Taxes and Labour Supply Theory, Evidence and Policy David Phillips (IFS) © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Outline 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. The Basics: Income, Substitution and Deadweight Loss Enriching the Model: Fixed costs and more Measurement Issues: Econometric Problems A Review of the Emprical Evidence Alternate Measures: Taxable Income Elasticities Policies: Mini Jobs for Lone Parents Conclusions © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 The Basics ‘Labour Supply’ is the supply of effort and time by individuals for monetary compensation. • • Working out revenue implications of tax reforms Working out the ‘optimal’ tax rate structure. Theoretical and empirical work has traditionally focused upon hours of work but more recently a recognition of: • • The participation decision (extensive margin) Effort and Compensation Form But what basic lessons can we use from Econ 101? © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Income and Substitution Effects NI Higher tax rate reduces the net income. Ifwage marginal leisure and is hence a normal the price good of anthis extra reduces hour of demandThis leisure. for leisure acts toand decrease increases Labour Labour supply. Supply. A A’ A’’ l H Tax has an ambiguous effect on Labour Supply © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Abolition of the 10p Starting Rate And Cutting Basic Rate to 20p NI Old Tax Schedule What about Labour Supply?? l H New Tax Schedule © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Abolition of the 10p Starting Rate And Cutting Basic Rate to 20p • • • • Those not working or earning less than the personal allowance are unaffected. Those previously paying starting rate have lower income (work more) but face a higher marginal rate (work less) – Ambiguous. Those paying basic rate and earning upto about £19,000 have lower income (work more) and a lower marginal rate (work more) – Work MORE. Those paying basic rate and earning more than £19,000 have higher income (work less) but face a lower marginal rate (work more) - Ambiguous © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Elasticity of Labour Supply There are two types of elasticity we are interested in: • The uncompensated elasticity. • The compensated elasticity. Linked together by the Slutsky Equation: εh = εm - [(w*h)/(w*T+y)]* εi εh = Compensated Elasticity εm= Uncompensated Elasticity εi = Income Elasticity y = Unearned Income © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 w = Wage h = hours of work T = time endowment Tax Rates and Tax Revenues The uncompensated elasticity determines revenue: Change in Revenue ≈ (1- εm)*(%Δ(1-t)w)*w*h*t NI Here a tax rise increases revenue but if labour supply is elastic would see a fall in revenue. A A’’ l H © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Tax Rates and Deadweight Loss When substitution occurs there is always deadweight loss. It is determined by the compensated elasticity. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 The Hours Distribution Now imagine a tax cut. The model predicts some not working will enter work and do 1 or 2 hours per week. Distribution of Male Hours (Aged 22 - 59, Employees Only) 20 18 16 14 Percentage 12 10 Percentage of Male Workers 8 6 But we don’t observe this... Why? 4 2 Hours © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 81 78 74 71 68 65 62 59 56 53 50 47 44 41 38 35 32 29 26 23 20 17 14 11 8 4 1 0 Adding Fixed Costs of Work When you start work there are certain fixed costs: Transport costs Work clothing costs Childcare costs And others NI A’ A H © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 l Fixed costs mean not working better than working few hours provided leisure and income are both ‘goods’ The Welfare System: Non Convexity The welfare system (benefits and tax credits) mean that people on low incomes can face very high effective marginal tax rates. This ‘non convexity’ causes similar discontinuous labour supply responses. NI Introducing nonconvexities (e.g. WFTC) can encourage ‘jumps’ in labour supply (e.g. From 10 to 30 hours) A’ A l H © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 The Family: Harmony or Bargaining? Unitary Model: Family is a single unit with a single utility function and behaviour of all members chosen to maximise this. Uf(c, li, lj) This implies: • Full income pooling • Symmetry of response to changes in other partners wage. Neither Hold Collective Model: Family as a group of individuals who engage in (paretoefficient) bargaining. This group of model allows one to extend models from just labour supply to looking at intra-household allocations of welfare. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Putting it together… hi = f(wi,wj, t, b, yi, yj, fi, fj, c, r) t = tax system f = fixed costs b = benefit system r = real interest rate Analysis of Labour supply can’t be done by a simple OLS regression of hours on wages because of the complexity of the budget constraint and substitution over time and within the household. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Econometric Issues (1)… You have data – a cross section of hours, wages and demographic characteristics. But theres a problem... People have different preferences for work/leisure. • Those who like work are likely to work longer hours. • They are also likely to work harder, engage in training more, have tried harder at school and are probably more able. Spurious positive correlation between hours and wages • If taxes exhibit increasing marginal rates, those working longer hours will face higher marginal rates and have lower net wages. Spurious negative correlation between hours and wages © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Econometric Issues (2)… ‘Second Generation’ models attempted to account for the downward bias induced by increasing marginal rates of tax. • very carefully modelled the tax system. • assume utility maximising and rational behaviour. People bunch at the ‘kinks’ as marginal rates change. Desired labour supply below kink at post-kink tax rate, and above kink at pre-kink tax rate. When you combine this with a linear labour supply model Restricts so that must estimate a positive uncompensated wage elasticity. H = α + βW + γY © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Econometric Issues (3)… Solutions: • Use time series changes in wages (potentially a panel data series). •Preferably have exogenous reforms – e.g. Reduction of top rates of income tax, introduction of E.I.T.C. • Remember to control for aggregate preference changes (e.g. Social acceptability of women working). E.G Blundell, Duncan & Meghir (1998) • Avoid modelling the complex tax system by using only women paying basic rate (nearly linear budget constraint). • Avoid preference problem by making use of changes in income distribution and tax reform in the 1980s. • Makes use in differential changes in post-tax wages for different cohorts and educational groups. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Econometric Issues (4)… Solutions: Treat labour supply as discrete (e.g. full time, part time, not work) and estimate income at these points using full tax and benefit system. E.G Meghir & Phillips (2008) • Men have a 1-0 choice of working or not, with income in work estimated as a weighted average of income at various hours points. • Use predicted wages for both non-workers and workers to account for (spurious) correlation of hours of work and pre-tax wages due to preferences. • Use the differential trends across regions in wages and housing benefits (out of work income) as exogenous changes in work incentives. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Elasticity Estimates (Female) Author(s) Basic Methodology Estimated Elasticities Wage: 0.906 – 0.995 Income: -0.121 – - 0.13 Hausman (1981) Linear labour supply with convex and nonconvex budget sets Cogan (1981) Log-linear labour Wage: 0.864 supply, fixed costs, Income: -0.16 linear budget constraint Blundell, Duncan and Meghir (1998) Log-linear labour supply, fixed costs, accounts for taxes and benefits. Wage: 0.13 – 0.37 Income: -0.06 – -0.19 Aaberge et al (1999) Flexible labour supply, taxes and benefits, supply and demand constraints Wage: 0.654 Income: -0.014 © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Elasticity Estimates (Male) Author(s) Basic Methodology Estimated Elasticities Ashenfelter & Heckman (1974) Labour supply linear in Wage: 0.06 differences. No account Income: -0.11 of taxes or benefits Bourgiugnon and Magnac (1990) Linear labour supply, convex budget with taxes and fixed costs Wage: 0.10 Income: -0.07 Blomquist & Newey (2002) Non-parametric and allowance for ‘small’ non-convexities Wage: 0.06 – 0.08 Income: -0.02 Meghir & Phillips (2008) Discrete choice with full ‘Wage’: 0.32 (low educ) tax and benefit 0.13 (mid educ) modelling and control 0.03 (high educ) for endogenous wages © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Other