VOTING PARTICIPATION Slide One Audio: This presentation is courtesy of Brian Dille. I'm the speaker and I'm a Professor of Political Science at Mesa Community College, a College of the Miracle Good Community College District in Mesa, Arizona. I hope you've enjoyed this presentation. Slide Two Audio: Welcome to America and Arizona Government for Elementary Teachers. This is Presentation 18, Voting and Participation. In the previous presentations we've discussed the structures of American Government and the various processes of politics. We now turn to the concept of active citizenship, how citizens can use these processes within the structures to affect change and maintain their policy preference outcomes. In this presentation we will first look at the notion of active citizenship and how people and groups engage the system through voting and direct participation. We will then look at elections and campaigns. These are probably the most visible ways that people engage politics, and it's important to understand the rules and dynamics of elections in order to understand election outcomes. Slide Three Audio: In this presentation we will be examining the AEPA Objective 14, understand the election process in the United States, as well as the Arizona Social Studies Standards Strand 3 Concept for Rights, Responsibilities and Roles of Citizenship. As always, I recommend you look at the Strand 3 document that is articulated by grade level so that you can look at the objectives by grade level, and then at the end of this presentation go back and review that document and make sure that you understand the objectives associated with this presentation so that you can exhibit competence on those objectives. Slide Four Audio: When we look at political participation we can divide most people into one of four categories. They're either uninvolved and don't participate, at all, they're a voter who engages in periodic symbolic participation, they're activists who are highly motivated and periodically involved. And then there are the professionals, who do politics as a career. Slide Five Audio: The first group, the uninvolved, actually represent a fairly large portion of Americans. A lot of Americans don't register to vote. A lot of the people who do register to vote don't show-up to vote. Sometimes when the people vote they will only vote on a presidential election, they don't vote during midterm or local elections. Why is that? Why would so many Americans not take advantage of the freedom and the responsibility to engage the system and participate in politics? Well, there's a few reasons for it. Part of it is apathy. People tend not to engage a process unless Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 1 VOTING PARTICIPATION they feel that they have a stake in the process or they feel threatened by that process. And many people don't understand the impact that politics has on them, and so they don't see politics as being something that they need to participate in. Now, of course, politics happens all around us every day, and the consequences of policy decisions affect us every day, but many people don't see those consequences and don't understand the implications. And, as a result, they are apathetic because they feel that they do not need to be involved because the outcome doesn't affect them. Another group of people who are involved are not apathetic, but are, in fact, highly engaged on a particular issue, but they have decided that the political system doesn't work for them. These are people that I refer to as conscientious objectors. They follow the issues, but they make a conscious choice not to participate. This tends to be a fairly small group, graduate students in college is the way I characterize this group. They don't have much impact on the outcome because of their lack of participation in the process. As Mario Cuomo, the former Mayor of New York said, we live in a political system that rewards participation and punishes nonparticipation. Slide Six Audio: The next group of participants are the voters, and this is the vast majority of the electorate. These are people who do vote. They may vote occasionally, but they do vote, but they don't pay a whole lot of attention to politics in between elections and they certainly are not what we would consider activists. They're not donating time or money or marching on the street or writing letters or doing any of those things that might make them an activist, but they are engaged in their civic duty of voting. So their participation is a periodic symbolic participation. They go through the ritual of going to the voting location, going into the booth, making their check or their slide or however or whatever voting machine they're using, and then returning from that and wearing their I Voted sticker with pride. Now political scientists have tried to figure out why people vote because from a rational point of view it doesn't make a lot of sense. The political scientists refer to this as the paradox of voting. The paradox is that if you look at the cost benefit analysis for voting the costs almost always outweigh the benefits. The cost of voting include registering, keeping your registration intact and current. You typically have to travel to a voter location that may or may not be close to your home. If you're an hourly employee you may have to take time off of work which will cost you real money or you have to vote early in the morning or late at night before or after work. You have to engage in the information costs if you want to be a conscientious voter, of taking the time to learn about the issues, learn about the candidates, so that you can make a coherent defendable position or decision. So these were all the costs that are incurred by deciding to vote. Well, what are the benefits of voting? Well, you get one vote towards the overall total of the vote that is cast. So in the United States there are 330 odd million people, only about two-thirds of those people are eligible to vote, the rest are either children or people with green cards or immigrants or whatever, so only about 200 million of those people are eligible to vote. Of those people only about 60% actually register, and so that's down to about 120 million. And of the people who register only about 50% to 60% actually show-up to vote. So out of a country of 330 million, about 80 to 90 Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 2 VOTING PARTICIPATION million on a midterm election, anyways, would actually show-up and vote. Well, your vote is then 180 millionth of the outcome. Or let's not be so pessimistic, let's look at the governor's race in Arizona. In Arizona there's three million people, and if we use the same calculations we come up with about a million votes for a governor's race in Arizona. Well, that means that your vote is one one-millionth of the outcome. Now here's the paradox, is that if you assume people are rational, meaning they engage in cost benefit analysis before they take action then that would suggest that the costs that they would incur to be able to vote are greater than the benefit, the one one-millionth of a voice towards the outcome. So why then does anybody vote? Well, the political scientists struggle about that, but the answer is found in the intangible benefit, that you can't simply weigh on a scale, like one one-millionth, and that is the warm fuzzy that you get from doing your civic duty, from participating in the system, from having a say in the outcome. That has a tremendous value, as the slide says, never underestimate the value of a warm fuzzy. The cost of voting are not great and the benefit from voting is a psychological benefit that comes from knowing that you have contributed to the maintenance of the democratic order that we live in. Another way to look at it, as well, to try to address the concerns with the political scientists who are doing the math is that if you remember so many people can't vote and so many other people don't vote because they're not registered or they don't show-up, that it's as if your vote counts for more than just you because the people who do vote have a disproportionate voice because so many others choose not to use their voice. Another way of thinking of this is that you have a collective impact on your vote that goes beyond merely the mathematical equation of what your single vote might otherwise be worth. An example of this would be in central Phoenix, the central Phoenix neighborhood has a voter turnout rate, meaning the people who actually show-up and vote, of about 75%. And you can contrast that with south Phoenix, which has a voter turnout rate of about 28% give or take 25% to 30% on any given election. If you want to be elected to a city council position in Phoenix then you need to make sure that the central Phoenix people are happy because they're the ones who actually show-up and vote. The south Phoenix people may or may not like you. It's almost irrelevant whether they like you or not because they don't vote, which means their neighborhood doesn't get the attention that the central Phoenix neighborhood gets. In central Phoenix there are no potholes, the police patrol regularly, the lights all work because it's in the interest of the city leadership to keep those people happy. So your individual vote may only be one one-millionth or whatever, but if you and your group, however you define your group, vote consistently and have a high turnout rate then your group will get the attention of policymakers because they like their job and so they want people to vote for them. They're going to pay attention to the people who actually vote. This is one reason, for example, why social security will continue even though it is bankrupting the nation because old people vote and young people, the ones who are going to have to increase their taxes to pay for social security, don't vote. And so politicians will keep old people happy at the expense of young people because young people don't vote. So there is a very real power in voting, even if not individually there's a collective power that if you and your group does not participate, as Mario Cuomo said, you will be punished and the groups that do participate will be rewarded. Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 3 VOTING PARTICIPATION Slide Seven Audio: The next group of actors are activists. Now these are people who engage in a sustained attention span. They're not like the voters who only pay attention periodically to politics. These are people who are passionate about a particular issue or a particular candidate. These are people who follow that issue or candidate over time. And they're people who give of their means or their time to promote their cause or their candidate. They do this because of the passion that they feel for the cause or candidate they're supporting. And they become invested in the outcome of that policy debate or that election. I've seen people who are volunteering on campaigns and they put their whole life and soul into that campaign. And when their candidate wins, they're on top of the world. And when their candidate loses, they fall into a deep funk for days because they're personalized that battle. And the same holds true for issue advocates when their policy preference goes through Congress, they're elated. And when a judge overturns that policy for constitutional reasons, they're devastated. And so activists are involved because they get a personal benefit emotionally from the outcome. In addition, there are advocates who are -- oh sorry, activists who are engaged because they have more than an emotional benefit: they have an actual benefit. They're group has a tangible benefit from policy. Maybe it's a welfare check or maybe it's a subsidy to their farm. Or maybe it's a tariff on their good. They get a tangible benefit from policy. And so those groups are highly motivated to pay attention and have their voice heard and be an activist in favor of or in opposition to the policy that affects them most. Now activists are the vocal groups that draw a lot of the attention in American politics. Now activists can become professionals as they develop a -- expertise on the issue that they're advocating for. Slide Eight Audio: Which leads us to the last group of activists -- or of actors and that's the professionals. The professionals do politics all day. It's their job. They are career professionals who are paid for what they do. And they do that because they're passionate but also because they are good at what they do. And that ability to effectively make policy and advocate for policy preference is recognized by other groups. And it is sought out and it becomes a marketable skill. This is one reason why if you are good at politics, you can do it professionally because others who don't have the time or skills will pay you to use your time and your skills to advocate for policy. In addition, those who win election and are elected into office are part of this category as well. And these are people who either are paid or volunteer but spend large amounts of time in the development and pursuit of public policy. So again, even if they're not getting paid they should be considered in this professional class of actors. Slide Nine Audio: So now that we know what categories to put political actors, let's talk a bit about why political action is important. And the first part of this is to talk about the importance of civil society. Civil society is that part of the society that is a voluntary association. It is not organized Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 4 VOTING PARTICIPATION by the government. It's not regulated by the government. It's not supported by the government. It is people doing things with other people simply because they want to. Examples of this would be churches. It would be people meeting in coffee houses. It would be the Boy Scouts, the PTA, The Oprah Book Club: these are all groups of people who get together to pursue a common interest. And it may not even be a political interest but it's a common interest all the same. The Rosarian Society just loves gardening and culturing roses and so they form an organization to promote their garden. That is civil society. And what I'm arguing is that this civil society is an essential part of a functioning democracy. In fact it is so important that new democracies that don't have a functioning civil society tend to fail. Where as societies that do have a functioning civil society tend to develop vibrant democracies. When authoritarian regimes take over a free society, the first thing they do is destroy or eliminate the civil society. So example: when communist regimes would take over, they would eliminate churches for example. And the reason is, is because civil society are places of organization that they government does not control. And so if it's an authorization regime, that's a potential threat. So labor unions, churches, other volunteer associations are threats to authoritarian government and the very lifeblood of a democracy. Slide Ten Audio: The reason civil society is so necessary for democracy is because it is in the settings of a voluntary association that people learn the habits of citizenship. They learn how to interact with others in a way that is helpful. They learn how to handle meeting, how to organize, how to treat one another. It's in all of these skills and traits that are necessary for citizenship are fostered in clubs and groups and board meetings and all the various elements of civil society. As an example, civil society teaches up not just the skill set of how to run a meeting, but how to treat one another. It teaches us how to be civil in the sense of polite as well as civil in the sense of public. If I have a disagreement with my neighbor because my neighbor belongs to a different political party, therefore I feel that my neighbor's an idiot of course because otherwise he wouldn't belong to that other party. So I might be tempted to think of my neighbor in conflictual terms. He is the opponent. He is the enemy. He is someone who I have no respect for because we have opposite views on some political issues. But then it turns out that we both go to the same church for example. Well now when my neighbor is sitting in a church pew close to me, I'm supposed to be thinking of that person in a different light. I'm supposed to be thinking of that person as a fellow member of this organization: not the idiot over there who belongs to a different political party. And maybe we work together on the Boy Scouts and now because we're working together to teach these kids about citizenship, we develop a certain level of respect for one another. Now I still might think my neighbor's an idiot because his political views are ridiculous, but at least I can acknowledge the good nature of my neighbor: that his intentions might be good even though they've gone horribly awry in his political views. Working together in civil society builds connections between citizens that go beyond politics that cement the society together so that despite our differences, despite the political disagreements we might Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 5 VOTING PARTICIPATION have, we still can treat each other as fellow citizens and accord a certain level of respect to one another. Now in societies that don't have civil society, those relationships don't form. The trust that builds up between people who work together on projects, don't form. And so when there's a political struggle and one side wins, the loser side might burn tires in the intersection. You know, they're not willing to accept defeat from this other group because they don't see a common cause in that society. So, civil society teaches us how to disagree with one another in a civil way. In addition, it also teaches us how to engage in nonviolent conflict resolution when you belong to school board -- well, no that's an elected position. That's not civil society. But if you volunteer your time for the Parent-Teacher Association at the school and you want to have cookies and someone else wants to have popcorn and you have an argument over that, and you decide to have a vote on whether you're going to have cookies or popcorn and you lose, you come to terms with that. Growing up in these types of associations, having the experience of winning some battles and losing other battles, helps instill the norms of nonviolent conflict resolution. So that our politicians - people running the country - get their experience from other political jobs and when the experience they had before they entered political jobs was in these voluntary associations. And so the civil society trains - not just the citizenry - but trains the leadership in how to act in a democratic society. Slide Eleven Audio: This presence or absence of a healthy civil society helps explain why some democracies fail while others succeed. Some societies are simply more prepared for democracy and are able to maintain a democracy better than other societies. Looking at the slide of the triangle and the diamond reminds you of the conversation earlier when we were talking about civil rights, that societies that are authoritarian in structure like the diamond -- oh sorry, like the triangle on the left tend to be societies where democracies do not last. And the last time we saw this diagram, we used a class explanation for why these democracies fail. The elites who control the instruments of power are unwilling to let a populist candidate who is elected by the poor to overturn and radicalize society so they overthrow the democratically elected government and impose their own authoritarian structure to maintain control over that society. Where the societies on the right which have a strong middle class tend to elect establishment leaders who while they may have differences with one another, none of the candidates that are being voted for are radical, revolutionary candidates. Now the presence of civil society impacts this as well because in an authoritarian system, civil society tends not to thrive because the poor who make up the vast majority of society do not have the resources or leisure time to engage in social interactions: voluntary associations. They tend to be working on a subsistence level and they are trying to scrape and make ends meat. They don't have the energy or [inaudible] or education for that matter to organize a viable association. This means that when they get engaged in the political process, they tend to follow leaders from the elite who have been radicalized or they follow an indigenous populist candidate but do not use the nonviolent norms that have been developed in voluntary associations. On the other hand a society with its a diamond shape has a Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 6 VOTING PARTICIPATION stable middle class. The middle class does typically have the education, the economic means, the leisure time and the interest in engaging in social interactions: voluntary associations. And so in these societies, civil society flourishes and becomes a solid basis for democracy to function. Now it's a bit of a chicken and egg situation that you need a good civil society for democracy to flourish and a flourishing democracy fosters civil society. Likewise, if you do not have a strong civil society, your democracy will not flourish. And if you don't have a democracy, you're probably not going to be advocating voluntary associations. So there's a complex connection here between civil society and democracy but it is an absolutely essential one. And if we look in the last 20 years at societies that democratized at the end of the Cold War, some of those democracies flourished and others did not. And you can draw a direct correlation between societies that had a vibrant nongovernmental voluntary association community and the health of democracy versus societies that were authoritarian in structure as well has authoritarian in culture, which means they did not have a strong society in those places. Democracy almost always failed. This is one reason why you can't export democracy. Democracy has to gradually develop along with the gradual development of civil society. Slide Twelve Audio: This is why when Alexis de Tocqueville traveled to America in the early 1800s, he very quickly caught on that civil society was the key to the success of the American experiment in democracy. And de Tocqueville's classic [inaudible] is "Democracy in America" is still used today because of the insights that he gathered from his trip across America were so true to the mark. And when he argued he