EP06: Energy and Climate Change Dr Jean-Francois Mercure, Pablo Salas, jm801@cam.ac.uk pas80@cam.ac.uk Lecture 6 – Innovation and economic development Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - McFadden’s discrete choice models Kahneman’s Prospect theory and the perception of gains and losses Rational expectations, perfect information, representative agent and utility maximisation Bounded rationality and access to information Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - Successive waves of technology and investment - The first and second industrial revolutions - Access to new methods and materials: spillovers across sectors - In the neoclassical perspective - Solow’s residual: the contribution of technological change to growth - Arrow’s economic implications of learning-by-doing - Schumpeter and ‘Creative Destruction’ - The role of the innovator, the entrepreneur’s profit - Schumpeter’s historical approach and business cycles - Productivity change and economic development - Endogenous vs exogenous technological progress Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - McFadden’s discrete choice models - Intro: 2 classes of behavioural effects in economics ‘non-rational’ effects Diversity effects - Agents do not follow economic rationality - E.g. Given a repeated problem, agents do not behave the same way every time, i.e. their response is probabilistic - Agents do not behave identically - E.g. Different agents will respond differently, have distributed income i.e. their response is probabilistic - Agents do not follow expected utility theory U = p1x1 + p2x2 +…+ pnxn - Prospect theory Kahneman & Tversky (1979) - Agents do not have the same economic perspectives - Discrete choice theory McFadden (1973) See Ben-Akiva & Lerman (1985) - Classical assumption that is broken: - Rationality, rational expectations - The theorist assumes more knowledge than he really has on the perspectives of the representative agent - Classical assumption that is broken: - Representative agent - The theorist assumes more knowledge than he really has on the perspectives of diverse agents Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - McFadden’s discrete choice models - How to integrate a diversity of agents: the binary logit - The theory can use either a random Utility maximisation or a generalised Cost minimisation (i.e. disutility) It goes as follows: we define the random utility, which is distributed according to agent diversity V is the systematic part (the mean) ε is the distributed (random) part Can be written in terms of many socio-economic components We must find the probability (or proportion of cases) where the utility of option i is greater than the utility of option j Std(ε): Assuming that U follows an extreme value distribution, Solution: a logistic curve: See Ben-Akiva & Lerman, ‘Discrete Choice Analysis’ (1985) Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - McFadden’s discrete choice models - How to integrate a diversity of agents: the binary logit Revealed preferences integrates agent diversity Assuming that U follows an extreme value distribution, Solution: a logistic curve: See Ben-Akiva & Lerman, ‘Discrete Choice Analysis’ (1985) Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - McFadden’s discrete choice models - How to integrate a diversity of agents: the multinomial logit We can define a discrete choice model for a choice between several options. - Here, one of the distributions corresponds to the maximum of all the alternatives We carry out the same calculation, and we obtain: It assumes however that agents have perfect knowledge of all their options See Ben-Akiva & Lerman, ‘Discrete Choice Analysis’ (1985) Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - Kahneman’s Prospect theory and the perception of gains and losses - - Expected utility theory is - Linear in probability - E.g. with x as outcome, p as probability, U = p1x1 + p2x2 + p3x3 +…+ pnxn - Absolute, not relative - Decisions are made on final states, not on changes of state - Symmetrical gains vs losses (a loss is identical to a non-gain) - Both are risk-averse Prospect theory: - People overweight outcomes that are certain - Relative to status quo (or starting situation or perspective) - E.g. (4000, .80) and (3000) (1000, .80) Gains are risk averse, losses are risk-taking - E.g. (4000, .80) and (3000) ≠ (-4000, .80) and (-3000) Kahneman & Tversky, Econometrica, Vol. 47, No. 2. (1979), pp. 263-292 Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - Bounded rationality and access to information - About rational expectations, perfect information, representative agent and utility maximisation To help bring the abstract ideas about energy efficiency costs, benefits, barriers and drivers down to earth, consider a small house in London: my house, comprising the upper two floors of a former collective housing block, sold under Mrs Thatcher’s property reforms. It had old wood-framed windows, filament lights and central heating powered by a gas boiler past its prime that fed water to a hot tank. I checked there was some insulation in the loft and on the tank. I soon fitted compact fluorescent lights – where they would fit (a ‘hidden cost’ eliminated by new designs a few years later) – and eventually (inertia – a ‘behavioural’ feature) got around to buying a new ‘A-rated’ fridge and separate freezer. By that time, they were clearly labelled (reducing the ‘hidden cost’ of trying to find out what was most efficient – and also tweaking my ‘hidden benefit’ driver, the label displaying to everyone I had gone for the