Addendum to Business Case for the Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP) Following submission of the Business Case for GAFSP to the Secretary of State and his approval, he concluded that our contribution to GAFSP should be $20m (year 1), $60m (year 2 -in 2 tranches of 30); and $40m (year 3). This has been communicated to the trustees of the multi-donor trust fund (the World Bank) and to the Chair of the GAFSP Steering Committee. The costs and profiling set out in the Financial Case section of the Business Case should therefore be updated as follows: DFID will provide £76,000,000 funding to GAFSP over three financial years from October 2012 to 31 December 2014. The spending will be profiled as follows: (i) £12,500,000 to the Public Sector Window in October 2012 (ii) £37,500,000 to the Private Sector Window in two equal tranches of £18,750,000 paid between 1 April 2013 and 31st March 2014 (iii) £26,000,000 to the Private Sector Window between 1 st April 2014 and 31st December 2014, subject to satisfactory progress with operational reforms and results. Business Case and Intervention Summary Title: Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme What support will the UK provide? DFID will provide up to £50mn (~US $80mn) to the Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP). The contribution will be split into two parts; £13mn (~US $20mn), to be released in 2012/13 to fund public sector-led work on improving agriculture and food security. In 2013/14, contingent on progress with proposed reforms and planned contributions from other donors, £37mn (~US $60mn) will be invested through the private sector window to boost agricultural production, help farmers deal with risks and encourage more commercial investment in agriculture. DFID’s contribution to the Public Sector Window will provide sufficient funding to support implementation of one country investment plan drawn from the countries which have submitted requests to the GAFSP Steering Committee but have yet to have their plans approved. Together our £50mn will provide additional funding for public and private investment in agriculture and food security in at least 2-3 countries. Our burden share of total GAFSP funding will not exceed 10%, in line with our share of other multi-donor initiatives. DFID will also provide sufficient staff time, including through active membership of the Steering Committee, to influence and aspects of programme governance and crucially, to ensure operational reforms are carried through successfully, including strengthening the Private Sector Window. Why is UK support required? To achieve the Millennium Development Goal of halving the number of people who do not have enough to eat, FAO estimates that the number of undernourished people must fall by 73 million a year. Better nourishment, especially for children, is an urgent development priority. Without enough to eat in the first two years of life, a child’s development is permanently impaired. Climate change is predicted to cut production of food. In some of the most food insecure areas of the world, yield losses could reach 20% by 2030. Less food means higher prices. It is estimated that the food price rises of 2007/8 pushed an extra 100 million people into poverty. Prices of many food commodities have returned recently to their 2008 levels. After years of declining direct investment, the importance of improving agriculture productivity in developing countries sustainably, has again been recognised. Some estimates put the level of under-investment in agriculture in SSA as US$ 15 bn per year. Most African countries have now pledged to invest 10% of their budgets in agriculture, but many poor countries struggle to afford the levels of investment in infrastructure and public goods and services required to boost agricultural productivity and economic growth in the sector. DFID’s funding will help to support the implementation of country-led investment plans and to leverage additional funding from others, including from the private sector. GAFSP is a multi-donor trust fund set up in 2010 by signatories of the L’Aquila Food Security Initiative (AFSI) to provide an effective means of supporting countryled and strategic agriculture investment plans in low income countries. Seven donors have pledged funds (US, Australia, Canada, the Gates Foundation, Ireland, Korea and Spain) totalling US$ 972mn, of which US$ 581mn has already been transferred to the Fund Trustees and US$ 481 m allocated to 12 country proposals (out of the 60 countries which are eligible to apply). A UK contribution to GAFSP now will help: Provide a critical mass of available funds to support both public and private sector investment plans with which to help meet the widely anticipated demand when the Coordinating Unit next calls for proposals. Demonstrate UK commitment to the use of effective instruments for delivery of development assistance (GAFSP procedures are designed to comply with the key tenants of the Aid Effectiveness agenda). Trigger other AFSI signatories to agree to channel funds through GAFSP (a combination of their greater confidence in the mechanism and greater pressure to match fellow donors). Over US$ 100mn has already been mobilised in additional funding in three countries whose GAFSP investment proposals were approved in 2010. It is probable that other GAFSP investments will leverage further funds in other countries as programme implementation begins on the ground. What are the expected results? Developing countries submit proposals to the Public Sector Window of GAFSP that are in line with their overall plans for growth and for development of their food and agriculture sector. Money for the private sector window goes directly to support agribusiness. Supervising organisations provide managerial and technical support. Each country investment plan must have specific targets and a results framework in order to receive support from GAFSP. The GAFSP Coordinating Unit have calculated that the 12 country investment plans which have received Public Sector Window finance to date, at a cost of $481mn, will reach 1.5mn rural households (or roughly 7.5mn people) when fully implemented. This will raise total incomes of beneficiaries by an estimated US $ 100mn per year (see methodology at Annex 3). It is reasonable to assume that the next 12 country investment plans which receive funding will deliver broadly similar results. If a DFID contribution of £50mn (US$ 80mn) was applied to these expected results of the GAFSP Public Window, it would help raise the income of roughly 7.5mn people by US $16.6mn. Using the existing 12 funded plans as a benchmark, the GAFSP Coordination Unit has estimated aggregate figures for four key indicators, covering three outputs that would be produced if 12 of the country investment plans which have now been submitted but not yet funded, were funded in full, at cost of US$ 487mn. If a DFID contribution of £50mn (US$ 80mn) was applied to these results of the GAFSP Public Window it would, at a minimum, buy the following outputs: Smallholders supported in use of higher yielding technologies and management practices e.g. over 80,000 smallholder farmers with access to agricultural advisory services Infrastructure in place to support agriculture e.g. rehabilitation of over 4,000 hectares of irrigation and upgrading of over 750 kilometers of road People better protected against risk and less vulnerable to shocks affecting the agriculture sector e.g. over 110,000 people living in rural areas receiving direct (conditional) cash transfers. Funds provided through the Public Sector Window will also help to build capacity in important public sector institutions responsible for creating key aspects of the enabling environment for increased investment in agriculture. If the bulk of DFID’s £50m is applied to the Private Sector Window, there is not yet a succinct results offer to which it can be easily applied. However, IFC estimates that every US$ 1mn of concessional funding provided by the PSW will mobilise US$ 67mn of commercial funding. This would produce £300-350mn of added value for a £50mn contribution. IFC also intends to contribute its own resources and blend these with GAFSP funding for each project to increase the leverage potential. An early $15mm PSW project in Bangladesh gives some indication of possible future results: 1,200 jobs created Improve the availability of food Increase the competitive pricing for food products The latter two results could benefit thousands of food consumers in impoverished communities. DFID’s participation in GAFSP will secure key reforms to the current operation of GAFSP so that it is more strongly supportive of UK objectives of: ensuring a strong results focus of work on food security, particularly on gender; improved cost effectiveness of interventions; greater attention to resilience to climate change and to improvement of nutritional status in the appraisal of investment plans; and a strengthened private sector ‘window’ to complement the operation of the current public sector window. Our approach to securing reforms and for monitoring and evaluation of our contribution to GAFSP is summarised in the Strategic Case (p. 19, paras. 64-65), where the more detailed treatment of these issues in the Appraisal and Management Cases is also sign-posted. Acronyms Used in Business Case AfDB African Development Bank AFSI L'Aquila Food Security Initiative AsDB Asian Development Bank AU African Union BMGF Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation CAADP Comprehensive Africa Agriculture Development Programme CGIAR Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research CSOs Civil Society Organisations CU Coordination Unit DAC Development Assistance Committee DIME Development Impact Evaluation Initiative DOTS Development Outcome Tracking System ECOWAS Economic Community of West African States FAO Food & Agriculture Organisation FNST Food & Nutrition Security Team FTI Fast Track Initiative GAFSP Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme GDP Gross Domestic Product GFATM Global Fund to Fight Aids, TB & Malaria GHG Green House Gases GPE Global Partnerships for Education GRD Growth & Resilience Department HMT Her Majesty's Treasury IBRD International Bank for Reconstruction and Development IDA International Development Association IDB International Development Banks IE Impact Evaluation IEG Investment Evaluation Group IFAD International Fund for Agricultural Development IFC International Finance Corporation IFI International Financial Institutions IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute MAR Multilateral Aid Review MDBs Multilateral Development Banks MDG Millennium Development Goal NEPAD New Partnership for Africa's Development NPK Nitrogen, Phosphorous and Potassium ODI Overseas Development Institute OECD Organisation for Economic Cooperation & Development PIC Project Investment Committee PIDG Private Infrastructure Development Group PSW Private Sector Window RMs Results Management Systems SAFANSI South Asia Food & Nutrition Security Initiative SBS Sector Budget Support SE Supervising Entity SMEs Small & Medium Enterprises SSA Sub Saharan Africa TAC Technical Advisory Committee TFP Total Factor Productivity TOR Terms of Reference WB World Bank WDR World Development Report WFP World Food Programme Strategic Case A. Context and need for a DFID intervention 1. The Millennium Development Goal target to halve the number of people who do not have enough to eat (MDG1) is severely off track. Globally estimates suggest that around 850 million people remain undernourishedi; an estimated 642 million people in Asia, 265 million in Sub-Saharan Africa. To meet MDG1, the FAO estimates that the number of undernourished people must fall by 73 million a year. 2. The poorest people, dependent on agriculture for their livelihoods, are most vulnerable to stresses and sudden shocks. For example, more than 100 million extra people are estimated to have been pushed into poverty as a result of the 2007/08 food crisis. Climate change is expected to decrease food security. By 2050, global yields are expected to be reduced by about 7%. But for some of the most food insecure regions, yield losses are likely to be 20% or more as soon as 2030ii. Food and Nutritional Security 3. Food and nutritional security depends on the physical availability of food, the affordability of an adequate and appropriate diet, and the ability of people to make effective use of the food they consume. Some of the factors that enable poor people to access the financial and other resources needed to consume, purchase and grow enough nutritious food lie outside the ‘food system’ and the ‘agricultural sector’. But agricultural sector development can have a positive impact on food and nutritional security of poor people in a number of ways: the technologies, institutions, infrastructure and information that support sustainable and equitable increases in agricultural productivity can increase the supply of a diverse and locally desirable diet at affordable prices; these same increases in productivity can improve economic access for all by raising farm income, generating employment on and off farm, and reducing prices; increasing productivity can change social access to food by deliberately empowering women or socially excluded groups; and by improving the nutritional content of food and the nutritional status of consumersiii; 4. The linkages between agriculture and food and nutritional security are complex and there are gaps in the evidence on how one affects the other. Food security is an overriding priority for poor people, who often have limited access to sufficient productive assets such as land or water for irrigation. To maintain their livelihood they use a diversity of resources – crops, livestock, trees and fish- for the purposes of sale or exchange. Poor farmers often grow a selection of crops and different varieties of each crop to spread their risk and make them less vulnerable to biological, climatic or price shocks. Livestock are a key asset that can be sold to contribute to household food security during seasonal or periodic stresses. 5. Central to people’s livelihood strategies is access to and control over resources, particularly land and water. Land is a particularly important resource and inequitable or insecure land tenure often has a significant impact on levels of food security. 6. To improve their food security status and increase their incomes, rural households often diversify into a wide range of off-farm activities. Non-farm incomes constitute a significant and growing part of rural incomes. In turn, the rural non-farm economy can contribute to the agriculture sector, through agroprocessing and the distribution and provision of farm inputs. Clearly farm and non-farm sources of income are closely linked and the distinction between rural and urban activities is increasingly blurred. More productive agriculture sectors: an engine of growth in developing countries 7. Most countries with large numbers of poor and hungry people depend on agriculture for growth and economic development. In Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) the agricultural sector employs nearly two thirds of the population and accounts for 20-30% of GDPiv. 8. Studies of growth in the agriculture sector repeatedly show that, compared to economic growth in other sectors, it is more effective in reducing povertyv,vi.vii,viii,ix. The most recent empirical evidence is in a 2011 cross country study of the OECD which concludes: ”More than half of the reduction in poverty achieved in the selected countries … can be attributed to growth in agricultural incomes, over onethird to growth in remittances, and the rest is due to growth in non-farm incomes.”x It also states that this pro-poor effect is unambiguous and not dependent on country characteristics. The 2008 World Development Report supports this conclusion finding that GDP growth originating in agriculture is more effective in raising incomes of extremely poor people than GDP growth originating outside the sector”xi. Rural households depend on agricultural production for their income – especially poorer rural households, which get a bigger part of their income from farming and agricultural labour than do better-off households. xii This evidence indicates that strengthening agricultural sectors is likely to have a bigger poverty reducing effect than support to other sectors by raising rural incomes. But it makes no claims about the costs of doing so and therefore the relative value for money of agricultural interventions compared to other uses of UK funding. 9. Support to agriculture reaches the poor directly, even in a rapidly urbanising worldxiii. Most of the poor still reside in rural areas. This is particularly true for women and girls who provide much of the labour for agriculture but who, in most cultural contexts, are less mobile than men and boysxiv. Many urban poor – those in precarious informal jobs or are unemployed - also depend on extended family networks in the local rural hinterland and rely on agriculture as a safety netxv. 10. Two thirds of the world’s agricultural value added is created in developing countriesxvi. All top-performing countries that have successfully reduced poverty in recent years initially emphasised support to agriculture through increased total factor productivity (TFP). For example, China’s successful support for smallholder production TFP growth has had a major impact on its agricultural production. China’s strong initial emphasis on agricultural growth has also been essential to its success in reducing povertyxvii. 11. In order to boost agriculture sector productivity, national governments and the private sector need to: make higher yielding technologies; improve the infrastructural base; provide better access to markets for farmers; create an enabling environment for private sector investment in agriculture. Higher yielding technologies 12. Every 10% increase in yields of staple food crops in Africa is estimated to reduce poverty by 7%xviii. In Africa, maize yields on farmers’ fields are often only one third of what can be achieved in experimental trials. Closing the yield gap will require the generation of new technologies adapted to and appropriate for the needs of developing country farmers, better management practices and increased use of improved seed varieties and fertilisers. Labour productivity can be further improved with increased use of mechanisation. 13. Agricultural research and development can produce substantial returns on investment, ranging from 35% (SSA) to 50% (Asia) in 700 studiesxix. But farmers must be able to participate in priority setting, design and implementation of research. Adoption of improved technologies is enhanced if farmers can see it working in their fields and if they are supported by effective extension, information and advisory services. Enabling farmers, particularly small holders, to benefit from these higher yielding technologies and practices requires that linkages between farmers and advisory services are strengthened with well-functioning support markets to provide them sustainably. Translating higher adaptation rates for improved technologies into reductions in poverty also requires more equitable access to assets by poor farmers. Improved infrastructure 14. Agricultural growth and poverty reduction also depend critically on investments in rural infrastructure, which generally provide high returns. Transport costs are often 50-60 percent of total costs, creating situations where staple food crops are not competitive to produce for export out of local production areas even in good years and are expensive to import in bad years. Without investment in the construction, rehabilitation and upgrading of rural feeder roads, local food producers are left highly vulnerable to weather shocks that translate into high and volatile staple food prices, particularly in rural areas. 15. Investment in irrigation has also provided high payoffs. Sub-Saharan Africa has large untapped water resources available for agriculture. Here, after many failures in the 1980s, returns on irrigation projects now often reach 15 to 20%, xx and irrigation is expected to become more important as a source of productivity growth. In Asia the scope for further expanding irrigated land is now limited and more efforts are needed to increase water use efficiency. Better functioning markets 16. For large numbers of rural producers to benefit substantially from improved technologies and infrastructure, they need efficient markets. This includes affordable access to accurate and timely market information, support for meeting the quality standards of potential customers, increased access to finance and to risk management tools such as weather based crop-insurance. Better functioning markets can increase the share of the retail price farmers receive for their products. Well integrated regional agricultural markets can also reduce the cost of food and uncertainty of supply, with positive impacts on food security. 17. More efficient markets alone do not promote equitable outcomes. Building the bargaining power of smallholders by providing support for strengthening producer organisations can improve prices farmers receive for their products and lower the cost of inputs. Improved management of risks and increased resilience to shocks 18. Growth in low income countries is more volatile and both asset and income risks are higher than in more developed countries. So, while raising agricultural sector productivity and improving access to markets are important for increasing the economic opportunities for poor people, sustainable reductions in poverty also require that poor producers are better able to manage risks and their livelihoods are made more resilient to economic shocks. 19. The nature of risks facing farmers varies from one country to another but in many developing countries there are certain common factors. Often financial and insurance markets, which can help farmers to manage their risks are underdeveloped or completely absent. The most vulnerable populations are often dispersed and asset-poor small holders have limited access to technology and markets. They face high operational costs for access to risk management programmes and products. Women headed households typically fare worst as their access to assets, finance, extension service support and risk management tools is even more limited than for other small producers. 20. Reducing risks and vulnerability to shocks means helping to build human capital, assets and access to employment, thereby freeing families to make more productive investments as they become more confident in their economic security. It can also mean providing social protection measures which help individuals and families smooth their consumption and handle shocks and stresses through better coping strategies. A number of themes have emerged as important in building poor people’s adaptive capacity in the face of food-related stresses and shocks: the importance of access to assets; the value of innovation; the role of knowledge and information; flexibility and foresight – forms of governance which can deal with complex challenges and build resilience to address them. A Better Business Environment for Agribusiness 21. Policies, rules and institutions that promote predictable business operations reduce unnecessary costs and facilitate the monetization of assets to build wealth all help strengthen and build agricultural markets. By reducing costs of complying with government administration, a better business environment enhances agricultural productivity. Making it easier to enforce contracts and establish property rights facilitates access to finance, encourages longer term investment and increases predictability of future income. All of these effects help to strengthen agricultural markets and contribute significantly to the sector’s overall growth. 22. A better agribusiness environment also involves streamlining the rules and procedures for trading across borders which is an essential ingredient for global food security and for connecting developing country farmers to bigger markets. Costly import and export regimes can act as a barrier to trade and keep agricultural products uncompetitive in regional and global markets. 23. Wider societal and governance reforms are also important if economic growth in the agriculture sector is going to contribute significantly to food security and poverty reduction. These reforms often include equalising rights of access to resources such as land and water; employment; finance; education and support services, as well as the ability to mobilise social capital. Investment levels in agriculture Public sector 24. Many developing country governments have neglected investment in agriculture, generally, and in small holder agriculture specifically. In Africa, aggregate public spending on agriculture accounted for 5–7% of the total national budget from 1980 to 2005 – compared with agriculture’s 20-30% contribution to GDP. Asia fares better on agricultural investment, putting in 6–15%xxi. 25. The agricultural sector has faced a marked decline in direct public investment over the past 20 years. The low level of government investment has been reflected in direct aid to agriculture. Although total aid to developing countries grew by about 5% a year from US$7 bn in 1980 to US$27 bn in 2006, in relative terms the direct investment in agriculture fell from 20% in 1980 to 4% by 2006 largely as the result of donors moving into complementary areas such as rural infrastructure (WDR, 2008). 26. While the level of direct investment in agriculture has begun to rise, IFPRI suggests that, in SSA alone, the total public investment in agriculture required to achieve the hunger target of MDG 1 by 2015 is at least $33 bn per annum (IFPRI, 2008). In 2004, total public expenditure on agriculture in SSA was $9 bn, a $24 bn annual shortfall. Even assuming an ambitious 10% annual increase in funding over 7 years from 2004 to 2011 would increase funding to only $17.5 bn, leaving a conservative annual gap (ignoring the cumulative gap) of over $15 bn in SSA alone. According to rough FAO estimates, the overall annual public and private financing gap in developing countries is $67 bn in order to ensure food security for all by 2050xxii. 27. In 2003, many SSA country governments pledged to increase support to agriculture in order to achieve the goal of 6% annual agricultural growth (The Maputo Declaration). Under the Comprehensive African Agricultural Development Programme (CAADP), African heads of state agreed to allocate 10% of their national budgets to agriculture. But many African governments are operating in an environment of scarce public resources, and so far only a few states have met these growth and spending targets. Private sector 28. Development assistance cannot, by itself, grow agriculture sectors to realise their potential for growth and poverty reduction. It must be complemented by public investment which, when used strategically, can strengthen the business environment by developing conducive policies and regulations or funding public infrastructure that helps to deepen markets and lower transaction costs, so that investing in the food and agriculture sectors becomes more attractive. Ultimately, agriculture is a for profit activity undertaken by private individuals who must compete in dynamic local, national and international markets. For this reason above all, private sector investment will be critical to filling the remaining financing gap in the sector and is critical to the sustainability of interventions aimed at agriculture sector growth and poverty reduction. 29. The private investment gap in agriculture in developing countries, though not authoritatively estimated, is a substantial part of FAO’s rough $67 bn estimate. Commercial bank lending to the primary agricultural sector has historically been small. Agriculture accounts for 30% of Africa’s economy but less than 5% of bank lending goes into the sector in SSA.xxiii. For example, agriculture accounts for 40% of Nigerian GDP, yet the sector receives only 1% of commercial bank loans. In Mozambique in 2007, 80% of the financing for agriculture was in the form of public finance including loans and grants from development institutions. Less than 5 % was from domestic private sector investors. 30. The recent increase in the prices of agricultural commodities has trigged an upswing in domestic bank lending and foreign private investment in some developing countries. It has also helped to spawn a range of innovative publicprivate partnerships, for example to support the development of regional agricultural growth corridors in Southern Tanzania and around Beira in Mozambique. There is renewed interest in farmers’ organisations, ‘hub-out grower’ and contract farming models, which increase opportunities for farmers to access finance, technical expertise and markets. These experiences demonstrate that private investment is responsive to positive changes in agricultural markets. 31. To ensure permanent long term growth in commercial investment at the scale that would bridge the significant financing gap in the sector requires competitive, fairly contested and well-functioning markets backed by good infrastructure, a conducive enabling environment, vibrant cross border trade and stronger partnerships between public and private sectors to provide all the necessary inputs that support well-functioning markets. Aid Effectiveness in the Food and Agriculture Sector 32. Applying aid effectiveness principles to the food and agriculture sectors is especially challenging, because of the sectors’ breadth and the spread of responsibilities across different parts of government. Unlike service delivery in social sectors such as health and education, which is predominantly in the hands of the public sector, agriculture is overwhelmingly a private sector activity and agricultural outcomes are a result of complex interactions between the public and private sectors and civil society. The range of actors, the diversity and complexity of the economic activity involved, and the drive for rapid action with credible results all point to the need for improved effectiveness of assistance to the sector. 33. As aid to agriculture increases again, country leadership is under threat even where, as with African countries in which the CAADP process is most advanced, national strategies with strong technical frameworks are in place. In 2009, signatories to the L’Aquila Food Security Initiative (AFSI) made commitments to provide more and better public and private investment in agriculture and related sectors, in order to improve the income and food security of poor people in low income countries. They also committed to adhering to aid effectiveness principles because they recognised that their own pledges to increase resources for food security and agriculture risked - i) increasing fragmentation in the sector, potentially weakening country ownership and alignment; and ii) undermining efforts to define and measure development impact on the ground attributable to their funding. 