said, "Americans are joiners." That America breeds civil society. We create voluntary associations organically and quickly. And we can look at the recent Tea Party movement as an example of this. People don't appreciate what's going on in government. They're frustrated with the incumbents. They're feeling somewhat powerless by the amazing amount of money being spent in Washington and as citizens feel like there's not a lot they can do about it. So what is their reaction? Do they burn tires in the intersection? Do they wall off a compound and declare a sovereign state? Well some people have done that but the people who do that are people who are already disconnected from civil society within America. What other people did is they formed a new voluntary association called The Tea Party Movement. This is a group of citizens who are likeminded folks. They get together and they are not connected with the government or a political party: at least initially. And they created this movement that changed the political discourse in the first 6 months of the year 2010. So that dynamic happens over and over and over again in America. It's one reason our democracy is so vibrant that our culture breeds these civil societies: these voluntary associations. The Oprah Book Club, The Boy Scouts, the churches: if we compare American's level of engagement, we're typically higher than most other democratic states and it's because of this culture of joining that exists in the United States. Slide Thirteen Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 7 VOTING PARTICIPATION Audio: There are voices however that warn that the American culture of joining is beginning to shift. Robert Putnam in his books "Bowling Alone" put forward the thesis that American civil society is in trouble and that it has been in decline since the 1960s and a continuous decline and that that decline accelerated in the 1980s. Putnam blames most of that decline on television and later on the internet. Although he published this book before the internet had really taken off. And his argument is that because of television that Americans have changed the way they interact with others: that prior to the advent of television when someone wanted to relax or be entertained or socialize, they left their house and they interacted with their neighbors. They perhaps sat on the front porch and talked to people who were walking by or they would go to a dime store movie and hang out with people before and after that movie. They would go to the local store or the coffee house. They went to poetry readings: something that rarely happens these days. They played board games or they did all of these things that fostered communication, conversation and association. Putman measured the quantity of voluntary associations in the country. He's looking at things like The Elk's Club, The Rotary Club, The Debate Clubs, the various entities that are out there that people belong to: formal, organized, voluntary associations. And what he found is that with television, people's habits changed. Now to relax and to socialize, they don't leave their home. They sit in their living room and turn on the television and are passively entertained as an atomized individual or as a family unit perhaps. But they do not seek that relaxation entertainment through associations with their fellow citizens. So Putman's book was that American's are losing the habits of civil society. And that's what the title of it - The Bowling Alone - meant, that we don't belong to the bowling clubs anymore. We go out and bowl by ourselves. And with the internet that argument is even more stark that we don't even watch TV as a family anymore. Now we seek our entertainment solely from the internet or that as we're entertained by the internet, that is an individualized experience and that it -- the internet doesn't serve the same function of civil society, meaning we seek out communities on the internet that we already agree with. It's a giant exochamber that unlike a normal voluntary association, The Bowling Club, where you're forced to interact with fellow citizens whose views different with yours and come to accept them on the terms of fellow citizen. Instead, in an internet room you typically are talking to people you already agree with or you engage in vilifying anonymous attacks on the other side. IT doesn't foster that mutual understanding or norms of conflict resolution. So Putnam was quite worried that civil society was in serious decline in the United States and meant his book as a voice of warning that if our civil society continued to decline, it was only a matter of time before our democracy began to falter as well. Slide Fourteen Audio: Now I should point out here that Putnam is not without his critics: that there are many people who agree with Putnam and worry quite a bit about the health of our civil society. And many argue that the increased tone of partisanship in our country and the inability it seems for the two political sides to engage in a civil debate where compromise and a mutually agreed upon solution is possible. Some argue that that is evidence that Putnam's concerns are valid: that we Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 8 VOTING PARTICIPATION are losing our ability for nonviolent conflict resolution and that are democracy is beginning to falter as a result. Now there are critics. There are those who disagree with Putnam. And the primary argument is that Putnam being an aging baby boomer has looked at the artifacts of his own culture - the culture he grew up in, in the 1950s - and saw that those institutions, those associations are in decline. And Putnam's book is basically another example of "Those Darn Kids" written by an aging baby boomer. Instead, these critics charge that had he looked at modern forms of association he would have seen that American civil society is continuing to thrive. These critics charge that while the internet can be atomizing - meaning it isolates individuals - it can also build community and the whole social network aspect of the internet had not really occurred yet at the time Putnam wrote his book. The argument is that by erasing the barriers of time and distance, the internet has actually increased the viability of communication and association: that groups can form, friendships can organize, associations can thrive among a group of people who are distant from one another where back in the 1950s, if you were going to join the Rotary Club, you joined your local Rotary Club. And the people you interacted with were your immediate neighbors. Now, you can join a Facebook fan club and be joined with tens of thousands of people from all across the country and even the world in this common interest. Now the counter charge to that is that these associations from acquaintances but not real relationships and that because of the relative anonymity of the internet it still does not foster those norms of nonviolent conflict resolution or the skills of how to run a meeting, how to debate civilly, how to speak in public, those sort of skill sets that civil society perform are not serviced very well by internet chat rooms. Now the other counter arguments Putnam know is that if you discard the 1950s versions of associations, if you're not looking at bowling clubs and the animal clubs - you know the elks and the moose and the rotaries - and instead look at activities. How do people spend their time when they're in public? What you find is that Americans are still very publicly engaged but they're engaged in acts of service more than acts of entertainment or debate. So service organizations have blossomed. The people seek out service opportunities. And if you - and there are people who have measured the amount of voluntary service being done and it is dramatically increased since the 1950s. People donate more time and more money to causes they associate with now than they did back in the 1950s and 60s. And so the argument is that civil society is not in decline and it is not being destroyed as Putnam charges, but rather it is shifting. It is changing the way it's organized from formal groups that have charters and attendance rosters to informal groups that people come and go with: whether that's an internet group or a Race for the Cure or some other voluntary group. So that's the debate on American civil society and I'll let you decide the outcome of that debate: whether or not our civil society is in decline or is being maintained. The one thing I will note though is that it is a vitally important issue whether or not our civil society is in decline because if it is, our democracy is in big trouble. If it's not in decline, then perhaps there's hope for the republic. Slide Fifteen Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 9 VOTING PARTICIPATION Audio: We'll now transition this discussion to looking at elections which is a particular type of participation and is the most prominent and visible example of political participation in our country. As I discuss this section, we'll look at the most prominent election which is the presidency and how a candidate gets the nomination to become president. We'll also look closely at the Electoral College. Then we'll look at campaign finance law and the impact that has on elections. And finally, we'll look at campaign strategies that hold true for any election whether it's a local justice of the peace race or the presidency of the United States. Slide Sixteen Audio: This slide shows a timeline for becoming President. And while you have to turn your head sideways to see the timeline, if we start at the right hand side at January after an election year, and that's when you take the oath of office. That's ultimately how you become President is you take the oath of office. So we ask how do we decide who that person is? Well that's chosen in December of the election year by the electoral college. And we'll discuss that in more detail in a few minutes. So how do we decide who the electoral college votes for? Well that's determined a month previous in November, on election day. The popular vote determines what the electoral college will do, with a little bit of slippage, but by and large the outcome is determined in November. So then you ask who are these people, and how did they get on the ballot? How did they get to be the ones who are selected by the voters? Well those are determined by the political parties in their conventions in the summer of an election season. So at the national party conventions, the delegates to that convention decide who their nominee is going to be. So then you can ask how do the delegates decide who to vote for. Well that's done in the early spring of that year, by primary elections, and we'll talk about that in a little bit as well. But the other question is who are these people that decide who the nominee's going to be? How do they get to be in that room to cast that vote? Well the delegates to the national convention are selected by the state parties in their conventions, in the early summer. And so those state conventions pick who's going to go to the national convention, and then the delegate to the national convention vote for the candidate who won the primary in their state. Now prior to that is what is referred to as the invisible primaries, in the late fall of