An Introduction to Behavioral Finance SIP Course on “Stock Market Anomalies and Asset Management” Professors S.P. Kothari and Jon Lewellen March 15, 2004 An Introduction to Behavioral Finance Efficient markets hypothesis Large number of market participants Incentives to gather and process information about securities and trade on the basis of their analysis until individual participant’s valuation is similar to the observed market price Prices in such markets reflect information available to the participants, which means opportunities to earn above-normal rates of return on a consistent basis are limited Prediction: Stock returns are (almost) impossible to predict Except that riskier securities on average earn higher rates of returns compared to less risky firms 2 An Introduction to Behavioral Finance Behavioral finance Widespread evidence of anomalies is inconsistent with the efficient markets theory Bad models, data mining, and results by chance Alternatively, invalid theory Anomalies as a pre-cursor to behavioral finance Challenge in developing a behavioral finance theory of markets Evidence of both over- and under-reaction to events Event-dependent over- and under-reaction, e.g., IPOs, dividend initiations, seasoned equity issues, earnings announcements, accounting accruals Horizon dependent phenomenon: short-term overreaction, medium-term momentum, and long-run overreaction 3 An Introduction to Behavioral Finance Behavioral finance theory rests on the following three assumptions/characteristics Investors exhibit information processing biases that cause them to over- and under-react Individual investors’ errors/biases in processing information must be correlated across investors so that they are not averaged out Limited arbitrage: Existence of rational investors should not be sufficient to make markets efficient 4 Behavioral finance theories Human information processing biases Information processing biases are generally relative to the Bayes rule for updating our priors on the basis of new information Two biases are central to behavioral finance theories Representativeness bias (Kahneman and Tversky, 1982) Conservatism bias (Edwards, 1968). Other biases: Over confidence and biased self-attribution 5 Behavioral finance theories Human information processing biases Representativeness bias causes people to overweight recent information and deemphasize base rates or priors E.g., conclude too quickly that a yellow object found on the street is gold (i.e., ignore the low base rate of finding gold) People over-infer the properties of the underlying distribution on the basis of sample information For example, investors might extrapolate a firm’s recent high sales growth and thus overreact to news in sales growth Representativeness bias underlies many recent behavioral finance models of market inefficiency 6 Behavioral finance theories Human information processing biases Conservatism bias: Investors are slow to update their beliefs, i.e., they underweight sample information which contributes to investor underreaction to news Conservatism bias implies investor underreaction to new information Conservatism bias can generate short-term momentum in stock returns The post-earnings announcement drift, i.e., the tendency of stock prices to drift in the direction of earnings news for three-to-twelve months following an earnings 7 announcement also entails investor under-reaction Behavioral finance theories Human information processing biases Investor overconfidence Overconfident investors place too much faith in their ability to process information Investors overreact to their private information about the company’s prospects Biased self-attribution Overreact to public information that confirms an investor’s private information Underreact to public signals that disconfirm an investor’s private information Contradictory evidence is viewed as due to chance Genrate underreaction to public signals 8 Behavioral finance theories Human information processing biases Investor overconfidence and biased self-attribution In the short run, overconfidence and biased selfattribution together result in a continuing overreaction that induces momentum. Subsequent earnings outcomes eventually reveal the investor overconfidence, however, resulting in predictable price reversals over long horizons. Since biased self-attribution causes investors to down play the importance of some publicly disseminated information, information releases like earnings announcements generate incomplete price adjustments. 