McCance-Katz, Price, McDougle, Kosten, Black, Jatlow (1993)

advertisement
ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM
Addictive Substances
Substitutes or Complements?
Jordy A. Lindeloo
23-6-2012
Introduction
As a result of mankind’s relentless desire to establish order in a universe of chaos, economists have since the origin of economics as a science - classified the myriad of existing economic goods or
products into different subgroups. In an average economics textbook one is likely to encounter terms
such as normal goods, inferior goods, luxury goods, Giffen goods, Veblen goods et cetera. However,
the term ‘addictive good’ has emerged comparatively recently in the context of economics. This
obviously does not imply that such goods and their consumers (possibly addicts) did not exist before.
As a matter of fact, economists basically ignored the issue of addiction, regarding it as a psychological
rather than economic topic. The most important pioneers of incorporating addiction in the science of
economics were economists Kevin Murphy and Gary Becker, who formulated the highly controversial
theory of Rational Addiction. According to this theory, the consumption of addictive goods is
perfectly rational behaviour for the individual who engages in such activity. This statement is
defended by the claim that although a certain addict’s life might seem miserable, he or she would
have been even more unhappy without the consumption of the addictive substance. However, the
rational addiction model mainly emphasises the fact that addicts respond rationally to present and
future price changes, thereby largely ignoring the non-pecuniary costs that addictive substances may
induce.
Current consumption of addictive goods is influenced by future prices as a result of two
characteristics that differentiate such goods from normal goods. First of all, the consumption of an
addictive product causes tolerance, which implies that the higher the amount of total past
consumption, or so-called “addictive capital”, the lower the utility derived by an individual at a
specific point in time. This indicates that consumption of an addictive good results in harmful
consequences for health and therefore this only applies to unhealthy addictive goods. In case of
healthy addictions such as exercising, a larger quantity of addictive stock leads to higher level of
utility. In addition, reinforcement results from using an addictive good.
2
This means that greater past consumption causes a greater desire for consuming a certain addictive
good (Becker, Grossman, Murphy, 1991). In other words, the marginal utility derived from consuming
an additional unit of addictive substance increases when the stock of past consumption of the
substance increases. This entails the existence of so-called “adjacent complementarity”: past
consumption positively affects present consumption; hence present consumption positively affects
future consumption. Graph 1 illustrates the combined effects of tolerance and reinforcement: both
utility functions (with and without current consumption) are downward-sloping with respect to the
stock of past consumption, an indication of tolerance; in addition, the vertical gap between the two
utility functions widens as the stock of past consumption rises, implying reinforcement.
Graph 1: The lower line depicts individual utility without current consumption of the addictive good;
the upper line demonstrates utility with current consumption
Utility
Marginal Utility of Consumption
Low
High
3
Stock of Past Consumption
Taking the reinforcement effect (or adjacent complementarity) into account, rational addicts react to
announced future price increases by curtailing their present consumption of an addictive substance,
realising that this will reduce their future desire of consumption and hence their future consumption
itself. This implies that addicts also have a downward sloping demand curve and can thus be
considered ‘rational’. This prediction has been supported by empirical evidence. However, being
responsive to price changes does not necessarily make an individual rational. This is claimed by
supporters of the counterpart of the rational addiction model, the so-called myopic addiction model.
They believe that individuals do not always behave in their own best interest. One prominent pitfall
of the rational addiction model is the assumption that agents are in the possession of perfect
information. Needless to say, this assumption does not always hold in the real world. For example, in
the case of drug use, consumers are occasionally unaware of the harmful consequences that drug
usage imposes on them. This possibly explains the empirical findings showing that drug use is
significantly more prevalent amongst individuals having a relatively low socioeconomic status
compared to those having a high socioeconomic status. Those having a lower educational
background and thus having a lower socioeconomic position may lack the essential knowledge
regarding the negative consequences of drug utilisation, thereby being more likely to consume
unhealthy (and possibly addictive) products.
Furthermore, there are several other explanations of why an individual might not behave in
his or her own best interest. Even if a person is provided with complete information concerning the
consequences of utilising a specific drug or another addictive good, he or she might still irrationally
decide to consume the good. One explanation is the concept called ‘time inconsistency’, which
implies that an individual initially intends to behave in a certain way, after which he or she decides to
behave differently. In Behavioural Economics, time inconsistency is modelled by the use of
hyperbolic discounting, in which case future costs and benefits are severely underestimated.
Therefore, individuals behaving in a time inconsistent manner are called ‘present-biased’.
4
When this reasoning is applied to the consumption of addictive goods, a probable possibility exists
that a student decides to consume just two beers at a housewarming taking place two weeks from
now, taking all consequences of drinking too much beer into consideration, while ending up totally
wasted at the housewarming, since he was in a present-biased state of mind at the moment the first
sip of beer was taken. In this case, the rational decision made by his ‘farsighted planner’ was
replaced by the irrational decision made by his ‘myopic doer’, implying that the same person can
have different ‘selves’ behaving differently (Thaler and Shefrin, 1981). Therefore, individuals should
be aware of the fact that they can only make truly rational decisions when they are in the so-called
‘cold’ state and that they have to stick to these decisions when in the ‘hot’ state.
Nevertheless, awareness alone is not sufficient, since weakness of will can still induce an
individual to behave irrationally, despite the fact that he or she is aware of it. This human trait is
clearly demonstrated by the fact that there are countless individuals who desperately want to quit
smoking, but are somehow incapable of doing so. Another example is the too regular occurrence of
obesity amongst inhabitants of developed countries, even though many obese individuals realise
they would be better off in a more healthy condition.
Yet another reason of behaving sub-optimally regarding the consumption of addictive
substances is the ‘status quo bias’. Behavioural economists have discovered the phenomenon that
people in general excessively retain the current situation, in spite of other existing options that
would have made someone better off. With respect to the consumption of addictive goods, one
could argue that once a certain addiction has become a habit, addicts are reluctant to give up this
habit because they do not want to alter the status quo.
Finally, empirical evidence has indicated that many individuals are too confident about their
own abilities, which is called overconfidence or over-optimism.
5
As a result, an individual might have perfect information regarding the addictiveness of a certain
good, but might simultaneously believe that this information does not apply to him or her, since this
individual is overconfident about his or her ability to avoid becoming addicted. Considering the
multitude of explanations of irrational behaviour, claiming that addiction is perfectly rational would
certainly be a bold statement.
Besides, the nature of addictive products is tediously complex. Since a wide array of addictive
substances exists, the effects caused by these substances differ significantly. This implies that some
of these goods have more detrimental effects on health than other goods, whereas yet other goods
impose no harm on health at all. It is no wonder that cocaine usage has more severe consequences
on health than drinking too much coffee. And an individual who is addicted to exercising in the gym
might actually improve rather than deteriorate his or her health. Secondly, addiction is a rather
subjective concept, meaning that a specific substance might be addictive to one person, whilst not to
another. For example, many people in non-Islamic countries consume alcoholic beverages, but only a
fraction of these people is truly addicted. Moreover, individuals can be addicted to products that are
not officially classified as addictive substances, such as an addiction to working, which is called ‘being
a workaholic’. However, these kinds of highly ‘customised’ addictions will not be discussed in this
paper.
Another feature of addictive substances is that some are always maleficent to one’s health,
whereas other substances can be either beneficial, neutral or harmful with respect to health,
depending on the quantity consumed. Alcohol use for instance is not necessarily harmful when
consumed in relatively small quantities, just like food, which is even a necessity, although both are
detrimental to health when consumed in excessive quantities. Other addictive goods on the other
hand, such as cigarettes and cocaine, are always harmful to one’s health, regardless of the amount
consumed. In addition, the consumption of addictive substances can give rise to non-pecuniary costs
that are not directly related to health. Exorbitant alcohol consumption for instance causes damage to
brain cells, thereby diminishing the user’s intelligence.