34. GAFSP was established in April 2010 as a means by which countries which had committed increased funding under AFSI could do so in a way that improved the effectiveness of aid delivery rather than undermined it. Its governance and operating methods have been specifically designed to promote country ownership, improve donor alignment with national plans, provide additional resources and not replace other funding, make transparent funding decisions, focus on results and allow lesson learning between countries and institutions. Fit with UK strategic priorities 35. Increasing DFID support to agriculture responds to recent evidencebased, scientifically-validated, UK Government policy thinking. In January 2011, the DFID and DEFRA Secretaries of State jointly launched a report of the Government Office of Science on “The Future of Food and Farming” saying there is “a strong case for governments, the private sector and civil society to continue to prioritise global food security [and] sustainable agricultural production.” The report highlights that a sustainable increase in agricultural productivity is necessary to feed a growing global populationxxiv. 36. The UK government is committed to the achievement of the Millennium Development Goals and has made specific public commitments to tackle MDG1: halving poverty and hunger. Forty countries including most of SSA and South Asia are off-track against the hunger target of MDG1. The publication “Changing lives, delivering results” states that over the next four years the UK will: stop 10 million more children going hungry (since increased to 20 million); ensure another four million people have enough food throughout the year; and Help more than six million of the world’s poorest people to escape extreme povertyxxv. Help poor families to grow enough food by increasing their access to seeds, tools and training in farming”. 37. Support for agriculture sector growth will contribute to other UK government/ DFID priorities: To work more with the private sector and stimulate private investment (as outlined in the ‘Engine of Growth Strategy’) in order to create wealth in developing countries; To foster growth, trade and economic integration in Africa, for example through its support for the Regional Economic Communities in Southern, Eastern and West Africa. And the African Free Trade initiative (AFTI). A large part of the trade these initiatives are design to promote is likely to be in food and agricultural commodities. Given that agriculture is also a source of greenhouse gas emissions and contributes to climate change, investing in sustainable intensification in agriculture in developing countries will help adapt to and mitigate the impacts of agriculture on climate change. 38. DFID has committed to reach 20 million children under five between now and 2015 with our nutrition programmes. Undernutrition is a major challenge to human and economic development. It has complex causes which must be addressed through a combination of direct interventions and nutrition-sensitive development in health, education, and agriculture. Agriculture has the potential to drive improved nutritional outcomes, although the evidence for how this can be done most effectively is weak. It provides a source of food and nutrients, a source of income, has effects on food prices, affects the environment in which people live and influences women‘s time for taking care of very young children. Several studies show that a 10% increase in income per capita usually results in a 3-4% decline in stuntingxxvi. But if growth is in the agriculture sector, and concentrated amongst the rural poor, we see a faster reduction in stuntingxxvii .This relationship is even stronger in food insecure contextsxxviii. While we know agricultural growth is important for reducing stunting at the aggregate level, the evidence for the impact of agricultural programmes on nutrition is weaker. In 2010, a DFID funded review of the nutritional impact of agriculture interventions concluded that agricultural interventions improve the production and consumption of nutritious food among poor households but could not identify a direct impact on the nutritional status of children because most studies were too smallxxix. This is an important current field of investigation for DFID and its development partners. 39. DFID is committed to empowerment of women and girls through increasing access to jobs and financial services. Women account for 70% of the global workforce in agriculture. But they own just 1% of the land receive only 5% of extension services and only 10% of farm credit. But investment in women as farmers and food producers has significant benefits in terms of poverty reduction, agricultural productivity, food security and natural resource managementxxx. The strong economic relationship between gender inequality and hunger (which is overwhelmingly female) suggests that reducing gender disparities in areas such as small-holder agriculture is essential to reducing hunger levelsxxxi. Reducing the gender gap in the control of agricultural resources (i.e. land, inputs and finance) can increase agricultural productivity by 1520%xxxii. In SSA it has been calculated that agricultural productivity could increase by up to 20% if women’s access to such resources as land, seed and fertiliser were equal to men’sxxxiii. Women-focused support for agri-business development can also add social valuexxxiv. Greater direct incomes for women from agriculture lead to improved gender equity and provide benefits for the entire familyxxxv. Evidence also suggests that effective support to agriculture also speeds up the achievement of the MDGs related to education, maternal health, HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseasesxxxvi. Argument for DFID intervention 40. There is a pressing need for more and better financial support to help accelerate agricultural sector growth and improve food security for approximately 1 billion people worldwide. Developing countries have expressed high level demand for increased investment, requiring collective global action to meet the conservative estimate of $15 bn per year in additional public investment and the rough $67 bn per year investment overall required to meet the financial gap. With food prices now higher than in 2008, a rising global population, the uncertainty of global climate change and increasing food demands from emerging economies, addressing the causes of high and volatile prices and their impacts on the poor have become prominent and pressing global concerns. 41. DFID is an important global player on agricultural sector development with a good track record of support. An informal analysis of OECD data shows DFID as the fifth biggest donor to ‘agriculture’ in SSA (when we include our multilateral contributions). DFID’s annual ‘core’ funding combined to three main UN-affiliated bodies responsible for food and agriculture - WFP, FAO and IFAD, is increasing from £52mn in 20011/12 to £82mn in 2014/15. DFID support to agricultural research has increased by 60% since FY 2008/9 and DFID plans to scale up investment in the uptake of research including developing new cofunding arrangements with the private sector, and integrating climate change and agriculture, through development of new research programmes. 42. Increased engagement will complement and improve the effectiveness of existing DFID investments. In Africa, DFID is providing £10mn to a World Bank Multi Donor Trust Fund to support the development of the Comprehensive Africa Agricultural Development Programme (CAADP) country investment plans/programmes. DFID has been a strong advocate of CAADP, which aims to increase investment in agriculture and align donors behind national government’s own plans to improve the productivity and sustainability of the agriculture sector. In South Asia, DFID works with the World Bank and other partners on the South Asia Food and Nutrition Security Initiative (SAFANSI) to develop evidence on the most effective ways of achieving food security, raise awareness on the challenges, and promote advocacy for action amongst the various stakeholders. This demonstrates UK support for its non-financial AFSI commitments on aideffectiveness, including support for the implementation of country-led agricultural investment plans through country-led coordination processes, consistent with the Accra Agenda for Action. 43. DFID also has the potential to provide leadership on private sector development in agriculture, building on the expanding challenge funds such as the African Enterprise Challenge Fund and the Food Retail Industry Challenge Fundxxxvii that encourages private sector companies to compete for funding for new and innovative business and projects in agriculture. 44. The need for investment in developing country agriculture is enormous and immediate. The GAFSP vehicle is already responding to increasing country demand and the roughly £67 bn annual financing gap in developing countries. Six AFSI donors plus the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation (BMGF) pledged US$ 972mn to GAFSP, of which to date US$ 570mn has been received by the Trustee (see Annex 1). Of the 60 countries eligible to apply for GAFSP (see Table 5 in the Management Case), 25 have submitted funding requests totalling US$1.2 bn, 14 of which were from Africa. The GAFSP Steering Committee has, to date, allocated US$ 481mn in grants to 12 countries (see Table 6 in the Management Case). A further 18 countries have submitted requests to the latest call for proposals (including Ghana, Tanzania, Malawi, Kenya, Senegal, Burkina Faso, Niger, Burundi and Yemen). Some of the countries applying to GAFSP, such as Yemen and Kenya, are experiencing rapid increases in level of food insecurity. Others, such as Ghana, are attracting interest from investors who see the potential for significant growth in the agriculture sector, driven by rapid increases in agricultural commodity prices. 45. Increasing DFID support to agriculture would meet UK political commitments to tackle food security internationally made at every G8 and G20 Summit since the food price spike in 2008. The UK has met in full its commitment to contribute £1.1 bn towards the AFSI pledge of $20 bn investment in food security and agriculture in the 3-year period from 2009 - 2012xxxviii. The US-led G8 Summit in May 2012 will see the launch of a New Alliance for Food and Nutritional Security in Africa which will involve G8 countries, including the UK, recommitting to support global efforts to improve food security, with a focus on private sector investment in African agriculture. Re-energising GAFSP and increasing its funding base, particularly for the private sector window, will be part of this package. At the G20 in 2011 Agriculture Ministers agreed an Action Plan on Food Price Volatility and Agriculture. This committed all G20 governments to: ”improve agricultural production and productivity both in the short and long term in order to respond to a growing demand for agricultural commodities’xxxix; and ‘promote sustainable crop diversification and agricultural systems which contribute to … a sustainable use of natural resources in particular land, water and biodiversity”. 46. GAFSP is a vehicle with significant potential for positively transforming global agriculture and meeting the world’s food security challenges. As set out in para 44 above, its public sector window is already helping to address the public financing shortfall in developing countries and its private sector window, which is currently being reformed and strengthened, has the potential to leverage billions in private financing to i) meet the overall global investment shortfall that purely public investment would struggle to meet and ii) sustain a transformation in agricultural productivity and promote more resilient agricultural markets to meet the future challenges of increased demand and climate uncertainty. In addition, by supporting both public and private investment, GAFSP will be uniquely placed to strengthen synergies, complementarities and scale economies to deepen the impact of increased investments in both public and private sectors. 47. In summary the key strategic and practical reasons for DFID intervening by increasing financial support to agriculture are: Meeting large scale demand from developing countries for more resources and addressing the pressing need to expand global food availability. The need for faster progress on MDG 1 DFID’s strong role on aspects of this agenda and on related development issues to which agricultural growth makes a crucial contribution. Closing the substantial public and private funding gaps in the sector in developing countries, estimated at a combined $67 bn per year. Meeting high level political commitments on food security. Meeting on-going commitments on aid effectiveness. Meeting DFID’s corporate priority of increasing private sector investment, growing open markets and free trade by supporting the development of agricultural markets. Consequences of DFID not intervening : 48. Economic results foregone: Recipient countries will not realise the potential for increased agricultural productivity, higher incomes for the poor in the sector and improved agricultural infrastructure all of which would contribute to poverty reduction. Failure to increase investment in agriculture - a primary economic sector –threatens the implementation of nationally-driven, and internationally endorsed development plans. 49. Political/reputational: A decision by the UK not to contribute will generate significant criticism from some development partners (other donor governments, international and domestic thought leaders, members of think tanks and NGOs, parliamentarians), who will accuse the UK of failing to live up to its rhetoric on supporting a step change in agricultural sector development and in food security. 50. Failure by DFID to invest in development of the food and agriculture sector will have a negative impact on international commitments to increase investment, and the contribution that the sector can make to enhancing food security. 51. Not investing could also jeopardise developing country government commitments to invest. African Union countries signed the Maputo Declaration in 2003, pledging to increase spending on agriculture to at least 10% of national budgets; seeking a 6% increase in productivity. The AU Commission is encouraging African countries to deliver on this commitment but they may fail to do so if donors do not adequately support them in meeting their commitments. 52. Social: The poorest who are most dependent on agriculture are women. Investing in agriculture invests in women, through helping them to increase income from a more sustainable and secure livelihood. Not investing in agriculture misses an opportunity to advance the economic empowerment of women and girls living in poor rural communities. 53. Institutional: If DFID does not intervene it will lose the opportunity to play a role in shaping the aid architecture for effective delivery in this important sector. What will we do? 54. We will provide financial support to help meet both the public and private investment shortfalls in agriculture faced by developing countries. Our public investment will support stronger institutions, better policies and improved physical infrastructure to support expansion and strengthening of agricultural markets and better connecting small and medium sized agribusiness and farmers to them Our private investment will increase commercial investment for small and medium sized agri-businesses and farmers, by facilitating access to finance and expanding investment opportunities to strengthen productivity and improve their capacity to participate in global agricultural value chains. 55. To maximize GAFSP’s comparative advantage and the impact of DFID funding, we are proposing support of £50mn over two years. The first disbursement will be made in July 2012 for £13mn to the public sector window to support the investments in public institutions and infrastructure that strengthen agricultural markets. The second will be made to the private sector window in 2013/14 in two equal tranches of £18.5mn each. The rationale for our larger support to the private window is to maximize our ability to help meet the global funding gap and stimulate the growth of open agricultural markets. It will be subject to a number of conditions (see appraisal and management cases) and more detailed appraisal before final transfer of funds. DFID’s £50mn will provide additional funding for public and private investment in agriculture and food security in 2-3 countriesxl. These countries will come from among the 18 (including Ghana, Tanzania, Malawi, Kenya and Yemen) which have submitted requests but not yet received approval of their plans from GAFSP. Sustainability of GAFSP interventions 56. For World Bank administrative purposes the end date of the Programme has been set at 2019, but there is nothing in its statutes or operating procedures which would prevent GAFSP from continuing as long as there is demand from low income countries and private sector entities and available resources. The impact of each country level investment plan will depend on the degree to which capacity constraints of key sectoral institutions are addressed, the extent of local ownership of interventions and the relevance of policy reforms implemented in support of GAFSP funded investments. The sustainability of individual public sector investments will also depend on the extent to which the Supervising Entity responsible and recipient government have sustainability as one of its design criteria. For the Private Sector projects, sustainability will be one of the criteria which IFC will use in decision making about individual proposals. 57. Any decision about future DFID contributions to GAFSP, beyond the recommended £50mn contribution spread over two financial years will only be made after the independent evaluation of GAFSP which we will commission in 2013 and will be subject to a new business case. B. Impact and Outcome that we expect to achieve 58. The expected impacts of the intervention will be reduced rural poverty. This will be measured by increased household incomes and additional rural economic opportunities for the poor. 59. The outcome (and key indicators) of the programme intervention will result in more productive agricultural sectors in developing countries. This will be measured by yield increases and increased returns to investment in the agriculture sector. The outcome will be achieved through delivery of five broadly defined outputs as set out in the appraisal case: 1. 2. 3. 4. higher yielding agricultural technologies developed and in use; improved infrastructure to support agriculture in place and operational; better functioning markets which farmers are able to access; improved risk management and increased resilience of rural people to shocks; and 5. improved policies and capacity of relevant institutions to administer a conducive agribusiness enabling environment. 60. Each GAFSP financed project identifies which of these five outputs it will achieve results against and selects at least one indicator for each of the relevant outputs from an agreed set of core indicators (see list at Annex 2). The selected indicators form the basis of each project’s Results Framework. Because they are drawn from a common core set they can be aggregated across projects. 61. In generating a Log Frame for DFID’s contribution to GAFSP we have focused on Outputs 1-4. GAFSP has not yet developed specific results it will deliver from Output 5 – which relates to the enabling environment –and its inclusion runs the risk of setting objectives for GAFSP that have not been agreed by its constituent donors. For this reason we have left it out of our initial logframe but it can be added once it is formulated and agreed by GAFSP. In the DFID Log Frame we have selected the highest level and most easily measured indicator from the core set for each of Outputs 1-4 and added a fifth, specific to DFID – GAFSP Internal Reforms – against which to measure achievement of the reforms set out on page 43 in the Appraisal Case. 62. The GAFSP Coordinating Unit have calculated that the 12 country investment plans which have received Public Sector Window finance to date, at a cost of $481mn, will reach 1.5mn rural households (or roughly 7.5mn people) when fully implemented. This will raise total incomes of beneficiaries by an estimated US $ 100mn per year (see methodology at Annex 3). It is reasonable to assume that the next 12 country investment plans which receive funding will deliver broadly similar results. If A DFID contribution of £50mn (US$ 80mn) was applied to these expected results of the GAFSP Public Window it would help raise the income of roughly 7.5mn people by US $16.6mn. Using the existing 12 funded plans as a benchmark, the GAFSP Coordination Unit has estimated aggregate figures for four key indicators, covering three outputs that would be produced if 12 of the country investment plans which have now been submitted but not yet funded, were funded in full, at cost of US$ 487mn. If a DFID contribution of £50mn (US$ 80mn) was applied to these results of the GAFSP Public Window it would, at a minimum, buy the following outputs: smallholders supported in use of higher yielding technologies and management practices e.g. over 80,000 smallholder farmers with access to agricultural advisory services infrastructure in place to support agriculture e.g. rehabilitation of over 4,000 hectares of irrigation and upgrading of over 750 kilometres of road people better protected against risk and less vulnerable to shocks affecting the agriculture sector e.g. over 110,000 people living in rural areas receiving direct (conditional) cash transfers. Funds provided through the Public Sector Window will also help to build capacity in important public sector institutions responsible for creating key aspects of the enabling environment for increased investment in agriculture. 63. If the bulk of DFID’s £50m is applied to the Private Sector Window, there is not yet a succinct results offer to which it can be easily applied. However, IFC estimates that every US$ 1mn of concessional funding provided by the PSW will mobilise US$ 6-7mn of commercial funding. This would produce £300-350mn of added value for a £50mn contribution. IFC also intends to contribute its own resources and blend these with GAFSP funding for each project and increase leveraging potential. An early $15mm PSW project in Bangladesh gives some indication of possible future results: 1,200 jobs created Improve the availability of food Increase the competitive pricing for food products The latter two results could benefit thousands of food consumers in impoverished communities. 64. DFID’s participation will also secure key reforms to GAFSP so that the use of its total financial resources is more strongly supportive of UK objectives of: ensuring a strong results focus of work on food security, particularly on gender; improved cost effectiveness of interventions; greater attention to resilience to climate change; improvement of nutritional status in the appraisal of investment plans; and an improved private sector ‘window’ to complement and exploit synergies with the current public sector window. 65. Our agenda for change and for monitoring and evaluation of our contribution to GAFSP are set out as follows: on identification and prioritisation of operational reforms – in the Appraisal Case on ‘Reform Options’ (p.42/43) and in the Management Case (p 60); on our approach to releasing funding for the Private Sector Window – in the Management Case (p. 60); on overall monitoring and evaluation - in the Management Case, Section D p.69-73. 66. In summary, we will review progress against our priority reforms and make a detail assessment of progress with the Private Sectors Window’s operations before deciding whether to recommend making the proposed contribution to this Window. We will secure agreement through the Steering Committee to an overall independent evaluation of GAFSP to be carried out two years after we join the Steering Committee and before consideration is given to any future UK contribution to GAFSP, beyond that recommended here. Appraisal Case A. What are the feasible options that address the need set out in the Strategic case? 1. This appraisal consists of four parts. Part 1 sets out the theory of change of support to agriculture: both the benefits of increasing the sector’s productivity and of strengthening the welfare of the poor whose livelihoods depend on agriculture. Part 2 constructs feasibility criteria using the Strategic Case’s justification for DFID intervention and uses these to select, from different modalities, the preferred options to provide support and achieve maximum value for money. Part 3 conducts economic, reform and financial engagement appraisals of the feasible options and recommends a preferred overall option. Part 4 assesses the value for money of the preferred option. Part 1: Theory of Change 2. The results chain schematic at Annex 4 represents the links between growth in agriculture sector and rural poverty reduction – reflecting the role of agriculture both as a source of income and a direct source of food for poor rural people. In summary the theory of change is as follows: activities and outputs which increase agricultural yields, improve infrastructure and give farmers access to better functioning markets help to improve the productivity of the agricultural sector. Activities which increase the resilience of poor people to shocks help to protect their assets and their livelihoods. These outputs increase the productivity of the agriculture sector and create economic opportunities which, if targeted at poor and vulnerable groups deliver poverty reduction as an impact. In the Log Frame we have added a fifth output – not represented in the Theory of Change diagram – internal reforms of GAFSP. These are described in the Appraisal Case and in the Management Case. The link between impact (reduced rural poverty) and the outcome (more productive agriculture sectors) 3. The evidence underlying the link between Outcome 1 (more productive agriculture sectors) and impact (reduced rural poverty) is set out in the Strategic Case. To summarise, studies of growth in the agriculture sector repeatedly show that, compared to economic growth in other sectors, it is more effective in reducing povertyxli,xlii,xliii,xliv,xlv. This does not imply that poverty reduction in the agricultural sector is more cost effective than in other sectors, simply that strengthening agricultural sectors is likely to have a bigger poverty reducing effect than support to other sectors by raising rural incomes. Rural households depend on agricultural production for their income – especially poorer rural households, which get a bigger part of their income from farming and agricultural labour than do better-off households. 4. Agriculture is fundamentally a private sector activity. It is unique in that structural transformation in the sector leads to productivity gains, surplus capital and labour being released into other sectors, keeps food prices lower for the urban poor and provides export earningsxlvi. Historically, the wealth generated by agriculture sector growth has been the platform for more diversified economic development and rising of living standards of the rural population. Increasing farm incomes brings rural economies to life, generates jobs for other poor people and increases demand for domestically produced goods and services. Increased incomes generally lead to improved nutrition, better health, and increased investment in educationxlvii. We judge the evidence on the link between increasing agricultural productivity and poverty reduction to be strong. It comes from a range of reputable sources including institutions with no obvious vested interest in reaching such a conclusion, such as the OECD. Link between outputs and outcome 5. Given that agriculture is a heterogeneous sector with multiple markets, commodities and business types, there is a large range of interventions through which the outcome can be achieved. The evidence for some of the linkages between the key interventions, as outlined in the theory of change, is given below. Output 1 – Higher yielding agricultural technologies developed and in use lead to increases in agricultural productivity 6. Agricultural productivity critically depends on investment in agricultural technology that is developed and adopted by farmers. Dramatic rises in productivity have been based on the development and application of new technologiesxlviii. Over the past 50 years global food production has more than tripled. Global yields per hectare of the major staple crops grew at an annual rate of 2-3% between 1961 and 1990, exceeding population growth rates and contributing to a long-term decline in food prices. Major food security successes – such as the Asian Green Revolution, and the expansion of improved maize varieties in East and Southern Africa, have been driven by agricultural innovation. Agricultural research and development also produces substantial returns on investment, ranging from 35% (SSA) to 50% (Asia) in 700 studiesxlix. Most recently, an assessment of the impact of the International Rice Research Institute’s research on improving rice varietal yield between 1985 and 2009 found a boost in rice yields by up to 13%. 7. However, there is also evidence that market inefficiencies constrain agricultural technology adoption in developing countries. In SSA, adoption of new technologies has lagged behind that of Asia. For example, by 2000, adoption of modern varieties of maize was estimated to be 17 percent of total area harvested in SSA compared to 90% in East and South East Asia and the Pacific and 57 % in Latin America and the Caribbean (Gollin et al. 2005). What is lacking is a systematic analysis of why such innovations haven’t been successful scaled up in SSA. We judge the evidence to be strong given the key role that technology plays in productivity improvements in any economic sector as well as in economic theory. Different sources and historical experience demonstrate a strong linkage. Output 2 – Improved infrastructure in place to support agriculture 8. There is evidence of how investment in agricultural and rural infrastructure (output 2) can provide high returns. The development of irrigation has provided high payoffs in Asia. In SSA, after many failures in the 1980s, returns on irrigation projects now often reach 15 to 20%.l. Irrigation development has been recommended as a powerful tool to enhance agricultural productivity ultimately reducing povertyli,lii,liii. Arif and Ahmad (2001) estimated that rural poverty had been reduced to 13.8% in the rain fed areas of Punjab as a result of enhanced irrigation schemesliv. The World Bank argues that investment in irrigation in SSA is negligible. Only 4 % of the area in production is under irrigation, compared with 39 % in South Asia and 29 % in East Asialv. 