The Economics of Monopoly Power The US justice department filed antitrust charges against Microsoft. In 2000 the court declared that Microsoft was a monopoly. In 2008, the European Commission sent Intel Corp. a new set of antitrust charges for abuse of dominant position with the goal of excluding its main rival from the x86 central processing units market Antitrust charges against Starbucks for lease agreement that excludes competitors from occupying the same building Antitrust charges have been filed against big corporations like Wal-Mart, Toys R Us, Apple and AT&T A significant percentage of innovations produced by firms with monopoly power. Regulation of big firms imposes costs on society Diminished incentives to innovate Big governments Objective Develop an economic basis for analyzing O The economic performance of businesses with monopoly power O Prices in monopoly markets vs. perfect competitive markets O Welfare implications of monopoly behavior Economics of Monopoly Power Monopoly market: is a market where there is a single seller of a good or a service that has no close substitute Monopoly power of a firm refers to the extent of its control over the supply of the product produced by the industry The larger the output of the firm relative to the industry’s, the greater its monopoly power Relative not absolute size Monopoly Power Price • Assume 4 firms • If one firm reduces its output, it can raise the market price • Max price P3 • Only if own output is zero • If 100 firms instead, the power to raise price would be much less P3 P4 Demand 0 Q3 Q4 Quantity Market Concentration Economists use concentration ratios to measure the degree of monopoly power in imperfect competitive markets. Four-firm concentration ratio measures the percentage of total output produced by the largest four firms. Quantifying Market Power Industry Concentration Ratio Cigarettes 97.8 Breweries 89.5 Primary Aluminum 85.3 Cereal Breakfast Food 80.4 Aircraft 74.3 Automobile 67.6 Soap and Other Detergent 67.1 Snack Foods 53.2 Cement 40.8 Output and Prices: PC markets A Competitive Firm Is one of many producers Faces a horizontal demand curve Is a price taker Sells as much or as little at same price The firm has no control over the market price Output and Prices: PC markets (a) An individual Firm (b) Market Supply Price Price S MC ATC P* D 0 q Quantity (firm) 0 Quantity (market) Q* (=n x q) Welfare Implications: Allocative Efficiency Is Q* Efficient? (b) Market Supply Price The PC market produces a quantity where MSB equals MSC. The PC market achieves allocative Efficiency. S MSC D MSB 0 Quantity (market) Q* (=n x q) Welfare Implications: Production Efficiency Is Q* Efficient? (a) An individual Firm Firms are making zero economic profit. Price MC Firms produce at the lowest possible unit cost, i.e. firms are operating at their efficient scale. ATC P* 0 PC market achieves production efficiency q Quantity (firm) Output and Prices: Monopoly markets A Monopoly Firm Is a single seller in the market Has no close substitute to its product Faces a downward sloping demand curve Is a price maker Can lower or raise price by changing the amount it sells Monopoly: Output and Price Price MC Monopoly price Marginal Revenue (MPB) 0 Monopoly quantity Demand (MSB) Quantity ThePriceInefficiency of Monopoly Deadweight loss MSC Monopoly price Allocative Efficiency Marginal Revenue (MPB) 0 Monopoly Efficient quantity quantity Demand MSB Quantity PRICE DISCRIMINATION Price discrimination is the practice of charging different prices to different customers for essentially the same good or service In order to price discriminate, the firm must have some market power. The Analytics of Price Discrimination Two important effects of price discrimination: It can increase the monopolist’s profits. It can reduce deadweight loss. Perfect Price Discrimination Perfect (first degree) Price Discrimination The monopolist knows the willingness to pay of each buyer identical goods are sold at different prices to each buyer based on his willingness to pay. Welfare with and without Price Discrimination (a) Monopolist with Single Price Price Consumer surplus Deadweight loss Monopoly price Profit Marginal cost Marginal revenue 0 Quantity sold Demand Quantity Welfare with and without Price Discrimination (b) Monopolist with Perfect Price Discrimination Price Every consumer gets charged a different price -- the highest price they are willing to pay -- so in this special case, the demand curve is also MR! Consumer surplus and deadweight loss have both been converted into profit. Profit Marginal cost Demand Marginal revenue 0 Quantity sold Quantity Examples of Perfect Price Discrimination You can see this type of price discrimination in the