best). Anyway, by that time, so many people were buying A efficiency fridges that they were almost as cheap as others (‘economies of scale’). For a long time, I didn’t get round to the rest (inertia again – not a reasoned weighing of costs and benefits). However, one day the local council announced that it was going to do a major windows replacement. Workmen came in – a disruption (‘hidden cost’) – and soon I had a new set of gleaming, double-glazed and high-efficiency windows, together with a hefty bill to pay back over several years. Left to myself, I would never have found the capital (the upfront cost barrier) or organised it (transaction cost), and the savings probably haven’t yet paid back the cost. But the place is less prone to draughts, more secure against break-ins and has less noise from the street (all ‘hidden benefits’). By then, however, I had rented out the house and the tenants get many of these benefits (‘split incentives’). Two years later I received a letter: on 16 September, unless I declined, workers would arrive to install much deeper insulation in the loft. It turned out I only had two inches – at least six was recommended. The council would pay, not me; I just had to clear the loft. As an exercise in behavioural nudging, combined with a bit of subsidy, it was masterful. To get out of it, I’d have to refuse. (How could I possibly do that?) Rising energy prices also helped the tenants consent to the disruption. It took me two days to clear the loft properly and put things back afterwards (a sizeable ‘hidden cost’), but I found some valuable things – including an unused stereo system (!) – and at long last had everything there ordered and sorted, easy to get at again, and with some nice old stuff also given away to charity (‘hidden benefits’, widely shared), followed by noticeably lower energy bills – the classical benefit, but almost entirely irrelevant to the actual decision. Some years later, I have no hesitation in pronouncing the cost-benefit balance to be positive, but if the local council hadn’t butted in, I would probably never have got around to it. I did eventually replace the ancient boiler with a smaller, neater combi condensing one (aided by a small subsidy), which also meant I could remove the old tank – some chunky metal for recycling and a whole new cupboard space for me (more hidden benefits, this time from technical progress). Energy consumption (and costs and emissions) are now way down. Due to my own rational, cost-benefit approach to decision-making? You must be joking – and I was Chief Economist at the Carbon Trust. A final, bemusing thought is that some of the simplistic economic models don’t only assume free market economies to be ‘optimally efficient’, they also assume that changes are reversible: that an efficiency measure that may be cost-effective at high energy prices will reverse if the energy price falls. More sophisticated economic models allow for capital lifetimes, typically a few decades. I fully expect my new windows to be there for decades, and they won’t be replaced by worse ones. As for the loft, I expect the insulation to be there for as long as the house (probably a century or more). Even if energy were free, you wouldn’t find me removing it. Grubb M., Planetary Economics Ch 4 p. 143 (2014) Lecture 6-H2: The adoption of technology and behavioural economics - Bounded rationality and access to information - E.g. Agent diversity in car markets across the globe UK - USA Consumer diversity is high, and is country-dependent. Marketing research generally make full account of agent diversity (market segments) Marketing research + socio-anthropological work = car purchases are socially determined Therefore 1 size fits all approach to policy-making for influencing consumer choice would not work Mercure & Lam, http://arxiv.org/abs/1411.2384 (2015) Lecture 6 – Innovation and economic development Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - Successive waves of technology and investment - The first and second industrial revolutions - Access to new methods and materials: spillovers across sectors - In the neoclassical perspective - Solow’s residual: the contribution of technological change to growth - Arrow’s economic implications of learning-by-doing - Schumpeter and ‘Creative Destruction’ - The role of the innovator, the entrepreneur’s profit - Schumpeter’s historical approach and business cycles - Productivity change and economic development - Endogenous vs exogenous technological progress Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - Successive waves of technology and investment Biotech Internal combustion engine IT Electricity Steam Textiles - Kondratiev Waves: Waves of technological development, approx 55 years long Each wave of technological change was tied to waves of economic development and social change The end of each wave was tied to social, political and economic turbulence The level of R&D investment per sector is indicative of where activity is in the economy: - Currently biotech is leading in terms of R&D investment Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 11 p420 and Ch 9 p 321 (2014) See also Freeman & Louça (2001) and C. Perez (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - The first industrial revolution How does technological change influence the global economy? Investments create productivity growth and price declines that propagate across the economy - Productivity change and cross-sectoral spillovers! Take the first industrial revolution: Textiles and cotton spinning - Investment in a sector leads to investment