9. Some studies show that deficient transport infrastructure can be one determinant of low technological adoption, restricted cropping choices and low agricultural productivity in developing countries (Omamo 1998; Zeller et al. 1998; Von Oppen et al. 1997; Antle 1983). Trader surveys in Benin, Madagascar, and Malawi find that transport costs account for 50– 60 percent of total marketing costslvi. Rural road development has the potential to reduce transport costs and generate market activity. In Vietnam, road rehabilitation increased the variety of goods that households sold in the market—primary fruits, vegetables, and meat— and encouraged greater participation in trade and services. In Georgia, the construction and rehabilitation of roads increased the opportunities for off-farm and female employment. In Madagascar, simulations suggest that a 50% reduction in travel time per kilometre on roads would increase rice production by 1%lvii. 10. We judge the evidence of returns to investment in rural infrastructure and irrigation to be adequately robust. Output 3 – Better functioning markets which farmers can access 11. Linking farmers to markets can also help to increase agricultural productivity and profitability. Some studies have found that aggregate physical productivity increases with improvement in market accesslviii. Inefficient rural markets fail to provide the great majority of rural families with enough income to cross the poverty linelix. Market access creates incentives in the agricultural sectorlx. Price incentives, provide positive signals for production decisions, resource allocation and market orientation in ways that may contribute to eradicating rural povertylxi,lxii,lxiii. Effective interventions include improving pricing policies or improving the transmission of information, physical changes to markets, e.g. improvements to wholesale markets. A survey of wholesale markets handling fresh produce in four states in India found that 40% of the shops had no electricity, and only 6% of the markets had a cold storage facility which affected their ability to do businesslxiv. But another study in India found that wealthier farmers tend to capture a disproportionate share of the benefits of facilities in congested wholesale marketslxv. Access to well functioning commodity markets can help to influence farm incomeslxvi. 12. Alongside better functioning output markets, input markets for capital, land, and labour need to be made more efficient so that farmers can better access those factors. There are particular barriers in each case for women. Access to agricultural credit has been positively linked to agricultural productivity in several studies. The development of local financial markets improves efficiency of inputs use in agriculturelxvii. Effective land rental markets can contribute to rural diversification and income growth in a rapidly growing economy. 13. Evidence assessment is strong given the wide range of evidence from multiple context and reputable sources and of accepted economic theory on the importance of efficiently functioning markets for increased productivity and growth more generally. Output 4 – Improved management of risks and increased resilience to shocks 14. Shocks to the food system, such as the sudden increase in food prices, can expose the lack of resilience of the poor. Without access to risk management tools such as credit, insurance, and safe and effective storage facilities, or support for coping strategies such as direct transfers, their assets can be eroded with subsequent long-term effects on livelihoods and overall agriculture sector productivity. 15. One of the ways that economic and physical shocks manifest themselves on rural households is through the sale or loss of productive assets. Land is a key asset for the poor. It provides a foundation for economic activity and the functioning of market-based institutions (e.g. credit) and nonmarket institutions (e.g. local governments and social networks) in many developing countrieslxviii. Improving land tenure systems can benefit the poor. Lessening the risk of expropriation reduces the need to spend private resources and time on protecting assets, increases productivity and provides incentives to invest. 16. Analysis of a recent land certification initiative in Ethiopia, which registered over 20 million parcels of land to some six million households, found that although certification failed to eliminate tenure insecurity, it significantly reduced fear of land loss by 10%. The propensity to invest in soil and water conservation increases by between 20 and 30 %. Certification consistently increased the amount of land rented out by about one tenth of a hectarelxix. However, as property rights systems are complex institutions and tend to be entrenched in the local social, economic and political power dynamics, causal chains become quite complex and evidence tends to be context specific. 17. Forced sale of livestock assets has multiple impacts on the poor – reducing availability of food for the households, reducing income from the sale of meat, milk, eggs and reducing collateral. Given that about three quarters of the extreme poor are estimated to keep livestock as part of their livelihood portfolios 2009), safeguarding and increasing the returns from their livestock assets is expected to help them to escape poverty lxx. 18. There is a growing understanding of the link between social protection and development of productive and market-oriented smallholder agriculture in developing countries. Farmers faced with increasingly volatile local food markets will be reluctant to commit their scarce resources to market-led developing of agriculture, often involving activities other than producing staple crops, if they have no effective way of managing risks or no reliable safety net. In such situations, global price spikes or catastrophic rain failures will reduce food security and increase poverty. There is a need to manage risk and the long-term negative impacts of failure to protect households from irreversible shocks. Farmers who are supported to diversify their livelihoods, sustainably, will be more resilient to shocks. 19. We know that a growing agricultural sector can improve nutritional outcomes by increasing aggregate availability, lowering prices and reducing price volatility but it cannot guarantee food acquisition by the poor and vulnerable. More work is needed to identify effective transmission mechanisms but these are likely to include effective cash transfers programmes and other targeting mechanisms (such as school nutrition programmes). 20. In addition to investments in agriculture, scaled-up investments in social protection that focus on nutrition are also crucial for improving the lives of poor rural people. Evidence from developing countries confirms that increases in food prices cause maternal and child undernutrition levels to riselxxi. Nutritional deficiencies in very early in pregnancy increase the likelihood of reduced foetal and infant growthlxxii. A child who was undernourished during its first two years of life is less likely to complete school (due to impact on cognitive development), diminishing their human capital which is a key asset, and will earn, on average, a 10-17% lower income than one who was well-nourishedlxxiii. Mothers who are undernourished during pregnancy are more likely to give birth to undernourished children. Children who are undernourished in the first two years after birth are likely to suffer from poorer health and to attain less in terms of education and income generating outcomes through their life. So improving the resilience of the rural poor to shocks has intergenerational benefits for poverty reduction. Food and Nutritional Security 21. As highlighted in the Strategic Case, the linkages between agriculture and food and nutritional security are complex and there are gaps in the evidence on how one affects the other. This Business Case focuses on the factors that affect people’s food security that fall primarily within the agricultural sector, including through the use of direct transfers which help them protect their assets in times of stress. Its Outcome will be increased agriculture sector productivity, specifically among disadvantaged farming households. Focusing on a wider range of possible factors that can impact on food security would risk spreading the Programme’s resources too thin, diminishing its impact on the ground, and making monitoring and evaluation more problematic. 22. Although not explicitly stated in the Output or Outcome statements, this intervention will improve the food security of the beneficiaries through more than one of the transmission mechanism previously described i.e. i) increasing direct availability of more food and more nutritious food to food producers, by improving their productivity; ii) increasing aggregate availability, lowering prices locally, reducing price volatility and, therefore, increasing affordability of food for poor consumers (NB. most poor farming households produce some crops but purchase others, even staple foods in periods between harvests.) ; iii) increasing the income from the sale of their own produce and therefore increasing the purchasing power of producers; iii) providing employment for landless rural workers; and iv) reducing the risks and increasing the resilience of rural households to shocks. The enabling environment 23. The theory of change model used here (Annex 4) and the Log Frame has been kept deliberately simple to aid measurement of results and attribution of impact. It does not include enabling environment because GAFSP has not set out a high level result on this agenda. But evidence shows the importance of policies and procedures that encourage private sector investment and more open markets. Recent OECD analysis on links between agricultural development and poverty reduction shows that among the countries which have made the fastest progress in reducing poverty between 1980 and 2005, improvements in agricultural productivity have been accompanied by reductions in dis-protectionist policies for agriculture such as over-valued exchange rates and high taxes on agricultural exports. And more generally the evidence on improving the enabling environment from empirical studies and literature reviews by the World Bank on business registration show how reducing red tape and streamlining regulation can have meaningful positive impacts on investment and the number of firms.lxxiv The Private Sector Window - Theory of Change 24. The Private Sector Window theory of change is an integral part of the overall GAFSP Theory of Change. The Private Sector Window will provide financing and advisory services to support new technologies in existing firms and unlock constrained private investment in infrastructure, input markets and services which all contribute to the development of agricultural markets. These activities are all amply reflected in the overall GAFSP Theory of Change: Output 1: new technology developed that enhances productivity. PSW investments and advice have as a direct objective the development and acquisition of new technology to enhance agricultural productivity. Output 2: Development of Infrastructure to support agriculture. PSW financing and advice will stimulate private sector investment in infrastructure assets and services to support agricultural markets. Output 3: Better functioning markets that farmers can access: PSW will provide funds, instruments and advice to reduce market constraints and facilitate more productive operations by small and medium enterprises that will strengthen the functioning of markets. Its focus on SME agribusiness and on catalytic investments should lead to better access for individual farmers. 25. Evidence of impact of investments and advisory services in private markets is available from market development initiatives in DFID agricultural market development projects: In Bangladesh, the Katalyst (DFID, multi-donor) programme has supported market development initiatives to generate an extra £150m of income for over 1.6m small farmers and businesses, in sectors ranging from maize to fish to furniture, including the most vulnerable communities in flood-prone areas. In Nigeria over 10,000 small farmers are using tractor services for the first time, resulting in cost savings of £37 for the average farmer (5-10% of household income). And a commercial fertiliser supply chain has been established, delivering more appropriate inputs to small farmers (e.g. 1kg bags) at prices they can afford – increasing yields and creating jobs.lxxv1 More generally, investment is a critical input into the functioning of markets, whether locally or through foreign investment that also imports new technology and knowledge. This is not a contentious point. 26. We judge the evidence in favour of facilitating private sector investment to be strong given the importance of the private sector to all economic activity. This linkage is a core part of DFID policy (see DFID’s recent Private Sector Development Strategy). Institutional, Social and Political Appraisal 27. Agricultural markets operate within political, institutional and social structures which underpin the assumptions which ensure that the links in each part of the theory of change hold. Without political will or institutional capacity in country, the success of GAFSP interventions would be significantly compromised. Without social appraisal it is impossible to fully understand whether interventions benefit or hurt end beneficiaries and achieve the stated impact. 28. GAFSP directly tackles the political will concern by requiring investment plans to be signed off and submitted by country Ministries of Finance as well as ensuring country governments play a central role in drafting them. This affords political buy-in for the use of GAFSP funds at a high political level. Social and institutional issues are intervention specific and are thus best addressed at that level. Supervising Entities (which have all been ranked good value for money by the DFID multilateral aid review) have rules and procedures to safeguard social and institutional issues as part of their operational policies. Any further strengthening would need to be led through DFID’s corporate relationship with, and core funding for each entity which can be subsequently supported through the GAFSP mechanism. This same analysis also applies to environmental safeguards. Part 2: Identifying Feasible Options I. Constructing Criteria 29. We construct criteria based on i) the rationale for DFID intervention and ii) basic operational requirements for demonstrating and improving results. In summary the rationale for DFID intervention is: Meeting large scale demand for more resources from developing countries and addressing the pressing need to expand global food availability. The need for faster progress on MDG 1 DFID’s strong role on aspects of this agenda and on related development issues to which agricultural growth makes a crucial contribution. Closing the substantial public and private funding gaps in the sector in developing countries, estimated at a combined $67 bn per year. Meeting high level political commitments on food security. Meeting on-going commitments on aid effectiveness. Meeting DFID’s corporate priority of increasing private sector investment, growing open markets and free trade by supporting the development of agricultural markets.. 30. All options except doing nothing additional imply additional DFID support to agriculture. We assume these all address DFID political commitments, its role on agriculture and a significant contribution to meeting MDG 1. To differentiate between the options we construct criteria based on meeting large scale demand and pressing need, closing the funding gap and meeting aid effectiveness commitments as well as operational focus on results: Table 1: Feasibility Criteria to Assess Possible Options Criteria Description 1 Addresses need to meet immediate, large scale demand from developing countries for more public and private investment in agriculture and the pressing need to increase agricultural productivity to address global geopolitical risks and trends. 2 Meets aid effectiveness commitments by supporting interventions led by developing countries. 3 Helps close the output gap by leveraging contributions from others and focusing on results, VfM and improved accountability and transparency. 4 Has a high level framework of results which can be aggregated across different countries and by different type of intervention 5 Provides an independent evaluation of results 6 Drives increased private sector investment to develop agricultural markets. II. Possible Options 31. The possible options for increasing support to agriculture to achieve the outcomes and impact are: Option 1: Maintain current levels of funding and mechanisms for delivery (country programmes, agricultural research, multilateral funding) Option 2: Support the Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP) Option 3: Support the Private Infrastructure Development Group (PIDG) Option 4: Support to Sector-Budget Support (SBS) in DFID target countries Of these, Options 2, 3 and 4 will be assessed for feasibility (with rankings of high, medium and low) to include in an appraisal to compare against the ‘maintain current levels’ (i.e. the ‘do nothing additional’) option. This is always feasible and so it is not assessed for feasibility. 32. Our criteria for exclusion are: If an option scores ‘low’ on more than one of any of these criteria (i.e. one third of criteria) then, in our judgement, the option is not feasible. This section briefly describes each option and how it contributes to impacts in the agricultural sector. Each option is then evaluated against the feasibility criteria. III. Feasibility Analysis Overall Results Table 2: Summary of Feasibility Assessment for all Funding Options Criteria GAFSP PIDG Meets Urgent Need High Low Addresses Aid Effectiveness Commitments High Low Helps Address Financing Gap by leveraging others. Medium High Has a Results Framework Low High Evaluates Results Medium High Drives private sector investment Medium High OVERALL Keep Discard Sector Budget Low Medium/High Low Medium High Low Discard Feasibility Analysis Result: options that should be assessed in an economic appraisal are: Option 1: Maintain current levels of funding and mechanisms for delivery Option 2: Financial Support to GAFSP IV. Detailed Feasibility Analysis Option 2: GAFSP i) Brief Description: 33. GAFSP is a multi-donor trust fund which provides a pool of grant funds for evidencebased, technically robust, country-led agriculture and food security projects for low income countries, including fragile states, which exhibit both significant need and clear readiness to use funds effectively. To date, seven donors have contributed and US$ 481mn has been awarded in grants to twelve countries to help finance agricultural investment plans that increase long-term food security. The World Bank provides the Coordination Unit (financial management and oversight) for the Programme. 34. GAFSP consists of a public sector window which funds developing country agricultural investment plans and a private sector window - currently undergoing reform - that is expected to increase private investment in agriculture by piloting innovative schemes to provide finance to smallholder farmers and small and medium-sized agribusinesses. Given GAFSP’s current status, immediate DFID support will focus on the Public Sector Window and the appraisal, through financing and reform options, and the management case, will set out an approach to a strengthened private sector window. 35. Most of the GAFSP allocations to date have focused on promoting growth in the agriculture sector. More than 60% of the allocations have focused on agricultural productivity growth, about 20% to linking farmers to markets and to improve market efficiency. GAFSP also supports the maintenance and increase in the assets of the poor by supporting country plans which can include interventions to improve resilience. ii) Contribution to Agricultural Impact: 36. The main impact of GAFSP on poverty reduction is through improved agricultural productivity and increased farmers’ access to markets, with a secondary focus on increasing the economic resilience of poor people. Proposals cover a range of agricultural and food security interventions such as those which improve irrigation, crop and livestock production, smallholder access to credit and inputs such as seeds and fertilisers. GAFSP targets poorer countries. Though the fund is new (2010) and there has not been evidence to date of its impact, examples of the desired results from countries which have received funding include: Sierra Leone – Reducing the gap between national rice production and demand (representing 70,000 metric tons) through: (a) increase in rice upland yields by 15%; (b) intensification of rice production on 4,000 ha of Inland Valley Swamps; (c) reduction of rice post-harvest losses by 20%; and (d) improvement in access to inputs for farmers targeted groups by 10%. Rwanda - Increased Productivity in irrigated command area ($/ha) from 1000 to 1700, increased Productivity in non-irrigated hillsides ($/ha) from 1000 to 1400 and increase the share in commercialized products in project areas (%) from 35% – 60% Nepal – 2000 women’s groups will be strengthened, enabling women to better engage in commercial agriculture. Social transfers for women and community education programme will benefit 50,000 girls and young mothers e.g. reduced levels of anaemia by 15% and increase in maternal weight during pregnancy by 50% Togo - 650,000 households raising poultry and/or small ruminants will benefit from dedicated animal vaccination campaigns. 37. The Private Sector Window leverages private capital to support traditionally ‘unbanked’ or ‘underbanked’ groups such as small holder farmers or SMEs in the agribusiness sector. This represents an important complement to the public sector financing which helps create the infrastructure and enabling environment for agriculture. Greater private sector investment brings inflows of capital, knowledge and technology which are vital for the longer term sustainability of growth in the agriculture sector and to the potential for moving farmers and their families out of poverty permanently. iii) GAFSP Feasibility Analysis: Addresses Large Scale Investment Demand and Pressing Need– HIGH 38. GAFSP is able to deliver agricultural investment promptly to meet developing country demand at the scale of need and to respond to geopolitical pressures. When the private sector window is designed effectively, it will be in the unique position to both tackle the public and private financing gaps for agriculture and exploit synergies. It currently has a funding shortfall of at least US$ 402mn and 18 country plans ready to be considered for funding. The Steering Committee will make decisions on the allocation of funds to countries in May 2012. It can begin disbursing DFID funds within 3 months of business case approval. GAFSP enables the UK to put into action its international commitments for rapidly increasing and delivering support to global agriculture. Meets Aid Effectiveness Commitments – HIGH 39. The GAFSP Public Sector Window encapsulates the aid effectiveness principles underpinning the L’Aquila commitment in its support of country-led plans for agriculture and food security and through aligning donor support with countries’ own priorities. The Comprehensive Agriculture Development Programme (CAADP), which is overseen by the African Union New Partnership for African Development, governs the process the development of agriculture and food security strategies, and also the process for submitting proposals for funding from GAFSP. It ensures empowered developing country ownership of GAFSP-funded activities. 40. Support to GAFSP provides a mechanism through which DFID, together with other donors and International Financial Institutions, can align resources behind country-led plans that are internationally endorsed, and will enable the UK to put into action its international commitments to aid effectiveness. Helps Leverage Others – MEDIUM 41. GAFSP leverages other donor assistance. Of the eight country investment plans which were allocated funds in 2010, three countries (Haiti, Niger and Togo) have received equivalent matching finance, totalling US$ 106mn, in additional contributions from international institutions and bilateral donors. It is reasonable to assume that future allocations will also attract complementary funding from other donors. 42. The Private Sector Window, managed by the IFC, could help to unlock private capital and innovative investments in agriculture, specifically targeting smallholder farmers and SMEs in the agribusiness sector. When fully operational, IFC estimates that every US$ 1mn of concessional funding provided by GAFSP, it will mobilise US$ 6-7mn of commercial funding. With both windows operational, GAFSP would score high under this criterion. Has Results Framework – LOW 43. Currently, a high-level, comprehensive and streamlined results framework does not exist. Donors have asked GAFSP to develop a common menu of results indicators for all participating Supervising Entities to use in project monitoring and evaluation frameworks. The common results indicators will assist donors in comparing the results of GAFSP investments across countries and Supervising Entities. 44. For the Private Sector Window, results tracking will be integrated in the IFC’s monitoring and evaluation system. IFC will define time bound targets upfront using standard indicators and will track progress against these continuously throughout the project’s life span. In addition, IFC will also assess each project’s overall development outcome within each of four performance components – financial, economic, environmental and social. Evaluates Results Independently - MEDIUM 45. GAFSP has put in place a strong, country-level monitoring and evaluation framework, including rigorous, in-depth impact evaluations, which will help track and quantify the results of the fund’s investments. In the initial design of GAFSP, donors agreed to set aside 2.5% of fund resources for monitoring and evaluation activities, including rigorous impact evaluations. This investment in results measurement helps donors fulfil their fiduciary obligations vis-à-vis their own citizens and will also help others learn from GAFSP investments. But while programme level evaluation is robustly included in design, there are currently no plans for an independent evaluation of GAFSP as a whole. If DFID were to fund GAFSP, we would seek a commitment to independent evaluation of its operations after two years/by end of 2013 as a condition of DFID funding. Drives private sector investment - MEDIUM 46. The Private Sector Window supports new and innovative aimed at increasing the commercial potential of small and medium size agribusinesses and farmers by connecting them to local, national and global value chains. It is managed by the IFC who predict that every $1.00 invested from public funds will be able to leverage approximately $6.00- $7.00 of private sector investment. The Private Sector Window is behind in its operationalization –it held its first call for proposals in mid-2011 and only agreed its first investment (to Pran Group, a local food producer and processor in Bangladesh) in April 2012. 47. Overall Assessment: GAFSP is a feasible option. Its low performance on the results framework is being actively addressed and DFID would make an independent evaluation a condition of any funding. It performs well on the other criteria. It is particularly attractive for helping DFID meet its international commitments and its support to the private sector in the agriculture sector. Option 3: The Private Infrastructure Development Group (PIDG) i) Brief Description: 48. PIDG aims to address market and institutional failures that constrain the private sector’s involvement in infrastructure development which fosters economic growth and reduces poverty. On agriculture, it is able to invest "social venture capital" to create commercially viable agribusiness investment opportunities, until they attract private investment from domestic and overseas investors. It focuses on sustainable agricultural and agri-processing business opportunities, strengthening of agricultural market systems and the development of agriculture-supporting infrastructure such as irrigation, feeder roads and bulk storage. PIDG scored highly in DFID’s Multilateral Aid Review (both organisational strengths and commitment to UK development objectives were rated ‘strong’). ii) Contribution to Agricultural Impact: 49. The PIDG has a good track record in targeting investments at poor and fragile states with 51 % of all projects to date in fragile states. Its funding has supported the improvement of the agriculture sector in developing countries, for example through funding a large scale irrigation project. During 2010, PIDG supported 15 projects that reached financial close, attracting $4.1 bn of private investment commitments. But the vast majority of its financing (at least 97%) is not in the agricultural sector and there are only a small number of examples of the impact it delivers on agriculture. In Zambia, InfraCo, a facility of PIDG, provided funding for a project that will support 650 smallholder families (up to 6,500 individuals) with year-round irrigation services for at least 25 years, enabling them to enhance their incomes through profitable commercial-scale farming. It will end dependence on food aid for 900 families directly benefitting from the Project (up to 9,000 individuals); and stimulate growth in the wider economy which supports 15,000 people. 