9 Behavioral finance theories In addition to exhibiting information-processing biases, the biases must be correlated across investors so that they are not averaged out People share similar heuristics Focus on those that worked well in our evolutionary past Therefore, people are subject to similar biases Experimental psychology literature confirms systematic biases among people 10 Behavioral finance theories Limited arbitrage Efficient markets theory is predicated on the assumption that market participants with incentives to gather, process, and trade on information will arbitrage away systematic mispricing of securities caused by investors’ information processing biases Arbitrageurs will earn only a normal rate of return on their information-gathering activities Market efficiency and arbitrage: EMH assumes arbitrage forces are constantly at work Economic incentive to arbitrageurs exists only if there is mispricing, i.e., mispricing exists in equilibrium 11 Behavioral finance theories Behavioral finance assumes arbitrage is limited. What would cause limited arbitrage? Economic incentive to arbitrageurs exists only if there is mispricing Therefore, mispricing must exist in equilibrium Existence of rational investors must not be sufficient Notwithstanding arbitrageurs, inefficiency can persist for long periods because arbitrage is costly Trading costs: Brokerage, B-A spreads, price impact/slippage Holding costs: Duration of the arbitrage and cost of short selling Information costs: Information acquisition, analysis and monitoring 12 Behavioral finance theories Why can’t large firms end limited arbitrage? Arbitrage requires gathering of information about a firm’s prospects, spotting of mispriced securities, and trading in the securities until the mispricing is eliminated Analysts with the information typically do not have the capital needed for trading Firms (principals) supply the capital, but they must also delegate decision making (i.e., trading) authority to those who possess the information (agents) Agents cannot transfer their information to the principal, so decisions must be made by those who possess information Agents are compensated on the basis of outcomes, but the principal sets limits on the amount of capital at the agent’s disposal (the book) Limited capital means arbitrage can be limited 13 Behavioral finance theories Like the efficient markets theory, behavioral finance makes predictions about pricing behavior that must be tested Need for additional careful work in this respect Only then can we embrace behavioral finance as an adequate descriptor of the stock market behavior Recent research in finance is in this spirit just as the anomalies literature documents inconsistencies with the efficient markets hypothesis 14 Stock Returns, Aggregate Earnings Surprises, and Behavioral Finance S.P. Kothari, Jonathan Lewellen, Jerold B. Warner SIP Course on “Stock Market Anomalies and Asset Management” March 15, 2004 15 Objective of the study We study the relation between market index returns and aggregate earnings surprises We focus on concurrent and lagged surprises Do prices react slowly? Is there discount rate information in aggregate earnings changes? 16 Motivation At the firm level, post-earnings announcement drift is well-known The slow adjustment to public information is inconsistent with market efficiency Slow adjustment is consistent with behavioral finance Barberis/Shleifer/Vishny (BSV, 1998) Daniel/Hirshleifer/Subrahmanyam (DHS, 1998) Hong/Stein (HS, 1999) Aggregate return-earnings relation serves as an out-ofsample test of the behavioral hypothesis of investor underreaction Literature concentrates on cross-sectional return predictability We provide time-series evidence 17 Main findings Aggregate relation does not mimic the firm-level relation Market returns are negatively (not positively) related to concurrent earnings news Market returns do not depend on