in a myriad of connected sectors - E.g. investment in textiles spinning technology -> investment in iron industry + water power -> investment in coal mining -> investment building canals & roads -> … - Prices of factors of production decline - E.g. High iron demand in textiles -> investments in iron industry -> learning-by-doing -> lower price of iron -> low cost iron available for other uses - Re-defines the ‘design space’: lower cost factors of production enable new possibilities previously not possible - E.g. Investment in building canals -> low cost transport + coal + iron -> building other types of factories -> other goods become cheaper - New organisation of labour, management practices - Transition of labour from agriculture towards industry, economies of specialisation - General price levels declining (textiles, transport, coal, iron) corresponding to higher productivity, enables access to more with the same income - E.g. we see the development of a middle class - This sets the building blocks for the next wave of innovation: - The steam engine, built with low cost coal, iron and the development of engineering - The steam engine stays in the background as a crazy innovation for a long time Freeman & Louça, As time goes by, (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - The first industrial revolution Example: coal, coke and the production of metal iron - - - - Earlier in history (since the iron age) iron was produced by mixing iron ore with charcoal (carbon) and combusting at high temperatures - This was limited by the availability of vast quantities of wood to turn into charcoal Coal could not be used to produce quality iron Coke is derived from coal by heating it to high temperatures and outgassing liquid and oily hydrocarbons Engineers discovered that coke can replace charcoal: - this expanded the carbon resource for iron production by a huge amount - The production of coke generates combustible gas as by-product: Town gas Coke is still used nowadays to reduce iron ore, - e.g. Fe3O4 + 2C -> 3Fe + 2CO2 - Therefore coal is not just used for heat! The development of the iron and coal industries were tied together Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - Access to new methods and materials: spillovers across sectors Example: changing productivity with R&D investment: Sakichi Toyoda and textiles technology in Japan Development of the weaving device, importation of European technology: human power Development of successive versions of the automatic spinning technology Development of successive versions of the automatic weaving loom Each successive design reduced labour requirement and increased speed of production Productivity increased by a factor ~2 each generation Within ~45 years of R&D productivity changed by approx. a factor of > 10 Toyoda son sold a patent to the UK, re-invested profits and created what is now Toyota… The Toyoda Commemorative Museum of Industry and Technology, Nagoya, Japan, http://www.tcmit.org/english/exhibition/textile.html Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - The second industrial revolution How does technological change influence the global economy? - Productivity change and cross-sectoral spillovers! Take the second industrial revolution: the steam engine, railways, mechanisation - The steam engine was initially used first (among other things) to drain coal mines - Revolution in transport of goods and people - Mass availability of low cost transport over long distances enables new types of trade, business models, modes of living - The availability of the steam engine, machine tools and the engineering industry - Using steam power for mechanical work - Many applications of industry becoming mechanised - Replacing human/animal power for steam power - Using machines to make machines - Steam ships and shipping overseas (See Geels, Research Policy, 2002) Freeman & Louça, As time goes by, (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - Waves of technological change: Kondratiev and the historical approach - Access to new methods and materials: spillovers across sectors How does technological change influence the global economy? - You can see this similarly to the development of branches in a tree E.g. The input-output table representing cross-sectoral exchanges - If relative prices change, industry re-structures and the table changes Productivity increases changes IO coefficients - Technology developments branch out The main branch size is an analogy to sectoral growth, availability and price declines (e.g. coal and iron) Branches feed and enable the growth of an increasing technological diversity Freeman & Louça, As time goes by, (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - In the neoclassical perspective - Solow’s residual: the contribution of technological change to growth Production function: - - Assuming constant returns to scale (neoclassical model) Solow determined that only 1/8 of productivity growth was attributable to increased capital per man-hour => 7/8 of productivity increase is due to technological change (Think of Sakichi Toyoda!) Solow, The Review of Economics and Statistics, (1957) Lecture 6-H1: Waves of technological change - In the neoclassical perspective - Arrow’s economic implications of learning-by-doing Now [knowledge] trend projections, however necessary they may be in practice, are basically a confession of ignorance, and, what is worse from a practical viewpoint, are not policy variables. (Arrow 1962) - Arrow uses aggregate cumulative investment to construct a production function The productivity