Ch. 5: Factory Location as a Cost-
Minimizing Exercise
Transportation, cost minimization and location
Aly Konkol, Carine Lefevre
Neoclassical Location Theory
Form of economic determinism in which location of factories is ‘dictated’ by economic forces
Interprets firm as an Economic Man ( Homo
Economicus ) with perfect information and rationality
Competition ensures than only economically rational outcomes survive
Follows tradition begun by Alfred Weber in 1929
Two schools of neoclassical location theory
Profit-maximizing
Focus more on distribution costs
Incorporate effects of rival behavior on
location
Applied mainly to personal and retail services
Cost-minimizing
Focus more on transportation costs of inputs
Incorporate effects of location conditions on spatial variations in cost structures
Applied mainly to manufacturing
Types of inputs in costminimization theory
Ubiquitous: can be obtained in any location
Pure: experience no change in physical characteristics during processing
Impure: experience change in physical characteristics during processing
Material Index (MI) for impure materials
•
•
MI = weight of localized raw materials weight of final product
If MI>1, then activity is input-oriented
If MI<1, then activity is output-oriented
Isodapane Analysis
1.
2.
Used when an activity has more than one impure input from different sources
Calculate isotims (lines of equal transportation cost around each location factor)
Sum relevant isotims to identify least total transportation cost location (P)
Labour, external economies, etc.
Similar cost surfaces such as labor and external economies of scale can be combined with transportation cost surfaces to form a total cost surface
If L or E is inside the critical isodapane (where savings equal increased transportation cost), factory should relocate there
Spatial Margins to Profitability
As long as revenues exceed costs, plant locations are viable
Viable locations defined by spatial margins to profitability
Graphically summarized by a space-cost transect derived from a cost surface
Allows personal location preferences to be taken into account
Principle of Substitution
Location of factories uses substitutions or trade-offs among various factors
Ex. Procurement and distribution costs
For a factory of a given size, can also substitute among factors of production (land, labor, capital)
Graphing Substitution
Isoquant (line of equal output or scale) shows different combinations of two inputs, X and Y
Isocost lines show the relative costs of X and Y based on their slopes
When isoquant and isocost lines are combined, point on isoquant where costs are lowest determines ideal input combination
Endless variety of substitutions
Christaller’s Central Place Theory
Range of a good: maximum distance consumers will travel to purchase good, or maximum distance good can be transported to consumers economically
According to law of demand, demand will decrease with increased distance from factory
Threshold population: minimum level of demand necessary to sustain factories of at least minimum economically viable size
Inner range of a good: distance within which threshold population exists
More Central Place Theory
Additional factories are possible until all demands are met and surplus profits are eliminated
Ensures that threshold population exists within inner range of good
Assumes demand is evenly distributed and rival factories produce identical goods
Even More Central Place Theory!
Predicts an optimal location pattern for minimizing distribution costs
Factories serve hexagonalshaped market areas
Ensures all possible demands are met in spatially distributed market
Notes on C.P.T.
If factories produce different goods with distinctive thresholds and ranges, most accessible locations will attract factories whose goods have largest threshold/range requirements, as well as lowest
Less accessible locations attract only lowest
Hotelling’s Duopoly Model
Uncertainty over rival behavior may encourage concentration
Two sellers supplying a homogeneous product to a spatially distributed, linear market would locate at the center of the market
Any other location would be unstable because of uncertainty
Distribution costs would be minimized if sellers communicated and located at quartiles
Adopt-Adapt Dichotomy
Firms must “adapt” to changes in markets, resources, technology, or competition, or else they fail
Firms can also be “adopted”, or saved, by the actions of others (eg. government)
Adoption chances are much better for larger companies than smaller, and can be unintended through unexpected currency devaluations, etc.
Location Adjustment Possibilites
Adjustments to changes in economic environment can be in space , organization , or time dimension
Space : adjust operations onsite, change them between sites, develop new sites
Organization : small firms can respond faster, multi-plant firms have more decision-making capabilities
Location Adjustment Possibilities,
Related to Time
Short-term: small firms can use plant more intensively or use more labor, large firms can shift orders among plants
Medium-term: limited for small firm, large firms can do some expansion/consolidation
Long-term: new site locations, M&As
Locational Evolution
Old factories in “obsolete” locations may still be viable because they have paid off investments in fixed capital, which is cheaper than building a new factory
In general: many small firms and plants --> fewer, more dispersed,and larger plants
Product innovation --> process innovation
Industrial Location Policies
Advocated government policies include increasing worker and capital mobility
Regional equilibrium is achieved between core and peripheral regions when demand drives labor prices up in core regions, so firms relocate to peripheral regions for cheaper labor
Eventually, wage rates rise in peripheral regions too, but movement of workers to core region decreases wage pressure
More Industrial Location Policies
In the 1950s and 1960s, subsidies were granted to locate factories on social and political rather than economic grounds
This promoted inefficiency and an unneccesary duplication of facilities
Market solutions were not seen as relevant
During the 1980s and 1990s, many countries reduced or eliminated industrial location policy
Cost Structures and Locational
Orientation
Locational patterns of industries vary because of different cost and revenue structures
Cost structure calculations are based on actual production costs or hypothetical costs of production for brand new state-of-the-art mills
Primary manufacturing: material and transportation costs remain important
Secondary manufacturing: labor inputs are relatively more important
Primary Manufacturing: ex.
Sawmills
Input-oriented, principal raw material is timber
Compare PNW and US South regions with hypothetical mills as of mid-1980s
Wood costs are relatively lower in South, but energy costs are relatively lower in PNW
(overall cheaper in South)
Scale economies have been pushing down average costs of production
Secondary Manufacturing: ex. Auto
Industry
Traditionally has been located in industrialized countries to take advantage of skilled labor and scientific/engineering expertise (external economies)
Seek lower-cost labor in Mexico and Brazil,
South Korea, and Spain
Although Japanese wage rates are average,
Japan has a cost advantage through
“management systems and techniques”
(organization), which increase productivity
Conclusion
Neoclassical location theory emphasizes the
“relentless and rational pursuit of lower costs and more profits”
Criticism (Barnes 1987): denies or simplifies roles for local agency and local and political context, so demeaning the richness of economic geography
Regions are only spaces where capital may or may not be deposited