the year before an election. Because as we'll discuss, primary elections are very, very expensive, as is the national election that following summer. And so to be a real candidate, to have a hope of winning enough primaries to get the nomination that summer, a candidate has to collect a lot of money in the fall, before the spring primaries. And so the invisible primaries are the fundraising efforts by those candidates. And the more effective and popular candidates attract more money, which is why it's often called an invisible primary. Now if you want to raise lots and lots of money in the fall, that means you have to organize yourself in the spring and summer. That kind of an organization that's capable of raising the many millions of dollars necessary doesn't just spring up organically, it has to be organized. And so a serious contender for the President has to have an organization in place nationwide by the spring of the year before the election year. Which means that that winter, a serious candidate has to announce that they're going to run for President, so that volunteers and partisans can be Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 10 VOTING PARTICIPATION recruited in time for that spring and summer organization. So if we back up from the election cycle, if a candidate, for example Barack Obama as the most recent successful candidate to go through this process, was sworn into office January of '09, elected in November of '08, won enough of the primaries in the spring of '08 in order to get the nomination that summer, organized a nationwide campaign in the fall, and successfully fundraised. Now actually, if you looked in the fall of '07, Hillary Clinton actually had a lot more money than Barack Obama did. His money began to flow in in the spring. So Clinton won the invisible primaries, but lost the real primaries in the following spring. And so Obama announced that he was going to run for the Presidency in the late fall of 2006. And so becoming president, if you're a serious contender, is essentially a 2-year process. And so this lecture's being recorded in the year 2010, and so candidates are already beginning to jostle in the Republican party for who will get the nomination to run against Obama in 2012. If you're a serious candidate, that has to be done by December of 2010, otherwise you're not going to succeed in the invisible primaries that have to occur in 2011. So it's a long process, so let's look at some of the details of that process. Slide Seventeen Audio: This is a map of the electoral college. And as mentioned in the previous slide, the electoral college is who determines who the President is going to be. Now some students in the past have said it doesn't matter whether I vote for President, because it's the electoral college that decides anyways. That's not really the way it works, because the delegates from each state are given the charge to vote for their candidate, based on the outcome of the popular vote. So when you go to the polls here in Arizona, and you vote for President, what you're really voting for is which party sends a group of electors to the electoral college. At that statewide convention, which happens in the summer of an election cycle, the state convention decides who the electoral college members are going to be. And the party that wins that state's Presidential election popular vote is the party that gets to send their delegates to the electoral college. So Arizona gets 10 electoral votes. John McCain won the state of Arizona, which meant that those 10 Republicans got to send their votes in to the electoral college. Now that didn't mean John McCain won the national election, because Obama won enough of the larger states to actually win. But that's the way the process works. So the electoral college is directly connected to the popular vote. However, it is done on a state by state basis. The numbers for each state are determined by the number of members of House of Representatives plus Senators. So if you look at Montana, for example, Montana is not a very populous state, so it has two Senators like all other states, but it only has one member of the House of Representatives. So it gets a total of three votes. Arizona has two Senators, and eight members of the House of Representatives, so Arizona gets 10 votes. If you recall the discussion of reapportionment, when we were talking about the presentation on Congress, the 2010 census will likely increase the number of members of Congress that Arizona has. It may go to nine, or it may go to 10. We'll likely gain one or two seats in Congress, because of the shifting population of the country. What that means is that after that reapportionment happens, in the 2012 election, Arizona will have either 11 or 12 votes in the Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 11 VOTING PARTICIPATION electoral college. Now, this has a couple of consequences. The biggest consequence is that the largest states have the biggest voice in the electoral college. In fact, these states are large enough, compared to the other states, that all someone has to do to become President is win the election in five states, and they'll win the majority of the electoral college. Those five states are California, Texas, Florida, New York, and then one of either Pennsylvania, Ohio, or Illinois. And if you can win those four largest states and one of the three middle states, you'll have enough votes to guarantee the electoral college. Now it doesn't usually work out that way, because California tends to elect Democrats, and New York also tends to elect Democrats. Texas tends to elect Republicans, and Florida vacillates between the two of them. So no one party has a lock on those five states. But it alters the landscape of the contest to be President. Having an electoral college means that if you're President, you need to focus on those populous states. You need to take -- you need to focus on a large state that is in contention. Now you don't want to waste your resources campaigning in a large state where it's hopeless. So Republicans tend to only make a token appearance in California and New York, because they know they're going to lose those states. Democrats tend to not even bother going to Texas, because they know there's no way they'll win that state. They both spend a great deal of time in Florida, because Florida is a swing state -- it doesn't have a dominance of either side. They also, knowing that they can't get all of the big states, that means they need to get most of the medium states. And so candidates spend a lot of time in those medium states that are competitive. So they'll compete quite a bit in Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Illinois. And then they'll also compete in Arizona recently, because Arizona, while it consistently elects Republicans to the legislature, it also elects Democrats to statewide office. And so its 10 votes are up for grabs, and so increasingly Democratic and Republican candidates are beginning to come to Arizona, because it's no longer a solidly Republican electoral state. So what the electoral college does is it focuses the Presidential debate on the key states that are in question, they're swing states. Now some people argue that we should get rid of the electoral college. This debate took a particular force in the 2000 race, where Al Gore won the popular vote, meaning if you just added up all the votes that Al Gore got around the country, and compared that to all the votes that George Bush got around the country, Al Gore had more votes than George Bush. Yet George Bush won the electoral college after the legally contested debate in Florida finally came down on Bush's side. And so many people have argued that the electoral college is undemocratic, and we should get rid of it. Now if we were to eliminate the electoral college, which is a holdover from the founding of the Constitution, where the states and representation by the states was the key question for that generation of Americans - if we were to throw that out, say that's an archaic notion, let's just have a popular vote, what would happen is the electoral landscape for candidates would shift from a large and medium state centered campaign to an urban campaign, because the majority of American citizens live in urban areas. And so candidates would go to major city centers across the country, there are about 30 of them. And they would probably completely ignore the rest of the country, because rural America, as important as it is for our culture, is almost irrelevant electorally. There aren't enough people living the plains states, and much of the intermountain west to bother coming there. So Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 12 VOTING PARTICIPATION from Arizona's point of view, if we were to get rid of the electoral college, it would probably mean an increased presence of Presidential candidates in the Phoenix valley, because Phoenix is one of the top 10 urban centers in the nation. But it would mean that Presidential candidates would ignore rural areas, and particularly go away from some of the more rust belt cities that have declining populations. So the electoral college, that's how it works. And the debate on whether or not to get rid of the electoral college is a little more subtle than is sometimes given credit for. Slide Eighteen Audio: Now to win the electoral college then, you have to win a nationwide campaign, focused on the major population centers of the country. Likewise, to get your party's nomination, you have to essentially do the same thing. You have to win a series of statewide elections in the major population centers of the country. And this is because the political parties have a nomination process that looks remarkably similar to the electoral college, meaning states send delegates to the national convention. And those -- the number of delegates at that convention are also pegged to the populations of those states. So large states send more candidates than small states. So a candidate who wants to be a nominee has to win those races. But here's an ironic thing, is that the primary campaign can often be more expensive than the general campaign. And this is because in the general election, because of the electoral college, candidates can safely ignore states that their party is not competitive. Again, Republicans, it's a waste for their time to go to California or New York, Democrats, it's a waste of their time to go to Texas. However, in the party nomination, it is the Democrats in Texas, you know, both of them who are -- who send delegates to the party. And because it's a populous state, they get to send a lot of delegates, which means democrats have to campaign in Texas if they want to gain the party's nomination. Likewise, Republicans need to campaign in New York and California for the nomination. And so the primary campaigns are actually more far reaching than the Presidential campaigns are. That's an expensive process, which raises the need for fund raising, which we'll talk about in a little bit. It also -- another reason it is more difficult to win a primary campaign than it is to win a national campaign is because the field of contenders are so diverse, and so it's more difficult for any one candidate to stand out and garner support from donors and