50. Its generic impact statement says that it will provide smallholder farmers and local communities with: Affordable irrigation services Improved access to agricultural inputs, expertise and markets A share of profits from large-scale commercial farming activity Ability to add-value through processing and storage facilities Job creation throughout the value chain 51. PIDG does not specifically address food security or building the economic resilience of poor people. DFID’s Multilateral Aid Review recommended that PIDG should continue to target low income countries and work for maximum value for money in countrylxxvi. iii) PIDG Feasibility Analysis: Addresses Large Scale Investment Demand and Pressing Need– LOW 52. PIDG’s current support to agriculture through AgDevCo is a small part of its investment portfolio. It can help meet the private investment gap but not the public investment gap since it works exclusively through the private sector. To increase its support it will need to develop expertise, recruit more staff and put in place expanded operational procedures. This will take at least 1 year and it could be 18 months before DFID funds can begin to be effectively disbursed. But even then, it will need to significantly expand its operations to meet the need for scaling up in agricultural investment. This could take even longer. And such a shift in PIDG’s focus, and the increased dominance of DFID shareholding that would result, would, in any case, be subject to agreement and negotiation with its other funding contributors. The long and uncertain process this involves means PIDG scores low on this criterion. Meets Aid Effectiveness Commitments – LOW 53. PIDG invests in private sector led or partnered initiatives. Though this means that it can be country-led, it is not well placed to bring together multiple donors to support comprehensive agricultural development plans from a wide range of developing country governments across the world and to reduce the transaction costs of multiple donor initiatives in the agricultural sector. It therefore is not well placed to contribute to DFID’s aid effectiveness commitments for agriculture. Helps Leverage Others – HIGH 54. PIDG has catalysed $30 of private investment for each $1 of donor funding and it is anticipated that the PIDG will continue to achieve excellent value for donor money if it were to expand its work into agriculture. It is unclear whether a large additional contribution from DFID would leverage other donors but the leverage of the private sector would be significant. Has Results Framework – HIGH 55. PIDG produces post project completion reports to monitor development impacts. It also measures the number of consumers increased and additional services provided, by country. However, it does not disaggregate by level of customer or who is using new services, so it is not known if it is reaching the poorest. Evaluates Results Independently – HIGH 56. Every two years there are independent evaluations of each of the facilities of the PIDG. There is currently a strategic review of PIDG underway. An independent review of results was undertaken as part of the MAR. Drives private sector investment – HIGH 57. The PIDG is designed to leverage private finance and catalyse private investment in infrastructure and reports significant leverage rates on private sector finance of 30 to 1. Though it still has to develop its expertise in agricultural markets, it is rated high under this criterion as it is well set up to drive private investment. 58. Overall Assessment: Since two criteria are ranked low, this option is not feasible. Although a well performing vehicle that DFID already funds, its low expertise on agriculture, the length of time needed to build up its agricultural portfolio and its focus on private sector financing means that it does not contribute strongly to aid effectiveness commitments; it is poorly placed to meet demand from developing countries at scale and to quickly implement to meet pressing global needs. Option 4: Sector Budget Support (SBS) i) Brief Description: 59. The transfer of financial resources specifically targeted at a particular sector to the national treasury of a partner country. For the agriculture sector, Agriculture Ministries in recipient countries are then likely to be responsible for programming and monitoring spend. As a result, Agricultural SBS can be targeted at a country’s own agricultural goals, which obviously vary for individual countries. ii) Contribution to Agricultural Impact: 60. An ODI study of ten cases of SBS in agriculture found that they were generally “all about processes and procedures and very little about development results on the ground”lxxvii. Another review of SBS found that it provides a number of benefits to project approaches including supporting the expansion of service delivery, but primarily has procedural benefits, such as improving the efficiency of the budgeting, planning and monitoring cycle, strengthening public financial management and policy implementationlxxviii,lxxix . iii) SBS Feasibility Analysis: Addresses Large Scale Investment Demand and Pressing Need– LOW 61. This option would need to be based on DFID country-office demand for increased support for agriculture. However, the process of identifying those countries and establishing an SBS mechanism (DFID currently only provides SBS to agriculture in one country Rwanda) would be complex as DFID would need to establish what the current donor arrangements exist in country and what kind of support the national government favours. SBS also requires significant adviser input in terms of regular liaison with government ministries and programme reviews. This may require participating country offices to recruit additional expertise. Scaling up sector budget support in multiple country offices assumes that partner governments would request DFID to prioritise agriculture consistently across programmes and would require either a shift in country budget prioritisation or the provision of additional funds that would distort existing country allocations. The full implications across the DFID country office portfolio given competing needs would need to be negotiated by DFID corporately in addition to in-country. With high coordination costs and no guarantee that scale up would occur to meet large scale demand and pressing global need, this approach is not well suited to meeting this criterion. Meets Aid Effectiveness Commitments –MEDIUM/ HIGH but potentially LOW at Country Level 62. SBS support tends to be country-led and works through government systems and is therefore well placed to meet aid effectiveness commitments. The major drawback is that by restricting funding to a sector, donors distort government priorities. Agriculture may not be placed as high on the list of priorities, relative to other sectors, as increased donor financing might dictate. If this is so, either DFID funding would not be used to scale up agriculture or DFID would distort country priorities to meet its commitments to agriculture which would undermine aid effectiveness. Helps Leverage Others – LOW 63. The dialogue with government which accompanies SBS could encourage individual developing country governments to increase their budgetary allocations to the sector. Providing SBS could also encourage other donors to increase their contributions to agriculture, but it is as likely to have the opposite effect if donors perceive DFID to be the primary donor to the sector. Given the major scale up envisaged, it is unlikely that DFID will leverage significant levels of donor funding in multiple countries. Has Results Framework – MEDIUM 64. A high level framework of results would comprise the results framework which countries themselves develop as part of their agricultural strategies. Strategies may not be comparable across countries; therefore DFID would need to require that specific results were included so that results could be aggregated. This could also be time consuming and difficult. Evaluates Results Independently – HIGH 65. An independent evaluation of SBS in country would be specified as part of the funding commitment for DFID corporate reporting requirements. Drives private sector investment – LOW 66. SBS is generally focused on government action and public sector delivery and while some of that may be helpful to the private sector, there is no particular emphasis on direct facilitation of private investment and so it is assessed as low under this criterion. 67. Overall Assessment: This option is not feasible. Operationalising a major increase in sector budget support to agriculture requires that too many assumptions be satisfied with respect to country office programming and corporate processes. It is unclear whether other donors would contribute more across multiple countries. The risks and complexity under two (if not three) criteria : meeting large scale demand and leveraging others are significant giving it a low score on both and thus the option should be discarded. B. Assessing the strength of the evidence base for each feasible option Option 2 (GAFSP) Evidence rating Medium 68. The positive evidence that GAFSP will be a good vehicle for achieving development impact includes: Good value for money scores in the Multilateral Aid Review (MAR) of other Global Funds in health and education sectors - such as the education Fast Track Initiative, Global Alliance on Vaccinations and Immunization, and the Global Fund for Aids, TB and Malaria. The MAR included criteria on delivery and results. A recent evaluation of World Bank Trust Fundslxxx found that they add value as a distinct aid vehicle by providing coordinated financing and grant resources for individual countries, targeted development issues, and global public goods. [Assessment: GAFSP reinforces coordinated financing for individual countries and targets a specific sector.] 69. The negative or missing evidence includes: The use of a Global Fund to support to an economic sector where the private sector dominates but public goods investments are required to support it is unique and it is unclear how effective it can be. The recent evaluation of World Bank Trust Funds: value added of trust funds is more evident when they support global public goods than when they are used merely to supplement national development efforts. [Assessment: GAFSP supports national development efforts so does not fare well on this point.] They do not necessarily integrate well with countries’ own programs, nor do they foster coordination on the ground with other sources of aid. [Assessment: It is unclear how well GAFSP tackles in country coordination as Supervising Entities are primarily in charge of implementation rather than country governments yet are supposed to be working in concert with country plans. ] Many trust funds of global scope involve insufficient recipient participation in the design of their objectives and modalities, and lack clear outcome objectives. [Assessment: Countries are an integral part of agricultural plan development in GAFSP and participate in GAFSP’s corporate governance, although it is unclear how much true leadership and ownership they exercise vis-à-vis donors and Supervising Entities that design and implement programmes.] Improved accountability for the results of trust-funded activities is needed and needs to be integrated with World Bank management processes. [Assessment: As noted earlier, GAFSP aggregate results management and accountability need strengthening although at the individual intervention level, significant resources have been made available to support monitoring and robust evaluation.] 70. Overall: The evidence base is assessed as ‘medium’. The modality has generally proved effective but is untried in an economic sector led by the private sector. To maintain a medium rating DFID should ensure GAFSP implements a reform programme to strengthen results and accountability and ensures client governments have ownership of GAFSP governance and supervising entity programme design and implementation. What is the likely impact (positive and negative) on climate change and environment for each feasible option? 71. One of the four outputs of the programme is to improve the management of risks and resilience to shocks including those due to environmental and climate change. This will be a significant opportunity and help to develop more sustainable and climate resilient agriculture or climate smart agriculture. The Climate and Environment Assurance Note (attached as Annex 5) sets out the opportunities and risks for each of the options, and the actions required to realise opportunities and mitigate or avoid risks, and where these are covered in the programme’s logframe. The main opportunities and risks are summarised below. 72. Rising populations are producing greater pressure on agricultural land. Over the last 50 years, arable land per capita has gradually declined from 0.44 ha to less than 0.25 ha.lxxxi Increasing pressure on land is leading to greater levels of land degradation. Experts estimates that 18% of the land in Asia (1034m ha) and 16% in Africa (494m ha) was degraded by human action. The overall global proportion of degraded land was estimated at 15%. lxxxiiLater studies, using satellite based measures of vegetation cover have lxxxiiiarrived at a figure of 24% of land being degraded, with a statistically significant increasing trend of land degradation concentrated in SSA, East Asia and parts of India. This figure will take into account deforestation and bringing land into cultivation as well as land other degradation. 73. Land degradation reduces the ability of soils to hold water and nutrients, and so reduces yield. FAOlxxxiv estimated that land degradation costs South Asia $10 billion a year, or 7% of gross agricultural product. 74. Low levels of fertilizer use and soil loss, especially in Africa, are leading to the depletion of soil nutrients. On average, 39Kg of nutrients (NPK) are lost annually per hectare of cultivated landlxxxv. In some areas it can be dramatically more, for example in Rwanda the net loss per year is estimated to be 136Kg.lxxxvi 75. The development of projects that address land degradation present opportunities to improve people’s livelihoods, and reduce the impact of agriculture on the environment. This could be by the adoption of more sustainable practices that deliver increased agriculture productivity, thereby reducing pressure to convert more forests to agriculture use, and reduce siltation and pollution of rivers from soil erosion. 76. Knowledge of how to reverse land degradation and nutrient loss exists. Simple techniques such as terracing, contour ploughing and grass or hedgerow strips can have a dramatic effect. For example, hedgerow strips can reduce soil loss resulting from a single storm from 24 metric tonnes per hectare to between 5 and 0.2 metric tonnes per hectare lxxxvii. 77. But it is important to match improvements to the situation and support people through the change. Conservation Agriculture can increase yields between 20 and 75%, but in the first few years yields may go down and labour demand goes up. In some sites, conservation agriculture may not work. lxxxviii 78. Assessing the potential impact of climate change on agriculture is not precise due in part to the uncertainty in predictions from climate change and agriculture models. A systematic review for DFID found that climate change is likely to lead to a yield depression of about 8% in Africa and South Asia. But this figure masks large regional differences, with maize yield losses for Southern Africa estimated at being 27% for the 2030’s and 44% by the 2050s.lxxxixIt is therefore important that agriculture programmes consider the impact of climate change, and include measures to help farmers adapt to current and future climate risks. This is a significant opportunity that will help build the resilience of farmers and help maintain and increase their incomes. Early action is likely to be needed to reduce their risks from the increased frequency of climatic extreme events (storms, floods and droughts). xc This will include better management of water resources and more efficient and effective irrigation and implementation of soil and water conservation measures including water harvesting and small scale on-farm storage. 79. Improved agricultural practices can also help to sequester carbon. Long term trials found that conservation agriculture increased soil carbon by about 6% compared to a 7% decrease for conventional tillage.xci 80. Options 2 to 4 all have opportunities to respond to the environmental and climate challenges outlined above. Projects and programmes developed under all aim to increase productivity and to do this sustainably. Of these options GAFSP potentially provides the most opportunity for agriculture programmes, and PIDG the least given that it has a boarder focus than agriculture. Sector budget support presents the best opportunity for main streaming climate and environment issues into agriculture policies, and realising a more transformational benefit. However, by sharing lessons from GAFSP projects with national partners also presents this opportunity for improving national policies and plans. Option 1 does not present any additional climate and environment opportunities. 81. Proposals for GAFSP projects already made put an emphasis on environmental conservation and addressing the climate change challenge. The details of how they will do this will be situation specific but are expected to include soil and water conservation, and more efficient irrigation. There are also expected to be mitigation co-benefits. For example the World Bank appraisal of the Rwanda proposal makes some general estimates of the value of added carbon sequestration of US$ 1.7 million over a 50 year period. 82. The opportunities offered by this programme for enhanced soil and water conservation are large. The country project documents do not go into detailed design however, and while the importance of taking climate change into account is recognised, it will be important to ensure the design of projects support people in the early years of change, when productivity can decline, and are able to cope with future climate variability including the likely impact of more frequent severe weather. Risks 83. There are risks that projects that focus on maximising food and crop production result in practices that negatively impact on the environment. This includes the conversion of forests to agricultural use resulting in increasing GHG emissions, and loss of biodiversity. Other technologies and practices may result in environmental pollution – for example poor or incorrect use of agrochemicals. Projects involving the construction of infrastructure also have potential significant negative environmental impacts. It is therefore essential that all projects developed under any of the options are subject to environment assessments. 84. There are risks that some of the proposed investments may lead to maladaptation to future climate change. For example projects that include rural infrastructure investments and provide better access to markets for the poorest may actually encourage people to stay or move into areas that in some cases will no longer be viable for agriculture in 20-30 years time. This issue was identified by the Foresight Report on Migration and Environmental Changexcii. 82. The environmental and social safeguards of the implementing agencies will need to address these risks upfront, through project design, policy dialogue, procurement, and M&E. 83. Table 3 summarises the climate change and environmental categories for the four different options being appraised. In undertaking this appraisal options were also assessed against how well they contributed to build the resilience of people and communities, especially small holder farmers, to present and future climate risks. The categories used in this appraisal are defined as: Category A, high potential risk or high opportunity; B, medium or manageable or medium opportunity; C, low or no risk, or no opportunity; or D, core contribution to a multilateral organisation. Based on this climate and environment appraisal the preferred option would be support to GAFSP and then increased sector budget support. Table 3 Climate change and environmental categories of options Option 1. Maintain current levels of support and delivery 2. Support Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP) Climate change and environment Risks and impacts Opportunities Category Category B C B A C. What are the costs and benefits of each feasible option? 84. Based on the feasibility analysis, the economic appraisal for rapidly increasing support to agriculture becomes a comparison of GAFSP against the counterfactual of doing nothing additional. If GAFSP’s benefits exceed its costs - both quantitative and qualitative - then there is a strong case to proceed with funding. This appraisal focuses on funding the GAFSP public sector window and assumes identical returns from the private sector window once it has been strengthened. Option 1. Maintain current levels of funding and mechanisms for delivery Pros: Reduces transaction costs for DFID by not administering another funding mechanism Reduces opportunity cost for strategic priorities other than food security and frees up funds for those to be targeted. Cons: Underfunded interventions at country level which support agricultural performance and the protection of individuals’ assets thereby reduced possible impact on poverty reduction. Misses possible opportunity to leverage more support for food security from others. Lost opportunity to potentially leverage private sector investment. Risks continued underinvestment in country-led agricultural sector development plans where funding gaps already exist. Fails to meet the clear demand and urgent need for increased investment in agriculture. Signals a lack of UK commitment to support agriculture and food security. 85. Assessment: Given the urgency of the need to increase investment in sustainable agricultural development, the scale of need and the implications for poverty, the cons outweigh the pros from a poverty reduction perspective and the ‘do nothing’ option should be discarded. If we assume total net benefits of 0 (zero) for doing nothing additional, provided GAFSP produces positive net benefits then the case for funding from an economic perspective is strengthened. Option 2: (a) GAFSP Quantitative Benefits and Costs 86. Taking a traditional Cost and Benefit analysis approach to complex multilateral funding requires exhaustive quantification of benefits and costs for each individual intervention in each country, with differentiated discount rates and development of a robust method for overall aggregation. This is neither feasible, cost effective nor a recommended procedure for business cases involving multi-lateral funding. Instead, we use GAFSP analysis of outputs and the economic rates of return it calculates for its own existing project plans to build an estimated quantitative appraisal with sensitivity analysis to check its internal robustness. The appraisal is meant to provide a measure of confidence in the value of funding GAFSP but it is by no means definitive or exhaustive and should not be construed as a fully accurate derivation of the expected net benefit. 87. So far, 12 countries (6 African) have received allocations from GAFSP totalling US$ 481mn. Another 18 countries (12 African) have submitted proposals with a total cost of US$ 736 million. Although the next set of country investment plans to receive an allocation of funds are likely to be broadly comparable to those approved most recently by the Steering Committee, the detailed outputs from the country investment plans which would receive UK funding cannot be known at this stage (a call for proposals is likely in early 2012). Unit costs produced by the GAFSP Coordinating Unit have therefore been used to calculate indicative outputs for the next 12 countries to receive funding and the proportion of these results that could be attributed to DFID funding. (See Intervention Summary). 88. Since the specific outputs DFID would be funding are unknown, the economic rates of return associated with these outputs are also unknown. For this reason we have used conservative rates of return based on GAFSP analysis to guide the appraisal. a) Quantitative Benefits 89. GAFSP results are produced in four distinct types of intervention. Table 4 shows each intervention type, its share of total current GAFSP programme funding and its corresponding economic rate of return. In the first two cases, the figures come from GAFSP’s own technical analysis using World Bank data to calculate economic rates of return for some current country investment programmes in the particular intervention types for which we have taken simple averages. The income streams these benefits relate to are, on agricultural productivity, higher production yields and from agricultural market development, increased profitability. Economic rates of return are therefore based on private returns due to increases in income for individual farms. Form illustrative purposes only, estimates for rates of return of Nutrition/ Social Protection investments are taken from academic papers. Since GAFSP has not calculated them in existing interventions, they are not used in the subsequent analysis.xciii Table 4. Increased Agricultural productivity Agricultural Market Development Share of Total GAFSP Prog. 69% 22% Annual Rate of Return Estimate 25.2% 24.5% Social Protection Nutrition Enhancement 1.0% 1.0% 60% 1060% Assumptions: 90. To construct a conservative appraisal we assume that GAFSP public and private windows together have an economic rate of return equal to the lowest rate of return of a GAFSP intervention which is 24.5%. We also assume DFID is providing a £50mn contribution in two instalments: £13mn to the public sector window in mid-2012 and £37mn in mid-2013, that DFID funding starts to accrue full benefits in 2014 (2 years after the first transfer) and that benefits accrue equally on a yearly basis over 9 years. Although we believe that the transformational impact of private sector window funding could increase returns above those obtained from the public sector window, in the absence of evidence, we take a conservative assumption that the economic rates of return between public and private windows are the same. Assuming a conservative, high discount rate of 10% to reflect the pressing need to quickly meet large scale need and geopolitical pressures, the annual net benefit of a £50mn contribution with these benefit characteristics is £31.9mn. b) Quantitative Costs 91. The rate of return calculations above already include the direct and indirect costs of funded projects. To obtain the effective rate of return we also need to subtract the cost of GAFSP administration, both of administering the Fund itself and of the supervising entities managing GAFSP funds. We also need to integrate DFID administrative costs for managing our GAFSP contribution. i) DFID costs: We assume this cost to be equal to 1.0 Full Time Equivalent cost at advisory (A1) level per year for 2 years at a daily rate of £386 for 220 days per year. We estimate the administrative cost to be: £85,000 per year of managing DFID’s contribution. Ii) Internal Admin Costs: GAFSP reports its administrative costs to be 0.85% for internal administration and 5% for supervising entity administration both as a percentage of total funding. Together GAFSP’s total administrative costs are 5.85% of total funding. 92. Putting DFID and GAFSP costs together for DFID’s £50mn contribution, total costs come to £3.01mn per year. c) Net Benefits 93. To construct net benefits we assume a net benefits stream with the characteristics set out in the assumptions and subtract from this stream annual administrative costs, starting from the moment that the first DFID instalment is transferred in Year 0 (2012). 94. This produces Estimated Total Net Benefits of DFID’s £50mn contribution to GAFSP funding of £11.23mn, an effective rate of return of 15.4%. This is a lower total rate of return than the WB’s own estimate of 20% aggregate rate of return for GAFSP. d) Sensitivity Analysis. 95. All the figures in the analysis above are rough standard estimates, not a rigorous derivation based on future GAFSP programmes with independent verification of robustness. There are two other important limitations to the methodology to highlightxciv: (i) Some costs have not been counted in the World Bank’s economic rate of return methodology. In particular, we noted that an increased use of carbon and its negative externalities did not feature in their cost calculations. (ii) The assumption that the profile of net benefits accrual is constant is a major simplification. It is more likely that benefits increase rapidly in the first few years, maximize midway through the 9 year cycle and then reduce and persist beyond the 9 year period. 96. The second limitation is less of a worry as it suggests that we may have understated the benefits which would not change our decision to proceed with funding. To deal with the first concern, which could lead us to fund when the true costs outweigh the benefits, we construct two simple sensitivity analysis tests and combine them in a third test: (i) Increase administrative costs by 50% to 9% of total funding to capture costs that are not captured in the Bank’s economic rate of return methodology. (ii) Increase the discount rate to 12% which is the World Bank’s discount rate for the poorest countries. This makes the analysis even more conservative as it assumes only the poorest countries receive GAFSP funding. Test 1 Net Benefits: £3.18mn Test 2 Net Benefits: £7.25mn Combined Test Net Benefits: - £ 0.80mn 97. When combining both factors to make the appraisal more conservative, the net benefits become slightly negative. Break even analysis indicates that at a 10% discount rate, increasing total costs by up to 68% still produces a positive net benefit. At a 12% discount rate this increased cost figure is 44%. This analysis and its conservative parameters gives a measure of confidence that, from a purely quantitative perspective, the economic case in favour of funding GAFSP is sound. It also puts focus on three issues DFID should monitor and engage on to ensure net benefits remain positive: i. Costs need to be kept under control and, where feasible, efficiency of operations improved. ii. Disbursements by GAFSP and implementation by the supervising entity need to be timely. If benefits fail to accrue 2 years after DFID’s initial contribution, net benefits quickly become negative. iii. To strengthen value for money, given the process of strengthening the private sector window, DFID should tranche its contributions, both to enhance the net benefits stream and to ensure the instrument is performing well before the funds are disbursed. All of these issues have been included in the priority reforms and/or management case in the analysis below. Usefulness and Limitations 98. The analysis above provides a reasonable estimate of the net benefits of funding GAFSP because it: I. Is built on a lower rate of return than GAFSP’s own estimate of the programme’s aggregated rate of return (20% versus 15.4%). II. Significantly increases costs and the discount rate well above those expected yet still reports positive net benefits. III. Assumes a conservative 2 year lag between DFID funding disbursement and the start of accrual of benefits. The actual lag may be half of this thus strengthening the results. IV. Assumes a conservative 10% social discount rate. 99. But this appraisal should not be considered a definitive statement of Net Benefits because it does not thoroughly or accurately aggregate the rates of return of all existing GAFSP programmes nor differentiates between public and private window rates of return (the latter are not yet available). 