne and Diene, 2011). The authors argue that most existing studies focus on a limited number of countries only, and that the data are frequently more than 15 years old. An initial objective of the present paper was therefore to fill this gap by looking at the return to higher education in a range of African countries using recent household and labour force survey data. This is one contribution this paper makes to the literature. 1 http://www.bis.gov.uk/news/speeches/david-willetts-guardian-he-summit A second contribution of the paper is that it adjusts these private rates of return to higher education by the likelihood of finding employment. As argued by Barceinas et al (2000) “increasing the educational level is profitable not only because this allows the more educated to obtain higher wages, but also because the more educated have a lower probability to become unemployed. As a consequence, the returns to education must be computed taking the unemployment probability into account.” Similarly, Colclough et al (2009) remark that the returns to education in developing countries are “typically not adjusted for unemployment among the educated”. Writing in the context of Europe, where unemployment decreases with education, Barceinas et al (2000) conclude that “unadjusted marginal rates of return to education present a general underestimation because the differentials in employment probability […] across levels of education are not taken into account”.2 In many African countries the unemployment rate for graduates is higher than for the working age population overall (top panel Figure 1). However, because of high rates of inactivity among people with lower levels of education, this is not true of the level of joblessness (bottom panel Figure 1), which is almost always lower among graduates. So, unlike in Europe, a complex relationship exists in Africa between the level of education and labour market outcomes. In nearly all countries analysed in this paper we find that the returns to higher education increase once the risk of joblessness is factored in. This effect is particularly strong for women. The analysis uncovered some other interesting findings. Most importantly, we show that the return to higher education varies widely with the method used for estimating it. In particular, we find that estimates of Mincerian coefficients are frequently higher than the true internal rate of return, and should therefore not be confounded with them. This calls for more caution and candidness by researchers in describing the methods that they use as well as in explaining the meaning of their estimates. We follow Heckman, Lochner and Todd (2008) in arguing that Mincerian coefficients should no longer be blindly (and often wrongly) presented as estimates of the “return to education”3. Finally, we find that the rate of return to higher education varies considerably across countries. Interestingly, we find that in countries where a high proportion of the working age population has a university qualification, the rate of return to higher education is the highest. 2 Similarly, in the case of Spain, Arrazola and de Hevia (2008) conclude that “an additional year of education not only means an increase in the average wage of employed individuals but also raises the probability of being employed”. 3 Similarly, Björklund and Kjellström argue that “the internal rate of return is one such measure [of the return to investment in schooling], but the wage premium is not”. Figure 1: Graduate unemployment and joblessness in Africa Unemployment 45% University All 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Guinea (1996) Sudan (2008) Egypt (2006) Sierra Leone (2004) Rwanda (2002) Uganda (2002) Mali (1998) Tanzania (2002) Senegal (2002) Kenya (1999) Ghana (2000) Malawi (2008) South Africa (2007) Tanzania (2002) Senegal (2002) Kenya (1999) Ghana (2000) Malawi (2008) South Africa (2007) Joblessness 70% University All 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Guinea (1996) Sudan (2008) Egypt (2006) Sierra Leone (2004) Rwanda (2002) Uganda (2002) Mali (1998) Source: Authors’ calculations based on Minnesota Population Center (2011). Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, International: Version 6.1 The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides a brief overview of the literature on the returns to higher education in Africa. Section 3 offers a discussion of the methodologies used for estimating the returns to education, their drawbacks and advantages. Section 4 describes the data that we use in our paper, and Section 5 presents the results from the analysis. Section 6 concludes. 