Finance 2: Investors and Markets The plan for Wednesday May 27, 2009 • Mixed bag of remarks • Sharpe’s Ch. 8. Many words, concepts and thoughts; no cases. Remarks The course evaluation form should show up soon. We have A104 (too) for next week’s exam. I forgot the ”self-fulfilling prophecy” Merton remark on Mon. (Yes, I drag that out every time.) Next Wed we also do multi-period portfolio choice from Mossin to Munk. We need to see some equations. Chapter 8: Words & Terms Positive (what people actually do) vs. normative (what people show do) economics. We’ve been ”largely positive”, although the distintics is less than clear. Advisors. (Beware: Salesmen too.) Life-cycle decisions: Education, work, retirement. Pensions: Defined benefit vs. defined contribution. Asymmetric information: Adverse selection and moral hazard. Chapter 8: Past and future returns Densities of 25Y yearly mean and standard deviation estimators 15 st. dev. 10 mean 0 5 Density Expected returns are hard to predict. Even past ones! Standard deviations are more accurately estmated. (Last week’s exercises.) The graph on the right is my version of Sharpe’s exepriment in Sec. 8.4. Increasing sampling frequency makes this even more pronounced. -0.1 0.0 0.1 Estimate 0.2 0.3 Sharpe’s Figure 8.4 shows that portfolios based on estimates are all over the place. (The welfare loss, though, is not clear.) Portfolio choice based on historically estimated returns typically gives a lot less diversification that ”we would like”, Three words: Equity premium puzzle. Sharpe suggests (Sec. 8.8.1) reverse optimization/engineering: Estimate (co)variances and use (say) CAPM backwards to estimate expected returns. I’m not sure I 100% understand his experimental design on p. 203-4. (Nonzero correlation between something nonrandom and … what?). Hand-In #2. Espec. w/ Black-Litterman thrown in too. Correlation caveat 100 companies ~5,000 covariances to estimate. 500 companies ~ 125,000 Probably more than the #observations you have. Clearly, simple estimation is unstable. Popular sol’n: Put some structure on; the single index model, for instance: r_i =a+ b * r_M + eps_i (CAPM if a=0) May work well for stocks and portfolio choice. And looks very stable. However, correlation is not a suitable measure for dependence in extreme cases. Thus, a ”single index approach” does not work well for credit risk modelling. But that was exactly what people did – under the fancier heading of ”the Gaussian copula model”. The rest is history. Factor models CAPM type regression of individual stock returns on the market (index) have ”patterns in residuals”. Fama/French say that variations are well explained by 2 extra factors: ”small minus big” returns and ”growth minus value” returns. Fits right into regression framework. Enourmous literature. (One note: Arbitrage pricing theory in Sec. 8.6.2 isn’t what you’d think.) Sec 8.7-8: Investing or Betting? Investing: Take clients’ preferences and positions into account to comprise portfolios. Betting: Try to beat the market based on better predictions. (Picking stocks, strategic asset allocation.) Again, the distinction is fuzzy in reality. Macro consistency is a test: If you advised everybody, would markets clear? If not, you’re betting. Sec. 8.11: More Advice From Sharpe Diversify. Economize. Costs matter. Personalize. Contextualize. (Too bad - Sharpe did almost the whole book without such ”management speak”!) Asset prices are not set in a vacuum” And May I Add: We Have Seen ... Inductive rather than deductive approach. Run experiments, analyze results. When we let agents trade ’till equilibrium, there is a strong tendency for the market to end up in a situation where CAPM’ish results give a good description of prices. That despite assumption voilations. Portfolios, though, can differ a lot. It’s not a zero-sum game: • There are gains from trades – even from structured products. • There are losses from ”poor structures” (Case 11.) But remain sceptical: • Not everybody can beat the market. • There are probably very few free lunches.