of capital increases (the labour required per unit capital decreases) He derives employment of labour and capital Obtains a production function with increasing returns to scale - Indicates endogenous growth due to knowledge accumulation Concludes that full employment is only one possibility, but that the solution admits the possible unemployment of either labour or capital It means that the economy can undergo cycles Old capital, with higher labour requirements, is scrapped when its cost of operation is higher than its income Arrow K., The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 3 (1962), pp. 155-173 Lecture 6-H1: Technological change and economic development - Schumpeter and ‘Creative Destruction’ - The role of the innovator, the entrepreneur’s profit Schumpeter: father of evolutionary economic theory (without specifically aiming at that) - Schumpeter 1934: The theory of Economic Development Sets the stage for an explanation of economic change through entrepreneurial activity: 1- The entrepreneur finds a new way to combine factors of production at lower costs 2- He borrows funds to finance his enterprise 3- He applies his innovation, and if successful, reduces costs compared to competitors 4- For a time, the price remaining nearly unchanged, his lower production costs earns him a profit in comparison to his competitors, and he repays his loan over time 5- His competitors catch up, the price declines and reaches the entrepreneur’s costs, making his profit vanish 6- The entrepreneur ventures into other innovations and borrows more funds - Credit plays an essential role: the finance of R&D and innovation Initial Price Cost/Price - Market Price Entrepreneur’s Cost Entrepreneur’s Profit Final Price Time Schumpeter, The theory of economic development (1934) Lecture 6-H1: Technological change and economic development - Schumpeter and ‘Creative Destruction’ - Schumpeter’s historical approach and business cycles - - - According to Schumpeter, R&D investment lead to economic development through the role of the entrepreneur. Economic development corresponds to productivity growth and relative price declines, enabling higher levels of consumption for the same income. This is done through perpetually challenging the state of technology The implication of Schumpeter’s idea means that economic development takes place at the expense of breaking old socio-technical regimes and creating new ones: this was called ‘Creative Destruction’ - E.g. The internal combustion engine changed patterns of mobility and displaced the steam engine - The telephone replaced the telegraph - The smart phone displaced the old landlines, combining telecom with computing - Computerising the firm decentralised management systems (e.g. emails) Credit plays a central role in Schumpeterian economics: - The entrepreneur is not the financier, i.e. he risks someone else’s money (e.g. bank’s) - Entrepreneurial activity takes place in ‘clusters’ - Clusters are due to connections between innovations, which occur within specific sectors - Therefore economic development occurs in clusters, and this leads to business cycles => Economics out of equilibrium => Entrepreneurial activity leads to economic booms and crashes => Speculation on technology leads to bubbles and stock market crashes (e.g. the IT bubble) Schumpeter, The theory of economic development (1934) See also Carlota Perez, Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Technological change and economic development - Schumpeter and ‘Creative Destruction’ - Technology finance and business cycles - Perez associates financial crises historically with technology developments and speculation that they have aroused in financial markets (e.g. the canal mania, railway mania, IT bubble) Technology developments slowly emerge, then attracts attention of financiers, then leads to speculative behaviour, to a financial crash, and afterwards to a technology consolidation phase Carlota Perez, Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital (2001) Lecture 6-H1: Technological change and economic development - Productivity change and economic development - Endogenous vs exogenous technological progress Exogenous growth models - Productivity A(t) is specified ‘in advance’, independently of economic activity - In a utility optimisation framework, it gives a tendency to agents not to invest into R&D since productivity growth happens on its own, ‘like manna falling from heaven’ - However, it keeps the model between clear bounds with unique solutions (i.e. not path-dependent) Endogenous growth models - Productivity increases take place in terms of economic activity through investments in capital and R&D Capital investments Productivity Growth Increased output Price Declines Lecture 6: Further reading - Following this lecture, please read: - Michael Grubb, Planetary Economics (2014) Chapters 9, 10 ,11 Lecture 6: References Arrow K., The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 3 (1962), pp. 155-173 Ben-Akiva & Lerman, ‘Discrete Choice Analysis’, MIT press (1985) Freeman & Louça, As time goes by, Oxford (2001) Grubb, Planetary Economics, Routledge (2014) Kahneman & Tversky, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk, Econometrica, Vol. 47, No. 2. (1979), pp. 263-292 Mercure & Lam, http://arxiv.org/abs/1411.2384 (2015) Carlota Perez, Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital, Edward Elgar (2001) Schumpeter, The theory of economic development, Transaction Publishers (1934) Solow R., Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39, No. 3 (1957), pp. 312-320