6 public window projects from 3 countries (Togo, Bangladesh and Ethiopia) have been used to give an indication of the expected rate of return. The programmes chosen are of the same type as 91% of the GAFSP portfolio but they cannot be said to be fully representative of the GAFSP programme. 100. The rates of return calculated by the Bank have their own methodological limitations as set out in para 91. In fact, an aggregate cost benefit analysis of any complex multilateral funding cannot be accurate without a significant resource investment to properly measure benefits and costs accrual and aggregate and benchmark effective rates of return. The present analysis serves to increase confidence on the basis of reasonable assumptions and evidence without providing a definitive and accurate calculation. Option 2: (b) Qualitative Benefits and Costs 101. While the estimated analysis suggests strongly that GAFSP will achieve net benefits in quantitative terms, it is important to consider qualitative costs and benefits to provide an overall picture of total net positive value: Qualitative Benefits: Promotes ownership: supports country-led plans and investment gaps identified by individual countries. Addresses high level political commitments for support to agriculture, builds political capital for DFID. Generates UK influence over larger resource flows and recipient government plans. High poverty impact: intervention areas of agriculture and nutrition are highly effective in reducing poverty in comparison with growth in other sectors and other kinds of interventionxcv. Also supports enabling environment improvements that cannot be easily quantified and that can have further knock-on benefits on the overall quality of governance. Channelling multiple sources of donor financing through a common mechanism can reduce fragmentation at the country level and recipient country transaction costs. Qualitative Costs: lacks a track record: risk that fund fails to perform as expected. Creates further "verticalisation" of Multilateral Aid and compartmentalisation of overall global aid resources. Current aggregation of results is partial and not used for accountability. DFID has estimated the impact it is buying – but there is currently no commitment from GAFSP to be held accountable for a comprehensive set of results that UK funds will buy. DFID cannot determine where funds are allocated except through influencing GAFSP processes, which could mean lower DFID priority countries get funded. Difficulty in divesting once invested: once invested in GAFSP, which has high political backing, it will be difficult to remove DFID support without a political cost. Qualitative Costs and benefits generally balance each other out because: Increased compartmentalisation of aid at the global level is balanced by the reduced fragmentation at the country level. The difficulty in divesting is balanced by the political capital gained in an important, poverty-focused sector and in a major funding instrument. The lack of flexibility in use of funds is set against the gain in influence for a large and politically important funding vehicle. 102. And there is scope for benefits to exceed costs. Enabling environment benefits can be substantial if they lead to systemic improvements for agricultural sectors as a whole that all beneficiaries benefit from while the risks to fund performance and the weak results framework can be addressed by the reform and funding options set out below. 103. There is a strong likelihood that qualitative benefits will exceed qualitative costs, provided that risks to fund performance are addressed. Therefore in sum, combining the qualitative and quantitative appraisals, DFID can have a sufficient level of confidence that a contribution to GAFSP will produce positive net benefits. Overall Recommendation: 104. Based on this appraisal, the ‘do nothing additional’ option should be discarded and DFID should proceed to make a funding contribution to GAFSP. But it should consider reform, financing and engagement options to reduce the risks to DFID’s investment, maximize its impact and safeguard positive net benefits. 4. Feasible Reform, Financing and Engagement Options for GAFSP Funding 105. Reform Options: 1. Implement proposed reforms of Private Sector Window (PSW): Reforms currently proposed to improve coherence with public sector window, deliver tangible results and ensure additionality of its financing. 2. Strengthen Results Framework: currently GAFSP only partially aggregates results. In common with other multilaterals, it could strengthen its results framework to improve its delivery and accountability. 3. Strengthen Cost Consciousness: Make cost effectiveness criteria a core part of its internal operations and approval mechanisms and use these to incentivise improved cost consciousness from its supervising entities. This is important to safeguard value for money (see assessment below) and safeguard the net benefits in the economic appraisal. 4. Speed of Disbursement: Project design and appraisal take time but sequencing of due process could be improved to increase the pace of delivery and implementation and ensure positive net benefits from a DFID perspective. 5. Improve Gender Disaggregation: Many GAFSP indicators are gender-blind. Improving disaggregation would be an important step to better address the different roles that men and women play in agricultural sectors. 6. Implement a streamlined evaluation into operations: Include as part of its operational procedures a built in evaluation process every two years from the start of new GAFSP programmes and for GAFSP as a whole. 7. Ensure appraisal investment plans place greater weight on resilience to climate change and to delivering improvements in nutrition as part of the results framework. 106. Prioritising Criteria: We have considered these reforms and their importance and urgency in terms of: i) the contribution to DFID corporate priorities (value for money, impact, results, evidence, fragility, gender, private sector); ii) the extent of buy-in from other GAFSP donors and therefore the likelihood of achievement; iii) the extent to which they improve delivery in country. 107. Recommendation: Using the prioritising criteria above, DFID should focus its initial reform ‘ask’ on three ‘one off’ reforms: Improving efficacy of the Private Sector Window’s operation. Baseline: the issues which we believe need to be addressed in order for this to be achieved are described in detail in the Management Case, p.60/61, paras. 42 and 43. An assessment of progress on these issues will be made as the basis for a decision on whether or not to provide £37mn for the Private Sector Window. Our working assumption is that this assessment will be carried out 12 months after DFID takes up a seat on the Steering Committee and linked to our funding disbursement (see recommended approach below). Creation of a high-level, aggregated Results Framework Baseline: no aggregated RF exists to date. This should include either DFID or World Bank core indicators and should be reflected in individual funding proposals. Our working assumption is that such an aggregated RF will be completed within 12 months of DFID taking up a seat on the Steering Committee. Improving speed of disbursement and strengthening management. Baseline: the Coordination Unit has indicated that this has been taking up to 12 months from the point at which funds are allocated through the Public Sector Window to the point at which funds are transferred to the Supervising Entity. Our target is to have this reduced to 6 months within 12 months of DFID taking up a seat on the Steering Committee. Our corporate relationship with the Bank is stipulating that we push the Bank to be more pro-active in solving problems faced by staff managing Trust Fund programmes. We will monitor this and strive for full compliance with DFID corporate positions as they relate to GAFSP. 108. In addition, in keeping with DFID’s strong corporate reform agenda with World Bank Trust Funds, DFID officials should work on an ongoing basis to ensure a continual improvement in: Cost consciousness of GAFSP operations across the board, especially in negotiating competitive trust fund management fees charged by the Bank; Gender disaggregation of data. Attention to climate change and nutrition as aspects of food security. Strengthening the processes for filling staffing gaps. Ensuring the Bank fulfils appropriate roles that avoid conflict of interest (eg Supervising Entity, Trustee and Coordination Unit) in management and delivery and makes use of private sector expertise to take over responsibility for key functions if and where appropriate 109. Since reforms score highly for DFID corporate objectives, additional funding should be considered to motivate these reforms (see financing options below). b. Financial Options: 110. What is a fair contribution from DFID? A fair DFID contribution to GAFSP needs to consider: 1. The scale of need for agriculture: to meet the scale of need for funding, which is in the billions of pounds, even with significant leveraging of funding from others, and a fair burden share to the scale of need, a DFID contribution would need to be substantial (at least in the tens of millions). The burden share for the UK of a multilateral fund: UK provides roughly 10% of global ODA. Currently, $570mn has been received by or firmly committed to GAFSP. This figure will shortly increase by Eu10mn from the Dutch and $25mn from the US. This will raise total receipts to $733mn (assuming 1 EUR = US$1.38). 10% of this total would mean a DFID contribution of $73.3mn or £47mn (assuming £1 = US$1.55). A figure of £50mn is therefore just over 10% - lower than historical comparators including the education Fast Track Initiative (21%) and the Global Alliance for Vaccinations and Immunizations (33%); much closer to the UK burden share of IDA (12%) and broadly equivalent to GFATM (10%). 2. The leverage capacity of our funding: Leverage potential of our GAFSP contribution is uncertain for the Public Sector Window. Our contribution may spur additional investment from other donors but at a scale likely commensurate with our funding levels. In contrast, the Private Sector Window has the potential to leverage a significant amount of additional funding from private investment –estimated at a ratio of £6-7 for each £1 of DFID contribution. It also provides an important complement to public funding to ensure sustainability and broader ownership of agricultural investments. Recommended Funding Option and Approach: 111. Bringing all of these considerations together along with the reform options in the previous section, the proposed approach is to approve funding to GAFSP for up to £50mn (~US $80mn) representing approximately a 10% burden share over two financial years, 2012/13 – 2013/14 as follows: i) Provide £13mn (~US$20mn) to the GAFSP Public Sector Window in 2012/13 to help meet the scale of need for public investment and possibly incentivise additional donor funding. ii) Approve an additional £37mn (~US$60mn) which will be disbursed to the Private Sector Window in two equal tranches of £18.5mn in early 2013/14 and the second before the end of the 2013/14 financial year. This will complement our Public Sector Window funding, critically leverage significant additional resources from the private sector to meet the global financing gap and make our total contribution more commensurate with the scale of need. 112. Our reform options will be integrated into our funding approach. We will make final disbursement of the second year of funding (£37mn) contingent on progress on our priority reform objectives (see para. 103 above) being achieved. As stated in the previous section other priority reforms will be pursued as part of our role in GAFSP’s governance. This means that our engagement approach with GAFSP will involve pursuing reform, lobbying others and influencing effectively to see them through. The management implications of this recommendation are set out in the Management Case below. Overall Summary of Selected Option: 113. The appraisal and options analysis leads to the recommendation to fund GAFSP with a total contribution of £50mn to signal that DFID ambition matches the scale of need. £13mn will be provided to the Public Sector Window to meet core commitments and our fair burden share of total GAFSP pledges. £37mn will be designated to the Private Sector Window subject to completion of reforms and a satisfactory supplementary DFID assessment. D. What measures can be used to assess Value for Money (VfM) for the intervention? 114. The Technical Committee does take VfM considerations into account in approving country led proposals. The metrics that the TAC will use and that will be used to track programme success will be the main criteria for tracking VfM. If we secure funding and a seat on the Steering Committee we would expect to insist on continued revisions to this framework and to an overarching VfM framework that monitors results, costs etc (see Management Case below). 115. Key summary points: Strategic fit - GAFSP supports the delivery of MDG1 and UK’s commitment to poverty reduction. GAFSP prioritises countries which have a greater level and depth of poverty. The average poverty headcount and poverty gap of the 12 financed countries is 47.3% and 17.9% respectively, compared to 40.6% and 15.6% for all GAFSP eligible countries. Within countries it favours public investment in poorer areas or in high potential areas most likely to contribute to growth. UK priorities - GAFSP ‘private sector window’ fits with UK strategic priorities of generating private sector led solutions to agricultural challenge although the functioning of the window needs to be properly established going forward. Geographic fit – GAFSP can support any eligible country but over 60% of approved funding is for African countries Partnership - GAFSP is having a catalytic effect in encouraging countries to develop comprehensive plans, with agreed results defined by country need. Management - Decision making for funding is made by consensus of all GAFSP board members supporting by technical advice. Financial management – GAFSP is committed to project implementation less than a year after approval of grants Transparency – GAFSP routinely publishes project documentation. However, it is less clear how it promotes transparency amongst partners and recipient countries Cross cutting issues – Some of the GAFSP proposals are from fragile states (e.g. Sierra Leone); whilst others focus (e.g. Bangladesh) aim to increase resilience of farmers against increased risk of flooding resulting from climate change. Scope for reform – Though it is too early to tell whether the governing body will strive for continual reforms to GAFSP, membership would allow the UK to influence the direction of any reform agenda. Cost Control – see below 116. There are two aspects that are at the core of the VfM assessment of GAFSP: i) the cost consciousness of its internal administration and ii) the VfM and cost consciousness of the Supervising Entities that implement GAFSP projects. We use the robust, evidence-based Multilateral Aid Review (MAR) process as the evidence and methodology for the latter. For the former there are pros and cons in terms of VfM. Pros: Aid is allocated in a transparent and predictable way using GAFSP internal assessment procedures. GAFSP administration costs are low and the Steering Committee (of which DFID would be a part) has the power to keep costs under control. The appraisal process for evaluating investment plans typically considers the proposed design against alternatives (potentially of lower cost). For some types of investments the economic assessment will include a cost-effectiveness analysis or a calculation of economic rates of return. Cons: GAFSP does not challenge or support partners to think about VfM. The Technical Assistance Committee does not prioritise cost effectiveness in decision-making. A Meta-MAR Assessment of GAFSP Supervising Entities 117. Most Supervising Entities – which countries select themselves – have had full MAR assessments. 98.6% of GAFSP funding to-date is managed by entities that have been rated good or very good value for money overall: World Bank (54.2% of GAFSP funds), AfDB (16.5%), IFAD (14.6%), AsDB (8.1%), IDB (5.2%) and IFC. This list does not include FAO and WFP which are Supervising Entities that provide technical support only and do not manage GAFSP funds. 118. These institutions have the following scores on cost consciousness in the MAR assessment: The World Bank (satisfactory), AfDB (satisfactory), IFAD (weak), AsDB (satisfactory), IDB (satisfactory). 84% of GAFSP funds are implemented by Supervising Entities with satisfactory cost consciousness. 119. VfM performance by Supervising Entities is good. Increased funding to IFAD relative to other MDBs could worsen this score in the absence of IFAD reforms. Since this assessment is based solely on the formal MAR process, the evidence underpinning it is judged to be strong. 120. Overall we anticipate that the GAFSP has the potential to offer good VfM. But there are also concerns about how well the GAFSP will focus on cost effectiveness in the choice and stewardship of interventions. More broadly some of the features of the GAFSP are very similar to features of the Fast Track Initiative (FTI) / Global Partnership for Education (GPE) which historically have led to weak performance management. In particular that it has been difficult to hold supervising entities to account and in particular that it has been hard for the World Bank as implementing agency to be held to account by the Secretariat. In this regard it will be very important for the GAFSP Steering Committee to require all implementers to sign up to high performance standards, including delivery and speed of grant signing and first disbursement. These issues have taken some time to sort in the FTI/GPE. 121. There has also been work in the context of FTI/GPE to make sure that the secretariat is fully accountable to the governing structures and not to the parent institution (in this case the World Bank). In general, in Global Funds it has also been very difficult to balance a challenge fund model with sufficient visibility for sound planning and budgeting by partner countries. In both the FTI/GPE and GFATM the full challenge fund model is in the process of being diluted and countries are being given ex-ante planning scenarios based on a resource allocation model. We are confident that GAFSP is seeking to learn lessons from the GPE/FTI process but we will need to push hard on these and keep them under review (see reform agenda). 122. This assessment of GAFSP has not gone through rigorous peer review like most multilateral agencies and is based primarily on documentary evidence provided by the World Bank. But it has followed the MAR methodology and core questions. The evidence underpinning this assessment is moderate. E. Summary Value for Money Statement for the preferred option 123. GAFSP’s own internal cost control can be considered satisfactory: administrative costs are low and can be controlled by the Steering Committee while cost issues are assessed in programme appraisals. 124. The procedures of Supervising Entities make up the bulk of GAFSP administrative costs so their good or very good value for money on the MAR applies to the bulk of GAFSP’s own value for money. 125. Performance would strengthen if GAFSP actively encouraged increased cost consciousness on the part of its Supervising Entities and government partners, made cost issues a stronger part of its assessment procedures, and ensured increased relative funding to IFAD vis-à-vis other multilaterals is contingent on improved cost consciousness. 126. Overall: Satisfactory GAFSP internal value for money performance and good value for money ratings for Supervising Entities on the MAR means that we can expect GAFSP to provide good value for money. The evidence underlying this assessment is rated as moderately strong. Lesson learning from the MAR is important to help shape our engagement with the GAFSP Steering Committee and gives us confidence that going forward we will be able to keep pushing for overall VfM in the way funds are allocated, programmed and stewarded by GAFSP. Commercial Case: Direct procurement A. Clearly state the procurement/commercial requirements for intervention 1. DFID will not undertake any direct procurement in relation to this intervention. Once investment or Technical Assistance proposals are approved by the Steering Committee and funds are transferred, the procurement procedures of the specific supervising entity in receipt of the GAFSP funds will apply. B. How does the intervention design use competition to drive commercial advantage for DFID? Not applicable C. How do we expect the market place will respond to this opportunity? Not applicable D. What are the key cost elements that affect overall price? How is value added and how will we measure and improve this? Not applicable E. What is the intended Procurement Process to support contract award? Not applicable F. How will contract & supplier performance be managed through the life of the intervention? Not applicable Indirect procurement A. Why is the proposed funding mechanism/form of arrangement the right one for this intervention, with this development partner? 2. The funding mechanism chosen is Administrative Arrangements with accompanying governance documents – one with the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) for the Public Sector Window and one with the International Finance Corporation (IFC) for the Private Sector window. Such administration arrangements are the usual mechanism when providing funding to World Bank trust funds. Whilst the governance document contains standard provisions common to all donors, the administration arrangements can be varied to suit DFID’s own particular requirements such as ensuring that the language is appropriate and that paragraphs on e.g. corruption and fraud are included. B. Value for money through procurement 3. The alternative to providing funds to GAFSP would be to contract the technical assistance and pay for the costs of programme directly. This would present a complex and challenging administrative burden on DFID - one that could not easily be managed with the existing work loads of staff. This would also impede the realisation of reduced rural poverty as measured by increased rural incomes. DFID has considerable experience of funding through the World Bank and has confidence in their systems and controls as exemplified by their overall ‘very strong’ rating and their satisfactory assessment for ‘Organisational Strengths’ in the Multilateral Aid Review. Financial Case A. What are the costs, how are they profiled and how will you ensure accurate forecasting? 1. DFID will provide £50mn funding to GAFSP over two financial years, from May 2012 to 31 December 2013. This allocation has been approved by the Policy Division Director. Expenditure will not extend beyond the current spending round unless a further allocation of funding is justified based on delivery of results and proven value for money. 2. As this intervention is above £40mn, it has been formally reviewed by the Quality Assurance Unit and shared with HMT. This Business Case has been copied to the Policy Division Accountant who worked with Management Accounts to secure HMT approval. 3. Total Costs of the Public Sector Window investment are as follows: £13mn investment of which 2.5% will be set aside for monitoring and evaluation activities. £170,000 staff costs of managing DFID engagement over two years. 5% supervising entity programme management costs and 0.85% Trust Fund management costs which give £0.761mn of administration fees for a £13mn investment. These fee rates are set by broader World Bank policy on full cost recovery for the operation of Trust Funds but can be further reduced and negotiated for large Trust Funds like GAFSP provided DFID can obtain support of other donors. Total costs: £13.931mn Total (estimated) Costs of the Private Sector Window investment are as follows: £37mn investment of which some amount will be set aside for monitoring and evaluation activities. Staff costs of managing DFID engagement over two years included in the public sector window calculation above and not double counted here. Assuming the same fee rates of 5% supervising entity programme management costs and 0.85% Trust Fund management costs gives £2.165mn of administration fees for a £37mn investment. Total costs: £39.165mn 4. These figures will be updated for the Private Sector Window when more information on cost recovery is available to trigger a subsequent release of the additional £37mn in funds. B. How will it be funded: capital/programme/admin? 5. As the beneficiaries of the intervention are DFID partner countries this is programme expenditure. C. How will funds be paid out? 6. The total budget allocated for GAFSP is £50,000,000 and is provisionally projected to be disbursed as follows: 2012/13 – £ 13,000,000 to the Public Sector Window – by end of July 2012. 2013/14 – £ appraisal: 37,000,000 to the Private Sector Window subject to reforms and further DFID £18.5mn by end of July 2013 £18.5mn by end of December 2013 The funding contribution to the GAFSP Public Sector Window will be made through an Administration Arrangement and accompanying governance document between DFID and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, who act as the Trustee. 7. The funding to the GAFSP Private Sector Window, if approved following an assessment of progress with reforms, will be made by means of an Administration Arrangement and accompanying governance document with the International Finance Corporation (IFC). The wording of these Arrangements will be cleared with Accounts Department and Finance and Corporate Performance Department. The first payment of £60m will be made on signature of the first Administration Arrangement with the stipulation that the funds will be allocated through the early 2012 Public Sector Funding window within six months of receipt of the contribution. The payment in 2012/13 will be made to the Private Sector window. D. What is the assessment of financial risk and fraud? 8. The Administration Agreements with the World Bank and with IFC (the latter required if and when funds are provided to the Private Sector Window) will contain a paragraph to ensure that DFID is made aware immediately of any suspicion of the misappropriation or diversion of funds or possible fraud or corruption relating to the activities being funded. 9. GAFSP funds disbursed to the country level are managed and accounted for by the Supervising Entities (see Management Case). DFID’s Multilateral Aid Review (MAR) looked at how these multilateral organisations allocate, disburse and account for their resources. Scores were high for those who, among other things, showed clear and transparent resource allocation decisions, strong policies and processes for financial accountability and oversight, and a pro-active approach to managing poorly performing projects. All but one (FAO) of the GAFSP Supervising Entities were assessed as ‘satisfactory’ or ‘strong’ on financial resource management in the MAR. 10. It is worth noting that World Food Programme (WFP), an important GAFSP partner providing technical assistance to recipient governments, is the first UN organisation to implement International Public Sector Accounting Standards, against which it has now achieved two unqualified annual audits. WFP has zero tolerance of fraud, corruption or collusive practices. Whistleblower policies give staff protection from retaliation against reporting financial irregularities and where irregularities are identified WFP always takes disciplinary or legal action. 