2. Literature review Popular wisdom, influenced by the work of Psacharopoulos (1973, 1981, 1985, 1994) and Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2004a, 2007), has it that the returns to higher education in Africa are lower than those at lower levels of education. These findings have very much influenced donor investments in education across the continent, but have been criticised by a number of authors, including Bennell (1996) who questioned the quality of the data and analysis used in these studies, as well as Schultz (2003) who analysed data from six African countries and found that private returns were actually higher at secondary and post-secondary levels that at primary level. Since then, a large number of individual country studies have been published, and these have recently been reviewed by Diagne and Diene (2011). The studies they review for the period 2000-10 (ten studies for six countries) reveal an average rate of return to higher education of 19.0%. The estimates obtained by Colclough et al for four African countries average 26.0%, and their literature review suggests an average return of 22.7%. All these estimates are for one year of university education. Furthermore, Diagne and Diene (2011) conclude that the return to higher education is higher than for other levels of education (a finding confirmed by Kingdon et al, 2008; and Colclough et al, 2009), although it has been falling over time. As Diagne and Diene (2011) and others allude to, one obvious problem with the various estimates obtained in the literature is that there is very little consistency in the methods used to obtain them. There are issues about: how comparison groups are constructed; how higher education is defined; how wages, earnings or income are measured4; what control variables are included (if any); what type of data is used; etc… In addition to these relatively minor issues, there are more fundamental methodological concerns with the estimates obtained in the literature, with the majority of results reported not truly estimates of the “return to education”. This is the subject of the next section. 3. Methodology Although the return to education is a standard concept in the economics of education, there is little consistency in the approach used for estimating it. A variety of methods/measures exist, and researchers frequently use them interchangeably without necessarily being clear about what it is they are estimating, or about the limitations of the method they are applying. This section starts by setting out some of the methods used in the literature and ends by outlining the approach used in this paper. Method 1: “Elaborate” internal rate of return As with any other investment, the private rate of return to an investment in a given level of education is estimated by finding the rate of discount that equalises the stream of discounted benefits to the stream of costs at a given point in time. In the case of a university education lasting four years (and assuming a working life of 42 years), the formula is: 42 4 π‘=1 π‘=1 (πΈπ’ − πΈπ )π‘ ∑ = ∑(πΈπ )π‘ (1 + π)π‘ (1 + π)π‘ 4 (i) The choice of dependent variable is not innocuous. Wages are the pay per unit of time. Earnings are wages times the time worked. So earnings include both a wage as well as an employment effect. Because education also has an employment effect, the return to education using earnings tends to be higher than the return using wages (Karasiotou 2003). In this paper, where possible, we use earnings as a dependent variable. Where (Eu-Es) is the earnings differential between a university graduate (subscript u) and a secondary school graduate (subscript s). The right-hand side represents the opportunity cost of higher education (i.e. 4 years of foregone earnings at the level of what someone with secondary education would have earned). The right-hand side could also be augmented with other costs associated with education such as tuition fees. However, for the sake of simplicity and because most university systems in Africa do not charge fees, these will be left out in the analysis presented in this paper. Although this may not be realistic, it should be remembered that foregone earnings are the largest cost associated with a university education5. It is also worth pointing out that, although fees are left out of the calculation, so are grants, scholarships and bursaries which are common in many African countries, as well as any income that students may earn while studying. The internal rate of return (IRR) as defined above is calculated by building age-earnings profiles for both secondary school and university graduates (assuming no earnings for the first four years in the case of university graduates), differencing the two, and finding the discount rate that results in a 0 (zero) net present value of this net age-earnings profile. In practice, this “elaborate method” is very data intensive as sufficient observations are need to populate each age/qualification cell