Chapter 10

advertisement
10
Monopolistic Competition and
Oligopoly
 What market structures lie between perfect
competition and monopoly, and what are
their characteristics?
 How is monopolistic competition similar to
perfect competition? How is it similar to
monopoly?
 How do monopolistically competitive firms
choose price and quantity? Do they earn
economic profit?
10
Monopolistic Competition and
Oligopoly
 What is game theory?
 How is game theory related to oligopoly?
 What outcomes are possible under
oligopoly?
 Why is it difficult for oligopoly firms to
cooperate?
Introduction:
Between Monopoly and Competition
Two extremes
• Competitive markets: many firms, identical
products
• Monopoly: one firm, unique product
In between these extremes
• Oligopoly: only a few sellers offer similar or
identical products.
• Monopolistic competition: many firms sell
similar but not identical products.
Market Structures
Perfect
Competition
# of firms
type of
product
control
over price
free
entry/exit
long run 
Monopolistic
Competition
Oligopoly Monopoly
Introduction to Monopolistic
Competition
 Monopolistic competition:
a market structure in which many firms sell
products that are similar but not identical.
 Examples:
• apartments, books, bottled water, clothing, fast
food, night clubs, gasoline
A Monopolistically Competitive Firm
Earning Profits in the Short Run
The firm faces a
downward-sloping
D curve.
At each Q, MR < P.
To maximize profit,
firm produces Q
where MR = MC.
Price
profit
MC
ATC
P
ATC
D
MR
The firm uses the
D curve to set P.
Q
Quantity
A Monopolistically Competitive
Firm with Losses in the Short Run
For this firm,
P < ATC
at the output where
MR = MC.
The best this firm
can do is to
minimize its losses.
Price
MC
losses
ATC
ATC
P
D
MR
Q
Quantity
Comparing Monopolistic
Competition and Monopoly
 Short run: Under monopolistic competition, firm
behavior is very similar to monopoly.
 Long run: In monopolistic competition, entry and
exit drive economic profit to zero (similar to PC).
• If  > 0 in the short run:
New firms enter market, lowering the demand
faced by existing firms, prices and profits fall.
• If  < 0 in the short run:
Some firms exit the market, remaining firms
enjoy greater demand and prices.
A Monopolistic Competitor
in the Long Run
Entry and exit
occurs until
P = ATC and
profit = zero.
Notice that the
firm charges a
price that is
greater than MC,
and does not
produce at
minimum ATC.
Price
MC
ATC
P = ATC
markup
D
MC
MR
Q
Quantity
Why Monopolistic Competition Is
Less Efficient than Perfect Competition
1. Excess capacity (No Productive Efficiency)
• The monopolistic competitor operates on the
downward-sloping part of its ATC curve, and
produces less than the cost-minimizing output.
• Under perfect competition, firms produce the
quantity that minimizes ATC.
2. Markup over marginal cost (No Allocative
Efficiency)
• Under monopolistic competition, P > MC.
• Under perfect competition, P = MC.
Deadweight Loss of Monopolistic
Competition
 Monopolistically competitive markets do not
have all the desirable properties of perfectly
competitive markets.
•
•
Because P > MC, the market quantity is below
the socially efficient quantity.
But, we get variety.
 It is not easy for policymakers to fix this problem:
Firms earn zero profits, so policymakers cannot
require them to reduce prices.
Advertising
 In monopolistically competitive industries,
product differentiation and markup pricing
lead naturally to the use of advertising.
 In general, the more differentiated the products,
the more advertising firms buy.
 Economists disagree about the social value of
advertising. Does it:
• waste resources and manipulate consumers?
• provide information and induce competition?
Oligopoly
 The most important feature of an oligopolistic
market is the interdependence between firms.
• Each firm knows that any change it makes
(regarding price, output, quality, advertising,
etc.) will lead to a reaction from its competitors.
 Products sold may be
• differentiated: cereals, airlines, cars
• undifferentiated: crude oil, raw steel
EXAMPLE: Cell Phone Duopoly in Smalltown
P
Q
$0
140
 Smalltown has 140 residents
5
130
 The “good”: cell service with unlimited
10
120
15
110
20
100
25
90
30
80
35
70
40
60
45
50
anytime minutes and free phone
 Smalltown’s demand schedule
 Two firms: Cingular, Verizon
(duopoly: an oligopoly with two firms)
 Each firm’s costs: FC = $0, MC = $10
EXAMPLE: Cell Phone Duopoly in Smalltown
TR
TC

P
Q
$0
140
5
130
650
1,300
–650
10
120
1,200
1,200
0
15
110
1,650
1,100
550
20
100
2,000
1,000
1,000
25
90
2,250
900
1,350
30
80
2,400
800
1,600
35
70
2,450
700
1,750
40
60
2,400
600
1,800
45
50
2,250
500
1,750
$0 $1,400 –1,400
Competitive
outcome:
P=
Q=
Profit =
Monopoly
outcome:
P=
Q=
Profit =
EXAMPLE: Cell Phone Duopoly in Smalltown
 One possible duopoly outcome: collusion
 Collusion: an agreement among firms in a
market about quantities to produce or prices to
charge
 Cingular and Verizon could agree to each produce
half of the monopoly output:
• For each firm:
Q=
,P=
, profits =
 Cartel: a group of firms acting in unison
1:
Collusion vs. self-interest
ACTIVE LEARNING
P
Q
$0
140
5
130
10
120
15
110
20
100
25
90
30
80
35
70
40
60
45
50
Duopoly outcome with collusion:
Each firm agrees to produce Q = 30,
earns profit = $900.