11. The following assessments of the financial and administrative capacities of the proposed Supervising Entities below are drawn from DFID’s own assessments. The main source is the Multilateral Aid Review, which can be found here. Asia Development Bank (AsDB) (drawn from DFID’s engagement strategy paper) The bank has a strong results culture and robust evaluation mechanisms, but there has been concern over the quality of some projects. Although financial management is good, the Bank is highly centralised and can be slow to respond, and country offices do not feel empowered to make decisions without a mission from HQ. This has been changing over the last 10 years. The bank now has 23 resident missions covering 80% of developing member countries, with 21 leading on country partnership strategies. AsDB has also piloted new approaches to decentralisation, such as the “Joint Venture” working operating in Pakistan. This allows direct links between professional advisers in RMs and headquarters, with responsibility for sector programmes assigned to sector teams. The UK has a 2% stake in the Banks and so has limited ability to influence decisions. African Development Bank The procedures in the bank are rated as satisfactory, with strong cost control, and robust evaluation policies. For the fund that DFID assessed under the MAR (the African Development Fund) disbursement was slow with only 60% of funds disbursed on time. Inter American Development Bank Results from the MAR in the area of financial and administrative efficiency and results management noted that the Bank, as on the whole, satisfactory (3 out of 4). There are strong evaluation procedures. Financial procedures are robust, although highly centralised. Money is disbursed on time. New procedures to combat fraud were put in place at the end of 2010. International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) IFAD was rated to have satisfactory results and evaluation procedures, although it could do more to focus on sustainability. It’s financial management and cost control were rated as weak, with relatively high overhead costs. Its financial system is slow in disbursing money. The MAR also assessed that the ability of IFAD to sustain reform was uncertain, given that it had a new management team and immediate reform goals had been achieved. Food and Agriculture Organisation The MAR noted that while much needed reform was underway, there was much to do. Overall the agency was rated as weak. Country offices’ capacity was very variable, power was centralised and processes not transparent. Financial procedures were slow and there was insufficient attention to value for money. The scale of reform needed and that reform will depend very much on the new Director, due to take office in 2012. FAO is restricted to providing technical co-operation only under the GAFSP. World Food Programme WFP is a satisfactory performer, with improving evaluation standards. It has measured performance against its strategic results framework since 2009 and has clear financial procedures. It is a cost conscious organisation. The area marked for improvement was in transparency, where it was felt its standard project report could do more to illustrate project performance. WFP is restricted to providing technical co-operation only under the GAFSP. World Bank The World Bank is rated as a strong organisation, with particularly strong technical knowledge and ability. It’s financial and management systems are robust. International Finance Corporation The IFC has a strong record of effectiveness, with 74% of its investments scoring satisfactory or better. For SSA the figure is lower at 58%, but is improving from the average score of 40% achieved in the last decade. The capacity of its advisory services is also rated highly in 70% of its interventions. It is progressively moving more staff to the field with 54% now based in recipient countries. It rates as satisfactory or better for financial management, cost consciousness and performance. A strong evaluation system is in place. It is weakest in working with others. While it is a leader in developing ways to measure impact, its country collaboration and work with other parts of the World Bank is patchy. E. How will expenditure be monitored, reported, and accounted for? 12. The design of GAFSP stipulates that once investment or Technical Assistance proposals are approved by the Steering Committee, the preparation and implementation – including Monitoring and Evaluation of GAFSP projects will follow the guidelines of the respective Supervising Entity. Upon the transfer of funds, fiduciary responsibilities and legal liability will be transferred from the Trustee to the Supervising Entity. Agreements between the Trustee and the Supervising Entities set out the streamlined financial reporting requirements to the Trustee and outline accountability requirements to the Trustee regarding financial transactions (such as cancellations of approved amounts, financial closures and unutilised funds if any). 13. The rules, guidelines, policies, procedures for procurement, financial management, safeguards and supervision of the specific Supervising Entity in receipt of the GAFSP funds will apply. Accountability for the proper handling and the use of funds will thus be between the Supervising Entity receiving the funds and the Steering Committee. To allow consolidated reporting to the donors and the Steering Committee, for the Public Sector and Private Sector Windows Supervising Entities will submit annual implementation results reports on the use of the GAFSP funding to the Steering Committee through the Coordination Unit, and periodic financial reports (including an annual audited financial statement) to the Steering Committee through the Trustee. 14. Contributions to GAFSP and allocations to countries are easily tracked through GAFSP, helping to reinforce donor accountability and transparency e.g. using the World Bank Trust Funds Directory and the World Bank Client Connection Website which allows easy access to programme and financial information. Management Case A. What are the Management Arrangements for implementing the intervention? 1. GAFSP was established in April 2010 at the request of the G20 to provide a mechanism for channelling more and better public and private investment, including funds pledged at the G8 Summit at L’Aquila in 2009, into agriculture and related sectors to improve incomes and food security of poor people in low income countries. 2. Since the launch of GAFSP in April 2010, the Steering Committee has made funding decisions worth US$ 481mn and approved key governance mechanism such as the Governance Document, the Monitoring and Evaluation Plan, selection criteria for financing, and administrative budgets. 3. The current focus of management activity is on: (i) implementation of the 12 country plans already approved for GAFSP financing, (ii) incorporating lessons learned into revised protocols; (iii) resource mobilisation to meet the high demand for GAFSP financing and the launch of the next Call for Proposals before the end of 2011; (iv) establishing baseline data for the project Monitoring & Evaluation; and (v) operationalising the Private Sector Window. 4. GAFSP has an end date, for World Bank Trustee administrative purposes only of 2019. GAFSP Management Structures 5. The overall governance architecture for GAFSP was set out in a Framework Document, prepared by a Task Team comprising members of a number of different World Bank Departments, representatives from IFAD, FAO and WFP, and the governments of the US, Canada and Spain. The Framework document sets out: the Objectives and value added of the programme; the scope of the programme; eligibility for the public and private sector windows; the main elements of governance and accountability – through the Steering Committee, Technical Advisory Committee (TAC), Supervising Entities (SEs), Coordination Unit, and Trustee. trust fund operations; and procedures for preparing and submitting proposals, implementation of those which are approved and reporting of results. Governance 6. GAFSP operates as a Financial Intermediary Fund for which the World Bank serves as Trustee. Its governance is intended to be simple and flexible and to allow for evolution as lessons are learned and needs evolve. The decision making body of GAFSP is an external Steering Committee. The Committee is advised by an independent external Technical Advisory Committee and supported by a small Coordination Unit in the World Bank’s Agriculture and Rural Development Department and a team in the IFC for the Private Sector Window. 7. The World Bank plays three roles in the governance of GAFSP i) Trustee, ii) Coordination Unit and iii) potential Supervising Entity for GAFSP financed projects. I. In its capacity as Trustee, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, holds funds in trust, as the legal owner, and administers the funds received from each donor, in accordance with the terms of the Administrative Agreement entered into with each donor. It is accountable to the Steering Committee for the performance of its fiduciary responsibilities as set out in the Trust Fund Administrative Agreements. The Trustee remits project funds to the Supervising Entities, receives financial reports from them, provides financial reports to the Steering Committee and arranges for annual audit of the Trust Fund. II. The Coordination Unit in the World Bank provides support to the GAFSP Steering Committee and the TAC. It receives investment and technical assistance proposals from Ministries of Finance in developing countries or from Regional Organisations and submits these to the Steering Committee. It organises ‘Calls for Proposals’, liaises with the Trustee on the allocation of funds and provides an aggregate annual implementation results report based on the results reports submitted by each supervising entity. It has no role in evaluating or making recommendations to i) the TAC with respect to any of the proposals it receives from countries and regional organisations; ii) the Steering Committee with respect to the annual investment plans it receives from the IFC. III. Supervising Entities provide technical expertise and management/financial supervision of for the preparation and implementation of GAFSP proposals. The World Bank only acts as Supervising Entity if requested to do so by the developing country government concerned and if their selection is approved by the Steering Committee. 8. The multiple roles of the Bank represent a potential conflict of interest that could affect Fund performance. This is dealt with as Risk 9 in the risk management section below. 9. The Steering Committee awards investment funds to countries whose investment plan has been approved. The Steering committee consists of an equal number of donor and recipient countries as voting members, and representatives from organisations that will supervise projects in country and NGOs as non voting members. The voting members are: one representative each from the five original contributing membersxcvi, and five regional representatives from recipient countries, as nominated by the Executive Directors of the Bank from IDA countries. The voting members may decide to grant voting rights to future contributors, but the voting members will remain balanced between recipient countries and contributors. It is expected that the UK will be invited to become a voting member. The Chair of the Steering Committee, currently the US, is elected by the voting members and serves for one year, subject to renewal. 10. The Steering Committee makes decisions on proposals by consensus. A voting member can block assent to a proposal, register an objection to a proposal but let it go ahead, or block a proposal outright. By agreement, individual recipient country members do not take decisions on their own countries’ proposals and refrain from voting on those of other countries when their own country proposal are under consideration in that particular call for proposals. 11. The non-voting members are: funding contributors who are not voting members; a representative from each of the additional Recipient Countries as agreed by the Steering Committee; two representatives of ‘Southern’ CSOs (currently Farmer and Nature Net from Cambodia and an interim representative from Africa selected by the Pan African Farmers Union), one representative ‘Northern’ CSO (currently Director of Policy and Campaigns for Action Aid); and representatives from the World Bank; the United Nations Secretary General’s Special Representative on Food Security and Nutrition; the IFC, and Supervising Entities xcvii, who hold the money, administer projects and are responsible for fiduciary risk at country level (see comment in Financial Case, Section D and ‘Risk 4’ below). 12. While the Steering Committee has not yet had to deal with a case of fraud or corrupt practices identified by one of the Supervising Entities, it has the powers to: decide to direct the Trustee to suspend any further commitment and/or withhold disbursements of the Trust Fund funds to Supervising Entities in accordance with the Transfer Agreements for reasons, including but not limited to: (i) a substantial deviation from Project work plans and budgets approved by the Steering Committee; (ii) failure of the Supervising Entity to comply with any of the terms of the Transfer Agreement and to remedy or cause to be remedied such non-compliance in accordance with the terms of the Transfer Agreement; or (iii) evidence of financial mismanagement in Projects; decide to direct the Trustee to claim repayment of the Trust Fund funds in full or in part directly from the Supervising Entity to the extent the Supervising Entity has been able to obtain repayment of the same from the negligent party if the Trust Fund funds are found to be misused or not satisfactorily accounted for; decide whether to cancel all or part of a Project or Projects for reasons, including but not limited to, the reasons set forth in the first bullet above and informing the Coordination Unit and the Trustee thereof; and decide the procedures for the Contributors seeking direct recourse against the relevant Supervising Entity or Supervising Entities as third party beneficiaries under the Transfer Agreement or Transfer Agreements. 13. The Steering Committee is recipient of reports of overall annual implementation results concerning both Public and Private Sector Windows, compiled by the Coordination Unit; and periodic financial reports (including annual audited financial statements) on the finances of the GAFSP Trust Fund compiled by the Trustee. It is responsible for approving a common format to be used by each Supervising Entity for reporting implementation results of each project. These follow World Bank rules and procedures and are therefore considered robust. 14. A Technical Advisory Committee (TAC) has been appointed from nominations made by voting and non-voting members of the Steering Committee with no involvement of the World Bank or other SEs. From a total of 28 nominees, 13 were selected by the Steering Committee based on availability and level of expert knowledge. TAC members have globally recognised expertise on agriculture, food and nutritional security and wider development policy, half of whom come from developing countries and some of whom are familiar with the CAADP process in Africa. 15. Administratively, TAC members have been hired by the World Bank as Short Term Consultants to carry out the functions defined in the TAC TOR. The period for which any member serves on the TAC is still to be determined. Information on composition of the TAC and its TOR will be posted on the GAFSP website when the next call for proposals is launched. 16. TAC members are mandated to screen country and regional proposals with regard to: the quality assurance process used to formulate country plans; the proposed level and composition of national government and donor expenditures proposed; the conduciveness of national and regional policies to broad based agriculture sector growth and social protection; any alternative sources of support for proposed investments; and relative magnitude of needs. 17. The Coordination Unit prepares guidelines, collates proposals and receives and readies progress reports for the Steering Committee and the Trustee. As GAFSP grows, in terms of funding and country-level operations, the Steering Committee has discussed whether to recommend strengthening the capacity of the Coordination Unit to match. This would allow it to play a more proactive role on strategic functions such as communications and outreach. GAFSP is potentially vulnerable to the loss of institutional memory which would accompany the departure of a small number of key individuals in the Coordinating Unit from their current roles. Process 18. Proposals can only be submitted to GAFSP by countries eeligible to receive financing from IDA and not IBRD (“IDA-only countries”) and whose oldest loan repayment arrears are less than six months old (non-accrual status). IDA ‘blend’ (i.e. creditworthy for IBRD) countries can receive funding only if approved by the Steering Committee. Table 5: countries currently eligible to apply for GAFSP support Africa East Asia ECA (4) Latin (35 countries) (9) America (4) Angola Benin Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon CAR Chad Comoros DRC Congo, Rep. Cote d’Ivoire Ethiopia Eritrea Gambia Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Kenya Lesotho Liberia Madagascar Malawi Mali Mauritania Mozambique Niger Nigeria Rwanda Sao Tome & Principe Senegal Sierra Leone Tanzania Togo Uganda Zambia Cambodia Kiribati Laos PDR Mongolia Samoa Solomon Is. Timor-Leste Tonga Vanuatu Kosovo Kyrgyz Rep. Moldova Tajikistan Guyana Haiti Honduras Nicaragua MENA (2) South Asia (6 ) Djibouti Yemen Afghanistan Bangladesh Bhutan Maldives Nepal Sri Lanka 19. Individual countries, through their Ministry of Finance, submit investment proposals to the GAFSP Coordination Unit with the endorsement of the proposal by the Chair of the in-country donor group for food and agriculture (or equivalent) to certify that no locally-available sources can finance the proposed investments. This is intended to ensure requests are country-led, and offer additionality, complementarity and reinforcement of what national governments and their partners have agreed as priorities. Governments execute programmes and are accountable for the use of funds to the Supervising Entities selected to support execution. Regional Organisations with legal personality e.g. ECOWAS can similarly submit proposals to GAFSP. 20. In order to ensure that proposals are explicitly aligned with country investment plans and exploit regional technical networks, the TAC is required to ensure that proposals submitted by African countries and regional organisations have been through a CAADP or CAADP like duediligence process and are aligned to the four CAADP pillars (land and water management, market access, food availability and access, and agricultural research). Similarly, evidence is required that non-African countries have followed an equivalent process of consultation with a range of national and regional stakeholders who have endorsed the final investment plan. 21. Proposals are prepared by country governments with the assistance of one or more Supervising Entity, selected by the country applying for funds. Supervising Entities are international organisations with expertise in the development and delivering of support for food and agriculture sector programmes in developing countries. Their role is to assist in the design of projects, set up and sign grant agreements to disburse funds, arrange for technical assistance, submit annual implementation results reports to the Steering Committee and provide financial reports to the Steering Committee through the World Bank as Trustee. (FAO and WFP only provide technical assistance to projects.) Supervising Entities are responsible for the use of funds transferred by the Trustee and directly accountable to the Steering Committee in accordance with their own fiduciary framework, policies, guidelines and procedures. The terms of the Transfer Agreements between the Trustee and the Supervising Entities specifically requires them to inform the Steering Committee immediately in instances of illegal or corrupt practices. 22. The proposals are weighted due to country need (levels of undernourishment and poverty, levels of donor investment in agriculture – overall weighting 30%), policy readiness (degree to which country policies will help generate higher investment returns – overall weighting 30%), and country readiness (for all countries, the specific objectives and targeted results, activities, and extent of local consultation; for African countries the completion of a Comprehensive Africa Agriculture Development Programme (CAADP) post-compact investment plan, for non African countries and equivalent externally reviewed project proposal – overall weighting 40%). 23. The TAC take into account how well proposals fits with existing policy, the institutional capacity to carry out the proposals, the degree to which they were produced with the participation of those to be affected, gender dimensions, how it takes account of climate change, the technical quality of the programmes, their value for money and management feasibility. Once projects have started they follow the normal procedures of the Supervising Entity. Up to 5% of the grant cost can be applied to the administrative costs of the Supervising Entity, as defined in the Administrative Agreement between the Trustee and the SE. 24. The list of Supervising Entities for GAFSP Public Sector Window Investment Plans which have already been allocated funds is at Table 6 below. Table 6: Country Cambodia Bangladesh Ethiopia Haiti Liberia Mongolia Nepal Niger Rwanda Sierra Leone Tajikistan Togo Supervising Entity Asian Development Bank World Bank & Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO) World Bank and FAO Inter-American Development Bank and World Bank African Development Bank World Bank and FAO World Bank and FAO African Development Bank World Bank International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) World Bank IFAD and World Bank 25. 18 countries have submitted proposals for which funding has not yet been approved: Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, The Gambia, Ghana, Kenya, Malawi, , Mali, Mauritania, Niger, Senegal, Tanzania, Lao PDR, Kyrgyz Republic, Yemen, Bhutan, Honduras, Nicaragua Private sector 26. The Private Sector Window of GAFSP will be run according to the procedures of the IFC. Private sector organizations and firms of financial intermediaries) operating in eligible countries and working in agribusiness, including agriculture, associated infrastructure, commodity trading, co-operatives, processers and agricultural suppliers can apply. 27. The Private Sector Window’s governance structures are analogous to those of the Public Sector Window. Its Project Investment Committee (PIC) has the same approval function as the TAC for the Public Sector Window and it has its own Secretariat, in IFC, to manage its operations. The GAFSP Steering Committee oversees both windows. The first call for proposal was made in July 2011. A background paper on the Private Sector Window was issued by the IFC on the 23 September. The paper, subject to approval by the IFC board, calls for concessional funding to be made available from GAFSP funds as well as fully commercial finance. Commercial finance will be made on an equal footing with other IFC investments. 28. Concessional finance may be applied to enterprises that require a temporary subsidy to become fully commercially viable as approved by the IFC Board in 2012. Funding from the Private Sector Window will also be used to fund advisory services for organisations receiving concessional funding, either from IFC staff or from consultants contracted by IFC. The concessional finance will provide the minimum amount of concessions in order to avoid market distortion, and be time bound with a clear pathway to sustainability. IFC’s current experience indicates that concessional finance can mobilize $6-7 for every $1 invested. 29. Investments will be direct - for example funding innovative companies trying out new technologies and indirect; offering hedge funding for agricultural price changes; first loss facilities; and concessional debt and equity products. 30. Advisory services are expected to build on IFC's existing work in the agricultural sector, and be concentrated on increasing access to finance for farmers, improving supply chain links, reducing risks through insurance, strengthening farmers’ organizations and adapting to and mitigating climate change. 31. The IFC paper welcomes possible future partnership with other finance institutions on a project by project basis. It has developed a master co-operation agreement to streamline this process. In 2010, a total of US$ 734mn was mobilized from 13 parallel lenders in 10 countries. Financing 32. Since the launch of GAFSP in April 2010, the Steering Committee has made funding allocations worth US$ 480mn to 12 countries including Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Bangladesh, Ethiopia and Nepal. Awards made to date provide an indication of the types of investments GAFSP supports: Bangladesh will expand the adoption of improved rice varieties and better water management practices to enhance farmers’ climate resilience; Rwanda will transform hillside agriculture by reducing erosion and boosting production of high value horticulture crops; Sierra Leone will link small farmers to markets more effectively through new Agricultural Business Centres; Ethiopia will support agriculture in high potential but under developed areas of the country and Nepal will enhance the food security and nutritional status of poor and vulnerable households in selected locations, with a focus on women farmers. 33. A further US$ 490mn has been pledged by donors but not yet transferred (see Annex 1), and 18 countries - including Ghana, Tanzania, Malawi, Kenya and Yemen - have submitted initial proposals for which funding has not yet been approved. The US plans to make another contribution of US$ 100mn to the Public Sector Window as soon as their fiscal year 2012 budgets are confirmed. The Netherlands and the US also plan to contribute Euro 100mn and US$ 25mn to the Private Sector Window in the coming months. 34. A total UK contribution of £50mn would put us in the middle of the donor contributing pack based on current pledges – less than the US, Canada, Australia and Spain, but ahead of Korea, Ireland and Gates. DFID’s burden share of total pledges to GAFSP would be broadly in line with our contribution to IDA (12%) and GFATM (10%) at around 10%. DFID agenda for the reform of GAFSP 35. Our initial assessment of GAFSP’s performance suggests the need for the reforms outlined in Section 4a of the Appraisal Case to address: stronger operation of the Private Sector Window; a higher level results framework; cost consciousness; speed of disbursement and stronger management; gender disaggregation; prompt filling of staffing gaps and filling appropriate roles, overall evaluation; climate change; and nutrition. Our ability to pursue these reforms effectively is dependent on the UK’s presence on the GAFSP Steering Committee. In particular, this is key to our ability to work with other members of the Committee to secure desired improvements in the operation of the Private Sector Window before we make a final decision on the provision of funding to that window. The time frames set for the achievement of these reforms therefore relate to the point at which we take up a seat on the Steering Committee. 36. We have discussed this with the current Chair of the Committee who has indicated that, provided the DFID contribution is at least comparable in size with the other donors on the Committee, the UK would take up one of the remaining two donor seats on the Committee. As outlined above, a UK contribution of £50mn would put us in the middle of the donor contributing pack, above some who are already on the Committee. We are therefore confident of being offered a seat on the Committee and of being able to use this position to drive our reform agenda. 37. While the performance of Supervising Entities in their role within GAFSP may highlight some areas of weakness overall in these institutions, we do not propose to focus on influencing their corporate performance through our role on the GAFSP Steering Committee. Instead, we would expect the UK to use its position on the boards of these institutions and the follow up to the MAR process to address any systemic failures on their part. DFID management processes and oversight 38. The Head of the Food and Nutritional Security Team (FNST) in GRD will sit on the GAFSP Steering Committee and act as the primary liaison point for DFID with other Steering Committee and with members of the World Bank Coordination Unit. Financial reports, compliance and administrative functions will be dealt with by administrative staff responsible for FNST in the GRD Programme and Corporate Team. Modest support on engaging with IFC on the Private Sector Window will be needed from Private Sector Department. Support from International Financial Institutions Department and UKDel Washington will be needed on aspects of governance and the reform agenda we will pursue with GAFSP. Some feedback on the progress of the projects in countries where DFID is active may be sought from DFID country based staff as appropriate, for example using the 10% allocation of advisory time to DFID-wide cadre responsibilities. Approach to Funding of the Private Sector Window (PSW): 39. IFC, the manager and implementer of the PSW, was rated a good multi-lateral in the DFID multilateral aid review with good financial and developmental performance and a strong results framework. Its performance in low income countries and fragile states was considered weaker (especially in Africa) than its overall performance. A recent IEG evaluation of its work on agribusiness corroborates this finding, stating that its performance in SSA was weak, as was the case for the rest of the World Bank Group, due to challenging business environments for agriculture. It performed better in other regions. It has recently agreed a new Agribusiness Strategy. 40. DFID’s own corporate priorities for IFC are for it to do more work in IDA countries, fragile states, provide greater support to SMEs and improve integration of climate and gender issues. Given the PSW’s focus in IDA-countries, the PSW addresses the focus on core IDA countries but how other DFID priorities will be integrated into its operations must still be finalised and fully operationalised. 41. The appraisal case sets out the need for the PSW’s efficacy to be improved as a key reform priority. The more focused engagement of three donors (the Netherlands (Euro 100mn), Canada ($50mn) and the US ($25mn) has begun to bear fruit. The IFC has agreed on the need to launch more innovative financial products (e.g. first less cover, partial credit guarantees, micro-insurance) that will allow riskier financing of small to medium sized companies along the agribusiness supply chain in low-income countries. It has also begun to package technical assistance along with blended finance (a mix of commercial and concessional lending) to decrease the financial risk and increase the bankability of small and medium enterprises. This should ensure that PSW funds are deployed efficiently and can be accessed by less experienced end users. 42. Other changes that we will pursue and that reflect the priorities of other key donors include: Ensuring the IFC engages more strategically with the investment needs of the agricultural sector in its management of PSW funds, and in line with is agribusiness strategy; changing from a simple open call for proposals to a portfolio management approach, shaped by a new advisory strategy; taking more account of what others, such as the Africa Union/Grow Africa Task Force, are doing to improve the enabling environment for investment in agriculture in specific countries; organising ‘market place’ events so that partners with experience in lending to or investing in African agriculture can come together to develop bankable proposals for GAFSP; maximising the complementarity of the Private and Public Sector Windows; deepening the engagement with IFC of IFAD, Regional Development Banks and other Development Finance Institutions with a track record of investing in agriculture; increasing the familiarity of IFC’s lending officers with the risk profile of farmers and agribusinesses in low income countries; and increasing the gender sensitivity of IFC managed investments. The approach taken by these donors is similar to that DFID is taking to encourage IFC lending to SMEs and is in line with IFC’s proposed new policy on blending commercial and concessional finance in selected sectors including agriculture and climate change. 