Problems in Cost of Capital Estimation: Illustrations from the Gas Industry Kevin Davis Colonial Professor of Finance Department of Accounting and Finance The University of Melbourne k.davis@ecomfac.unimelb.edu.au Ph: 03 9344 8015 http://www.ecom.unimelb.edu.au/accwww fax: 03 9349 2397 Overview Significance of the Cost of Capital Alternative Cost of Capital Measures pre versus post tax » imputation considerations nominal versus real equity versus entity (WACC) Estimating components of the WACC betas; leverage; tax rates; franking credit valuation; Dealing with non-systematic risk Why is the Cost of Capital Relevant? Evaluation of new projects Net Present Value (NPV) techniques Performance measurement of existing business Economic Value Added (EVA) Pricing Policy Access provisions Financing Choice Optimal Capital Structure Problems in Determining the Cost of Capital Cost of Equity capital not directly observable Interest Rate quoted on debt finance not necessarily equal to rate of return expected by providers of debt finance Hybrid securities often involve option characteristics which have a cost which needs to be evaluated The Regulatory Model for Access Pricing A net revenue stream which equals the required rate of return on written down book value plus depreciation each period means that the initial investment is zero NPV Initial book value of assets established as DORC value Depreciated Optimised Replacement Cost The Regulatory Model Determine target revenue stream for 5 year horizon, based on Projections of volume Revenue to cover (efficient) operating costs, return on capital, return of capital (depreciation) Initial price determined from year 1 target revenue and volume projections Subsequent prices for 5 year horizon set using CPI – X rule, where X set to give Present Value of resulting revenue stream equal to that of target revenue stream Note: approximately 50% of target revenue is return on capital Background (continued) Access prices should mimic a (hypothetical) competitive outcome Market value of business should be close to replacement value of assets Privatization sale prices were over twice the replacement value of assets Cannot be explained by potential operating efficiency gains or synergy Unlikely to be largely due to “winner’s curse” Unlikely to be due to underestimation of asset replacement value Indicative of use of excessively high cost of capital in regulatory determination The Building Block Approach Target Revenue = Operating Costs + Return of Capital + Return on Capital Fundamental Decisions real versus nominal (is inflation reflected in return of or return on capital?) post tax versus pre tax (is tax component of target revenues implicit in (pre tax) return on capital or identified explicitly from (post tax) return on capital?) entity versus equity (is focus on return to all providers of funds or only owners?) Consistency Issues Any number of different approaches can be shown to be equivalent provided that “correct” input parameter values are used Unfortunately, correct values aren’t known and errors lead to wealth transfers Approach adopted should aim to enhance: Accuracy of estimation of key parameters in each approach Transparency of the process Ease of interpretation Real versus Nominal Approach Either real (CCA depreciation) or nominal (historical cost depreciation) approach can be used no effect on NPV of target revenue stream first cash flow and X factor may be affected Real pre tax approach requires derivation of real pre tax cost of capital no simple conversion formula to get real pre tax from nominal post tax cost of capital real pre tax concept not commonly used Imputation Implications Gas Industry approach commenced with a nominal WACC formula which started with “partially grossed up” cost of equity (re), available from CAPM adjusted this to be applicable to cash flows after company tax (ie not including franking credits in cash flows) E (1 T ) D r re . rd . .(1 T ) V (1 T (1 )) V i o Then adjusted for tax and inflation to apply to real pre tax cash flows Imputation Implications Problems What is value of ? What is appropriate value of T ? Alternatives “Entity Basis” cash flows to all capital providers after tax » » tax as levered or unlevered entity? Add value of franking credits into cash flows “Equity Basis” cash flows (plus value of franking credits) to equity providers after tax The Regulatory Problem Cost of capital “built up” from component parts many “unknowns” » » CAPM parameters, tax issues, leverage & debt costs real, pre tax WACC figure required (not well understood) “cherry picking” of parameter estimates by participants in process bias towards