volunteers to help work with them. So in the slide, this is the 2008 Presidential campaign. We have a slew of Republican candidates on the top slide, and a whole batch of Democratic candidates on the bottom slide. And each of these candidates had to compete with not one opponent, but several opponents, and not in only key states, but across the entire nation. So the primary campaign is grueling and expensive. Slide Nineteen Audio: That expense then requires candidates who want to actually win, as opposed to candidates who just want to run, to gather lots and lots of money. Now let me clarify what I just said. There are some candidates who understand that they don't stand a chance of becoming Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 13 VOTING PARTICIPATION President of the United States. They also realize they probably are not even going to win the nomination of their party, and yet they run for President anyways. This is because for some people, running for President is an end in and of itself. Whether they win is besides the point, they want to run. And there's a couple of reasons for this. One is pure ego -- there's nothing like being the center of attention for several months. But also, as you're making speeches around the country, and drawing attention to the ideas in your speeches, it's a way to -- running for President is a way to attempt to shift the debate, and move the position of your political party on an issue that you feel passionate about. And the party will only move towards your position if you are successful in your early primary races. What happens if there's an early candidate who's successful, and is giving maybe a different message than everyone else is giving, is that the other candidates will begin to adopt that same message as a way to neutralize the threat that this new candidate poses. Once they've adopted your message, you've gained a large victory. You know, one of the reasons you ran for President was to bring these issues up. Well now everybody's talking about these issues, you've succeeded. You don't actually have to be elected President to achieve your policy goals. So those are some of the reasons why people run for President, even though they know they don't stand a chance of actually winning. Alright, but if you're serious about actually winning, then you need to win not just a few key races to draw attention to yourself, you have to win enough races to guarantee the vote and the party convention will go your way. Now there's a whole dynamic to those primaries, and winning early is always good. Because people don't like giving campaign contributions to somebody who's going to lose. And so you need to win early races in order to attract more campaign contributions. So that means you have to be ready with a nationwide mobilization effort before those primaries even begin. Well that takes a lot of money, and so this leads us to the invisible primaries then. The invisible primaries are the primaries that occur behind the scenes. The regular primary, every Joe Schmoe, every registered voter has a voice in who the candidate's going to be. The invisible primary is where the candidates jockey for attention, and the good will of people who have deep pockets, people who have money they're willing to contribute to a political candidate. Now those people are surprisingly available. There are many of them in the country. But with some organization, you can even reach people who don't normally give, and persuade them to give, even in small amounts. And so this invisible primary is an indicator -- an early indicator of the viability of a candidate. And so as the bullet point says on the slide, money is a proxy for the depth of support, and the electability of a candidate. If a candidate is running out of money, that is usually a sign that they probably will have trouble getting people to vote for them, and also a sign that they are not going to really be able to effectively mount a campaign against the other party in the national election. And so the more money problems you have, the more money problems you're going to have. It tends to be a reinforcing cycle, where the more money you get, the more money you're able to attract, because success breeds success. So money is an important measure of support. I have colleagues who thought that Hillary Clinton was going to win the nomination, because she had been the front runner candidate, the media favored her, she had the experience, and the sort of presence of a Presidential candidate. And so they all assumed she would be the candidate. And Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 14 VOTING PARTICIPATION I said no, I don't think it's going to happen, I think Barack Obama's going to get the nomination. And my colleagues looked at me like I was crazy, because Obama had not won the early primary races, and nobody was really talking about him. But my argument was that in the month prior to us having this conversation, Barack Obama had raised more than twice as much money as Hillary Clinton had, that basically Clinton's finance machine had dried up. She'd already tapped everyone who was going to give her money early on, whereas Obama's money machine was just picking momentum up, and getting more and more going. So the invisible primary is important, but does not predetermine the outcome. 'Cause as I said before, Hillary Clinton won the invisible primary -- she had more money going into the primary season, but yet she lost the nomination. So it's not a determining factor, but it can narrow the field as candidates who would like to be President realize in that fall before the election year that nobody's returning their calls. Those people will drop out, rather than run an ineffective campaign in the following spring. Slide Twenty Audio: So let's turn then to the role that money plays in these elections, and the regulations on how that money's gathered, and how it's spent. And so the collective term for all that is campaign finance -- campaign finance law, and campaign finance procedures. It is a fairly arcane concept, and only -- not that many people are specialists in this field. In fact, if you want to make a career as a political consultant, become an expert on campaign finance, and you're guaranteed a lucrative career. But let me talk about some of the history of campaign finance, how the system that we have in place got there. And I'll start the clock in the 1968 Democratic convention. This convention was in Chicago, and it was a complete disaster for the Democrats. What was happening was the anti-Vietnam War peace wing of the Democratic party had their candidate, and then the establishment Democratic party, who were going to continue the war that Johnson had begun, were on the other side of this debate. And at the time, there were not a whole lot of primaries. Most delegates to the state conventions were determined by party caucus, which means party insiders, and establishment party members decided who went to the national convention. Which means that the establishment candidates got the nomination, whereas the insurgent outsider candidates were shut out. And so the followers of the insurgent candidate protested, and were also protesting the war. Well the organizer of the Democratic campaign was Mayor Daley in Chicago. And he was an old-school party boss, you know, machine politics guy. And he did not want these hippies and rabble rousers to damage the impact of his convention, or be on TV, and he wanted a smooth convention to be shown. And so he did a couple of things. One was he kicked the media out of the convention floor, because the convention floor was having this debate between the establishment party and the anti-war insurgents. And they didn't want to broadcast that debate, they wanted the party to look unified. So he kicked the media out. Well at the same time, there were anti-war protestors going on in the streets of Chicago, and so he called his union friends, and they had the brick layers come in wielding axe handles. And they waded into these Vietnam War protestors, and started cracking heads open, and just cleared 'em out of the streets. Well the national media that had been kicked out of the convention was just Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 15 VOTING PARTICIPATION sitting around on the streets, and so they broadcast the beatings that were going on in Chicago, rather than the arguments that were going on in the convention. It really was not a good thing for the Democratic party to show that this is what their convention had come to. And so the party had an emergency meeting, and they agreed to some of the demands of the anti-war party members. They agreed to let their candidate give a speech during prime time, and they agreed to give them a role in the convention, if they would stop the protests, and stop the arguments so that the convention would look neat and orderly on TV. What they did was they put them in a committee that was a boring committee that nobody wants to serve on anyways. It was the rules committee. Figured they would -- couldn't do much harm there. Well what these people did was they changed the rules by which delegates are determined to come to the convention. And as a result, they drastically altered the way we pick who are Presidents are going to be. The rule changes are listed on the slide there. They eliminated the winner take all system, unlike the electoral college, where -- using Arizona as an example, if John McCain wins 55% of the vote, and Barack Obama wins 45% of the vote, McCain gets all 10 of Arizona's electoral votes. Well on the primaries, at least on the Democratic side, the winner take all system is gone. So if Barack Obama wins 55% of the vote, and Hillary Clinton wins 45% of the vote, Barack Obama gets 6 of the state delegates, and Hillary Clinton gets 4. So it's proportionally based, not winner take all. That allows minor candidates to stay in the game, even though they may not win outright. And this is one reason Obama was able to gain the nominations, because the states that Hillary Clinton won, she barely won, and the states that Obama won, he typically won by a large margin. And so Obama, through this proportional system, racked up more delegates than Hillary Clinton, even though at the beginning she was winning more states than Obama was. Alright, the next change was they changed from caucuses to primaries. So rather than have the bigwigs in the back room -- the party bosses decide who the candidates were going to be, they would shift to primary elections, where everyday registered members of the party get to decide who the candidates are going to be. And then they increase the representation of women and minorities. And this was tested then in the '72 convention when the southern states sent their usual delegation of good old boy party members, and the Democratic party refused to seat them. They then ran back home and got some women and minorities to bring back with them in order to go to the convention. And ever since then, they've -- the party's been careful to ensure that the representation of the delegation matches the representation of that state. Okay. Why did they do this? To democratize the selection process, to make it so that the people -- the rank and file voters members of the party got to decide