and construct well-behaved age-earnings profiles. This is rarely the case in African labour force or household surveys6 and so this method is generally impractical. One way around this problem is to estimate two simple earnings equations (one for secondary school and one for university graduates) with earnings as the dependent variable, and age and age squared as explanatory variables: log(ππππππππ ) = π½ + πππ + πππ 2 + π (ii) Using the coefficients of these regressions, smooth age-earnings profiles can be built for both secondary school and university graduates7. As before, no earnings are assumed for the first four years of those investing in a university education. Using these age-earnings profiles we can then calculate the internal rate of return as before. As in the case of the full/elaborate method, this method is rarely used in the literature. Method 2: Simple earnings function/Mincerian method In practice, many researchers have made use of the earnings function/Mincerian method (Mincer 1958; 1974) to estimate the returns to education. This is primarily due to its simplicity: 5 Recent estimates of the rates of return to tertiary education across the OECD suggest that that, in the OECD, direct costs represent around 22% of the overall estimated costs of attending higher education – the remainder being made up by foregone earnings (OECD, 2012). 6 As shown in Table 1, the number of observations with tertiary education is rarely more than a few hundred. 7 Another option is to estimate the earnings profiles non-parametrically using local linear regressions (as in Heckman (2005) who use local linear regression). log(ππππππππ ) = π½0 + π½1 π»πΈ + ππ₯ππππππππ + ππ₯ππππππππ 2 + π (iii) In this equation, experience is frequently replaced by age and other explanatory variables (like sex) are added to the right hand side – although the inclusion of such variables is not innocuous as many (e.g. sector of employment, marital status, number of children, region) may be considered endogenous and so should not be included in the regression8. The equation above would be run on a sub-sample of individuals with secondary and tertiary education only, and so the coefficient β1 would identify the effect on earnings of having a higher education qualification9. Frequently, the estimate is then converted into an annual return by dividing by the number of years of higher education. Most research using the Mincerian method interprets the coefficient on HE as the return to higher education, and uses it as a substitute for the IRR calculated through the method described previously. Heckman, Lochner and Todd (2008) criticise this interpretation and argue that many strong assumptions are required to claim that estimates of β1 accurately measure the internal rate of return. One obvious difference with the two methods described previously is that the Mincerian equation assumes no loss of working life with additional years of schooling, so that the coefficient β1 is more accurately interpreted as the earnings premium or mark-up associated with a higher education qualification than as a rate of return. Psacharopoulos (1994) uses numerous empirical studies to show that earnings’ functions and the elaborate method yield very similar results – however Heckman, Lochner and Todd (2008) reach a different conclusion, and so do we in this paper. Method 3: The “short-cut” method In addition to the methods described above, Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2004b) describe a “short-cut” method for calculating the rate of return which does not rely on the availability of individual data. The formula used is simply: ππππ£ππ‘π πππ‘π’ππ = πΈπ’ − πΈπ 4πΈπ (iv) Where πΈπ’ are the average earnings of those with a university qualification, and πΈπ the average earnings of someone with just secondary schooling. The denominator represents the opportunity cost of an investment in higher education (i.e. four years of earnings at the level of 8 Pereira and Martins (2004) address this issue in detail. They show why considering a number of educationdependent covariates in a wage equation decreases the coefficient of education in that equation and argue for the use of a simple specification of the Mincer equation for the study of the total returns to education. 