If Cingular reneges on the agreement and
produces Q = 40, what happens to the
market price? Cingular’s profits?
Is it in Cingular’s interest to renege on the
agreement?
If both firms renege and produce Q = 40,
determine each firm’s profits.
16
ACTIVE LEARNING
Answers
P
Q
$0
140
5
130
10
120
15
110
20
100
25
90
30
80
35
70
40
60
45
50
1:
If both firms stick to agreement,
each firm’s profit =
If Cingular reneges on agreement and
produces Q = 40:
Market quantity =
, P=
Cingular’s profit =
Verizon will conclude the same, so
both firms renege, each produces Q = 40:
Market quantity = , P =
Each firm’s profit =
The Equilibrium for an Oligopoly
 Nash equilibrium: a situation in which
economic participants interacting with one another
each choose their best strategy given the strategies
that all the others have chosen
Collusion vs. Self-Interest
 Our duopoly example has a Nash equilibrium
in which each firm produces Q = 40.
• Given that Verizon produces Q = 40,
Cingular’s best move is to produce Q = 40.
• Given that Cingular produces Q = 40,
Verizon’s best move is to produce Q = 40.
Collusion vs. Self-Interest
 Both firms would be better off if both stick to the
cartel agreement.
 But each firm has incentive to renege on the
agreement.
 Lesson:
It is difficult for oligopoly firms to form cartels and
honor their agreements.
A Comparison of Market Outcomes
When firms in an oligopoly individually choose
production to maximize profit,
• Q is greater than monopoly Q
but smaller than competitive market Q
• P is greater than competitive market P
but less than monopoly P
The Size of the Oligopoly
 As the number of firms in the market increases,
• the oligopoly looks more and more like a
•
•
competitive market
P approaches MC
the market quantity approaches the socially
efficient quantity
Another benefit of international trade:
Trade increases the number of firms competing,
increases Q, keeps P closer to marginal cost
Game Theory
 Game theory: the study of how people behave
in strategic situations
 Dominant strategy: a strategy that is best
for a player in a game regardless of the
strategies chosen by the other players
 Prisoners’ dilemma: a “game” between
two captured criminals that illustrates
why cooperation is difficult even when it is
mutually beneficial
Prisoners’ Dilemma Example
 The police have caught Bonnie and Clyde,
two suspected bank robbers, but only have
enough evidence to imprison each for 1 year.
 The police question each in separate rooms,
offer each the following deal:
•
If you confess and implicate your partner,
you go free.
•
If you do not confess but your partner implicates
you, you get 20 years in prison.
•
If you both confess, each gets 8 years in prison.
Prisoners’ Dilemma Example
Bonnie’s decision
Confess
Confess
Clyde’s
decision
Remain silent
Bonnie gets
8 years
Clyde
gets 8 years
Bonnie goes
free
Remain
silent Clyde
gets 20 years
Bonnie gets
20 years
Clyde
goes free
Bonnie gets
1 year
Clyde
gets 1 year
Prisoners’ Dilemma Example
 Outcome: Bonnie and Clyde both confess,
each gets 8 years in prison.
 Both would have been better off if both remained
silent.
 But even if Bonnie and Clyde had agreed before
being caught to remain silent, the logic of selfinterest takes over and leads them to confess.
2:
The “fare wars” game
ACTIVE LEARNING
The players: American Airlines and United Airlines
The choice: cut fares by 50% or leave fares alone.
• If both airlines cut fares,
each airline’s profit = $400 million
• If neither airline cuts fares,
each airline’s profit = $600 million
• If only one airline cuts its fares,
its profit = $800 million
the other airline’s profits = $200 million
Draw the payoff matrix, find the Nash equilibrium.
27
ACTIVE LEARNING
Answers
2:
American Airlines
Cut fares
$400 million
Don’t cut fares
$200 million
Cut fares
United
Airlines
$400 million
$800 million
$800 million
$600 million
Don’t cut
fares
$200 million
$600 million
28
Other Examples of the
Prisoners’ Dilemma
Advertising Wars
Two firms spend millions on TV ads to steal
business from each other. Each firm’s ad
cancels out the effects of the other,
and both firms’ profits fall by the cost of the ads.
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
Member countries try to act like a cartel, agree to
limit oil production to boost prices & profits.
But agreements sometimes break down
when individual countries renege.
Another Example – A Game of Chicken
 Game of Chicken:
Two hooligans with something to prove drive at
each other on a narrow road. The first to swerve
loses faces among his peers. If neither swerves,
however, a terminal fate plagues both.
Game of Chicken
Player One’s decision
Swerve
Stay
0
5
Swerve
Player Two’s
decision
0
-5
-5
-50
Stay
5
-50
Why People Sometimes Cooperate
 When the game is repeated many times,
cooperation may be possible.
 “Tit-for-tat”
Whatever move your rival takes in one round
you do the same move in the next round.
Why a Tit-for-Tat Strategy Works
American Airlines
Cut fares
$400 million
Don’t cut fares
$200 million
Cut fares
United
Airlines
$400 million
$800 million
$800 million
$600 million
Don’t cut
fares
$200 million
$600 million
33
Download