6
The same holds for a selection of other drugs, such as, among others, cocaine, amphetamines and
heroin. Another example is that cigarette smoking, besides causing harmful effects on health, also
deteriorates the quality of the skin, which can also be considered as a cost to the user. Finally, many
addictive goods not only cause damage to their users, but also affect society at large negatively.
Examples of these so-called negative external effects or externalities are plentiful. For example, being
a passive smoker by inhaling another individual’s cigarette smoke is also detrimental to one’s health.
Driving under influence also imposes a great threat to other persons’ lives. Alcohol abuse is one of
the main contributors to the occurrence of violence in night life areas. These are just three examples
from a virtually endless list of negative externalities that accompany the consumption of addictive
substances.
Taking all these characteristics of addictive goods into account, this paper will focus on the
relationships amongst the variety of addictive substances. So far several researchers have tried to
unravel these relationships, analysing empirical data or conducting experimental research in order to
discover whether addictive goods are substitutes or complements of one another. According to the
rational addiction model, such goods should be complements of each other, since an addict who is
behaving in a rational manner when consuming an addictive substance apparently does not care
much about his or her health and should therefore also consume other unhealthy addictive goods in
order to behave rationally, assuming that all addictive goods provide (at least initially) some sort of
pleasure for the user. However, not caring about one’s health might potentially induce irrational
behaviour as empirical research (for example in the field of Happiness Economics) has proved that
health is a vital determinant of someone ’s happiness in which case a positive relationship between
health and happiness exists.
Despite the attempt of multiple researchers to uncover whether addictive goods are
substitutes or complements, the results are heavily mixed. In order to clarify the findings, potential
explanations for both substitutability and complementarity have to be analysed thoroughly.
7
If this can be accomplished successfully, the empirical evidence will be supported by underlying
theory, which will greatly increase the validity and reliability of the empirical findings. This will be the
extension of this paper regarding the economics of addictive products. There are mainly two reasons
why a study such as this one is of great importance. First of all, from a positive perspective, it will
provide us with a better comprehension of the world around us, which is the goal of any scientific
study. Secondly, from a normative point of view, the results of this study have the potential to be
useful policy implications. For example, if it is proved that alcohol consumption has a positive causal
effect on cigarette consumption, then increasing the governmental taxes on alcoholic beverages
might simultaneously reduce the consumption of alcohol and cigarettes, thereby killing two birds
with one stone. If evidence is provided that alcohol and cannabis consumption are economic
substitutes, then legalisation of cannabis use could lead to an increase of marijuana consumption
and hence to a decrease in the consumption of alcohol. As a result, additional harm caused by
increased utilisation of cannabis could be nullified by decreased alcohol consumption, hence
producing a net effect of zero on population health after legalisation of the cannabis market.
The remainder of this paper will be structured in the following manner: section II will discuss
evidence for complementarity amongst addictive substances; section III will focus on proof of
substitutability amongst addictive goods; in section IV evidence from behavioural economic studies
for both the existence of economic substitutes and complements will be examined; in section V
potential explanations for a complementary relationship will be analysed; in section VI reasons for a
substitute relationship will be examined; section VII will consist of concluding remarks and the final
section will consist of a discussion concerning the political and legislative relevance of this study.
8
Statistical evidence for complementarity
Over the years numerous economists have investigated whether addictive substances are economic
complements or substitutes of each other. The two most commonly utilised substances in their
research have been alcohol and cigarettes. The primary reason for this is the fact that these two
drugs are sold legally in most countries (strict Islamic countries may be an exception) and thus there
is transparency regarding their prices. This information is vital in suchlike research since a price
increase of one good results in a decreased demand for another good in case these two are
complements, while it results in an increased demand for the other good if the two goods are
economic substitutes. These tendencies are called cross-price elasticities. However, an overall
consensus regarding the economic relationship between alcohol and cigarette consumption has so
far not been achieved. Even single papers produce opposing results. In this section multiple papers
will be discussed which conclude that addictive substances are complements of one another.
It is important to note that complementarity between two addictive goods is not necessarily
symmetric (Pacula, 1998a). For example, it could be perfectly possible that smoking cigarettes does
not coincide with drinking alcoholic beverages, but that drinking on the other hand is accompanied
by cigarette smoking. The former relationship either implies that the two goods are economic
substitutes or that they are unrelated, while the latter one means that they are economic
complements. Even if we would assume that those who smoke cigarettes never combine this with
drinking alcohol, we cannot say that the two are therefore economic substitutes. Two goods are
substitutes of each other when they more or less satisfy the same needs. Thus, never combining
salmon with red wine in a restaurant for instance does not entail that the two goods are economic
substitutes.
Using micro-level data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (USA) to estimate
individual demand equations for alcohol and cannabis, Pacula (1998a) concludes that increasing
taxes on beer not only results in a lower demand for beer itself, but also in a reduced demand for
marijuana in an even more sensitive manner.
9
Furthermore, Pacula found that in decriminalised states – states in which consumption of cannabis is
legalised to a certain degree – the prevalence of alcohol consumption is statistically significantly
higher compared to other states. This implies that the greater demand for cannabis in the
decriminalised states has resulted in a greater demand for alcoholic beverages as well and hence
complementarity between the two goods. These findings are reinforced by results produced by Thies
and Register (1993), who used combined data on youth drug use, drinking age laws and
decriminalisation indicators in order to capture the full price of both alcohol and cannabis and
concluded that individuals inhabiting states where cannabis consumption has been decriminalised
were more prone to consuming alcohol as well. Combining the conclusions of these two papers
would suggest that the complementary relationship between alcohol and marijuana consumption
has a symmetric nature. In addition, Saffer and Chaloupka (1998), using nationally representative
household surveys (USA) on drug use, found a negative relationship between the price of alcohol and
cannabis use and consequently concluded that the two are complements.
Evidence for complementarity also exists with respect to the consumption of cannabis and
cigarettes. According to a study conducted by Cameron and Williams (2001), using individual level
data obtained from the National Drug Strategy Household Surveys (Australia), the price of cannabis
has a negative and significant effect on the probability of being a cigarette smoker. A 10 per cent
increase in the price of marijuana decreases the probability of being a smoker by 1.32 percentage
points (Cameron and Williams, 2001). This propensity could result from the fact that cannabis and
tobacco are often consumed simultaneously, known as a joint. When the price of cannabis increases,
the demand for cannabis declines, which is in accordance to the law of demand. Consequently, the
reduced demand for marijuana requires a smaller amount of tobacco, correspondingly resulting in a
lower demand for cigarettes as well. Moreover, they also found a complementary relationship
between the consumption of alcohol and cigarettes.
10
Although the price of alcohol was found to have an insignificant effect on cigarette smoking
participation, the probability of participation in alcohol consumption is negatively and significantly
affected by the price of cigarettes. Therefore, the authors concluded that, on average, alcoholic
drinks and cigarettes are economic complements.
Since most addictive substances are illicit drugs, the availability of price data regarding these
substances is extremely limited. This is problematic for estimating the cross-price elasticities
between two addictive goods, which requires the use of price data. In order to remedy this
impediment, the researchers use proxies as a substitute for the market price. Examples of such
proxies regarding marijuana use include the probability of being arrested for cannabis possession and
the severity of fines and jail sentences after being caught. A higher probability of being arrested can
be translated to a higher indirect price of marijuana in case the consumer is arrested. If, on the other
hand, the probability of the producer or seller of cannabis being arrested is increased, the costs of
producing or selling marijuana will increase. As a result, the producer will charge a higher market
price (direct price) for cannabis. The same reasoning can be applied to the strictness of fines and jail
sentences regarding the production and consumption of marijuana. Hence, decriminalisation status
in a particular state or country is a frequently used proxy for the price of cannabis as legalisation
reduces the indirect costs of producing and/or consuming marijuana and thus its full price.