9 Halvorsen and Palmquist (1980) and Kennedy (1981) point out that, in semilog models in which discrete variables are used as regressors, the percentage change in the level of the dependent variable is not equal to the coefficient of the dummy multiplied by 100, as is the case of continuous variables. Instead, the appropriate measure for the proportional effect on the outcome variable is exp(β)-1. a secondary school graduate10). Although simple, the method has clear drawbacks in that it assumes flat age-earnings profiles and no discounting of earnings that occur later in life. Accounting for the risk of joblessness Given that education has both an impact on earnings as well as the likelihood of employment, it is surprising that very few estimates in the literature have factored in the risk of joblessness in estimating the returns to higher education. In countries with low rates of joblessness, this is perhaps understandable, but in Africa, where the level of joblessness frequently ranges between 20% and 60% of the working age population (Figure 1), this would seem a major omission. One contribution of this paper is that we adjust the estimates of the return to higher education by the risk of joblessness. In practice, we calculate the adjusted internal rate of return by generating age-expected earnings profiles. We predict age-earnings profiles using equation (ii) above. In addition, however, we simulate age-employment profiles using a logit regression of the following form: employment = π½ + πππ + πππ 2 + π (v) At each age, we then weight the predicted earnings by the predicted likelihood of being in employment at that age in order to derive an age-expected earnings profile. We do this separately for those with secondary and those with tertiary qualifications. Ability bias Much of the recent literature on returns to education has been dedicated to tackling ability bias in estimating the return to schooling. As early as 1964, Denison (1964) expressed scepticism about the causal effect of schooling on earnings, arguing that observed differences in earnings between education groups are more likely to reflect inherent ability differences rather than true productivity differentials. Generally, it is believed that the correlation between schooling and earnings obtained through OLS overstates the true causal effect of education. A standard solution to this problem is instrumental variables estimation and a large literature has developed using instruments such as the minimum school leaving age, the geographic proximity of schools, etc… Generally, this literature has found that OLS under- rather than overestimates the return to schooling. One potential explanation for this finding advanced by Card (2001) is that these estimates are frequently obtained using structural changes in schooling systems (for example a raising of the school-leaving age) which affect more marginal students for whom the return to schooling might be higher. 10 Note that Psacharaopoulos and Patrinos (2004b) divide by the average earnings of those with a university education. However, it appears more realistic to assume that, without a university qualification, those currently studying could only command average earnings equal to those with just a secondary school qualification. In this paper, we do not attempt to tackle the issue of ability bias. Although instrumental variables methods have proved useful in trying to establish the causal effect of schooling on earnings, they suffer from the same drawback as outlined above for the Mincer equation: except under very restrictive assumptions, they do not estimate rates of return to schooling, nor are they designed to (Heckman, Lochner and Todd, 2005). Given that instrumental variable estimates have generally been found to be larger than standard OLS estimates, and that the OLS estimates we obtain are already considerably larger than the ones obtained through our nonparametric IRR method, this omission does not detract from the main arguments made in this paper. Summary Before turning to a description of the data, we briefly summarise the methodologies employed in this paper. We estimate the return to higher education using four different methods: (1) simple Mincerian earnings functions as in equation (iii) – with experience replaced by age; (2) the short-cut method (equation (iv)); (3) the IRR using simple earnings functions as in equation (ii); and the IRR adjusted for employment probabilities. Across all countries and estimation methods we attempt to be consistent in the definition of variables and assumptions used. We define the working age population as those aged 15-64. We restrict our sample to those with tertiary and, where possible, academic secondary education only. Only the latter are included as we aim to generate a control group of individuals who had the potential to go on to university (but this is not always feasible). Tertiary education includes everything from diplomas and degree through to postgraduate qualifications (masters and doctorates)11. This was a pragmatic decision in view of the small sample sizes of higher educated individuals encountered in most African household and labour force surveys. We ignore selection issues, and do not include any additional explanatory variables in our regressions (although we do estimate the returns separately for men and