past earnings surprises Inconsistent with underreaction (or overreaction) #s seem economically significant Earnings and interest/ discount rate shocks are positively correlated Good aggregate earnings news can be bad news Decomposing earnings changes does not fully eliminate the negative correlation between earnings news and returns, a troubling result 18 Firm level drift and behavioral models Drift could occur if investors systematically ignore the time-series properties of earnings. Bernard/Thomas (1990) show that quarterly earnings changes have positive serial dependence (.34,.19,.06 at the first 3 lags) If investors underestimate the dependence, prices will respond slowly and they will be surprised by predictable changes in earnings. Consistent with this, the pattern of trading profits at subsequent earnings announcements matches the autocorrelation pattern. 19 Evidence Time-series properties of earnings Stock returns and aggregate earnings surprises Returns, earnings, and discount rates 20 Earnings series Compustat Quarterly database, 1970 – 2000 NYSE, Amex, and NASDAQ stocks with … Earnings before ext. items, quarter t and t – 4 Price, quarter t – 4 Book value, quarter t – 4 Plus … December fiscal year end Price > $1 Exclude top and bottom 0.5% based on dE/P 21 Sample Quarterly returns (%), 1970 – 2000 N Returns VW EW CRSP avg. std. deviation 6,062 -- 3.34 8.79 3.82 12.60 Sample avg. std. deviation 2,423 -- 3.26 8.38 3.42 11.40 22 E/P, 1970 – 2000 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 1970.1 -0.02 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1 E/P-agg E/P-ew -0.04 23 Firms w/ positive earnings, 1970 – 2000 5000 1.0 4000 0.8 3000 0.6 2000 0.4 Number of firms (left scale) 1000 0 1970.1 Fraction E > 0 (right scale) 0.2 0.0 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1 24 Quarterly earnings changes (%), 1970 – 2000 Aggregate dE/P Full sample avg stdev Small stocks avg stdev Large stocks avg stdev Low B/M avg stdev High B/M avg stdev VW dE/B dE/E dE/P EW dE/P 0.15 0.39 0.25 0.59 8.26 18.58 0.10 0.36 0.30 0.55 0.42 1.18 0.39 1.14 --- 0.56 0.90 0.86 1.13 0.14 0.37 0.25 0.58 7.90 17.60 0.10 0.35 0.08 0.38 0.17 0.23 0.54 0.73 12.11 16.69 0.16 0.22 0.60 0.69 0.19 1.13 0.11 0.81 --- 0.09 1.02 0.22 1.21 25 Aggregate earnings growth, 1970 – 2000 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1 -0.20 -0.40 -0.60 dE/E-AGG 26 dE scaled by lagged price, 1970 – 2000 .015 .010 .005 .000 1970.1 1974.1 1978.1 1982.1 1986.1 1990.1 1994.1 1998.1 -.005 -.010 -.015 dE/P-VW dE/P-EW 27 Autocorrelations Seasonally-differenced earnings (dE = Et – Et-4) Estimation dE/St = 0 + k dE/St-k + t dE/St = 0 + 1 dE/St-1 + 2 dE/St-2 + ….. + 5 dE/St-5 + t Market: Time-series regressions Firms: Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions 28 Autocorrelations, dE/P, 1970 – 2000 Simple regressions Multiple regressions Lag Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Firms 1 2 3 4 5 0.38 0.22 0.08 -0.28 -0.11 18.48 14.58 5.67 -16.82 -7.03 ------ 0.40 0.14 0.06 -0.42 0.16 18.39 11.20 6.47 -22.83 12.93 -- EW 1 2 3 4 5 0.64 0.40 0.14 -0.15 -0.21 8.81 4.62 1.49 -1.62 -2.26 0.39 0.14 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.61 0.11 0.00 -0.30 0.04 6.33 1.05 0.01 -2.76 0.40 0.43 VW 1 2 3 4 5 0.73 0.52 0.23 -0.00 -0.12 11.54 6.65 2.55 -0.03 -1.30 0.52 0.26 0.04 -0.01 0.01 0.73 0.22 -0.22 -0.18 0.07 7.75 1.93 -1.92 -1.62 0.80 0.57 29 Implications Basic message Specifics Transitory, idiosyncratic component in firm earnings Pattern similar for firms and market Persistence stronger for market – good for tests Aggregate earnings changes are permanent Earnings changes predictable but volatile ( = 18.6%) AR1 similar to AR5 30 Returns and earnings surprises Rt+k = + dE/Pt + et+k k = 0, …, 4 Changes and surprises Market: Time-series regressions Firms: Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions 31 Returns and earnings, 1970 – 2000 Earnings change Earnings surprise k Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Slope T-stat Adj. R2 Firms 0 1 2 3 4 0.53 0.58 0.20 0.09 0.00 26.94 28.70 10.66 5.24 0.03 ------ EW 0 1 2 3 4 -1.30 -3.75 -2.81 -1.36 -3.14 -0.90 -2.60 -1.97 -0.95 -2.23 0.00 0.05 0.02 0.00 0.03 1.54 -3.70 -3.03 1.15 -4.48 