Public Sector Economics Taxes and Market Distortions – Theory Main Lessons • rational foundations of policy distortions • how policy distortions are a result of “incomplete markets” • why labor supply is so important • tax equivalencies • wealth vs. substitution effect of a tax • rigorous definition of deadweight cost • the “taxable income elasticity” • measuring marginal tax rates • public policy needs market analysis • applications of the results to other economics fields Rational Foundations • Olson’s Logic of Collective Action – people do not voluntarily and unilaterally pay taxes (in the amount they are forced to pay) or otherwise contribute to collective goods, even if they appreciate the way tax revenues are used, because they rely on others to make the contribution – restaurant example – is this logic correct? • in large groups? • how else can tax distortions be explained? • tax payments vs. user fees – eg., Feldstein-Samwick on SS “contributions” – mandatory employee benefits • voluntary contributions • “excessive” tax compliance, “insufficient” take-up Soviet Collective Farms Marxism-Leninism insisted that small-scale production in agriculture was “uneconomic, conducive to low productivity and absorbing too much of the labor force of the country.” Dolot, Miron (2011) Image credit: http://www.eonimages.com/media/5c62b78c-3e50-11e0-b No U.S. copyright applies. Chinese Communes MaoZedong Zedongtouts on Mao communes: “Their advantage in “the superiority of is large combining industry, cooperatives” agriculture, commerce, education, and the military for more convenient management.” Jisheng (2012) Image credit: http://chineseposters.net/photographs/a62-938.php Image credit: http://iftf.typepad.com/photos/uncategorized/great_leap_fo Soviet Collective Farms “…the land was no longer theirs. They could work that land, but there was no guarantee that they could harvest the crop.” Dolot, Miron (2011) Image credit: http://www.eonimages.com/media/5c62b78c-3e50-11e0-b No U.S. copyright applies. Chinese Communes “the state monopoly stifled incentives for increasing production… deprived peasants of their right to obtain food and made them dependent on the government for every meal, while punishing them for applying individual effort in food production.” Jisheng (2012) Image credit: http://chineseposters.net/photographs/a62-938.php Image credit: http://iftf.typepad.com/photos/uncategorized/great_leap_fo Soviet Collective Farms “the Soviet economy is proof that, contrary to what many skeptics had earlier believed, a socialist command economy can function and even thrive.” Paul Samuelson and William Nordhaus (1989!) Image credit: http://www.eonimages.com/media/5c62b78c-3e50-11e0-b No U.S. copyright applies. Soviet Collective Farms “[surprised:] Private allotments of land on the collective farm often have much higher, not lower productivity than the collectivized sectors.” Paul Samuelson (1976) Image credit: http://www.eonimages.com/media/5c62b78c-3e50-11e0-b No U.S. copyright applies. Soviet Collectivization “That is why buildings in the Soviet Union – like public housing in the United States – look decrepit within a year or two of their construction.” Milton and Rose Friedman (1980) Image credit: http://www.eonimages.com/media/5c62b78c-3e50-11e0-b No U.S. copyright applies. The Virtues of Collective Ownership • E.g., journalists on single-payer health care – Europeans have healthcare payroll taxes withheld from pay – Americans have insurance premiums withheld from pay – Supposedly no difference (per $ withheld) 1,100.00 BCBS FAMILY PREMIUM 5,500.00 1,951.28 1,100.00 110.00 390.26 549.99 1,100.00 National HI Tax 110.00 549.99 Roberts family NHI benefits are independent of what (if anything) James pays 5,500.00 1,951.28 1,100.00 390.26 1,100.00 BCBS family premium 110.00 549.99 Roberts family gets BCBS benefits ONLY if James pays in full 5,500.00 1,951.28 1,100.00 390.26 The Virtues of Collective Ownership • E.g., journalists on single-payer health care – Europeans have healthcare payroll taxes withheld from pay – Americans have insurance premiums withheld from pay – Supposedly no difference (per $ withheld) • Public ownership is simpler/less costly – U.S. physicians annual spend $61k more (than Canadian docs) dealing with insurance companies – See also Peter Diamond on the administrative costs of retirement accounts: SSA has proportionally less admin cost • Government’s large scale permits it to invest more in each decision and share the resulting wisdom • Government gets a bulk discount more people served • Only real costs of public ownership: government faced with “difficult decisions” • These arguments work for most industries: health, education, groceries, airlines, housing, banking Table 2.3. Payroll taxes earmarked for medical benefits in the U.S. and Western Europe, 2010 Country U.S. (before the ACA) Austria Luxembourg Greece Belgium Finland France Germany Netherlands Medical benefits payroll tax rate, employee equivalent 2.5 4.2 4.4 4.5 5.1 5.3 6.4 9.0 15.2 Western Europe average 6.8 In addition, Switzerland has an individual mandate with premiums capped at 8 percent of income. Source: Philipson, et al., Health Affairs 2012. Source: Philipson, et al., Health Affairs 2012. Source: Philipson, et al., Health Affairs 2012. Rational Foundations (cont’d) How complete are markets in Public Finance? • complete enough that: – profits are zero – goods (factor) prices equal marginal cost (product) • not so complete that there are contracts on untaxed goods (otherwise lump sum taxation is possible) • [not a complete set of policy contingent claims] • insufficient substitutes for complete markets. eg, – altruism – voluntary provision Labor Tax