for women). We also ignore taxes, benefits, tuition fees and scholarships. On the other hand, in our IRR calculations, we assume foregone earnings for a period of four years, equivalent to the average earnings for those whose highest qualification is upper secondary education. Finally, our measure of earnings will depend on the survey employed, but we have tried to focus on earnings from the primary occupation where possible (i.e. excluding benefits). Also note that, in order to avoid estimation problems induced by outlier values, we trim our dataset by removing the top and bottom percentile of earnings.12 11 Note that, where possible, we focus on qualifications obtained rather than on years of education. There is evidence that qualifications, and not years of education, drive the returns to education (Dickson and Smith, 2011). 12 Annex A provides further detail on the exact variables and definitions used. 4. Data Table 1 below provides an overview of the data used in this paper. We use a mixture of household and labour force surveys for 12 African countries. None of the data is older than 2005.13 Table 1 highlights one of the key issues in estimating the returns to higher education in Africa. In many countries, educational attainment is so low that the number of observations with tertiary qualifications (or even upper secondary qualifications) is very small14 – apart from in some of the middle income or larger countries like Egypt, Nigeria and South Africa. The proportion of the working age population with tertiary education ranges from 0.7% in Rwanda to 13.8% in Tunisia. This is a problem rarely highlighted in the literature, yet is one of the reasons why estimates of the return to higher education vary so widely, even within the same country. Table 1 also confirms some of the analysis presented in Figure 1. In nearly all countries, a higher education qualification leads to a higher employment probability than for those with upper secondary education, with the exception of Rwanda, Tanzania and Uganda. The table also reminds us that, in some African countries, joblessness rates reach alarmingly high levels, and hence that ignoring the impact of education on the likelihood of finding employment in estimating the returns to education would be a significant omission. Finally, the table shows average university graduates earnings in comparison with secondary school graduate earnings (index=100 for the latter). On average, across all countries, the average earnings of university graduates are twice as high as those of individuals with upper secondary qualifications. 13 Annex B provides a list of the exact data sources used. In fact, in many African countries, nearly all those with upper secondary qualifications go on to higher education. So in some of the samples looked at, there are more observations with tertiary education than with upper secondary education. 14 Table 1: Summary overview of data sources Burundi15 Ghana Egypt Mali Nigeria Rwanda Soudan RSA Tanzania Togo Tunisia Uganda 2006 2005 2006 2007 2010 2005 2009 2010 2011 2011 2010 2006 Number of observations 6,646 37,128 37,140 16,350 23,212 34,461 33,660 342,470 20,559 29,781 549,015 43,097 Working age population 75.1% 55.4% 63.9% 46.0% 61.7% 54.2% 49.1% 64.0% 52.0% 53.7% 69.3% 45.3% Upper secondary 322 1,358 7,368 249 3,160 492 210 47,544 482 464 144,893 1,350 % of working age population 6.7% 6.9% 29.9% 2.4% 23.9% 2.4% 1.1% 24.7% 3.4% 3.5% 39.8% 6.7% Tertiary 455 662 3,046 178 639 211 233 18,747 148 577 41,869 303 % of working age population 9.6% 3.4% 12.2% 1.6% 5.2% 0.7% 0.9% 9.8% 0.8% 4.7% 13.8% 1.6% Inactive 49.3% 38.5% 36.0% 23.1% 37.6% 18.1% 28.9% 31.4% 35.7% 41.1% 52.2% 28.1% Unemployed 11.7% 8.2% 7.5% 19.4% 5.8% 10.8% 9.2% 18.3% 3.2% 8.6% 6.6% 3.6% Employed 39.0% 53.3% 56.5% 57.6% 56.6% 71.1% 61.9% 50.3% 61.1% 50.4% 41.2% 68.3% Inactive 31.9% 11% 20.5% 26.5% 19.5% 26.0% 18.4% 12.9% 39.4% 37.8% 32.0% 38.8% Unemployed 10.1% 8.2% 12.1% 12.7% 9.0% 9.4% 8.2% 8.0% 6.4% 9.1% 15.6% 6.5% Employed 58.0% 80.8% 67.4% 60.9% 71.5% 64.6% 73.4% 79.1% 54.2% 53.1% 52.4% 54.7% Upper secondary 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Tertiary 187 200 187 143 209 277 190 181 268 148 162 265 Country Year Population Education Employment status, by education Upper secondary Tertiary Earnings, by education (indexed) 15 Urban population only. 5. Results Table 2 presents estimates of the return to higher education (in comparison to those with upper secondary qualifications) for the 12 African countries analysed. Estimates are derived using the four different methods summarised at the end of Section 3. Table 2: The return to higher education Country Mincer Short-Cut Method IRR IRR (Employment Adjusted) Burundi 95% 22% 29% 42% Egypt 32% 22% 10% 15% Ghana 78% 25% 26% 49% Mali 44% 11% 9% 13% Nigeria 96% 27% 13% 