0.85 -2.04 -1.65 0.63 -2.43 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.03 0.03 VW 0 1 2 3 4 -4.98 -5.23 -0.80 -1.34 -0.90 -2.31 -2.41 -0.37 -0.63 -0.42 0.03 0.04 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -2.59 -10.10 0.51 -1.41 -3.05 -0.83 -3.34 0.16 -0.45 -0.97 0.04 0.07 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 32 Contemporaneous relation Explanatory power: 4 – 8% Fitted values: dE/P-vw Std. dev. of earnings surprises = 0.25% Slope = –10.10 Two std. deviation shock –5% drop in prices Historical Earnings change in top 25%: return 1% (s.e. = 1.7%) Earnings change in bottom 25%: return 7% (s.e. = 1.6%) 33 Contemporaneous relation Early overreaction No theory Not in firm returns Movements in discount rates Rt = d,t – r,t Cash flow news vs. expected-return news 34 Returns and past earnings Zero to negative No evidence of under-reaction Inconsistent with behavioral theories Results are robust Alternative definitions of earnings Subperiods Annual returns and earnings Subsets of stocks (size, B/M terciles) 35 Summary observations Large portfolio Earnings more persistent Initial market reaction more negative Puzzling from a cashflow-news perspective Small portfolio Reversal at lag 4 Negatively related to CRSP, but not own returns 36 Earnings and discount rates Rt = d,t – r,t d,t = cashflow news r,t = expected-return news = discount-rate news Returns and earnings cov(dEt, Rt) = cov(dEt, d,t) – cov(dEt, r,t) cov(dEt, r,t)? inflation and interest rates (+) consumption smoothing (–) changes in aggregate risk aversion (–) 37 Earnings and the macroeconomy, 1970 – 2000: Correlations Nominal dE EW VW Real dE EW VW TBILL TERM DEF 0.35 -0.35 -0.59 0.60 -0.52 -0.37 0.27 -0.33 -0.66 0.50 -0.52 -0.49 SENT GDP IPROD CONS 0.37 0.13 0.39 0.20 0.40 0.67 0.29 0.54 0.65 0.42 0.61 0.72 0.53 0.67 0.74 0.52 dE = seasonally-differenced earnings Macro = annual changes or growth rates, ending in qtr t 38 Earnings and the macroeconomy, 1970 – 2000 dEt = + TBILLt + TERMt + DEFt + dEt-1 + Nominal dE EW VW Real dE EW VW TBILL 0.04 1.39 0.04 2.72 0.02 0.73 0.03 1.78 TERM 0.00 0.09 -0.01 -0.29 -0.01 -0.23 -0.02 -0.69 -0.55 -4.95 -0.22 -3.96 -0.64 -5.70 -0.26 -4.79 dEt-1 0.39 4.62 0.53 7.53 0.35 4.29 0.53 7.71 Adj. R2 0.49 0.62 0.53 0.62 Adj. R2 w/o AR1 0.41 0.44 0.46 0.43 DEF 39 Controlling for discount rates Two-stage approach dEt = + TBILLt + TERMt + DEFt + dEt-1 + Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k Timing? Rt Rt+1 Rt+2 Rt+3 Rt+4 dEt 40 Returns and earnings, 1970 – 2000 Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k, k Fitted dE Slope T-stat Residual dE Slope T-stat Adj. R2 EW 0 1 2 3 4 -6.86 -5.01 -2.93 -4.20 -1.55 -3.44 -2.51 -1.45 -2.09 -0.76 3.57 -3.02 -2.44 1.47 -4.53 1.89 -1.55 -1.23 0.75 -2.28 0.10 0.05 0.01 0.02 0.03 VW 0 1 2 3 4 -9.08 -2.58 -2.84 -1.09 0.29 -3.27 -0.95 -1.02 -0.39 0.10 0.76 -9.27 2.30 -1.65 -2.53 0.23 -2.84 0.69 -0.49 -0.75 0.07 0.05 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 41 Annual dE/P, 1970 – 2000 Rt+k = + Fitted(dEt) + Residual(dEt) + et+k, Fitted dE Residual dE k Slope T-stat Slope T-stat Adj. R2 EW 0 1 2 3 -4.49 -0.64 2.19 1.11 -2.03 -0.26 0.88 0.45 -2.30 1.29 0.71 -0.27 -1.15 0.58 0.32 -0.13 0.11 -0.06 -0.04 -0.07 VW 0 1 2 3 -5.86 -1.19 2.95 1.41 -2.04 -0.40 0.91 0.44 -3.97 7.74 -1.75 0.71 -1.23 2.29 -0.48 0.20 0.11 0.11 -0.04 -0.07 42 How big are the effects? Over the last 30 years, CRSP VWT portfolio Increased 6.5% in value in the quarters with negative earnings growth Increased 1.9% in value in quarters with positive earnings growth 43 Conclusions Market’s reaction to earnings surprises much different at the aggregate level Negative reaction to good earnings news Past earnings contain little (inconsistent) information about future returns Investment strategy: Long in quarters when aggregate earnings changes are negative Open questions Do earnings proxy for discount rates? Is there a coherent behavioral story for the patterns? 