Compared to studies focusing on the relationship between alcohol and cannabis
consumption, those examining the interdependencies between marijuana and tobacco consumption
are relatively rare. Pecula (1998b), utilising the National Longitudinal Study of Youth, discovered that
both current and past prices of cigarettes have a negative impact on the probability of current
marijuana use, indicating a complementary relationship between the two products. This conclusion is
supported by the results acquired by Chaloupka et al. (1999), who examined cross-sectional data
regarding 8th , 10th and 12th graders from the 1992 – 1994 Monitoring the Future Surveys.
11
They found that an increase in cigarette prices results in a decrease in both the probability – albeit
not statistically significantly so – and frequency of cannabis consumption, whilst the own price
elasticity of cigarettes is less strong than the cross-price effect of cigarettes with respect to marijuana
use. A similar tendency has been found by Pacula (1998a) concerning the cross-price elasticity of
beer with respect to cannabis use, which has been discussed earlier. However, the reliability of the
results indicating that tobacco and marijuana are complements of each other can be disputed. Not
only do the studies rely on a rather limited number of years of time series cross-sectional data,
thereby curbing the variation in cigarette prices, also the number of cross-sections themselves are
too limited to control for unobserved, state-specific characteristics.
Using data on seven years of pooled cross-sections and a more extensive database regarding
marijuana policies, Farrelly et al. (2000) claim that they have controlled for state-specific
characteristics by incorporating state-fixed effects. An example of state-specific characteristics that
potentially bias the results is the fact that state policies could be endogenous. This implies for
instance that states in which tobacco consumption is more prevalent are more likely to impose
higher cigarette taxes. Nevertheless, these authors also conclude that cigarettes and cannabis are
economic complements.
It is important to note that a certain relationship between two addictive products might
differ among different age groups and between gender. This further impedes the implementation of
government policies aimed at hampering addictive substances. For example, alcohol and tobacco
might be complements for teenagers, but substitutes for adults. This means that imposing higher
taxes on alcoholic beverages leads to a diminished amount of cigarettes smoked by teenagers, but a
larger amount smoked by adults. In order to distinguish these different effects, some papers have
either focused on one age group only or examined different age groups and genders independently.
In an elaborate paper produced by Williams, Pecula, Chaloupka and Wechsler (2001), the relationship
between alcohol and marijuana use among US college students has been analysed.
12
The fact that the implementation of stricter alcohol policies aimed at discouraging binge drinking on
college campuses has coincided with an increase of marijuana use amongst college students by 22
per cent between 1993 and 1999 might indicate that the two substances are economic substitutes.
However, the paper provides “overwhelming evidence” that alcohol and cannabis are complements.
In addition to the fact that a higher price of marijuana results in a lower probability of both marijuana
and alcohol consumption, hindering access to alcohol resulted in a reduced amount of marijuana
consumed. Instead, the rise in cannabis consumption amongst college students was caused by a
substantial decrease in the price of marijuana during the period under investigation. Considering that
youths are particularly price responsive due to their relatively low incomes compared to adults, and
thus face a relatively high price elasticity of demand, means that it is not surprising that their
demand for cannabis has increased. The subsequent section will be devoted to existing evidence
regarding substitution amongst addictive products.
13
Statistical evidence for substitution
It is not surprising that there are also economists who believe that a substitution effect exists
amongst the various kinds of addictive substances. Several of such substances, as a matter of fact,
satisfy the same desire: being in an altered state of consciousness. As a result, literature regarding
the substitutability amongst a number of addictive products has accumulated over the last decades,
in which researchers have reinforced their belief in a substitution effect by empirical evidence.
Besides, several economists analysing this subject have found inconclusive or mixed results, implying
that either no clear relationship between two addictive goods has been found or that the empirical
data support both the hypothesis of complementarity and substitutability, depending on the
methods applied and the substances taken into consideration.
According to research conducted by DiNardo and Limieux in 1992, based on annual state
level data measures of cannabis and alcohol use from the 1980 through 1989 Monitoring the Future
(MTF) surveys to examine the effects of higher legal drinking ages, marijuana and alcohol are
economic substitutes. As expected, the higher legal drinking ages resulted in a reduction of alcohol
consumption by youths; in addition, this tendency was accompanied by an almost proportional
increase in the consumption of cannabis. This relationship between the two substances was regarded
as persuasive evidence of an economic substitution effect. The same conclusion has been obtained
by Model, who studied the effects of marijuana decriminalisation on drug related emergency room
hospitalisations and violent crime. She uncovered that states in which cannabis had been
decriminalised faced higher numbers of emergency room hospitalisations resulting from the
consumption of marijuana, whilst those related to alcohol and other illicit drugs were in fact lower.
Furthermore, she found that lower violent crime rates coincide with marijuana decriminalisation. As
many of such crimes result from alcohol abuse, she concluded that the lower crime rates were the
consequence of substation away from alcohol to cannabis in the decriminalised states.
Supplementing these findings is research conducted by Chaloupka and Laixuthai (1997).
14
Utilising data obtained from the 1982 and 1989 Monitoring the Future surveys and the Fatal Accident
Reporting System, they found a positive relationship between the price of cannabis and the number
of fatal and non-fatal driving accidents. They applied the ensuing reasoning in order to explain this
relationship: although a decrease in the full price of marijuana, for example resulting from reduced
penalties for possession and/or use after the implementation of decriminalisation policies,
unsurprisingly leads to a higher demand for marijuana, it simultaneously leads to a lesser demand for
alcoholic drinks and other illegal substances (besides cannabis), thus exhibiting a substitution effect
between marijuana on one hand and alcohol and other illicit drugs on the other. Apparently, this
substitution from one type (alcohol) of drugs to the other (cannabis) causes a decline in the number
of driving accidents. There are several explanations that address this issue. First of all, individuals
under the influence of marijuana, thereby performing so-called “stoned driving”, are potentially
more careful and are driving more slowly than their drunk counterparts (Stein 1983; Robbe and
O’Hanlon, 1993). Secondly, youths tend to be less likely to drive after consuming cannabis, resulting
from the fact that alcohol, unlike marijuana, stimulates risky or reckless behaviours. Thirdly, it is very
probable that the consumption of cannabis does not impair someone’s driving skills as heavily as
alcohol does (Hansteen et al. 1976; Moskowitz et al. 1976). In short, substitution from alcohol to
marijuana leads to a net decrease in driving accidents, insinuating that the higher number of
cannabis induced car accidents is more than offset by the lower amount of driving accidents resulting
from alcohol consumption.
Mixed results are obtained from a study conducted by Cameron and Williams (2001) focusing
on the interrelatedness of cannabis, alcohol and cigarette consumption, which has been discussed in
the previous section. Utilising individual level data from the National Drug Strategy Household
Surveys (Australia), one of their findings is that a 10 percent increase in the full price of alcoholic
drinks increases the probability of marijuana use (not the frequency) by 4.17 percentage points,
implying that the two goods are economic substitutes.
15
However, this is contradicted by the fact that an individual residing in the state of South Australia,
which was the only decriminalised state concerning cannabis use in Australia, is 2.8 percentage
points more likely to consume alcohol. This provides evidence for complementarity instead of
substitutability between the two substances. Nevertheless, the latter finding might be biased as a
result of a so-called ‘South Australia’ effect, which means that inhabitants of this particular state are
more liberal towards alcohol and cannabis use, thereby not necessarily proving evidence of a
complementary relationship between the two types of drugs.