Conversion Factors Wealth vs. Substitution Effects c slope = 𝑤 slope = 1 − 𝜏 𝑤 𝜈 + 𝑓 𝑛 − 𝑤𝑛 𝑓 𝑛 − 𝑤𝑛 0 n c dg dg 0 n substitution effect wealth effect combined effect Table 5.1. Sliding Scale Exchange Subsidies as a function of household income for the calendar year Income as a ratio to FPL 1 1.33 1.5 2 2.5 3 4 4+ Percentage of income owed as premium 2% 3% 4% 6.3% 8.05% 9.5% 9.5% full premium Discount on out-of-pocket cost (jumps when crossing thresholds) 80% 80% 57% 10% 0% 0% 0% 0% Notes on interval premium percentage is constant on this interval, jumping at 1.33 premium percentage is constant on this interval premium jumps here because the premium cap is eliminated Notes: (a) the first column indicates the bottom threshold of the income interval (b) income percentages change continuously between thresholds unless otherwise noted. (c) FPL = federal poverty line. (d) Income percentages for 2015-18, and any year thereafter in which the exchange subsides are less than 0.504% of GDP, are indexed to the excess of health cost inflation over income growth. Figure 5.1. 2016 health payments as a function of family income and policy type Payments by subsidy-eligible participants, ratio to FPL 1 full price 0.9 family of 4, parents aged 50, actual 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 family income, ratio to FPL 4 4.5 5 Figure 5.1. 2016 health payments as a function of family income and policy type Payments by subsidy-eligible participants, ratio to FPL 1 full price 0.9 family of 4, parents aged 50, actual 0.8 family of 4, 28% approx. 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 family income, ratio to FPL 4 4.5 5 Table 5.3. The ACA can erase the reward to work for exchange plan participants An example of how unemployment can be "free" under the ACA Scenario for the calendar year 10 months employed Employed all year Income sources Employment UI (only replaces half) All sources 10 months 1 month 11 months 12 months 0 months 12 months Work-related expense bases (number of months where expenses accrue) IIT 11 months 12 months Payroll tax 10 months 12 months Work expense 10 months 12 months Difference = consequence of working 12 months rather than 10 2 months -1 month 1 month 1 month 2 months 2 months Expense amounts at the margin IIT (including exchange subsidies) @ 64% Employee payroll @ 7.65% Work expense @ 10% All expenses 0.6 months 0.2 months 0.2 months 1.0 months Income sources net of work-related expenses 0.0 months Notes: IIT denotes individual income taxes. UI denotes unemployment insurance benefits. To illustrate simply the economics of a 50 percent UI replacement rate, UI is assumed to fully replace employment income for half of the time unemployed rather than replacing half of the income all of the time. The marginal rate is 15 percent for normal federal and state taxes, plus 21 percent for EITC phaseout, plus 28 percent loss of exchange subsidies that are based on calendar-year income. UI is taxable by the IIT, but not by the payroll tax. Employment vs Earnings Tests benefit amount b0 earningstested benefit employmenttested benefit 0 (magnitude of) slope = “benefit reduction rate” beneficiary earnings Variations on the Employment Test benefit amount b0 employmenttested benefit 0 beneficiary earnings Budget Set Induced by Income Taxes/Benefit Phaseouts The horizontal axis measures beneficiary income, from highest to lowest. The black segment is the budget set without taxes and benefits. all other goods Tax paid/benefit foregone MTR = 0% MTR = 0% MTR = 50% MTR = 100% MTR = 150% b 0 -1*(full income) 0 -1*(wage income) Nonlinear Budget Constraints Instances of Nonlinear Taxation • deductions • employment-related tax breaks – tax exempt savings – health expenditures – consumption at work, fringes • tax evasion • EITC [Earned Income Tax Credit] • “progressivity” [continuous and kinked versions] • “compliance costs” • effort Table 3.2. The distribution of marginal penalty amounts among employees not offered coverage Coverage year 2016. Dollar amounts in 2014 $. Number of penalties triggered by the full-time marginal employee possible frequency distributions employees number amount w/o ACA w/ ACA average < 49 0 0 0.650 0.650 0.650 49 10 $31,630 0.033 0.094 0.063 first 30 are exempt 50 10.5 $33,212 0.022 0 0.011 51+ 1 $3,163 0.296 0.256 0.276 Employee-weighted average $ amount: $2,684 $3,783 $3,233 Notes: Assumes zero part-time employees and ignores the "look back" for determining large-employer status. The possible frequencies are employee-weighted and are for purposes of illustration. Deadweight Loss • also known as deadweight cost, excess burden • 5 definitions – – – – effect of policy on indirect utility (measured in “utils”) area under the Marshallian demand curve (measured in $) area under the Hicksian demand curve additional income required to achieve old (pre-policy) utility at new prices – income change required to achieve new utility at old (prepolicy) prices • equivalence results • the “taxable income elasticity” Nontaxed Activity as a Composite Good • tax avoidance can occur on many margins – – – – – – – hours per week weeks per year work or not work cheat or not cheat occupational choice compensation composition … • taxable income elasticity as a summary statistic Market Analysis Measuring “the Marginal Tax Rate” • MTR = statutory tax rate? – on a particular margin – substitution between tax base and untaxed activities – “tax base” may be of limited interest economically. eg., • model may be about “capital,” but only some capital income is taxable • model about “cigarettes,” but there are legal and illegal cigarette sales • MTR = average tax rate? – “progressivity” – marginal vs. average substitution