who the nominees were going to be, not the wellestablished good old boys, normal everyday party bosses, as had been the case. Now, what was the consequence of this change -- and we'll see in this discussion we're going to have lots of unintended consequences. What it meant is that it became very expensive to become President. Because now, rather than just making sure that the party was on your side, you had to actually run a popular campaign to get the voters in every state to vote for you in the primary, which increased the cost of becoming the party's nominee exponentially. Those increased costs meant that candidates had to go to larger and larger donors to get the money to run, which led to some Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 16 VOTING PARTICIPATION unsettling situations, where wealthy millionaires were bankrolling candidates. That's not at all what the reformers had in mind in 1968. Now one last point on this is that when the Democratic party changed its rules -- remember that elections in the United States are run by states -- the Democrats controlled most of the state legislatures at the time in 1968. So when the Democratic party changed its rules, the state legislatures changed their election laws to comply with those rules, which forced the Republicans to follow those same rules. Now not the representation rules, but the elimination of the winner take all system, and the changing to primaries, that altered the Republican contest. However, the Republican party has more caucuses than the Democratic party does, because it was not a complete one for one change. But by and large, the Republican party was dragged into these changes, along with the Democratic party. Slide Twenty-One Audio: Now the problem of millionaires picking who's going to be President led to -- led Congress to make some changes, in order to try to regulate the situation, and decrease the influence of big money on elections. One incident that triggered these was the election of Richard Nixon. There was a millionaire from New York who singlehandedly paid for a large percentage of Nixon's election campaign. And after Nixon became President, this New York millionaire spent several nights in the Lincoln bedroom, and consulted with the President on several legislation issues. That relationship -- that overly cozy relationship with this donor led some to worry that the electoral system could be bought. So they created these campaign finance laws called the FECA Act, which stands for Federal Election Campaign Act. This was passed in 1971. It did a couple of things. First it set campaign contribution limits. It made it so that you could only contribute a maximum of 1,000 dollars per candidate, per election. You also -- it prohibited unions and corporations, and interest groups from donating money directly to a candidate. Instead, they had to form a political action committee, where its members could give the money to this action committee, which would donate money to the candidates. So there was an indirect path between a union or a corporation, as opposed to the direct path that used to exist. And those packs could only contribute 5,000 dollars per election, per candidate. Now the -- it also allowed for public financing of federal elections for Congressional, Senate, and Presidential, but primarily Presidential elections. If you followed -- if a candidate were to voluntarily abide by the limits set by the FECA law, then they would be eligible for these federal campaign contributions. If they opted out of the campaign finance system, then they were not eligible for the federal funds, but the limits on donors did not apply either. So it led to a situation where some candidates -- and typically most candidates do abide by these rules, while other candidates opt out. Now let's talk about unintended consequences again. It was supposed to decrease the influence of big money on elections. An unintended consequence that happened immediately was political parties around the country -- the state offices of political parties began to dry up, because donors could no longer contribute to the parties. And the national parties began to suffer as well. And so Congress needed to change that. Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 17 VOTING PARTICIPATION Slide Twenty-Two Audio: They changed the law then in 1979 to allow unlimited donations to parties so you couldn't give more than $1,000 to a candidate but you could give whatever you wanted to to political parties. And this enabled the parties to raise their funds, to stay viable and, you know, buy their office space, do all the things that political parties need to do that we talked about in an earlier presentation. All right. Again, the next unintended consequence was that these unlimited donations, which were termed soft money, now hard money was money given directly to a candidate, soft money is given for the party for party building purposes, that soft money allowed a loophole to allow big donors to get around these restrictions. So a big donor would give $1,000 to the candidate and then give $100,000 to the political party and the political party would use that $100,000 to directly benefit the candidate. An example of an abuse that I read was candidate was -- had their campaign staff and they were talking about their media strategy and they were going to put a TV ad on Monday night and a TV ad on Tuesday night and a TV ad on Friday night. And then the campaign manager said, you know, that's our strategy, that's all the money we have for is to do those, I sure wish we had money to run a powerful, effective ad on Wednesday and Thursday but we just don't, oh well. And while the person saying that, they're looking eye contact with the party representative who's sitting in the room taking notes. So the candidate would then run ads on Monday, Wednesday, Friday and then the political party would run ads paid for by the political party on Tuesday and Thursday. So the soft money loophole became a wink-wink nudge-nudge way to bypass the campaign limits and both parties were using that soft money loophole to continue to have large donors have a huge impact on campaign. Slide Twenty-Three Audio: This led eventually to the McCain Feingold Campaign Financial Reform Bill in 2002 and the main goal of that campaign finance bill was to eliminate that loophole and so it -- what that law did is it eliminated soft money altogether, candidates were not allowed to give these unlimited donations and parties couldn't solicit them. Now it did recognize that it's no longer 1971 so it increased the monetary limit that is allowed from 1,000 to 5,000 and it increased the PAC limits as well. So that, you know, sort of adjusting for inflation basically. The other thing that it did is it allowed for bundling so a political entrepreneur could go around and collect large donations from a number of different people and could then bundle those together into one large donation that exceeded the FICA limits and as long as the component parts of that bundle didn't exceed the limits, then that contribution was allowed. Now this opened the door for groups who have access to a lot of reasonably wealthy donors to package those and become very influential. Now the McCain Feingold process is still being determined because the Supreme Court overturned the soft money ban in 2010, it said that Congress cannot prohibit a union or corporation or an interest group from donating money to a presidential campaign or political party. And the court went further and ruled that corporations are people essentially, that they Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 18 VOTING PARTICIPATION have -- they've -- corporations have had that status for a long time but what the Supreme Court did was it extended the First Amendment rights to corporations and said that corporations have the freedom to speak and give money to whoever they give and whatever amounts they want to give. And so that 2010 Supreme Court decision has effectively gutted the McCain Feingold Bill. And so the situation of campaign finance is a little ambiguous right now which, again, is why experts in campaign finance are in high demand. And if you want to work in politics, being a campaign finance lawyer appears to be a growth industry. Slide Twenty-Four Audio: All right. So we've discussed the campaign nomination process, how you become a candidate and we've discussed campaign finance, how you pay for a candidacy so now let's look at the process of a campaign. And some of the strategies that successful political campaign needs to adopt. There are essentially two main categories of strategies, there's persuasion and mobilization. Persuasion refers a campaign that tries to convince people that they're the right candidate, that they try to be the best candidate on the most important issue and get that message out to the broadest array of voters they possibly can in the hopes that they'll convince those voters to vote for them. A mobilization strategy instead, focuses on people who you know are going to vote for you, make sure they show up and they vote. It's taking the voters that already in your pocket and making sure that their vote counts. And then the opposite of trying to prevent or discourage voters who are in the pocket of the other side from being able to vote so that's a mobilization strategy. You're not trying to convince the undecideds, you're trying to make sure that more of your people show up than their people do. Now the problem with these two strategies is that most campaigns have to choose which one to focus on. Now all campaigns do both but which one do you want your emphasis to be on because in a world of finite resources, you have to make choices and you have to put your emphasis or your focus on one or the other. Now if you're awash in money, if you're like the Obama '08 Campaign, which had more money than they could spend, the were able to do both. But the MCain Campaign, which was short on funds, had to decide what was their emphasis going to be on. Slide Twenty-Five Audio: The persuasion strategy is -- involves activities that we often associate with just general campaigning, these are when a campaign uses speeches and advertisements and fliers to convince voters that they are the best candidate on the most important issue. Now the way candidates find out what the most important issue for voters is is with polls. And if you recall the discussion on polling, there are scientific survey methods to accurately determine what people's opinions are on particular issues, as well as how important they feel about a particular issue. Of the opinion polls, they vary in reliability, the least reliable opinion poll is an internet or television survey. Those are, by definition, entertainment because it's impossible to get a representative sample when people decide whether or not to participate in a poll. The next step up above that Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 19 VOTING PARTICIPATION would be push polls, which are intentionally deceptive but nevertheless are contacting real people. Above that would be the campaign polls, polls that are done by a campaign in order to promote their campaign, it's a version of a push poll. So any poll that a campaign advertises and sends out is part of that campaign's