43. We will conduct an additional assessment and communications process, to be annexed to this business case in months 11 and 12 after the point at which we take up a seat on the Steering Committee, to ensure funding is only provided when we are confident that the PSW design and performance is adequate. The proposed plan for this process is : 1. Assess status of the key outstanding questions (current views of PSW stakeholders in brackets): What returns does IFC expect to make from PSW investments? What are the net returns from its existing agribusiness portfolio and strategy as an objective indication? A projection of expected success should be added to the PSW results framework. (Other donors agree and are willing to prioritise this). What are the specific plans for PSW to work with other IFIs and what proactive steps will it take? (Other donors agree to a limited extent and are willing to explore this with us). Why isn’t more of IFC’s own ample finance being used to expand the size and reach of the PSW, especially since early use of PSW is likely to be on a fully commercial basis? (Other donors strongly agree and expect IFC to make an announcement of its own contribution in due course). Commercially viable projects should be accompanied by a full explanation of their developmental benefits to agribusiness markets to justify IFC investment additionality. Funding requirements and evidence will need to demonstrate that it is crowding in more private investment and that its engagement is catalytic and subject to an adequate exit strategy. (Other donors strongly agree and are willing to tighten up the mechanism to reflect this). IFC additionality must be a firm condition of commercial and concessional investment in line with its strategy for blended financing. Will the PSW funding criteria be strengthened to properly reflect this? ( Other donors strongly agree as above) Will the criteria be strengthened to prioritise SMEs now that concessional finance has been approved? Will a target on SME engagement be set and what additional criteria will be added to ensure concessional financing has broad market development impacts and does not undermine existing financial markets? (Other donors, US and Netherlands especially, strongly agree and will pursue with us) If funding cannot be moved between windows, what recourse would donors have if PSW isn’t performing as expected? (Funding cannot be moved but there is plenty of support from other donors to increase synergies between the windows that DFID can influence) What innovations and new approaches will lead to IFC’s improved performance and engagement in SSA through the PSW mechanism? How will PSW integrate DFID IFC priorities of gender, environment and fragile states engagement? (This is an area where there is donor interest but plenty of shaping of the mechanism still needed) In addition, questions around the PSW’s risk profile, use of investment returns and donors’ appetite for risk need to be answered to ensure a balanced approach that maximizes development impact. (this is an ongoing agenda which DFID can feed into but US and Netherlands have voiced a significant appetite for higher risk exposure in return for greater development impact potential) 2. Use this assessment as part of an economic appraisal of the PSW compared to at least two other feasible alternatives for global funding at scale if they exist. 3. Conduct and update value for money and financial management assessments for IFC using the latest MAR information. 4. Update the management case with relevant management actions, cost metrics and evaluation questions related to the PSW. 5. Share assessment with PSD and jointly submit an information note to ministers on whether or not to fund. 6. Disburse funding if analysis justifies it. DFID Influencing Strategy 44. Priority reforms which DFID will pursue during the first 12 months as a contributor to GAFSP, are: Improving efficacy of the Private Sector Window operation with a separate DFID assessment as an addendum to this business case. The assessment plan is set out in para 43 above. Creation of a high-level, aggregated Results Framework Improving speed of disbursement and proactive Bank management. 45. In addition, DFID officials should work on an ongoing basis to ensure a continual improvement in: Cost consciousness of GAFSP operations across the board; especially in negotiating competitive trust fund management fees charged by the Bank; Gender disaggregation of data. Attention to climate change and nutrition as aspects of food security Strengthening the processes for filling staffing gaps. Ensuring the Bank fulfils appropriate roles that avoid conflict of interest (e.g. Supervising Entity, Trustee and Coordination Unit) in management and delivery and makes use of private sector expertise to take over responsibility for key functions if and where appropriate. 46. To influence GAFSP we will: 1. Use our position as an active voting member on the Steering Committee (to be confirmed) to push for reforms. The regular place on the Committee will be taken by the Head of the Food and Nutritional Security Team in Policy Division. 2. Use DFID’s bilateral relationship with the other contributors – including through more senior management and Minister engagement when necessary - to agree common approaches to driving continuous improvement in GAFSP. In particular we will work with the Dutch, the US and the Canadians to drive reforms of the Private Sector Window. DFID has already attended one GAFSP donor review meeting as observer. We will use the opportunity of our regular contacts with key like-minded contributors such as US, Canada, Australia and BMGF, at events such as the Aquila Food Security Initiative Review Group meetings and in processes such as the G20 work on Food Security to build consensus around approaches to important reforms. The Head of Growth and Resilience Department used this to highlight initial concerns over issues such as the need for an aggregated results framework against which to report overall achievements and intensified cost consciousness on the part of all organizations in the results delivery chain. This elicited recognition from the existing contributors that more could be done to focus on results, value for money, gender and nutritional outcomes and an expectation that should DFID agree to contribute to GAFSP that we would play a leading role in pursuing these objectives. 3. Work with International Financial Institutions Department and United Nations and Commonwealth Department and with UKDel Washington to use the UK position on the governing boards of the World Bank, IFC and other Supervising Entities to reinforce messages about their role in GAFSP implementation, as and when appropriate. 4. Use our position as a long-standing supporter of and contributor to the CAADP Trust Fund, to ensure that the CAADP process provides the basis for high quality investment proposals going to the GAFSP after CAADP due diligence. 5. Use early engagement in the Steering Group to propose operational improvements such as increasing focus on empowerment of women and to identify champions for change, like-minded supporters of reforms and any potential blockers. Thereafter we will develop a plan for achieving our priority reforms. Indicatively, we will achieve the three priority ‘one off’ reforms identified in the Appraisal Case (improved performance of the private sector window, agreement on an aggregated results framework and improved speed of delivery) by the end of the first year of our membership of the Steering Committee. We will assess the success of our efforts to make continuous improvement in two others areas (cost consciousness and gender) when the 6. Negotiate specific triggers for the release of the second year tranches to the Private Sector Window with GAFSP management and the Steering Committee in line with both our assessment criteria for the private sector window and the overall GAFSP reform actions (in paragraphs 43-45 above). Having discussed our key assessment issues for the Private Sector Window with other donors, it is clear that our concerns are widely shared and that we will have ample opportunity to influence the strengthening of the mechanism. Our engagement in the Steering Committee and our ability to withhold PSW funding until issues highlighted in the PSW approach section above have been adequately resolved provide us the necessary tools to ensure a positive outcome to strengthening both the PSW and the overall GAFSP mechanism. 7. Seek a commitment to independent evaluation of GAFSP, at the overall fund level, two years after our initial contribution is made, as a condition of further DFID funding. 47. If the assessment which we will carry out of progress on our priority reform indicates that targets have not been met 12 months after taking up a seat on the Steering Committee, then we will not go ahead with planned funding to the PSW. B). What are the risks and how these will be managed? 48. Developments on the ground funded by GAFSP will result from country-led programme designs and be executed through a Supervising Entity. The ability of the GAFSP Steering Committee to impact the quality of work on the ground is therefore dependent on the robustness of appraisal processes and the monitoring and evaluation systems which are being put in place. Private Sector Window Risk 1. Weakness in the design of the Private Sector Window and of the separate public and private sector funding channels more generally result in lost opportunities to leverage additional resources into agriculture and reduce GAFSP’s overall impact on food security. 49. To date, IFC has been reluctant to act as a coordinator and trustee for funds which might pass through it to other Supervising Entities. This threatens to limit the degree of coordination on work to support private sector investment in developing country agriculture. As does the weak linkages between the two windows. For example, there is no link between countries which receive Public Sector Window support for their overall investment plans and the location of companies bidding to the Private Sector Window or any mechanism for prioritising private sector investments which complement public investments through the other window. Mitigation 50. We will be committed to driving through reforms to the Private Sector Window and, in keeping with GAFSP overall philosophy of on-going learning and improvement, will work to ensure its overall governance and operational approach are delivering maximum impact. We will not make any contributions to the Private Sector Window until reforms to its operations have made progress. There is significant support and willingness to engage on these issues from other donors that we will leverage through our influencing strategy on pages 63-64. Any funding would be subject to an assessment presented as an addendum to this business case. 51. Steps have been taken to clarify the rules for IFC’s investments. An IFC paper of the 23 September advocates strongly for concessional finance to be provided under the GAFSP, which would allow finance to be provided to projects that need an initial subsidy to be viable. Public Sector Window Risk 2: Applicant countries take insufficient ownership of the process and are insufficiently prepared to implement programmes supported by GAFSP funds. 52. The GAFSP programme guidelines require that proposals must be in line with externally reviewed national plans for agricultural investment. But the TAC only has paper reports on which to base its judgement on the link between the investment plans submitted to GAFSP and overarching national development plans. To date, available reports have been under a page, and while they are good at picking up where proposals are not in line with national agricultural plans (e.g. Tajikistan), their ability to assess the capacity to implement are more limited. 53. For African countries, the national plans on which GAFSP submissions are based are produced as part of the CAADP process. A review carried out in 2010 noted that the CAADP process has yet to fulfil its potential. Country level agricultural investment plans vary in quality and in some cases were simply a repackaging of existing country development plansxcviii. DFID is committed to supporting CAADP process and has provided £10mn to help countries which have not yet done so to produce high quality investment plans. Mitigation 54. An informal review of GAFSP’s first year of operations by the contributing donors, done in August, produced a ‘white paper’ and recommended adjustments to procedures to address the twin issues of ownership and readiness. 55. To boost country ownership and commitment to quality of plans: By adding a requirement for co-financing from country government and Supervising Entities. 56. DFID will support recommendations to provide a greater depth of scrutiny of proposals by the TAC, without compromising the country-led nature of the process. The provision of independent extra technical help for producing proposals, preferably through the early involvement of the Supervising Entity will be considered. DFID will also advocate for increased scrutiny of the links of GAFSP proposals to overarching national plans, and the viability of those plans. 57. The current guidelines mention the need to assure sustainability of investments in the face of climate change. DFID will advocate for this to include specific criteria, especially where the construction of irrigation and soil and water conservation infrastructure is planned. The criteria should ensure that the detailed designs are such that they can reasonably be expected to have a positive return over their design lifetime, taking into account the projected changes due to climate change. DFID will advocate for the reports explicitly to take into account not only the current progress of the project, but also an assessment of the changing external environment and a critical appraisal of changes that may be needed to make sure projects remain able to deliver transformational outcomes. Risk 3: The programmes funded lack technical expertise to deliver the promised outcomes. 58. An important part of the role of Supervising Entities is to fill gaps in country based expertise through technical and management assistance. The TAC scrutiny of the proposals does not specifically require an appraisal of the suitability and capacity of the Supervising Entity. This could change if the appraisals done by the Supervising Entities can be made available to TAC in advance of funding. Mitigation 59. DFID’s MAR process confirms that the Supervising Entities are all international organisations with a strong track record in technical assistance. They are able to draw on world wide expertise. The possible exception to this is FAO, whose performance was variable, but with good ratings on some aspects of performance. 60. The Supervising Entities own appraisals will provide an assessment of the technical assistance needed to carry out the projects. The recommendation that proposals are endorsed by a Supervising Entity at an earlier stages, should allow an early assessment to be made of the technical assistance needed. During project implementation the monitoring of the project at 6 monthly intervals will enable GAFSP to track the efficiency of the projects. Risk 4: The programmes cannot be implemented due to a lack of management capacity on the part of recipient Governments. Mitigation 61. The management capacity of the Governments to deliver the projects can be initially assessed through the scrutiny of the national level plans and the project proposal. DFID will advocate for increased scrutiny of the quality and viability of national plans that the place of GAFSP projects in contributing to their achievement. The Supervising Entities will be in a position to assist countries with implementation. Risk 5: The programmes cannot be implemented due to a lack of management capacity of the Supervising Entities, including acting against corruption and fraud. 62. A critical factor in the delivery of the programmes is the financial and administrative capacity of the Supervising Entity, as all funds will ultimately be routed through them. Mitigation 63. Mitigation rests with the management ability of the Supervising Entities. The MAR has shown that the Supervising Entities are technically competent (see Financial Case). The plan to get supervising entities to endorse plans before they go to the steering committee will help to assure the viability of project plans. DFID will advocate for a clear management appraisal to be available to the technical and steering committees. 64. The responsibility for action to combat corruption and fraud among country level implementing partners rests with the Supervising Entities and their own internal procedures. The agreement between the Supervising Entities and the GAFSP specifically requires that the Supervising Entities inform the Steering Committee immediately in instances of illegal or corrupt practices. Any repayment made by a Supervising Entity due to instances of corrupt practices would be made in accordance with its policies and procedures and only to the extent that it (the SE) has been able to obtain repayment from the negligent party. Risk 6: GAFSP procedures and approach cause delays in delivery, which undermine confidence among recipient, donor and potential donor countries. 65. Project design and appraisal take time but in several cases implementation has been delayed for reasons that would appear to have been within the control of the Supervising Entity and recipient government. The approval of proposals by GAFSP is followed by a more detailed appraisal of projects by the Supervising Entity. In most cases this has only begun once the overall country investment plan has been approved by GAFSP, lengthening the time to implementation. Mitigation 66. To accelerate implementation DFID will work with others on the Steering Committee to: Permit Supervising Entities to use a proportion of the funds for project start up activities. For example, IFAD used its own funds for this in Togo; with the result that project implementation began within a year. Require the Supervising Entity to endorse the proposal to encourage them to begin appraisals before funding is awarded. This would help to provide greater assurance on the quality of the proposals and the in-country capacity to implement, but would also require greater investment by Supervising Entities in advance of funding. Increase the capacity of the Co-ordination Unit in the World Bank so that they can play a more active role in sharing planning and operational information between Supervising Entities - allowing them to compare notes and benefit from best practice. Risk 7. The results from the projects funded by GAFSP do not provide clear evidence that shows the aggregate impact of the GAFSP. Mitigation 67. The monitoring and evaluation plan requires the collection of baseline data and the use of standard indicators, with all data disaggregated by gender. The co-ordinating unit is charged with producing synthesis reports of impact. A proportion of projects (10-30%) will have experimental or quasi experimental impact assessments. All other projects wil be subject to a rapid impact evaluation. 68. The steering committee and the Bank are committed to ensure the programme learns as it goes along. Already an informal review by steering committee members has suggested improvements to the programmes processes. 69. DFID will advocate for regular reviews of programme performance as a whole and an evaluation after two years. Risk 8. The programme does not provide the best possible value for money because of a lack of attention to cost control. 70. The assessment process of country proposals do not have a strong emphasis on value for money and cost consciousness and in the assessment of projects by the technical committee. Currently, the Steering Committee does not engage strongly enough with the procedures on the Supervising Entities on value for money. Mitigation 71. DFID will use its position on the Steering Committee to include a stronger emphasis on value for money in project appraisal. The Supervising Entities have acceptable scores on cost consciousness in the MAR except for IFAD. DFID will ensure that where IFAD is the supervising entity, specific requirements are put in place to ensure they raise their efforts on value for money. DFID will also consider building donor support for reduced Trust Fund management fees and negotiate accordingly to reduce administrative overheads in line with emerging corporate guidance. Risk 9: The World Bank’s multiple roles as Trustee; Secretariat to the Steering Committee and Potential Supervising Entity could create a conflict of interest or otherwise negatively affect GAFSP’s performance. 72. The World Bank manages the funding on behalf of donors, recommends funding approvals to the steering committee and implements funds approved. This could create actual conflict of interest between its different roles and compromise the quality of GAFSP’s internal processes. Alternatively a lack of clarity and space between its roles could feed perceptions of conflicts of interest. For example, there have been instances in other Trust Funds where the Fund Secretariat has been primarily accountable to Bank Management rather than the Fund Steering Committee. Mitigation 73. There are procedural controls in place on each of the roles which the Bank plays in GAFSP that are set out in the management case. A key mitigating factor is that the Bank is not the sole supervising entity and often works in partnership with other institutions. Having a choice of implementing partner creates a healthy level of competition and positive incentives for the Bank to play an effective role. 74. Though certain incentives and procedures are in place, to ensure the risk is proactively managed, DFID will use its role on the Steering Committee to strengthen existing procedures and corrective measures to include: setting up and enforcing firewalls between different parts of the Bank engaged in different roles to ensure objectivity, the ability to take away one or more of the Bank’s roles if conflict of interest becomes persistent or entrenched and offer them to other qualified parties, ensuring conflict of interest issues are assessed in all annual reviews and evaluations. C. What conditions apply (for financial aid only)? D. How will progress and results be monitored, measured and evaluated? 75. The Steering Committee of GAFSP approved a Monitoring and Evaluation plan in February 2011. The Plan builds on the existing monitoring systems of the Supervising Entities to ensure that a comprehensive results framework is created against which donor countries and their tax payers, recipient country governments and their publics, and the wider development community can judge the impact of GAFSP interventions. The main elements of the Plan are set out below covering Preparation, Implementation and Completion stages of the project cycle. DFID will also make completion of an independent, external evaluation of the GAFSP mechanism, to be carried out two years after we join the Steering Committee (ie in early 2014), endorsed by the Steering Committee, a firm condition of any further engagement with the mechanism. Project Preparation Baseline data – will be collected at the latest before the end of the first year of implementation. The baseline indicators required for impact evaluation are the household income of direct project beneficiaries and the proportion of the target population below the minimum level of dietary energy. Ex ante cost benefit analysis - will be done for all investment projects, and made publicly available, before project implementation begins. To be acceptable on economic grounds a project’s expected present value of the project’s net benefits must be significant and positive. Project implementation Core indicators – A core set of indicators have been compiled by the Coordination Unit from the IDA core sector indicators and indicator sets recently agreed by the Global Donor Platform, FAO and the World Bank. These indicators have been agreed with the Supervising Entities. They cover each of the GAFSP Output areas (see the Theory of Change or Logframe). At least one of the core indicators per results area must be included in project level results framework so that these can be aggregated up and report at the programme level. Progress reporting –Supervising Entities will report every 6 months against the GAFSP core indicators. Mapping of results - By the end of the first year a map of project activities, overlaid with development indicators. Project completion. Project completion report – The template for the project completion report sets out the need for both quantitative and qualitative assessments of the performance of the project, with sections for lessons learned and cost efficiency of the project. Independent Evaluation – Supervising Entities must ensure that all projects undergo independent evaluation which will be submitted to the Steering Committee and made public. Impact Evaluation (IE) - All projects will undergo an impact evaluation. For some projects (10 -30%) the impact evaluation will employ experimental or quasi-experimental methods. 76. The impact evaluation policy as set out in the GAFSP Monitoring and Evaluation Plan is as below: Table 7: Target I. In-depth IEs (experimental or quasiexperimental IE) II. Rapid IEs (nonexperimental IE) Target Approximately 10-30 % of all GAFSP projects selected according to lesson-learning priorities All GAFSP projects (except for those that have been chosen to carry out the in-depth Indicative cost $800,000 for each IE Implementation Funding CU to centrally contract a specialized organization to carry out all indepth IEs To be funded separately by the SC $50,000 for each IE Each project to contract a specialized organization to carry out its rapid IE To be funded from each GAFSPawarded Grant IEs) amount 77. While the programme will follow the protocols of the Supervising Entities for project evaluation and monitoring, the Monitoring and Evaluation Plan sets the common elements of an approach which all projects under the public sector window must follow in order to maximise lesson learning and accountability. A survey of Supervising Entities has clarified that they all collect baseline data, all do cost benefit analyses, and all carry out project completion reports. Not all Supervising Entities evaluate or do impact assessments of all projects. Where this is the case the Supervising Entities will ensure that the GAFSP projects are chosen for evaluation and impact studies. Not all Supervising Entities make their reports available to the public. Where reports are not routinely publicly available, the Coordination Unit (CU) will extract data and publish it. The Coordination Unit (CU) will be responsible for reminding partners of the due dates of reports and summarising and presenting information at a programme level to the Steering Committee and to the public. 78. As indicated in the table above, for a sub-set of GAFSP programmes, an in-depth impact evaluation will be carried out by a suitable research organisation with a proven track record in impact evaluation of food security projects. The Steering Committee has agreed that the World Bank’s Development Impact Evaluation Initiative (DIME) will be one of the impact evaluation organisations available to Supervising Entities to conduct in-depth impact evaluation. DIME is a World Bank programme that works with 300 agencies in 72 countries across 15 development themes to generate knowledge, improve the quality of operations and strengthen country capacity for evidence-based policy making. It is governed by a Steering Group composed of chief economists and directors from the Banks networks and regional units and reports to the Bank’s Managing Director responsible for knowledge management and to the Chief Economist. Dissemination of results and lesson learning 79. The Coordination Unit will develop a results page in the GAFSP website to report on programme-wide progress at least every six months. It will also prepare project results sheets and other dissemination material and upload this onto the GAFSP website, along with links to the individual project websites and project activity maps. It will liaise with the Monitoring and Evaluation counterparts in related organisations – such as the Regional Strategic Analysis and Knowledge System for CAADP, and organise and participate in global and regional workshops with such bodies. 80. The Steering Committee will commission an annual workshop from the Global Donor Platform for Rural Development – involving representatives of different stakeholder groups implementing GAFSP - to communicate progress on results and lessons learned from implementation of country investment plans and the project level evaluations carried out by DIME and others. 81. The detailed roles of the Steering Committee, the Coordination Unit and the Supervising Entities are set out in Table B in the GAFSP Monitoring and Evaluation Plan. Private Sector 82. IFC is the Supervising Entity for the Private Sector Window. The IFC will use its highly rated Development Outcome Tracking System (DOTS) to measure progress and report annually. 83. Projects are assessed according to financial, economic, environmental, social and private sector development performance. Indicators proposed for GAFSP are as in the figure below. 84. Annual reports from all investments will be aggregated to measure the development impact of the facility as a whole. The IFC will submit to the Co-ordinating Unit an annual progress report by May 31 of each year. Evaluation 85. The independent Investment Evaluation Group (IEG), which was rated highly in DFID’s MAR process will be in charge of the in depth evaluation of a random sample of projects five years after they were approved. The evaluations will be carried out by IFC staff and validated by the IEG. IEG’s independence is safe guarded by its requirement to report direct to the World Bank Board not to anyone in the management chain at IFC or the World Bank. 86. Role of the Steering Committee: The Steering Committee will review progress made at the programme level and in the individual countries either virtually or at Steering Committee meetings. Once the Steering Committee has reviewed the progress, the documentation will be disclosed on the GAFSP website. 87. While individual programme level evaluation is robustly included in the design of GAFSP, there are currently no plans for an independent evaluation of GAFSP as a whole. As a funding contributor to GAFSP, DFID will seek a commitment to independent evaluation of its overall operations two years after DFID takes up a seat on the Steering Committee, as a condition of DFID funding beyond the initial payment of £60mn to the Public Sector Window. 