Clark, Henry C., Commerce, Culture & Liberty: Readings on Capitalism Before Adam Smith (2003), 680p. This is an edited scholarly anthology of important writings on the development of capitalist ideas and culture in Europe during the 17th and 18th centuries published before Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations (1776). The latter is generally considered to be the foundation of the modern discipline of economics and a key statement on the moral value of capitalism. This nicely produced and inexpensive book was produced by the Liberty Fund Foundation in Indianapolis, which states that its purpose is “to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals.” As the editor points out in his Foreword, during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, students of economics “combined their analyses with moral and cultural considerations more often than is usually the case in today’s more specialized intellectual environment.” One could go further and say that almost all economic writing before economics became a professional discipline in the second half of the nineteenth century was quite explicit about its moral, cultural, political and ideological purpose and perspective. Among the topics discussed in these selected and edited writings are: the nature of exchange relations and their effects on a traditional and hierarchical social order, the role of commerce in fostering civility and sociability, the effects of commerce on the fabric of community life, the dangers to moral virtue posed by increasing prosperity, the impact of commerce on sex roles and the condition of women, and the complex interplay between commerce and civil or political liberty” (p. ix). This is a substantial volume that includes thirty-seven selections, ranging from about ten to thirty pages, with good brief introductions and scholarly references. The book also includes a useful glossary and index. The selections consist of mostly well known but also some interesting less-known authors. Some of the better-known authors include, Pieter de la Court, Josiah Child, Dudley North, John Law, Bernard Mandeville, Daniel Defoe, Voltaire, Montesquieu, Henry Fielding, Jean Jacques Rousseau, David Hume, and John Millar. Reading the selections chronologically one learns that the meaning of the word ‘commerce’ was quite different in the early modern period than in today’s common usage. Daring the early modern period, and especially in the seventeenth century, ‘commerce’ was still often used to describe social relationships rather than just business transactions, although by the late eighteenth century its modern usage had become much more common. The editor’s use of ‘culture’ in the title does not refer to the formal works of art of the period but to the modern anthropological use of the term as social relations. One of the fundamental themes in these edited primary sources is the debate about the creation of a commercial society during the period that challenged more traditional social and cultural values, customs and mores. The debate about the social utility of luxury in the eighteenth century was an especially important indicator of the rise of individual acquisitiveness as a social value and relationship. The period also saw a fundamental discussion of the morality and utility of individual freedom. This volume is a good introduction to the larger question of whether individual freedom, or liberty, which in Western society became increasingly viewed as central to economic growth and the triumph of capitalism during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries and, despite powerful socialist critiques, should remain fundamental to our understanding of the history of capitalism, in light of the economic success of Asia in recent times, which appears to have been forged with less regard to what we in the West would call individual liberty.