persuasion strategy, it's an attempt to either convince people of their position or make their popularity look stronger than it is in an attempt to persuade independents and undecided voters to go ahead and join a winning side. Now the next step above that are media campaigns that are often done carefully and with professionalism but they're not the most accurate because they typically are driven by deadlines. And so that means that they are highly topical but their sample frame is too low to be completely reliable. Now above that are academic polls, which follow all the rules as well, they don't have a publication and so those can be highly accurate but not exactly topical, meaning if you want to know what happened two years ago, read an academic journal. If you want to know what happened today, go to the media, understanding that they might have got it wrong. Now the most accurate polls are those done by campaigns that are not made public. These are polls that are done properly and with the proper sample frame in a short period of time, that's expensive to do. And so candidates who need to know what their constituencies really think will fund a poll but not make the results of those poll public because they usually have to pay a pretty penny for that kind of quick topical information. The candidates will then use that opinion survey as part of their persuasion strategy. Now if they were to make that campaign -- that poll result public, it would be giving free information to their opponent. So the point here is that campaign polls that are maintained by the campaign for the campaign's purposes tend to be the most accurate polling out there. So once a campaign can know what the, what the constituent thinks is the most important position, they then use their polling to find out what the best strategy is or what the most popular position is on that issue. And that gives them a good sense of where they sit relative to other candidates on the most important position of the day. Slide Twenty-Six Audio: This diagram illustrates how those poll results are used to determine a candidate's position so here we have the important campaign of the student body president for the sixth grade and we have three candidates, Rosy, Jacob and Sarah and they are campaigning on a few issues, what the lunch menu is, what kind of games are going to be played at recess and how to adequately supply the crayon box. And those are the driving issues of the grade school. Now different students in the grade school might rank those issues with different importance, the artists really want a full supply of crayons. The kickball kids really want to make sure that kickball is included in the recess games and the equipment for that is there. And then other kids want to make sure that the lunch menu has items that you can actually eat. So if we were to conduct a survey of all the kids at the grade school, what we'd find is that the lunch menu rises in importance, that most kids rank that as the most important issues with recess coming in second and crayons coming in third. Now on the lunch issue topic, Sarah has the favorite position because she advocates smoothies for everybody. Jacob has a position that is popular but not quite Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 20 VOTING PARTICIPATION as popular as Sarah's smoothie idea. And then Rosy is advocating carrots and sandwiches and so her platform is the least popular on that issue. Now Rosy has the best campaign on the recess issue, she belongs to the kickball club and she wants new equipment for kickball. Sarah is also popular but not quite as popular as Rosy, she wants to put tether ball issues in. And then Jacob wants to pave over the kickball area in order to put the four square and use the balls for four square, not a very popular position. On the crayon supplies, Jacob has the best position, Sarah's comes in second, and Rosy's is third. So there's an accurate poll conducted and we find out that this is what the student body thinks of how they rank the issues and then on each of those issues, how they rank the candidates. Now the way you win an election is you position yourself so you are the best candidate on the most important issue. So if the election were held today, Sarah would probably win because her smoothie promise is very popular and the issue of what's going to be there for lunch is the most important issue. So Sarah wins given this situation. Slide Twenty-Seven Audio: Now, if you're helping Jacob with his campaign, that's a problem, because Jacob's going to lose to Sarah. And so you've got a couple of options, a couple of tactics that you can follow to succeed in your persuasion strategy. The first tactic is to change the issue salience. Now, the lunch menu item was the most important issue, but Jacob ranked higher on crayons than Sarah did. So what Jacob's campaign can do is really put a push for why crayons are important, and try to change the issue ranging so that the crayon issue which Jacob naturally is the best candidate on, moves up in that ranking and actually can overcome the lunch issue. And if the debate on the student body election is all about crayons, Jacob wins the election because he's the best candidate on the crayon issue. If Sarah, though, can successfully keep the topic of discussion in the lunchroom, then she wins. So that's one strategy is to change the issue salience. The next strategy is to change the rank on the most salient issue. Just accept the fact that lunch is going to be the dominant issue, and instead you want to persuade people that your position is better. So Jacob will then take Sarah head on on this smoothie issue and argue that his position is better than the smoothie position. And if the persuasive strategy works, then the voters will agree with Jacob that his solution is better than Sarah's solution, and when that happens, the order of the candidates on that issue switches and Jacob then becomes the candidate with the preferred position on the most important issue. So that is as difficult to do as changing the issue salience, but it leads to a direct issue-based confrontation with the leading candidate. Now, the third strategy is to co-opt the opponent's position. Now, this is a strategy that Jacob actually will probably not want to do, because what co-opting does is you adopt your opponent's position. You then become indistinguishable to the voters on that issue. So that issue is then taken off the table, because there's no way to differentiate between the candidates on that issue. At that point the second most important issue becomes the deciding issue. So if Jacob were to adopt the smoothie issue and so there's no difference between Jacob and Sarah on the lunch position, the next most important issue is the playground issue, which Jacob doesn't win. Rosie wins that issue. So this would be a viable option for Rosie to adopt, that if Rosie abandons her carrots and Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 21 VOTING PARTICIPATION sandwich position and instead begins to say, if I'm elected I, too, will put smoothies on, the voters then can't distinguish between Rosie and Sarah on the lunch issue. They then go to their second most important issue, which is recess, and Rosie wins that issue. So that co-optation can be a powerful strategy. The Republicans, for example, hated Bill Clinton because he was really good at doing this. He would take the best ideas the Republicans were putting out there and adopt them as his own, which meant that the voters had no reason to vote for the Republicans because Clinton was going to do the same things, and so they would then go to their next issue, which he was able to beat the Republicans on. So the fourth strategy is to actually change your candidate's position. And this is similar to co-opting the other person's position but it's becoming, taking whatever is the most popular position on the most popular issue and then adopting that as your own. And so in this case, if smoothies at lunch is the most popular issue, then the candidate suddenly becomes an advocate for smoothies. And on the playground, the polling shows that Dodge ball is the most popular game, then the candidate suddenly becomes a big advocate for Dodge ball. And by doing this, it makes it so the candidate can be optimally placed to have the best position on the best issue. Now, there is a danger in doing this, though, is that if the voting public is paying attention and notices when those positions shift, your candidate begins to look like an opportunist, someone who does not have their own stable issue, their own center. They look like they're just going with whatever's popular, and that can really hurt a candidate's credibility. So this last strategy of changing the candidate's position to match what the polls say can be an effective one, but it is fraught with danger if the candidate gets caught doing it. So all of these tactics are designed to position the candidate to be the most popular candidate on the most important issue, because that's how you win an election, using the persuasion strategy. Slide Twenty-Eight Audio: The next campaign strategy is the mobilization strategy. Now, this one is not attempting to persuade the voters that your candidate is the best candidate on the most important issue, rather this tactic is taking voters who are likely to vote for you anyways and making sure that they turn out and vote in larger numbers than the supporters of your opponent, so you're mobilizing voters that are already are going to vote for you rather than persuading voters to decide to vote for you. Now, if we go back to the bell curve of voter distribution that was introduced when we talked about the miracle of aggregation, we have the diehards reds on the left and the leaning reds as we go towards the middle. Then we have the undecideds or independents in the middle, which is the majority of the voters, and then you have the leaning blues as you move to the right, and then you have the diehard blues. So what a mobilization strategy is designed to do is to make sure that the diehards go vote, because you know they're going to vote for you. Almost regardless of your qualifications, they will vote for you. Then the leaners, you just need to reassure them enough to remind them that you are their favorite candidate, and then make sure they show up and vote. The independents and undecideds, they're random voters. They're going to cancel each other out so you can safely ignore them. The leaners on the other side, though, you want to dissuade them from voting, and there's a number of ways Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 22 VOTING PARTICIPATION to do that. The diehards on the other side, there's no way you can influence their voting or not, so the mobilization strategy doesn't focus on the other side. It focuses on your own side, turning out your supporters so that they outnumber the supporters on the other side, recognizing that the independents and undecideds will cancel each other out. Slide Twenty-Nine Audio: Some of the tactics that are followed in this mobilization strategy are a registration drive. Now, this is where you try to get people who are likely to vote for you to register, to be eligible to vote for you. So an example of this would be in the 2008 