88. Evaluation questions for the Public Sector Window, that address weaknesses in the evidence base in the theory of change, as well as assumptions and challenges in the strategic and management cases, and which we propose should be pursued through the independent evaluation, are as follows: 1. How well suited is the GAFSP mechanism to support an economic sector? (Given that this is an innovative use of a Financial Intermediary Fund, has complex relationships with a range of multilateral supervising entities and in country stakeholders, and the evidence presented in appraisal case is judged as weak). 2. How well has GAFSP tackled the links between increased agricultural productivity and improved nutrition in its funded programmes? (Given low evidence as set out in the Strategic Case.) 3. How well is business enabling environment interventions integrated into GAFSP in terms of its results framework, investment plan criteria and funded interventions? 4. How well has GAFSP helped bridge the private and public financing gaps for agriculture? (as set out in the Strategic Case as a core rationale for DFID intervention) 5. Have GAFSP outputs led to increased agricultural productivity and has this led to measurable improvements in rural incomes and expanded economic opportunity? (as set out in the Theory of Change) 6. Do all interventions have thorough results chains and indicators to ensure a clear line of sight to support attribution to GAFSP for poverty impacts? 7. To what extent do GAFSP interventions ensure local ownership and maximize use of local systems to create change at all stages of the intervention cycle? (To assess their sustainability.) 8. Does GAFSP’s 20% aggregate rate of return remain relevant given actual project results? (To ensure continued validity of the economic appraisal.) 9. Does GAFSP funding take a systematic approach to tackling deficiencies in agricultural systems to ensure investments address assumptions and lead to the expected outcomes? (As set out in the Theory of Change.) 10. Which GAFSP market development improvements have contributed most to enhancing agricultural productivity and reducing poverty? (As set out in the Theory of Change.) 11. Is GAFSP’s approach to cost control appropriate and effective? (as set out in Reform Priorities) 12. Is GAFSP’s speed of disbursement adequate and cost efficient? (As set out in Reform Priorities.) Logframe Quest No of logframe for this intervention: 3254262 i World Bank (WRD 2008) What are the links between agricultural production and food security? ii What are the projected impacts of climate change on food crop productivity in Africa and S Asia? DFID Systematic Review J.W. Knox, T.M. Hess, A. Daccache and M. Perez Ortola 12th April 2011 iii World Bank (WRD 2008) What are the links between agricultural production and food security? iv World Bank. (2008). World Development Report – Agriculture for Development v Gallup, J., S. Radelet and A. Warner. (1997). Economic growth and the income of the poor. AER Discussion Paper No. 36. Harvard Institute for International Development: Cambridge. vi Ligon, Ethan, and Elisabeth Sadoulet. 2007. “Estimating the Effects of Aggregate Agricultural Growth on the Distribution of Expenditures.” Background paper for the WDR 2008 vii Julie Litchfield (January 2010), SRF, for DFID, Agriculture and Growth Theme Reviews, p. 2 viii Global Harvest Initiative (October 2010), The Global Harvest Initiative’s 2010 GAP Report – Measuring Agricultural Productivity”, ix Fan, Shenggen, Nestorova, Bella and Olofinbiyi, Tolulope (2010), China’s Agricultural and Rural Development: Implications for Africa; IFPRI; Godoy, Julio (2010), Africa Should Take Lessons from China, IPS News x Dewbre, J., D. Cervantes-Godoy and S. Sorescu (2011), "Agricultural Progress and Poverty Reduction: Synthesis Report", OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Working Papers, No. 49, OECD Publishing. xi World Bank. (2008). World Development Report – Agriculture for Development xii World Bank. (2008). World Development Report – Agriculture for Development xiii IFPRI, Welthungerhilfe (GAA), Concern (October 2009): Global Hunger Index 2009 xiv DFID (2007), Gender Equality at the Heart of Development, p. 13 xv Andrew Shepherd, ODI, Paper presented at the CPRC Poverty Conference, 8-10 Sept. 2010, Manchester, Agriculture and Escaping Rural Poverty: an Analysis of Movements and Markets xvi World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development Fan, Shenggen, Nestorova, Bella and Olofinbiyi, Tolulope (2010), China’s Agricultural and Rural Development: Implications for Africa; IFPRI; Godoy, Julio (2010), Africa Should Take Lessons from China, IPS News xviii Government Office of Science. (2010). Global Food and Farming Futures xix World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development. xx World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development. xxi Fan, S., T. Mogues, and S. Benin (2009). Setting Priorities for Public Spending for Agriculture and Rural Development in Africa. IFPRI Policy Brief. April 2009 xxii How to Feed the World in 2050, Food and Agriculture Organisation available at: http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/wsfs/docs/expert_paper/How_to_Feed_the_World_in_ 2050.pdf. xxiii Mhalanga, N. (2010). Private Sector Agri-Business Investment in Sub Saharan Africa. Food and Agriculture Organisation. xxiv http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http://www.bis.gov.uk/foresight/ourwork/projects/current-projects/global-food-and-farming-futures xvii xxv UKaid (2011). Changing lives, delivering results Webb P and Block S, 2010. Support for agriculture during economic transformation: Impacts on poverty and undernutrition. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America xxvii Webb and Headey, D, 2011, Turning Economic growth into nutrition sensitive growth 2020 Conference Paper 6. IFPRI. xxviii Webb P and Block S, 2010. Support for agriculture during economic transformation: Impacts on poverty and undernutrition. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America xxix Masset E et al, 2011, What is the impact of interventions to increase agricultural production on children’s nutritional status? A systematic review of interventions aiming at increasing income and improving the diet of the rural poor. Unpublished. xxx Oxfam International Research Report (September 2009), Harnessing Agriculture for Development xxvi xxxi Von Grebmer, K., B. Nestorova, A. Quisumbing, R. Fertziger, H. Fritschel, R. PandyaLorch, and Y. Yohannes for IFPRI, Welthungerhilfe, Concern (October 2009), Global Hunger Index 2009 - The Challenge of Hunger: Focus on Financial Crisis and Gender Inequality xxxii World Bank (2009), Gender in Agriculture Sourcebook xxxiii DFID (2007), Gender Equality at the Heart of Development, p. 13 xxxiv Chatham House & vivid economics (September 2010), Evidence for Action: Gender Equality and Economic Growth xxxv Chatham House & vivid economics (September 2010), Evidence for Action: Gender Equality and Economic Growth xxxvi Oxfam International Research Report (September 2009), Harnessing Agriculture for Development xxxvii (DFID) The Engine of Development: The private sector and prosperity for the poor G8. (2009). L’Aquila Joint Statement on Global Food Security. http://agriculture.gouv.fr/G20-agriculture xl Based on an average spend of £25m per country xli Gallup, J., S. Radelet and A. Warner. (1997). Economic growth and the income of the poor. AER Discussion Paper No. 36. Harvard Institute for International Development: Cambridge. xlii Ligon, Ethan, and Elisabeth Sadoulet. 2007. “Estimating the Effects of Aggregate Agricultural Growth on the Distribution of Expenditures.” Background paper for the WDR 2008 xliii Julie Litchfield (January 2010), SRF, for DFID, Agriculture and Growth Theme Reviews, p. 2 xliv Global Harvest Initiative (October 2010), The Global Harvest Initiative’s 2010 GAP Report – Measuring Agricultural Productivity”, xlv Fan, Shenggen, Nestorova, Bella and Olofinbiyi, Tolulope (2010), China’s Agricultural and Rural Development: Implications for Africa; IFPRI; Godoy, Julio (2010), Africa Should Take Lessons from China, IPS News xlvi Dorward, A., J. Kydd, J. Morrison, and I. Urey. 2004. A Policy Agenda for Pro-Poor Agricultural Growth. World Development 32 (1): 73-89. xlvii Oxfam International, Duncan G. (2008), From Poverty to Power: How Active Citizens and Effective States Can Change the World xlviii Global yields per hectare of the major cereal crops (maize, wheat and rice) have more than doubled due to improved seeds and husbandry. Between 1961 and 1990 wheat yields grew at an annual average of 3%, but between 1990 and 2007 this had fallen to 0.5%. Corresponding figures for rice are 2.2% which fell to 1.0%, and for maize 2.3% down to 1.9% (FAOSTAT database). xlix World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development. l World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development. li Carruthers, J.; M.W. Rosegrant; and D. Schuler,1997: Irrigation and Food Security in the 21st Century”. Irrigation and Draining System, 11:83-101. lii Fan, S; P. Hazaell; and S. Thorat, 1999:. Linkages between Government Spending, Growth and Poverty in Rural India, IFPRI Research Report No 11, International Food Policy Research Institute, EPTD. Washington D.C liii Molden, D; Sakthivadival, R, Perry; C.J. Fraiture, C. and Kloezen, W.H.1998: Indicators for Comparing Performance of Irrigated Agricultural Systems, Research Report No. 20, IWMI, Colombo, Sri Lanka liv Arif GM. and Ahmad M. 2001:. Poverty Across the Agro Ecological Zones in the Rural Pakistan, Proceedings of National Workshops on Pro Poor Intervention Strategies in Irrigated Agriculture in Asia, International Water Management Institute Colombo, Sri Lanka lv World Bank. (2008). World Development Report - Agriculture for Development. lvi van der Walle, Dominique. 2007. “Impacts of Road Infrastructure on Markets and Productivity.” lvii Limao, Nuno, and Anthony J. Venables. 2001. “Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage, Transport Costs, and Trade.” World Bank Economic Review 15(3):451–79. lviii Kamara, AB. (2004). The Impact of Market Access on Input Use and Agricultural Productivity: Evidence from the Machakos District, Kenya. Agrekon, Vol 43, No 2 (June 2004) lix CGIAR (1998). Fair Growth lx MAKANDA DW (1987). Managing Kenya’s agricultural sector to the year 2000 and beyond. Workshop on Kenya’s industrial and agricultural strategies towards the year 2000. Nairobi, 21-25th September 1987, pp 17-29 lxi Boserup, E . Population and technological change. Chicago: the University of Chicago Press, USA. xxxviii xxxix lxii Coleman D, and Young T. (1989). Principles of agricultural economics: Markets and prices in less developed countries. WYE studies in agriculture and rural development. Cambridge University Press, UK, pp 167–262 lxiii Hayami, Y. (1997). Development economics: From poverty to the wealth of nations. Claredon Press, Oxford, pp 35-48 lxiv Marketing survey covering 78 wholesale markets handling mangoes, tomatoes, potatoes, tumeric, and maize in the Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, Orissa, and Uttar Pradesh, India (World Bank 2007f). lxv Shilpi, Forhad, and Dina Umali-Deininger. 2006. “Where to Sell? Market Facilities and Agricultural Marketing?” World Bank. Washington, DC. Processed. lxvi Manfred, Z et al. (1997). Market access by smallholder farmers in Malawi, IFPRI lxvii Deininger K, and Okidi J. (1997?) Capital market access, factor demand, and agricultural development in rural areas of developing countries: The case of Uganda. World Bank and Economic Policy Research Center, Kampala lxviii World Bank. (2003). Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. lxix Ethiopia – 2008 Deiniger, Ali and Alemu Deininger, K., D.A. Ali, and T. Alemu. 2008. “Impacts of Land Certification on Tenure Security, Investment, and Land Market Activity: Evidence from Ethiopia.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. World Bank, Washington, DC lxx FAO) (20110) Livestock assets, livestock income and rural households - Cross-country evidence from household surveys. lxxi FAO/GIEWS. (2010). Global Cereal Supply and Demand Update. lxxii United Nations Standing Committee on Nutrition. (2009). Global recession increasesmalnutrition for the most vulnerable people indeveloping countries lxxiii World Bank (2009) http://youthink.worldbank.org/blog/tackling-child-malnutrition-southasia lxxiv Motta, M, Oviedo, A M and Santini M, “An Open Door For Firms: The impact of Business Entry Reforms” Viewpoint Note No 323 June 2010, World Bank and IFC, Washington DC. lxxv Mitchell, Andrew. (2011) Africa is open for business. Speech at the London School of Business, 11/07/2011; PrOpCom. (2011) Fertiliser + training for Nigeria’s farmers. lxxvi DFID Multilateral Aid Review March 2011, http://www.dfid.gov.uk/About-DFID/Who-wework-with/Multilateral-agencies/Multilateral-Aid-Review/ lxxvii ODI. (2009:45). SBS in Practice: Mozambique Case Study lxxviii Williamson, Tim and Catherine Dom, Sector Budget Support in Practice: Synthesis Report, Overseas Development Institute, London, 2009. lxxix Williamson, Tim and Catherine Dom, op.cit.. lxxx “An Evaluation of the World Bank’s Trust Fund Portfolio: Trust Fund Support for Development”, Independent Evaluation Group, Washington DC available at: ieg.worldbankgroup.org/content/dam/ieg/tf_eval.pdf lxxxi FAO The State of the World's Land and Water Resources for Food and Agriculture (SOLAW) June 2011 lxxxii Oldeman, L.R., Hakkeling, R.T.A. & Sombroek, W.G. 1991. World map of the status of human-induced soil degradation, 2nd edn. ISRIC, Wageningen lxxxiii Proxy global assessment of land degradation Z. G. Bai1, D. L. Dent1, L. Olsson2 & M. E. Schaepman3 Soil Use and Management, September 2008, 24, 223–234 lxxxiv Land Degradation in South Asia: its severity, causes and effects upon the people, Rome, FAO, 1994 lxxxv Africa’s Growing Soil Fertility Crisis: What Role For Fertilizer? Jonathan Agwe, Michael Morris, and Erick Fernandes . Agricultural and rural development notes World Bank 2007 lxxxvi Food and Agricultural Organization (FAO). 2003. Assessment of Soil Nutrient Balance: Approaches and Methodologies. FAO Fertilizer and Plant Nutrition Bulletin 14. FAO, Rome lxxxvii The effectiveness of contour hedgerows for soil and water conservation Anthony Young Agroforestry Forum December 1997 Volume 8 Number 4 2 lxxxviii Evidence Base for Climate Resilient and Productive Agriculture in Southern Africa. Martin Whiteside. 2011 DFID Report lxxxix What are the projected impacts of climate change on food crop productivity in Africa and S Asia? DFID Systematic Review J.W. Knox, T.M. Hess,A. Daccache and M. Perez Ortola 12th April 2011 xc IPCC SREX Extreme Events Report (2011) Summary for Policymakers Ibid – footnote 8. xcii Foresight: Migration and Environmental Change Report. 2011. Government Office for Science, London. xci xciii a. On nutrition: Behrman, J., H. Alderman, and J. Hoddinott. 2004. “Hunger and Malnutrition.” In Global Crises, Global Solutions, ed. B. Lomborg. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. b. On cash transfers: de Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie, and Christopher Woodru_, “Returns to Capital in Microenterprises: Evidence from a Field Experiment," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 2008, 123 (4), 1329-1372 and Gertler, Paul, Sebastian Martinez, and Marta Rubio-Codina, “Investing cash transfers to raise long term living standards," Policy Research Working Paper Series 3994, The World Bank August 2006 A more minor discrepancy in the World Bank’s figures is possible double counting of some benefits in its economic rate of return calculations. But this is not significant enough to warrant additional attention beyond the existing sensitivity analysis. xciv xcv Conditional on an even distribution of land, GDP growth originating in agriculture is up to four times more effective in raising incomes of extremely poor people than GDP growth originating outside the sector according to Ravallion, M., and Chen, S.. (2007).China’s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Journal of Development Economics 82(1):1–42 xcvi Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, Canada, the Republic of Korea, Spain and the United States of America xcvii IFAD, FAO, WFP, the World Bank, African Development Bank, Asian development Bank, Inter American Development Bank, and the IFC for the Private Sector window. xcviii CAADP Review, NEPAD, March 2010 Annex 1: Pledges and funds transferred to GAFSP Contributor Currency Total USD equivalent (# million) AUD CAD USD EUR EUR Amount pledged [Public/Private] (# million) 100.0 180/50 30.0 0.5 100 92.6 223.0 30.0 0.7 133.4 Amount transferred (as of (31/12/2011) 65.0 223 30.0 0.7 - Australia Canada Gates Found’n Ireland The Netherlands (all to private sector window) Korea Spain US USD EUR USD 50.0 70.0 450/25 50.0 93.4 475.0 29.0 93.4 166.4 * Australia has committed a further US$ 46.3mn, of which US$ 15.8mn has already been transferred, taking their total contribution to US$ 92.6mn. This second tranche of funding is still to be announced officially. (Information taken from GAFSP website) ANNEX 2: DEFINITION OF CORE INDICATORS IN GAFSP MONITORING AND EVALUATION PLAN Output 1: Higher yielding technologies developed 1. Number of collaborative research or extension sub-projects implemented 2. Number of client days of training provided to raise agricultural productivity (disaggregated by gender) 3. Number of client days of extension services provided to farmers, community members etc (disaggregated by gender) 4. Number of farmers who have adopted the technology being promoted Output 2: Improved infrastructure to support agriculture in place and operational 5. Number of additional hectares which have adopted the technology being promoted 6. Area with new irrigation and drainage services 7. Area with new improved/rehabilitated irrigation and drainage services 8. Number of water users provided with new/improved/rehabilitated irrigation and drainage services (disaggregated by gender) 9. Number of operational water user associations 10. Number of target population with use or ownership rights recorded (disaggregated by gender) in a manner recognized by national or customary law 11. Percent of target land area with use or ownership rights recorded in a manner recognized by national or customary law 12. Km of roads constructed (disaggregated by all-weather or seasonal) 13. Km of roads rehabilitated (disaggregated by all-weather or seasonal) 14. Number of targeted clients who are members of an association including producer association, cooperative, water user association, etc (disaggregated by gender) Output 3: Better functioning markets which farmers are able to access 15. Number of rural markets/market centers constructed 16. Volume of produce under improved post-harvest management 17. Number of private or public-private agro-processing facilities installed 19. Outstanding rural microfinance loan portfolio (amount US$) 20. Outstanding rural SME loan portfolio (amount US$) 21. Number of active microfinance loan accounts of holders domiciled in rural areas (disaggregated by gender of holder) 22. Number of active loan accounts of rural SMEs 23. ‘At-risk’ proportion of microfinance loan portfolio 24. ‘At-risk’ proportion of rural SMEs 25. Volume of food for which price risk has been managed using market based tools 26. Value of food for which price risk has been managed using market based tools 27. Number of systems introduced or restored to improve food security monitoring and early warning for weather-related risks Output 4: Rural people more resilient to shocks and able to build assets 28. Number and frequency of food security and crop assessment surveys conducted 29. Volume of production covered by risk mitigation programs directed towards vulnerable groups. 30. Number of households benefiting from cash transfer programs 31. Number of households receiving food-based transfers (disaggregated by gender, vulnerable groups) 32. % increase in production of fortified foods including complementary foods and special nutritional products 33. Number of people receiving improved nutrition services (e.g., Ready to Use Therapeutic Food [RUTFs], Vitamin A, micronutrients, bio-fortified foods), disaggregated by gender, age, vulnerable groups 34. Number of client days of non-farm related vocational training provided (disaggregated by gender) 35. Percentage of targeted clients satisfied with non-farm related vocational training provided (disaggregated by gender) Output 5: Institution-building and capacity development 36. Number of policies, strategies, frameworks or investment plans adopted 37. Number of public expenditure reviews published 38. Number of trained additional civil servants dedicated to sectoral planning and strategy 39. Number and percentage of community based organizations which reflect community interests and needs that actively participate in national or provincial level technical and policy bodies or project implementation related to food security or agriculture programs 40. Number of additional community based organizations‟ staff trained in institutional strengthening/sectoral planning and strategy 41. Number of participants in M&E workshops, training events, seminars, conferences etc. (disaggregated by gender and affiliation) 42. Number and cost of analytical reports published ANNEX 3: WORLD BANK METHODOLOGY FOR CALCULATING FOR TOTAL INCREASING IN INCOME RESULTING FROM 12 COUNTRY INVESTMENT PLANS APPROVED TO DATE US $ 100mn is the estimated income increase implied by a 20% rate of return on the US $ 481mn allocation to the 12 countries. The median economic rate of return from recent World Bank agriculture projects is 24%. As the WB is the supervising entity of 8 out of the 12 investment plans approved so far, it was considered to be indicative of likely returns across all 12 plans. In addition, the estimated economic returns to investments in the 5 GAFSP projects furthest forward in terms of detailed appraisal are: Bangladesh 21.4% (over 20 years); Togo 16.4 % (over 20 years); Ethiopia 19.9% (over 20 years); Rwanda 29% (over 50 years) and Sierra Leone 14.2% (over 20 years). The assumption used is that income increase begins only in Year 2 of project implementation when it will reach 20% of the expected full income increase. From Year 3, the assumption is an equal increase until Year 6 when the expected full target is reached. After Year 6 the expected full income increase is expected to remain for 14 years. Annexe 5 : Climate & Environment Assurance Note Intervention Details Title Home Department Budget Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP) Growth and Resilience Department (GRD) £76,000,000 over 3 years Responsible Officers Title Name Department Project Owner Climate Change and Environment Advisor Kenny Dick David Howlett GRD Climate and Environment Appraisal Success Criteria Resilience of people and communities, especially small holder farmers, to climate risks (present and future) Climate & Environment Category Risks & impacts Option 1 – Maintain current levels of support and delivery: B (medium risk) Option 2 – Support Global Agriculture and Food Security Programme (GAFSP) (medium risk) Option 3: - Support Private Sector Infrastructure Development Group (PIDG): B (medium risk) Option 4: Sector budget support in DFID target countries Sensitivity Analysis Carried out for all options Opportunities Option 1: C (No opportunities) Option 2: A (significant opportunities) Option 3: B (opportunity) Option 4: A (significant opportunities) Management Risks and opportunities defined Opportunities Climate & Environment Measures agreed Climate & Environment Measures in log-frame Options (2) and (4) provide significant opportunities. Option 1 does not present any extra opportunities, and option 3 while presenting similar opportunities described below due to PIDG not being focussed on agriculture and food security these will not be as great. Main opportunities are summarised below. A. Present and future climate risk is putting peoples’ food security at risk. Current climate risks of extreme weather events (floods and droughts), especially when accompanied by poverty, weak governance and lack of access to markets results in serious food security problems and potential long term impacts especially for women and children. Projects under GAFSP and under budget support have the potential to tackle these challenges, and to reduce the impact of agriculture on the environment (e.g. loss of biodiversity, reduced deforestation). A1. The programme will fund projects to help build resilience to present and future risks of smallholder farmers and their communities. Under GAFSP this can be strengthened by ensuring technical assessment include criteria on resilience and responding to climate change. Similar under framework for sector budget support should include these. A2. Indicators on resilience, climate change adaptation and sustainability should be part of GAFSP/sector budget support monitoring and evaluation. A3. DFID programme adviser(s) should work with the implementing agencies on developing M&E and indicators of country projects that capture climate change and environmental sustainability as part of output 5 (indicator - Agreed results frameworks for public and private sector window which can aggregate results across countries). B. Options 2 and 4 both have the opportunity to help improve policies and plans to build resilience, tackle climate risk and deliver more sustainable agriculture practices, and adaptation. These will have a positive impact especially where these policies are linked to national development and economic policies. B1. This can be strengthened at the national level by the mainstreaming of agriculture into the development of new strategies and plans on climate change, and development. This would include national adaptation and mitigation plans, climate compatible development plans. Option 4 under budget support is likely to be the best opportunity for this. B2. For GAFSP evidence and knowledge from the different programmes needs to be documented and shared as part of the knowledge management parts of the programme. Under output 1 the provision of improved agricultural technologies that produce higher yields indicators should be developed for projects to capture how these technologies will help farmers become more resilient to climate variability and future climate change, and help develop sustainable farming systems. These should identify how these impact on women and men. Under output 2 Infrastructure to support agriculture in place and operational project indicators on irrigation and roads targets need to capture that these are sustainable and are climate proof. Under output 4 management of risks and increased resilience to shocks it is expected this will include activities to respond to climate and environment risks. Log frames for projects should include indicators on these. No direct links in log frame but this will be part of output 5 on reform. C. Many practices that will be implemented under the programme can also reduce emissions of GHG and/or sequester carbon into soils and biomass. This includes soil and water conservation, biogas units, agroforestry and conservation agriculture. This provides an opportunity for significant mitigation co-benefits. C1. Projects under GAFSP are planning to capture data and information on practices to determine mitigation potential. This should be reported under overall GAFSP reporting, and this should be shared under its knowledge management and communication activities to help in building the evidence base for “climate smart/resilient agriculture”. Under output 1 the provision of improved agricultural technologies that produce higher yields indicators for projects can be developed to capture how much carbon has been sequestered and emissions reduced. C2. Option 4 could also develop system to capture data on reduced emissions and carbon sequestration but this would take longer and require significant resources in terms of capacity building. Thus early evidence on what projects can deliver would not be quickly available. Risks A. The main risk for options (2) to (4) would be that projects developed under these options focus on maximising food and crop production using practices that impact on the environment. This could also lead to the conversion of forests to agricultural use leading to an increase greenhouse gas emissions from this change in land use, loss of biodiversity, over use of water resources for irrigation, and environmental pollution from agrochemicals. B. Projects involving the construction of infrastructure (e.g. roads, irrigation and dams, and market and processing facilities all have potential negative environmental impacts. A1. Programme is designed to promote more sustainable and resilient agriculture, and therefore these risks should be avoided. But all major investments particularly in irrigation and intensive agriculture should be subject to separate environment assessments that meet international standards. DFID should ensure implementing agencies have effective climate change and environment policies in place. A2. Implementing agencies should report how projects have been assessed and where negative impacts identified what measures have been take to avoid or reduce these impacts. This should be part of the framework developed under output 5. B1. All projects developed under all option should be subject to separate environment assessments that meet international standards. Option 4 would also benefit from strategic environment assessment of policies and plans under budget support. B2. All infrastructure developed under all the options should use low carbon and energy efficient technologies. Not in logframe Under output 2 Infrastructure to support agriculture in place and operational project indicators on irrigation and roads targets need to capture how these are using low carbon technologies and designing energy efficient facilities that and are also climate proof. C. Options 2 to 4 require increased resources for travel, and programme activities. For financial (VFM) and environmental reasons these need to be reduced and increased energy use avoided where possible. C1. Implementing agencies to minimise resource use by improved working practices and reducing travel. This should be set out in their climate change and environment policies. C2. Implementing agencies should work with national partners to ensure that they either have, or are working to have, climate change and environmental management systems that meet national and international standards. Evidence Relevant documents Business case : Quest doc. 3677961 Logframe: Quest doc. 3254262 SIGNED OFF BY: David Howlett DATE: 1 October 2012 Not in log frame