16% Rwanda 158% 44% 33% 29% South Africa 85% 20% 21% 51% Sudan 90% 23% 16% 25% Tanzania 141% 42% 26% 31% Togo 70% 12% 31% 42% Tunisia 81% 18% 22% 27% Uganda 87% 41% 22% 18% A few interesting conclusions can be drawn from this table. First, estimates vary considerably depending on the method used. As previously discussed, the Mincer coefficient does not represent a true rate of return, but merely an earnings premium associated with having a higher education qualification. The Mincer coefficients we estimate are always (considerably) larger than the IRR. The Mincer-to-IRR ratio ranges from 2 in Togo to 7 in Nigeria. This suggests that previous estimates obtained in the literature for the rate of return to higher education using Mincer coefficients are likely overestimates of the true rate of return to higher education in Africa. That said, the IRR almost always increases once the probability of being in employment is taken into account (except for in Rwanda and Uganda). On average, for the twelve countries considered, the IRR increases by 9% once adjusted for the rate of joblessness. This confirms our hypothesis that, in countries where the likelihood of being in employment varies considerably with the level of education, calculations of the rate of return to education cannot ignore the effect it has on employment. Interestingly, the employment adjusted IRRs obtained in our analysis, when converted to a return by year of education, average around 7.5%. This is considerably below the rates of return obtained elsewhere in the literature (which hover are 20%, which is very close to our average Mincerian coefficient converted to a return by year of education, i.e. 22%). No clear relationship emerges when comparing the estimates obtained through the short-cut method and those obtained with the IRR. These differences are probably driven by differences in the shape of the earnings functions, with the IRR method providing greater weight to earnings occurring early on in the graduate’s career. We also observe that the rate of return to higher education varies considerably across countries. The employment-adjusted IRR ranges from 13% in Mali to 51% in South Africa. This begs the question as to why this might be the case. One possibility is that, in countries where university graduates are scarce, the return to higher education is high. Figure 2 explores this issue by plotting the employment-adjusted IRR against the proportion of the working age population which has attained a tertiary qualification. At first, no obvious relationship emerges, however removing the two North Africa countries and focusing on the Sub-Saharan countries, we observe the opposite of what we would expect: in countries where a high proportion of the working age population is educated to tertiary level, the rate of return is high. Figure 2: Proportion of the working age populated with higher education and the return to higher education A number of conceivable explanations for this apparent puzzle exist. One is the possibility of reverse causality: in countries where the return to higher education is high, people have invested more in higher education. Another explanation might be that supply creates its own demand: in countries where the supply of university graduates is high, there may be more innovation, business start-ups, etc… which in turn would increase the demand for university graduates and hence the return to education. Either way, this is an issue which merits to be further investigated. In Table 3, we break down the analysis by gender. When considering the Mincer coefficients, no clear pattern emerges: in about half the countries looked at the return to higher education is higher for females; in the other half it is higher for men. However, once we turn to the employment adjusted IRR, the return to higher education is higher for women in eight of the countries considered. This suggests that factoring in the employment effect of education is even more important when looking at the return for women who, in many African countries, tend to have worse employment outcomes, particularly at lower levels of education. Table 3: The return to higher education, by gender Country Mincer Short-Cut Method IRR IRR (Employment Adjusted) Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women Burundi 108% 70% 27% 11% 38% 22% 45% 39% Egypt 41% 20% 22% 23% 11% 9% 13% 19% Ghana 67% 108% 21% 36% 26% 27% 45% 58% Mali 63% ns 12% ns 14% ns 12% Ns Nigeria 104% 78% 27% 22% 15% 12% 16% 15% Rwanda 127% 227% 40% 50% 27% 42% 21% 46% South Africa 77% 103% 19% 24% 20% 22% 48% 55% Sudan 88% 107% 21% 42% 16% 18% 22% 34% Uganda 86% 108% 23% 131% 18% 26% 17% 20% Tanzania 145% 140% 47% 29% 22% 36% 23% 56% Togo 76% 38% 14% 5% 34% 22% 36% 69% Tunisia 80% 84% 18% 19% 20% 23% 19% 11% Conclusion In this paper, we have