Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government Class Number/Section Class Number: 2157 Section: 4 The Value of POSC 100 - 1 Government and Politics Impact almost Every Area of Our Lives We will examine about as important a group of questions as possible: The Value of POSC 100 - 2 1 – Why Have Government? 2 – How Representative of the Views of Americans are Governmental Policies and Actions? The Value of POSC 100 - 3 3 – How Fair are the Policies American Governments Produce? 4 – How do Governmental Policies and Actions Affect the Degree of Freedom Americans Possess? NOTE: Goals May Clash! What’s Good for Fairness May Not Be Good for Freedom Content of POSC 100 - 1 Three Sections of the Course: 1. The Need, Purpose, Structure and Performance of Government 2. Mass Politics and Un-Elected Policymakers Content of POSC 100 - 2 3. Elected Policy-Makers and Public Policy Approach the material in each of these three sections from the standpoint of REPRESENTATION, FAIRNESS and FREEDOM CONDUCT!!! If you stay in this class you are agreeing to the following rules: (1) Come on Time - if you’re late you must sit on the end in a back row; (2) Stay the Whole Time - if you must leave early (e.g., doctor’s appointment) you need to let me know at the beginning of class; (3) No Talking Unless You are Responding to Me or Another Student’s Comments. CONDUCT!!! The previous rules are all mentioned in the syllabus. You’ll be sanctioned if you don’t follow them. Beginning with the second class meeting and omitting exam days, each student will receive 1 bonus point on their next exam for each class period I don’t have to call someone out for talking in class, leaving class early or arriving late and trying to sit in other than the last couple rows. CONDUCT!!! Either every student receives the possible bonus point for that class meeting or no student receives it. For example, Exam #1 is on the 9th class meeting. Therefore, there are a maximum of 7 bonus points each student could receive on Exam #1 (i.e., 1 point for each class meeting between meetings 2 and 8). If class is cancelled the bonus point will be awarded. There are no bonus points for the final exam or the quizzes. POSC 100 – Grading - 1 As the syllabus, which is in the coursepack [and is available at my website: http://web.csulb.edu/~cdennis/ (click on “Courses”)] discusses, your grade is based upon four equally weighted components: POSC 100 – Grading - 2 Your best two performances on Exams 13. Thus, you poorest performance on Exams 1-3 is dropped. Which of the following is your worst test? (your score/lowest A) 90/88 91/93 88/85 POSC 100 – Grading - 3 The Final Exam counts the same as each of Exams 1-3, however, the Final Exam CANNOT be dropped. The last component of your grade is your total score on a series of UNANNOUNCED QUIZZES. Your lowest two scores are dropped. POSC 100 – Grading - 4 Missed Exams and Quizzes: If you miss one of Exams 1-3, for ANY REASON, that is AUTOMATICALLY the exam you drop. The first two missed quizzes (regardless of the reason you missed) are AUTOMATICALLY dropped. POSC 100 – Grading - 5 Thus, to qualify for a makeup exam you would have to miss two of the first three exams and have a valid excuse posted with me within one week of the second missed exam. To qualify for a makeup quiz you would have to miss three quizzes and have a valid excuse posted with me within one week of the third missed quiz. POSC 100 – Grading - 6 Grades in this section will be like the typical POSC 100 class – about 2.6 on a 4 point scale POSC 100 – Course Materials- 1 You Will Need the Following Materials from: http://web.csulb.edu/~cdennis/ (CLICK ON “COURSES”) 1. The Coursepack – Contains the Syllabus, Study Guides and Reading Material Used Later in the Course; 2. Introductory Email/Textbook Information 3. PowerPoint slides POSC 100 – Course Materials- 2 Textbooks: 1. Thomas Patterson, The American Democracy, 9-11th alternate edition (note it’s the “alternate” edition) 2. Lawrence L. Giventer, Governing California, 2nd edition Both are bound together in the CSULB Bookstore. Buying earlier editions can cause you to miss exam questions. POSC 100 – Course Materials- 3 By the beginning of next week you will need to read the first of a series of weekly newspaper columns. Each column will state the days quiz questions could come from that column. No questions on the exams will be taken from the newspaper columns. All the newspaper columns are currently available at my website under POSC 100 - “Newspaper Columns.” Newspaper Columns The Newspaper Columns file is password protected. Since the password is not available in any of the material you can download you need to write it down. POSC 100 – Course Materials- 3 For each newspaper column be able to do the following: (1) summarize the column in two sentences; and (2) explain why the column was important enough that I assigned it. If you can do these two things you should be able to answer any question I’ll ask from the newspaper columns. Make Use of Me! I. Office Hours: M, W 9:00-9:30, 10:4511:00, 1:50-2:20 in SPA-241 II. Phone: See Email I Sent Containing My Phone Number (which isn’t available in downloadable material) - call times: 3:00-4:00 Tuesday, Thursday, Friday, Saturday and Sunday (No Messages - I Don’t Return Phone Calls) Call – Email Isn’t Good for Questions Make Use of Me! III. The Phone is a Method of Helping You Understand the Lectures. It’s NOT a Method of Avoiding Class or NOT taking Notes when You’re in Class. When You Call, I Will Typically Ask, “What Do Your Notes Say?” I’m Here to Help People Who are Making the Effort to Attend Class and Take Notes. Make Use of Me! You can download ALL of the PowerPoint slides for this course at my website (look under the appropriate course). However, knowing these slides is NOT NEARLY sufficient. The slides are outlines and DO NOT contain much of the lecture material that is on the quizzes and tests. I’m glad to help you but for that to happen you’ll need to take notes in class. Need for Government - 1 I. NEED FOR GOVERNMENT A. Free Market: voluntary exchanges between mutually consenting individuals B. Capitalism: private ownership of production and distribution C. THE FREE MARKET/CAPITALISM NEEDS GOVERNMENT!!! Need for Government - 2 1. Without the government DEFINING what constitutes private property (e.g., the air waves), the SCOPE of private property (e.g., the sidewalk on your property is not under your control) and PROTECTING private property rights (e.g., by the police) the free market/capitalism COULDN’T function. Need for Government - 3 2. To Provide Public Goods – Characteristics of Public Goods: a. No one is excluded Need for Government - 4 b. One person’s consumption of the good does not reduce the amount available for someone else. Need for Government - 5 1. Examples: (a) Clean Air – Why would one individual, or group, provide it if everyone else could benefit for free? (b) National Defense – Would you want private individuals to control nuclear weapons? (c) Tennessee Valley Authority (d) Some Medical Research Need for Government – 6A 3. Economic Regulation a. Natural Monopolies - Government regulation to counteract price gouging by monopolies b. Where harm is caused by agents who don’t bear the true cost of their action – e.g., individuals and firms that pollute justify a carbon tax Need for Government – 6B c. Government Regulation can help the free market perform better. 1. One of the assumptions of the free market is that both buyers and sellers have perfect market knowledge. Need for Government – 6C 2. Government regulations requiring restaurants to list the fat and calorie content of their meals on menus means that customers have better information upon which to base their decisions. 3. While restaurant owners may not like the requirement it fits perfectly with the assumptions of a free market. Need for Government - 7 4. Macroeconomic Management a. Countercyclical spending to offset a recession 1. Balancing the federal budget during a recession would be a disaster! Need for Government - 8 b. Employer of Last Resort 1. The goal of a business is profit NOT providing jobs. 2. Because government is NOT profit driven, it can create jobs when it is NOT economically profitable for the private sector to do so. Need for Government - 9 3. It’s well documented that persistent unemployment results in a permanent loss of output and labor productivity. 4. The U.S. had successful government employment programs during the Great Depression of the 1930s. So have many other nations. Need for Government - 10 5. Social Values a. The ingenuity of capitalism’s “creative destruction” means that business CANNOT pursue social values/goals over profitability. Thus, the very strength of capitalism is a prime reason why it can be argued that a strong social safety net is absolutely necessary. b. Example: Increasing Income Inequality Need for Government - 11 Share of Income Going to the Richest 1% of American Households: 1970 – 9.0% 1990 -14.3% 2012- 21.5% The above figures are about TWICE as high as in Europe. Should Government Reduce this Huge Increase in Inequality? Need for Government - 12 c. Effects of Globalization or Internationally Mobile Capital on the Rich and Poor 1. The internet/advanced communications permits emerging nations to rapidly import new technologies. Need for Government - 13 2.Opening nations such as China to international trade greatly increased the supply of low skill workers which reduced the income of low skill/income Americans. 3. Governments have competed for capital by lowering taxes, labor standards and government regulation of business. Need for Government - 14 4. Lowered labor costs reduce product prices which much more benefits high income Americans whose income aren’t reduced much by international competition. 5. Thus, a very good case can be made that the “winners” under this scenario should compensate the “losers.” Need for Government - 15 d. In a private market each person’s “worth” is determined by how much money they have whereas in a political market each voter has one vote. Thus, votes are distributed more equally than money. Need for Government - 16 e. Therefore, the electoral incentives of government produce a distribution of goods/services that more favors middle and low income groups than occurs in a private market. f. This is one fundamental reason why liberals like government more than conservatives. Need for Government – 17 6. Lack of Information Example: Health Care Need for Government - 18 Comparison of U.S. and Foreign Health Care Systems (2009-2013) Per Capita WHO Spending Ranking U.S. $8,895 37th France $4,690 1st Canada $5,741 30th U.K. $3,647 18th Need for Government - 19 What incentive do U.S. insurance companies, pharmaceutical companies, and physicians have to tell you the preceding information? POSC 100 – Course Materials The Coursepack – Contains the Syllabus, Study Guides and Reading Material Used Later in the Course – is available at: www.csulb.edu/~cdennis (Click on “Courses”) Structure of Government - 1 I. Government Under the Articles of Confederation A. Unanimous Vote of the States Needed to Amend 1. Is Unanimity Necessary for Representation? Structure of Government - 2 B. National Government Couldn’t Require States to Pay Taxes 1. If some states don’t pay, is this fair? C. No President or Supreme Court Structure of Government - 3 D. Military Security Needs in the West and the Recession in the Northeast Pitted Region against Region. 1. The national government couldn’t get a unanimous vote. So these crises weren’t solved. 2. Representation? Fairness? Structure of Government - 4 II. The Constitutional Convention A. Philosophy of James Madison 1. Freedom “To” (action – e.g., speech) vs. Freedom “From” (e.g., food stamps - government protects you from starving) Structure of Government - 5 2. The Constitution is mainly concerned with protecting the “freedom to.” B. Philosophy of John Rawls 1. Equal right to the most extensive system of liberties consistent with the guarantee of the same liberties for all. Structure of Government - 6 2. Any social and economic inequalities should redound to the benefit of society’s least advantaged individuals. C. How would you compare Madison and Rawls on “fairness” and “representation”? Structure of Government - 7 D. For Madison, Government was the Major Threat to the "Freedom To“ (e.g., Congress shall make no law abridging freedom of speech) 1. Government can be an extender of the “freedom to.” Structure of Government - 8 2. Economic Inequality was not a major concern of Madison. 3. Compared to the Democracies of Western Europe, the U.S. is a low tax, low social service country. Structure of Government - 9 Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies: U.S. – 32.2%, Canada – 38.3%, Great Britain – 41.2%, Germany – 44.6%, Italy – 47.8%, Sweden – 50.9%, France – 52.9% and Denmark – 57.4%. Source: OECD as reported in NY Times 11/16/14 Structure of Government – 10A Federal Taxes as a percentage of our economy are lower today than they have been in over 60 years. 1951- 16.1 % (before Medicare enacted) 1971 – 17.3% 2001 – 19.5% 2011 – 15.4% Structure of Government – 10B Effective Tax Rates on Income of $100,000 in 2012 Nation Income Tax Social Security U.S. – 26.0% 18.7% 7.3% G. Brit.- 31.4% 24.1% 7.3% Sweden- 36.3% 36.3% 0% France – 42.0% 20.0% 22.0% Germany-43.8% 28.3% 15.5% Structure of Government – 10C Government Mandated Paid Annual Leave and Paid Days of Vacation U.S. - 0 Great Britain - 20 Sweden - 25 German - 30 France - 31 Structure of Government - 11 E. Fearing Government, the Founders Made it Difficult for the Government to Act. 1. Separation of Powers a. Parliamentary Systems combine executive and legislative power Structure of Government - 12 b. Parliamentary Systems encourage more issue oriented voting than Presidential systems c. U.S. uses a “winner-take-all” (candidate with most votes wins) rather than proportional (a party receives seats equal to it’s share of the vote) system to elect representatives. Structure of Government - 13 e. States with approximately 11% of the U.S. population elect a sufficient number of senators (42) to prevent legislation. d. Winner-take-all systems typically produce less government spending to help the poor than proportional systems. 1. The closer middle class voters’ incomes are to the poor, the more the political power of the poor increases. Structure of Government - 14 2.Checks and Balances 3. Federalism Structure of Government - 15 a. Strengths of Federalism 1.Little Centralized Leadership 2.Increases Participation (offers more offices/chances for citizens to participate in holding/selecting offices) Structure of Government - 16 3. Increases Policy Responsiveness more decisions are made locally 4. Encouraging Policy Innovation-States are viewed as “laboratories of democracy” Structure of Government - 17 b. Weaknesses of Federalism 1. Obstructing National Policies – e.g., protected slavery (might be “responsive” to a local area that desired slavery but definitely not “fair” to slaves) Structure of Government - 18 2. Allows Great Inequalities between States (fairness?) 3. Confusion: In a crisis what level of government is responsible? 4. Representation: citizens typically are better informed about national than local issues – local decisions more favor the advantaged Structure of Government - 19 F. While Liberty (through Private Property) was Written into the Constitution, a Bill of Rights was Not. Why? Structure of Government - 20 III. Interpretation and Change Under the Constitution A. Flexibility – The Minnesota Moratorium Act 1. Fairness? Structure of Government - 21 B. Formal Amendment C. Judicial Review 1. Marbury v. Madison (1803) Structure of Government - 22 D. Informal Change – Reinterpreting the Same Words 1. Heart of Atlanta Motel (1965) 2. Fairness? Structure of Government – 23 IV. National Supremacy A. McCulloch v. Maryland (1819) California Constitution - 1 I. California’s Constitution Contains Over 6 Times as Many Words as the U.S. Constitution A. California Constitution is Frequently Amended California Constitution - 2 1. U.S. Constitution is Difficult to Amend whereas the California Constitution is Easy to Amend 2. Only 8% of California Voters Need to Sign Petition to put a Constitutional Amendment on the Ballot California Constitution - 3 3. A Constitutional Initiative only Needs a Majority Vote to Pass B. Focus of the U.S. Constitution is on the Structure of Government and the Fundamental Law California Constitution - 4 C. By Contrast, the California Constitution details both Law and Policy (e.g., K-12 Spending Formula) D. Constitutional Restrictions have made it Very Difficult to Enact a Budget and Raise Taxes California Constitution - 5 E. Impact on Representation and Fairness 1. Ease of Amending the California Constitution Increases the Likelihood of Discrimination (e.g., Proposition 8) California Constitution - 6 2. The Initiative Process itself Makes it Much Easier for Special Interests to Skew Public Policy in their Interests. a. Monetary Cost of a Successful Ballot Initiative California Constitution - 7 b. An Initiative Passed with a Majority Vote can Require a Future 2/3rds Vote to Override it. 1. Effects raising taxes and fees, and hence, the California Budget. Civil Rights - 1 VI. Civil Rights A. The UNELECTED Supreme Court acted BEFORE Popularly Elected Officials 1. Representation? Fairness? Civil Rights - 2 2. Proposition 14 – 1964 3. Proposition 8 – 2008 B. Least “Threatening” Civil Rights Laws Enacted First. Civil Rights - 3 C. Civil Rights helped trigger a large realignment of voters. Judicial Selection - 1 I. Judicial Appointment A. Constitutional protections require an independent (non-elected) judiciary 1. The Constitution and public law may not be popular but they must be defended. B. This is why federal judges are appointed, NOT ELECTED. Judicial Selection - 2 C. It is also why federal judges serve for life D. Federal judges are appointed not on the basis of the popularity of their views, but on the basis of their ability to think clearly about legal and Constitutional questions Judicial Selection – 3 E. DON’T WRITE THE FOLLOWING STATEMENTS FROM PRESIDENTIAL CANDIDATES. JUST READ THEM AND THINK HOW THEY WOULD CHANGE OUR COURT SYSTEM. 