sale of both new and used cars. People will pay different prices for cars with identical features, and the salesperson must attempt to gauge the maximum price at which the car can be sold. This type of price discrimination often includes a bargaining aspect, where the consumer attempts to negotiate the price. Second-degree price discrimination In many situations the firm does not know the willingness to pay of each buyer, and cannot sell identical units of the good at different prices Second-degree price discrimination Hurdle Pricing: Firm puts a “hurdle” to sort the different types of consumers Self selection: a certain type of consumers will go through the hurdle. Ideally that is the low willingness to pay type. Those who go through the hurdle get the lowest price Examples of Second-Degree Price Discrimination Bulk discounts: a reduced price may be offered if you buy two t-shirts instead of just one. (e.g., 1/$6.99 or 2/$10) Small vs. Large cup of coffee Airline Tickets Discount coupons 8 oz $1.5 16 oz $1.79 Are profits higher with price discrimination? A bookseller knows that there are two groups of people willing to buy a given book. high demand group is willing to pay $50, low demand group is willing to pay $20 There are 100 people in each group The cost of each book is zero (for simplicity) What pricing strategy (single pricing vs. price discriminations)? What hurdle? Higher Profits? Efficiency? Third Degree Price Discrimination Different groups of consumers that are easily identifiable Seller can identify which group the consumer belongs to The seller knows the demand of each group but not the WTP of each individual Third Degree Price Discrimination in the Market for Movie Tickets (b) Demand by people below age 60 (b) Senior citizen demand Pric e P1 The relative prices charged will depend on the price elasticity of demand in each market: P 1 1 1 P2 2 1 1 1 P2 Marginal cost Demand Demand M R MR Q1 Q2 Entry Barriers As an industry realizes economic profit, new firms enter the market hoping to realize the above average rate of return. Entry helps to allocate resources among industries Attempts to deter entry or exit in an industry would create a misallocation of resources. Entry Barriers Sometimes the process of entry is impeded resulting in imperfect competitive market structures The impediments may be raised by firms already in the market who have an interest in keeping prices high Private Barriers Arise from the nature of the market or the actions of participant: Ownership of a key resource The threat to fight new entrants by lowering prices Private Barriers Arise from the nature of the market or the actions of participant: Product differentiation and offering a large variety Network economies: value of the product is enhanced by increased adoption Economies of scale: average cost decline with production. A single producer is more efficient than a large number of producers. Government-Created Monopolies Governments may restrict entry by giving a single firm the exclusive right to sell a particular good in certain markets. Patent and copyright laws are two important examples of how government creates a monopoly to serve the public interest. Natural Monopolies An industry is a natural monopoly when a single firm can supply a good or service to an entire market at a smaller cost than could two or more firms. A natural monopoly arises when there are economies of scale over the relevant range of output. Examples: water services and electricity. It is very expensive to build transmission networks (water/gas pipelines, electricity and telephone lines), therefore it is unlikely that a potential competitor would be willing to make the capital investment needed to even enter the monopolists market Natural Monopoly: One is Better than Two! Cost With two firms, each produces 20 units and average cost rises to $7/unit Suppose 40 units can be sold. A monopoly firm produces 40 units at a cost of $5/unit 7 5 Average total cost 0 20 40 Quantity of Output Natural Monopoly:…But One is A Monopoly! Cost While it is desirable to have a single firm, the monopolist does not produce the socially optimum output level since P>MR=MC ATC MR 0 Q monopoly P Q optimum MC Quantity Natural Monopoly Cost Regulation: Requiring the firm to produce the optimum output level results in losses since ATC>MC=P ATC P 0 20 Q optimum MC Quantity The Exception: Natural Monopoly Since economies of scale exist, it is not socially desirable to promote competition Requiring a firm to produce the socially optimal amount results in economic losses However, the free operation of the market with a monopoly firm does not result in the socially optimal level of output How can the government regulate this market?