estimated the return to higher education for 12 African countries using recent data and a variety of methods. Importantly, one of our methods adjusts for the effect of higher education on the rate of joblessness, which is substantial in most African countries. Our results confirm that Mincerian coefficients cannot be interpreted as a true rate of return, and that the true rate of return (even after taking into account the employment effect) is considerably lower than what has previously been suggested in the literature (less than half). Our paper highlights the importance of considering the employment effect of education in countries where the level of joblessness is high, particularly when estimating the rate of return for women. Further research should refine the methodology by taking into account the direct costs of education (fees, books, etc…), bursaries and other financial aid, as well as more realistic estimates of the time taken to complete a university education and considering the tax/benefit implications of higher earnings. Finally, we uncover an interesting relationship between a country’s level of education and the return to higher education: contrary to expectations, we find that in countries where a high proportion of the working age population is educated to tertiary level, the return to higher education is the highest. Further research should aim to understand the reasons behind this seemingly counterintuitive finding. Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Arnaud Chevalier and Paul Schultz for comments on earlier drafts of this paper. All remaining errors are our own. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not in any way reflect those of the African Development Bank. References Arrazola, M. and J. de Hevia (2008) ‘Three measures of returns to education: An illustration for the case of Spain’, Economics of Education Review, 27(3): 266-275. Barceinas, F., J. Oliver, J.L. Raymond, J.L. Roig and B. Weber (2000) ‘Unemployment and returns to education in Europe’ PURE Working Paper. Bennell, P. (1996) ‘Rates of return to education: Does the conventional pattern prevail in SubSaharan Africa?’ World Development, 24 (1): 183-199. Björklund, A. and C. Kjellström (2002) ‘Estimating the return to investments in education: how useful is the standard Mincer equation?’ Economics of Education Review, 21(3): 195-210. Card (2001) ‘Estimating the return to schooling: Progress on some persistent econometric problems’ Econometrica, 69 (5): 1127-1160. Colclough, C., G. Kingdon and H.A. Patrinos (2009) ‘The pattern of returns to education and its implications’ Research Consortium on Educational Outcomes and Poverty (RECOUP) Policy Brief 4. Denison, E.F. (1964) ‘Measuring the contribution of education (and the residual) to economic growth’, in The Residual Factor and Economic Growth, Study Group in the Economics of Education. Paris: OECD. Diagne, A. and B. Diene (2011) ‘Estimating returns to higher education: A survey of models, methods and empirical evidence’ Journal of African Economies, 20, AERC Supplement 3: iii80–iii132. Dickson, M. and S. Smith (2011) ‘What determines the return to education: An extra year or a hurdle cleared?’ IZA Discussion Paper 5524, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Halvorsen, R. and R. Palmquist (1980). ‘The interpretation of dummy variables in semilogarithmic equations’, American Economic Review, 70: 474-75. Heckman, J.J., L.J. Lochner and P.E. Todd (2005). ‘Earnings functions, rates of return and treatment effects: The Mincer equation and beyond’, IZA Discussion Paper 1700. Heckman, J.J., L.J. Lochner and P.E. Todd (2008) ‘Earnings functions and rates of return’, University of Western Ontario CIBC Working Paper 2008-2. Karasiotou, P. (2003). ‘Education, unemployment and earnings: Decomposing the returns to education’ Center for Research in Economics Working Paper 2003/4, Facultés universitaires Saint-Louis, Brussels. Kennedy, P. (1981). ’Estimation with correctly interpreted dummy variables in semilogarithmic equations’ American Economic Review, 71, 801. Kingdon, G., H.A. Patrinos, C. Sakellariou and M. Söderbom (2008) ‘International pattern of returns to education’, World Bank Mimeo. OECD (2012). ‘Education at a glance 2012’, OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing. Pereira, P.T., and P.S. Martins (2004) ‘Returns to education and wage equations’, Applied Economics, 36(6): 1-7 Psacharopoulos, G. (1973) ‘Returns to education: An international comparison’, Amsterdam: Elsevier. Psacharopoulos, G. (1981) ‘Returns to education: An updated international comparison’, Comparative Education, 17 (3): 321-341. Psacharopoulos, G. (1985) ‘Returns to education: A further international update and implications’, Journal of Human Resources, 20 (4): 583-604. Psacharopoulos, G. (1994) ‘Returns