1. “Appointees to the federal bench will not receive lifetime appointment” - Rick Perry Judicial Selection - 4 2. “Sign a bill tomorrow to eliminate the 9th Circuit” (U.S. Court of Appeals) - Rick Santorum 3. Newt Gingrich has called for impeaching judges, abolishing judgeships and even eliminating courts whose rulings he dislikes. (Los Angeles Times – 12/20/11 – A21) Judicial Philosophies - 1 I. Judicial Philosophies A. Preferred Freedoms 1. Court should actively look for cases where the rights of a minority may have been violated. Judicial Philosophies - 2 2. If there is a conflict, noneconomic freedoms are “preferred” over economic freedoms. 3. To restrict a preferred freedom, the burden of proof is on the restrictor, who must show a clear and imminent danger. Judicial Philosophies - 3 Free Speech Standards Violent Overthrow of the Government Clear and Imminent Danger Clear and Present Danger Bad Tendency Doctrine Judicial Philosophies - 4 B. Judicial Self-Restraint 1. The judiciary should “restrain itself” from declaring many laws unconstitutional Judicial Philosophies - 5 2. Since the constitution doesn’t seem to “prefer” certain freedoms all freedoms are equal. 3. No “fixed” standard for cases involving what some term “preferred freedoms.” Judicial Philosophies - 6 C. Democratic justices are typically closer to the “Preferred Freedoms” model than Republican Justices. D. Since cases often involve conflicting values/points of law, judicial philosophy inevitably becomes important. Judicial Philosophies - 7 E. State Courts: Democratic judges are more likely to side with the economically less advantaged party and find a violation of the rights of the accused than Republican judges. 1. Exception: Democrats favor the government in tax cases – Why? Civil Liberties - 1 I. Civil Liberties A. Well-Protected by the Constitution and the Courts B. Reduced Somewhat During Popular National Wars Civil Liberties - 2 C. Many of the Most Important Cases Occur During War Periods D. Free Speech Examples 1. Schenck v. U.S. (1919) Civil Liberties - 3 2. Dennis v. U.S. (1951) 3. Tinker v. Des Moines (1969) Civil Liberties - 4 E. Freedom of Press Examples 1. Near v. Minnesota (1931) 2. New York Times v. U.S. (1971) Civil Liberties - 5 F. Religious Freedom 1. Each religious sect wanted its religion to be the Established Religion a. This is still what some American religious fundamentalists would like b. It is the basis of the governments of Saudi Arabia and Iran Civil Liberties - 6 2. Above all, each sect’s members feared that if one of the other denominations got control over the government that they would have to obey that other false religion’s laws (this is why they had emigrated to the American colonies) 3. Members of other religions increasingly fear discrimination and loss of rights Civil Liberties - 7 4. Most large scale civil wars and civil conflicts today have something to do with religious disputes 5. The second-best solution = no group’s religion gets to be the Established Religion Civil Liberties - 8 G. Religious Freedom is so Important that the 1st Amendment Contains Two Clauses Protecting Religious Freedom 1. Free Exercise Clause 2. Establishment Clause Civil Liberties - 9 a. Wall of Separation between Church and State 1. No connection/relationship between government and religion Civil Liberties - 10 c. No-Preference Standard 1. Government and religion can have some relationship as long as all religions are treated equally. Civil Liberties - 11 2. Government provided bus rides to religious schools viewed as an aid to education, not religion. 3. Can’t have government officials write prayers or have prayers spoken in class denominationally neutral prayer is impossible. Civil Liberties - 12 What words would the prayer contain? Whom to pray to? Are teachers allowed to use sacred objects: rosaries, prayer rugs? When to pray? Individually or in groups? Silently or aloud? Civil Liberties - 13 3. Los Angeles County Seal/Christian Cross Over a Military Cemetary Juries - 1 I. Legal Standards Juries Use A. Criminal Cases – Beyond a Reasonable Doubt 1. If you think there is an 80% the defendant is guilty you should vote “not guilty” (20% is NOT beyond a reasonable doubt). Juries - 2 B. Civil Cases – A Preponderance of the Evidence Juries - 3 II. Decision-Making A. The Missouri Juror – Show me the evidence B. The Neighborhood Watch Juror – Looks for suspicious activity Juries - 4 III. Jury Service A. California uses a “one day or one trial” system. B. Don’t be disappointed if your background disqualifies you from serving on a particular jury . Preparing for the Exam - 1 1. Be able to answer the study guide questions on page 10 of the coursepack (www.csulb.edu/~cdennis click on “Courses”) 2. Be able to explain any concept or term on the slides and why that concept or term was important enough to be discussed. Preparing for the Exam - 2 3. Be able to “compare and contrast” concepts. For example, what are the similarities and differences between a presidential system and a parliamentary system? Beginning of Section II The material for Exam #2 begins with the next slide. Political Opinion - 1 I. Public Opinion A. Economic and Noneconomic B. Abstract and Specific Public Opinion - 2 1. Basic rule: People give more tolerant or “democratic" responses in the abstract than they do in the specific. C. Liberal and Conservative 1.Relative not Absolute Definitions Public Opinion - 3 2. Liberal - greater commitment to reducing economic inequality and maintaining economic security/greater support for the noneconomic freedom to differ Public Opinion - 4 3. Conservative – greater individual free choice-less commitment to equality in economics/less commitment to the freedom to differ in noneconomics Public Opinion - 5 D. If Asked Their Political Orientation Conservatives Outnumber Liberals Two to One. 1. Symbolic Conservatism (they say they’re “conservative”) but Operational Liberalism (support greater government spending on education, health care, etc.) Public Opinion - 6 2. Conservatives have, with much success, attempted to switch the notion of an “elite” from an economic elite (which politically hurts conservatives) to a cultural elite (which politically helps conservatives). a. Sarah Palin/Rick Santorum – the well-educated are “against us” Public Opinion - 7 E. Public support for greater government spending on social welfare programs moves opposite the partisanship of the president (e.g., public support for more government spending on environmental protection increases under Republican presidents because the public feels the Republicans aren’t very environmentally oriented). Public Opinion - 8 F. Citizens Often Hold Competing Values Such as Freedom and Equality (e.g., desiring both tax cuts and increased government services) 1. Public opinion can often be easily manipulated. Public Opinion - 9 G. Public Opinion is Individually Irrational but Collectively Rational 1. Most people don’t follow politics closely and aren’t well-informed. However, a small group of voters are well-informed and this means that overall opinion moves in a rational manner. Public Opinion - 10 H. Political Parties and Voters - Specific Issue Positions – “Four-Celled Diagram” The Voters: Economic - Liberal/ Noneconomic -Conservative Public Opinion - 11 Democratic Party: Economic – Liberal/ Noneconomic – Liberal Public Opinion - 12 Republican Party: Economic – Conservative/ Noneconomic – Conservative Public Opinion - 13 Libertarians – Economic – Conservative/ Noneconomic – Liberal Since political support is often based upon intolerance, libertarianism will have difficulty building much mass support. Public Opinion - 14 I. Relationship Between Socioeconomic Status (SES) and Political Opinions 1. Socioeconomic Status - income, education and occupational status Public Opinion - 15 2. Economic Issues – Negative Association - As SES increases support for liberal positions decreases Public Opinion - 16 3. Noneconomic Issues - Positive Association – As SES increases support for liberal positions increases Public Opinion - 17 4. Typically, a party will “frame” an issue as an issue they “own.” Democrats would frame universal health care as either security for workers losing insurance and/or fairness, while the Republicans would frame universal health care as either a tax increase and/or the size and scope of government (i.e., “big government”). Public Opinion - 18 a. Republicans are perceived as better able to handle foreign policy and defense issues, reducing taxes, controlling inflation, reducing government spending, reducing crime and promoting moral values than Democrats. Public Opinion - 19 b. Conversely, Democrats are perceived as better able to handle social welfare policies and/or “fairness” issues such as protecting Social Security, improving health care, helping the poor, supporting public schools, reducing unemployment, solving farm problems, and protecting the environment than Republicans. Public Opinion - 20 J. Public Support for the Bush Tax Cuts A. 40% of the benefits go to the wealthiest 1% of households (annual income above $370,000) – this is equal to the amount received by the poorest 70% of households COMBINED! Public Opinion - 21 1. 75% of households LOSE under the Bush Tax Cuts a. Mean Cut - $1,199 Median Cut - $217 2. People Overly Upwardly Identify (19% thought they were in the top 1%) Public Opinion - 22 B. Those FAVORING greater government spending more FAVORED the Bush Tax Cuts - SEE THE CONTRADICTION? 1.Similarily half of California voters think the state’s budget could be reduced 20% WITHOUT reducing services. Public Opinion - 23 C. The MORE One Thinks Their OWN Tax Burden is Too High the MORE they SUPPORT the Bush Tax Cuts - SEE THE CONTRADICTION? D. The Public Simply Doesn’t Connect the Bush Tax Cuts to Either Other Public Policies (services cutbacks, higher interest rates) or Inequality. Public Opinion on Income Inequality - 1 The next several slides show what groups in the United States, Japan and Sweden think is the actual and fair degree of income inequality between an executive and an auto worker. Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 2 – United States Perceived Income Republicans 13.2/1 Democrats 15.4/1 Fair Income 11.3/1 8.2/1 Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 3 - Japan Conservative Party Left Parties Perceived Income 7.1/1 Fair Income 5.4/1 10.3/1 3.7/1 Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 4 - Sweden Conservative/ Center Party Left Party Perceived Income Fair Income 2.2/1 2.1/1 3.2/1 1.9/1 Political Participation - 1 I. Political Participation A. Types of Political Participation Political Participation - 2 B. Who Participates? 1. Basic rule: while voting is positively related to socioeconomic status (SES) non-voting forms of political participation are even more strongly positively related to socioeconomic status. Political Participation - 3 C. “60-30-10” Diagram 1. SES Composition of the Highest Participating One-Fifth of Adult Americans Political Participation - 4 Highest 1/3 SES - 60% Middle 1/3 SES - 30% Lowest 1/3 SES - 10% Political Participation - 5 D. Consequences 1.Message Received: Too Economically Conservative and Socially Liberal Political Participation - 6 E. Comparison 1. Only In India was the Relationship between SES and Participation as Strong as in the U.S. Political Participation - 7 F. Why? 1. Relative Absence of Class-Related Politics in the U.S. 2. Relative Lack of Work Organizations/Unions in the U.S. Political Parties - 1 I. Why Political Parties are Important A. Provide Candidates for Office 1. Importance of opposing candidates – even in lopsided elections Political Parties - 2 B. Provide Policy Alternatives 1. Election should provide a referendum on policy 2. Information Reduction Device for Voters Political Parties - 3 2008 Presidential Candidates L= AFL-CIO (Labor) E = League of Conservation Voters (Environment) Political Parties – 3 (continued) DON’T WRITE DOWN THE NUMBERS THAT APPEAR ON THE NEXT SEVERAL SLIDES. I’M ONLY INTERESTED IN WHAT THE NUMBERS MEAN – THE PATTERN OF THE NUMBERS - NOT THE NUMBERS THEMSELVES. Political Parties - 4 Democratic - 2008 Edwards L E Clinton L E Obama L E 97% 88% 94% 87% 98% 86% 2004 Democratic Ave. LCV – 85% Political Parties – 5A Republican - 2008 McCain Thompson L E L E 17% 24% 8% 6% 2004 Republican Ave. LCV – 10% Note: McCain Changed Virtually Every Moderate Position to Appease the Republican base: Bush Tax Cuts, Off Shore Drilling, etc. Political Parties – 5B Republican - 2012 Gingrich Santorum Paul Ryan L E L 10% 29% L 13% E L E E 0% 18% 30% 14% 24% NOTE: Gingrich’s record became consistently less environmental over time. In 1995 the LCV called the Gingrich-led legislative agenda “an environment train wreck.” Political Parties – 5C Republican - 2016 Paul Rubio Graham L E L E L E 4% 9% 6% 9% 16% 11% Cruz L E 0% 11% Kasich L E 0% 13% Jindal L E 21% 6% Political Parties – 5D Democratic - 2016 Clinton Sanders Warren L E L E L E 94% 87% 98% 95% 100% 94% Biden L E 85% 83% Warner L E 86% 89% Webb L E 95% 81% Political Parties - 6 C. Accountability 1. G. H. W. Bush–No New Taxes Pledge 2. Republicans in California after Republican defections in the state legislature over 2009 budget Political Parties - 7 3. Most Party Platform Pledges are Honored Political Parties - 8 I. Political Party Systems Cadre Where Found: U.S. Mass Membership All other Wealthy Democracies Political Parties - 9 Goal: Winning Greater Emphasis on Standing for Something Different than the Opposition Traits: Few Dues Many Dues Paying Members Paying Members Political Parties - 10 Little Public Education Policy Flexibility High Much Public Education Low Political Parties - 11 II. Why the U.S. Developed a Cadre rather than a Mass Membership Party System A. "Absolutist Individualism" – to make the individual as self-reliant as is practically possible B. Little for the Political System to do Political Parties - 12 III. Why the U. S. Has Such a Strong Commitment to Absolutist Individualism A. Great Wealth Political Parties - 13 B. Frontier Experience 1. Self-Sufficiency 2. Ease of Owning Property Political Parties - 14 3. Basic rule: government actions to help the poor often involve some reduction in property rights 4. Zoning Political Parties - 15 C. Agrarian Experience 1. Difficult to Organize Farmers Political Parties - 16 D. Ethnic Diversity 1. Basic Rule: A society strongly divided on racial, ethnic or religious lines is more difficult to divide on social class lines Political Parties - 17 E. Lateness of the Industrial Revolution 1. Strong Commitment to Absolutist Individualism Prior to Industrialization 2. Reliance on “Craft” Unions Voting Behavior - 1 I. Voting Behavior A. Realigning Election B. Current Division between the Parties is Quite Close Voting Behavior - 2 II. The Republican Coalition A. White Evangelicals – Moral Decline B. Deep South – Civil Rights Voting Behavior - 3 C. Country Folk – Culture D. Exurbia – White Flight Voting Behavior - 4 E. Young Blue Collars Boys – White Men Without College Degrees F. Blue Collar Old Men – Social Security can cause defections Voting Behavior - 5 G. Privileged Men – Noneconomic liberalism of this group can cause defections Voting Behavior - 6 III. The Democratic Coalition A. African-Americans – Civil Rights plus Economic Need 1. Republican support eroded once Civil Rights involved government regulation of business Voting Behavior - 7 B. Hispanics – Similar Calculus to African-Americans C. Well-Educated Women – Relatively Liberal both Economically and Socially (support Affirmative Action – Abortion Rights and Gun Control) Voting Behavior - 8 D. Secular Warriors – Don’t Go to Church and Don’t Own Guns E. Cosmopolitan States (large, diverse populations) Voting Behavior - 9 F. Union Families IV. Contested Groups – Typically Economically Liberal and Socially Conservative A. Catholics Voting Behavior - 10 B. Single Women – Economically Vulnerable C. Young Voters – Tend to be Relatively Liberal but Don’t Vote as Much Voting Behavior - 11 I. Question – If poor people disproportionately vote Democratic and richer people disproportionately vote Republican, why do Democratic Presidential candidates win the richer states and Republican Presidential candidates win the poorer states? Voting Behavior - 12 Voting Behavior - 13 Voting Behavior – 14 - Race is Half the Story Voting Behavior - 15 I. Voting and the Culture War A. The culture war is fought by the wealthy, in part, because their economic needs are met. B. The wealthy have sufficient money to move to an area that is culturally suitable for them. Voting Behavior - 16 I. The Issue Positions/Ideology of Today’s Voters More Accurately Reflect the Views of Their Party than during the 1950-1980 period. A. During the 1960-1980 period the message from party elites became more consistent within each party. Voting Behavior - 17 B. Two Fundamental Causes 1. Reaction to the Civil Rights movement – the South becomes much more Republican 2. Political losses by business cause it to spend much more on lobbying for a message of low taxes and regulation Voting Behavior - 18 C. As the cues from party officeholders become more similar within each party, there are fewer voters whose issue positions/ideology don’t fit their political party (i.e., liberal Republicans and conservative Democrats). Voting Behavior - 19 1. Independent voters who “lean” toward a party typically behave as partisans (i.e., hold opinions similar to their party and vote for that party). 2. If faced with a conflict between their ideology and their party, most voters change their ideology to fit their party rather than vice versa. Voting Behavior - 20 D. All these factors, plus the greater turnout rate among partisans, have caused campaigns to increasing focus on activating their “base” rather than appealing to independent voters. Voting Behavior - 21 E. All of these factors greatly increase the “cost” to politicians of compromising with the opposition party (e.g., you may get a primary election challenge within your party). Noneconomic Party Differences1 I. Left (Non-Communist)/Right (NonFascist) on Noneconomic Issues A. Right 1. Maintain Traditional Social Relationships/Regime Maintenance Noneconomic Party Differences2 2. Freedom of Expression 3. Increase Civil Rights and Liberties Noneconomic Party Differences3 B. Left 1. Freedom of Expression 2. Increase Civil Rights and Liberties Noneconomic Party Differences4 3. Maintain Traditional Social Relationships/Regime Maintenance Congress/California Legislature 1 I. Congress – Perspectives A. Executive Dominated 1. President Sets the Agenda Congress/California Legislature 2 2. Unity 3. Expertise 4. Governor has Line-Item Veto 5. Term Limits for California Legislature have reduced it’s willingness to change the governor’s budget Congress/California Legislature 3 B. High Level of Political Polarization 1.Cohesion within each party has increased and the distance between the parties has widened. Congress/California Legislature 4 2. 