Economics and Electing the President The work of Ray Fair http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/ http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/vote 2008/index2.htm http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/RAY FAIR/PDF/2006CHTM.HTM Presidential Election Links http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/ http://www.apsanet.org/content_58382.cf m http://www.douglashibbs.com/Election2012/2012ElectionMainPage.htm Economic Growth and the United States Presidency: Can You Evaluate the Players Without a Scorecard? David J. Berri Department of Applied Economics California State University – Bakersfield Bakersfield, California 93311 661-654-2027 dberri@csub.edu James Peach P. O. Box 30001/ MSC 3CQ Department of Economics New Mexico State University Las Cruces, NM 88003 505-646-2113 jpeach@nmsu.edu ABSTRACT In several academic papers and a book, Ray Fair (1978, 1996, 2002) has demonstrated a link between the state of the macroeconomy and the outcome of the Presidential Election in the United States. Beginning with the 1916 election, Fair’s model, based on such factors as economic growth, inflation, and incumbency, was able to accurately predict the winner in virtually every election. The purpose of this research is to take the Fair model back to the 19th century. The question we address is as follows: Can a version of Fair’s model accurately predict in an environment where economic data was not made available to the voter? LOUIS BEAN (1948) HOW TO PREDICT ELECTIONS “Business depressions played a powerful role in throwing the Republicans out of office in 1874, after 1908, and in 1932, and they had exactly the same influence in ousting Democrats after the panic of 1858 and during the economic setbacks of 1894 and 1920.” “Harding in 1920, McKinley in 1896, and Cleveland in 1884 were also depression-made presidents. Had the deciding electoral vote been cast for the candidate who had the majority of the popular vote in 1876, Tilden too, would have been a depression-made President.” THE WORK OF RAY FAIR Fair, Ray C. 1978. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President.” The Review of Economics and Statistics (Vol. LX, No. 2):159-173 May 1978. Fair, Ray C. 1978. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President: 1980 Results.” The Review of Economics and Statistics (Vol. 64, No. 2):322-25 May 1978. Fair, Ray. C. 1996. “Econometrics and Presidential Elections.” Journal of Economic Perspectives (Vol. 10, No 3):89-102 (Summer 1996). Fair, Ray C. 2002. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President: 2000 Update.” http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM Downloaded Feb 2, 2006. Fair, Ray C. 2002. Predicting Presidential Elections and other things. Stanford: Stanford Business Books. A FAIR MODEL VOTE= a1 + a2GROWTH+ a3INFLATION + a4PARTY + a5PERSON + a6DURATION + a7GOODNEWS + ε DEFINING THE VARIABLES EMPLOYED HTTP://FAIRMODEL.ECON.YALE.EDU/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002D HTM.HTM VOTE = Incumbent share of the two-party presidential vote. GROWTH = annual growth rate of real per capita GDP in the first three quarters of the election year. INFLATION = absolute value of the growth rate of the GDP deflator in the first 15 quarters of the administration (annual rate) except for 1920, 1944, and 1948, where the values are zero. DEFINING THE VARIABLES EMPLOYED HTTP://FAIRMODEL.ECON.YALE.EDU/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002D HTM.HTM PARTY = 1 if Democrats are in power, = -1 if Republicans are in power PERSON = 1 if the president is running, = 0 otherwise DURATION = 0 if the incumbent party has been in power for one term, 1 if the incumbent party has been in power for two consecutive terms, 1.25 if the incumbent party has been in power for three consecutive terms, 1.50 for four consecutive terms, and so on. WAR = 1 for the elections of 1920, 1944, and 1948 and 0 otherwise GOODNEWS = number of quarters in the first 15 quarters of the administration in which the growth rate of real per capita GDP is greater than 3.2 percent at an annual rate except for 1920, 1944, and 1948, where the values are zero. Table One The Accuracy of the Fair Model 1916-2000 Actual VOTE Predicted VOTE Incumbent Party received