An example of a study that supports substitutability between alcohol and cigarette
consumption is the one conducted by Goel and Morey (1995). Using panel data on the US state-level
for the period 1959 – 1982 the authors estimated both own and cross price effects regarding the
demand for cigarettes and alcoholic beverages. They found cross price elasticities of 0.1 and 0.332
with respect to the demand for cigarettes and liquor respectively, of which the positive signs indicate
economic substitution. However, according to the researchers Decker and Schwartz, their study has
several drawbacks. Firstly, the own price elasticity concerning the demand for alcoholic drinks
reported in their study deviates substantially from those reported in other, closely related studies.
Their figure of -0.13 is much smaller compared to figures obtained in alternative studies, implying a
smaller degree of price sensitivity with respect to alcohol consumption. Furthermore, their estimated
income elasticity of the demand for cigarettes is 0.312, of which its positive sign indicates that
cigarettes are a normal good (an income elasticity larger than + 1 is a luxury or superior good),
thereby opposing the results found elsewhere in the literature which indicate that cigarettes are an
inferior good. Cigarettes being an inferior good means that cigarette consumption decreases as one’s
income rises, thus implying a negative relationship between income and tobacco consumption.
Decker and Schwartz on the other hand, conducting a similar research of their own, used individual
level data rather than state level data concerning approximately half a million individuals from 45
states surveyed between 1985 and 1993 from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System.
16
The advantage of using individual level data over state-level data is the avoidance of biased results
arising from the discrepancy between state sales levels and actual state consumption, since
smuggling and bootlegging of cigarettes among different states account for higher sales levels than
consumption levels in states with relatively low excise taxes on cigarettes and vice versa. In addition,
the use of individual level data capacitates one to estimate price effects on participation and quantity
demanded separately and to execute separate subgroup analyses for men and women (Decker and
Schwartz, 2000). The overall cross price elasticity of alcohol consumption with respect to the price of
cigarettes found by the authors is 0.5, implying that alcohol and cigarettes are substitutes, since 0.5
constitutes a positive number. The main contributor to this positive cross price elasticity is the
change in participation in drinking rather than the change in consumption level amongst current
drinkers, since the separate cross price elasticities are 0.39 and 0.12 for the effect of cigarette price
changes on drinking participation and consumption of alcohol respectively. Moreover, it seems that
women’s drinking participation is significantly more price responsive than men’s, as the cross price
elasticity of participation is 0.52 for women, while it is 0.27 in case of men (Decker and Schwartz,
2000). Surprisingly, the cross price elasticity in the opposite direction, the effect of the price of beer
on cigarette consumption, is the figure -0.14, which is negative and therefore indicates a
complementary instead of a substitution relationship. Although the cross price elasticity of cigarette
consumption amongst current smokers has been estimated at 0.04, implying that an increase in the
price of beer results in an increase in the amount of cigarettes consumed, this positive relationship is
nonetheless reversed by the significantly more powerful and negative relationship between smoking
participation and beer prices. Besides, cigarette consumption amongst women has a greater price
responsiveness than consumption amongst men, which contradicts the results obtained by Decker
and Schwartz on own price elasticity of cigarette consumption.
17
Summarising, Decker and Schwartz have found asymmetric cross price elasticities of alcohol
and cigarette consumption: the relationship between the price of cigarettes and the demand for
alcoholic beverages is positive (substitutability), whereas the demand for cigarettes has a negative
cross price elasticity with respect to the price of beer (complementarity).
18
Behavioural economic evidence regarding complementarity and substitutability
Thus far evidence for the existence of either substitutability or complementarity between two
addictive commodities has been attained by examining actual, real life data. However, this procedure
potentially lacks reliability when the interrelatedness of several addictive substances is being
analysed. The main reason is the limited transparency and availability regarding the actual prices of
the various kinds of illicit drugs. It goes without saying that this is not a surprising fact, considering
that the sales of such drugs exclusively occur in the black market or underground economy. Another
drawback of statistical research in this area is the probable discrepancy between the total amount of
sales and actual consumption in a particular geographical location, which has been described
previously. In order to avoid these issues, some researchers have applied tools from behavioural
economics to the topic of addictive goods.
An example of such research is a study conducted by Sumnall et al. (2004), in which cross
price elasticities amongst alcohol, cocaine, ecstasy and amphetamine (more familiar by its informal
name ‘speed’) have been estimated. In the conducted experiment forty-three participants, all of
which were polysubstance users (using at least three different kinds of drugs) were allotted £40 and
a price list indicating the respective prices of the four types of drugs, which reflected the street prices
when the study was designed. In order to uncover the cross price elasticities, the price of one type of
drug was altered whereas the other kinds remained constant. By applying the same strategy to each
type of drug, the following results were obtained: alcohol was substituted for amphetamine as the
price of alcohol rose, cocaine was a complement drug with respect to alcohol while ecstasy use was
independent; when altering the price of amphetamine, alcohol was found to be a substitute while
the other forms of drugs were independent of the price of amphetamine; in case of a change in the
price of cocaine, the results showed that alcohol and ecstasy can be regarded as substitute drugs,
whilst the purchase of amphetamine was not affected by the price of cocaine; finally, only the
purchase of cocaine was influenced by a modification of the price of ecstasy, in such a manner that
the two drugs can be thought of as substitutes of one another.
19
Taking this study into account, one could argue that different relationships exist between alternative
kinds of drugs. However, due to the fact that this study is a laboratory simulation, the authors
recommend to interpret their findings with caution.
A similar kind of study is a behavioural economic analysis performed by Petry (2000), in
which fifty-three subjects participated. Only those having a history of alcohol abuse or dependence
and having used at least three other types of drugs were considered eligible for participation. As a
form of compensation for their efforts, all participants received $50 for participation. The types of
drugs used in this experiment were alcohol, cocaine, heroin, marijuana, nicotine and Valium (a form
of tranquilliser which is a licit prescription drug) and their respective prices were the actual street
prices for the amounts generally required for a successful ‘hit’. Three different experiments were
executed: one in which the price of alcohol varied whereas the other drug prices remained constant;
in the second experiment the price of cocaine fluctuated; in the final experiment Valium was
assigned several different prices while the other prices remained unchanged. In each experiment, the
subject was able to spend $35 of imitation money during each of the four different price scenarios
with respect to the price of alcohol, cocaine and Valium respectively. When the price of alcohol
increased, only the number of cocaine purchases plummeted significantly, whilst the purchased
quantities of the other drugs remained unaffected as the price of alcohol increased, indicating that
cocaine can be regarded as a complement to alcohol and that the demand for the other types of
drugs is independent of alcohol prices. Moreover, the price of cocaine was found to significantly
influence the demand for alcohol, since more alcohol was purchased when the price of cocaine was
relatively high, implying that alcohol was a substitute for cocaine amongst the participants of this
experimental study. Apart from alcohol, no other drug purchases were modified as a result of
changes in the price of cocaine, and thus these drug purchases are independent of cocaine price.
Finally, shifts in the price of Valium did not affect the quantities of drugs purchased besides the
quantity of Valium itself. Therefore, neither a complementary nor a substitute relationship seems to
exist between Valium and alternative kinds of drugs involved in the experiments.