2008-2016 Presidential Contender Scores on Labor/Environment 3. California Legislature: Support for the Chamber of Commerce: All Republicans 80%-100%; 80% of Democrats 0%-40% Congress/California Legislature 5 4. Compromise can bring a Primary Challenger 5. Reasons for 1-4 a. Electoral Coalitions of Parties have become more Dissimilar Congress/California Legislature 6 b. Increasing Income Inequality c. Civil Rights Era brings Less Tolerant Voters into Republican Party Congress/California Legislature 7 C. “Anticipated” Public Opinion, Not “Current” Public Opinion Matters Most 1. Traceability 2. Closing Military Bases Congress/California Legislature 8 3. Incentive: take actions with immediate positive payoffs (e.g., tax cuts) and avoid actions which have negative short-term effects (e.g., gas tax increases) but positive long-term effects (cleaner environment). Congress/California Legislature 9 4. Particular vs. General Benefits a. Those Who Don’t Get Cancer because of Reduced Pollution Won’t Know it b. Fairness? Congress/California Legislature 10 D. Responsiveness Without Responsibility 1. Doing what voters want “now” but without explaining “long-term” harm. 2. California: term limits shield legislators from long-term consequences Congress/California Legislature 11 E. State Legislators Think Public Opinion Is More Conservative Than It Is. 1. On average, conservative state legislators over-estimated constituency conservatism by 20% while liberal state legislators substantially overestimate constituency conservatism but by a smaller margin. Congress/California Legislature 12 F. Congress Often Legitimates Governmental Decisions. 1. Panama Canal Treaty Congress/California Legislature 13 G. Incremental Decision-Making 1. Budgets Congress/California Legislature 14 H. Political Activity and the Popularity of Congress 1. Public dislikes conflict – which is the very essence of politics 2. Don’t See Supreme Court Justices Arguing on T.V. Congress/California Legislature 15 I. Congressional Elections 1. Referendum on President 2. Unpopular Incumbent leads to Better Challenger Congress/California Legislature 16 3. As the issue bases of partisan attachments have increased there has been less opportunity for Congressmen to receive “personal vote.” 4. Fewer Competitive Districts Congress/California Legislature 17 5. Less Turnover in Congress 6. Big Republican Win in 2010 Yielded No Republican Gains in California Legislature Congress/California Legislature 18 II. Representation and Fairness A. Since the Primary Election is Often More Important than the General Election and Primary Voters are More Extreme, Representation Can be Harmed. Congress/California Legislature 19 2. Politically, it can be Advantageous for a Legislator to Vote in the Direction Favored by a Small, Extreme, But Vocal Minority Who Cast their Votes on the Issue rather than Vote in the Direction of Majority Public Opinion. Congress/California Legislature 20 B. Since You Often Need 60 of the 100 Senators to Vote “Yes” and Each State Receives Two Senators, Small States Can Have Disproportionate Influence. Congress/California Legislature 21 I. Partisan Differences in the U.S. Congress A. 95% Direction Rule B. 40% Difference Rule Congress/California Legislature 22 C. Policy Areas – least to greatest partisan difference 1. Civil Liberties 2. International Involvement Congress/California Legislature 23 3. Agricultural Assistance 4. Social Welfare 5. Government Management of the Economy Preparing for the Exam - 1 1. Be able to answer the study guide questions on page 11 of the coursepack (www.csulb.edu/~cdennis click on “Courses”) 2. Be able to explain any concept or term on the slides and why that concept or term was important enough to be discussed. Preparing for the Exam - 2 3. Be able to “compare and contrast” concepts or ideas. For example, compare and contrast cadre and mass membership political parties. 4. What’s related to what? For example, as a person’s income increases does their probability of voting increase or decrease? Beginning of Section III The material for Exam #3 begins with the next slide. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1A DON’T WRITE DOWN ANY OF THE MATERIAL OVER THE NEXT 220 SLIDES. ALL OF IT IS IN THE COURSEPACK. JUST LISTEN TO THE DISCUSSION! Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1B I. Policy Orientation of This Discussion A. Since the U.S. has the weakest social safety net and highest level of income inequality of any wealthy democracy the obvious comparison is to the other wealthy democracy that have stronger social safety nets and less income inequality than we do. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1C B. I know that isn’t “comforting.” We naturally want to think of our nation as “best” on all criteria. Realistically, this is impossible. A nation that has the lowest taxes won’t have the least inequality. The United States ranks high on some social programs (e.g., higher education) but not on income security and reducing inequality. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1D C. If I were teaching this class in a nation with a very strong social safety net and much less income inequality (e.g., Sweden), I would compare it to nations that have less strong social safety nets and greater income inequality (e.g., Canada and Great Britain with moderately strong social safety nets and the U.S. with a very social safety net). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1E D. Therefore, while I will touch on proposals to weaken the U.S. safety net, the vast bulk of the discussion ahead will focus on what other wealthy democracies do to reduce income equality, how well these policies work and what the U.S. could do in this regard while still preserving our freedoms and improving our political system. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 2 I. Incentives of the Two Major Political Parties A. Unemployment has a large impact which disproportionately falls on low and middle-income voters. 1. Nonmonetary costs of unemployment Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 3 B. The poorest 80% of American households are relatively unaffected by inflation. However, inflation has a greater adverse impact on the richest 20% of American households. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 4 C. Marginal Substitution Rate Democrats .90 Independents Republicans 2.0 1.5 Macroeconomic Theory - 1 I. Macroeconomic Theory A. Neoclassical 1. The free market was assumed to yield full employment (i.e., no/low unemployment) and to grow without limitation and to correct any imbalances that might develop Macroeconomic Theory - 2 2. Since the higher one’s income the greater the percentage of their income they save/invest and the smaller percentage of their income they spend, the greater the share of income the rich possessed the greater the investment, and hence, economic innovation/growth. Macroeconomic Theory - 3 3. By this view, a major goal of macroeconomic policy was to keep the costs of production low (e.g., low wages – through the absence of labor unions, a low minimum wage, low taxes, little government regulation of business, etc.) in order to increase profits and investment. 4. Couldn’t explain the Great Depression Macroeconomic Theory - 4 B. Keynesianism 1. If the non-rich lacked sufficient money to purchase goods, the economy would not reach its’ full potential because businessmen would not open new business, or expand current ones, if they felt they could not sell the resulting products or services. Macroeconomic Theory - 5 2. This meant that middle and lowerincome groups, who spend a greater share of their income than upper income groups, need to have a significant share of the national income (through a minimum wage, labor unions, etc.). Macroeconomic Theory - 6 3. If economic demand was insufficient, Keynes argued that the government should increase its’ spending and be willing to run large deficits (i.e., spend more money than it receives in taxes). 4. If both inflation and unemployment are high (late 1970s & early 1980s) – trouble. Macroeconomic Theory – 7A C. The aforementioned difficulties of Keynesian economics, plus the renewed political strength of a Republican Party whose ideology was similar to neoclassical economics, resulted in a rebirth of neoclassical economics under several different names. Macroeconomic Theory – 7B D. Corporate profits were 25% to 30% higher at the official end of the Great Recession than they were before it started (2007). Meanwhile, wages as a share of national income fell to 58%. That’s the lowest wage share had been since it began to be recorded after World War II. Macroeconomic Theory – 7C If wages were at their postwar (World War II) average of 63%, U.S. workers would earn an extra $740 (billion) this year (2012) or about $5,000 per worker. That’s a lot of consuming power.” Macroeconomic Theory - 8 D. Supply-Side Economics - Ronald Reagan 1981 & Newt Gingrich 2012 1. Like Neoclassical Economics – much more concerned with reducing impediments to supply (high labor costs, taxes and regulations) than in stimulating demand. Macroeconomic Theory - 9 2. Tax Cuts DON’T pay for themselves. 3. Gregory Mankiw – supply-side economics devised by “charlatans and cranks” E. Relationship between the philosophy/self-interest of both major political parties and the economic theory they use. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 5 D. Recent research by political scientists shows that all income groups up through the 95th percentile (i.e., all but the richest 5% of households – today those earning about $200,000, or less, per year) gain under the Democrats relative to the Republicans. However, the poor gain at a greater rate under the Democrats. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 6 E. Our Current Situation 1. Tremendous loss of consumer demand due to the collapse of real estate 2. Government needs to replace this lost demand – i.e., NOT cutback Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 7 3. 300 billion dollars of stimulus will reduce the unemployment rate by 1%. The Obama Stimulus Plan was approximately 775 billion dollars spread over two years. Given the composition of the Obama Stimulus Plan (e.g., tax cuts – which have low stimulative value) it is equivalent to about 510 billion dollars of stimulus rather than 775 billion dollars. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 8 This means that, due to the Obama Stimulus Plan, the unemployment rate, while high, is about 1.7 percentage points lower that it would have been without the plan (510/300 = 1.7). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 9 4. Many economists think that the federal government needs to do two things to improve the economy: (1) provide a larger stimulus than the Obama Stimulus Plan; and (2) more strongly regulate the financial markets (to avoid the bad loans that precipitated our current problems). This is difficult for the Republican Party: their ideology conceives of government as “the problem,” not “the solution.” Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 10 Income Inequality in Wealthy Democracies in the Mid-1980s – Percentage Distribution Japan Sweden U.S. Richest 20% 37.5% 41.7% 42.0% Poorest 20% 8.7% 7.4% 5.0% 2009 >>> 3.9% Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11A Year 1920 Richest Richest 10% 1% 39.0% 14.8% 1970 32.6% 9.0% Richest ½ of 1% 11.1% 6.3% 2008 48.2% 21.0% 16.9% SHARES FOR THE RICHEST 1% AND ½ OF 1% ARE ABOUT TWICE AS HIGH AS IN EUROPE Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11B U.C. Berkeley Economist Emmanuel Saez’s comments on the reasons for increase income inequality in the U.S.: “…The changes in income concentration are just too abrupt and too closely correlated with policy developments for the standard story about pay equaling productivity to hold everywhere. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11C Between 1971 and 2007, U.S. hourly wages, adjusted for inflation, rose by 4%. (That’s not 4% a year; it’s 4% over 36 years!) during those same decades, productivity increased by 99% - that is, it nearly doubled. In other words, the average worker’s productivity rose 25 times more than his pay. Los Angeles Times, May 14, 2013, page A11). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11D That is, if pay is equal to productivity, you would think that deep economic changes in skills would evolve slowly and make a gradual difference in the distribution—but what we see in the data are very abrupt changes. Basically all western countries had very high levels of income concentration up to the first decades of the 20th century Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11E and then income concentration fell dramatically in most western countries following the historical narrative of each country. For example, in the United States the Great Depression followed by the New Deal and then World War II. And I could go on with other countries. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11F Symmetrically, the reversal—that is, the surge in income concentration in some but not all countries—follows political developments closely. You see the highest increases in income concentration in countries such as the United States and the United Kingdom (Great Britain), Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11G following precisely what has been called the Reagan (Republican President from 1981-1988) and Thatcher (Conservative Party Prime Minister of Great Britain from 1979-1990) revolutions: deregulation, cuts in top tax rates, and policy changes that favored upper-income brackets. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11H You don’t see nearly as much of an increase in income concentration in countries such as Japan, Germany, or France, which haven’t gone through such sharp, drastic policy changes. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11I Apportioning the 12 percentage Increase in the Share of Income Going to the Top 1% - 1976-2008 (8.9% to 20.9%) Tax Reductions – 45% Political Polarization – 28% Unexplained 26% Conservative tax changes and the increased conservatism of the Republican Party have had a large impact on inequality. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 12 If you include government transfers and subtract taxes from 1979 to 2006, the richest 1% of households had a 256% increase income while middle-income households (40th-60th percentiles) had a 21% increase and lowincome households (1st-20th percentiles) only an 11% increase. In the United States today, the richest 1% of households have over 1.5 times as much income as the entire poorest 40% of households combined. Changes in California - 1 In California, between 1987 and 2009, more than 33% of the income gains went to the richest 1% of Californians, and almost 75% went to the richest 10% while the bottom 90% received just over 25% of the growth in incomes. During the last two decades, the average income of the richest 1% of Californians increased by more than 50%, Changes in California - 2 after adjusting for inflation, while the average income of the middle fifth (i.e., the 40th – 60th percentiles) decreased by 15%. In 2009, the average income of the richest 1% of Californians was $1.2 million – more than 30 times that of Californians in the middle fifth. California’s income gap is wider than most other states. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 13 Americans in the poorest 10% had a living standard 22% below low-income Finns, 24% below low- income Dutch and 15% below low-income Italians. However, the wealthiest 10% of Americans had incomes 50% higher than the wealthiest 10% in the other OECD nations (Great Britain, France, Canada, Japan, Australia and New Zealand). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy -14 One fundamental reason the poor in the U.S. have a lower standard of living than in several other nations is that, after taxes, the U.S. transfers only about onethird the percentage of income to the poorest 20% of households (1.5%) as does the average (4.2%) of the world’s wealthy democracies. Analysis from the World Bank Publication, “Social Safety Nets and Target Assistance: Lessons from the European Experience,” Chris de Neubourg, et. al. While the average American has a higher living standard than the average resident in the other countries, this does not hold for the entire spectrum of the income distribution. Despite the higher aggregate and average standard of living in the United States, people in the lower deciles of the income distribution are far worse off in US than poorer persons or households in Europe, if compared to the median income of their own country. (p. 5) Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 15 The median Swedish family has a living standard roughly comparable with that of the median U.S. family: wages are, if anything, higher in Sweden, and a higher tax burden is offset by public provision of health care and generally better public services. As you move further down the income distribution, Swedish living standards are much higher than in the U.S.: at the 10th percentile (poorer than 90% of the population) the Swedish living standard is 60% higher than in the U.S. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 16 In this light it is worth noting that approximately 38% of the benefits from the Bush Tax Cuts go to the richest 1% of the households (i.e., the same households who have been receiving a much higher share of personal income over the past 40 years). The richest 1% of U.S. households receive more money from the Bush Tax Cuts than the entire poorest 70% of U.S. households combined (roughly households with annual incomes of about $90,000 or less). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 17 Wealth is a storehouse of assets: trusts, stocks, bonds, etc. whereas income is what you live on over a short period – say, a year. As the following statistics will make clear: Wealth is even more unequally distributed than income. In the United States the wealthiest 1% of households have over 33% of the national wealth while the poorest 50% of households have approximately 7% of the national wealth. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 18 A rather large amount of research tells us the following: (1) Americans vastly overestimate their chances of becoming rich; (2) vastly underestimate the degree of income inequality (i.e., do not think the wealthy are as wealthy as the actually are); and (3) have a difficult time connecting public policy to economic outcomes (e.g., not that many see the Bush Tax Cuts as a tremendous redistribution to the wealthy). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 19 Currently, wealth in America is distributed as follows: the richest 20% of households (percentiles 81-100) have approximately 84% of the wealth, the next richest 20% (i.e., percentiles 61-80) have approximately 11%, the middle quintile (i.e., percentiles 41-60) have approximately 4%, the next poorest 20% (i.e., percentiles 21-40) have approximately .2% (two tenths of 1%) and the poorest quintile (i.e., percentiles 1-20) have approximately .1% (one tenth of 1%). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 20 Americans do desire a less unequal distribution of wealth. Recently, two scholars tried an interesting experiment. Not being told what nations had what distribution of wealth, Americans were offered three choices: (1) the current American distribution of wealth; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 21 (2) perfect equality (i.e., each quintile getting an equal – 20% - share of the wealth); or (3) the current Swedish distribution of wealth (the richest 20% of households approximately 36% of the wealth, the next richest 20% approximately 21% of the wealth, the middle quintile approximately 18% of the wealth, the next poorest 20% approximately 15% of the wealth and the poorest quintile approximately 11% of the wealth). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 22 The results were as follows: 47% chose Sweden’s distribution, 43% chose perfect equality while only 10% chose the current American distribution. Additionally, American’s are less satisfied with their lives than citizens in a number of European countries that have less per capita income, but much stronger safety nets/less income inequality than the U.S. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22A I.How Should We Measure “Well-Being”? A. If someone spends $1,000 on diabetes medicine it counts as part of GDP. However, wouldn’t the same person have a better life if they didn’t have diabetes but spent $750 on a computer? Since $1,000 is greater than $750, in this example GDP would be higher for diabetes oriented spending than for buying a computer. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22B B. GDP (Gross Domestic Product) only measures the monetary value of the economy. It tells nothing about how the money is used or any nonmonetary value (national health, the functioning of the political system, job security and measures of community well-being). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22C C. Typically, on such indicators, the United States ranks lower than the high tax and strong welfare state countries of Northern Europe (e.g., Norway, Sweden, Denmark, Finland, and the Netherlands). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 23 Mobility is NOT that high in the U.S. If you compare the eventual income of two children from different families, on average, the child from the richer family receives an annual income that is higher than the child from the poorer family by approximately 30%-40% of the difference in the incomes of their parents. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 24 A child from a family that made $100,000 per year would, on average, out earn a child from a family that made $25,000 by approximately $25,000 per year (the difference in their parents incomes was $75,000 – i.e., $100,000 - $25,000 = $75,000; 33% of $75,000 = $25,000). Thus, if later in life the child of the poorer family was earning $25,000 per year and the child of the richer family was earning $50,000 per year, you could say that the difference was entirely due to background. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 25 Put another way: children born into the poorest 20% of households have approximately a 42% chance of ending up in the poorest 20% themselves, a 24% chance of ending up in the next poorest 20% and only a 6% chance of ending up in the richest 20%. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 26 Father’s and Son’s incomes in the U.S. correlate at about .43 (correlation ranges from 0 to 1.0 so this is a moderate correlation), and is higher in the U.S. (i.e., less mobility) than in Sweden, Norway, Finland, France, Spain, Germany, and Canada. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 27 The Bush Tax Cuts reveal a very pertinent fact about economic policy: there is often a great difference between programs that help the non-wealthy acquire wealth versus policies that protect the wealth of those who already have it. What is good for one group is not necessarily good, and often harmful, for the other group. Approximately 75% of American household lose under the Bush Tax Cuts. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 28 Consider how the Bush Tax Cuts affect mobility from low to high-income groups. First, by repealing the estate tax and reducing other taxes on high-income individuals, the Bush Tax Cuts give the wealthy more wealth to leave their heirs. Obviously, this makes it more difficult for most of you to try to amass more wealth than the heirs of the currently very wealthy due to the fact these heirs will be given such a tremendous head start on you. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 29 Second, by reducing the revenue of the federal government, the Bush Tax Cuts will all but require reductions in programs that help low and middle-income people ascend the economic ladder (e.g., the Pell Grant Program for poor college students, health care for the poor, job training, public transportation, etc.). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 30 The Bush Tax Cuts are one of the very least effective, and most costly, methods of stimulating the economy and, ultimately, reducing unemployment. As economic research indicates: lower-income households spend a higher percentage of each additional dollar they receive than higher-income households. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 31 For example, a household with a $40,000 annual income will spend a higher percentage of each additional dollar it receives than a household with a $200,000 annual income. This is because lower-income households have greater unmet needs than higher-income households (e.g., replacing a worn out car). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 32 By showering more money on the richest 1% of households (i.e., households with incomes above $370,000) than on the entire poorest 70% of households combined, the Bush Tax Cuts place the most money in the hands of those least likely to spend it. Contrast this with the items on the next slide – favored by Democrats. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 33 The following indicates how much additional economic activity occurs per dollar spent: extending unemployment compensation $1.60; payroll tax reduction - $1.09; and extending the Bush Tax Cuts - $.35 (i.e. for each dollar given to tax payers through the Bush Tax Cuts, we only receive 35 cents of additional economic activity – only a fourth as much per dollar spent as on unemployment compensation – i.e., $.35 is about ¼ of $1.60). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 34 Since all income groups will save some percentage of the money they receive (i.e., lower-income households will save some money, just not as a great percentage as higher-income households), having the government directly spend money is more stimulative than tax cuts. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 35 If the government both taxes and spends a large share of the economy won’t we end up with more equal slices of a smaller pie (or a pie that isn’t growing as fast as it otherwise would)? While this is an important point, the evidence in favor of it is NOT compelling. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36A Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies: U.S. – 32.2%, Canada – 38.3%, Great Britain – 41.2%, Germany – 44.6%, Italy – 47.8%, Sweden – 50.9%, France – 52.9% and Denmark – 57.4%. Source: OECD as reported in NY Times 11/16/14 Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36B Federal Taxes as a percentage of our economy are lower today than they have been in over 60 years. 1951- 16.1 % (before Medicare enacted) 1971 – 17.3% 2001 – 19.5% 2011 – 15.4% Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36C Effective Tax Rates on Income of $100,000 in 2012 Nation Income Tax Social Security U.S. – 26.0% 18.7% 7.3% G. Brit.- 31.4% 24.1% 7.3% Sweden- 36.3% 36.3% 0% France – 42.0% 20.0% 22.0% Germany-43.8% 28.3% 15.5% Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36D Government Mandated Paid Annual Leave and Paid Days of Vacation U.S. - 0 Great Britain - 20 Sweden - 25 German - 30 France - 31 Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 37 From 1990-2005 per capita (i.e., per person - to adjust for differences in population size between nations) growth rates were as follows: U.S. - 85%, Netherlands – 86%, Norway – 134%, France – 60%, Australia – 91%, Canada – 69%, Denmark – 80%, United Kingdom – 111%. Since 1980, per capita real G.D.P. (Gross Domestic Product) – which is what matters most for living standards - has risen at about the same rate in America and in the E.U.(U.S. - 1.95%, E.U. - 1.83%). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 38 As economist Peter Lindert of the University of California at Davis put it, “No matter how you torture the data, there is no negative relationship between a commitment to the welfare state and the growth rate in how well off we are.” While taxes may reduce the willingness of some to work as hard, many of the purposes for which tax dollars are spent (e.g., education, infrastructure, etc.) increase the growth rate. One of the reasons the Nordic countries (Norway, Sweden, Denmark and Finland) spend about TWICE the percentage of GDP (3%-4%) on research and development as the U.S. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 39 In light of the Obama Health Care Plan, let me mention the following: EVERY nation in the world rations health care. For example, would you pay an additional $200 per month for health care in order to prolong the life of terminally ill patients an average of 3 months? If “yes,” how about $400 per month? Once you say “no” (i.e., refuse to pay), you are rationing health care. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 40 Let me offer the following question: Would you prefer to have a government panel – typically headed by physicians – make the necessary rationing decisions or would you rather have a for-profit insurance company make them? That’s the choice we actually have. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 41 Government policies do have important affects on the rationing decisions that all health care systems must make. For example, cigarette taxes reduce cigarette smoking. Economists have found that a 10% increase in the cost of cigarettes reduces smoking by about 3%-4%. Thus, cigarette taxes reduce the amount of smoking which, in turn, reduces the onset of a large number of adverse health consequences (e.g., cancer, heart attack, stroke, etc.). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 42 Many of those who claim the Obama Health Care Plan will lead to government rationing of health care to the elderly are the same individuals/groups who oppose government regulations (e.g., soda taxes, meat taxes, restaurant menu labeling requiring disclosure of calories, fat, sodium, etc.) which would greatly reduce adverse health consequences (e.g., obesity) which, in turn, would leave more money for the health care needs of senior citizens. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 43 Broad-based government programs, such as Medicare (a government health care program for senior citizens), have two big cost saving advantages over a completely free market social insurance system: (1) compulsion – i.e., requiring everyone to buy health insurance lowers the cost because the cost of the “expensive” individuals (e.g., those likely to be ill) is spread over a large group (e.g., the healthy) and; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 44 (2) administrative cost (e.g., the typical private health insurer spends about 10% of its outlays on administrative costs, weeding out sick people, etc. whereas the government run Medicare program spends between 2%-3% of its budget on administrative costs). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 45 The preceding are two of the major reasons why the #1 ranked (by the World Health Organization) French health care system spends only a little more than half as much money per person as the 37th ranked U.S. health care system (France - $4,690, U.S. - $8,895). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 46 Government run programs such as Medicare aren’t the same as government ownership of productive assets. Medicare doesn’t own hospitals or employ doctors, it contracts with privately owned hospitals and private physicians. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 47 I should also mention that government programs such as Medicare and Medicaid (a government run health care program for the poor) currently pay substantially more of our nation’s health care costs (approximately 47%) than private insurance (approximately 35%). Thus, we can’t “get the government out of health care.” Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 48 It should also be mentioned that the democracies of Western Europe are, in the main, NOT socialist nations. Socialism means that the government owns the modes of production and distribution. For example, socialism in the U.S. would mean that the government would own the major fast food outlets (e.g., McDonalds, Wendy’s etc.). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 49 Considerations about the size of government on personal freedom are complicated. Equating the size of government with personal freedom often involves equating private property with personal freedom. This is difficult. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 50 For example, would most Californians have more freedom if the beaches were sold to private individuals or if the State of California operates them? Additionally, if state taxes were reduced taxpayers would have a greater freedom of choice in spending their money. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 51 However, if these state tax cuts resulted in higher fees for U.C. and CSU students fewer students would attend college. Not attending college would reduce both the future incomes and occupational choices of the individuals who did not attend college due to the budget reductions resulting from the state tax cuts. In short, it would reduce their future freedom. So, would such a state tax cut result in a “net” gain or loss in freedom? Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 52 A relatively small loss in freedom for a large group of people (requiring each person to purchase health insurance) will provide a much larger amount of freedom (to make all the decisions living people can make) for a smaller group of people (the unhealthy). If so, has the amount of freedom either increased or decreased? It’s not so easy to answer! You would have to balance the loss of many small amounts of freedom against a fewer large gains in freedom. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 53 People in the democracies of Western Europe are typically as “free” as Americans. For example, free speech in Great Britain is as great as it is in the United States. Additionally, some Western European nations actually have higher scores on some measures of democracy than the United States. Typically, this occurs because of lower voter turnout and fewer major political parties in the United States. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 54 The “big picture” is that, if we wanted to, our nation could reduce economic inequality significantly and still have an equally vibrant, growing economy with the same level of freedom we currently enjoy. This is really a question of values (i.e., Do we want to?) rather than possibilities (i.e., Could we?) Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55A Increased redistribution of income and wealth might well improve the functioning of democracy in the United States. What some refer to as “the Debilitating Cycle” is a very important problem: greater income inequality leads to a greater reliance of politicians on campaign contributions from the wealthy, which, can easily cause these same politicians to adopt policies that even more favor the wealthy, which starts the same cycle again. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55B Relative to the average American, the very wealthy (net worth of $40 million or more) are: (1) much more concerned about budget deficits; (2) much more favorable to cutting social welfare programs, especially Social Security and health care; (3) are considerably less supportive of an above-poverty-level minimum wage, or having the federal government “see to” or provide jobs for the unemployed; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55C (4) much less supportive of providing broad educational opportunities; (5) much less willing to redistributive income to those poorer than themselves; (6) less willing to raise taxes on high income groups (e.g., less supportive of having an estate tax); and (7) are less willing to regulate either the stock market or businesses. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 56 Proposals of the Political Parties President George W. Bush proposed a series of policies to deal with our nation’s economic future that were collectively referred to as “The Ownership Society.” The idea is that each individual citizen would “own” items that had previously been provided by the government. For example, if each individual citizen can choose how to invest their money in a personal Social Security Account you could say that person “owned” their retirement. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 57 Let’s see how “The Ownership Society” would have changed American health care policy and the degree of health care security American’s have. Former President George W. Bush did not favor requiring all Americans to purchase health insurance. He did favor (and at his urging Congress did pass) legislation setting up Health Savings Accounts in 2003. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 58 In 2008, an individual could contribute up to $2,400 per year to such an account ($5,800 for a family). The gains from this investment are not taxed and the money could be withdrawn to pay the deductable under a health insurance policy. This is a tax free method of investing for those fortunate enough to have the money to participate. Not surprisingly, those most likely to contribute to Health Savings Accounts are much richer than average. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 59 Look at the relationships between wealth/education and health: (1) more welleducated and higher-income individuals are more likely to value delayed gratification – i.e., foregoing something today for a greater future gain - in this case eating healthier food, maintaining a healthier weight, not smoking, etc. than less well-educated and lower-income individuals; thus, Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 60 (2) more well-educated and higher-income individuals are less likely to need medical attention than less well-educated and lowerincome individuals; and (3) more welleducated and higher-income individuals are more likely to contribute to Health Savings Accounts than less well-educated and lowerincome individuals. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 61 By not requiring people to buy insurance and by allowing people to put money into Health Savings Accounts, higher-income people, who are typically more healthy, are able to remove money that would’ve gone into an insurance pool from which the unhealthy could benefit. Thus, the practical effect of Health Savings Accounts is to reduce the ability to spread medical costs over a larger, healthier, population. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 62 Withdrawing money that a healthier population would have put into an insurance pool and, instead, placing it in the hands of higherincome households means that the costs of health insurance to the less healthy population, disproportionately drawn from middle and low-income households, will increase. All of this works to the advantage of higher- income individuals. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 63 The Ownership Society proposal for education (another tax-free savings plan) has a similar effect to the Health Savings Accounts. Here’s why: (1) higher-income individuals are much more likely to have the necessary money to put into such an account; (2) citizens are more likely to vote in favor of increased taxes for education when they have children in the public education system; and Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 64 (3) the money from an Educational Savings Account will either allow more students to afford a private college and/or reduce their need for more funding for state run colleges. For example, the money from the account means they are less likely to need financial aid than other students. Points 1-3 mean that the educational “gap” between students from lower and higher-income households will increase. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 65 Republican Congressman Paul Ryan calls his plan, “The Roadmap for America’s Future.” His plan would: (1) cut federal taxes of the richest 1% of households by 50% (i.e., in half – this is in addition to the tax cuts this group would receive by making the Bush Tax Cuts permanent); Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 66 (2) replace some of the lost revenue from the tax cuts for the richest 1% of households with a much more regressive consumption tax on most goods and services (i.e., paid much more by middle and low-income households – families with incomes between $50,000 and $75,000 would face a tax increase of around $900 per year); Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 67 (3) freeze discretionary domestic spending (keep in mind that, that after adjusting for inflation and population growth, this would mean a 25% reduction over 10 years in such items as public transportation, etc.); (4) privatize Social Security (i.e., individual accounts) and; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 68 (5) replace Medicare for senior citizens with a voucher (i.e., an amount of money to buy health insurance). Since the Ryan plan doesn’t require all citizens to buy health insurance and includes Health Savings Accounts, health care costs will increase (see previous discussion). These increases would occur at the same time that Ryan wants to reduce Medicare spending. Thus, senior citizens would have much poorer health care under the Ryan plan than currently. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 69 The Ryan plan proposes large cuts in Social Security benefits — roughly 16 percent for the average new retiree in 2050 and 28 percent in 2080 from price indexing alone — and initially diverts most of these savings to help fund private accounts rather than to restore Social Security solvency.” Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 70 This is very similar to former President George W. Bush’s proposal for Social Security. Unlike Bush’s Social Security Proposal, the Ryan Plan protects those whose investments result in less income than under the traditional Social Security program. Ryan’s guarantee would encourage seniors to make more risky investments. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 71 Why not gamble on an investment with large possible gain (but also large possible loss) when the federal government insures you against loss? Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 72 While the Ryan Plan does include a protection for senior citizen’s whose investments yielded a return lower than what they would have received under traditional Social Security, it is extremely unlikely that this guarantee would be paid in full. Here’s why: Ryan would use government revenues to replace the lost income to senior citizens whose investments performed poorly. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–73A The cost of this guarantee would be very high. Given the reductions in other programs that would be required to fully fund this guarantee (e.g., in defense, education, environmental protection, etc.) it would be extremely unlikely to be fully realized. The “big picture” is that the current Republican plans, including Mitt Romney’s, are very similar to former President Bush’s plans. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–73B Regardless of whether one agrees or disagrees with the philosophy of the Republican party, the following conclusion is inescapable: the Republican proposals would make what is already, by far, the weakest social safety net of any wealthy democracy in the world much weaker still while simultaneously increasing the degree of after-tax income inequality in what is already the most economically unequal wealthy democracy in the world. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 74 Which of the following seems more appropriate: (1) As personal economic risk increases, you need the government less? (2) As personal economic risk increases, you need the government more? Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 75 The two parties differ widely. The Republican Party approach (i.e., “The Ownership Society” and “The Roadmap for America’s Future”) is to load increased personal economic risk back on the individual (i.e., less governmental guarantees – privatization of Social Security rather than guaranteed benefit levels, giving senior citizens a voucher rather guaranteed Medicare – same with health care for the poor; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 76 reducing taxes on high income earners that can be applied to public services for middle and low-income earners) while the Democratic Party approach is more in favor of using the government to offset increased personal financial risk (e.g., the Obama Health Care Plan – making health care more affordable for middle and low-income earners, increasing the Pell Grant program for low-income college students, Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 77 reducing the Bush Tax Cuts, increasing government deficit spending and increasing regulation of financial markets). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 78 Tax rates are NOT highly progressive in the United States. The rich pay a higher percentage of their income in taxes than the poor, but not greatly so. All federal taxes together (i.e., income taxes, Social Security taxes, etc.) take approximately 9.4% of the income of households making $16,000 per year, approximately 20.5% of the income of households making $52,000, Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 79 approximately 27.2% of the income of households making $200,000 per year and approximately 34% of households making $18,000,000 per year. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 80 It is very important to mention that federal taxes have been made much LESS progressive over time. To demonstrate the impact of reduced federal tax progressivity consider the following: “In 2000, the richest 1 household in 1,000 (i.e., .1 of 1%) had about 7.3% of total national after-tax income. If the effect of taxes on their income had remained what it was in 1970, they would have had about 4.5% of after-tax national income. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 81 This would be a reduction of approximately 38% in their after-tax income (7.3% 4.5% = 2.8 and 2.8 is approximately 38% of 7.3). This decrease in federal tax progressivity was prior to the Bush Tax Cuts (which, as previously discussed, overwhelmingly benefit households with very high incomes). Tax Rates Over Time Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 82 State and local taxes are even LESS progressive than federal taxes. Thus, if you add state and local taxes to federal taxes (i.e., to obtain “total taxes”) the tax burden is less favorable to the poor (i.e., less progressive) than for federal taxes alone. State and Local Taxes are a greater percentage of personal income for the poorest 20% of a state’s households than for the wealthiest 1% of a state’s households in virtually every state (all but one). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 83 In California state and local taxes take approximately 11.3% of the income of the poorest 20% of households while taking only 7.2% of the income of the richest 1% of households. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 84 For example, in California, the wealthiest 10% of the taxpayers pay approximately 75% of the state income tax. While true, this argument is misleading for two reasons: (1) the most important consideration is taxes as a percentage of income and not the percentage of a tax borne by a particular income group – thus, if California’s state income tax was only to raise $1 and Steven Spielberg paid that $1 he would have borne 100% of the state income tax burden – Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 85 however, $1 would be virtually 0% of his income – thus it’s the percentage of income paid in a tax and not the percentage of a tax that a particular income group pays that is the important consideration; (2) this calculation excludes all taxes except the income tax (e.g., state sales taxes, property taxes, etc.) – when we include all state and local taxes and fees, state and local taxes are a higher percentage of income for the very poor than the very rich. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 86 As a share of personal income, California typically ranks about 18th (out of 50 states) in state and local tax burden with state and local revenues equal to approximately 17% of personal income. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 87 One often hears candidates for state office talking about “runaway” state spending. Adjusting for population growth and inflation, to maintain the same level of service in 2009 that the state of California provided in 1999 state spending would have had to increase by 53%. Over the 1999-2009 period spending by the State of California only increased by 29% (i.e., a 24% REDUCTION in real per capita spending). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 88 Another way of looking at the question of state spending is to take account of both need (i.e., what type of population we have) and state wealth (i.e., our “ability to pay”). By such a measure, California ranked 37th out of the 50 states. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 89 Some state tax increase would IMPROVE the functioning of California’s economy: (1) tax internet purchases – not taxing them discriminates against bricks and mortar stores; (2) change business property taxes annually (i.e., not only when the property is sold) current practice favors those who hold a property longer – harms new businesses; Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 90 (3) tax carbon, pollution and oil - from an economic standpoint, the cost of pollution should be taxed to provide the appropriate disincentives to reduce pollution. Currently, California is the only oil producing state that does not have a severance tax on oil. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 91 One factor that would greatly help California’s business climate is a more highly educated workforce. To meet employment needs, the percentage of California’s workforce with at least a bachelor’s degree needs to roughly double over the next 15 years (from approximately 21% to approximately 41%). Tax cuts that result in reduced funding for higher education will not help us meet this critical need. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92A A final point, California does NOT have a “big bureaucracy.” State and local employees constitute a SMALLER share of California’s population than in approximately 45 of the 50 states. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92B HOMELESSNESS: In 2005, Utah calculated the annual cost of E.R. visits and jail stays for an average homeless person was $16,670, while the cost of providing an apartment and social worker would be $11,000. Each participant works with a caseworker to become self-sufficient, but if they fail, they still get to keep their apartment.” Due to drug and alcohol use shelters are much less beneficial than individual apartments. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92C Will poor people make better decisions if they have greater economic security (e.g., guaranteed housing, food, medical care, etc.) or less economic security? The evidence we have is lopsidedly on the side that says poor people will make better decisions (e.g., decisions concerning employment, health, etc. that involve current sacrifice but have greater Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92D long-term benefits) under conditions of greater rather than lesser security. In reviewing a recent study by an economist and psychologist, Tina Rosenberg notes, “Worrying about money when it is tight captures our brains. It reduces our cognitive capacity — especially our abstract intelligence, Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92E which we use for problem-solving. It also reduces our executive control, which governs planning, impulses and willpower. The bad decisions of the poor, say the authors, are not a product of bad character or low native intelligence. They are a product of poverty itself. Your natural capability doesn’t decrease when you experience scarcity. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92F But less of that capacity is available for use. If you put a middle-class person into a situation of scarcity, she will behave like a poor person.” Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 93 Why Not Policies that Would More Help Middle and Low-Income Households? While both our strong commitment to absolutist individualism and the framework of our political system (e.g., the separation of powers), make it difficult for the government to pass laws, there are important changes in the balance of domestic political power that have taken place over the past 40 years that make it even more difficult for the federal government to act on Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 94 behalf of the interests of middle and lowincome citizens. In a “nutshell,” here’s what happened: (1) after suffering a large number of political defeats through the 1960s under both political parties, during the mid-1970s business groups (the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, the National of Manufacturers, the National Federation of Independent Business, etc.) Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 95 decided to invest tremendous amounts of money both in lobbying members of Congress and contributing to political campaigns; (2) the relative strength of the counter-weight to business, labor unions, declined precipitously (in 1954 – 32% of the workforce was unionized - today only 13%), and with it a tremendous loss in both political information supplied to middle and low- income households and political participation by these citizens Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 96 (i.e., unions contacting their membership with information on political issues, the membership then contacting elected officials); (3) the interest groups that have formed on the political left have dealt more with the concerns/interests of well-educated higher income voters rather than the working class (i.e., environmentalism, women’s rights and gay rights do not deal with the distribution of the tax burden, Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 97 subsidies for low-wage workers or extending governmental provided health care); (4) due to the increased share of income going to the rich and greatly increased campaign costs – Democrats have had to turn more to business and upper-income groups for campaign contributions; and (5) due to factors 1-4, the political position of business has become much more advantaged relative to labor. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 98 Think of the political consequences of policy philosophies such as The Bush Tax Cuts, The Ownership Society and The Roadmap for America’s Future. All of these policies accomplish three goals of many (but not all) conservative leaders: (1) they shift the distribution of the tax burden away from taxing investments (i.e., money made with money – income sources primarily of very high-income households) Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 99 toward higher taxes on labor (i.e., taxes more paid by income from wages and salaries – the principle sources of income for the poorest 90%, or more, of households - by relying on consumption taxes); (2) reduce the amount of money redistributed to middle and low-income groups through public programs (e.g., mass transit, job retraining, guarantees for Social Security, Medicare, etc.); and Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –100 (3) increase the size of the federal deficit to the point that future Democratic Administrations will have difficulty in undertaking programs primarily benefitting middle and low-income households. For example, notice how difficult it is for Obama to get the necessary funding to implement his health care plan due to the size of the federal deficit (greatly swelled by the Bush Tax Cuts). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –101 The political consequences of the above mentioned policies significantly reduce the incentive for low and middle-income people to participate in the political process (e.g., vote) because they will perceive that government is not that helpful to them (i.e., their taxes will increase and the value of their government benefits will decrease). So, why invest time and effort in politics? Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –102 This protects high-income households from future adverse political events. Thus, if increasing income inequality might cause low and middle-income people to desire income redistribution, make it difficult for the government to accomplish this and reduce the incentives for low and middle-income people to get involved in the political process. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –103 What could we do? The basic answer is to undo the changes of the past 40 years. While any proposed “reforms” would spark opposition from those who do well under the current system, I’ll mention two possible changes that would greatly alter the political landscape in a direction much more favorable to middle and low-income groups. First, make it easier for workers to unionize. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –104 Canada offers a compelling lesson. According to the survey evidence, American workers are as favorable to unionization as Canadian workers. However, over the past 40 years, the gap between the percentage of the Canadian workforce that is unionized and the percentage of the U.S. workforce that is unionized has steadily increased (Canada: 1960 - 32%, 2000 – 32%| U.S.: 1960 - 31%, 2000 – 13%). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –105 Without a lengthy discussion, the differences over time are mostly attributable to differences in public policies governing the unionization process. Not surprisingly, this was one of the earliest results of increased business political strength: make it more difficult for workers to unionize. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –106 The second change would be to enact Yale Law Professor Bruce Ackerman’s “Patriot Dollars” proposal for campaign financing: have the federal government give each voter an ATM valued at $50 for each federal election cycle (i.e., every two years). This money could only be used for campaign contributions (i.e., all unused money would be returned to the federal government – “yes” it could be done – i.e., the technology to ensure this does exist). Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –107 A voter could give their contribution to one, or a series, of candidates. By not limiting how much individuals, businesses or unions contribute, this policy would not be invalidated by the Supreme Court. The Supreme Court has ruled that restricting how much an individual, or group, can contribute violates their free speech (i.e., money equals speech). Since Professor Ackerman’s proposal does not limit speech, it is constitutional. Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –108 By greatly increasing the amount of campaign money available, Professor Ackerman’s proposed policy would reduce the tremendous monetary advantage of both business and the wealthy. Lessons from Canada - 1 Currently, the federal deficit (i.e., the difference between what the federal government receives in taxes and what it spends) is approximately 10% of GDP. Rather than the painful cuts to the poor (food programs, medical care, job training, etc.) and education, we could eliminate the ENTIRE deficit by Lessons from Canada - 2 having U.S. taxes as a percentage of GDP equal Canadian taxes as a percentage of GDP (U.S. taxes would increase from 27% of GDP to 37%). Next to the United States, Canada has one the VERY WEAKEST social safety nets of the wealthy democracies. Thus, Canada is NOT a “high tax, big welfare state” nation. However, Canadian taxes represent 10% more of GDP than in the United States. We are a very LOW tax nation. Rationale for Budget Austerity In voting in favor the Ryan Budget, Representative Tim Walberg (R-Michigan) said, “They understand in my district: We’re broke. If we don’t deal with this, we lose the social safety net.” One could ask, “Why can’t the wealthiest democracy in the world guarantee to it’s citizens the same social welfare protections (universal health care, greater income support, etc.) that all other wealthy democracies guarantee their citizens”? U.S. & Canada – Taxes and Spending as a Percent of GDP U.S. Canada Taxes 27% 37% Health Care 16% 10% W. Health Org. Rank 37th 30th Defense 4.7% 1.1% It’s not that we “can’t afford” to provide a better social safety net but rather we tax much less and spend much more on health care and defense. Defense spending in Great Britain and France is approx. 2.5% of GDP. Areas to Reduce Spending If you’re thinking of areas to reduce federal spending consider defense. U.S. military spending is about 4.7% of GDP. U.S. military spending is approximately 46.5% of the military expenditures of the ENTIRE WORLD. To put this in perspective the second highest spending nation, China, spends about 6.6% of the military expenditures of the entire world. The next largest spenders are France (4.2%), Great Britain (3.8%) and Russia (3.5%). The Social Safety Net - 1 Even the comparatively weak U.S. safety net still helps. In the current recession, the U.S. Census Bureau estimates that the combination of unemployment insurance, food stamps and tax credits for the working poor lifted the incomes of between 3 to 5 MILLION U.S. households above the poverty line. Now think of the human cost of reducing the funding for these programs. The Social Safety Net - 2 The most important fundamental change is to realize that a more activist government will be necessary. If present economic trends continue (e.g., small increases in hourly wages for most middle and low-income workers, reduced employer provided health care and less generous and secure private sector retirement benefits), The Social Safety Net - 3 the obvious “solution” is to have the federal government provide the benefits that the private sector use to provide. This means having the federal government supplement wages (i.e., to provide cash payments to those who work but earn little), provide a health care benefits package to all citizens similar to Canada and Western Europe, provide child care/day care to working mothers and increase the amount of money Social Security provides to retirees. The Social Safety Net - 4 Concerning Social Security remember: 1.It Is LESS GENEROUS than similar programs in other wealthy democracies; 2. For TWO-THIRDS of the retired population it provides OVER HALF of their income and for ONE-THIRD of the retired population over 90% of their income; The Social Safety Net - 5 3. Is an “INSURANCE” against poverty for the elderly and income loss due to disability – to do this it MUST have GUARANTEED benefits; 4. As “INSURANCE” against poverty and disability it is NOT comparable to a risk-laden 401k plan; The Social Safety Net - 6 5. Future shortfalls in necessary revenues can EASILY be accomplished by having ALL income subject to the Social Security tax; 6. Future support for Social Security would be GREATLY weakened if ALL elderly did NOT receive benefits. The Social Safety Net - 7 One of the primary difficulties the United States faces in confronting growing inequality and poverty “head on” is the following core set of beliefs about poverty: (1) poverty is the fault of the victim; (2) economic growth will greatly reduce poverty; (3) government intervention will increase poverty. Each of these beliefs, at best, is “suspect. ” The Social Safety Net - 8 Greater economic growth does reduce the poverty rate in the U.S. However, what this means is that the U.S. poverty rate (typically around 17% of households - Great Britain and Canada around 12%, and the Scandinavian countries – Norway, Sweden and Denmark – around 6.5%) fluctuates around a much higher average than in other wealthy democracies and even at it’s lowest level, is much higher than most all other wealthy democracies. The Social Safety Net - 9 The “big picture”: the main reason that the U.S. has a much higher poverty rate than the vast bulk of wealthy democracies is that we don’t spend nearly as much of our economy in the following programs as do other wealthy democracies on income transfers (i.e., direct cash payments to either the unemployed or the working poor and the elderly) and do not providing comprehensive health insurance and childcare to all. The Social Safety Net - 10 Wage Subsidy: Assuming a minimum wage of $8 per hour, here’s how such a plan might operate: a worker earning the minimum wage of $8 per hour would receive a $4 per hour subsidy from the federal government (i.e., their “total wage” would be $12 per hour - $8 per hour from their employer plus $4 per hour from the federal government = $12 per hour) with the subsidy decreasing by 10% for each additional dollar per hour they earned. The Social Safety Net - 11 This plan does NOT increase unemployment because employers are NOT required to pay their employees more. Far from discouraging work and rewording laziness, the wage subsidy plan encourages work by making work pay more (i.e., the normal wage plus the value of the wage subsidy). The more work “pays”, the more leisure “costs” (i.e., each hour you don’t work costs you more when income per hour is higher than when it is lower). Since you have to work, this isn’t “welfare.” The Social Safety Net - 12 Furthermore, by making work pay more, and increasing the cost of not working in a legitimate occupation (e.g., selling drugs), the wage subsidy plan will reduce government expenditures by reducing the occurrence of two circumstances which increase government costs: (1) crime (by offering more money for being employed in non-criminal employment) and; (2) teen pregnancy (by increasing the cost of not working – having children typically reduces the hours a mother can or will work). Reaction to the Wage Subsidy Plan When a senior economic advisor to former President George W. Bush was asked about the wage plan he replied, “that’s the type of thing we’d do if we were serious.” Value of Education It is very important to mention the tremendous impact education has on earnings. In 1975 those with a bachelor’s degree out earned those with a high school diploma by approximately 60%. By 2008 this differential rose to approximately 100%. Unfortunately, the United States ranks 12th in the percentage of 25 to 34 year olds with at least an associate’s degree. The Social Safety Net - 11 In addition to the wage subsidy, other programs that would greatly benefit low and middle-income earners are: universal childcare, fully funding the Obama Health Care plan and the “Patriot Dollars” campaign finance plan. The Social Safety Net - 12 In all high-income countries, the parents’ socioeconomic status shapes a child’s educational and earnings prospects, but much less so in Sweden than elsewhere and much more so in the United States. In Sweden, even a child growing up in relative poverty has almost the same education and earnings prospects as a child growing up at the top on the income curve. The Social Safety Net - 13 Sweden’s distinction lies not in its support for public education, which is roughly matched by other countries, but in its public support for families and their children from the earliest age, even before formal schooling. All of Sweden’s families have access to affordable highquality day care, which is publicly provided. The Social Safety Net - 14 This enables mothers to work without leaving their children behind in an unsafe environment. Female heads of household, a group marked by a high rate of poverty in the United States, are not poor in Sweden. Remarkable, their poverty in Sweden, is only 4 percent, compared with the United States, where the Census Bureau recorded a 30 percent poverty rate in 2009. Similarly, all of Sweden’s children are afforded high-quality preschooling. The Social Safety Net - 15 The annual costs of these programs are: 1. wage subsidy ($150 billion) 2. universal childcare ($150 billion) 3. Obama Health Care Plan ($96 billion) 4. Patriot Dollars ($4 billion)_______ Total Annual Cost: $400 billion Note: wage subsidy costs over time are likely to be much lower than listed above The Social Safety Net - 16 Paying for the these programs: 1. Allowing the Bush Tax Cuts to expire will bring in approximately $363 billion per year. 2. Ackerman and Alstott’s Wealth Tax - a 2% annual wealth tax on households owning more than $7.2 million in assets (the richest ½ of 1% of households) would bring in at least $70 billion dollars per year – France, Norway and Switzerland have this The Social Safety Net - 17 If repealing the Bush Tax Cuts and instituting Ackerman and Alstott’s wealth tax seems “too hard” on the wealthy, consider the following: (1) the wealthy did very well, as did the economy as a whole, under the tax rates that would be in effect if the Bush Tax Cuts were allowed to expire (i.e., economic growth was greater under the higher tax rates of the Clinton Administration than during the Bush Administration); The Social Safety Net - 18 (2) over the 1980-2008 period 98% of the income gains went to the richest 10% of American households (i.e., exactly those that gained, by far, the most under the Bush Tax Cuts); (3) the share of income going to the richest 1% of American income earners more than doubled between 1970 and 2010 (from about 7% to over 18% of personal income); The Social Safety Net - 19 (4) reducing the concentration of income and wealth at the top of the income distribution would likely improve the performance of our democracy by reducing the previously discussed “debilitating cycle” (i.e., where the increasingly concentration of income and wealth among the very rich increases the reliance of politicians on campaign contributions from the very rich which, in turn, leads politicians to enact policies which further advantage the very rich); The Social Safety Net - 20 (5) many of the very rich inherited their wealth which rewards “luck” (you can’t pick your parents/grandparents) not “merit”; and The Social Safety Net - 21 (6) much of the income of very wealthy citizens was made possible by taxpayers. For example, while Henry Ford made a fortune from developing the Ford automobile, he wouldn’t have been successful unless taxpayers and/or government provided roads/highways, street lights, a public education system to provide an educated workforce to design, build and sell Ford cars, and a highway patrol to keep the highways safe. The Social Safety Net - 22 Similarly, would Bill Gates and Steve Jobs have been able to amass vast fortunes without the research and development provided by the National Science Foundation (an agency of the federal government which provided many of the protocols used for the internet) and the public school system to train the designers and builders of computers? The Social Safety Net - 23 In all of these cases, it is misleading to say that these individuals achieved their success “alone”, or without government help. Since taxpayers provided much of the requirements for their success, doesn’t it seem reasonable to suggest that taxpayers were investors in these projects and, as such, should reap the rewards of their investment (through tax payments)? The Social Safety Net - 24 Even if all of the preceding policy and tax changes were adopted, by comparison to the other wealthy democracies of the world the U.S. Social Safety net would still be “weak” and taxes would still be “very low.” It’s not “big government.” The Social Safety Net - 25 We could more than save the annual $400 billion cost of these programs by switching to a Canadian or European style health care system. The Social Safety Net – 26 If we adopted a European Health Care system taxes would increase, but this would be more than offset by the savings. For example, if your taxes increase by $100 per month, but your take-home pay increases by $200 per month (due to either less money deducted by your employer for health insurance) or your medical expenses decrease by $200 per month (by reducing the amount you have to pay out of your own pocket for health