by received by Year Candidate Challenger incumbent incumbent Error 1916 1920 1924 1928 1932 1936 1940 1944 1948 1952 1956 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 Wilson Cox Coolidge Hoover Hoover Roosevelt Roosevelt Roosevelt Truman Stevenson Eisenhower Nixon L. Johnson Humphrey Nixon Ford Carter Reagan G. Bush G. Bush Clinton Gore Hughes Harding Davis Smith Roosevelt Landon Willkie Dewey Dewey Eisenhower Stevenson Kennedy Goldwater Nixon McGovern Carter Reagan Mondale Dukakis Clinton Dole G.W. Bush 51.7 36.1 58.2 58.8 40.8 62.5 55.0 53.8 52.4 44.6 57.8 49.9 61.3 49.6 61.8 48.9 44.7 59.2 53.9 46.5 54.7 50.3 50.9 39.2 57.3 57.6 38.8 63.8 55.7 52.5 50.5 44.4 57.3 51.6 61.1 50.2 59.4 48.9 45.7 62.0 51.3 51.7 53.7 48.9 Source: http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM.HTM -0.8 3.1 -1.0 -1.2 -2.1 1.4 0.7 -1.2 -1.8 -0.2 -0.5 1.7 -0.3 0.6 -2.4 0.0 1.0 2.9 -2.6 5.1 -1.0 -1.3 Actual Winner Predicted Winner Wilson Harding Coolidge Hoover Roosevelt Roosevelt Roosevelt Roosevelt Truman Eisenhower Eisenhower Kennedy L. Johnson Nixon Nixon Carter Reagan Reagan G. Bush Clinton Clinton G.W. Bush Wilson Harding Coolidge Hoover Roosevelt Roosevelt Roosevelt Roosevelt Truman Eisenhower Eisenhower Nixon L. Johnson Humphrey Nixon Carter Reagan Reagan G. Bush G. Bush Clinton G.W. Bush SUMMARIZING FAIR: 1916-2000 Only incorrect in three elections: 1960, 1964, 1992. Average absolute error: 1.5 Results are driven by economic variables with no consideration of a candidate’s appearance, debating talents, advertisements, or general campaign skills. TAKING FAIR BACK TO 1824 New measures of growth and inflation are needed. Louis Johnston and Samuel H. Williamson, "The Annual Real and Nominal GDP for the United States, 1789 - Present." Economic History Services, April 2002, URL : http://www.eh.net/hmit/gdp/ This data has been updated. Updated data did not change our general findings. THE MODELS TO BE ESTIMATED Model 1 Original Fair Model (1916-2000) Model 2 Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION (1916-2000) Model 3 Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION, no GOODNEWS (1916-2000) Model 4 Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION, no GOODNEWS (1916-2004) Model 5 Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION, no GOODNEWS (1824-1912) Model 6 Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION, no GOODNEWS (1824-2004) Table Three Various Estimates of Fair’s Model Dependent Variable is VOTE White Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Standard Errors & Covariance Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 1916-2000 1916-2000 1916-2000 1916-2004 1824-1912 1824-2004 0.691* 0.457* 0.409** 0.413** -0.135 0.342 (6.169) (3.526) (2.569) (2.649) (-0.560) (1.577) INFLATION -0.775* -0.808* -0.988* -0.943* 0.438 -0.191 (3.915) (4.132) (5.405) (5.051) (0.511) (0.731) PARTY -2.713* -2.054** -1.644*** -1.252 0.647 -0.594 (5.434) (2.644) (1.946) (1.363) (0.344) (0.580) PERSON 3.251*** 2.145 1.701 1.578 -0.372 1.705 (1.837) (1.007) (0.698) (0.663) (0.083) (0.625) DURATION -3.628** -4.238** -5.216** -4.519*** 1.414 -0.448 (2.517) (2.410) (2.315) (1.968) (0.611) (0.208) 3.855 5.268 2.905 2.262 -1.881 -0.835 (1.102) (0.832) (0.102) (0.214) Sample: GROWTH WAR GOODNEWS INTERCEPT R-Square (1.213) (1.369) 0.837** 0.539 (2.932) (1.238) 49.607* 52.871* 57.769* 56.892 48.458 50.889 (19.550) (15.512) (18.169) (17.736) (10.618) (15.184) 0.923 0.845 0.828 0.769 0.093 0.116 0.683 8.883* 23 -0.248 0.272 23 -0.020 0.850 46 Adjusted R-Square 0.885 0.767 0.759 F-Statistic 24.000* 10.888* 12.015* Observation 22 22 22 t-statistics in parenthesis below each coefficient. * - Significant at the 1% level ** - Significant at the 5% level *** - Significant at the 10% level Table Four The Accuracy of the Fair Model 1824-1912 Forecast Based on Model 3 Year 1824 1828 1832 1836 1840 1844 1848 1852 1856 1860 1864 1868 1872 1876 1880 1884 1888 1892 1896 1900 1904 1908 1912 Incumbent Party Candidate Challenger Jackson J.Q. Adams J.Q. Adams Jackson Jackson Clay Van Buren W. Harrison Van Buren W. Harrison Clay Polk Cass Taylor Scott Pierce Buchanan Fremont Breckinridge Lincoln Lincoln McClellan Grant Seymour Grant Greeley Hayes Tilden Garfield Hancock Blaine Cleveland Cleveland B. Harrison B. Harrison