election, the Obama campaign did a great job of mobilizing younger voters and immigrants, people who were eligible to vote but had never voted before. They used social media and they used peer groups to approach people who had not voted before, to get them excited about that presidential election to get them to vote. And the Obama campaign was highly successful in that mobilization strategy. We can contrast that with the 2004 election, where the Republication party did a masterful job of mobilizing their base. They in almost a stealth campaign, mobilized registered voters using churches throughout the country, by tapping into the religious right, the people who agree with the Republican party on their social issues, and they then did voter registration drives in those faith communities. Those faith communities were more likely to register as Republican than as Democrat, and they then brought a whole bunch of people out to vote who had never really voted before and turned that election for Bush, even though many of the elite thought Kerry was going to win because of the difficulties Bush was experiencing. The Bush campaign in '04 used a mobilization strategy to bring a bunch of new voters , sort of to surprise that outcome. The second strategy is to encourage early voting among the base. Most states now, or many states anyways, allow for early voting, where if you send in a request here in Arizona, you request the Secretary of State's office and they will mail a ballot to you long before the election. You can then fill that ballot out and mail it in. Now, parties love this among their base, because once that ballot has been mailed in, it's in the bank. That's a vote that campaign doesn't have to fight for any longer. That's a vote that's impervious to the persuasion strategy of the other side, because the vote has already been cast. And so if your base is voting early, again, it's highly likely that base, the diehards and the leaners are going to vote for your side. So you want them to vote early. It helps guarantee a large number of votes on election day are already in your pocket. Another strategy is to provide transportation. This strategy is more common in urban areas, poor areas, areas with elderly. These are all areas that are traditional supporters of Democratic candidates, and so this is a tactic that the Democratic party employs more often than the Republican party. They'll have buses that will drive around voter districts and precinct captains will go and take people and provide a free ride to the polls in order to vote. There's no guarantee they're going to vote for your candidate, but you would do this among your base. So if there is a neighborhood community center that has young or immigrants or poor people that tend to congregate at that center, the Democratic party is going to get a bus at that center and have a shuttle going to and from the voting booth. The Republican Party, not interested in organizing a shuttle from that low income center to the voting Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 23 VOTING PARTICIPATION booth. The Republican Party might sponsor shuttles from areas that have a Republican Party advantage over others. The point again is to mobilize each oar base at the expense of the other side's base. Which leads us to the next two strategies, to provide an incentive and to engage in negative advertising. Providing an incentive used to be the way the American elections operated, that you would go to vote in -- and I'm talking 1800s now -- you would go to vote, and there would be two tents. One tent would be the Republican Party and the other tent would be the Democratic Party, and both tents would have barbecue and beer and music and dancing, and you would decide which tent you wanted to go to and partake in the party that was going on. And you'd have to cast your vote in order to go to the party, to the tent. That kind of incentivizing is frowned upon anymore, and illegal. In many cases, parties can't offer beer like they used to. They can't have barbecues for people who voted for their party. Instead, other forms of incentives are to have parties after, in the evening, to try to watch the campaigns. Those typically are only for party activists. They're open to anybody, but typically only party activists attend those. So providing incentives has dramatically decreased as a mobilization strategy. But maybe a precinct chairperson might offer to fix someone's steps if they'll come out and vote, knowing that they're likely to vote for their chosen candidate -- that type of thing. Negative advertising is not trying to get your side to come out so much as trying to keep the other side at home. Everybody hates negative advertising, the sort of black and white pictures with ominous music and some snide, sarcastic narrator talking about how terrible the other candidate is. Nobody likes that, but yet it's used in every election. Why is that? It's because it works, and the way that negative advertising works is it makes everyone sick to death of advertising, negative advertising. As more and more paths run lambasting each other, people tune out and they stop listening to political ads. They get sick to death of it, which means if you're following a mobilization strategy and your opponent is following a persuasion strategy, and the negative campaigning ads have caused a large part of the electorate to tune out of the campaign ads -- I'm sick to death of it, they turn the TV off -- you've now effectively dismantled your opponent's persuasion strategy, because the electorate is no longer paying attention to those carefully crafted messages that the other side is giving. They've tuned out completely. So people turn off the persuasion strategies of your opponent. The other thing that happens is the undecideds, the independents, say those Republicans and Democrats are throwing mud at each other; I'm sick to death of the whole thing. A Pox on Both Their Houses; I'm going to stay home. Well, if someone throws in the towel and stays home, then your mobilization strategy has actually succeeded, because your side, your diehards and your leaners, are voting. Maybe you've already got them to vote early, so those votes are already in the bank. It's the undecideds and the independents and maybe even the leaners on the other side who get disgusted by the whole thing and stay home. That means you win. Your mobilization strategy works. So by decreasing voter turnout, it doesn't improve the nation, but it does help you win your election, which is why both sides tend to resort to negative advertising, even though everybody hates it. So these are some of the strategies that you follow if you're trying to win by mobilization rather than winning through persuasion. Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 24 VOTING PARTICIPATION Slide Thirty Audio: These two strategies sometimes can both be done together, but often are working at odds with each other, and both strategies are expensive, particularly if you're using it on a national stage. It costs a lot of money to buy television and radio ads. It costs a lot of money to send flyers out and mailers and signs. And so that means that choices have to be made. Candidates usually have to pick which of these strategies are they going to follow? Are they going to follow a persuasion strategy or mobilization strategy? It's never exclusive. All campaigns that are effective do both strategies. The issue is, where is your emphasize going to be? And this is particularly true if they're working at odds with each other. For example, if you're doing a persuasion strategy and you're trying to convince the electorate that you're the best candidate on the most important issue, and at the same time, you're engaged in a negative campaign ad to demobilize the other side and to get your independents and undecideds to tune out, well, you've just disengaged your primary audience for your persuasion strategy. So candidates have to be careful that they don't undermine their own efforts as they compete in these two different strategies. Now, some candidates, like Obama in '08, have so many resources that they are able to engage in both. And you can look at examples in the '08 campaign that the Obama campaign effectively used both strategies. A key component of that was to avoid going negative, because they did not want to disengage voters with a negative campaign ad. So while the Obama campaign harshly criticized the Bush Administration, it was only towards the end of the campaign season that he began to harshly criticize McCain. He criticized McCain's positions but tried to stay above the fray. McCain, similarly tried to avoid negative advertising on Obama. Now, whether that's because it was part of a persuasion strategy or the difficulty of how to engage in a negative campaign on Obama, given that he was a young African America, it's difficult to craft a negative ad and not suffer from blowback. But the point is that Obama was able to do both strategies. McCain had to pick because his resources were more tighter. This also emphasizes why fundraising is so critical for effective campaigns. The amount of money you have on hand determines your capabilities. Money is a proxy for popularity and power. If you have money, you have the power to do things. if you don't have money, it's probably because you're not popular enough. You're incapable of generating the kind of support you need. Money drives the campaign. Money is also a good support keeper for a campaign. But all of these combined together, help determine what the campaign strategy will be for a given candidate. Slide Thirty-One Audio: This presentation has focused on how citizens can use the processes of politics in order to effect the outcome of their policies. We looked at why participation is important, what keeps democracy working, why some people participate more than others do. It's important to remember that voting, while essential to the function of democracy, is by itself a symbolic periodic participation, that meaningful participation typically requires more of the citizen. It requires a monetary donations to interest groups that will advocate for causes they support, and it Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 25 VOTING PARTICIPATION requires time to volunteer and engage in with those interest groups. In addition to engaging in explicitly political processes, democracy requires citizens to engage in their communities and as neighbors in voluntary associations, that as they do that they build habits and skill sets needed for citizenship. And finally we've looked at how individuals who want to hold elective office, need to use the campaign process in order to position themselves in a way to be palatable to voters and to ultimately win those elections. And so participation from the individual citizen to the candidate who wins office, is vital for making this experiment in American democracy work. Now, this concludes this presentation. The next presentation, we'll look at how people have used these institutions and these political processes in the past to create change and the public policymaking process that citizens can then impact in order to get government to do what they want it to do. Arizona State University | United States and Arizona Social Studies 26