expenses), your standard of living would increase by $100 per month. Size of Government - 1 There are good reasons to think that the government budget is too small in a democracy. First, consider the power of advertising. Isn’t the purpose of the tremendous amount of advertising private companies buy to get you to spend money on their product rather on an alternative use of the same money (e.g., higher taxes to provide government benefits)? Size of Government - 2 Second, there is ample evidence that the public does not have a good sense of not only the benefits other citizens derive from government programs, but of the value they themselves derive from government programs. The percentage of people who (a) benefit from various government programs, and Size of Government - 3 (b) claim in response to a government survey that they 'have not used a government social program’ are as follows: Home Mortgage Interest Deduction (a huge benefit for home owners) – 60%, Student Loans – 53.3%, Child and Dependent Tax Credit – 51.7%, Earned Income Tax Credit – 47.1%, Pell Grants – 43.1%, Medicare – 39.8% and Food Stamps – 25.4%. Size of Government - 4 Third, many of those who most benefit from government programs vote the least frequently. As discussed in both class and the readings, lower income citizens disproportionately benefit from government social welfare programs. Additionally, lower income citizens vote less frequently than middle and upper income citizens. Size of Government - 5 Fourth, many upper income individuals might prefer a greater government effort to help the poor if they thought they might be poor in the future. It doesn’t take much “courage” to favor low taxes and oppose government spending to help the poor when the person in question, either by their current economic position (upper income) or a realistic assessment of their future economic position (e.g., being born into a wealthy family, being close to completing medical school, etc.) Size of Government - 6 strongly suggests that they aren’t likely to become poor. Would this same individual be as likely to oppose government programs for the poor if they did NOT know (or have a pretty good idea) of their future economic position? Size of Government - 7 So, wouldn’t the obvious political incentive be for politicians to provide lower government benefits to the poor than would be provided if the poor voted in proportion to their strength in the population? Size of Government - 8 A person’s political philosophy is likely to their willingness to spend money to reduce income inequality. If you are political liberal, you probably viewed the programs I mentioned previously (the wage subsidy, universal child care, the Obama Health Care Plan and the Patriot Dollars campaign finance reform) favorably. Size of Government - 9 However, if you are liberal you have to face the question of how far you would go (i.e., how much of your money would you spend) to reduce income inequality? Size of Government - 10 If you are politically conservative, a reasonable question to ask is: What are you trying to “conserve”? On the one hand you could answer that you were trying to conserve freedom and since taxes reduce a person’s freedom to spend their money as they please, then the government should be very small and taxes very low and, hence, you would probably not support the programs I mentioned previously. Size of Government - 11 That’s certainly a philosophically defensible position. It could be useful, however, to consider the following two questions: (1) Is freedom the only value that matters? (i.e., inequality, poverty, the performance of democracy – think back to the discussion of the “debilitating cycle” - don’t matter much); Size of Government - 12 (2) Does a small government actually deliver the most freedom? For example, would increase if: (1) the State of California sold off public beaches to private citizens and; (2) if taxes were reduced but fewer students could go to college and hence suffer a reduction in career choices later in life? Size of Government - 13 A second answer to the question of what you are trying to conserve might be as follows: an America where the benefits of economic growth and technological change are widely shared, such as occurred between the end of World War II (1945) and the early 1970s (i.e., where economic growth was high and the share of income going to very high income groups decreased substantially). If this is what you are trying to conserve, then the programs previously mentioned could be quite beneficial to your goal. Thiessen’s Comments - 1 Mitt Romney, the 2012 Republican Presidential nominee, said the following: “We have a very ample safety net, and we can talk about whether it needs to be strengthened or whether there are holes in it. But we have food stamps, we have Medicaid, we have housing vouchers, we have programs to help the poor.” Thiessen’s Comments - 2 Now the reaction to Romney’s comments from Washington Post editorial writer Marc Thiessen. “So Romney is fine with an entire class of Americans being permanently on food stamps, Medicaid, housing vouchers and other government welfare programs? His solution for our fellow citizens trapped in poverty and dependency is to find holes in the safety net and repair them? That is not conservatism. Thiessen’s Comments - 3 That is liberalism. The left judges compassion by how much money we spend, which is why the liberal project is to strengthen the safety net and grow the nanny state. The conservative project is to help people escape the safety net. Conservatives seek to create an opportunity society where we can lift people out of lives of dependency. Thiessen’s Comments - 4 That is liberalism. The left judges compassion by how much money we spend, which is why the liberal project is to strengthen the safety net and grow the nanny state. The conservative project is to help people escape the safety net. Conservatives seek to create an opportunity society where we can lift people out of lives of dependency. Thiessen’s Comments - 5 We are not okay with having millions of Americans trapped in poverty and living on the dole. We are not okay with multiple generations trapped in government welfare. We believe in a society where the poor have opportunities for advancement. Thiessen’s Comments - 6 We want them to have the education and skills they need to find good jobs, get off public assistance and to move up to the middle class and beyond-as far as their ambition and ability will take them.” Thiessen’s Comments - 7 First, our economy does not, and will not, generate sufficient jobs to employ all of the poor who want to work. The Great Recession, which began in late 2007, caused the economy to lose 8 million jobs. According to the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office, the unemployment rate is NOT expected to get as low as even 5% by 2016. Thiessen’s Comments - 8 Put another way, for the nine year period from 2007 through 2016, the unemployment rate would be high enough to leave several million job seekers without employment. How could these people be expected to work over this period when the jobs simply aren’t available? Thiessen’s Comments - 9 Furthermore, as explained very early in this writing, Republican/Conservative Administrations and politics weight reducing inflation more highly than Democratic/Liberal Administrations. Think back to the Obama Stimulus plan’s effect: unemployment was 1.7% lower than it otherwise would have been. Thiessen’s Comments - 10 As much research by political scientists and economists has found, more liberal administrations typically produce lower unemployment and higher inflation than conservative administrations (see earlier discussion and sources cited therein). So, the policies of the very philosophy Thiessen favors actually produces less employment, and hence, less opportunity for the poor than more liberal administrations/politicians. Thiessen’s Comments - 11 If the growth rate in the economy appeared to be high enough to actually employ all those who wanted to work, the inflation rate would move into, as policymakers see it, a danger zone. What would happen is that as economic growth exceed about 4% per year the federal reserve would raise interest rates, making borrowing more costly and, thus, ultimately reducing the economic growth rate and employment. Thiessen’s Comments - 12 Since the Great Recession started, millions of Americans cannot find work and the economy will not likely grow sufficiently to employ them for many years, if ever. Thiessen’s Comments - 13 Second, many jobs simply do not provide the level of compensation necessary to provide workers with a standard of living that Americans would consider “decent.” Working 40 hours per week, 50 weeks per year, at $9 per hour translates into an income of $18,000 per year. Most such jobs do not come with either health care or retirement benefits. Thiessen’s Comments - 14 Think of your family living on such an income. Is this how you want low wage workers to live? The very government programs Thiessen refers to are the only bulwark such low workers have against living on an income that does not adequately provide even the “essentials” of life. Think back to the discussion of the wage subsidy program. Thiessen’s Comments - 15 Take the food stamp program. Food stamps only provide approximately 70% of the money necessary to provide what the U.S. Department of Agriculture says is a nutritionally adequate diet Over three times as many households that receive food stamps had at least one worker than relied solely on government assistance. Thiessen’s Comments - 16 Finally, each $1 spent on the food stamp program generates $1.72 in economic activity. Think back to the previous discussion of how much economic activity per dollar spent was generated by other programs that benefit the poor (e.g., extending unemployment compensation - $1.60; payroll tax reduction - $1.09 or the wage subsidy program) versus Thiessen’s Comments - 17 the economic stimulation per dollar of the Bush Tax Cuts ($.35). Thus, the food stamp program helps generate the very economic activity that helps reduce the unemployment rate. Thiessen’s Comments - 18 Generations of the same family could not be on cash welfare for entire lifetimes because each person is restricted to 5 years. Second, Mitt Romney supports the previously discussed Ryan Budget, which will require large reductions in what is, by far, the weakest social safety net of any wealthy democracy in the world. Thiessen’s Comments - 19 No other wealthy democracy has pursued the type of system Thiessen desires. Third, the Ryan Budget, will require large spending reductions in exactly the types of programs (e.g., education) that would make the poor/unemployed more competitive in today’s labor market. Thiessen’s Comments - 20 Fourth, the previously discussed wage subsidy plan increases the incentive for people to work because it “makes work pay more” for low-income workers than it current does. Thus, if we adopted such a plan, it would use government programs to increase, not decrease, work effort. Thiessen’s Comments - 21 Wage Subsidy: Assuming a minimum wage of $8 per hour, here’s how such a plan might operate: a worker earning the minimum wage of $8 per hour would receive a $4 per hour subsidy from the federal government (i.e., their “total wage” would be $12 per hour - $8 per hour from their employer plus $4 per hour from the federal government = $12 per hour) with the subsidy decreasing by 10% for each additional dollar per hour they earned. Conclusions - 1 Budget Waste/Fraud: One of the most important findings from the study of citizen attitudes toward government programs is this: people typically think that unpopular spending programs (e.g., welfare and foreign aid) makeup a much larger share of the budget than they actually do. In studies I read many Americans think that welfare and foreign aid each account for 10%, or more, of federal spending. Actually, welfare and foreign aid each account for less than 1% of federal spending. Conclusions - 2 The error rate in the food stamp program is 2% (92% of the money goes to the beneficiaries). Since one-third of those eligible for food stamps do not receive them, we spend much less on food stamps than we would if fraud were completely eliminated and everyone who was eligible for foods stamps participated. Conclusions - 3 Eliminating politicians “pet projects” (e.g., “earmarks” – the famous “bridge to nowhere”) are .1% of GDP (i.e., one tenth of one percent). The “big picture” is that we will not meaningfully reduce the budget deficit by eliminating “waste, fraud and abuse.” Waste, fraud and abuse simply aren’t large enough to have a discernible impact on budgets. Conclusions - 4 The ingenuity of capitalism’s “creative destruction” means that business CANNOT pursue social goals/values over profitability. Thus, the very strength of capitalism is a prime reason why it can be argued that a strong social safety net is absolutely necessary. Conclusions - 5 None of this is to say that our current policies are “wrong” or that the conservative vision of low taxes, high levels of inequality and a low degree of economic security are “wrong.” However, if we want to provide greater economic security and reduce income inequality in America, there are very viable options to both our current policies and conservative proposals. Health Care - 1 I. Partisan Difference on Health Care A. Medicare – 1965 1. Presidential History a. Truman Health Care - 2 1. Due to absolutist individualism, Truman shifts from universal plan to Medicare b. Eisenhower c. Kennedy Health Care - 3 d. Johnson 1. 1964 election aids passage 2. Fewer than 30% of congressional Repubicans vote for Medicare Health Care - 4 2. Interest Groups – Medicare For Against AFL-CIO AMA NFU AFBF (small farmers) (large farmers) Health Care - 5 For Against CCUS (business) NAM (business) Blue Cross Health Care - 6 Note: (1) the relative wealth difference between the “for” and “against” groups; (2) “for” groups support Democrats while “against” groups support Republicans Health Care - 7 3. Ramifications a. Virtually impossible to repeal b. America lags well behind other wealthy democracies in both the time of adoption and the scope of coverage Health Care - 8 c. Incremental attempts to increase coverage can make it difficult to eventually cover everyone B. Clinton – 1994 1. Expansion of coverage again attempted by Democrats opposed by Republicans Health Care - 9 2. Almost identical interest group alignment as on Medicare C. Obama – 2009 1. Democrats try to expand coverage while Republicans oppose Health Care - 10 2. If fully implemented, would reduce uninsured rate from about 17% to about 3%. Health Care - 11 Rudy Giuliani: “The American way is not single-payer, government controlled anything. That’s a European way of doing something; that’s frankly a socialist way of doing something.” “That’s why when you hear Democrats in particular talk about single-mandated health care, universal health care, what they’re talking about is socialized medicine.” Health Care - 12 “That is where Hillary Clinton, Barack Obama and John Edwards are taking you,” he said, “You have got to see the trap. Otherwise we are in for a disaster. We are in for Canadian health care, French health care, British health care.” (“Giuliani Seeks to Transform U.S. Health Care Coverage,” Marc Santora, New York Times, August 1, 2007) Health Care - 13 II. Comparison of U.S. and Foreign Health Care Systems Per Capita WHO Spending Ranking U.S. $5,711 37th France $3,048 1st Canada $2,998 30th U.K. $2,317 18th Health Care - 14 A. Why do the others do better at lower cost? 1.Require Everyone to Buy Insurance a. adverse selection if people aren’t required to buy insurance Health Care - 15 b. Need a strong minimum benefits package-must shift costs to the healthy 2. Single-Payer Plans have much Lower Administrative Costs 3. Government Bulk Buying of Medicine Health Care - 16 4. Pay Doctors Less Question: If we are measuring “wait times” for a procedure should we start when your physician recommends the procedure or when it is medically advisable? Remember 18% of Americans don’t have a physician and Americans see doctors less frequently than in Europe/Canada. U.S. “wait times” are longer than frequently stated. Health Care - 17 A thought: Isn’t there a tension between opposing government regulation of behavior with health consequences (e.g., cigarette taxes, soda taxes, meat taxes, etc.) and believing in personal responsibility? The least regulatory, or “smallest government,” may not be the government that most fosters personal responsibility. Especially when personal irresponsibility imposes costs on others (i.e., people whom my costly actions shouldn’t harm). Health Care - 18 Not only do all other wealthy democracies in the world cover all their citizens for health care, even poorer nations are moving in this direction: (1) China has a 3-year initiative that will cover 90% of it’s population; (2) Mexico just completed an 8-year drive for universal coverage; and (3) in Thailand, where per capita GDP is one-fifth of America’s, 99% of the population has health insurance. Health Care - 19 Dr. Julio Frenk, Dean of the Harvard School of Public Health: “As countries advance, they are realizing that creating universal healthcare systems is a necessity for long-term economic development.” This is leaving America behind. “We are really an outlier,” said David DeFerranti, a former World Bank vide president. (source for last two slides, Los Angeles Times, May 12, 2012) California Budget - 1 I. Why it is Difficult for the California Legislature to Adopt a Budget A. Public Expectations California Budget - 2 1. 