20
The most interesting finding that this study offers is the fact that there is asymmetrical substitution
between alcohol and cocaine, since cocaine seems to be a complement to alcohol while on the other
hand alcohol seems to be a substitute for cocaine. In order to test the validity of the results obtained
from the simulation, the hypothetical drug purchases of individuals submitting urine samples which
were positive for the respective drugs were compared to those of subjects submitting urine samples
which were negative for the respective drugs. One may expect that participants who have recently
consumed a specific type of drug are quite likely to purchase an ostensibly greater amount of this
drug during the experiment. This difference in quantities purchased between subjects tested either
positive or negative was statistically significant regarding cocaine and heroin purchases, but
insignificant with respect to cannabis purchases. In addition, the hypothetical drug purchases of all
types of drugs were positively correlated with self-reported years of lifetime use. However, the
author stresses that the study must be interpreted cautiously. The foremost reason for this
recommendation of hers is the fact that the results of this research cannot be generalised to
everyone, considering that exclusively primary alcoholics with rather prolonged histories of polydrug
use were eligible for participation in the experiments.
Another, quite recent behavioural economic analysis concerning the interrelatedness of
various types of drugs is an Australian study conducted by Chalmers et al. which was published in
2010. The subjects consisted of one hundred and one individuals being at least 18 years of age who
stated that they were methamphetamine (a psychoactive drug known for its highly stimulant effects)
users. Besides, the subjects were predominantly male characterised by a relatively low socioeconomic status. The design of this study resembles that of the two behavioural studies discussed
previously. Each participant was assigned an amount of $200 of artificial money which could be spent
freely on several types of drugs (heroin, methamphetamine, cannabis, cocaine, non-prescription
benzodiazepines, alcohol and non-prescription pharmaceutical opioids), the baseline prices of which
were obtained from a 2008 survey.
21
A novelty of this research is the fact that the authors, amongst the subjects, distinguished those
dependent on neither drug, dependent on methamphetamine only, dependent on heroin only and
those dependent on both drugs. Regarding cross-price elasticity, a change in the price of
methamphetamine did not significantly induce a modification of the demand for other types of
drugs. Exceptions to this tendency were the fact that subjects not dependent on either drug decided
to consume a larger amount of pharmaceutical opioids as the price of methamphetamine increased,
whilst the participants dependent on both drugs simultaneously purchased more heroin and those
only dependent on heroin demanded more cocaine. A change in the price of heroin on the other
hand affected the purchases of other types of drugs more significantly. First, all participants,
regardless of the group to which they belonged, decided to buy more pharmaceutical opioids as the
price of heroin increased. The estimated cross price elasticity concerning these opioids was three to
four times larger for the non-dependent users compared to those for the other three groups.
Second, the subjects dependent on both drugs also substituted benzodiazepines (sleep-inducing
sedatives) for heroin. Conversely, those dependent on heroin purchased less cocaine and those only
dependent on heroin decided to consume a smaller amount of cannabis, both of which imply a
complementary relationship. Finally, the participants dependent on both drugs purchased more
methamphetamine as the price of heroin rose, indicating that the substitution between
methamphetamine and heroin was symmetric. (Chalmers et al. 2010).¹
¹ In the original paper, the authors stated that “those dependent on both drugs purchased more heroin” as the price of heroin
rose. Since this statement contradicts standard economic theory concerning economic substitutes, one may assume that the
authors actually meant that purchases of methamphetamine increased, but that they mistakenly substituted the word
“methamphetamine” for “heroin”.
22
The main policy implication stressed by the authors is the conclusion that although some evidence
for substitution into other drugs – as the price of either methamphetamine or heroin increased – has
been found, the decrease of either methamphetamine or heroin use resulting from respective price
increases evidently outweighs the rise in consumption of substitute substances. However, the
authors caution that their behavioural economic research is subject to limitations and that their
findings should therefore be interpreted carefully. The two foremost shortcomings of this study are
the fixed budget of $200 received by the subjects in each experiment, thereby restraining their
purchasing decisions unrealistically, and the lack of a truly representative sample of Australian
methamphetamine users, since snowball sampling (a sampling technique in which case current
subjects themselves recruit additional subjects amongst their own acquaintances) was used instead
of the more reliable technique of random sampling.
23
Reasons for complementarity amongst addictive substances
In the previous three chapters, the statistical and experimental evidence for the existence of
economic substitutes and complements regarding addictive commodities has been examined. It has
become evident that the relationships amongst such commodities are far from straightforward.
Some types of drugs appear to be complements to one another, whereas other types seem to serve
as economic substitutes for each other. Even more confusing is the fact that the findings of many
scientific studies devoted to this subject are contradictory. In an endeavour to create order from
chaos, this section will focus on the underlying potential explanations for complementarity amongst
addictive substances. Having a clearer insight with respect to the possible causes of either
complementarity or substitutability will be useful in determining which statistical and experimental
findings are likely to be correct and which are more dubious.
Despite some discrepancies, most studies confirm the existence of a complementary
relationship (although asymmetrical) between alcohol and cigarettes, in which case the use of
alcohol affects the consumption of cigarettes. This implies that an increase in the price of alcohol –
for example due to additional excise taxes – results not only in a decrease in alcohol consumption
itself, but also in the demand for cigarettes. What could be the reasons for this phenomenon? First,
alcohol is renowned for the fact that it tends to encourage more risky behaviours and actions by
users, since the ability to evaluate the consequences of their behaviours is impaired. Therefore, it is
quite probable that individuals who would abstain from smoking when in a sober state of mind are
more tempted to consume cigarettes after a few drinks, since the hazardous effects on health
induced by tobacco use are recognised to a lesser extent when under the influence of alcohol.
Another potential reason concerns the effects generated by the consumption of cigarettes. In case of
many complementary goods, the purchase of only one of the two goods is utterly useless unless its
complement is purchased as well.
24
For example, buying ink cartridges is utterly futile if one has not bought a printer first; procuring
DVDs does not make sense without owning a DVD player; buying antivirus software will not be
beneficial in any respect when you are not in the possession of a computer and so forth. In case of
cigarettes, a similar kind of reasoning may be applied. One could argue that the effects of smoking a
cigarette are more pleasurable after consuming alcohol. Under normal circumstances, the benefits of
smoking tobacco may not outweigh the costs (both monetary and non-pecuniary costs), while
consuming cigarettes when tipsy or drunk does induce a greater amount of pleasure of one kind or
another that exceeds the costs of smoking, which remain unchanged. Furthermore, the decision to
smoke might be influenced by situational factors that are in turn affected by the price of alcoholic
drinks (Decker and Schwartz, 2000). For instance, the price of alcohol is one of the determinants of
the willingness to go out tonight: if the price of alcohol is too excessive, going out may not be an
option anymore. If you do decide to go out, you are provided with a more suitable setting in which to
smoke. Thus, going out may result in smoking activities that would not have occurred in another
setting.
Among others, Pacula (1998a) has found a complementary relationship between alcohol and
cannabis. This relationship could be attributed to the so-called ‘gateway effect’, which implies that
using a relatively mild or easily available type of drugs (alcohol) results in an increased probability of
subsequently trying more hazardous or illicit kinds of drugs (cannabis is illicit in most countries).
However, this gateway effect is subject to several criticisms, the most important of which is the fact
that the positive correlation between alcohol and marijuana consumption may not occur as a result
of a gateway effect. Alternatively, the mere fact that licit drugs are available at an earlier age
compared to illicit drugs, could be the reason for the fact that experimenting teenagers and
adolescents start with the use of the former type of drugs, after which they are also eager to use the
latter kind of drugs as soon as this type becomes more easily available.
25
If the gateway theory does not hold for the relationship between alcohol and cannabis, then it goes
without saying that this theory will not suffice as a potential explanation for a complementary
relationship between alcohol and marijuana. According to Pacula, an increase in the taxes on beer
not only results in a reduced quantity of beer demanded, but also in a reduction of both the quantity
and probability of cannabis consumption. Similar reasons that applied to the complementary
relationship between alcoholic beverages and cigarettes might also apply to the positive relationship
between alcohol and marijuana consumption. Nevertheless, it has to be taken into account that this
relationship is contradicted by other studies providing evidence for economic substitutability
between the two substances.