Cleveland Bryan McKinley McKinley Bryan T. Roosevelt Parker Taft Bryan Taft/Roosevelt Wilson * - did not win popular vote Actual VOTE received by incumbent 57.2 43.8 59.2 58.1 47.0 49.3 47.3 46.3 57.8 31.2 55.0 52.7 55.9 48.5 50.0 49.9 50.4 48.3 47.8 53.2 60.0 54.5 54.7 Predicted VOTE received by incumbent 39.8 56.9 58.0 43.7 51.4 58.6 53.5 62.0 55.2 56.4 42.9 48.5 55.9 50.3 50.0 45.1 59.1 61.2 53.7 59.5 49.9 46.8 50.6 Error 17.4 13.1 1.2 14.4 4.4 9.4 6.2 15.7 2.6 25.2 12.1 4.2 0.0 1.8 0.2 4.8 8.7 13.0 5.9 6.3 10.1 7.6 4.1 Actual Winner J.Q. Adams* Jackson Jackson Van Buren W. Harrison Polk Taylor Pierce Buchanan Lincoln Lincoln Grant Grant Hayes* Garfield Cleveland B.Harrison* Cleveland McKinley McKinley T. Roosevelt Taft Wilson* Predicted Winner J.Q. Adams J.Q. Adams Jackson W. Harrison Van Buren Clay Cass Scott Buchanan Breckinridge McClellan Seymour Grant Hayes Hancock Cleveland Cleveland B. Harrison Bryan McKinley Parker Bryan Taft-Roosevelt WHY DOES THE FAIR MODEL FAIR POORLY BEFORE 1916? Economic data did not exist. U.S. economy not integrated. Federal government was not held responsible for the macroeconomy. Non-economic issues were more important in the 19th century. Econometrics and Presidential Elections Larry M. Bartels OVERVIEW OF THE FAIR MODEL One of the most interesting aspects of Fair's essay is the unusually frank and detailed description it provides of the enormous amount of exploratory research underlying published analyses of aggregate election outcomes. What is the relevant sample period? Which economic variables matter? Measured over what time span? What does one do with third party votes, war years, or an unelected incumbent? In fewer than a dozen pages, Fair raises and resolves many such questions, as any data analyst must. In the process, he makes clear how much of what Leamer (1978) has referred to as “specification uncertainty” plagues this (or any other) statistical analysis of presidential election outcomes. CHOOSING A MODEL ….(Fair’s) choice of model specification seems to have been guided by goodness-of-fit considerations rather than by a priori political or economic considerations. His data set begins in 1916 because “some experimentation . . . using observations prior to 1916" produced results that “were not as good.” Gerald Ford is sometimes counted as an incumbent and sometimes not, depending upon which treatment “improves the fit of the equation.” Revised economic data produced significant changes in several key coefficients, prompting renewed searching “to see which set of economic variables led to the best fit,” and so on. WHAT HAVE WE LEARNED? What most electoral scholars really care about is what the relationship between economic conditions and election outcomes tells us about voting behavior and democratic accountability. On that score, what have we learned, and what have we yet to learn? The clearest and most significant implication of aggregate election analyses is that objective economic conditions -not clever television ads, debate performances, or the other ephemera of day-to-day campaigning -- are the single most important influence upon an incumbent president's prospects for reelection. Despite a good deal of uncertainty regarding the exact form of the relationship, the relevant time horizon, and the relative importance of specific economic indicators, there can be no doubt that presidential elections are, in significant part, referenda on the state of the economy. THREE KINDS OF VOTERS… My own thoughts… Three voters in the election… Republicans (vote Republican) Democrates (vote Democrat) Independents The only free agents are independents. These are voters who care so little, they don’t join a party. And these are the voters that matter. Why the economy? It is the one issue that matters to the independent. Politics and football… Some football coaches believe the run sets up the pass. Others think the pass sets up the run. Fans, though, don’t care. You win, you keep your job. You lose, you lose your job. Applied to politics… some people believe in smaller government and low taxes. Others believe in more government to solve problems. Independents, though, don’t care. The economy does well, you keep your job. If not, your fired. What the politician believes is simply not relevant.