50% of California Voters thought that State Spending Could be Reduced 20% Without Reducing Services California Budget - 3 2. Voter Backed Initiatives Mandate Spending and Reduce the Options of the Legislature a. Among the 24 states that permit initiatives, California is the only one that does NOT permit the legislature to amend or repeal them. California Budget - 4 B. Two-Thirds Vote of Both Houses of the California Legislature is Required to Raise Taxes and Many Fees 1. Only 7 States Require This California Budget - 5 2. The Majority Party Typically Holds Less Than 2/3rds of the Legislature 3. Very Different Party Coalitions Reduce Chance of Republican Support for Tax/Fee Increases California Budget - 6 C. Most Legislative Districts are Not Politically Competitive 1. Greater Socioeconomic Difference Between Counties Over Time California Budget - 7 2. Real Election is Often in the Primary 3. Compromising with the Opposition Party Could Lead to a Primary Challenger California Budget - 8 D. As the Distribution of Income has Become Much Less Equal in California, the Policy Differences Between the Two Major Political Parties have Noticeably Increased. California Budget - 9 1. This Reduces the Ability to Achieve Compromise E. About the Only Policy Area Californians are Willing to Cut is Prisons 1. Don’t Want to Cut Education – Which is a Big Budget Item California Budget - 10 1. Voter Backed Initiatives Require Long Prison Sentences 2. Think of the Public Outrage if We Released Prisoners Early Who Then Committed Crimes. California Budget - 11 II. California’s Structural Budget Deficit is Approximately 15 Billion Dollars. A. The Structural Deficit is about 10%-15% of the Size of the Budget California Budget - 12 B. Solutions: Short-Term 1. Formula from the Past: Temporary Tax Increases and Spending Cuts California Budget - 13 C. Long-Term 1. Spending Cuts Alone Won’t Work a. Firing ALL State Workers Paid from the General Fund would save about 9.2 billion California Budget - 14 (California Currently Ranks 46th in State Employees as a Percentage of the Population – Not “Big Government!) b. Eliminating ALL funding for CSU and UC would only save 5.4 billion. California Budget - 15 c. Eliminating the ENTIRE Cal Works Welfare Program would save 3 billion. d. Closing ALL Prisons would save 9 billion. California Budget - 16 D. Public Employees 1. Government typically pays LESS than the private sector for comparable work. 2. Top Government Officials are paid MUCH less than Private Sector. California Budget - 17 3. State Workers in California are Typically Paid More than in Most States. a. However, 50% of the difference is due to the higher cost of living in California. California Budget - 18 4. Pensions a. Few State Workers can Retire at age 50! b. Pensions were one of the few politically accepted ways of increasing compensation. California Budget - 19 c. Thus, if we reduce pensions, then we owe state workers the pay they gave up in order to get better pension benefits. California Budget - 20 E. Revenue Increases Will be Needed 1. Overturn the 2/3rds Vote Needed to Raise Taxes and Fees a. Representation/Fairness – majority vote needed California Budget - 21 2. Taxes are NOT High or Very Progressive in either the United States as a whole or in California a. Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies: U.S. - 27%, Canada – 34%, Germany – 35%, Great Britain – 37%, Italy – 41%, France – 44% and Sweden - 51%. California Budget - 22 b. Federal Taxes - All federal taxes together (i.e., income taxes, Social Security taxes, etc.) take approximately 9.4% of the income of households making $16,000 per year, approximately 20.5% of the income of households making $52,000, approximately 27.2% of the income of households making $200,000 per year and approximately 34% of households making $18,000,000 per year. California Budget - 23 It is very important to mention that federal taxes have been made much LESS progressive over time. To demonstrate the impact of reduced federal tax progressivity consider the following: In 2000, the richest 1 household in 1,000 (i.e., .1 of 1%) had about 7.3% of total national after-tax income. If the effect of taxes on their income had remained what it was in 1970, they would have had about 4.5% of after-tax national income. California Budget - 24 C. State and local taxes are even LESS progressive than federal taxes. Thus, if you add state and local taxes to federal taxes (i.e., to obtain “total taxes”) the tax burden is less favorable to the poor (i.e., less progressive) than for federal taxes alone. State and Local Taxes are a greater percentage of personal income for the poorest 20% of a state’s households than for the wealthiest 1% of a state’s households in virtually every state. California Budget - 25 In California state and local taxes take approximately 11.3% of the income of the poorest 20% of households while taking only 7.2% of the income of the richest 1% of households. California Budget - 26 In California, the wealthiest 10% of the taxpayers pay approximately 75% of the state income tax. While true, this argument is misleading for two reasons: (1) the most important consideration is taxes as a percentage of income and not the percentage of a tax borne by a particular income group – thus, if California’s state income tax was only to raise $1 and Steven Spielberg paid that $1 he would have borne 100% of the state income tax burden – California Budget - 27 however, $1 would be virtually 0% of his income – thus it’s the percentage of income paid in a tax and not the percentage of a tax that a particular income group pays that is the important consideration; (2) this calculation excludes all taxes except the income tax (e.g., state sales taxes, property taxes, etc.) – when we include all state and local taxes and fees, state and local taxes are a higher percentage of income for the very poor than the very rich. California Budget - 28 F. Some state tax increases would IMPROVE the functioning of California’s economy and raise revenue: a. tax services – no economic rationale for not taxing them California Budget - 29 b. change business property taxes annually (i.e., not only when the property is sold) - current practice favors those who hold a property longer – harms new businesses; California Budget - 30 c. tax carbon, pollution and oil - from an economic standpoint, the cost of pollution should be taxed to provide the appropriate disincentives to reduce pollution. Currently, California is the only oil producing state that does not have a severance tax on oil. 1. New “Cap and Trade” System. California Budget - 31 G. State Spending Has NOT kept pace with either Inflation/Population or Personal Income 1. Adjusting for population growth and inflation, to maintain the SAME level of service in 2009 that the state of California provided in 1999 state spending would have had to increase by 53%. It only increased by 29%. California Budget - 32 2. In 1980 California General Fund Expenditures (i.e., state spending) was 7.4% of personal income. For 2009-2010, this figure had dropped to only 5.5%. California Budget - 33 3. As a share of personal income, California typically ranks about 18th (out of 50 states) in state and local tax burden with state and local revenues equal to approximately 17% of personal income. Libertarianism - 1 I. Libertarianism A. World View – Most Everything flows from selfishness B. Goal - Maximizes the "Freedom To“ in both economic and noneconomic situations Libertarianism - 2 B. Method – The Free Market 1. Definition – voluntary exchanges between mutually consenting individuals C. Economic freedom (the free market) is part of total Freedom and a precondition of political freedom Libertarianism - 3 1. In this view political freedom depends upon economic freedom – not the other way around. 2. When the Soviet Union collapsed the opposite happened: political freedom preceded economic freedom. Libertarianism - 4 D. An individual must be able to earn a living in order to use political freedom. E. The Free Market accomplishes this by two methods: Libertarianism - 5 1. It increases the number of decisions necessary to restrict, or eliminate, someone’s livelihood. 2. It encourages economic decisions (buy/sell decisions) to be made on the basis of production factors (e.g., quality or price) as opposed to nonproduction factors (e.g., the race or political views of the workforce). Libertarianism - 6 3. Since government can only institute one set of priorities libertarians see governmental action as a restriction of individual free choice. 4. Therefore, libertarians largely reduce the government to umpire like functions (e.g., antitrust, police, military) Libertarianism - 7 II. Critique of Libertarianism A. Goals – Doesn’t any goal other than free choice matter (e.g., political and economic inequality, mobility, security or stability)? Libertarianism - 8 B. Methods – Is an extremely strong reliance on the free market the best way to maximize freedom? C. Libertarians assume that at any one point in time the number of free decisions is fixed – thus if government makes more of them individuals will make fewer of them. Libertarianism - 9 1. The number of decisions isn’t fixed. For example, consider public transportation: while the taxes paid to build it may reduce personal freedom the public transportation system increases personal freedom. 2. How much freedom to use the beach would we have if the beaches were privately, rather than governmentally, owned? Libertarianism - 10 3. By not having universal health care in the U.S. we have approximately 18,000 additional deaths per year. You can’t make many free decisions after you’re dead! Libertarianism - 11 4. Even if you accept the goal of maximizing individual free choice: Is the “freedom to" maximized by (1) removing force (e.g., not having to pay Social Security taxes) - with the possibility of economic hardship, or (2) reducing economic hardship - with the possibility of political restraints (e.g., not protesting government policy because you fear the loss of government benefits) ? 5. Libertarians must opt for option #1 above. Libertarianism - 12 6. Think of the reductions in personal freedom through laws/political actions that have resulted from economic hardship (e.g., Hilter, Proposition 187 in California, etc.). 7. There is little evidence that citizens in democracies with extensive social safety nets (e.g., Sweden) are afraid to speak out against government policy. Final Exam Essay - 1 DON’T WRITE DOWN ANY OF THE MATERIAL OVER THE NEXT GROUP OF SLIDES. ALL OF IT IS IN THE LAST 6 PAGES OF THE COURSEPACK. JUST LISTEN TO THE DISCUSSION! Final Exam Essay - 2 THE FINAL EXAM ESSAY IS TO BE DONE OUTSIDE OF CLASS AND SUBMITTED AT THE TIME OF THE FINAL EXAMINATION. YOU NEED TO SUBMIT A “HARD COPY” OF THE ESSAY WHEN YOU TAKE THE FINAL EXAM. DO NOT EMAIL A COPY TO ME. Final Exam Essay - 3 Since you will be a voter, a critical topic in this class concerns the choices the political parties offer voters. To examine this in Congress, select an issue that was voted on by either the House of Representatives or the Senate. The vote you choose can be either recent, or from the distant past. Since political party differences can only occur where there is controversy, select a vote where at least 20% of those voting voted on the losing side. Final Exam Essay - 4 For example, if the vote in the House of Representative is 70 "yes" and 330 "no" the vote was not sufficiently conflictual. However, had the vote been 80-320, 320-80 (or closer) it would have been “okay.” Similarly, if a Senate vote is 8218, you could not use it. It makes NO difference if the legislation was “passed” or “defeated.” Final Exam Essay - 5 The source you are required to use is Congressional Quarterly Weekly. You will find instructions for accessing CQ Weekly in the coursepack. If for any reason you cannot access CQ Weekly, there is an alternative website mentioned on the very last page of the coursepack. “Google” your topic (e.g., U.S. Senate voting on health care) to find the date of a vote. Final Exam Essay - 6 When examining a vote make sure you do not confuse voting "yes" or "no" with supporting the concept. Let me explain. If the legislature is voting on a motion to "table" or "recommit" the legislation, voting "yes" on such a motion is to oppose the actual bill (if the legislature votes to "table" a bill then the bill will not be voted on). Final Exam Essay - 7 If the bill is not voted on it could not be passed. Therefore, voting "yes" on a motion to "table" the bill has the same effect as voting "no" on the bill itself. Additionally, the word "strike" means to remove (i.e., take out or delete). Finally, “substitute” means to replace part of the legislation (e.g., “substitute” 6 months for 3 months). Final Exam Essay - 8 You may want to use a vote on an "amendment" to the proposed legislation. Amendments modify (i.e., change) the legislation. Much of the most interesting legislative "action" is on amendments. Final Exam Essay - 9 This assignment is worth 30 points and a “hard copy” is due (typed) at the time of the final examination. Scores are lowered 10 points per day late (later on the day of the final exam also counts as one day late). NO excuses (e.g., my printer ran out of ink) will be accepted. That’s why you should start EARLY! Assume there will be problems. Final Exam Essay - 10 Additionally, you CANNOT use a computer malfunction as an excuse to take the final exam later. If you can’t bring a printed copy of the essay at the time of the final exam, your best approach is to email the paper and pay the “10 point penalty.” Final Exam Essay - 11 The following information is from the two page sample essay that appears in the coursepack. The discussion of “how” to obtain the congressional vote you will use is placed AFTER the sample term paper. Thus, don’t “panic” when you see a sample term in the coursepack and don’t yet have your vote. It’s all explained. Just read the 6 pages!! Final Exam Essay - 12 Issue and Importance (<<use headings) In order to provide the funds for governmental projects, citizens pay taxes. Since taxes can be a sizeable expenditure for many families and individuals, the question of who bears the tax burden becomes important. Final Exam Essay - 13 Several years ago the U.S. Senate voted on an amendment offered by Senator Gore (DTennessee) that would have raised income taxes on high income groups and reduced proposed increases in taxes that would primarily fall on middle and low income groups (CQ Weekly Report, October 27, 1990, page 3655 – if you are using the internet version you will not have a page number). Final Exam Essay - 14 The purpose of this paper is to examine how Democratic and Republican senators voted on the Gore Amendment. We shall now develop a hypothesis concerning how we would expect Democratic and Republican senators to vote on the Gore Amendment. Final Exam Essay - 15 Hypothesis As discussed in class, political issues can typically be thought of as primarily either economic or noneconomic (lecture of 3/30/10 - if you do not "date" your notes, estimate the date). Taxation would clearly be an economic issue. Final Exam Essay - 16 Furthermore, liberal and conservative political ideologies take very different positions on economic issues. Liberals tend to think the government should try to minimize economic inequality and maintain economic security whereas conservatives value freedom of choice most highly with economic equality being much less important (lecture of 3/30/10). Final Exam Essay - 17 Additionally, class lecture has stressed that Democratic officeholders are typically more liberal (or less conservative) than Republican officeholders (lecture of 3/30/10). Since the Gore Amendment would raise taxes on high income groups and reduce proposed tax increases on middle and low-income groups, it is probably best classified as a liberal proposal. Final Exam Essay - 18 As Democratic senators are likely to be more liberal than Republican senators the following hypothesis seems reasonable: H1 Democratic senators are more likely to vote in favor of the Gore Amendment than Republican senators. (Note: phrased in probabalistic – i.e., “more likely” and not “certain” terms) Final Exam Essay - 19 Findings The Gore Amendment was voted on by the United States Senate on October 18, 1990. The amendment was defeated by a vote of 45 to 55 (i.e., 45 senators voted "yes" while 55 senators voted "no" - CQ Weekly Report, October 27, 1990, page 3655). Final Exam Essay - 20 Therefore, the Gore Amendment meets the criteria that at least 20% of those voting voted on the losing side (i.e., 45 out of 100 = 45% and 45% is equal to or greater than 20%). Final Exam Essay - 21 Among Democratic senators, 67% voted in favor (i.e., "yes") on the Gore Amendment [37-18 and 37/(37+18) = 37/55 = .67]. By contrast, only 18% of the Republican senators voted in favor of the Gore Amendment [8-37 and 8/(8+37) = 8/45 = .18]. (NOTE: you need to calculate percentages and NOT say the vote was “37-18” to “8-37”) Final Exam Essay - 22 Since Democratic senators were much more likely to vote in favor of the Gore Amendment than Republican senators (67% vs. 18%) the results offer strong support for the hypothesis. Final Exam Essay - 23 Implications In this section of the paper you need to put your findings in a wider perspective. Thus, are the differences between Democratic and Republican officeholders on the Gore Amendment similar to their differences on other economic issues? If so, what does this tell you about American politics? If not, why? Final Exam Essay - 24 In the implications section you need to cite pages from the assigned readings. The sample essay contains page numbers from the assigned readings that deal with party differences. Remember! 1. Do NOT advocate a particular policy or make “value judgments.” Remember, you’re an analyst, NOT an advocate. 2. Do NOT make statements that imply there is only one correct viewpoint (e.g., do NOT say something such as “any rational educated mind …”). 3. Do NOT use the first person or offer opinions (i.e., do NOT say “I think that …” or “I feel that”). Final Exam Essay - 25 In addition to substance, grammar, and neatness, points will be subtracted from your score for each of the following: (1) Not calculating the percentage (i.e., NOT the number but the percentage) of Democratic legislators and the percentage of Republican legislators who voted "yes" on the proposal (5 points). Final Exam Essay - 26 (2) Not citing specific pages from the textbook in the "Implications" section of the paper (5 points). (3) Not stapling a copy of your vote (i.e., printout a copy of the vote) to your paper (5 points). Final Exam Essay - 27 (4) Untyped papers will not be accepted. (5) You need to STAPLE your paper (i.e,. NO “DOG EARED” PAPERS – this will cost 5 points). Late papers lose 10 points per day. Essays turned in after the final exam period are counted as one day late.