aspects of Labour Supply So far we have focused on hours but what about other aspects of labour supply? • intensity of effort (payment by results) • effort to seek promotion • investment in skills, education and complimentary capital If substitution is easier for effort/investment than for workhours hours elasticities underestimate welfare cost of taxation. Problem: we cannot measure effort... © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Taxable Income Elasticity (1) ... but we can measure income. Income reflects both hours of work and effort per hour. • It is a proxy for total effort. Two measures: • Broad Income – reflects changes in effort. • Taxable Income – reflects changes in effort but also shifts in income from taxable to non-taxable forms (tax avoidance) and tax evasion. Reallocation of income also entails welfare costs, and of course, revenue implications. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Taxable Income Elasticity (2) Main method of calculating taxable income elasticities is difference-in-differences. • Two groups – one affected by a change in tax rates (H), the other not (L). Elasticity = Elasticity = difference in % change in income ΔlnEH – ΔlnEL . Δln(1-tH) - Δln(1-tL) © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 . Taxable Income Elasticity (3) Problems with this methodology: • Mean Reversion E = μ + αt + Xi’β +Uit Some people in group H likely to have transitory high income, and vice versa. Revert to mean: expect high income to fall, low income to rise. Estimates of elasticity will be downwardly biased. • General Equilibrium Labour of different prices is probably labour of different ‘types’ to some extent. Increased supply of those benefiting from tax cut (e.g. High skilled) will depress price of this ‘type’, reducing income. Estimates of elasticity will be downwardly biased. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Taxable Income Elasticity (4) Problems with this methodology: • Secular Trends in Skills prices The price of various types of Labour may be changing for reasons other than tax reforms – e.g. trade or technological change. Varies, but in 1980s/1990s, elasticity will be upwardly biased. • Timing If a tax rise (or cut) is announced, people will bring forward (or put back) income if they have such flexibility – e.g. Bonuses, dividends, capital gains. Estimates of elasticity upwardly biased unless account for these ‘timing’ effects. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Elasticity Estimates Author(s) Basic Methodology Estimated Elasticities Feldstein (1995) No controls 1.1 (Low Income) 3.05 (High Income) Goolsbee (1999) No controls. - 1.3 to 2.0 depending on reform. Gruber & Saez (2000) Includes (lagged) log income, trends and a 10-piece spline. 0.12 (Broad Income) 0.4 (Taxable Income) 0.57 (High) 0.12 (Low) © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Reforming Support for Lone Parents Fewer than 60% of lone parents employed versus about 70% of mothers in couples: • Similar number of lone parents working 16+ hours. • But far fewer lone parents working 1 – 15 hours. Why? No incentive to do so: • Income Support is Tapered away at 100% above earnings of £20 a week. • Housing Benefit and Council tax have tapers of 65% and 20%. When combined with income tax, tapers of over 95%. • No working tax credit (WTC) unless you work 16 hours per week. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 The Gains of Labour... £470 Weekly family income net of taxes, benefits and tax credits, rent and council tax £325 £300 £445 £275 £420 £250 £395 £225 £370 £200 £345 £175 £320 With rent and CT £150 £295 No rent or CT £125 £270 Second earner Weekly hours worked .. are less for lone parents for 8 – 16 hours. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 £245 0 £100 .. and they face high effective tax rates 0.7000 0.6000 Participation tax rate 0.5000 0.4000 0.3000 0.2000 Lone Parent 0.1000 Second earner in couple with children 0.0000 0 10 20 30 Weekly Hours Worked © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 40 50 Making ‘mini jobs’ Pay... IFS and One Parent Families were asked by the Joseph Rowntree Foundation to look at ways of improve work incentives. • Giving WTC to lone parents working less than 16 hours per week. • Increasing the earnings disregard for income support and other means-tested benefits. • Reducing the taper rate on income support and other means-tested benefits. - does more to encourage jobs with higher rates of pay. - but administratively more burdensome as still need to know about small changes in income. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Modelling Lone Parent’s Labour Supply... Model used is: • estimated using repeated cross sections from the Family Resources Survey (FRS) – roughly 17,000 lone parents. • uses cross-sectional and time-series (policy reforms) variation in work incentives. • discrete choice: not work, 1 – 15 hours, 16 – 23, 24 – 29, 30 – 37, 38+. • income estimated at each of these choices. • they take up all benefits and tax credits entitled to. • use of childcare determined by family circumstances and hours – not price or subsidies. • repeatedly draw a prediction for each lone parent to get weights for each hours choice, before and after reform. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Results Cost (no Ls) Cost (with Ls) Change in Earnings Less than 16 hours 16 – 29 hours 30 + hours £85 million £175 million - £118 million +2.10 -0.54 -0.57 Increase Income £269 Support, HB and million CTB disregard to £50. £278 million + £71 million +2.19 +0.66 -0.56 Increase Income Support, HB and CTB disregard to £88.32 (16*MW) £791 million + £317 million +3.55 +2.71 -0.86 Policy Reduce WTC hours from 16 to 8 £735 million WTC reduces average hours, offsetting extra tax credits. Increased disregards also encourage 16 – 30 hours work, increasing average hours and earnings. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Conclusions (1) • Income and substitution effects can give some important insights (e.g. the ‘10p tax’). - But non-convexities and fixed costs means can see ‘jumps’ in Labour supply in response to reforms. • Compensated versus uncompensated elasticities - Tax rises have an ambiguous effect on labour supply and revenue but always entail deadweight loss. • Estimation of model made difficult due to complex budget constraint and unobserved preferences for work. - Use exogenous variation in incentives due to secular wage changes or tax reforms as basis of estimation. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Conclusions (2) • Estimated responsiveness varies by group - Low for men - Higher for women, particularly lone parents - Participation decision particularly sensitive • Taxable Income Elasticities - Picks up effort and reallocation of income - But problems if simple diff-in-difference techniques used. • Example: Lone Parents and Mini-jobs. - Lone parents face poor incentives to enter work at low hours. - Reforms to benefits and tax credits can have a big impact on labour supply for this sensitive group. © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Main Readings C. Meghir & D. Phillips (2008) – Labour Supply and Taxes http://www.ifs.org.uk/wps/wp0804.pdf K. Bell, M. Brewer & D. Phillips (2007) – Lone Parents and Mini-jobs http://www.jrf.org.uk/bookshop/eBooks/2110-lone-parents-minijobs.pdf © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008 Additional References Aaberge, Colombino, Strom (1999) "Labour Supply in Italy: An Empirical Analysis of Joint Household Decisions with Taxes and Quantity Constraints", Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol 14. No 4. Ashenfelter & Heckman (1974) "The Estimation of Income and Substitution Effects in a model of Family Labor supply", Econometrica, Vol 42, No 1 Blomquist & Newey (2002), "Nonparametric Estimation with Nonlinear Budget Constraints", Ecometrica, Vol. 70, No. 6 Blundell, Duncan, Meghir, (1992), "Taxation in Empricial Labour Supply Models: Lone Mothers in the UK", The Economic Journal, Vol 102, No 411 Blundell, Duncan, Meghir (1998) "Estimating Labor Supply Responses using Tax Reforms, Econometrica, Vol 66, No 4 Bourguignon & Magnac (1990) "Labor Supply and Taxation in France", The Journal of Human Resources, Vol 25, No 3 Cogan (1981), "Fixed Costs and Labor Supply", Econometrica, Vol 49, No 4 Feldstein (1995), "The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Taxable Income: a Panel study of the 1986 Tax Reform Act", Journal of Political Economy, Vol 103, No 3 Goolsbee (1999) "Evidence on the High-Income Laffer Curve from Six Decades of Tax Reform", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol 1999, No 2 Gruber & Saez (2000) "The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications", NBER Working Paper Series Hausman (1981), Labour Supply: How Taxes affect Economic Behaviour", Tax and the Economy, Brookings Institute © Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2008