Contrary to the asymmetric interrelatedness between alcohol and cigarette use, there is
evidence that a greater cannabis use results in higher quantities of alcohol consumption as well. For
example, purchases of alcoholic drinks seem to be more prevalent in states which have
decriminalised marijuana usage. If we assume that this is indeed the result of a complementary
relationship in this direction rather than the result of a spurious effect due to the existence of
confounding factors, such as unobserved characteristics regarding the states that have decided to
legitimate cannabis use, there must be an explanation for this relationship. One possible explanation
is the fact that consumers of marijuana have the tendency to strengthen or extend their pleasurable
experience by drinking alcohol simultaneously, in which case cannabis serves as their base drug. The
opposite is equally likely, in which case marijuana use supplements alcohol consumption in order to
enhance the feelings of relaxation. It should be noted that this form of reasoning is interchangeable
with the idea that smoking cigarettes is more palatable after the consumption of alcohol, as
mentioned earlier: namely, one could state that tobacco smoking while in an intoxicated state of
mind enhances the effects induced by alcohol, thereby making the overall experience temporarily
more agreeable.
Furthermore, several papers conclude that a complementary relationship exists between
marijuana and cigarettes.
26
For two main reasons, this connection between the two substances is modestly predictable. First, in
most countries, among which the US is the main exception, cannabis is blended with tobacco in order
to smoke and inhale the drug more conveniently. Therefore, the purchase of marijuana necessarily
requires the purchase of tobacco (cigarettes). This implies that the price of cannabis negatively
affects the amount of cigarettes purchased. Besides, evidence has also been found of cigarette prices
influencing marijuana consumption. One could argue that the consumption of cigarettes serves as an
ideal steppingstone for using cannabis, as consuming cigarettes familiarises the user with the
principles of smoking, which are also applied when consuming marijuana. On the other hand, it could
also be possible that a person who initiates smoking tobacco is doing so for the fact that, among
other reasons, he or she is more comfortable at inhaling smoke. This means that such an individual
has a higher probability of becoming a smoker, both of cigarettes and cannabis; the fact that
cigarette smoking itself causes the tendency to try marijuana as well may be a mere illusion as
cigarettes are simply more easily available at a younger age and thus consumed before cannabis.
The final combination of substances of which evidence of concurrent use has been found is
the joint consumption of alcohol and cocaine, in which case cocaine has a complementary role with
respect to the consumption of alcohol. However, this relationship appears to be an asymmetric one,
since evidence obtained from the same studies suggests that cocaine is substituted in exchange for
alcohol when the price of cocaine increases sufficiently. Since this chapter covers complementary
relationships only, for the time being only the former rather than the latter relationship between
alcohol and cocaine use will be clarified by potential explanations. Combined use of these two drugs
may result in an enhanced or extended high (McCance et al., 1993) and is therefore preferable over
the situation in which either drug is consumed separately. In addition, there is a possibility that the
two drugs are mutually consumed as a result of their opposing drug type characteristics, since
alcohol is regarded as a depressant (or downer) while cocaine is a stimulant (or upper). Hence, the
effects of these two drugs when consumed simultaneously balance each other out.
27
For example, being heavily intoxicated by alcohol and thus having diminished bodily functions such
as limitations of motion and reaction might evoke an individual’s desire to use cocaine in order to
remedy the adverse effects induced by alcohol consumption. Another reason for the apparently
concurrent consumption of alcohol and cocaine could be the attenuation of the negative effects of
cocaine such as nervousness and insomnia (Gawin and Kleber, 1986). Which of these possible
explanations for economic complementarity between alcohol and cocaine is prevailing in reality is a
question that requires additional research before it can be answered properly, which is beyond the
scope of this paper. In the subsequent section, potential explanations for substitutability amongst
several addictive commodities will be scrutinised.
28
Reasons for substitutability amongst addictive substances
In short, two goods are considered economic substitutes of one another when they fulfil
approximately the same need. This implies that a change in the price of a product affects not only its
own quantity demanded, but also that of its substitute(s). In real life, many varieties of substitute
goods exist, among which different brands of automobiles is just one example. In this case, the need
that is satisfied by all the various brands is transportation from one place to another. A characteristic
that all the different kinds of drugs have in common is the mind altering effect they have upon the
user. Therefore, rather broadly speaking, one could argue that drugs in general gratify the same
need, namely the desire to be in an altered state of consciousness. Solely based on this reasoning,
different types of drugs can be regarded as economic substitutes. However, the scientific evidence
on this subject that has been accumulated over the years does not corroborate this statement. As
discussed previously, some types of drugs appear to be economic complements instead of
substitutes. Thus, one might question whether it is actually true that various types of drugs basically
fulfil the same desire. One could just as easily argue that the effects resulting from the use of the
various types of drugs are so divergent that the same need is not satisfied by all kinds drugs at all.
Nonetheless, evidence of substitutability amongst drugs also exists and this section will therefore
attempt to examine possible explanations for such a relationship.
Albeit the preceding chapter focussed on potential causes of a complementary relationship
between alcohol and cannabis, scientific verification of a negative correlation between alcohol and
marijuana consumption exists as well. The most straightforward explanation has been discussed
before, namely the fact that consumers are to some extent indifferent regarding the preference for
alcohol and marijuana, since both substances more of less fulfil the same need for intoxication.
However, in case of narcotics there might also be additional reasons for economic substitution that
do not apply to normal substitute goods. One alternative reason why an increase in cannabis
consumption occurs at the expense of alcohol use could be the fact that certain combinations of
drugs have severely adverse and acute consequences.
29
This eliminates the possibility for simultaneous use of different kinds of drugs and hence the
consumer has to choose which drug to utilise. Therefore, an increase in the price of cocaine for
example will tempt some individuals to switch entirely to ecstasy pills, since partial substitution away
from cocaine to ecstasy consumption is not an option due to the disadvantageous effects of
combined use. Besides, combinations of certain types of drugs exist of which their respective effects
nullify each other, which renders their combined use utterly useless. Among others, an example of
such a combination is the concurrent use of different kinds of psychedelic drugs (e.g. psilocybin
mushrooms and LSD), which are known to be cross-tolerant to one another (Appel and Freedman,
1968). This also coerces an individual to choose which drug to take and hence these drugs can be
considered substitutes. Since the contemporaneous consumption of alcohol and cannabis has neither
dangerous adverse consequences nor effects of cross-tolerance, these two potential reasons for the
reluctance to combine two kinds of drugs are not applicable to marijuana and alcoholic drinks. The
fact that both drugs are depressants and hence fulfil approximately the same need, on the other
hand, could explain the evidence of substitutability between the two drugs.
Likewise, the apparent substitutability between cocaine and ecstasy, found by Sumnall et al.
(2004), may result from the fact that these two compounds have equivalent, stimulant effects.
Individuals having a desire for temporarily enhanced mental and physical functions are possibly to a
large extent indifferent regarding which stimulant drug to consume (Boys et al.). Therefore, the
respective market prices of such drugs play quite a prominent role in determining the drug of choice.
Naturally, this implies that a price increase of a stimulant drug, e.g. cocaine, affects the demand for
other ‘uppers’ such as ecstasy in a positive manner. By the same token, it is quite possible that the
apparent substitute relationship between heroin and pharmaceutical opioids is caused by the
similarity of their effects (Chalmers et al.). However, the evidence only supports the notion of
asymmetric substitutability, in the sense that an increase in the price of heroin positively affects the
quantity of pharmaceutical opioids demanded (but not vice-versa).
