Issues in Scaling-up of Development Aid Flows Benu Schneider The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent those of the Financing for Development Office, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, UN Second Committee Panel Discussion on 20 October 2006, New York Recent Trends in ODA ODA rose 31.4% to $106.5 bn in 2005 or 0.33% of GNI (largely due to debt relief to Iraq and Nigeria and Tsunami aid) G8 pledged to double aid to Africa by 2010 to $50 bn; $150 bn are needed to reach the MDGs by 2015; At 0.36% of GNI by 2010, ODA remains below the 0.5% achieved in early years of DAC and below the 0.7% target Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness Adopted at the Paris High-level Forum in 2005 Partner countries & donors committed to: • Implementing Partner Commitments and 12 Indicators of Progress covering (i) Ownership, (ii) Alignment, (iii) Harmonization, (iv) Managing for results, and (v) Mutual accountability; • Periodically monitoring progress; • Several efforts, such as encouraging ownership of development strategy by untying aid, or monitoring, already made good progress; • But Declaration lacks targets to tackle volatility of aid, herding behaviors and selectivity; Issues in ODA flows Aid is concentrated in a few selected countries Aid flows in some cases are large relative to the size of the economy Surges in aid flows have been problematic in spite of a country’s best efforts at macroeconomic management under IMF surveillance and policy advice Issues in ODA flows (contd.) Aid flows – uncertain, volatile and herding among donors Management of surges of aid flows similar to managing surges in private capital flows Management in low income countries is exacerbated by underdeveloped financial sector Costs of surges illustrated with the case study of Uganda, Mozambique. Ghana and Tanzania. Sterilization of donor inflows through sale of government paper led to massive build-up of domestic debt and a rapid increase in interest payments on domestic debt. Sterilization of inflow through sale of foreign exchange to the banking sector led to high outflows of foreign exchange through the banking sector as there was little demand for foreign exchange in the domestic country. Proposal for a new mechanism to intermediate donor flows Selectivity Top 20 recipients received more than half of net bilateral ODA Concentration of ODA in recipient countries, 1981-2004 65% 60% 55% Less than 50 % of aid recipients received 90 % of all aid from DAC donors. 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 Share of top 20 Aid Recipients in Total Aid Flows (bilateral, net) Percentage of Recipient Countries Accounting for 90% of Aid Concentration of ODA ODA a s % of GNI 20.00% Sub-Sahar a Afr ica Uganda 18.00% 16.00% 14.00% 12.00% 10.00% 8.00% 6.00% 4.00% 2.00% 0.00% 1995 Source: OECD/DAC 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Herding Collective deviation of flows of ODA among donors, 1981-2004 0.193381 0.173381 0.153381 0.133381 Herding behavior can be detected by the divergence of actual changes in ODA relative to average behavior. If all donors follow average behavior, the difference between actual and average behavior is zero and there is no herding. A value greater than 0.1 indicates significant herding. 0.113381 0.093381 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 MEANLSV Source: WESS 2005 MEANLSVSMALL MEANLSVBIG Linear (MEANLSV) This figure analyses the behavior of 10 large and 13 small donors and confirms the existence of herding. Volatility Size is not the only important aspect of ODA — predictability is equally important Aid selectivity causes volatility similar to that of private capital flows to emerging market economies The gap between aid commitment and aid disbursement reduces predictability 99 /0 0 00 /0 1 01 /0 2 02 /0 3 03 /0 4 04 /0 5 Uganda:Financing of the Budget (million shs) Overall deficit (including grants) 98 /9 9 Overall deficit (excluding grants) Net External Financing 97 /9 8 Domestic Financing -1700000 -1200000 -700000 -200000 millions of shs Source: Bank of Uganda 300000 Source: Bank of Uganda 01/05/2001 01/04/2001 01/03/2001 01/02/2001 01/01/2001 01/12/2000 01/11/2000 01/10/2000 01/09/2000 01/08/2000 01/07/2000 01/06/2000 01/05/2000 01/04/2000 01/03/2000 01/02/2000 01/01/2000 01/12/1999 01/11/1999 01/10/1999 01/09/1999 01/08/1999 01/07/1999 Shilling billions Uganda: Commercial Bank Reserves 250,000 200,000 150,000 EXCESS RESERVES REQUIRED RESERVES 100,000 50,000 0 Mozambique Financing of the Budget Ghana Financing of the Budget 2004 2004 2003 2003 2002 2002 2001 2001 2000 2000 -1000 -800 -600 -400 -200 1999 0 200 400 600 -20000 million US$ -15000 -10000 -5000 billion meticais Source: Bank of Ghana Source: IMF Tanzania Financing of the Budget (million TZS) ■ Domestic Financing ■ Foreign Financing ■ Budget Deficit without Grants ■ Budget Deficit 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 -2000000 -1500000 -1000000 -500000 M illion TZS Source: Bank of Tanzania 0 500000 1000000 0 5000 10000 “The main challenge to monetary policy continued to be the management of excess liquidity injections, resulting