overstatement of WACC by participants Effective Company Tax Rate Company Tax Rate Leverage Equity B Asset b Real Pre Tax WACC Nominal Post Tax WACC “Comparables” Equity b Market Risk Premium Nominal Post Tax Cost of Equity Valuation of Franking Credits Real Risk Free Rate Dividend Policy Risk Free Rate Cost of Debt Credit Rating Inflation Estimating CAPM parameters Risk free rate Theory suggests short term rate Practitioners use long term rate Compromise: use current long term rate less historical “long - short” risk premium to get expected long run average of short term rate Does “duration” of activity matter? Should current day rate or historical average be used? The Market Risk Premium “Conventional Wisdom” suggests MRP of 6-8 per cent Theory and the “Equity Premium Puzzle” 6-8 per cent not compatible with “normal” risk aversion parameters What is historical evidence? For Australia post WW2, arguably < 6% p.a. » compare return on equity with risk free rate for same holding period How is return on market (and thus MRP) measured post imputation? » Partially/ fully grossed up? Estimating Beta Directly - regression of past returns on particular stock against past returns on market Purchase estimates Accounting information / cash flow analysis Comparables - identify similar risk companies and adapt the beta estimates for those systematic risk needs to be the same » » is “market” portfolio the same how does regulation affect risk leverage adjustment needs to be made » “unlever” and “relever” beta Delevering - Levering Equity beta reflects underlying asset (unlevered) beta leverage To calculate beta for similar company(ie similar business risk) with different leverage calculate asset beta (ie delever) and then relever to get equity beta for desired leverage Issues tax adjustments and appropriate formula beta of debt The GAS WACC Model E (1 T ) D r re . rd . .(1 T ) V (1 T (1 )) V i o re is a “partially grossed up” cost of equity WACC proposed is applicable to nominal cash flows calculated after tax but before interest (ie as if unlevered) Implicit assumptions perpetuity cash flow returns take form of 100% franked dividends » hence company in full tax paying position franking credits not fully valued capital gains taxed equivalently to other income An Alternative (Monkhouse) WACC model k r f b [ E( Rm ) r f ] D t f c e d re k D t f r f b [ E( Rm ) r f ] E c D c k w k e rd (1 T ) V V c e ' d ' kec is return measured excluding value of franking credits re is return measured including value of franking credits kwc is WACC to apply to cash flows Rm is partially grossed up market return Equivalent to proposed model if returns only take form of 100% franked dividends Notation re expected return, rf is the risk free rate E(Rm) is the expected return on the market – inclusive of the value of franking credits d utilization rate of distributed imputation credits (equivalent to Officer’s D’ is the grossed up dividend yield tf is the level of franking 0 in the case of an unfranked dividend T (co tax rate) for a fully franked dividend). D’ = d/[P(1-T)] where d is the cash dividend and P is the share price. Monkhouse’s CAPM under imputation No preferential tax treatment of capital gains Investors have different valuations of franking credits (from 0 to 100%) Investors do not shift between firms according to tax characteristics of returns (franked / unfranked etc) Retained franking credits may add some value (but assumed zero in version presented here) Comparing Approaches Risk Free Rate Market Risk Premium Beta Grossed Up div yield Cost of Equity (re) cf Cost of Equity (ke) %Equity (E/V) Cost of Debt (rd) % Debt (D/V) Gamma () Tax Rate (T) re [ (1-T)/(1-T(1- ))][E/V] Officer(1) 8.00% 6.50% 1.08 na 15.02% 0.4 8.75% 0.6 0.25 0.36 0.053 Officer(2) Monkhouse(1) Monkhouse(2) 6.00% 8.00% 6.00% 6.00% 6.50% 6.00% 0.60 1.08 0.60 na 6.00% 6.00% 9.60% 15.02% 9.60% 14.48% 8.52% 0.7 0.4 0.7 6.75% 8.75% 6.75% 0.3 0.6 0.3 0.50 0.25 0.50 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.052 ke[E/V] rd[1-T][D/V] ro na na 0.058 0.060 0.034 0.013 0.034 0.013 8.63% 6.54% 9.15% 7.26% Non systematic risk and the cost of capital CAPM only prices systematic risk Resulting cost of capital should be used in conjunction with expected cash flows Practitioners often add a “fudge factor” to CAPM estimate to compensate for non systematic risk but such risk involves both upside and downside! A significant problem is that cash flow figures used are often those viewed as most likely (modal), and cash flow distribution is skewed such that “expected” (mean) figure is lower solution - adjust cash flows for “insurance” cost of downside risk