30
A rather intriguing finding is the fact that, although cocaine seems to be a complement to
alcohol, cocaine is substituted for alcohol when the price of cocaine increases. One explanation could
be that an increase in the price of cocaine, which is already one of the most expensive types of drugs
considering the short duration of the ‘high’, makes the drug unaffordable, thereby forcing consumers
to abandon cocaine use and instead resort to alcohol as a substitute drug.
Finally, the observed economic substitutability amongst a range of different kinds of drugs
could be elucidated by the propensity of individuals to restrain their unhealthy behaviours in order to
preserve an adequate level of health. This idea implies that individuals will limit their drug use to a
certain extent and will thus have to decide which is their drug of choice. When determining which
drug to consume, prices play a considerable role. An increase in price of a certain kind of drug may
induce consumers to substitute away from that drug into other kinds. The concept of ‘an adequate
level of health’ is demonstrated by graph depicted below.
Happiness/Utility
Level of Health
Graph 2: Relationship between individual health and utility.
31
The graph illustrates that although an increase in health enhances one’s utility, it does so at a
decreasing rate. Stated differently, the marginal utility of health is positive though decreasing as an
individual’s level of health improves, until it eventually reaches the number zero. When an individual
has attained the level of health beyond which additional improvements in health no longer yield an
amelioration in utility, further enhancements in health are rendered fruitless. This means that an
individual who occasionally consumes unhealthy commodities such as drugs and thereby reduces his
or her level of health does not necessarily deteriorate his or her well-being, as long as he or she
remains on that part of the graph where the slope is equal to zero. Technically speaking, a person
maximises his or her well-being by consuming a specific amount of drugs in which case his or her
level of health is the lowest one possible whilst still having a marginal utility of zero². This level is the
represented in the graph by the intersection between the vertical red line and the horizontal axis.
Since the amount of drugs an individual can afford to consume without diminishing his or her level of
health below the threshold is (strictly) limited, economic substitution amongst different kinds of
drugs will inevitably occur.
Unfortunately, there is no universal explanation for the seeming substitutability among the
various addictive commodities. Which of the possible explanations discussed above prevail(s) in
reality, whether or not in combination with each other, remains tentative and therefore requires
further examination.
² This reasoning only holds under the assumption that this person derives pleasure from the consumption of drugs that exceeds the
monetary costs associated with purchasing drugs.
32
Conclusion
This paper endeavoured to shed more light on the issue of economic complementarity and
substitutability amongst the class of commodities that could be named ‘addictive substances’.
Despite the fact that most economists have a some kind of fetish for straightforward – and thus
potentially overconfident – answers to economic problems, this paper has done its utmost to
prevent being tempted by the appeal of aligning its conclusions to its preconceptions. Hence, this
paper does not provide a definite answer to the question it has addressed, which would thus
undoubtedly be most disturbing to policy makers, who always crave clear-cut information on which
to base their decisions. However, it has become evident that addictive substances cannot simply be
placed in one category; instead, some of them could be considered economic complements of each
other, whereas others economic substitutes. This means that policy makers should be very cautious
when implementing policies aimed at reducing drug abuse. For example, if the government of a
particular country decides to increase the excise taxes on alcoholic beverages, the result may not just
be an expected decline in alcohol abuse, but also an unexpected rise in the use of alternative kinds of
drugs that are substituted for alcohol. On the other hand, if only complementary drugs with respect
to alcohol exist, then the government is able to kill two birds with one stone: the reduction in alcohol
consumption leads to a simultaneous decline in the use of the complementary drugs. Thus, policy
makers are recommended to obtain relevant information about the specific drug towards which
policy implementations are directed.
In short, based on the evidence, we can assume that cigarettes are a complement to alcohol,
whereas this does not hold vice-versa; no general consensus has been achieved regarding the
relationship between alcohol and cannabis; while cocaine appears to be a complement to alcohol,
alcohol seems to be a substitute with respect to cocaine; ecstasy and cocaine are likely to be
economic substitutes and finally, pharmaceutical opioids seem to serve as substitutes with respect to
heroin.
33
The classification of the different types of drugs based on their respective substitutability or
complementarity with alternative kinds of addictive commodities is recapitulated in the table below.
Results obtained from less reliable studies have been omitted from the table. The names of the drugs
expressed in bold letters can be considered as the ‘reference’ drug (the drug of which the price is
altered). For example, one can observe that cigarettes, cannabis and cocaine are considered
complements with respect to alcohol (written in bold characters).
Types of drugs
Alc.
Tob.
Can.
Coke
XTC
Her.
Amph.
Meth.
Pharmaceutical
opioids
Alcohol
C
Tobacco
C/S
C
S
C
Cannabis
C/S
Cocaine
S
Ecstasy
S
S
Heroin
S
Amphetamine
S
S
Methamphetamine
S
S
Table 1: The abbreviations ‘S’ and ‘C’ utilised in the table denote ‘substitute
relationship’ and ‘complementary relationship’ respectively.
Furthermore, is has become obvious that there are several potential explanations for both
economic complementarity and substitution amongst the various types of addictive goods.
Therefore, it is not unreasonable to assume that a certain combination of the aforementioned
reasons for the existence economic substitutes and complements among addictive products is in
effect in real life.
34
The most important potential reason for complementarity is the increased pleasure derived from
combined drug usage; the most probable explanations for substitutability are the fact that all drugs
more or less fulfil the same desire for an altered state of mind and that most individuals tend to
refrain themselves from excessive drug use, thus opting for their drug of choice.
It is important to note that the possibility exists that a certain relationship between two
types of drugs differs among individuals: cannabis might be a substitute for alcohol for one person
but simultaneously a complement to alcohol for another individual. In addition, even the same
individual might regard alcohol a substitute for marijuana at a specific moment in time while a
complement to cannabis at a different moment. An individual’s mood or the setting in which he
finds himself could influence such a tendency.
Nevertheless, this issue still requires additional study in order to uncover which precise
combination of factors is responsible for either a positive or negative relationship between
whichever two addictive commodities.
35
Discussion
Currently the Dutch demissionary cabinet wishes to change its policies regarding cannabis
consumption. In order to reduce the negative externalities associated with drug tourists from
neighbouring countries – such as the disturbance caused by these tourists in the vicinity of coffee
shops or damage caused by these tourists while driving under the influence of cannabis – the
government has decided to implement a law which coerces owners of coffee shops to register their
customers by distributing a limited number of so-called ‘weed card’ per shop, in which case only
Dutch citizens are eligible for receiving such a card. This means that entry in a coffee shop is only
permitted after identifying oneself with the appropriate ‘weed card’, thereby fending off non-Dutch
drug tourists. If everything continues as planned, the law will be implemented on 1 January 2013 in
all Dutch provinces. Several criticisms towards this new policy have emerged from different corners
of Dutch society, the most notable of which is the expected surge in black market activities
concerning marijuana purchases by foreigners and citizens alike. This research might shed additional
light on the consequences of the implementation of the ‘weed card’ regarding possible changes in
drug use.
Focusing on Dutch civilians only, different scenarios could occur. If we assume that being in
the possession of a ‘weed card’ does not coincide with additional ‘costs’ to the customer of a certain
coffee shop, then we should not expect a shift in drug consumption. However, it is not unreasonable
to assume that there are also individuals who are quite reluctant to hold a ‘weed card’. Particularly
youths would consider the possession of such a card risky as their parents might more easily discover
their drug use. Moreover, since the ‘weed card’ will be linked to the holder’s social security number,
sensitive information might fall into the wrong hands. The customs at the airport for example have
the ability to check whether you are a card holder or not and could accordingly deny you access.