from government expenditure.” Bank of Uganda, Annual Report 2004/2005, p. 16. Monetary and exchange rate policy geared to managing liquidity to keep inflation low and maintain competitiveness by Sale of foreign exchange (round-tripping of flows as banks invest them abroad) Sale of treasury bills Uganda Commercial Banks liabilities in forex and external assets and forex lending to resident private sector million US$ 500 450 Commercial banks forex liabilities (million US$) 400 Commercial banks external assets (million US$) 350 Forex lending to resident private sector (million US$) 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2000 Source: Bank of Uganda 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Mozambique Commercial Banks Foreign Assets and Liabilities Ghana Foreign Assets and Foreign Liabilities of DMBs 600 12000000 10000000 400 million meticais million US$ 500 300 200 100 0 De J Au O cungct03 04 04 04 Source: Bank of Ghana and World Bank WDI De c04 J un05 Au g05 O ct05 De c05 Tanzania Foreign Assets and Foreign Liabilities of Commercial Banks 6000000 4000000 2000000 0 1998 Source: Bank of Mozambique 2000 2002 2003 2004 ■ Foreign Assets Commercial Banks (million) 700 ■ Foreign Liabilities Commercial Banks (million) 600 million US$ 8000000 500 400 300 200 100 0 1997 1998 Source: Bank of Tanzania 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Uganda: Treasury Bills Treasury Bills (million shs) R a t io o f T re a s ury B ills t o G ra nt s Jun-05 Jun-04 Jun-03 Jun-02 04/ 05 Jun-01 0 200000 400000 600000 800000 1000000 1200000 1400000 03/ 04 millions shs Ratio of Treasury Bill Holdings to Money Supply (M2) 02/ 03 04/05 0 1/ 0 2 03/04 02/03 01/02 00/ 01 00/01 0% 50% 10 0 % 15 0 % 99/00 0% Source: Bank of Uganda 20% 40% 60% 80% Uganda External and Internal Debt Interest Payments (million shs) 250,000 Interest on External Debt Interest on Internal Debt 200,000 million shs 150,000 100,000 50,000 0 97/98 Source: Bank of Uganda 98/99 99/00 00/01 01/02 02/03 03/04 04/05 Ghana Treasury Bills/Grants Tanzania Treasury Bills/Grants 2004 2004 2003 2003 2002 0% 50% 100% 150% 200% 250% 300% 350% 400% Source: Bank of Ghana Mozambique Tbills/Grants 2004 2003 2002 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% Source: Bank of Mozambique and World Bank GDF 50% 0% 50% Source: Bank of Tanzania and IMF 100% 150% 200% 250% 300% 350% Ghana Treasury Bills/M2 Mozambique Tbills/M2 Nov-05 2004 Sep-05 Jul-05 Dec-04 2003 Oct-04 Aug-04 2002 Jun-04 Dec-03 0% 0% 10% Source: Bank of Ghana 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% Tanzania Treasury Bills/M2 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 0.0% 10.0% 20.0% Source: Bank of Tanzania 30.0% 40.0% 50.0% 60.0% 70.0% 80.0% 10% 20% Source: Bank of Mozambique and GDF 30% 40% Mozambique Interest Payments on Internal and External Debt (mdc) Ghana Interest Payments on Domestic and External Debt 1200 1000 2500 800 2000 (mdc) Billions of Cedis 3000 1500 600 1000 400 500 200 0 of Source: Bank Ghana 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Source:Bank of Mozambique million TZS Tanzania Interest Payments on Domestic and Foreign Debt ▬ Domestic Interest Payments ▬ Foreign Interest Payments 200000 180000 160000 140000 120000 100000 80000 60000 40000 20000 0 2001 Source: Bank of Tanzania 2002 2003 2004 2005 2003 2004 2005 Investment in treasury bills in the Ugandan economy and private sector credit as a percentage of GDP 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% Treasury Bills/GDP % Private Sector Credit/GDP % 2% 0% 99/00 Source: Bank of Uganda 00/01 01/02 02/03 03/04 04/05 Uganda Assests of the commercial bank system as a percentage of GDP Source: Bank of Uganda Classification by aid absorption and expenditure Not Spent Not absorbed Ghana (0,7) Partly absorbed Ethiopia (20, 0) Partly Spent Mostly Spent Fully Spent Tanzania (0, 91) Uganda (27, 74) Mostly absorbed Mauritius Mozambique (66, 100) Fully absorbed Source: IMF (2005). The Macroeconomics of Managing Increased Aid Inflows: Experiences of Low-Income Countries and Policy Implications NOTE: “Spent” variable = Non-aid fiscal balance deterioration as percent of incremental aid inflow “Absorb” variable = Non-aid current account deterioration as percent of incremental aid inflow Excess liquidity hampers financial market development Excess liquidity hampers the development of the shortend of the market Absence of term money market Segmented financial markets so that liquidity shortages/surpluses are not efficiently intermediated through money, capital, forex, and government securities market 91 T-Bill rate virtually the reference rate for lending and deposit rates Interest rate structure does not reflect the differences in liquidity, maturity and risk Lack of activity in secondary market due to ample liquidity Lack of opportunities to lend in foreign currency Lack of opportunities to build assets in foreign currency Both the above lead to round-tripping of capital flows with banks holding assets abroad Investment in treasury bills and assets abroad reduce the incentive to lend 20.00% 2000000 18.00% 1800000 16.00% 1600000 14.00% 1400000 12.00% 