44 Richardson and Sloan (2003): External Financing and Future Stock Returns Prior evidence: Market is sluggish in rationally incorporating information in managers’ market timing motivation for external financing Sluggish reaction means opportunities for abnormal returns Market timing: Raise funds when the firm is overvalued and repurchase shares when the firm is undervalued. Slow assimilation of the information can be because of investors’ information processing biases How large are the returns to a trading strategy? What is the source of the abnormal returns? Is it related to the use of proceeds from external financing? Richardson and Sloan: Examine returns to a trading rule based on net external financing (not individual decisions like share repurchasing) 45 Returns following external financing Prior evidence Low returns following equity offerings, debt offerings, and bank borrowings High returns following share repurchases Managers seem to time external financing transactions to exploit mispricing Market’s immediate reaction to the financing decisions is incomplete (underreaction to public announcements of voluntary decisions) Market gradually reacts over the following one-tothree years – inconsistent with market efficiency and consistent with some of the information-processing 46 biases Returns following external financing Richardson and Sloan show that Net external financing generates a 12-month abnormal return of about 16% (Table 5) The return is on long-minus-short position that has a zero initial investment Long position is in firms that raise the least external financing (i.e., repurchase shares or retire debt) Short position is in firms that raise the most external financing – issue equity or debt or borrow from a bank 47 Returns following external financing Richardson and Sloan show that Use of the proceeds from external financing matters (Table 6) Investment in operating assets generates highest return on the zero-investment portfolio Suggests managers over-invest in assets Market fails to fully assimilate information in accruals What are accruals? Earnings (X) = CF + Accruals (A) When you sell on credit, earnings increase, cash flow does not, but accruals in the form of accounts receivables increase 48 Investment in operating assets is a form of accrual Returns following external financing 49 Returns following external financing External financing decisions as well as exceptional corporate performance (high sales growth or extreme decline) are all associated with large accruals A large increase in sales translates into a large increase in receivables, so an accrual increase is associated with increased sales Accruals also present opportunities to the management to manipulate them and/or create them fictitiously A fictitious dollar of sales and receivables accruals contributes dollar for dollar to earnings before taxes and also enhances profit margin (because the cost of 50 goods sold is not increased with fictitious sales) Returns following external financing Since extreme performance or financing activities or fictitious sales are typically not sustainable, accruals revert If investors suffer from information processing biases, do they recognize the time-series properties of accruals and its implications for future earnings? In particular, does the market recognize that “The persistence of current earnings is decreasing in the magnitude of accruals and increasing in cash flows?” Market overvalues accruals (i.e., fails to recognize that accrualsbased earnings are not permanent) Trading strategy implication: Long in low accrual stocks and short in high accrual stocks to generate above-normal performance. Trading strategy based on external financing is based on accruals – raise capital means high accruals means go short 51 Conclusions Investors exhibit many behavioral biases If the biases are similar across individuals and arbitrage forces are limited, then the behavioral biases can cause prices to deviate systematically from economic fundamentals Recent attempts to test the effects of behavioral biases in stock price data Aggregate earnings data and stock returns Individual firms’ financial data and stock returns Stock returns associated with external financing decisions Stock returns due to investors’ alleged inability to process information in accounting accruals Next set of issues How large is the mispricing? Can it be exploited? What are the barriers to implementation and what are the implications for asset 52 management?