Therefore, a cannabis user will have an incentive to either purchase their marijuana from illegal
street dealers or give up using cannabis in exchange for a substitute drug. According to the studies
analysed in this paper, two alternative consequences may occur.
36
If alcohol is considered a complement to cannabis, then a decline in marijuana use as result
of the implementation of the ‘weed card’ (without taking partial substitution to illegally purchased
cannabis into account) will coincide with a decrease in alcohol consumption. If, on the other hand,
alcohol is regarded as a substitute for cannabis, marijuana users will be encouraged to shift their
consumption away from cannabis towards alcohol; hence, alcohol consumption will increase. Since
the introduction of the card will oblige an adequate amount of individuals to relinquish cannabis use
altogether, it would not be surprising that they will fill the ‘pleasure vacuum’ with the consumption
of alcohol instead. Thus, the effect of substitutability will clearly outweigh the effect of
complementarity. One could expect that an insignificant drop in marijuana consumption by a certain
individual will result in a decrease of alcohol consumption as well, which would indicate a
complementary relationship. A substantial decline in cannabis use by someone resulting from
external factors, however, will deprive this specific individual from his or her base drug and hence
stimulate to find an alternative base drug (alcohol).
In conclusion, it can be said that the Dutch government should also consider the potential
shift in drug use that will result from the introduction of the mandatory possession of a ‘weed card’,
apart from the other disadvantages of such a policy which have already been expressed by critics
from a wide array of backgrounds.
37
References
Appel and Freedman (1968) “Tolerance and Cross-tolerance among psychotomimetic drugs”
Psychopharmacology ,Vol. 13, No. 3
Bask and Melkersson (2001) “Rationally addicted to drinking and smoking?” Applied Economics, Vol.
36, Issue 4.
Becker, Grossman and Murphy (1991) “Rational addiction and the effect of price on consumption”
The American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 2
Cameron and Williams (2001) “Cannabis, Alcohol and Cigarettes: substitutes or complements?”
Economic Record, Vol. 77, Issue 236, pp. 19 – 34
Cawley and Ruhm (2011)”The Economics of Risky Heath Behaviors” Handbook of Health Economics,
Vol. 2, pp. 95-199
Chalmers, Bradford and Jones (2010)” The effect of methamphetamine and heroin price on polydrug
use: A behavioural economics analysis in Sydney, Australia” International Journal of Drug Policy,
Vol. 21, Issue 5, pp. 381 – 389
Chaloupka and Laixuthai (1997) ”Do Youths Substitute Alcohol for Marijuana?” Eastern Economic
Journal, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp. 253 – 276
Chaloupka, Pacula, Farrelly, Johnston and O’Malley (1999) “Do higher cigarette prices encourage
youth to use marijuana?” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 6939
Chaloupka, Grossman and Tauras (1999) “ The demand for cocaine and marijuana by youth”
National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 133 – 156
Cole, Goudie, Field, Loverseed, Charlton and Sumnall (2007) “The effects of perceived quality on the
behavioural economics of alcohol, amphetamine, cannabis, cocaine, and ecstasy purchases” Drug
and Alcohol Dependence, Vol. 94, Issues 1 – 3, pp. 183 – 190
Cutler and Lleras-Muney (2010) “Understanding differences in health behaviors by education”
Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 29, Issue 1, pp. 1 – 28
Cutler and Glaeser (2005) ”What Explains Differences in Smoking, Drinking, and Other Health
Related Behaviors” American Economic Review, Vol. 95, pp. 238 – 242
Decker and Schwartz (2000) “Cigarettes and Alcohol: Substitutes or Complements?” National Bureau
of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 7535
DiNardo and Limieux (2001) “Alcohol, Marijuana and the American Youth: the unintended
consequences of government regulation” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 20, Issue 6, pp. 991 –
1010
Farrelly, Bray, Zarkin and Wendling (2000) “The joint demand for cigarettes and marijuana:
evidence from the National Household Surveys on Drug Abuse” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 20,
Issue 1, pp. 51 – 68
38
Gala ma and van Kippersluis (2010) “The Theory of Socioeconomic Disparities in Health over the Life
Cycle” Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 2010-079/3
Galama, Pacula, van Kippersluis, Buchinsky, van Ours, Angrisani, Avendano and van Ourti “Explicit
modeling of the trade-off between addiction and health, longevity”
Goel and Morey (1995) “The Interdependence of Cigarette and Liquor Demand” Southern Economic
Journal, Vol. 62, No. 2, pp. 451 – 459
Grossman, Chaloupka and Brown (1999) “The demand for cocaine by young adults: a rational
addiction approach” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 17, No 4, pp. 427 – 474
Gruber (2000) “Risky behaviour among Youths: An Economic Analysis” National Bureau of Economic
Research, Working Paper No. 7781
Loewenstein, Brennan and Volpp (2010) “Asymmetric Paternalism to improve health behaviours”
Journal of the American Medical Association, Vol. 298, No. 20
McCance-Katz, Price, McDougle, Kosten, Black, Jatlow (1993) “Concurrent cocaine-ethanol ingestion
in humans: pharmacology, physiology, behavior and the role cocaethylene” Psychopharmacology,
Vol. 111, No. 1
Measham (2004) “The decline of ecstasy, the rise of ‘binge’ drinking and the persistence of
pleasure” Probation Journal, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp. 309 – 326
Model (1993) “The Effect of Marijuana Decriminalisation on Hospital Emergency Room Drug
Episodes: 1975 – 1978” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 88, No. 423, pp. 737 –
747
O’Donoghue and Rabin (2001) “Risky Behavior among Youths: Some Issues from Behavioral
Economics” National Bureau of Economic Research, Vol. ISBN: 0-226-31013-2
Pacula (1998a) “Does increasing the beer tax reduce marijuana consumption?” Journal of Health
Economics, Vol. 17, Issue 5, pp. 557 – 585
Pacula (1998b) “Adolescent alcohol and marijuana consumption: is there really a gateway effect?”
National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 6348
Pacula, Chirqui and King (2003) “Marijuana Decriminalization: What does it mean in the United
States?” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 9690
Petry and Bickel (1998) “Polydrug abuse in heroin addicts: a behavioral economic analysis”
Addiction, Vol. 93, No. 3, pp. 321 – 335
Petry (2000) “A behavioral economic analysis of polydrug abuse in alcoholics asymmetrical
substitution of alcohol and cocaine” Drug and Alcohol Dependence, Vol. 62, Issue 1, pp. 31 – 39
Reiman (2009) “Cannabis as a substitute for alcohol and other drugs” Harm Reduction Journal, 6:35
39
Rogeberg (2003 ) ”Taking absurd theories seriously: Economics and the case of rational addiction
theories” Philosophy of Science, Vol. 71, No. 3
Sumnall, Tyler, Graham, Wagstaff, Cole (2004) ”A behavioural economic analysis of alcohol.
amphetamine, cocaine and ecstasy purchases by polysubstance misusers” Drug and Alcohol
Dependence, Vol. 76, Issue 1, pp. 93 – 99
Thaler and Shefrin (1981) “An Economic Theory of Self-Control” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89,
No. 2, pp. 392 – 406
Van Ours (2003) “A pint a day raises a man’s pay; but smoking blows that gain away” Journal of
Health Economics, Vol. 23, Issue 5, pp. 863 – 886
Viscusi (1992a) “The value of Risk to Life and Health” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 31, No. 4,
pp. 1912 – 1946
Williams, Pacula, Chaloupka and Wechsler (2001) “Alcohol and Marijuana Use Among College
Students: Economic Complements or Substitutes?” National Bureau of Economic Research, Health
Economics, Vol. 13, No. 9, pp. 825 – 843
40
41
Download