1200000 10.00% 1000000 8.00% 800000 6.00% 600000 4.00% 400000 Rate of change recurrent revenue 2.00% 200000 Recurrent Revenue (million shs) 0.00% 0 97/98 Source: Bank of Uganda 98/99 99/00 00/01 01/02 02/03 03/04 04/05 million shs Uganda Government Recurrent Revenue Uganda Treasury Bill Yields Mean T-Bill Yields 25 20 percent 15 10 91 days 5 182 days 273 days 364 days 0 2000 2001 Note: No issuance of 278 days T Bills in 2005 Source: Bank of Uganda 2002 2003 2004 2005 Uganda M onthly Interest Rates 30 25 per cent 20 15 10 91 da ys 182 da ys 5 273 da ys 364 da ys Source: Bank of Uganda 1 ar -0 M n01 Ja -0 0 v N o -0 0 ep S l00 Ju ay -0 0 M 0 ar -0 M Ja n00 0 Ugandan experience Overestimation of absorption and ability to raise domestic revenue in the expenditure framework A build of internal public debt negating the positive effects of debt relief Short-term choice between higher inflation or higher public debt Limit to the sale of foreign exchange by the authorities as there is very little demand for foreign exchange and banks invest it abroad. There are exposure limits to banks holding assets abroad, thereby posing a limit to the amount of foreign exchange the banks can buy. Increasing the import content of investments require the assured continuation of donor flows The signaling mechanism through the PRSP, PRGF, PSI, and CPIA leads to concentration of aid flows. Risk of reversal of donor flows in Uganda Amendment to the constitution to allow Museveni’s third term and arrest of Museveni’s rival Dr. Besigye caused withholding of aid by United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden. There is close watch on government response to post-election civil unrest and further aid cuts are possible. On the risk of reversibility of aid flows in countries with aid dependent budgets Time-consistent policies alone cannot reduce the risk of reversibility of donor flows as reversibility is determined by political factors as well A smooth transition to domestically financed budgets requires continuation of donor flows in the medium term Risk of huge fiscal and output contractions if aid flows go down with the risk of losing gains in poverty reduction Policy response Increase domestic savings in the interests of long-term viability. Augmentation of domestic revenue to avoid a sudden contraction of the economy. The partial use of donor funds for export diversification, infra-structure development and financial sector reforms import content of investments essential to shield the economy from their liquidity impact and as a secondary effect increase the demand for credit by the private sector. Keep volatility in interest rates in check to encourage take-off of credit. International financial architecture is not well designed to control the volatility and herding of private capital flows from the supply side ….. but donor flows emanate from the official sector International cooperation should aim at designing a framework that takes care of surges, volatility and herding behavior emanating from donor behavior Proposal for a new mechanism to intermediate donor flows Proposal: Establish a donor funded investment account outside the country for development – To mitigate volatility of donor inflows – To mitigate impact on liquidity through build-up of reserves and increased government expenditure – Example: Norway Who will be in control of such a fund? – Board set up by donors, consisting of officials from the Ministry of Finance and Central Banks – Portfolio management entrusted to BIS – Donors can set up indicators to control spending Proposal for a new mechanism to intermediate donor flows (contd.) The role of treasury bills: – Every converted donor dollar impacts monetary base – Central Bank must fine tune timing of inflow, financing of fiscal deficit, and liquidity situation – Dual role of treasury bills: • Source of funding for poverty reduction (in addition to initial dollar conversion) • Mopping up of liquidity after the multiplier has been in operation, minimizing impacts on M2 Additional benefit: development of domestic bond market and other sectors of financial sector Proposal for a new mechanism to intermediate donor flows (contd.) Implications of investment fund for central banks – A central Bank can draw down on resources according to economy’s liquidity situation and timing of expenditure – Allows for longer-term strategy for poverty reduction, independent of political climate or disbursement negotiations – Current trade-off between social sector spending and macro-stability can be avoided – Condition: unused funds in a financial year must be allowed to contribute to stock-building Proposal for a new mechanism to intermediate donor flows (contd.) The road ahead: multi-stakeholder dialogue and research – Donor community, IMF and World Bank are recommended to engage in dialogue and reach an agreement on this crucial issue – Donors need to understand full implications of donor funds in an economy – Further research needed • To investigate concrete operation mechanisms of the proposed investment fund • More generally, to design a new framework for financial intermediation of donor flow