to investment in education: A global update’, World Development, 22 (9): 1325-43. Psacharopoulos, G. and H.A. Patrinos (2004a) ‘Returns to investment in education: A further update’, Education Economics, 12 (2): 111-134. Psacharopoulos, G. and H.A. Patrinos (2004b) ‘Human capital and rates of return’, in G. Johnes and J. Johnes (ed.), International Handbook on the Economics of Education, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd. Psacharopoulos, G. and H.A. Patrinos (2007) ‘Returns to education: An international update, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. Schultz, T.P. (2003) ‘Evidence of returns to schooling in Africa from household surveys: Monitoring and restructuring the market for education’, Yale University Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper 875. Annex A: Education and earnings definitions and variables used Country Earnings variable used Education variables used Definition secondary Definition tertiary Burundi ο· Revtotal ο· M16: avez-vous été au moins à l'école primaire? ο· M20: quel niveau d'enseignement avez-vous atteint? supérieur Egypt ο· hrwg: hourly wage (primary job) ο· educ4: educational attainment (13 categories) secondaire général cycle II secondary Ghana ο· s4aq8: will you receive payment for this work ο· s4aq9a: amount including any bonuses received ο· s4aq9b: time unit ο· s2aq1: name ever attended school? ο· s2aq3: highest qualification attained gce 'o' level ssce gce 'a' level Mali ο· salmp: salaire moyen de l'activité principale ο· M11: avez-vous déjà été à l'école ? ο· M14: diplôme le plus élevé obtenu cap bt baccalauréat Nigeria ο· s3q21a: how much was your last payment ο· s3q21b: time unit ο· s2q4: have you ever attended school ο· s2q8: highest qualification attained sss 'o level' a level tech/prof cert tech/prof dip hnd bachelor masters doctorate DUTS/BTS/DUT/DEUG et autre niveau BAC+2 diplôme ens. supérieur ba/bsc/hnd tech/prof masters doctorate Rwanda ο· s6eq8: amount received last paycheck after deductions ο· s6eq8t: time unit ο· s2aq2: ever been to school ο· s2aq4: certificate or degree received humanities South Africa ο· Q54a_mon: monthly earnings for employees ο· Q57a_mon: monthly earnings for employers and selfemployed ο· Education: education status secondary completed Sudan ο· d8: value of last actual payment or expected payment (SDG) Tanzania ο· hh_e22_1: how much was your last payment? ο· hh_e22_2: what period of time did this payment cover? ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· sec. 4 sec. 5 sec. 6 ’O’ level form 5 form 6 c2: school attendance – ever c5: current school attendance c7: highest level of education hh_c03: did [NAME] ever go to school? hh_c07: what is the highest grade completed by [NAME]? hh_c09: what grade is [NAME] currently attending? university (4 & 5 yrs) postgraduate bachelor professional license engineer masters doctorate tertiary post-secondary diploma university U2 U3 U4 Country Earnings variable used Education variables used Definition secondary Definition tertiary ο· hh_c10: what grade was [NAME] attending last year? ‘A’+course Diploma U5&+ Togo ο· E28A: revenu moyen_unite de temps ο· E28B: revenu moyen_montant ο· C2: fréquentation de l'école ο· C3: dernier type d'enseignement suivi ο· C4: classe achevée terminale enseignement supérieur 1er, 2ème et 3ème cycle Tunisia ο· salaire: average monthly earnings ο· v_240: niveau d'instruction (ENPE) ο· level_educ secondary tertiary Uganda ο· h8q8a: how much was your last cash payment? ο· h8q8c: what period of time did this payment cover? ο· h4q2: have you ever attended any formal education? ο· h4q4: what was the highest grade that you completed? ο· h4q6: what grade are you currently attending? completed s.4 attending s.5 completed s.5 attending s.6 completed s.6 completed degree and above attending degree and above Annex B: List of surveys used in the analysis Country Survey Year Togo Questionnaire Unifié des Indicateurs de Base du Bien-être (QUIBB) 2011 Egypt Egypt Labor Market Panel Survey 2006 Mali Enquête Permanente Emploi Auprès des Ménages 2007 South Africa Labour Market Dynamics 2010 Nigeria General Household Survey –Panel (Post Plantingβ2010) 2010 Ghana Living Standars Survey 5 2005 Burundi Enquête 1-2-3: Phase 1 Enquête Emploi 2006 Rwanda Enquête Intégrale sur les Conditions de Vie des Ménages 2005 Tanzania National Panel Survey 2011 Sudan National Poverty Survey 2009 Uganda Uganda National Household Survey 2006 Tunisia* Enquête Nationale sur la Population et l’Emploi (ENPE) Administrative databases (National social security funds) 2010 * For Tunisia, we use two separate data sources. The employment equation is estimated using the Enquête Nationale sur la Population et l’Emploi. The wage regression is estimated using administrative data from the National Social Security Funds.